Huntsman Chemical v. Holland Plastics ( 2000 )


Menu:
  •                                                                         F I L E D
    United States Court of Appeals
    Tenth Circuit
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FEB 29 2000
    FOR THE TENTH CIRCUIT
    PATRICK FISHER
    Clerk
    HUNTSMAN CHEMICAL
    CORPORATION, a Utah corporation,
    Plaintiff-Counter-
    Defendant-Appellee,
    v.                                                  No. 98-4157
    (D.C. No. 94-CV-473-B)
    HOLLAND PLASTICS COMPANY,                            (D. Utah)
    an Iowa corporation,
    Defendant-Counter-
    Claimant-Appellant,
    and
    J. D. SCHIMMELPHENNIG,
    Defendant.
    ORDER AND JUDGMENT          *
    Before EBEL , KELLY , and BRISCOE , Circuit Judges.
    *
    This order and judgment is not binding precedent, except under the
    doctrines of law of the case, res judicata, and collateral estoppel. The court
    generally disfavors the citation of orders and judgments; nevertheless, an order
    and judgment may be cited under the terms and conditions of 10th Cir. R. 36.3.
    After examining the briefs and appellate record, this panel has determined
    unanimously that oral argument would not materially assist the determination of
    this appeal. See Fed. R. App. P. 34(a)(2); 10th Cir. R. 34.1(G). The case is
    therefore ordered submitted without oral argument.
    Appellant Holland Plastics Company [hereinafter “Holland”] appeals from
    an order granting summary judgment in favor of appellee Huntsman Chemical
    Corporation [hereinafter “Huntsman”] on Holland’s counterclaim for price
    discrimination in violation of the Robinson-Patman Price Discrimination Act,
    
    15 U.S.C. § 13
    (a), and for treble damages under Section 4 of the Clayton Act,
    
    15 U.S.C. § 15
    . Our jurisdiction arises under 
    28 U.S.C. § 1291
    , and we reverse.
    I. Background Facts and Proceedings
    We review the district court’s grant of summary judgment de novo.
    See McKnight v. Kimberly Clark Corp.   , 
    149 F.3d 1125
    , 1128 (10th Cir. 1998).
    In conducting that review,
    [w]e examine the record to determine whether any genuine issue of
    material fact was in dispute; if not, we determine [whether] the
    substantive law was applied correctly, and in so doing we examine
    the factual record and reasonable inferences therefrom in the light
    most favorable to the party opposing the motion.
    
    Id.
     (quotation omitted). Viewing the evidence in this light, the record shows the
    following: Huntsman, a manufacturer of modified expanded polystyrene beads
    (hereinafter “beads”) supplied Holland and one of Holland’s primary competitors,
    -2-
    Iowa EPS, with beads at the same price until sometime in 1990. Both Holland
    and Iowa EPS produced foam board from the beads and sold the board to end
    users. The board price quoted to end users was directly related to and dependent
    upon bead price, and the greatest factor in competition was board price. In 1990,
    Huntsman began delivering beads to Iowa EPS at a significantly lower price
    through a wholesale agreement with a third party, Cellofoam North America.
    As a result, Iowa EPS passed on the savings by submitting lower board price bids
    to its customers and potential customers. While Holland had successfully
    competed against Iowa EPS before 1990 and had a similar market share of the
    business, Holland’s revenues and sales decreased from 1990 until it declared
    bankruptcy in 1994. During this same time period, Iowa EPS increased its
    volume business and its market share. Holland produced testimony that, after
    1990, it lost customers, potential customers, and market share because it could
    not meet the price at which Iowa EPS was able to sell the board to end users.
