Sullivan v. National Football ( 1994 )


Menu:
  • USCA1 Opinion









    September 29, 1994

    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS

    FOR THE FIRST CIRCUIT

    No. 94-1031

    WILLIAM H. SULLIVAN II,

    Plaintiff - Appellee,

    v.

    PAUL TAGLIABUE, ET AL.,

    Defendants -Appellees.

    ____________________



    NATIONAL FOOTBALL LEAGUE, &

    MEMBERS OF THE NATIONAL FOOTBALL LEAGUE

    Defendants - Appellants.



    ____________________



    ERRATA SHEET



    The opinion of this Court issued on September 16, 1994, is

    amended as follows:



    The caption on the coversheet should read: "William H.

    Sullivan II, Plaintiff - Appellee v. National Football League, &

    Members of the National Football League." "Paul Tagliabue, et

    al., Defendants - Appellees" should be deleted.



















    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE FIRST CIRCUIT
    ____________________

    No. 94-1031

    WILLIAM H. SULLIVAN II,
    Plaintiff - Appellee,

    v.

    NATIONAL FOOTBALL LEAGUE, &
    MEMBERS OF THE NATIONAL FOOTBALL LEAGUE
    Defendants - Appellants.

    ____________________

    APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT

    FOR THE DISTRICT OF MASSACHUSETTS

    [Hon. Edward F. Harrington, U.S. District Judge]
    ___________________

    ____________________

    Before

    Torruella, Circuit Judge,
    _____________
    Coffin, Senior Circuit Judge,
    ____________________
    and Stahl, Circuit Judge.
    _____________

    _____________________

    John Vanderstar, with whom Sonya D. Winner, Ethan M. Posner,
    _______________ _______________ _______________
    Covington & Burling, Jeremiah T. O'Sullivan, Sarah Chapin
    _____________________ ________________________ ______________
    Columbia, Choate, Hall & Stewart, Joseph W. Cotchett, and
    ________ _________________________ ____________________
    Cotchett, Illston & Pitre were on brief for appellants.
    _________________________
    Joseph L. Alioto and Frederick P. Furth, with whom Angela M.
    ________________ __________________ _________
    Alioto, Law Offices of Joseph L. Alioto, Alan R. Hoffman, Lynch,
    ______ _______________________________ _______________ ______
    Brewer, Hoffman & Sands, Bruce J. Wecker, Michael P. Lehmann and
    ________________________ _______________ __________________
    Furth, Fahrner & Mason, were on brief for appellees.
    ______________________


    ____________________

    September 16, 1994
    ____________________



















    TORRUELLA, Circuit Judge. The National Football League
    _____________

    and twenty-one organizations owning NFL franchises (referred to

    collectively as the "NFL") appeal the judgment entered against

    them after a jury found that the NFL violated the antitrust laws

    by restricting owners of member football clubs from selling

    shares in their teams to the public. Plaintiff-appellee, William

    H. Sullivan, former owner of the New England Patriots football

    team (the "Patriots"), was awarded a total of $51 million in

    damages for the losses Sullivan incurred when he had to sell the

    Patriots to a private buyer after the NFL prevented him from

    offering 49% of the team to the public in the form of publicly

    traded stock. Because several prejudicial errors were committed

    during the trial, we vacate the judgment and remand for a new

    trial.

    I. BACKGROUND
    I. BACKGROUND

    Under Article 3.5 of the NFL's constitution and by-

    laws, three-quarters of the NFL club owners must approve all

    transfers of ownership interests in an NFL team, other than

    transfers within a family. In conjunction with this rule is an

    uncodified policy against the sale of ownership interests in an

    NFL club to the public through offerings of publicly traded

    stock. The members, however, retain full authority to approve

    any given transfer by a three-quarters vote according to Article

    3.5.

    Sullivan owned the Patriots from the team's inception

    in 1959 until October of 1988. When Sullivan formed the


    -2-














    Patriots, he and his partner sold non-voting shares of the team

    to the public beginning in 1960. At that time, the Patriots were

    in the old American Football League ("AFL"), which was separate

    from the NFL, and which had no policy against public ownership of

    teams. In 1966, the AFL and the old NFL merged into a single

    league. Under the terms of the merger, the new NFL would adopt

    the old NFL's policy against public ownership. The Patriots,

    however, were allowed to retain their level of public ownership

    as a special exception to the rule under a grandfather clause.

    In 1976, Sullivan sought to acquire the publicly held

    shares of the Patriots through a merger of the club into a new

    Sullivan-owned company. Stockholders approved the transfer and

    the transaction was subsequently consummated, although some

    shareholders subsequently brought suit, challenging the

    sufficiency of the purchase price. After protracted litigation,

    the shareholders obtained a judgment requiring Sullivan to pay

    them a higher price for their shares. The Patriots then became a

    fully privately owned club.

    Sullivan and his son, Chuck Sullivan, who owned the

    stadium where the Patriots played, began to experience financial

    difficulties and increasing debt burdens in the mid-1980s. The

    Sullivans decided that they needed to raise capital to alleviate

    their financial problems. After the Boston Celtics professional

    basketball franchise made a public offering of 40% of the team in

    December of 1986, the Sullivans decided to pursue a similar deal

    with the Patriots in order to raise cash to cover some of their


    -3-














    debts.

    On October 19, 1987, the Sullivans met with Stephens,

    Inc., a small investment banking firm in Little Rock, Arkansas.

    They discussed a debt financing deal whereby Stephens would loan

    the Sullivans $80 million dollars, with half going to the

    Patriots and the other half to Chuck Sullivan's company which

    owned the Patriots' stadium. The Patriots' portion of the loan

    would be repaid out of the proceeds of the sale of 49% of the

    Patriots through the offering of public stock. Stephens agreed

    to look into the possibility of arranging the deal, but informed

    the Sullivans that they would first have to get NFL approval.

    Sullivan ultimately never obtained NFL approval and the deal with

    Stephens never progressed beyond some preliminary discussions.

    At a meeting of the NFL owners on October 27, 1987,

    Sullivan raised his stock sale idea with the other owners and

    asked for a modification of the NFL's policy against public

    ownership to allow for certain controlled sales of minority

    interests in NFL clubs. Alternatively, Sullivan requested a

    waiver from the public ownership policy for his contemplated

    public offering of the Patriots. Sullivan's request was

    eventually tabled at this meeting. Discussions continued among

    the owners and, at one point, Sullivan counted 17 of the 21

    owners needed for approval as being in favor of allowing him to

    make his public offering (seven owners were still undecided).

    Pete Rozelle, NFL Commissioner at the time, told Sullivans that

    he was not in favor of Sullivan's proposals and that league


    -4-














    approval was "very dubious." Sullivan ultimately never asked for

    a vote on amending the ownership policy or on waiving the policy

    for the Patriots, and the NFL never held such a vote. Sullivan

    claims that he did not ask for a vote because it would have been

    futile.

    In October of 1988, Sullivan sold the Patriots for

    approximately $83.7 million to KMS Patriots L.P. ("KMS"), a

    limited partnership owned by Victor Kiam and Francis Murray.

    Sullivan alleges that, absent the NFL's public ownership policy,

    he would have been able to retain a majority share of a rapidly

    appreciating asset with a high potential for future profits.

    Instead, Sullivan asserts, he was forced to sell the Patriots at

    a depressed price to private buyers.

    On May 16, 1991, Sullivan sued the NFL claiming that,

    among other things, the NFL had violated the Sherman Antitrust

    Act, 15 U.S.C. 1-2, by preventing him from selling 49% of the

    Patriots to the public in an equity offering. Sullivan alleged

    that, as a result, he was forced to sell the entire team to a

    private buyer at a fire sale price in order to pay off existing

    debts. Prior to trial, the district court dismissed Sullivan's

    claim under 2 of the Sherman Act along with various state law

    claims. After a trial on Sullivan's claim under 1 of the

    Sherman Act, the jury rendered a verdict for Sullivan in the

    amount of $38 million, which the judge later reduced through

    remittitur to $17 million. Pursuant to 15 U.S.C. 15, which

    provides for treble damages for antitrust violations, the court


    -5-














    entered a final judgment for Sullivan of $51 million.




















































    -6-














    II. ANALYSIS
    II. ANALYSIS

    The NFL has raised a number of issues on appeal

    concerning the application of 1 of the Sherman Act to the facts

    of this case, which, according to the NFL, entitle it to judgment

    as a matter of law. We address these issues first to see if the

    present case should be dismissed, and we ultimately conclude that

    it should not. We next address the NFL's allegations of trial

    error and we find that several of them require that we overturn

    the verdict in this case and order a new trial.

    The first set of issues involves the district court's

    denial of the NFL's motions for judgment as a matter of law under

    Fed. R. Civ. P. 50. We review the court's decision de novo,
    _______

    using the same stringent decisional standards that controlled the

    district court. Gallagher v. Wilton Enterprises, Inc., 962 F.2d
    _________ _________________________

    120, 125 (1st Cir. 1992); Hendricks & Assocs., Inc. v. Daewoo
    __________________________ ______

    Corp., 923 F.2d 209, 214 (1st Cir. 1991). Under these standards,
    _____

    judgment for the NFL can only be ordered if the evidence, viewed

    in the light most favorable to Sullivan, points so strongly and

    overwhelmingly in favor of the NFL, that a reasonable jury could

    not have arrived at a verdict for Sullivan. Gallagher, 962 F.2d
    _________

    at 124-25; Hendricks, 923 F.2d at 214.
    _________

    III. ISSUES ALLEGEDLY REQUIRING JUDGMENT FOR THE NFL
    III. ISSUES ALLEGEDLY REQUIRING JUDGMENT FOR THE NFL

    A. Lack of Antitrust Injury
    A. Lack of Antitrust Injury

    To establish an antitrust violation under 1 of the

    Sherman Act, Sullivan must prove that the NFL's public ownership

    policy is "in restraint of trade." Monahan's Marine, Inc. v.
    _______________________


    -7-














    Boston Whaler, Inc., 866 F.2d 525, 526 (1st Cir. 1989). Under
    ___________________

    antitrust law's "rule of reason," the NFL's policy is in

    restraint of trade if the anticompetitive effects of the policy

    outweigh the policy's legitimate business justifications. Id. at
    __

    526-27 (citing Business Electronics Corp. v. Sharp Electronics
    __________________________ __________________

    Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 723 (1988)). Anticompetitive effects, more
    _____

    commonly referred to as "injury to competition" or "harm to the

    competitive process," are usually measured by a reduction in
    _____________

    output and an increase in prices in the relevant market.
    ______ ____________________

    National Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Board of Regents of Univ.
    ___________________________________ __________________________

    of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 104-07 (1984) ("Restrictions on price and
    _________

    output are the paradigmatic examples of restraints of trade")

    (hereinafter "NCAA"); Chicago Professional Sports Ltd.
    ____ _______________________________________

    Partnership v. National Basketball Association, 961 F.2d 667, 670
    ___________ _______________________________

    (7th Cir.), cert. denied, 113 S. Ct. 409 (1992). Injury to
    ____ ______

    competition has also been described more generally in terms of

    decreased efficiency in the marketplace which negatively impacts
    ____________________

    consumers. Town of Concord v. Boston Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17,
    _______________ _________________

    21-22 (1st Cir. 1990), cert. denied, 499 U.S. 931 (1991);
    ____ ______

    Interface Group, Inc. v. Massachusetts Port Auth., 816 F.2d 9, 10
    _____________________ ________________________

    (1st Cir. 1987). Thus, an action harms the competitive process

    "when it obstructs the achievement of competition's basic goals -

    - lower prices, better products, and more efficient production

    methods." Town of Concord, 915 F.2d at 22.
    _______________

    The jury determined in this case, via a special verdict

    form, that the relevant market is the "nationwide market for the


    -8-














    sale and purchase of ownership interests in the National Football

    League member clubs, in general, and in the New England Patriots,

    in particular." The jury went on to find that the NFL's policy

    had an "actual harmful effect" on competition in this market.

    The NFL argues on appeal that Sullivan has not

    established the existence of any injury to competition, and thus

    has not established a restraint of trade that can be attributed

    to the NFL's ownership policy. The league's attack is two-fold,

    asserting (1) that NFL clubs do not compete with each other for

    the sale of ownership interests in their teams so there exists no

    competition to be injured in the first place; and (2) Sullivan

    did not present sufficient evidence of injury to competition from

    which a reasonable jury could conclude that the NFL's policy

    restrains trade. Although we agree with the NFL that

    conceptualizing the harm to competition in this case is rather

    difficult, precedent and deference to the jury verdict ultimately

    require us to reject the NFL's challenge to the finding of injury

    to competition.

    Critically, the NFL does not challenge on appeal the
    ___

    jury's initial finding of the relevant market and no

    corresponding challenge was raised at trial.1 As a result, the

    ____________________

    1 The NFL argues in passing that certain expert testimony
    related to the relevant market issue was inherently unreasonable
    and thus could not support the jury's relevant market finding.
    We do not consider this passing argument to be sufficient to
    raise the relevant market issue on appeal as matters averted to
    in a perfunctory manner, unaccompanied by some effort at
    developed argumentation, are deemed waived on appeal. United
    ______
    States v. Innamorati, 996 F.2d 456, 468 (1st Cir. 1993). More
    ______ __________
    importantly, the NFL did not challenge the relevant market issue

    -9-














    NFL faces an uphill battle in its attack on the presence of an

    injury to competition. Given the existence of a relevant market

    for ownership interests in NFL teams, it is reasonable to presume

    that a policy restricting the buying and selling of such

    ownership interests injures competition in that market. The NFL

    nevertheless maintains that NFL teams do not compete against each

    other for the sale of their ownership interests, even if we

    accept that a market exists for such ownership interests.

    1. No Competition Subject to Injury as Matter of Law
    1. No Competition Subject to Injury as Matter of Law
    _________________________________________________

    The NFL correctly points out that member clubs must

    cooperate in a variety of ways, and may do so lawfully, in order

    to make the football league a success. See United States
    ___ ______________

    Football League v. National Football League, 842 F.2d 1335, 1372
    _______________ ________________________

    (2d Cir. 1988); Los Angeles Memorial Coliseum Comm'n v. National
    _____________________________________ ________

    Football League, 726 F.2d 1381, 1391-92 (9th Cir.), cert. denied,
    _______________ ____ ______

    469 U.S. 990 (1984) (hereinafter "L.A. Coliseum"); North American
    _____________ ______________

    Soccer League v. National Football League, 670 F.2d 1249, 1251
    ______________ _________________________

    (2d Cir.), cert. denied, 459 U.S. 1074 (1982) (hereinafter
    ____ ______

    "NASL"). On the other hand, it is well established that NFL
    ____

    clubs also compete with each other, both on and off the field,

    for things like fan support, players, coaches, ticket sales,

    local broadcast revenues, and the sale of team paraphernalia.

    Mid-South Grizzlies v. National Football League, 720 F.2d 772,
    ___________________ _________________________


    ____________________

    in either its directed verdict motion or in its motion for
    judgment as a matter of law. We will not consider arguments
    which could have been, but were not, advanced below. Domegan v.
    _______
    Fair, 859 F.2d 1059, 1065 (1st Cir. 1988).
    ____

    -10-














    786-87 (3d Cir. 1983), cert. denied, 467 U.S. 1215 (1984); L.A.
    ____ ______ ____

    Coliseum, 726 F.2d at 1390, 1393, 1395, 1397. The question of
    ________

    whether competition exists between NFL teams for sale of their

    ownership interests, such that the NFL's ownership policy injures

    this competition, is ultimately a question of fact. The NFL

    would have us find, however, that, as a matter of law, NFL teams

    do not compete against each other for the sale of their ownership

    interests. We decline to make such a finding.

    The NFL relies on a series of cases which allegedly

    stand for the "well established" rule that a professional sports

    league's restrictions on who may join the league or acquire an

    interest in a member club do not give rise to a claim under the

    antitrust laws. Seattle Totems Hockey Club, Inc. v. National
    __________________________________ ________

    Hockey League, 783 F.2d 1347 (9th Cir.), cert. denied, 479 U.S.
    _____________ ____ ______

    932 (1986); Fishman v. Estate of Wirtz, 807 F.2d 520 (7th Cir.
    _______ ________________

    1986); Mid-South Grizzlies, 720 F.2d at 772; Levin v. National
    ___________________ _____ ________

    Basketball Ass'n, 385 F. Supp. 149 (S.D.N.Y. 1974). These cases,
    ________________

    all involving a professional sport's league's refusal to approve

    individual transfers of team ownership or the creation of new

    teams, do not stand for the broad proposition that no NFL

    ownership policy can injure competition. See, e.g., NASL, 670
    ___ ____ ____

    F.2d at 1259-61 (finding that the NFL's policy against cross-

    ownership of NFL teams and franchises in competing sports

    leagues, which also effectively barred certain owners who owned

    other sports franchises from purchasing NFL teams, injured

    competition between the NFL and competing sports leagues and thus


    -11-














    violated 1 of the Sherman Act).

    None of the cases cited by the NFL considered the

    particular relevant market that was found by the jury in this

    case or a league policy against public ownership. Seattle Totems
    ______________

    and Mid-South Grizzlies considered potential inter-league
    _____________________ _____

    competition when a sports league rejected plaintiffs'

    applications for new league franchises. Seattle Totems, 783 F.2d
    ______________

    at 1349-50; Mid-South Grizzlies, 720 F.2d at 785-86. Those
    ____________________

    decisions found no injury to competition because the plaintiffs

    were not competing with the defendant sports leagues, but rather,

    were seeking to join those leagues. Seattle Totems, 783 F.2d at
    ______________

    1350; Mid-South Grizzlies, 720 F.2d at 785-86. Mid-South
    ____________________ _________

    Grizzlies left open the possibility that potential intra-league
    _________ _____

    competition between NFL football clubs could be harmed by the

    NFL's action, but found that the plaintiff in that case had not

    presented sufficient evidence of harm to such competition. Mid-
    ____

    South Grizzlies, 720 F.2d at 786-87.
    _______________

    The Fishman and Levin cases concerned the National
    _______ _____

    Basketball Association's ("N.B.A.") rejection of plaintiffs'

    attempts to buy an existing team. Fishman, 807 F.2d at 525-31;
    _______

    Levin, 385 F. Supp. at 150-51. Those cases also based their
    _____

    finding that there was no injury to competition on the fact that

    the plaintiffs were seeking to join with, rather than compete

    against, the N.B.A. Fishman, 807 F.2d at 544; Levin, 385 F.
    _______ _____

    Supp. at 152. Neither case considered whether competition

    between teams for investment capital was injured. As pointed out


    -12-














    in Piazza v. Major League Baseball, 831 F. Supp. 420 (E.D.Pa.
    ______ ______________________

    1993), Fishman explicitly recognized the potential for
    _______

    competition in the market for ownership of teams, although the

    plaintiff had failed to raise the issue, and Levin simply
    _____

    presumed, incorrectly, that there could never be any competition

    among league members. Piazza, 831 F. Supp. at 430-31 & n.16
    ______

    (citing Fishman, 807 F.2d at 532 n.9; and Levin, 385 F. Supp. at
    _______ _____

    152).

    The important distinction to make between the cases

    cited by the NFL and the present case is that here Sullivan

    alleges that the NFL's policy against public ownership generally

    restricts competition between clubs for the sale of their

    ownership interests, whereas in the aforementioned cases, a

    league's refusal to approve a given sale transaction or a new

    team merely prevented particular outsiders from joining the

    league, but did not limit competition between the teams

    themselves. To put it another way, the NFL's public ownership

    policy allegedly does not merely prevent the replacement of one

    club owner with another -- an action having little evident effect

    on competition -- it compromises the entire process by which

    competition for club ownership occurs.2

    ____________________

    2 This same argument distinguishes cases cited by the NFL for
    the proposition that a franchisor's disapproval of a proposed
    sale of a franchise does not give rise to an antitrust injury.
    See Kestenbaum v. Falstaff Brewing Corp., 514 F.2d 690 (5th Cir.
    ___ __________ ______________________
    1975), cert. denied, 424 U.S. 943 (1976); McDaniel v. General
    ____ ______ ________ _______
    Motors Corp., 480 F. Supp. 666 (E.D.N.Y. 1979). Individual
    _____________
    decisions to block the sale of a franchise do not implicate the
    harm to competition that is caused by a policy restricting all
    sales of a certain type of ownership interest. Only the broad-

    -13-














    We take a moment to briefly address a related argument

    raised by the NFL to the effect that NFL clubs are unable to

    conspire with each other under 1 of the Sherman Act because

    they function as a single enterprise in relation to the league's

    public ownership policy. The NFL asserts that the Supreme

    Court's holding in Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp.,
    ________________ _______________________

    467 U.S. 752 (1984), controls the facts of this case and

    overturns prior caselaw holding that NFL clubs do not constitute

    a single enterprise but rather, are separate entities which were

    capable of conspiring with each other under 1. See L.A.
    ___ ____

    Coliseum, 726 F.2d at 1387-90; NASL, 670 F.2d at 1256-58.
    ________ ____

    We do not agree that Copperweld, which found a
    __________

    corporation and its wholly owned subsidiary to be a single

    enterprise for purposes of 1, Copperweld, 467 U.S. at 771,
    __________

    applies to the facts of this case or affects the prior precedent

    concerning the NFL. See McNeil v. National Football League, 790
    ___ ______ ________________________

    F. Supp. 871, 879-80 (D.Minn. 1992) (holding that Copperweld did
    __________

    not apply to the NFL and its member clubs and finding the clubs

    to be separate entities capable of conspiring together under

    1). Copperweld's holding turned on the fact that the subsidiary
    __________

    of a corporation, although legally distinct from the corporation

    itself, "pursue[d] the common interests of the whole rather than

    interests separate from those of the corporation itself."

