PNE Energy Supply LLC v. Eversource Energy ( 2020 )


Menu:
  •           United States Court of Appeals
    For the First Circuit
    No. 19-1678
    PNE ENERGY SUPPLY LLC, on behalf of itself
    and all others similarly situated,
    Plaintiff, Appellant,
    v.
    EVERSOURCE ENERGY, a Massachusetts Voluntary Association;
    AVANGRID, INC., a New York Corporation,
    Defendants, Appellees.
    APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF MASSACHUSETTS
    [Hon. Denise J. Casper, U.S. District Judge]
    Before
    Thompson, Lipez, and Kayatta,
    Circuit Judges.
    Austin B. Cohen, Keith J. Verrier, Levin Sedran & Berman LLP,
    Anthony Tarricone, and Kreindler & Kreindler LLP on brief for
    appellant.
    Mark A. Gottlieb, Public Health Advocacy Institute, Sandeep
    Vaheesan, Open Markets Institute, Paula S. Bliss, and Bernheim
    Dolinsky Kelley LLC on brief for Open Markets Institute, amicus
    curiae.
    Douglas G. Green, Shannen W. Coffin, Mark C. Savignac, Steptoe
    & Johnson LLP, John D. Donovan, Jr., Chong S. Park, and Ropes &
    Gray LLP on joint brief for appellee Eversource Energy.
    Richard P. Bress, Marguerite M. Sullivan, Caroline A. Flynn,
    and Latham & Watkins LLP on joint brief for appellee Avangrid,
    Inc.
    September 9, 2020
    KAYATTA, Circuit Judge.        In 2017, a group of economists
    working with the Environmental Defense Fund published a report
    alleging that the defendants in this case were able to increase
    electricity prices in New England about 20% on average, totaling
    $3.6 billion in surcharges over three years between 2013 and 2016,
    by buying up and refusing to release excess transmission capacity
    in the Algonquin pipeline.         See Levi Marks et al., Vertical Market
    Power in Interconnected Natural Gas and Electricity Markets 4
    (2017),     https://www.edf.org/sites/default/files/vertical-market-
    power.pdf. In response, a group of electricity end consumers filed
    suit in November 2017 alleging violations of state and federal
    antitrust and unfair competition law.           See Breiding v. Eversource
    Energy, 
    344 F. Supp. 3d 433
    , 444 (D. Mass. 2018), aff'd, 
    939 F.3d 47
       (1st    Cir.    2019).      After   the   defendants    challenged   the
    electricity consumers' standing to sue under the federal antitrust
    laws for manipulation in gas transmission markets, PNE Energy
    Supply LLC, a wholesale energy purchaser, filed this lawsuit on
    behalf of itself and other similarly situated energy purchasers,
    also challenging the defendants' alleged manipulation of natural
    gas pipeline capacity.          Last fall, we affirmed the dismissal of
    the electricity consumers' suit. Breiding, 939 F.3d at 57. Rather
    than   taking   up    the     defendants'   challenge   to   the   electricity
    consumers' antitrust standing, we held that the antitrust claims
    failed on their merits because the defendants' challenged conduct,
    - 3 -
    in neither using nor releasing reserved pipeline capacity, all
    occurred pursuant to a tariff approved by the Federal Energy
    Regulatory Commission.         Id. at 52–56.     We now consider in this
    second case whether any differences between the two cases warrant
    a different outcome.          For the following reasons, we find that
    Breiding controls. We therefore affirm the dismissal of this case.
    I.
    A.
    To provide context regarding the relevant energy market
    and actors at issue in this case, we begin by repeating verbatim
    the description we provided in Breiding, 939 F.3d at 49–51:
    *    *      *
    "Wellhead" sales comprise the first step in the chain of
    market   transactions     that    readies    extracted   natural   gas   for
    consumption in the form of retail electricity.            At this initial
    stage, natural gas producers sell natural gas to direct purchasers
    through gas futures contracts, in which the producer agrees to
    sell a specific quantity of natural gas at some fixed time in the
    future   to    the   direct   purchaser.     Load-distribution     companies
    (LDCs) -- those entities that locally distribute natural gas,
    primarily to retail consumers who use the gas for heating and
    cooking -- have a relatively predictable need for natural gas and,
    - 4 -
    thus, often make use of this type of contract.1           Consumers with
    more variable demand for natural gas, such as power generators,
    often purchase gas on the secondary wholesale "spot market."            The
    spot market for natural gas allows direct purchasers that find
    themselves with rights to excess, unneeded natural gas to resell
    those rights in the immediate or near future.
    The Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) is the
    agency charged with implementing and executing the Natural Gas Act
    (NGA), "a comprehensive scheme of federal regulation of 'all
    wholesales of natural gas in interstate commerce.'"          N. Nat. Gas
    Co. v. State Corp. Comm'n, 
    372 U.S. 84
    , 91 (1963) (quoting Phillips
    Petroleum Co. v. Wisconsin, 
    347 U.S. 672
    , 682 (1954)); see also 15
    U.S.C. § 717c(a) (tasking FERC with ensuring that rates charged
    for sales of natural gas within FERC's jurisdiction are "just and
    reasonable").         Notwithstanding   the   comprehensiveness   of   this
    regulatory scheme, Congress also exempted wellhead sales from
    FERC's regulatory jurisdiction.         See 
    15 U.S.C. § 3431
    (a)(1)(A).
    Accordingly, market forces dictate the wellhead price of natural
    gas.       
    Id.
     § 3431(b)(1)(A) ("[A]ny amount paid in any first sale of
    natural gas shall be deemed to be just and reasonable.").              And
    while the NGA grants FERC regulatory authority over "sale[s] . . .
    1The defendants nevertheless point out that LDCs operating
    in New England do face some variability in demand for natural gas
    due to rapidly changing weather conditions in the region.
    - 5 -
    for resale" in the spot market for natural gas, see 
    15 U.S.C. § 717
    (b),    FERC    has    issued     a    "blanket       certificate       of    public
    convenience    and    necessity"       that       allows    such     transactions        to
    proceed at market rates, see 
    18 C.F.R. § 284.402
    .
    Direct       purchasers    of       natural    gas     also    pay    for   the
    transmission of natural gas from the wellhead.                      The Algonquin Gas
    pipeline serves as the primary interstate artery through which
    natural gas is transported in New England.                       Direct purchasers in
    New England must reserve transmission capacity -- that is, the
    physical space in the pipeline needed to transport the natural gas
    purchased    from    the    producer       --    along     the    Algonquin      pipeline
    commensurate with their transportation needs.                             FERC also has
    "exclusive jurisdiction over the transportation . . . of natural
    gas   in   interstate      commerce    for       resale"     and    is     charged      with
    "determin[ing]       a     'just      and       reasonable'        rate      for     [its]
    transportation."         Schneidewind v. ANR Pipeline Co., 
    485 U.S. 293
    ,
    300–01 (1988). Pursuant to this exclusive authority, FERC requires
    interstate pipeline operators like Algonquin to allow LDCs to
    purchase capacity using "no-notice" contracts.                     See Order No. 636,
    