    In 1994, Huntsman sued Holland for breach of an open account and
    Holland counterclaimed for price discrimination. Huntsman filed a motion for
    summary judgment in July 1997, alleging that Holland had not produced evidence
    sufficient to establish a prima facie case of violation of the Robinson-Patman Act;
    that it had failed to produce evidence of a causal connection between any alleged
    violation of the Act and its alleged damages; and that its theory of damages was
    -3-
    impermissible as a matter of law under   Rose Confections, Inc. v. Ambrosia
    Chocolate Co. , 
    816 F.2d 381
    , 394 (8th Cir. 1987).   1
    See Appellant’s App., Vol. I
    at 28. Holland responded with the above-described evidence showing price
    discrimination, causal connection, proof of losses, and an expert report that
    estimated actual damages. Huntsman’s reply focused on the legal argument that,
    under Rose Confections , Holland could not prove what its damages were in
    a violation-free state of affairs by basing them on the assumption that Holland
    would have received the same discriminatory price as Iowa EPS, and that
    Holland’s expert had improperly based his calculations solely on that assumption.
    See Appellant’s App., Vol II at 511-16. In its surreply, which was not produced
    for this court, Holland apparently asserted that Iowa EPS was Holland’s single
    competitor in Iowa, thus making    Rose Confections inapplicable.     See 
    id. at 527
    ,
    1
    In this case, based on the fact that the Clayton Act is a remedial statute
    whose purpose “is to place the antitrust plaintiff as far as possible in the position
    it would have occupied but for the [antitrust] violation,” the court held that “any
    calculation of section 4 damages must strive to approximate a violation-free state
    of affairs.” 
    816 F.2d at 394
    . The court held that an expert’s damage model
    whose calculations were based on what profits the disfavored purchaser would
    have made had it been given the same discriminatory benefit as the favored
    purchasers was therefore impermissible because if it had also been given the
    discriminatory price, other disfavored purchasers would have been discriminated
    against and the violation would continue.      See 
    id. at 394-95
    . The court noted
    that if the disfavored purchaser and the favored purchaser had been the only
    competitors in the market, it may have been proper to base damages on an
    assumption that the disfavored purchaser would receive the discriminatory
    benefit but for the antitrust violation.  See 
    id. at 394
    .
    -4-
    531. It also apparently argued that the issue was controlled by          Hasbrouck v.
    Texaco, Inc. , 
    842 F.2d 1034
     (9th Cir. 1987),      aff’d , 
    496 U.S. 543
     (1990), in which
    the court permitted consideration of damages based on the disfavored purchaser
    receiving the discriminatory price.     See Appellant’s App., Vol. II at 545. The
    court denied the motion in February 1998, concluding that Holland had submitted
    enough evidence to survive summary judgment.           See id. at 522.
    In March 1998, Huntsman moved for reconsideration of the court’s
    decision. It argued that the record did not support Holland’s assertion that Iowa
    EPS was the single competitor and claimed that Holland had misstated facts
    concerning Holland and Iowa EPS’s revenues and raw purchases. Demonstrating
    that Holland had previously stated in its answers to interrogatories that it had
    other competitors besides Iowa EPS, Huntsman argued that, without support from
    depositions, interrogatories, admissions, or affidavits, Holland’s “new” assertion
    that Iowa EPS was its sole competitor could not be considered by the court.
    See id. at 531. Huntsman also argued that the court had erred in failing to grant
    summary judgment on its legal proposition that Holland’s expert’s report was
    based on an “irreparably flawed model of damages” and that Holland had failed to
    produce direct evidence of actual antitrust injury.     Id. at 533-34.
    The court held a hearing on Huntsman’s motion for reconsideration on
    May 12, 1998. The court asked for another briefing on Holland’s “case for
    -5-
    damages,” and told the parties to “[a]ttach as exhibits anything else that you
    think that you need to.”   Id. at 539A. The court asked Holland specifically to
    demonstrate, if it could, a causal connection between damages and the price
    differential with anecdotal evidence, and to produce evidence to support its
    damage theory in regard to the expert report and/or to produce other evidence
    from which a jury could conclude that Holland suffered economic harm as a result
    of the price discrimination.   See id. at 539A-B. On the same day, the court
    granted Huntsman’s motion for an extension of time in which to file its expert
    report, which it had never submitted as required by Fed. R. Civ. P. 26(a)(2).