    Copperweld, 467 U.S. at 770. As emphasized in City of Mt.
    __________ ____________

    ____________________

    based policy has the potential to compromise the entire
    competitive process for the buying and selling of a good in a
    relevant market.

    -14-














    Pleasant, Iowa v. Associated Elec. Co-op., Inc., 838 F.2d 268
    _______________ ______________________________

    (8th Cir. 1988), upon which the NFL relies for the application of

    Copperweld to this case, the critical inquiry is whether the
    __________

    alleged antitrust conspirators have a "unity of interests" or

    whether, instead, "any of the defendants has pursued interests

    diverse from those of the cooperative itself." Id. at 274-77
    __

    (defining "diverse" as "interests which tend to show that any two

    of the defendants are, or have been, actual or potential

    competitors"). As we have already noted, NFL member clubs

    compete in several ways off the field, which itself tends to show

    that the teams pursue diverse interests and thus are not a single

    enterprise under 1.

    Ultimately, the NFL's Copperweld challenge is subsumed
    __________

    under the question of whether or not the evidence can support a

    finding that NFL teams compete against each other for the sale of

    their ownership interests. Proof of such competition defeats

    both the NFL's challenge to the existence of an injury to

    competition and the NFL's Copperweld argument as well.
    __________

    Insufficient proof of such competition would require a judgment

    in favor of the NFL anyway, regardless of the implications under

    Copperweld. As we discuss below, the jury's finding that there
    __________

    exists competition between teams for the sale of ownership

    interests was based on sufficient evidence.

    2. Insufficient Evidence of Harm to Competition
    2. Insufficient Evidence of Harm to Competition
    ____________________________________________

    The NFL contends that Sullivan did not present

    sufficient evidence concerning: (1) the existence of competition


    -15-














    between NFL clubs for the sale of ownership interests, or (2) a

    decrease in output, an increase in prices, a detrimental effect

    on efficiency or other incidents of harm to competition in the

    relevant market, from which a reasonable jury could conclude that

    the NFL's policy injured competition. Although we agree that the

    evidence of all these factors is rather thin, we disagree that

    the evidence is too thin to support a jury verdict in Sullivan's

    favor.

    With respect to evidence of the existence of

    competition for the sale of ownership interests, one of

    Sullivan's experts, Professor Roger Noll, testified that "one of

    the ways in which the NFL exercises monopoly power in the market

    for the franchises and ownership is by excluding certain people

    from owning all or part -- any type part of an NFL franchise."

    Dr. Noll explained that this "enables a group of owners, in this

    case, you only need eight owners, to exclude from the League and

    from competing with them, people who might be more effective

    competitors than they are." The record also contains statements

    from several NFL owners which could reasonably be interpreted as

    expressions of concern about their ability to compete with other

    teams in the market for investment capital in general, and for

    the sale of ownership interests in particular. For example,

    Arthur Rooney II of the Pittsburgh Steelers stated in a letter

    that he did not "believe that the individually or family owned

    teams will be able to compete with the consolidated groups."

    Ralph Wilson of the Buffalo Bills stated that big corporations


    -16-














    should not own teams because it gives them an "unfair competitive

    advantage" over other teams since corporations will funnel money

    into the team and make it "more competitive" than the other

    franchises. Former NFL Commissioner Pete Rozelle admitted that

    similar sentiments had been expressed by NFL members.

    Although it is not precisely clear that the

    "competition" about which Noll, Rooney, and Wilson were

    discussing is the same competition at issue here -- that is

    competition for the sale of ownership interests -- a jury could

    reasonably interpret these statements as expressing a belief that

    the competition exists between teams for the sale of ownership

    interests. The statements of the two NFL owners imply that

    greater access to capital for all teams will put increased

    pressure on some teams to compete with others for that capital,

    and all the statements reveal that the ownership rules,

    particularly the rule against public ownership, is the main

    obstacle preventing such access. The fact that ownership by

    "consolidated groups" is not necessarily the same as public

    ownership does not affect the conclusion that teams face

    competitive pressure in selling their ownership interests

    generally to whoever might buy them. We also note that evidence

    of actual, present competition is not necessary as long as the

    evidence shows that the potential for competition exists. See L.
    ___ __

    A. Coliseum, 726 F.2d at 1394 (discussing significance of
    ____________

    potential competition, especially where challenged policy limits
    _________

    such competition so that it is not evident in practice). It


    -17-














    would be difficult indeed to provide direct evidence of

    competition when the NFL effectively prohibits it.

    The NFL focusses on the fact that Professor Noll

    testified that many of the purchasers of Patriots' stock would be

    New England sports fans and others in the New England area. The

    NFL points out that other NFL teams would not compete with the

    Patriots for the sale of stock to their own fans. This argument

    slightly distorts Professor Noll's testimony. Professor Noll

    stated that local souvenir buyers would be one portion of the

    market for Patriots stock. Professor Noll also testified several

    times that other investors would buy Patriots stock as well, for

    investment purposes. Noll's point was that the souvenir buyers

    would serve to bid up the price of the stock above what the price

    would normally be if the Patriots were a regular company. His

    testimony did not preclude a finding that NFL teams compete

    against each other for investment capital via the sale of

    ownership interests.

    The record also contains sufficient evidence of the

    normal incidents of injury to competition from the NFL's policy -

    - reduced output, increased prices, and reduced efficiency -- to

    support the jury's verdict. As Dr. Noll pointed out in his

    testimony, the NFL's policy "excludes individuals . . . who might

    want to own a share of stock in a professional football team."

    Several NFL officials themselves admitted that the policy

    restricts the market for investment capital among NFL teams.

    There is thus little dispute that the NFL's ownership policy


    -18-














    reduces the available output of ownership interests.

    The NFL is correct that, in one sense, the overall pool

    of potential output is fixed because there are only 28 NFL teams

    and, although their value may fluctuate, the quantity of their

    ownership interests cannot. However, the NFL's public ownership

    policy completely wipes out a certain type of ownership interest

    -- public ownership of stock. By restricting output in one form
    ____

    of ownership, the NFL is thereby reducing the output of ownership

    interests overall. In other words, the NFL is literally

    restricting the output of a product -- a share in an NFL team.

    There was considerable testimony concerning the price

    effects of the NFL policy. Both of Sullivan's experts testified

    that the policy depressed the price of ownership interests in NFL

    teams because NFL franchises would normally command a premium on

    the public market relative to their value in the private market,

    which is all that the league currently permits. Professor Noll

    testified that fan loyalty would push up the price of ownership

    interests if sales to the public were allowed. Even former

    Commissioner Pete Rozelle acknowledged that "it was pointed out,

    with justification, it has been over the years, that [the

    ownership policy] does restrict your market and, very likely, the

    price you could get for one of our franchises if you wanted to

    sell it, because you are eliminating a very broad market . . . .

    And they have said that there is a depression on the price they

    could get for their franchise."

    The NFL points out that the alleged effect of its


    -19-














    ownership policy is to reduce prices of NFL team ownership
    ______

    interests, rather than to raise prices which is normally the

    measure of an injury to competition. E.g., Town of Concord, 915
    ____ _______________

    F.2d at 22. We acknowledge that it is not clear whether, absent

    some sort of dumping or predatory pricing, see, e.g., Monahan's
    ___ ____ _________

    Marine, Inc. v. Boston Whaler, Inc., 866 F.2d 525, 527 (1st Cir.
    ____________ ___________________

    1989), a decrease in prices can indicate injury to competition in

    a relevant market. The Supreme Court has emphasized, however,

    that overall consumer preferences in setting output and prices is

    more important than higher prices and lower output, per se, in
    ______

    determining whether there has been an injury to competition.

    NCAA, 468 U.S. at 107. In this case, regardless of the exact
    ____

    price effects of the NFL's policy, the overall market effects of

    the policy are plainly unresponsive to consumer demand for

    ownership interests in NFL teams. Dr. Noll testified that fans

    are interested in buying shares in NFL teams and that the NFL's

    policy deprives fans of this product. Moreover, evidence was

    presented concerning the public offering of the Boston Celtics

    professional basketball team which demonstrated, according to

    some of the testimony, fan interest in buying ownership of

    professional sports teams. Thus, a jury could conclude that the

    NFL's policy injured competition by making the relevant market

    "unresponsive to consumer preference." Id.3
    __

    ____________________

    3 The NFL maintains that price and output are not affected
    because its ownership policy does not limit the number of games
    or teams, does not raise ticket prices or the prices of game
    telecasts and does not affect the normal consumer of the NFL's
    product in any other way. Such facts might be relevant to an

    -20-














    As for overall efficiency of production in the relevant

    market,4 Sullivan's experts testified that the NFL's policy

    hindered efficiency gains, and that allowing public ownership

    would make for better football teams. Professor Noll stated that

    the NFL's public ownership policy prevented individuals who might

    be "more efficient and much better at running a professional

    football team" from owning teams. Dr. Noll also stated that

    publicly owned NFL teams would be better managed, and produce

    higher quality entertainment for the fans. Noll testified that

    the ownership rule excluded certain types of management

    structures which would likely be more efficient in running the

    teams, resulting in higher franchise values. One NFL owner,

    Lamar Hunt, acknowledged that increased access to capital can

    improve a team's operations and performance. A memorandum

    prepared by an NFL staff member stated that changes to the NFL's


    ____________________

    inquiry of whether the NFL's policy harms overall efficiency, see
    ___
    infra note [4], but it is not relevant to whether the policy
    _____
    affects output and prices in the relevant market for ownership
    _______________________
    interests. Just because consumers of "NFL football" are not
    affected by output controls and price increases does not mean
    that consumers of a product in the relevant market are not so
    affected. In this case, two types of consumers are denied
    products by the NFL policy: consumers who want to buy stock of
    the Patriots or other teams, and consumers like Sullivan who want
    to "purchase" investment capital in the market for public
    financing.