    57 Fed. Reg. 13,267
     (Apr. 16, 1992).                Such contracts allow LDCs to
    adjust capacity reservations downward or upward (up to their daily
    "firm entitlements") at any time without incurring penalties.                            Id.
    at 13,286.       Importantly, FERC regulations allow, but do not
    require, LDCs to resell unneeded transportation capacity to other
    - 6 -
    natural gas purchasers when they downwardly adjust their capacity
    reservations.     See 
    18 C.F.R. § 284.8
    ; Tenn. Gas Pipeline Co., 
    102 FERC ¶ 61,075
    , 61,119 (2003) ("[N]othing requires a shipper to
    release its capacity: it does so by choice.").
    In the wholesale market for electricity, load-serving
    entities (LSEs) that sell and deliver electricity to consumers for
    retail consumption purchase electricity from power generators.
    The Federal Power Act (FPA) charges FERC with regulating these
    wholesale sales2 of electricity in interstate commerce and ensuring
    that rates in that market are "just and reasonable."                 See 
    16 U.S.C. §§ 824
    (b)(1),     824d(a).        In    executing    that     charge,   FERC    has
    delegated     authority      to    nonprofit       organizations,       including
    independent    system     operators      (ISOs),    to   manage      auctions   for
    wholesale electricity in the various regional markets across the
    country.    Hughes v. Talen Energy Mktg., LLC, 
    136 S. Ct. 1288
    , 1292
    (2016).     ISO   New   England        (ISO-NE)    oversees    the    markets   for
    wholesale electricity in the New England region and administers
    two auctions for wholesale electricity that are relevant to this
    appeal: a same-day auction and a next-day auction to satisfy LSEs'
    short-term and near-term demand for electricity. In both auctions,
    ISO-NE accepts orders from LSEs designating the amount of energy
    they need at a given time.              Power generators then submit bids
    2  A "[s]ale of electric energy at wholesale" is a "sale of
    electric energy to any person for resale." 
    16 U.S.C. § 824
    (d).
    - 7 -
    indicating the amount of electricity they can produce at those
    times and the price they are willing to charge for it.                          ISO-NE
    accepts   those     bids   from     lowest         to    highest   until    demand   is
    satisfied.       The price of the last accepted bid is the "clearing
    price," which sets the price paid to all the generators whose bids
    were accepted.
    Approximately      half       of      New    England's   electricity     is
    generated from natural gas power plants.                    As a result, bids from
    natural gas generators usually set the clearing price for wholesale
    electricity, which then drives the retail prices charged by LSEs
    to retail consumers.          FERC does not oversee the retail sale of
    electricity.       See FERC v. Elec. Power Supply Ass'n, 
    136 S. Ct. 760
    , 766 (2016) ("[T]he law places beyond FERC's power, and leaves
    to the States alone, the regulation of 'any other sale' -- most
    notably, any retail sale -- of electricity."                       (citing 
    16 U.S.C. § 824
    (b))).
    *         *      *
    B.
    In    Breiding,    we       held      that   the   filed-rate     doctrine
    insulated    from    challenge      in    a       private   antitrust      lawsuit   the
    defendants' alleged use of no-notice contracts to restrict supply
    in the Algonquin pipeline transmission capacity market.                       939 F.3d
    at 52–56.    "The filed-rate doctrine is 'a set of rules that . . .
    revolve[s] around the notion that . . . utility filings with the
    - 8 -
    regulatory        agency       prevail    over     . . .    other     claims    seeking
    different rates or terms than those reflected in the filings with
    the agency.'"          Id. at 52 (second and third omissions in original)
    (quoting Town of Norwood v. FERC, 
    217 F.3d 24
    , 28 (1st Cir. 2000)).
    It    is   "a    form    of    deference     and    preemption,       which    precludes
    interference with the rate setting authority of an administrative
    agency, like FERC."            
    Id.
     (quoting Wah Chang v. Duke Energy Trading
    & Mktg., LLC, 
    507 F.3d 1222
    , 1225 (9th Cir. 2007)).                       Significant
    here, it applies not only to traditional service rates but also to