    See id. at 541.
    On June 2, 1998, Holland filed a motion for additional time to file its
    supplemental brief, accompanied by a motion for leave to conduct additional
    discovery of Iowa EPS and Huntsman regarding damage issues and a motion
    to submit a supplemental expert report that would calculate damages without
    consideration of the reduction in price component forbidden in   Rose Confections .
    See id. at 544-46. Holland noted that Huntsman would suffer no prejudice
    because it had not yet deposed Holland’s expert and still had not submitted its
    expert’s report, and trial had not been set. Huntsman objected to additional
    discovery and supplementation of the expert’s report, arguing that it would incur
    additional expert expense to rebut any new theories of recovery, that Holland had
    -6-
    failed to comply with Fed. R. Civ. P. 56(f), and that it would be prejudiced by
    further delay.   See id. at 554-55.
    On June 22, 1998, the district court granted Holland additional time in
    which to file its brief but denied leave to conduct additional discovery or to
    supplement its expert’s report with the new calculations because it had failed
    to comply with Rule 56(f) and because it would unjustifiably delay the case.
    See id. Vol. III at 562. On July 2, 1998, Holland filed supplemental answers
    to interrogatories and a document entitled “Clarification of Facts in Resistance
    to Motion for Summary Judgment” which included a “clarification affidavit”
    of Holland’s expert, the supplemental answers to Huntsman’s second set of
    interrogatories, and answers to Huntsman’s third set of interrogatories.       See id.
    at 571-84. Huntsman moved to strike the clarification of facts and supplemental
    answers to interrogatories, arguing that they were submitted in violation of
    the court’s discovery ruling and its order that Holland could not submit a
    supplemental expert report.    See id. at 622. Holland argued that the documents
    were not additional discovery, that its expert’s clarification was not a
    supplemental report espousing a different theory, and that the supplemental
    interrogatories were not inconsistent with the previous record.       See id. at 629.
    After a hearing, the court granted the motion to strike and the motion for
    summary judgment. At the hearing, the court ruled that the clarification of facts
    -7-
    and supplemental answers were contrary to his prior order and would not be
    considered. See id. at 814. The court did not rule on the adequacy of the
    evidence with respect to the fact of damages because that was “a closer question”
    and it was “not sure there is not a valid underlying case,” but that the case was
    being “thrown out” because of “the way it has been presented in litigation.”    Id.
    at 815. The court also did not comment on Holland’s argument that, even if the
    expert report could not be used, there was sufficient testimony in the record to
    raise a genuine issue of material fact regarding the amount of damages arising
    from price discrimination.   See id. at 811-16.
    II. Discussion
    Holland raises three issues for appeal: (1) the district court erred in
    striking and refusing to consider for summary judgment purposes its clarification
    of facts and supplemental answers to interrogatories; (2) its expert’s damage
    model was not improper as a matter of law; and (3) apart from the expert report,
    enough evidence regarding damages had been submitted to survive summary
    judgment.
    A. Court’s refusal to consider supplemental summary judgment
    evidence.   Holland does not contest the court’s denial of its motion to conduct
    further discovery or submit a supplemental expert report under Rule 56(f); rather
    it contends that the court erred in striking its supplemental affidavits and sworn
    -8-
    answers that were submitted without the need for additional discovery. Thus,
    although the parties couch the court’s refusal to consider the supplemental
    evidence as one involving “discovery issues” in which the standard of review is
    abuse of discretion, see Jensen v. Redevelopment Agency        , 
    998 F.2d 1550
    , 1553
    (10th Cir. 1993) (affirming denial of Rule 56(f) motion for additional discovery),
    in resolving the legal issue whether a court has given the non-moving party a
    sufficient opportunity under Rule 56 to rebut a motion for summary judgment
    absent additional discovery, we review the submitted summary judgment evidence
    de novo. See McKnight, 
    149 F.3d at 1128
     (stating that reviewing court conducts
    de novo review of record to determine whether a genuine issue of material fact
    is in dispute); see, e.g., Adams v. Campbell County Sch. Dist.      , 
    483 F.2d 1351
    ,
    1353-54 (10th Cir. 1973) (reversing summary judgment because court “deprived
    [non-moving party] of an adequate opportunity to be heard and denied them the
    right to present controverting material” and noting, in concurring opinion, that
    a non-moving party has the right on summary judgment to explain the record
    asserted by moving party or to deny its effect by counter-affidavit);     Peck v.