    4 Although the product at issue in the relevant market is
    "ownership interests," efficiency in production of that product
    can be measured by the value of the ownership interest. That is,
    an improved product produced more efficiently will be reflected
    in the value of the output in question (regardless of the price).
    In this case, the value of the product depends on the success of
    the Patriots' football team, the overall efficiency of its
    operations, and the success of the NFL in general.

    -21-














    public ownership policy could contribute to each NFL team's own

    financial strength and viability, which in turn would benefit the

    entire NFL because the league has a strong interest in having

    strong, viable teams.

    The NFL presented a large amount of evidence to the

    contrary and now claims on appeal that Sullivan's position was

    based on nothing more than sheer speculation. We have reviewed

    the record, however, and we cannot say that the evidence was so

    overwhelming that no reasonable jury could find against the NFL

    and in favor of Sullivan. We therefore refuse to enter judgment

    in favor of the NFL as a matter of law.

    B. Ancillary Benefits
    B. Ancillary Benefits

    The NFL next argues that even if its public ownership

    policy injures competition in a relevant market, it should be

    upheld as ancillary to the legitimate joint activity that is "NFL
    _________

    football" and thus not violative of the Sherman Act. We take no

    issue with the proposition that certain joint ventures enable

    separate business entities to combine their skills and resources

    in pursuit of a common goal that cannot be effectively pursued by

    the venturers acting alone. See, e.g., Broadcast Music, Inc. v.
    ___ ____ _____________________

    Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979). We also
    __________________________________

    do not dispute that a "restraint" that is ancillary to the

    functioning of such a joint activity -- i.e. one that is required

    to make the joint activity more efficient -- does not necessarily

    violate the antitrust laws. Broadcast Music, 441 U.S. at 23-25;
    _______________

    Rothery Storage & Van Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, Inc., 792 F.2d 210,
    _________________________ _____________________


    -22-














    at 223-24 (D.C. Cir. 1986), cert. denied, 479 U.S. 1033 (1987);
    ____ ______

    see also Northwest Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific
    _________ _______________________________________ _______

    Stationery & Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284, 295-96 (1985). We
    ___________________________

    further accept, for purposes of this appeal, that rules

    controlling who may join a joint venture can be ancillary to a

    legitimate joint activity and that the NFL's own policy against

    public ownership constitutes one example of such an ancillary
    ______

    rule. Finally, we accept the NFL's claim that its public

    ownership policy contributes to the ability of the NFL to

    function as an effective sports league, and that the NFL's

    functioning would be impaired if publicly owned teams were

    permitted, because the short-term dividend interests of a club's

    shareholder would often conflict with the long-term interests of

    the league as a whole. That is, the policy avoids a detrimental

    conflict of interests between team shareholders and the league.

    We disagree, however, that these factors are sufficient

    to establish as a matter of law that the NFL's ownership policy

    does not unreasonably restrain trade in violation of 1 of the

    Sherman Act. The holdings in Broadcast Music, Rothery Storage,
    ________________ _______________

    and Northwest Stationers, do not throw the "rule of reason" out
    ____________________

    the window merely because one establishes that a given practice

    among joint venture participants is ancillary to legitimate and

    efficient activity -- the injury to competition must still be

    weighed against the purported benefits under the rule of reason.

    See, e.g., Broadcast Music, 441 U.S. at 24 (holding only that a
    ___ ____ _______________

    particular ancillary restraint did not constitute a per se
    _______


    -23-














    violation of the Sherman Act and remanding for a determination of

    the case under a rule of reason analysis); Northwest Stationers,
    ____________________

    472 U.S. at 293-98 (same); see also SCFC ILC, Inc. v. Visa U.S.A.
    ________ ______________ ___________

    Inc., 819 F. Supp. 956, 979-80 (D.Utah 1993) (finding that the
    ____

    existence of a joint venture may save a restraint from per se
    ______

    illegality but not from the normal rule of reason scrutiny).

    One basic tenet of the rule of reason is that a given

    restriction is not reasonable, that is, its benefits cannot

    outweigh its harm to competition, if a reasonable, less

    restrictive alternative to the policy exists that would provide

    the same benefits as the current restraint. L.A. Coliseum, 726
    ______________

    F.2d at 1396. The record contains evidence of a clearly less

    restrictive alternative to the NFL's ownership policy that would

    yield the same benefits as the current policy. Sullivan points

    to one proposal to amend the current ownership policy by allowing

    for the sale of minority, nonvoting shares of team stock to the

    public with restrictions on the size of the holdings by any one

    individual. Dividend payments, if any, would be within the firm

    control of the NFL majority owner. Under such a policy, it would

    be reasonable for a jury to conclude that private control of

    member clubs is maintained, conflicts of interest are avoided,

    and all the other "benefits" of the NFL's joint venture

    arrangement are preserved while at the same time teams would have

    access to the market for public investment capital through the

    sale of ownership interests.

    C. Causation of Injury in Fact
    C. Causation of Injury in Fact


    -24-














    The NFL next argues that Sullivan did not present

    sufficient evidence to support a finding by the jury that the

    NFL's public ownership policy caused injury in fact to Sullivan.

    An antitrust plaintiff must prove that he or she suffered damages

    from an antitrust violation and that there is a causal connection

    between the illegal practice and the injury. Associated General
    __________________

    Contractors, Inc. v. California State Council of Carpenters, 459
    _________________ _______________________________________

    U.S. 519, 532-33 & n.26 (1983); Blue Shield of Virginia v.
    _________________________

    McCready, 457 U.S. 465, 476-78 (1982); Engine Specialties, Inc.
    ________ ________________________

    v. Bombardier Ltd., 605 F.2d 1, 13 (1st Cir. 1979), cert. denied,
    _______________ ____ ______

    446 U.S. 983 (1980). "Plaintiffs need not prove that the

    antitrust violation was the sole cause of their injury, but only

    that it was a material cause." Engine Specialties, 605 F.2d at
    __________________

    14.

    Sullivan asserted at trial that the NFL's ownership

    policy forced him to sell the Patriots at a depressed price, far

    below what the team would have been worth in a market that

    included public ownership of the team. "But for" the NFL's

    policy, Sullivan claims, he would have been able to offer 49% of

    the Patriots to the public for $70 million, pay off his debts,

    and retained ownership of a much more valuable and profitable

    team.

    The NFL contends that Sullivan failed to establish a

    causal connection between his "forced" sale of the Patriots and

    the NFL's ownership policy because (1) Sullivan never officially

    requested a vote on his proposals to amend or waive the policy so


    -25-














    there is no way of knowing whether the policy would have

    prevented a public offering in the first place; and (2) Sullivan

    never established that the public stock sale was feasible or

    potentially successful and thus an alternative to what ultimately

    happened (i.e., even if the NFL did not have a policy against

    public ownership, Sullivan would still have had to sell his team

    because the Patriots stock sale would not have happened or would

    not have raised enough money to pay off Sullivan's debts and

    prevent a fire sale of the team). Although the evidence of

    causation is not overwhelming, it is nevertheless sufficient to

    support the verdict.

    Regarding the NFL's first claim that Sullivan never

    called for a vote from the owners to change or waive the

    ownership policy, Sullivan presented sufficient evidence to show

    that the NFL essentially rejected Sullivan's request, even though

    no official vote was taken. Under certain circumstances, an

    antitrust plaintiff must make a demand on the defendant to allow

    the plaintiff to take some action or obtain some benefit, which

    the defendant's challenged practice is allegedly preventing the

    plaintiff from taking or obtaining, in order to prove that the

    practice caused injury in fact to the plaintiff. See Wells Real
    ___ __________

    Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Bd. of Realtors, 850 F.2d 803, 816
    ____________ ______________________________

    (1st Cir.), cert. denied, 488 U.S. 955 (1988); Out Front
    ____ ______ __________

    Productions, Inc. v. Magid, 748 F.2d 166, 170 (3d Cir. 1984).
    _________________ _____

    Such a requirement only applies, however, where the plaintiff

    cannot otherwise prove that the illegal practice exists or that


    -26-














    the practice is preventing the plaintiff from competing in the

    relevant market; in such cases, a refused demand is the only

    reliable evidence of causation. Out Front, 748 F.2d at 169-70.
    _________

    In cases like the present one, an official request and official

    refusal is not necessary to establish causality because there is

    other evidence showing that defendant's practice caused injury in

    fact to the plaintiff. Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research,
    __________________ __________________

    395 U.S. 100, 120 n.15 (1969); Continental Ore Co. v. Union
    ____________________ _____

    Carbide & Carbon Corp., 370 U.S. 690, 699-702 (1962). There is
    _______________________

    certainly no blanket requirement, as the NFL maintains, in Wells
    _____

    or any other case, that Sullivan must call for a vote and obtain

    an official refusal from the NFL, even if such a request would be

    futile. See, e.g., Wells, 850 F.2d at 816 (finding failure to
    ___ ____ _____

    request access to multiple listing service was critical because

    "[t]here was no evidence of a group boycott;" although court

    noted request "may have been futile," there was no evidence to

    indicate that it would have been, so an actual request was

    required); Chicago Ridge Theatre Ltd. Partnership v. M & R
    _________________________________________ _______

    Amusement Corp., 855 F.2d 465, 470 (7th Cir. 1988) (futility
    _______________

    obviates the need for a demand). Certainly, if Sullivan can

    prove futility independent of any official request, he need not

    show that he actually called for a vote and received a denial

    from the other NFL owners.

    The jury in this case heard evidence that would allow

    it to conclude that the NFL effectively denied Sullivan's request

    for a waiver or amendment of the public ownership policy, and


    -27-














    that an official vote would indeed have been futile. The NFL's

    policy against public ownership was long-standing, and the policy

    withstood several efforts to change it over the years as

    proffered amendment proposals were never brought to a vote.

