Council Tree Investors Inc v. FCC , 863 F.3d 237 ( 2017 )


Menu:
  •                                          PRECEDENTIAL
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    ___________
    No. 15-3754
    ___________
    COUNCIL TREE INVESTORS, INC.,
    Petitioner
    v.
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION;
    UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
    Respondents
    __________
    On Petition for Review of Orders of
    the Federal Communications Commission
    (FCC 15-80 & DA 15-1183)
    ___________
    Argued March 7, 2017
    Before: SMITH, Chief Judge, HARDIMAN, and KRAUSE,
    Circuit Judges.
    (Filed: July 13, 2017)
    Kevin Russell [Argued]
    Goldstein & Russell
    7475 Wisconsin Avenue, Suite 850
    Bethesda, MD 20814
    Attorney for Petitioner
    Jacob M. Lewis
    Clifford G. Pash, Jr. [Argued]
    Federal Communications Commission
    445 12th Street, S.W.
    Washington, DC 20554
    Attorneys for Respondent Federal Communications
    Commission
    Robert B. Nicholson
    Robert J. Wiggers
    United States Department of Justice, Appellate Section
    950 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W.
    Washington, DC 20530
    Attorneys for Respondent United States of America
    Carl W. Northrop
    Telecommunications Law Professionals
    1025 Connecticut Avenue, N.W., Suite 1011
    Washington, DC 20036
    Attorney for Amicus Petitioners
    ____________
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    ____________
    2
    HARDIMAN, Circuit Judge.
    This case involves the regulation of electromagnetic
    spectrum by the Federal Communications Commission. In
    1993, Congress amended the Communications Act of 1934,
    47 U.S.C. §§ 151–622, to allow the FCC to grant spectrum
    licenses through a system of competitive bidding. 47 U.S.C.
    § 309(j)(1), (3). The Act requires the FCC to pursue certain
    objectives required by statute, including
    promoting     economic      opportunity   and
    competition and ensuring that new and
    innovative technologies are readily accessible
    to the American people by avoiding excessive
    concentration of licenses and by disseminating
    licenses among a wide variety of applicants,
    including small businesses, rural telephone
    companies, and businesses owned by members
    of minority groups and women.
    47 U.S.C. § 309(j)(3)(B). In FCC parlance, these groups are
    known as designated entities (DEs). 47 C.F.R. § 1.2110(a). At
    this time, the FCC’s “principal means of fulfilling the
    statutory objectives for DEs” is to confer bidding credits upon
    small and rural businesses that participate in FCC auctions.
    Updating Competitive Bidding Rules, 80 Fed. Reg. 56764,
    56766 (September 18, 2015). Bidding credits operate as a
    discount on the spectrum DEs purchase, allowing them
    sometimes to outbid companies that make higher bids.
    3
    Council Tree Comm’ns, Inc. v. FCC, 
    619 F.3d 235
    , 239 (3d
    Cir. 2010) (Council Tree III).1
    The question presented here is whether the FCC acted
    legally when it limited the bidding credits available to DEs.
    We hold that it did.
    I
    In 2014, the FCC began a rulemaking proceeding in
    advance of a special 2016–17 Incentive Auction of “scarce
    low-band radio spectrum.” FCC Br. 13. According to its
    Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, the FCC thought it
    appropriate to
    revisit the Commission’s small business
    eligibility rules and evaluate whether to
    rebalance our competing goals in order to
    provide      small     businesses    additional
    opportunities to gain access to new sources of
    capital necessary for participation in the
    provision of spectrum-based services in today’s
    marketplace, while guarding against unjust
    enrichment of ineligible entities.
    1
    Like the parties, we refer to our 2010 decision as
    Council Tree III as it was preceded by two prior challenges to
    the same rulemaking. See Council Tree Commc’ns v. FCC,
    324 F. App’x 3 (D.C. Cir. 2009) (Council Tree II); Council
    Tree Commc’ns v. FCC, 
    503 F.3d 284
    (3d Cir. 2007)
    (Council Tree I).