    "ancillary conditions and terms included in [a FERC-approved]
    tariff."        
    Id.
     (alteration in original) (quoting Town of Norwood v.
    New Eng. Power Co., 
    202 F.3d 408
    , 416 (1st Cir. 2000)).
    While the district court in Breiding determined that it
    was FERC's seal of approval on the downstream (relative to the
    defendants' alleged failure to release excess capacity) ISO-NE
    market     prices       that    insulated     the       defendants'    behavior     from
    challenge under the antitrust laws in a district court, see 
    id.
     at
    51–53, we questioned that reasoning and explicitly did not endorse
    it, see 
    id.
     at 53–56.            Relying on our previous decision in Town of
    Norwood, 
    202 F.3d 408
    , we confirmed that upstream anticompetitive
    activity        that    indirectly       affects    a    downstream,    FERC-approved
    tariff is not categorically protected by the filed-rate doctrine
    applicable to the downstream activity.                   See Breiding, 939 F.3d at
    53.    We instead turned our attention to the activity that was
    - 9 -
    alleged    to   have   been   anticompetitive     and   asked   whether   that
    behavior itself had been sanctioned by FERC, id. at 53–55, focusing
    on a description of the conduct provided by plaintiffs there as
    follows:
    (1) "Eversource and Avangrid possess a large
    number of 'no-notice' contracts for natural
    gas transmission capacity along the Algonquin
    Pipeline"; and (2) "Eversource and Avangrid
    regularly reserved more pipeline capacity than
    they knew they needed and then, at the last
    minute,    cancelled    portions    of   their
    reservations"    without   "releas[ing]   that
    capacity, so that others could take advantage
    of it."
    Id.   at   54   (alteration     in    original)   (quoting      the   Breiding
    complaint).     Reviewing the regulations at issue, we saw that "FERC
    requires operators of interstate natural gas pipelines like the
    Algonquin Gas pipeline to provide '"no-notice" transportation
    service' to ensure that LDCs are able to meet unexpected demand."
    Id. (citing Order No. 636, 57 Fed. Reg. at 13,286).              Accordingly,
    the Algonquin tariff allows an LDC to
    increase its deliveries up to the [Maximum
    Daily Delivery Obligation] at any Primary
    Point(s) of Delivery, up to the [Maximum
    Hourly Transportation Quantity] during any
    Hour,   and   up    to   the  [Maximum   Daily
    Transportation Quantity], or to decrease its
    deliveries.      Provided that all of the
    operational conditions specified in Section 5
    of   this   rate   schedule  (the   "Section 5
    Conditions") are met, Algonquin shall consent
    to such increase or decrease in deliveries,
    thereby nullifying any daily scheduling or
    hourly scheduling penalty that would otherwise
    - 10 -
    be applicable pursuant to Section 23 of the
    General Terms and Conditions.
    Id. (alterations in original) (quoting Algonquin Gas Transmission,
    LLC Tariff, pt. 5, Rate Schedule AFT-E, § 4.3).   Similarly, an LDC
    "may release all or a part of its capacity under an Existing
    Service Agreement," but nothing requires it to do so. Id. (quoting
    Algonquin Gas Transmission, LLC Tariff, pt. 6, Capacity Release,
    § 14.2).
    Putting these allegations and the tariff together, we
    determined that
    neither defendant is alleged to have engaged
    in any conduct other than that allowed by
    Algonquin's     detailed    and     reasonably
    comprehensive FERC-approved tariff. FERC, in
    conformity with its broader regulatory scheme,
    expressly    declined    to   require   direct
    purchasers to release excess capacity in
    recognition of the fact that direct purchasers
    facing variable demand for natural gas might
    need to retain that capacity to ensure
    reliability.
    Id. (citing Order No. 636, 57 Fed. Reg. at 13,269).   Because FERC
    expressly required that LDCs be allowed to purchase excess capacity
    and not release it, at their discretion, we determined that "[t]he
    filed-rate doctrine prohibit[ed] us from questioning that reasoned
    judgment."   Id. at 55.
    - 11 -
    II.
    A.
    The question before us is simply whether Breiding's
    logic also applies to this lawsuit.                We begin our analysis with
    the most obvious difference between Breiding and this case:                           the