    Sullivan requested a wavier of, or amendment to, the policy at a

    meeting of the owners on October 27, 1987. His request was

    tabled. After further discussions, then-Commissioner Pete

    Rozelle said that he opposed the proposal and that the chances

    for league approval were "very dubious." Although Sullivan was

    only four votes shy of winning a vote, with seven votes still

    undecided, the jury could reasonably conclude that, in light of

    the Commissioner's statement, Sullivan tried but failed to

    convince those undecided owners to vote in his favor and that an

    actual vote would have been futile. The evidence is thus

    sufficient to support a finding that the NFL's policy was

    effectively enforced against Sullivan and that the policy did in

    fact, when considered with the evidence discussed below, prevent

    Sullivan from making his public offering of 49% of the Patriots.

    Sullivan also presented sufficient evidence to support

    a finding that the Patriots stock sale was both feasible and

    potentially successful. Sullivan met with Stephens, Inc., an

    investment banking firm, to discuss a deal whereby Stephens would

    arrange for a loan of $80 million to Sullivan and his son, half

    of which would be paid back out of the proceeds of the Patriots

    stock offering, which Stephens would also arrange. In a

    subsequent letter, Stephens stated that it had been retained to


    -28-














    assist in the "private placement of $80 million of debt" and set

    out some preliminary terms and conditions. Although specifics of

    the public offering were not discussed, and Stephens did not

    determine whether the stock offering was ultimately feasible,

    Stephens repeatedly made it clear to Sullivan that NFL approval

    was required -- indeed Stephens specifically singled out NFL

    approval as the prerequisite -- before Stephens could proceed any
    ___

    further with efforts to prepare for the placement of Patriots

    stock.

    As discussed above, NFL approval was never obtained.

    Therefore, the jury could conclude that lack of approval was the

    reason Stephens was unwilling to proceed with the deal, even

    though Stephens also expressed some concern about Sullivan's

    financial and legal troubles. The jury also heard testimony that

    Charles Allen, a prominent investment banker in New York, thought

    the Patriots public offering was feasible and that he was

    potentially interested in arranging the deal. Sullivan himself

    testified that the stock sale was feasible based on his

    experience with the previous public offering of Patriots stock in

    1960, and based on the public offering of the Boston Celtics.

    Finally, one of Sullivan's experts, Patrick Brake, testified that

    the public offering would have been feasible had the NFL not

    blocked it.

    In addition, despite significant financial and legal

    problems with the Patriots, the evidence is sufficient to support

    a finding that Sullivan could have solved these problems in the


    -29-














    course of the public offering and, further, that he could have

    brought off a successful stock sale that would have raised at

    least $70 million.

    The NFL focusses its challenge to the potential success

    of Sullivan's offering on the testimony of Patrick Brake, who

    provided the $70 million figure as the value for the stock sale.

    According to the NFL, Brake's testimony could not support the

    jury's finding on causation because it was not supported by any

    facts, it was not grounded in any rational methodology, and it

    ignored important factors indicating that the Patriots offering

    would not be a success. The NFL does not challenge the

    admissibility of Brake's opinion but, instead, claims that his

    opinion cannot support the jury's finding that the Patriots stock

    sale would have been a success if the NFL had allowed it to

    happen.

    "When an expert opinion is not supported by sufficient

    facts to validate it in the eyes of the law, or when indisputable

    record facts contradict or otherwise render the opinion

    unreasonable, it cannot support a jury's verdict." Brooke Group,
    _____________

    Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 113 S. Ct. 2578, 2589
    ____ ________________________________

    (1993); accord Price v. General Motors Corp., 931 F.2d 162, 165
    ______ _____ ____________________

    (1st Cir. 1991); Richardson v. Richardson-Merrell, Inc., 857 F.2d
    __________ ________________________

    823, 829 (D.C. Cir. 1988), cert. denied, 493 U.S. 882 (1989). A
    ____ ______

    jury verdict cannot rest solely on an expert's "bottom line"

    conclusion, without some underlying facts and reasons, or a

    logical inferential process to support the expert's opinion.


    -30-














    Mid-State Fertilizer Co. v. Exchange National Bank, 877 F.2d
    ________________________ _______________________

    1333, 1339 (7th Cir. 1989).

    We agree that the facts and reasoning underlying

    Brake's opinions and testimony leave much to be desired from the

    standpoint of a factfinder charged with determining the facts.

    As a matter of law, however, Brake provided enough of a basis for

    his opinions and had sufficient facts to back his opinions up, to

    support, in combination with the evidence from other sources, a

    jury finding of potential success of the Patriots stock sale

    venture. To begin with, Brake stated in his testimony that his

    opinion was based on a review of documents and depositions in the

    case, a review of the prospectus for the Boston Celtics public

    offering, the fact that future television revenues for the

    Patriots were likely to increase due to the Patriots' appearance

    in the Super Bowl, and the fact that the public stock for NFL

    teams, like the Patriots, would trade at a premium value over

    what the club would otherwise be worth. Brake also stated that

    he looked at a financial statement of the Patriots and was

    apprised of some of the debt and loss history of the club. Other

    testimony and evidence at trial supported the claim that stock of

    NFL teams would sell for a premium above the club's private sale

    value and the claim that TV revenues to the NFL teams would

    increase. Sullivan himself testified that a public offering

    would be successful based upon the success of his earlier

    offering of Patriots stock and on the results of the Celtics

    public offering. There was also testimony -- highly disputed,


    -31-














    but potentially credible testimony nonetheless -- to the effect

    that the Celtics' stock offering was a success and that the

    Patriots stock offering could be patterned after the Celtics

    offering.

    As for the source of Brake's specific $70 million

    figure for the likely proceeds from a sale of 49% of the

    Patriots, Brake explained a two-step public offering process

    which, after subtracting underwriting fees, would yield the

    Sullivan's $70 million. Brake arrived at this figure after

    starting with a base value of $150 million for the Patriots.

    Given the $80 million private sale price of the Patriots obtained

    by Sullivan when he actually sold the team, and given the

    testimony by Brake and others that public stock of NFL teams

    would sell at a premium, we cannot say that the opinion by Brake,

    an investment banking expert, was unreasonable or "not supported

    by sufficient facts to validate it in the eyes of the law."

    Brooke Group, 113 S. Ct. at 2589.
    ____________

    Brake's testimony was not merely conclusory. Rather,

    it was embellished by various explanations and justifications.

    His testimony was also not overwhelmingly contradicted by the

    weight of the evidence or inherently contradictory, unreasonable

    or irrational. Brake did overlook some important factors that

    contradicted his opinion, but he was questioned about these

    factors on cross-examination and the NFL argued them before the

    jury. The factors do not invalidate Brake's opinion as a matter

    of law; rather, they merely go to the weight and credibility of


    -32-














    his opinions which are matters for the jury to consider. The

    basis of the opinion regarding the success of the Patriots public

    offering may be flimsy, but it is not nonexistent or irrational

    as a matter of law.

    Although we share the NFL's skepticism that Sullivan

    would have succeeded in his public offering if the NFL had

    allowed him to try it, we cannot say that, as a matter of law,

    the evidence was so overwhelming that no reasonable jury could

    find that the NFL's policy harmed Sullivan by preventing him from

    doing something he would otherwise have been able to do. We

    therefore reject the NFL's claim that it is entitled to a

    judgment in its favor on the basis that Sullivan failed to prove

    his injury was caused by the alleged antitrust violation.

    D. Assignment of Antitrust Claim
    D. Assignment of Antitrust Claim

    The NFL argues that Sullivan cannot bring this lawsuit

    because he sold his antitrust claim when he sold the Patriots.

    The sale contract between Sullivan and KMS Patriots, L.P.,

    provided that Sullivan transferred to the buyers "all other

    assets" of the Patriots' and its holding company,5 besides those

    specifically listed and those specifically excluded. None of the

    listed or excluded assets include an antitrust claim. According

    to the NFL, the term "all other assets" should be interpreted

    ____________________

    5 The language of the contract actually states "all other assets
    of Selling Group," which includes Sullivan himself. However,
    neither party asserts that Sullivan intended to transfer all his
    personal assets with this clause and, anyway, the "all other
    assets" clause is number seventeen on a list of items referred to
    by the contract as "the following assets of the Club and Holdco
    [the Patriots' holding company]."

    -33-














    broadly to include the present antitrust cause of action. We

    disagree. Absent some express language to the effect that

    Sullivan was selling his football related "antitrust claims" or,

    at the very least, "causes of action," we cannot find that

    Sullivan assigned the present antitrust claim to the buyers of

    the Patriots. Gulfstream III Assocs., Inc. v. Gulfstream
    _______________________________ __________

    Aerospace Corp., 995 F.2d 425, 437-40 (3d Cir. 1993); see also
    ________________ ________

    Lerman v. Joyce Int'l, Inc., 10 F.3d 106, 112 (3d Cir. 1993)
    ______ __________________

    (affirming requirement in Gulfstream that assignment of claim
    __________

    must be "express" but expanding definition of "express" language

    to include a grant of "all causes of action, claims and demands

    of whatsoever nature"). As no such express language appears in

    the contract for the sale of the Patriots, Sullivan did not

    transfer his interest in the present lawsuit to KMS Patriots when

    he sold the team.

    The NFL's arguments concerning the application of 1

    of the Sherman Act to the facts of this case raise a substantial

    challenge to the jury verdict and are certainly weighty enough to

    give us pause. Upon careful consideration of the issues,

    however, we find Sullivan's theory of the case to be a plausible

    one and ultimately find the evidence sufficient to support it.

    For the foregoing reasons, therefore, we see no justification, as

    a matter of law, for ringing the death knell on this litigation.

    IV. TRIAL ERRORS
    IV. TRIAL ERRORS

    Having reviewed those issues which would have warranted

    a judgment in favor of the NFL, had we decided any of those


    -34-














    issues in the NFL's favor, we now turn to the NFL's claim that it

    is entitled to a new trial because of allegedly erroneous jury

    instructions and other trial errors. In particular, the NFL

    asserts that the district court failed to provide the jury with

    several crucial jury instructions that were required in order to

    present to the jury certain legal theories that were potentially

    dispositive of the verdict. The NFL argues that the court's

    failure to give the instructions was prejudicial error requiring

    a new trial.