    4
    29 FCC Rcd. 12426 (2014), 
    2014 WL 5088195
    at *7. The
    FCC later indicated in April 2015 that it was specifically
    considering a proposal to cap available DE credits within
    “any given auction” in order to “ensure that DEs cannot
    acquire spectrum in a manner that is wildly disproportionate
    to the concept of a small business.” Request for Further
    Comment, 30 FCC Rcd. 4153, 4158 (2015) (citations
    omitted).
    On July 21, 2015, the FCC concluded its rulemaking
    and released a final Report and Order entitled In the Matter of
    Updating Part I Competitive Bidding Rules, et al., 30 FCC
    Rcd. 7493 (2015) (hereinafter Order), published at 80 Fed.
    Reg. 56764 (Sept. 18, 2015). In the Order, the FCC issued a
    series of new rules, some designed to assist DEs and others
    intended to rein in perceived abuses of the DE program. New
    rules designed to assist DEs included: “greater flexibility” as
    to certain eligibility requirements, 30 FCC Rcd. at 7504, the
    creation of a “new bidding credit for eligible rural service
    providers,” 
    id. at 7521,
    and raising the revenue ceiling to
    qualify for DE credits. New measures intended to curb abuses
    included: revenue attribution rules designed to “restric[t]
    certain large carriers or companies from . . . exercising
    control over a DE,” 
    id. at 7511,
    limitations on joint bidding
    arrangements, and the rule at issue in this case: caps on
    bidding credits.
    Though the FCC determined generally that small
    business credits should be capped in future auctions, it did not
    mandate a particular dollar value for those caps. Rather, it
    determined that any future cap would be at least $25 million
    per auction. In doing so, the FCC noted that most DEs in
    three recent auctions would not have qualified for more than
    $25 million in bidding credits. The FCC also determined that
    5
    the $25 million minimum would “allow bona fide small
    businesses” to participate meaningfully in auctions,
    particularly “taking into account the changes we make today
    to increase a DE’s flexibility in other respects.” 
    Id. at 7541.
    Looking to the special 2016–17 Incentive Auction, the FCC
    decided to cap bidding credits at $150 million (well over the
    $25 million minimum) because of the “significant difference
    in value between low-band and higher-band spectrum.” 
    Id. at 7545.
    Based on data from prior auctions,2 the FCC predicted
    that the “cap would give small businesses a meaningful
    opportunity to compete” for available licenses in both large
    and small areas. 
    Id. On November
    13, 2015, Appellant Council Tree—a
    DE which had opposed caps during the rulemaking—filed a
    petition in this Court for review of the Order, claiming
    violations of the Administrative Procedure Act and the
    Communications Act.
    II
    We have jurisdiction over Council Tree’s petition
    under 47 U.S.C. § 402(a) and 28 U.S.C. § 2342(1). We
    2
    The FCC noted that in the three recent auctions
    previously discussed, nearly all DE bids would have been
    unaffected by this cap. Furthermore, reviewing the most
    recent of those three auctions and making appropriate price
    adjustments, the FCC predicted “a $150 million cap would
    not affect a 15 percent or 25 percent bidding credit discount
    for any individual license bid except in the top two markets
    (NY and LA).” 30 FCC Rcd. at 7545.
    6
    review “agency action, findings, and conclusions” to
    determine whether they are “arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of
    discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with law.” 5 U.S.C.
    § 706(2). Agency action is not arbitrary and capricious when
    the agency “examine[d] the relevant data and articulate[d] a
    satisfactory explanation for its action including a rational
    connection between the facts found and the choice made.”
    Council Tree 
    III, 619 F.3d at 250
    (quoting Motor Vehicle
    Mfrs. Ass’n of U.S. v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 
    463 U.S. 29
    , 43 (1983)).