    plaintiffs.       On issues of antitrust standing, see, e.g., Lorenzo
    v. Qualcomm Inc., 
    603 F. Supp. 2d 1291
    , 1300–01 (S.D. Cal. 2009),
    including        the     application        of    federal        direct     purchaser
    requirements, see Ill. Brick Co. v. Illinois, 
    431 U.S. 720
    , 728–
    29 (1977), the different positions occupied in the chain of sales
    that    link    plaintiffs      to   the    alleged    wrongdoers         can    make   a
    difference.            But   because   Breiding       did    not    rest        on   such
    considerations, the parties' differing status similarly makes no
    difference to the outcome here.
    B.
    We consider next the challenged conduct.              Examination of
    PNE's   complaint        confirms    that    it   seeks     to    impose    antitrust
    liability for the exact same conduct at issue in Breiding:                            The
    alleged overscheduling and withholding of transmission capacity
    under defendants' contracts with Algonquin pursuant to Algonquin's
    FERC-approved tariff.          Mining its own complaint for tidbits and
    inferences that do not appear to have been featured in Breiding,
    PNE nevertheless contends that we can fairly view the defendants'
    - 12 -
    conduct as something more than what we considered in Breiding for
    two reasons.
    First, PNE argues that the challenged activity took the
    form of a "refus[al] to deal" in the so-called short-term secondary
    capacity market, a market not alleged in Breiding and not regulated
    by   the   FERC   tariff.   Second,     it   argues   that    the   defendants
    manipulated a price index, the Algonquin Citygate Price, which
    manipulation PNE contends differs from failing to release excess
    capacity.    We address each of these arguments in turn.
    1.
    PNE contends that Breiding does not control because
    Breiding    focused    "solely    on    Defendants'     use    of   no-notice
    contracts," while PNE focuses on what defendants "refused" to do
    in the short-term "Secondary Capacity Market."            Instead of simply
    failing to release the excess transportation capacity to the
    primary capacity market, PNE argues, the defendants could have
    sold their extra capacity in this secondary market, either by
    itself or bundled with any excess natural gas to be transported.
    But the     claim in   Breiding was precisely that the defendants
    "reserved excess capacity . . . without using or reselling it."
    Breiding, 939 F.3d at 49 (emphasis added).            "[R]efusing to sell,"
    as PNE chooses to label the behavior, is just another way of saying
    "without . . . reselling."       And the Breiding plaintiffs claimed as
    well the same target of the alleged refusal to sell:                 increased
    - 13 -
    wholesale natural gas prices, which in turn resulted in higher
    electricity prices.    Id.        In both cases, the pivotal challenged
    conduct was the alleged over-reserving of and then failure to
    release gas transportation rights exercised under the defendants'
    contracts with the Algonquin pipeline, the terms of which were
    specifically allowed by FERC.           Because we found the balancing of
    competition and reliability of natural gas supply, given the
    market's limited transmission capacity, to be within the "bull's-
    eye of FERC's regulatory aims," id. at 55, we saw no reason to
    allow a jury in a private antitrust action to second-guess FERC's
    approach.
    Specifically,    as    we    noted   in   Breiding,   release   of
    capacity into this secondary market is expressly regulated by FERC
    through 
    18 C.F.R. § 284.8
    , which contains a detailed set of
    requirements for how and when a shipper may, "by choice," release
    capacity, including bidding requirements and other contractual and
    regulatory guarantees.       See 939 F.3d at 50 (quoting Tenn. Gas
    Pipeline Co., 
    102 FERC ¶ 61,075
    , 61,119 (2003)).            In other words,
    how and under what terms a shipper is to release any capacity falls
    precisely within FERC's regulatory purview.            As we discuss below,
    see infra Part II.D., FERC has issued an order determining that
    market-based rates for short-term capacity releases are just and
    reasonable. Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity Release Market,
    