    Determining whether the failure to give proffered jury

    instructions is error depends on whether the instructions

    actually given to the jury, taken as a whole, adequately

    explained the law or whether they tended to confuse or mislead

    the jury on the controlling issues of the case. Davet v.
    _____

    Maccarone, 973 F.2d 22, 26 (1st Cir. 1992); Transnational Corp.
    _________ ____________________

    v. Rodio & Ursillo, Ltd., 920 F.2d 1066, 1070 (1st Cir. 1990);
    ______________________

    see also L.A. Coliseum, 726 F.2d at 1398 ("The question, then, is
    ________ _____________

    whether, viewing the jury instructions as a whole, the trial

    judge gave adequate instructions on each element of the case to

    insure that the jury fully understood the issues."). We must

    also consider whether the NFL's proposed instructions are

    accurate or misleading. Shane v. Shane, 891 F.2d 976, 987 (1st
    _____ _____

    Cir. 1989). "As long as the judge's instruction properly

    apprises the jury of the applicable law, failure to give the

    exact instruction requested does not prejudice the objecting

    party." Brown v. Trustees of Boston Univ., 891 F.2d 337, 354
    _____ _________________________


    -35-














    (1st Cir. 1989), cert. denied, 496 U.S. 937 (1990) (internal
    ____ ______

    quotations omitted). A party, however, is entitled to have its

    legal theories on controlling issues, which are supported by the

    law and by the evidence, presented to the jury. Jerlyn Yacht
    _____________

    Sales, Inc. v. Roman Yacht Brokerage, 950 F.2d 60, 68 (1st Cir.
    ___________ _____________________

    1991); L.A. Coliseum, 726 F.2d at 1398. An error in the jury
    ______________

    instructions will warrant the reversal of the judgment and a new

    trial only if, upon review of the record as a whole, the error is

    determined to be prejudicial. Davet, 973 F.2d at 26; Jerlyn
    _____ ______

    Yacht Sales, 950 at 69; Transnational Corp., 920 F.2d at 1070.
    ___________ ___________________

    In this case, we find that the failure to give certain

    instructions was prejudicial error6 and we therefore vacate the

    judgment and order a new trial.

    A. Equal Involvement Defense
    A. Equal Involvement Defense

    The NFL argued before the district court that Sullivan

    was a complete and substantially equal participant in the NFL's

    ownership policy which he now challenges in the present lawsuit.

    As a result of Sullivan's involvement, the NFL claimed, Sullivan

    was barred from bringing a damages action under the antitrust

    laws pursuant to the "equal involvement defense" doctrine. The

    district court denied motions for summary judgment and a directed

    verdict on this issue and, further, refused to instruct the jury

    on the availability of the defense because it found that the

    ____________________

    6 The court's failure to instruct on the complete involvement
    defense was prejudicial error and, by itself, sufficient grounds
    for reversal and a new trial. We do not decide whether any of
    the other errors, standing alone, are prejudicial. We do hold,
    however, that all the errors taken together are prejudicial.

    -36-














    evidence showed that Sullivan "had very little, if any,

    involvement in the formulation of [the public ownership] rule,"

    and because the rule "was imposed on [Sullivan] by a preexisting

    National Football League rule." This ruling constituted

    prejudicial error because the "equal involvement defense" is an

    absolute defense to an antitrust claim and because the evidence

    warranted sending the issue to the jury.

    A plaintiff's "complete, voluntary, and substantially

    equal participation" in an illegal practice under the antitrust

    laws precludes recovery for that antitrust violation. CVD, Inc.
    __________

    v. Raytheon Co., 769 F.2d 842, 856 (1st Cir. 1985), cert. denied,
    ____________ ____ ______

    475 U.S. 1016 (1986); General Leaseways, Inc. v. National Truck
    ________________________ ______________

    Leasing Ass'n, 830 F.2d 716, 720-23 (7th Cir. 1987); THI-Hawaii,
    _____________ ___________

    Inc. v. First Commerce Financial Corp., 627 F.2d 991, 995 (9th
    ____ _______________________________

    Cir. 1980); see also Bateman Eichler, Hill, Richards, Inc. v.
    _________ _______________________________________

    Berner, 472 U.S. 299, 310-11 (1985) (applying equal involvement
    ______

    defense in securities law context). In order to establish an

    "equal involvement" defense, an antitrust defendant must prove,

    by a preponderance of the evidence, that the plaintiff bears at

    least substantially equal responsibility for an anticompetitive

    restriction by creating, approving, maintaining, continually and

    actively supporting, relying upon, or otherwise utilizing and

    implementing, that restriction to his or her benefit.7 General
    _______

    ____________________

    7 The Supreme Court in Bateman added an additional requirement
    _______
    to the "equal involvement" defense: that "preclusion of suit
    would not significantly interfere with the effective enforcement
    of" the antitrust laws. Bateman, 472 U.S. at 311. We do not see
    _______
    a preclusion of Sullivan's damages action as presenting any

    -37-














    Leaseways, 830 F.2d at 720-26; CVD, 769 F.2d at 856. It is not
    _________ ___

    essential to the defense that the plaintiff actually helped

    author or create the policy, although such facts would be highly

    probative, as long as the plaintiff was substantially responsible

    for maintaining and otherwise effectuating the policy. See,
    ___

    e.g., General Leaseways, 830 F.2d at 723 (applying equal
    ____ __________________

    involvement defense in case where plaintiff did not participate

    in the actual adoption of the policy although plaintiff was

    substantially involved in supporting, enforcing and maintaining

    the policy).8 On the other hand, proof that the plaintiff

    benefitted from the challenged policy or failed to object to the

    policy, without more, is not sufficient to show "substantially

    equal participation." See id., 830 F.2d at 725 (noting that
    ___ __

    "mere participation" in the challenged policy is not enough).

    Moreover, proof that the plaintiff was coerced ("economically" or


    ____________________

    significant interference with antitrust law enforcement. The
    NFL's policy is still subject to challenge under the antitrust
    laws. Because the equal involvement defense only precludes a
    damages action, Sullivan could have requested injunctive relief
    when the public ownership policy was allegedly preventing him
    from selling 49% of his team. In addition, other owners who were
    not involved in the adoption or support of the policy may still
    bring suit should they desire to sell ownership interests in
    their team to the public.

    8 To the extent this conflicts with the "but for" standard
    applied in THI-Hawaii, 627 F.2d at 995 (finding that "a
    __________
    plaintiff's recovery is not barred unless the illegal conspiracy
    would not have been formed but for its participation"), we
    ________
    decline to follow that portion of the case. There is no evidence
    of such a rigid "but for" requirement in the Supreme Court's
    formulation of the equal involvement defense in Bateman, 472 U.S.
    _______
    at 310-11 (finding the defense applies where "as a direct result
    of his own actions, the plaintiff bears at least substantially
    equal responsibility for the violations he seeks to redress").

    -38-














    otherwise) into supporting the policy, that the plaintiff

    attempted to oppose the illegal conduct, or that the plaintiff's

    participation was otherwise not voluntary, is highly probative of

    the absence of complete and equal involvement by the plaintiff in

    an antitrust violation. E.g., CVD, 769 F.2d at 856.
    ____ ___

    In this case, the evidence in the record was sufficient

    to support a jury instruction on the equal involvement defense.

    Sullivan was one of the three AFL members on the Joint Committee

    that established the policies, including the ownership policies,

    that were to govern the new expanded NFL. That Committee agreed,

    in a merger agreement signed by Sullivan, to adopt the NFL's

    policy against public ownership for the new NFL. Sullivan's son,

    Chuck, stated that Sullivan was the central figure in the merger

    negotiations. Sullivan subsequently relied on the NFL's public

    ownership policy to justify his purchase, through the merger of

    his team into a wholly owned company, of the outstanding stock of

    the Patriots in 1976. In the proxy statement for that

    transaction, Sullivan listed the NFL's policy against public

    ownership as one of the "Reasons for the Merger", and he attached

    a letter from the NFL justifying the public ownership policy and

    explaining that the continued presence of public stockholders

    conflicted with the interests of the league. Sullivan also

    affirmatively supported the policy in sworn testimony during the

    litigation with his former shareholders following the Patriots

    merger. Sullivan stated that the NFL's public ownership policy,

    and the justifications underlying the policy, were the reasons


    -39-














    for his desire to purchase all outstanding shares of the team.

    There is no evidence that Sullivan ever opposed or objected to

    theownership policypriorto thecircumstances surroundingthis case.

    Taken together, this evidence is sufficient for a

    reasonable jury to conclude that Sullivan bears substantially

    equal responsibility for the NFL's public ownership policy

    because Sullivan helped adopt the policy, he relied upon it, and

    he actively supported it. The jury, however, was never given an

    opportunity to consider this evidence in light of the equal

    involvement defense.

    Sullivan claims that he was not at the meetings in

    which Lamar Hunt, the chairman of the AFL committee, agreed to

    the NFL's public ownership policy, and that he did not know in

    advance that the old NFL's public ownership rule would be adopted

    by the new NFL. Mr. Hunt himself testified, however, that he

    always spoke for the entire AFL committee at his various meetings

    with NFL owners, and that he discussed various negotiating points

    with the other AFL owners, including Sullivan, before any

    decisions were made. Moreover, Sullivan's own team obtained a

    specific waiver from the ownership policy, which, a reasonably

    jury could infer, indicates that Sullivan was involved in the

    decision to adopt the policy. In any event, it is the jury's

    responsibility to weigh the evidence and make a choice in

    circumstances like this where the same evidence supports two

    different yet reasonable conclusions.

    The district court erred by failing to give the jury


    -40-














    the opportunity to choose between these versions of the facts.

    The court's "finding" that Sullivan's involvement in the public

    ownership policy was minimal ignores evidence in the record. The

    court's view that the NFL imposed the ownership policy on the AFL

    owners, rendering their participation involuntary, is largely

    unsupported by the record. Ultimately, however, these are

    factual questions for the jury and none of the instructions

    provided by the district court served to adequately instruct the

    jury on this issue or send the issue to the jury. Therefore, the

    district court erred in refusing to give the NFL's proffered

    instruction on the "equal involvement" defense.

    The error was prejudicial. By refusing to instruct the

    jury on the equal involvement defense, the district court

    deprived the NFL of a complete defense from Sullivan's lawsuit.