    III
    Council Tree seeks review of the FCC’s Order for
    three reasons. First, it claims the FCC’s explanation of its
    new rule ignored its statutory obligation to promote
    competition and avoid excessive concentration of licenses.
    Second, it argues the imposition of any cap on bidding credits
    was arbitrary and capricious because the FCC lacked
    evidence that the DE designation was being abused. Third, it
    contends the FCC set both its general minimum cap and the
    specific Incentive Auction cap in an arbitrary and capricious
    manner because these particular caps are unsupported by the
    data. We examine each argument in turn.
    A
    In designing its competitive bidding process, the FCC
    is bound by statute to “promot[e] economic opportunity and
    competition . . . by avoiding excessive concentration of
    licenses.” 47 U.S.C. § 309(j)(3)(B). Council Tree claims the
    FCC violated its obligation to promote these two objectives
    by not “considering the caps’ anti-competitive effects” or
    “explaining the agency’s reasoning” in how it balanced
    7
    concern for competition against its other statutory objectives.
    Council Tree Br. 28.
    In Council Tree III, we considered a similar challenge
    to the FCC’s imposition of a rule restricting the ability of DEs
    to lease or resell their spectrum capacity, which also was
    aimed at addressing abuse of the DE designation. See Council
    Tree 
    III, 619 F.3d at 251
    . As part of its challenge in that case,
    Council Tree claimed the FCC had violated its statutory duty
    to promote “economic opportunity and competition . . . by
    avoiding excessive concentration of licenses and by
    disseminating licenses among a wide variety of applicants”—
    since such a rule was likely to impede DEs’ profits and
    growth. 
    Id. at 249
    n.7 (alteration in original) (quoting 47
    U.S.C. § 309(j)(3)(B)).
    We rejected that argument. We noted the FCC’s new
    policy served other statutory objectives, including its
    obligation to “recover a portion of the value of the spectrum
    and prevent unjust enrichment.” 
    Id. (citing 47
    U.S.C.
    § 309(j)(3)(C)). Citing both “the general agreement that the
    DE program can be abused, [and] the continuing participation
    by DEs in auctions held under the new rules,” we could not
    “conclude that the FCC has failed to promote small-business
    participation at all.” 
    Id. We also
    recognized that the
    administrative “record reflect[ed] the FCC’s cognizance of
    the capitalization issue, and that it engaged in a line-drawing
    exercise in an attempt to prevent unjust enrichment without
    unduly impairing DEs’ capital access.” 
    Id. at 251–52.
    The FCC’s Order at issue in this appeal did more than
    take cognizance of the issue of DEs’ competitiveness. It
    reviewed data from past auctions before concluding that the
    cap would not significantly impair the ability of DEs (in the
    8
    aggregate) to compete in auctions. See, e.g., 30 FCC Rcd. at
    7541 (explaining the cap floor with reference to prior DE
    auction participation); 
    id. at 7545–46
    (justifying the $150
    million cap with reference to past auction results and pricing
    in different markets). The FCC also noted its bidding credit
    cap was paired with regulations that increased flexibility for
    DEs seeking to obtain capital, bolstering its conclusion that
    DEs would still be able to compete in the spectrum license
    market. See 
    id. at 7541
    (referring to the adjusted policy of
    when an investor’s revenue will be attributed to a DE,
    detailed at 30 FCC Rcd. 7502–21). The FCC therefore not
    only set forth a policy that is likely to allow continued
    participation by DEs, but also rationally explained why it
    expected no significant loss of DE participation. As such,
    under the standard we articulated in Council Tree III, the FCC
    did not fail to consider DEs’ ability to compete for licenses.
    Council Tree responds that the statements just noted
    did not relate to the FCC’s obligations to promote
    competition or avoid excessive concentration of licenses at
    all. Rather, they related only to the FCC’s obligation to
    “promote economic opportunity” for DEs. Council Tree Br.