    Horrocks Eng’rs, Inc. , 
    106 F.3d 949
    , 955 (10th Cir. 1997) (conducting de novo
    review of the affidavit, stating that party has right to submit affidavits only when
    that affidavit “set[s] forth specific facts showing that there is a genuine issue for
    trial” under Rule 56(e), and holding court did not abuse discretion in refusing to
    -9-
    consider affidavit that did not meet that standard (quotation omitted));       United
    States v. Mills , 
    372 F.2d 693
    , 697 (10th Cir. 1966) (independently reviewing
    affidavit submitted by nonmoving party and determining that court erred in
    refusing to consider it).
    We begin by noting that Huntsman did not present evidence that Iowa EPS
    was not Holland’s primary competitor. Rather, one of its key arguments in its
    motion for reconsideration was its allegation that there was an         absence of record
    evidence that Iowa EPS was Holland’s primary competitor and that Holland’s first
    interrogatory answers stated that it had many competitors. As stated above, the
    court invited Holland to attach to its supplemental brief whatever controverting
    exhibits it needed to support its objections to the motion for reconsideration.
    A review of Holland’s expert’s “clarification affidavit” shows that he
    explained that his damages model was based on the presumption made in his
    May 1997 addendum that Holland’s primary market was within 100 to 150 miles
    of Gilman, Iowa; that Iowa EPS was Holland’s only other major competitor in
    that area; and that was why he excluded from the damages model competitors that
    were outside that area.     See Appellant’s App., Vol. III at 573. Contrary to
    Huntsman’s assertions, the expert’s original presumptions were not “new”
    allegations made after the close of the discovery period and his “clarification
    affidavit” explanation of them did not contradict his earlier report.       Cf. 
    id.
     Vol. I
    -10-
    at 130-31 (May 12, 1997 addendum to expert report noting that Holland and
    Iowa EPS were the two primary producers in the Iowa market and explaining
    why the costs were lower for producers within 100 miles of their plants). The
    “clarification affidavit” also did not espouse a new theory of damages that had
    been prohibited by the court in its order denying supplementation of the expert’s
    report. In the tendered affidavit, by referring to his previously-submitted reports,
    Holland’s expert also rebutted arguments made in Huntsman’s motion for
    reconsideration regarding alleged misstatements of revenues and market share.
    See 
    id.
     Vol. III at 573-74. The tendered affidavit therefore set forth facts
    showing genuine issues for trial.
    Likewise, in its supplemental answers to interrogatories Holland did not
    seek to contradict its first answers to interrogatories, but rather sought to “square”
    those answers with its assertions that Iowa EPS was Holland’s only competitor in
    its primary market area. The supplemental answers demonstrated to the court the
    physical location of the other competitors listed in the original answers in relation
    to Holland and Iowa EPS by referring to its expert’s geographical market graph
    that had been submitted during the discovery period.    See 
    id. at 577-81
    . Holland
    could have submitted the same testimony through simply presenting an affidavit
    instead of “supplemental answers.” The court abused its discretion in refusing to
    consider Holland’s controverting affidavits and sworn supplemental answers and
    -11-
    thereby denying it an opportunity to rebut Huntsman’s summary judgment motion.
    Cf. Adams , 
    483 F.2d at 1353-54
    .