    123 FERC ¶ 61,286
    , ¶ 31 (June 19, 2008) (noting further that FERC
    - 14 -
    is "not relying solely on competition to ensure just and reasonable
    prices" but is rather "maintaining the rate cap on pipeline
    services that will provide the same protection for capacity release
    transactions     as     it   now   does   for    pipeline   negotiated      rate
    transactions").        Such an order does not transfer from FERC to the
    federal courts oversight of whether this market is functioning in
    a manner that makes for just and reasonable rates.
    PNE argues that, because "no rate limitation applies"
    under the regulations to certain capacity releases at issue here,
    these transactions fall outside of FERC's purview.             See 
    18 C.F.R. § 284.8
    (b)(2).        But this provision was added as part of FERC's
    determination that it would use market rates to satisfy the
    requirement     that    capacity    release     transactions   are   just    and
    reasonable.     See Promotion of a More Efficient Capacity Release
    Market, 
    73 Fed. Reg. 72,692
    -01, at 72,963 (Dec. 1, 2008) (noting
    that, "in order to enhance the efficiency and effectiveness of the
    secondary capacity release market," FERC lifted "the maximum rate
    ceiling on secondary capacity releases of one year or less").                 In
    other words, unlike wellhead sales, for example, releases of
    capacity still fall within FERC's jurisdiction, and a market-based
    system is simply the mechanism that FERC has opted to use to secure
    just and reasonable rates.          It does not follow, therefore, that
    this   market   is     "unregulated."      To    the   contrary,   noting    its
    continued "[o]versight" of capacity releases, FERC stated it "will
    - 15 -
    entertain complaints and respond to specific allegations of market
    power on a case-by-case basis if necessary.                     Furthermore, the
    Commission directs staff to monitor the capacity release program
    . . . using all available information."                  Promotion of a More
    Efficient Capacity Release Market, 123 FERC at ¶ 56.                       And it will
    "require[] informational postings of capacity release transactions
    [to] provide transparency and facilitate the filing of complaints
    if circumstances warrant."          Id. ¶ 31.
    Reframing       and   seeking     to    supplement       the    foregoing
    "refusal" to deal theory as distinguishing this case from Breiding,
    PNE also argues that the Breiding plaintiffs made no allegations
    regarding    other    possible     economic        activity    in    the     secondary
    capacity    market,    instead     "focusing       solely"    on    the     "no-notice
    contracts"    in     the    primary      capacity     market.         The    Breiding
    plaintiffs,    PNE     contends,      did    not     mention       everything      else
    defendants    did     not    do   that      restricted    supply      in     the    gas
    transmission market:         "[E]nter[] into bilateral agreements where
    they sold their excess capacity without releasing it, or bundle[]
    their capacity with gas and s[ell] it on the spot market; or . . .
    s[ell] gas that they had stored locally without requiring pipeline
    access."
    - 16 -
    The allegations in the complaint that PNE claims support
    this theory are sparse at best,3 but taking them as true and drawing
    reasonable inferences in PNE's favor, we find no rescue for PNE's
    claim.    Two of these economic activities allegedly eschewed by
    defendants actually hinged on reselling capacity on the pipeline,
    so fail for the reasons already stated.                 The last allegedly
    eschewed activity -- not selling locally stored gas -- fares no
    better.      The complaint contains no allegations that any such
    hoarding of physical gas has meaningful anticompetitive effects
    independent    of   any   transmission    capacity     constraints.      PNE's
    allegations center on the theory that whatever excess gas exists
    in the New England energy market cannot be utilized because the
    Algonquin    pipeline     often   sits   underfilled    due   to   defendants'
    failure to release capacity.        There is no claim that gas for which
    unreserved transmission capacity exists is being withheld from the
    market.     Nor is there any claim that defendants have market power
    in the physical natural gas market.            Indeed, no party to whom
    defendants have allegedly refused to sell any such gas has joined
    the complaint in this case.
    3  The extent of such allegations is that "[t]he relevant