    37. This strikes us as an artificial distinction. The relevant
    statutory language (47 U.S.C. § 309(j)(3)(B)) links these
    goals together because they are inextricable. When the FCC
    helps small businesses compete in the marketplace against
    large telecommunications providers, it necessarily increases
    competition for licenses and reduces license concentration.
    What Council Tree seems to suggest is that an
    appropriate analysis by the FCC would not have assessed
    only whether DEs could continue to participate at near-
    current levels, but also would have considered whether their
    current level of competition is adequate to challenge our
    9
    telecommunications quadropoly. See, e.g., Council Tree Br.
    15 & n.31 (referring to the “Big Four” of AT&T, Verizon,
    Sprint, and T-Mobile); 
    id. at 37
    (explaining that “the caps’
    effect on the amount of spectrum,” rather than the number of
    DEs affected by the cap, is “far more relevant” to assessing
    competition); 
    id. at 38
    (using auction data to show a mid-level
    DE capped at the minimum of $25 million in bidding credits
    would more than exhaust its credits to win a single license in
    most major markets). The problem with this approach is that
    it adds requirements to the statute not found in the text. The
    FCC’s statutory obligation is to ensure that its bidding system
    promotes competition and the broad dissemination of
    licenses, while also abiding by its obligations to, inter alia,
    “recove[r] for the public a portion of the value” of the
    spectrum licenses sold, avoid “unjust enrichment,” and ensure
    efficient use of spectrum. 47 U.S.C. § 309(j)(3)(B)–(D). As
    much as Council Tree would like the FCC to not merely
    promote, but maximize, competition against the Big Four,
    § 309 creates no such obligation. And insofar as Council Tree
    comes close to defining “competition” as “competition to [the
    market share of] incumbents in large urban markets, or on a
    regional or national scale,” Council Tree Br. 37, we will not
    insert this limiting language into the statute. See Alabama v.
    North Carolina, 
    560 U.S. 330
    , 352 (2010) (“We do not—we
    cannot—add provisions to a federal statute.”)
    The FCC’s Order: (1) preserved a significant bidding
    credit program; (2) reviewed data suggesting DE participation
    would continue despite the proposed caps; and (3) altered
    other rules to make DEs more competitive. We therefore
    “cannot conclude that the FCC has failed to promote small-
    business participation at all,” Council Tree 
    III, 619 F.3d at 249
    n.7, or that the Order at issue in this case failed to
    10
    promote the FCC’s dual objectives of competition and
    reduced concentration of licenses, see 47 U.S.C.
    § 309(j)(3)(B).
    B
    Council Tree argues that even if the FCC considered
    its statutory objectives under 47 U.S.C. § 309(j), it violated 5
    U.S.C. § 706 by arbitrarily and capriciously imposing caps on
    bidding credits. According to Council Tree, the FCC was
    chasing a phantom because its Order provides no evidence
    that DEs are “gaming the rules” or that DE investors are
    “unjustly enriched.” Council Tree Br. 28–29.
    It is true that the FCC’s Order did little to assess the
    scope and substantiality of the harm posed by large
    companies abusing the DE process. See 30 FCC Rcd. at
    7540–41 (discussing concern for “discourag[ing] entities that
    seek to game the Commission’s rules at taxpayer expense”
    without estimating that expense). However, as we stated in
    Council Tree III, there is at least “general agreement that the
    DE program can be abused” by larger 
    companies. 619 F.3d at 249
    n.7. Council Tree itself acknowledges, though it
    minimizes, complaints made to the FCC about one
    telecommunications company—DISH—abusing the DE
    program in a recent auction by allegedly exercising control
    over DE bidders. And the FCC articulated a concern
    regarding increased incentives for abuse, noting “that, as the
    cost of spectrum continues to grow, the incentives for
    structuring transactions to obtain bidding discounts increase[]
    significantly.” 30 FCC Rcd. at 7540.