    B. The expert’s damage model.          Holland’s expert calculated Holland’s
    lost profits on a damages model that assumed that, absent a price discrimination
    violation, Holland would have received the same bead price as Iowa EPS.
    The district court determined that the Supreme Court in       J. Truett Payne Co. v.
    Chrysler Motors Corp. , 
    451 U.S. 557
     (1981), prohibited use of a discriminatory
    price as a basis to determine damages in price discrimination cases.      See
    Appellant’s App., Vol. III   at 796, 806. The court also believed that allowing the
    disfavored buyer to assume, for purposes of calculating damages, that it would
    have received the discriminatory price absent the violation did not “approximate
    a violation free environment” under     Rose Confections and concluded that
    Holland’s expert’s damage model was “inappropriate.”          Id. at 814. Holland
    argues that J. Truett Payne Co.    does not prohibit use of the discriminatory price
    as an aid in calculating damages, and we agree.
    In J. Truett Payne Co.   a car dealership alleged that the manufacturer’s
    refusal to offer it the same incentives as other dealers caused it to pay more for
    its cars than other dealers had to, thus violating the Robinson-Patman Act.
    It contended that, at a minimum, damages should be measured by the amount
    of the price difference multiplied by the number of car purchases.      See 451 U.S.
    -12-
    at 559-60. The Fifth Circuit disagreed with the dealer’s theory that minimum
    “automatic damages” flow from the fact of price discrimination and reversed the
    jury award, finding that the dealer had failed to introduce substantial evidence of
    injury attributable to the incentive programs as well as evidence of the amount of
    any losses suffered because of such injury.          See id. at 560-61.
    The Supreme Court held that proof of Robinson-Patman price
    discrimination does not automatically entitle a plaintiff to damages under § 4
    of the Clayton Act because a violation of Robinson-Patman may be proved
    without the disfavored purchaser having actually been injured.            See id. at 562.
    In determining whether the plaintiff had presented enough evidence to survive
    a motion for directed verdict on liability, the court noted that the plaintiff had
    failed to show whether its competitors actually passed on their lower costs to their
    customers. See id. at 564. The plaintiff had only testified generally that price
    discrimination was one of the causes of the dealership going out of business
    because it lost sales to competitors; that the discrimination caused him to “force”
    business by giving more for trade-ins; and that his average gross profit on used
    car sales was below his competitors’ (though the same evidence revealed that his
    average profit on new sales was higher).       See id. at 563-64. Significantly,
    plaintiff’s expert testified regarding what the competitive market may have been
    like if plaintiff had received the same discriminatory bonuses from the
    -13-
    manufacturer.   See id. at 564. The Court did not question whether this testimony
    was a permissible assumption. Rather, the Court stated that the expert’s evidence
    of injury was weak because of the plaintiff’s failure to show that the favored
    retailers in fact lowered their retail prices because they received the incentives.
    See id. at 564 & n.4, 565. The Court remanded to the Fifth Circuit to determine
    whether the evidence supported a causal inference of actual antitrust injury
    arising from the incentive programs.   See id. at 568. If sufficient evidence existed
    to permit such an inference, then the “relaxed damages rules” would apply to
    permit an award of damages under the “just and reasonable inference”of damage
    standard. See id. at 566-67. Nowhere in the opinion did the Court imply that it is
    improper for an expert to use in a damages model a comparison of the profits the
    disfavored plaintiff would have made had it received the same discriminatory
    price as his favored competitors. The Court simply held that evidence of the
    amount of price discrimination,   standing alone , is not sufficient to prove damages
    actually suffered from an antitrust injury.
    Holland argues that Hasbrouck v. Texaco, Inc.     buttresses its position that
    its expert could properly base lost profits on what the disfavored purchaser would
    have made if it had received the discriminatory price. In this case, twelve service
    station owners successfully sued their supplier, Texaco, for selling gasoline to
    their competitors for between 2.5 and 5.75 cents/gallon lower than they paid.