    natural gas market is the 'secondary capacity market' which
    includes the spot market for the sale of natural gas and the
    related 'excess capacity release' market for gas transmission
    services (i.e., incorporating the excess capacity release market
    and other short-term capacity transactions, whether bundled with
    the physical commodity or not)."
    - 17 -
    2.
    PNE next argues that the defendants manipulated the
    Algonquin Citygate Price index and that such manipulation somehow
    makes the filed-rate doctrine inapplicable.          But the manipulation
    described in the complaint centers on the defendants' refusal to
    promptly release or sell transmission capacity, which purportedly
    drove up the average price of natural gas, thereby also increasing
    the index price.       As PNE describes the relationship, "by over-
    scheduling and withholding their excess capacity, [defendants]
    could drive up natural gas generators' input costs."               In other
    words, "[d]efendants knew that by driving up the price of natural
    gas in the unregulated spot market they drove up the Algonquin
    Citygate Price and the corresponding bids submitted by gas-powered
    generators in the electricity auction."           This is but another way
    of saying that defendants drove up prices by not releasing pipeline
    capacity.
    C.
    Taking a different tack, PNE argues that the tariff
    itself includes a clause that allows PNE to bring an antitrust
    claim to enforce the tariff.       The clause in question, Section 17,
    states   only   that    "all   terms      and   provisions   contained   or
    incorporated [in this tariff], and the respective obligations of
    the parties thereunder, are subject to valid laws, orders, rules
    and   regulations      of   duly    constituted      authorities     having
    - 18 -
    jurisdiction."    We see nothing in this language granting PNE any
    right to enforce the tariff.         PNE cites only a case under the
    Federal Communications Act (FCA), which contains a clause allowing
    private parties to recover damages from common carriers who violate
    the FCA.   See Brown v. MCI WorldCom Network Servs., Inc., 
    277 F.3d 1166
    , 1169–72 (9th Cir. 2002) (construing 
    47 U.S.C. §§ 206-207
    ).
    PNE   ignores   more   pertinent   authority   to   the   contrary.   See
    California ex rel. Lockyer v. Dynegy, Inc., 
    375 F.3d 831
    , 852 (9th
    Cir.) (holding that "substantive provisions of the tariff" are "an
    area reserved exclusively to FERC, both to enforce and to seek
    remedy"), opinion amended on denial of reh'g, 
    387 F.3d 966
     (9th
    Cir. 2004); see also Pub. Util. Dist. No. 1 v. Dynegy Power Mktg.,
    Inc., 
    384 F.3d 756
    , 762 (9th Cir. 2004) (same, citing Lockyer).
    Compare 
    47 U.S.C. § 207
     ("Any person claiming to be damaged by any
    common carrier subject to the provisions of [the FCA] . . . may
    bring suit for the recovery of the damages for which such common
    carrier may be liable under the provisions of this chapter, in any
    district    court      of   the      United    States      of   competent
    jurisdiction . . . ."), with 15 U.S.C. § 717s ("Whenever it shall
    appear to [FERC] that any person is engaged or about to engage in
    any acts or practices which constitute or will constitute a
    violation of the provisions of this chapter, or of any rule,
    regulation, or order thereunder, it may in its discretion bring an
    action in the proper district court . . . to enjoin such acts or
    - 19 -
    practices . . . ."),   15 U.S.C.   § 717l   (noting that government
    parties may bring complaints to FERC),        and 15 U.S.C.   § 717m
    (granting FERC power to investigate violations of the NGA).     With
    respect to criminal antitrust enforcement, for example, the NGA
    specifically states that FERC "may transmit such evidence as may
    be available concerning such acts or practices or concerning
    apparent violations of the Federal antitrust laws to the Attorney
    General, who, in his discretion, may institute the necessary
    criminal proceedings."   Id. § 717s(a).
    Nor does PNE explain how this clause grants jurisdiction
    to review tariff terms, rather than confirming that the tariff
    does not eliminate the obligation to comply with the many laws
    whose application does not run afoul of the filed-rate doctrine.
    Moreover, this clause is not some unique feature of this particular
    tariff.   Its usage has dated back at least to the 1950s and has
    been referenced in several FERC rulings.       See, e.g., Tenn. Gas
    Pipeline Co., 
    60 FERC ¶ 61,261
     (1992); United Gas Pipe Line Co.,
    