    In reviewing the FCC’s explanation for imposing its
    caps, we do not ask whether it would persuade us to impose
    11
    the same policy. We instead consider whether the agency
    “examine[d] the relevant data and articulate[d] a satisfactory
    explanation for its action including a rational connection
    between the facts found and the choice made.” Council Tree
    
    III, 619 F.3d at 250
    (quoting State 
    Farm, 463 U.S. at 43
    ).
    Here, the FCC identified a threat (abuse of the DE
    designation) to one of its statutory objectives (preventing
    unjust enrichment), and adopted a prophylactic measure. We
    see no reason to bar such measures as a general matter. See
    Stillwell v. Office of Thrift Supervision, 
    569 F.3d 514
    , 519
    (D.C. Cir. 2009) (“[A]gencies can, of course, adopt
    prophylactic rules to prevent potential problems before they
    arise.”).
    It would, of course, be preferable to have some
    estimate of the unjust enrichment that would have been
    anticipated had the FCC not capped bidding credits. And
    perhaps a prophylactic rule could be irrational if an agency
    (1) made no effort to measure its benefits, and (2) its impact
    on other statutory obligations was also unassessed (or
    negative). See, e.g., Prometheus Radio Project v. FCC, 
    652 F.3d 431
    , 469-72 (3d Cir. 2011). But as explained in Part III-
    
    A, supra
    , the FCC articulated a rational explanation, based on
    relevant data, as to why it believed its bidding credit caps
    would have only a minor impact on DEs’ ability to compete
    in the spectrum license marketplace.
    Though Council Tree objects that the FCC did not
    truly balance its obligations here, Council Tree III is again
    instructive. In that case we found the question of whether the
    rule restricting spectrum leasing was arbitrary and capricious
    “a close one” on first review, because “the FCC made few
    factual findings on the impact of the new rules on DE
    12
    financing.” Council Tree 
    III, 619 F.3d at 251
    . But despite the
    lack of concrete findings, we found “enough consideration of
    [the negative impact on] DE capitalization to pass the
    arbitrary and capricious threshold.” 
    Id. at 253.
    We reached this conclusion for two reasons. First, the
    FCC’s notice of proposed rulemaking “reflect[ed] the FCC’s
    cognizance of the capitalization issue” based on its stated
    concern for a “delicate balance” between avoiding abuse and
    allowing small businesses to access flexible sources of
    capital. 
    Id. at 251–52
    (citation omitted). Second, we noted
    that predictions about the future impact of rules were
    “inherently speculative.” 
    Id. at 252.
    Under our “necessarily
    deferential” review of “line-drawing determinations,” 
    id. at 250–51
    (citation omitted), we found it unnecessary to demand
    more despite the FCC’s consideration being “neither as clear
    nor as thorough as would be ideal,” 
    id. at 252–53.
    Unlike the rulemaking in Council Tree III, the FCC in
    this matter made factual findings on the likely impact of this
    new rule on DE auction competitiveness. Whether the FCC is
    right or wrong that the impact will be minimal, we cannot say
    its prediction is irrational based on the relevant data of record.
    The FCC’s balancing here was not arbitrary and capricious.3
    3
    As a subsidiary argument, Council Tree suggests that
    the Order actually reflects an FCC determination “that DEs
    should be nothing more than bit players in the wireless
    industry.” Council Tree Br. 28. Because “[t]he caps only
    apply to businesses the FCC has already deemed to be bona
    fide DEs,” Council Tree reasons that “there can be no claim
    that the caps are necessary to limit bidding credits to the kinds
    13
    C
    Finally, we consider Council Tree’s challenge to the
    specific caps imposed. Council Tree raises three related
    arguments contesting the rationality of these caps, none of
    which we find persuasive.