    -14-
    See 842 F.2d at 1037. On the issue of damages, Texaco made similar arguments
    as Huntsman does in this case: that the plaintiff failed to prove actual injury that
    the antitrust laws were designed to prevent; that there was no direct causal
    connection between any such injury and Texaco’s conduct because of the
    independent, intervening pricing decisions of plaintiff’s favored competitors; and
    that the district court improperly allowed the jury to consider the overcharge to
    the disfavored purchasers in its calculation of damages.       See id. at 1042-43. The
    Ninth Circuit stated that, to prove actual injury, the plaintiff had to show that
    he lost sales and profits as a result of Texaco’s discriminatory conduct.     See id.
    at 1042. The plaintiff had testified as to diverted sales and lost profits, presented
    evidence of the favored buyer’s increase in sales volume over the specific time
    period, and “testified that they would have recouped the lost revenues had they
    received a [similar] price break on their purchases of gasoline from Texaco.”
    Id. at 1043. Former customers testified that they switched service stations
    because of lower prices.    Id. The Ninth Circuit held that this testimony was
    sufficient to support a finding of both actual antitrust injury and causation.
    See id.
    The expert in Hasbrouck , like Holland’s expert, presented a market analysis
    that compared the plaintiff’s actual prices, volume, and profits to estimated
    amounts had the price discrimination not occurred. In some analyses, the expert
    -15-
    assumed that Texaco had raised its prices to the favored buyers; in others, the
    expert assumed that Texaco lowered its prices to the disfavored buyers.      See id.
    Answering Texaco’s claim that evidence of the overcharge was not a permissible
    consideration for the amount of damages, the Ninth Circuit stated that the
    various projections simply permitted the jury to compare estimates of
    damages in different market situations, allowing them to determine
    what [the plaintiff’s] sales and profits would have been in the
    absence of price discrimination. Obviously, such a determination
    necessarily entails postulating the elimination of the price
    differential, either by increasing the favored buyer’s price,
    decreasing the disfavored buyer’s price, or a combination of the two.
    Id. at 1043-44. The court stated that any danger that the jury may have awarded
    “automatic damages” based on the overcharge theory was offset by the district
    court’s oral admonition and the jury instructions.     Id. at 1044.
    On appeal to the United States Supreme Court, although Texaco’s petition
    for certiorari couched the issue as whether a retailer could “predicate injury and
    recover treble damages on the basis of how much better off he would have been
    had he, too, received the wholesaler discount,”      see Robert H. Whaley & Keith B.
    Leffler, Private Actions & Proof of Damages in Secondary Line Cases--the
    Texaco Inc. v. Hasbrouck Experience      , 59 Antitrust L.J. 811, 819 n.34 (1991), the
    Court addressed only Texaco’s contention that legitimate functional discounts do
    not violate the Clayton Act because a seller is not responsible for its customer’s
    independent resale pricing decisions.     See 
    496 U.S. at 547
    . It left the Ninth
    -16-
    Circuit’s discussion regarding proper damage models intact. In its discussion,
    however, the Court noted that the damages expert had estimated what the
    plaintiffs’ profits would have been if they had paid the same prices as their
    favored competitors and that the jury had based its award on this testimony.
    See 
    id. at 552
    . The Court later stated that this testimony provided a “sufficient
    basis for an acceptable estimate of the amount of damages.”    
    Id. at 572
    . Under
    Hasbrouck , therefore, the district court in this case improperly prohibited the use
    of Holland’s expert’s report.
    In the case before us, Holland presented evidence that it and Iowa EPS
    were the primary competitors in the Iowa geographic area and that Huntsman had
    directly delivered beads to Iowa EPS in amounts similar to those delivered to
    Holland for the discriminatory price over a long period of time. Holland argues
    that it was reasonable for its expert to assume that Holland would have received
    the discounted price absent Huntsman’s price discrimination because the
    discriminatory price was obviously an economically viable one for Huntsman.