    47 FERC ¶ 61,285
     (1989); San Diego Gas & Elec. Co., 
    42 FERC ¶ 63,011
    (1988); Columbia Gas Transmission Corp., 
    25 FERC ¶ 61,460
     (1983).
    See generally Pan Am. Petroleum Corp. v. Cities Serv. Gas Co., 
    182 F. Supp. 439
    , 441 (D. Kan. 1958).      We find it unlikely that FERC
    has been inadvertently invalidating through a backdoor its own
    - 20 -
    exclusive   power     to    enforce     the     NGA's    and     Code   of   Federal
    Regulations' prohibitions or the terms of its approved tariffs.4
    D.
    PNE finally suggests that we revisit our conclusion in
    Breiding that the filed-rate doctrine applies to the defendants'
    capacity-reserving decisions, see 939 F.3d at 55–56, in light of
    the fact that FERC does not affirmatively approve those precise
    decisions, see id. at 50.         PNE relies for this argument on Keogh
    v. Chicago & Northwestern Railway Co., 
    260 U.S. 156
     (1922), and
    Arkansas Louisiana Gas Co. v. Hall, 
    453 U.S. 571
     (1981), and this
    suggestion is cogently set forth in detail in the amicus brief
    filed by the Open Markets Institute.             In a nutshell, this argument
    points out that, by defaulting to the market-based rates in lieu
    of   cost-of-service         rate-making,         FERC     has       eliminated     a
    justification   for    the     filed-rate       doctrine       and   increased    the
    importance of ensuring that the pertinent markets are functioning
    properly.       See        generally     Alfred     E.     Kahn,        Deregulatory
    Schizophrenia, 
    75 Calif. L. Rev. 1059
     (1987).                  And as California's
    experience in its 2000 and 2001 energy crisis demonstrated, there
    4  As we noted in Breiding, FERC did conduct an investigation
    and determined that the no-notice contracts had not been
    anticompetitively abused. See 939 F.3d at 55 (citing News Release:
    FERC Staff Inquiry Finds No Withholding of Pipeline Capacity in
    New England Markets, Fed. Energy Regulatory Comm'n (Feb. 27, 2018),
    https://www.ca1.uscourts.gov/sites/ca1/files/citations/18-1995_
    BreidingvEversourceCitedURL.pdf).
    - 21 -
    is substantial evidence that FERC has been slow to recognize market
    defects that create opportunities to exploit market power.            See,
    e.g., Morgan Stanley Capital Grp. Inc. v. Pub. Util. Dist. No. 1
    of Snohomish Cnty., 
    554 U.S. 527
    , 553–55 (2008) (remanding to FERC,
    which had conducted only a summary analysis, for a more searching
    review as to whether alleged market manipulation had undermined
    the market factors that justify the use of the Mobile-Sierra
    presumption and might have led to supracompetitive prices).            In
    this   instance,   too,   FERC's     brief    and   conclusory   statement
    regarding its own investigation of the charges in this suit, see
    supra note 4, leaves one less-than-assured that FERC has been
    rigorous and thorough in filling the arguable enforcement gap
    created by the filed-rate doctrine.
    At base, though, a market-based rate or tariff term
    allowed by FERC under its rate-setting authority is still a rate
    approved by FERC, albeit with a rate-setting measure (the market)
    other than cost-of-service to achieve the requisite assurance that
    the rate is just and reasonable.            See E. & J. Gallo Winery v.
    EnCana Corp., 
    503 F.3d 1027
    , 1035–43 (9th Cir. 2007) (discussing
    the transition from cost-of-service rate-making to market-based
    rates in the natural gas market and finding the doctrine applicable
    to market-based rates because the same underlying rationale of
    deference and preemption applies to both rate-setting mechanisms).
    So at the core of its argument, PNE contends that FERC's use of
    - 22 -
    this alternative tool for disciplining the behavior of FERC-
    regulated entities renders these entities essentially not FERC-
    regulated, such that rates deemed just and reasonable by FERC may
    nevertheless be punished as unreasonable in private civil damage
    actions. Given that Congress allowed the use of market-based rates
    without   eliminating    the   filed-rate        doctrine,   see    15   U.S.C.
    § 717c(a),   (c)    (instructing    FERC    to    declare    only   "just   and
    reasonable" rates lawful); Mobil Oil Expl. & Producing Se. Inc. v.
    United Distrib. Cos., 
    498 U.S. 211
    , 224 (1991) ("[T]he just and
    reasonable standard does not compel the Commission to use any
    single pricing formula in general or vintaging in particular."),
    and given that Congress in the wake of the California energy crisis
    enacted remedial legislation that also contained no such provision
    limiting the doctrine's applicability or, as in the FCA, allowing
    enforcement in federal district courts, see Energy Policy Act of
    2005, Pub. L. No. 109–58, 
    119 Stat. 594
    , we see no license to
    embark on such a substantial change of course from that marked out
    by precedent.      None of this is to say that FERC has necessarily
    been diligent in ensuring that the markets it allows to set rates
    are themselves always properly functioning, a prerequisite for the
    assumption that the rates produced are just and reasonable.                 See
    Mont. Consumer Counsel v. FERC, 
    659 F.3d 910
    , 919 (9th Cir. 2011)
    (citing La. Energy & Power Auth. v. FERC, 
    141 F.3d 364
    , 365 (D.C.
    Cir. 1998)) (noting that "it is not unreasonable for FERC to
    - 23 -
    presume that rates will be just and reasonable" where "sellers do
    not have market power or the ability to manipulate the market
    (alone or in conjunction with others)").    Rather, it is to say
    that complaints to this effect need be raised with FERC and
    Congress, not with a jury, at least as we understand the law to
    now be.
    III.
    For the foregoing reasons, we affirm the decision of the
    district court dismissing the complaint for failure to state a
    claim.5
    5  "[T]he filed-rate doctrine applies with equal force to
    state-law challenges." Breiding, 939 F.3d at 56. PNE raises no
    argument to the contrary.
    - 24 -
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 19-1678P