    The NFL presented facts that could have led to a dismissal of the

    case if they were believed by a properly instructed jury. While

    the NFL could have highlighted, and in fact did highlight, some

    of the facts concerning Sullivan's support of, and reliance upon,

    the ownership policy in its closing argument before the jury,

    this effort was limited to the argument that the NFL's policy was

    "reasonable" for purposes of the rule of reason analysis. The

    NFL did not, and could not, argue to the jury that it should rule

    in favor of the NFL because Sullivan's participation in the

    adoption and maintenance of the public ownership policy was

    complete, voluntary and substantially equal. Without the

    proffered instruction, the jury had no occasion to consider


    -41-














    whether Sullivan should be deprived of a damages remedy because

    of his involvement in the policy he now challenges. As a result,

    the district court's refusal to send the equal involvement

    defense to the jury was prejudicial error requiring a new trial.

    B. Failure to Request an Official Vote of the Owners
    B. Failure to Request an Official Vote of the Owners

    As discussed in Section II.C. above, in order to

    establish that the policy actually caused injury to himself,

    Sullivan must prove that the NFL effectively denied his request

    to waive or amend its policy against public ownership. While

    there is evidence that supports a finding that the NFL's policy

    effectively blocked Sullivan from pursuing his public offering,

    there is also sufficient evidence to support a contrary finding.

    Sullivan's failure to request a vote from the owners after he

    discovered that he was four votes shy of obtaining a waiver with

    seven owners still undecided, combined with former Commissioner

    Rozelle's testimony that he told Sullivan that Rozelle would put

    to the owners any plan that Sullivan wished, could support a

    finding that Sullivan was a "dormant plaintiff" who did not

    "spring into action" until it was "time to file suit." Out
    ___

    Front, 748 F.2d at 170. As such, a jury could conclude that the
    _____

    NFL did not prevent Sullivan from pursuing his stock sale, but

    instead, Sullivan simply dropped the idea for reasons unrelated

    to the NFL's policy. If the jury had reached such a conclusion,

    Sullivan would have failed to prove that his injury was caused by

    the antitrust policy, and judgment for the NFL would be required.

    The NFL proposed instructions concerning Sullivan's


    -42-














    failure to ask for a vote essentially stating that such a failure

    would result in judgment for the NFL if it was reasonable to

    require Sullivan to make such a request. The court refused to

    give the instruction because it felt that to do so would be to

    comment on the evidence, and the court did not want to comment on

    any of the evidence presented at trial. We understand the

    court's concern but believe that, under the facts of this case,

    there is a crucial point of law contained in the NFL's

    instruction that was not otherwise provided to the jury.

    The jury was instructed generally on the issue of

    causation, but it was not told that it had to determine whether

    the NFL's policy against public ownership was actually enforced

    against Sullivan; that is, whether the policy, the alleged

    antitrust restraint, actually restrained Sullivan in any way from

    making a 49% public offering of his team. Although the NFL

    could, and did, argue that Sullivan's failure to ask for a vote

    was evidence that the policy did not cause injury to Sullivan,

    there was no legal hook upon which the jury could hang the NFL's

    argument. The failure of Sullivan to request a vote is a

    critical and potentially dispositive issue in this case. If the

    alleged restraint of trade does not even exist in practice, the

    whole case essentially disappears. Therefore, the jury should

    have been directed to make a specific finding as to whether the

    public ownership policy was enforced against Sullivan.

    If the jury is instructed that Sullivan must prove that

    the NFL's policy was enforced against him, the jury will have


    -43-














    cause to consider the crucial matter of whether the NFL actually

    enforced its policy against Sullivan or rather, whether the NFL

    never had the chance to enforce its policy because Sullivan was

    never prepared to pursue his public offering. The instructions

    as proffered by the NFL may need to be tailored to avoid

    commenting on the evidence surrounding the "missing" vote by the

    NFL owners, but that does not excuse the court from giving no

    instruction at all on the issue. The failure to give some

    instruction concerning the failure of Sullivan to request a vote

    was error.

    C. The Murray Option
    C. The Murray Option

    In 1986, prior to Sullivan's decision to sell Patriots

    stock to the public, Sullivan sold Fran Murray an option to buy

    the entire club. The NFL took the position that the Murray

    option would have been an absolute bar to any public sale of

    Patriots stock and that Sullivan therefore could not prove

    causation. The NFL's position was supported by evidence

    introduced at trial. Sullivan proffered evidence that the option

    was not a bar to sale because the option could be bought out and

    because it could not be legally enforced. The issue of whether

    Murray could have, or would have, blocked a public offering by

    the Patriots was ultimately disputed.

    The option agreement and Murray's deposition testimony

    were received into evidence. The district court, however,

    refused to admit Murray's statement that he would indeed have

    stopped any public stock sale of the Patriots from going forward


    -44-














    if he had been told about it. The court found the testimony to

    be too speculative to be admissible. While the court's decision

    to exclude Murray's "speculative" testimony is well within the

    court's wide latitude of discretion in making such evidentiary

    rulings, United States v. Abel, 469 U.S. 45, 54 (1984); Doty v.
    _____________ ____ ____

    Sewall, 908 F.2d 1053, 1058 (1st Cir. 1990), we note that
    ______

    Sullivan's entire case as to the causation of injury was equally

    speculative. Whether Sullivan's proposed stock sale could have

    proceeded and would have been successful in the absence of the

    NFL's public ownership policy was a matter of considerable

    conjecture. Fairness would seem to militate towards allowing the

    NFL to present its own version of the probable course of future

    events to counter Sullivans' theorizing.

    In any event, the court's subsequent refusal to give

    the NFL's proffered jury instruction on the law of options,

    specifically the legal consequences of options under

    Massachusetts law, erroneously removed another crucial issue from

    the jury's purview. The Murray option was a key defense for the

    NFL, because if Sullivan did not have a legal right to sell

    Patriots stock to the public, he did not suffer any harm from the

    NFL's ownership policy and the NFL would have been entitled to

    judgment in its favor. Again, the NFL could make this argument

    to the jury, but the jury would still lack crucial information

    concerning the legal underpinnings of a crucial defense for the

    NFL.

    Sullivan argues that the NFL's proposed instruction


    -45-














    would have singled out one factual issue related to causation for

    the jury's special attention, something that would have unfairly

    prejudiced Sullivan. Sullivan adds that allowing the instruction

    would have generated countering instructions on other legal

    facets of option law that were relevant to Sullivan's position on

    the option issue and ultimately would have confused the jury.

    These arguments notwithstanding, we feel that, as long as

    suitable instructions are provided covering the basic legal

    points relevant to each party's arguments, the jury would not be

    unduly confused. Furthermore, the risk of prejudice from the

    instruction -- due to the added attention afforded one of the

    NFL's defenses -- is not sufficient to justify effectively

    depriving the NFL of a crucial defense. Ultimately, it was for

    the jury to decide whether the Murray option constituted an

    insurmountable obstacle to Sullivan's case on causation, and the

    district court's refusal to instruct on the law of options

    virtually removed this issue from consideration by the jury.

    D. Balancing Procompetitive and Anticompetitive Effects
    D. Balancing Procompetitive and Anticompetitive Effects
    in the Relevant Market
    in the Relevant Market

    As we noted above, the rule of reason analysis requires

    a weighing of the injury and the benefits to competition

    attributable to a practice that allegedly violates the antitrust

    laws. Monahan's Marine, 866 F.2d at 526. The district court
    ________________

    instructed the jury on its verdict form to balance the injury to

    competition in the relevant market with the benefits to

    competition in that same relevant market. The NFL protested,

    claiming that all procompetitive effects of its policy, even

    -46-














    those in a market different from that in which the alleged

    restraint operated, should be considered. The NFL's case was

    premised on the claim that its policy against public ownership

    was an important part of the effective functioning of the league

    as a joint venture. Although it was not readily apparent that

    this beneficial effect applied to the market for ownership

    interests in NFL teams, the relevant market found by the jury,

    the NFL argued that its justification should necessarily be

    weighed by the jury under the rule of reason analysis. Sullivan

    responded, and the district court agreed, that a jury cannot be

    asked to compare what are essentially apples and oranges, and

    that it is impossible to conduct a balancing of alleged

    anticompetitive and procompetitive effects of a challenged

    practice in every definable market.

    The issue of defining the proper scope of a rule of

    reason analysis is a deceptive body of water, containing

    unforeseen currents and turbulence lying just below the surface

    of an otherwise calm and peaceful ocean. The waters are muddied

    by the Supreme Court's decision in NCAA -- one of the more
    ____

    extensive examples of the Court performing a rule of reason

    analysis -- where the Court considered the value of certain

    procompetitive effects that existed outside of the relevant

    market in which the restraint operated. NCAA, 468 U.S. at 115-20
    ____

    (considering the NCAA's interest in protecting live attendance at

    untelevised games and the NCAA's "legitimate and important"

    interest in maintaining competitive balance between amateur


    -47-














    athletic teams as a justification for a restraint that operated

    in a completely different market, the market for the telecasting

    of collegiate football games).9 Other courts have demonstrated

    similar confusion. See, e.g., L.A. Coliseum, 726 F.2d at 1381,
    ___ ____ _____________

    1392, 1397, 1399 (stating that the "relevant market provides the

    basis on which to balance competitive harms and benefits of the

    restraint at issue" but then considering a wide variety of

    alleged benefits, and then directing the finder of fact to

    "balance the gain to interbrand competition against the loss of

    intrabrand competition", where the two types of competition

    operated in different markets).

    To our knowledge, no authority has squarely addressed

    this issue. On the one hand, several courts have expressed

    concern over the use of wide ranging interests to justify an

    otherwise anticompetitive practice, and others have found

    particular justifications to be incomparable and not in

    correlation with the alleged restraint of trade. Smith v. Pro
    _____ ___

    Football, Inc., 593 F.2d 1173, 1186 (D.C. Cir. 1978); Brown v.
    _______________ _____

    Pro Football, Inc., 812 F. Supp. 237, 238 (D.D.C. 1992); Chicago
    __________________ _______

    Pro. Sports Ltd. Partnership v. National Basketball Ass'n, 754 F.
    ____________________________ _________________________

    ____________________

    9 The Supreme Court did not expressly consider the issue
    presented here. Therefore, it is impossible to tell whether the
    Court was consciously applying the rule of reason to include a
    broad area of procompetitive benefits in a variety of markets, or
    whether the Court was simply not being very careful and
    inadvertently extended the rule of reason past its proper scope.
    There is certainly no language, as Sullivan suggests, indicating
    that the Court was considering the alleged benefit of
    "competitive balance" only to the extent that it had
    procompetitive effects in the market for televised football
    games.