    Thus, there was arguably no danger that basing a calculation of lost profits on the
    lower price given to Iowa EPS would perpetuate an illegal discriminatory pricing
    scheme as proscribed by   Rose Confections , 
    816 F.2d at 394
    . Whether the price
    given to Iowa EPS was an economically viable one that Holland could have
    expected to receive absent the price discrimination is a jury question. While
    -17-
    Holland’s expert report is certainly subject to criticism in certain areas, those
    matters are for cross-examination at trial and we cannot say as a matter of law
    that the theory espoused therein does not have a basis in fact that could sustain a
    jury award.
    C. Sufficient evidence to support alternative theory          . Holland argues
    that the court further erred by granting summary judgment when it had presented
    sufficient evidence from other witnesses besides its expert to support an award
    of damages.   See, e.g., J. Truett Payne Co.   , 
    451 U.S. at
    564 n.4 (stating that “if
    by reason of the discrimination, the preferred producers have been able to divert
    business that would otherwise have gone to the disfavored shipper, damage has
    resulted to the extent of the diverted profits. If the effect of the discrimination
    has been to force the shipper to sell at a lowered price . . . damage has resulted to
    the extent of the reduction.” (quotation omitted)). Huntsman argues that Holland
    failed to specifically identify lost sales attributable to the price discrimination and
    that the testimony presented was insufficient to support an award of damages.
    This is not an appeal from denial of a motion for directed verdict after a full trial
    on the merits, however. In a summary judgment motion, a sufficiency inquiry
    asks only whether there was enough evidence to establish a genuine issue of
    material fact regarding the issue.
    -18-
    It is well established that a “relaxed” damage rule applies once a plaintiff
    establishes anticompetitive injury from a Robinson-Patman Act violation.         See
    Hasbrouck , 
    496 U.S. at 572-73
    . Antitrust damages are rarely susceptible of
    concrete, detailed proof and once antitrust injury is shown, antitrust plaintiffs
    should not face unduly rigorous standards for proving damages.        See 
    id.
     The rule
    is based on the well-established tenet that “it does not come with very good grace
    for the wrongdoer to insist upon specific and certain proof of the injury which
    it has itself inflicted.”   J. Truett Payne Co. , 
    451 U.S. at 566-67
    . Huntsman
    conceded Robinson-Patman liability for purposes of the summary judgment
    motion.
    Holland presented testimony that it had previously been competitive with
    Iowa EPS until Iowa EPS received lower prices in 1990 that allowed it to
    underbid Holland and forced Holland to sustain losses in order to keep customers.
    See Appellant’s App., Vol. I at 126, 130-32, 219-20, 232-33, 254; Vol. II at
    439-40. It presented testimony from an end user that it bought Iowa EPS board
    instead of board manufactured by Holland solely because the Iowa EPS board
    was cheaper, see 
    id.
     Vol. II at 282, and that it would usually buy the cheaper
    product in most instances,     see id. at 321. It also presented testimony that the
    lower the bead cost, the greater the profitability,   see id. ; Appellant’s Supp. App.
    at 610, and that if Iowa EPS had paid even one or two cents more per pound, it
    -19-
    would have made a difference in whether it had profits or losses on its bids.
    See Appellant’s App., Vol. II at 346; Appellant’s Supp. App. at 604. It produced
    net income figures showing actual amount of losses during the period from
    1990-94. See Appellant’s App., Vol. I at 124. The jury could infer from this
    evidence that Holland’s market share would have remained the same absent
    illegal price discrimination and that, absent the illegal discrimination, Holland
    could have made a profit on bids to customers such that its yearly net losses
    would not have increased to over $250,000 in a period of four years. We hold
    that Holland satisfied its burden of showing genuine issues of material fact in
    regard to the existence and amount of damages.
    The judgment of the United States District Court for the District of Utah is
    REVERSED, and we REMAND for further proceedings consistent with this order
    and judgment.
    Entered for the Court
    David M. Ebel
    Circuit Judge
    -20-