Filed Date: 9/9/2020

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/9/2020

Authorities (20)

Town of Norwood v. New England Power Co. , 202 F.3d 408 ( 2000 )

Town of Norwood, Massachusetts v. Federal Energy Regulatory ... , 217 F.3d 24 ( 2000 )

william-j-brown-iii-on-behalf-of-himself-and-all-others-similarly , 277 F.3d 1166 ( 2002 )

Montana Consumer Counsel v. Federal Energy Regulatory ... , 659 F.3d 910 ( 2011 )

E. & J. GALLO WINERY v. EnCana Corp. , 503 F.3d 1027 ( 2007 )

people-of-the-state-of-california-ex-rel-bill-lockyer-attorney-general , 387 F.3d 966 ( 2004 )

LA Engy & Power Auth v. FERC , 141 F.3d 364 ( 1998 )

people-of-the-state-of-california-ex-rel-bill-lockyer-attorney-general , 375 F.3d 831 ( 2004 )

public-utility-district-no-1-of-snohomish-county-a-municipal-corporation , 384 F.3d 756 ( 2004 )

Keogh v. Chicago & Northwestern Railway Co. , 43 S. Ct. 47 ( 1922 )

Phillips Petroleum Co. v. Wisconsin , 74 S. Ct. 794 ( 1954 )

Arkansas Louisiana Gas Co. v. Hall , 101 S. Ct. 2925 ( 1981 )

Northern Natural Gas Co. v. State Corp. Commission , 83 S. Ct. 646 ( 1963 )

Lorenzo v. Qualcomm Inc. , 603 F. Supp. 2d 1291 ( 2009 )

Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois , 97 S. Ct. 2061 ( 1977 )

Schneidewind v. ANR Pipeline Co. , 108 S. Ct. 1145 ( 1988 )

Mobil Oil Exploration & Producing Southeast, Inc. v. United ... , 111 S. Ct. 615 ( 1991 )

Morgan Stanley Capital Group Inc. v. Public Util. Dist. No. ... , 128 S. Ct. 2733 ( 2008 )

FERC v. Electric Power Supply Assn. , 136 S. Ct. 760 ( 2016 )

Hughes v. Talen Energy Marketing, LLC , 136 S. Ct. 1288 ( 2016 )

View All Authorities »