    -48-














    Supp. 1336, 1358 (N.D.Ill. 1991). We agree that the ultimate

    question under the rule of reason is whether a challenged

    practice promotes or suppresses competition. Thus, it seems

    improper to validate a practice that is decidedly in restraint of

    trade simply because the practice produces some unrelated

    benefits to competition in another market.

    On the other hand, several courts, including this

    Circuit, have found it appropriate in some cases to balance the

    anticompetitive effects on competition in one market with certain

    procompetitive benefits in other markets. See, e.g., NCAA, 468
    ___ ____ ____

    U.S. at 115-20; Grappone, Inc. v. Subaru of New England, Inc.,
    ______________ ____________________________

    858 F.2d 792, 799 (1st Cir. 1988); M & H Tire Co. v. Hoosier
    _______________ _______

    Racing Tire Corp., 733 F.2d 973, 986 (1st Cir. 1984); L.A.
    __________________ ____

    Coliseum, 726 F.2d at 1381, 1392, 1397, 1399. Moreover, the
    ________

    district court's argument that it would be impossible to compare

    the procompetitive effects of the NFL's policy in the interbrand
    _____

    market of competition between the NFL and other forms of

    entertainment, with the anticompetitive effects of the intrabrand
    _____

    market of competition between NFL teams for the sale of their

    ownership interests, is arguably refuted by the Supreme Court's

    holding in Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S.
    ______________________ _________________

    36 (1977). Continental T.V. explicitly recognized that positive
    _________________

    effects on interbrand competition can justify anticompetitive
    _____

    effects on intrabrand competition. Id. at 51-59. Although
    _____ __

    Continental T.V. can reasonably be interpreted as referring only
    ________________

    to interbrand and intrabrand components of the same relevant
    ______________


    -49-














    market, Hornsby Oil Co., Inc. v. Champion Spark Plug Co., 714
    ______ ______________________ ________________________

    F.2d 1384, 1394 (5th Cir. 1983), there is also some indication

    that interbrand and intrabrand competition necessarily refer to

    distinct, yet related, markets. Continental T.V., 433 U.S. at 52
    ________________

    n.19 ("The degree of intrabrand competition is wholly independent

    of the level of interbrand competition."). Arguably, the market

    put forward by the NFL -- that is the market for NFL football in

    competition with other forms of entertainment -- is closely

    related to the relevant market found by the jury such that the

    procompetitive benefits in one can be compared to the

    anticompetitive harms in the other. Clearly this question can

    only be answered upon a much more in-depth inquiry that we need

    not, nor find it appropriate to, embark upon at this time.

    Finally, we note that although balancing harms and

    benefits in different markets may be unwieldy and confusing, such

    is the case with a number of balancing tests that a court or jury

    is expected to apply all the time. Indeed, Justice Brandeis'

    famous formulation of the rule of reason seems to contemplate the

    balancing of a wide variety of factors and considerations, many

    of which are not necessarily comparable or correlative:

    The true test of legality is whether the
    restraint imposed is such as merely
    regulates and perhaps thereby promotes
    competition or whether it is such as may
    suppress or even destroy competition. To
    determine that question the court must
    ordinarily consider the facts peculiar to
    the business to which the restraint is
    applied; its condition before and after
    the restraint was imposed; the nature of
    the restraint and its effect, actual or
    probable. The history of the restraint,

    -50-














    the evil believed to exist, the reason
    for adopting the particular remedy, the
    purpose or end sought to be attained, are
    all relevant facts.

    Board of Trade of the City of Chicago v. United States, 246 U.S.
    ______________________________________ _____________

    231, 238 (1918).

    Although the issue of the proper scope of the rule of

    reason analysis is more appropriately resolved in a case where it

    is dispositive and more fully briefed, we can draw at least one

    general conclusion from the caselaw at this point: courts should

    generally give a measure of latitude to antitrust defendants in

    their efforts to explain the procompetitive justifications for

    their policies and practices; however, courts should also

    maintain some vigilance by excluding justifications that are so

    unrelated to the challenged practice that they amount to a

    collateral attempt to salvage a practice that is decidedly in

    restraint of trade.

    In any event, we need not enter these dangerous waters

    to resolve the instant dispute. The NFL wanted the jury to

    consider its proffered justifications for the public ownership

    policy -- namely that the policy enhanced the NFL's ability to

    effectively produce and present a popular entertainment product

    unimpaired by the conflicting interests that public ownership

    would cause. These procompetitive justifications should have

    been considered by the jury, even under Sullivan's theory of the

    proper scope of the rule of reason analysis. As we point out in

    note [4] above, and as Sullivan himself points out, to the extent

    the NFL's policy strengthens and improves the league, resulting

    -51-














    in increased competition in the market for ownership interests in

    NFL clubs through, for example, more valuable teams, the jury may

    consider the NFL's justifications as relevant factors in its rule

    of reason analysis. The danger of the proffered instructions on

    the verdict form is that they may have mislead the jury into

    thinking that it was precluded from considering the NFL's

    justifications for its ownership policy. Therefore, the relevant

    market language on the verdict form should be removed, or else

    the jury should be informed that evidence of benefits to

    competition in the relevant market can include evidence of

    benefits flowing indirectly from the public ownership policy that

    ultimately have a beneficial impact on competition in the

    relevant market itself.

    E. References to Prior Antitrust Cases Against the NFL
    E. References to Prior Antitrust Cases Against the NFL

    Despite a pretrial motion in limine and repeated
    __________

    objections by the NFL, the district court allowed the jury to

    hear numerous references to prior antitrust cases against the

    NFL. Evidence about prior antitrust violations by the defendant

    may, in appropriate cases, be admissible to show things like

    market power, intent to monopolize, motive, or method of

    conspiracy. United States Football League v. National Football
    _____________________________ _________________

    League, 842 F.2d 1335, 1371 (2d Cir. 1988) (hereinafter "USFL").
    ______ ____

    Because of the inherently prejudicial nature of such evidence,

    however, evidence of prior antitrust cases involving the NFL are

    only admissible if Sullivan can demonstrate that the conduct

    underlying those prior judgments had a direct, logical


    -52-














    relationship to the conduct at issue in the present case. USFL,
    ____

    842 F.2d at 1371; International Shoe Mach. Corp. v. United Shoe
    ______________________________ ___________

    Mach. Corp., 315 F.2d 449, 454 (1st Cir.), cert. denied, 375 U.S.
    ___________ ____ ______

    820 (1963) (plaintiff must show "that his claimed injury stemmed

    directly and proximately from the same type of practice condemned

    in the prior Government action"); see also Coleman Motor Co. v.
    ________ __________________

    Chrysler Corp., 525 F.2d 1338, 1351 (3d Cir. 1975). In many of
    _______________

    the instances where Sullivan or his counsel made references to

    prior antitrust cases at trial, Sullivan failed to satisfy this

    burden.

    Sullivan argues that the prior cases were relevant

    either to certain testimony regarding the reasonableness of the

    NFL's ownership policy and voting requirements or to the issue of

    defining the relevant market. Because none of the cases

    mentioned at trial concerned the NFL's ownership policy at issue

    here, evidence of those prior cases is not relevant to the

    reasonableness of the NFL's policy against public ownership. The

    general voting requirements are not in dispute, so cases touching

    solely upon them are also not relevant. Certain limited portions

    of some prior antitrust decisions are relevant to the issue of

    defining the relevant market. The testimony and commentary at

    trial concerning these prior cases, however, was not limited to

    the relevant market portions of these cases and, on the contrary,

    focussed primarily on the issue of whether the NFL's public

    ownership policy was unreasonable. As such, that evidence was

    prejudicial, without any balancing relevance to justify its


    -53-














    admission into evidence.

    The references to prior NFL cases were made in a number

    of different contexts during the trial (including during direct

    examination, cross-examination, and at closing argument), and

    they contained a variety of different information. These

    references are not likely to be repeated in precisely the same

    context upon a new trial. Therefore, instead of identifying

    which particular pieces of evidence were inadmissible, we think

    it would be more useful to point out more generally that

    references to prior NFL cases are not relevant to the issue of

    the reasonableness of the NFL's public ownership policy and such

    references should be excluded if they contain information about

    the unreasonableness of other policies of the NFL which were at

    issue in the other cases.

    Reversed and remanded.
    _____________________
























    -54-







Document Info

Docket Number: 94-1031

Filed Date: 9/29/1994

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/21/2015

Authorities (56)

Cvd, Incorporated v. Raytheon Company, and Third-Party , 769 F.2d 842 ( 1985 )

M & H Tire Company, Inc. v. Hoosier Racing Tire Corporation , 733 F.2d 973 ( 1984 )

The Interface Group, Inc. v. Massachusetts Port Authority , 816 F.2d 9 ( 1987 )

Monahan's Marine, Inc. v. Boston Whaler, Inc. , 866 F.2d 525 ( 1989 )

Hendricks & Associates, Inc. v. Daewoo Corporation , 923 F.2d 209 ( 1991 )

Jerlyn Yacht Sales, Inc., and Oklahoma Offset, Inc. v. ... , 950 F.2d 60 ( 1991 )

Herbert W. Price, Etc. v. General Motors Corporation, ... , 931 F.2d 162 ( 1991 )

Richard F. Davet v. Enrico MacCarone , 973 F.2d 22 ( 1992 )

Michael B. Shane v. James H. Shane , 891 F.2d 976 ( 1989 )

Arthur Doty v. Richard Sewall, Arthur Doty v. Richard Sewall , 908 F.2d 1053 ( 1990 )

Town of Concord, Massachusetts v. Boston Edison Company , 915 F.2d 17 ( 1990 )

Transnational Corp. v. Rodio & Ursillo, Ltd., Etc. , 920 F.2d 1066 ( 1990 )

International Shoe MacHine Corporation v. United Shoe ... , 315 F.2d 449 ( 1963 )

united-states-v-kenneth-innamorati-united-states-v-william-thompson , 996 F.2d 456 ( 1993 )

Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Board of Realtors , 850 F.2d 803 ( 1988 )

Dennis J. Domegan v. Michael v. Fair , 859 F.2d 1059 ( 1988 )

Grappone, Inc. v. Subaru of New England, Inc. , 858 F.2d 792 ( 1988 )

Engine Specialties, Inc. v. Bombardier Limited , 605 F.2d 1 ( 1979 )

Carolyn M. GALLAGHER, Plaintiff, Appellee, v. WILTON ... , 962 F.2d 120 ( 1992 )

united-states-football-league-arizona-outlaws-baltimore-stars-football , 842 F.2d 1335 ( 1988 )

View All Authorities »