    First, Council Tree complains that focusing on the
    number of affected DEs, instead of on their ability to break
    into major markets, is a poor way to measure the impact of a
    cap on competition. As discussed, we review the FCC’s
    reasoning to confirm that it used relevant data—not that it
    applied the most rigorous analysis available. Here, the FCC
    reviewed relevant auction data before evaluating whether the
    caps on bidding credits would reduce competition.
    Second, Council Tree argues that DEs were so
    hampered by old rules in two of the auctions that those
    of small businesses Congress had in mind.” 
    Id. at 45.
    Leaving
    aside the term “necessary,” which is irrelevant to a review for
    rationality, the FCC’s Order explains that its cap acts as “an
    important additional safeguard—or backstop” when its other
    measures for assessing bona fide DE status have failed. 30
    FCC Rcd. at 7540. Council Tree’s related argument on
    efficacy—including that the penalties in place are sufficiently
    “extensive,” Council Tree Br. 49, and that the caps “do not
    eliminate the alleged incentives for gamesmanship,” 
    id. at 51—are
    by and large policy disagreements that do not
    undercut the rationality of the FCC’s determination that
    bidding credit caps would serve as a safeguard against
    gamesmanship.
    14
    auctions should not have been used in estimates, and that
    even the third (ostensibly adequate) auction cannot be
    compared to the “once-in-a-generation” Incentive Auction.
    Council Tree Br. 58 (quoting Order ¶ 95). Here again, we
    review only for the use of relevant, not perfect, data. Council
    Tree 
    III, 619 F.3d at 250
    . And Council Tree has not offered,
    in briefing or at argument, any alternative data that the FCC
    should have considered in its estimates.
    Finally, Council Tree argues that the FCC’s
    justifications in support of the $25 million minimum on
    bidding credit caps and its $150 million cap for the Incentive
    Auction would be as consistent with limits of “$200 million,
    $500 million, or more,” making its explanation inadequate.
    Council Tree Br. 58. In support of this argument, Council
    Tree points to Bluewater Network v. EPA, where the Court of
    Appeals for the D.C. Circuit ordered the EPA to clarify the
    basis of its determination that only 70% of new snowmobiles
    in eight years could be fitted with emission reduction
    technology. 
    370 F.3d 1
    , 21 (D.C. Cir. 2004). The Bluewater
    court held the EPA’s statements regarding cost concerns for
    manufacturers—that design takes time and manufacturers
    have finite resources—were too vague. See 
    id. (“The Agency’s
    explanation of its reasoning could just as well
    support standards corresponding to 30% or 100% application
    in that time frame.”). By contrast, the FCC’s analysis here
    would not be consistent with a bidding credit cap of any
    value. For example, the FCC rejected caps of $10 million and
    $25 million for the Incentive Auction as less consistent with
    historical bidding thresholds. While the FCC did not
    explicitly reject any upper boundary as too high, we note that
    it set the $150 million cap such that, while “nearly all of the
    small businesses that claimed bidding credits . . . would have
    15
    fallen under” the cap, 30 FCC Rcd. at 7545, two successful
    DEs in one of the previous auctions would have exceeded it.
    Council Tree admits those two DEs, allegedly “financed in
    large part by investments from DISH,” prompted the concern
    that led to this rulemaking, allowing us to infer grounds for an
    upper bound in the record. Council Tree Br. 20. Even
    excluding that inference, however, the sources underlying the
    decision here are much more concrete than those in
    Bluewater. Besides, setting a reasonable cap is a
    quintessential “line-drawing determination[]” calling for
    “necessarily deferential” review in this Court. Council Tree
    
    III, 619 F.3d at 250
    –51 (citation omitted).
    In sum, the FCC made a “rational connection” between
    “relevant data” and the caps on bidding credits under review.
    State 
    Farm, 463 U.S. at 43
    .
    IV
    For the reasons stated, we hold that the FCC’s Order
    dated July 21, 2015 and published on September 18, 2015
    was not arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or
    otherwise contrary to law. We will deny Council Tree’s
    petition for review.
    16