Healy v. Cox Communications , 871 F.3d 1093 ( 2017 )


Menu:
  •                                                                                     FILED
    United States Court of Appeals
    PUBLISH                                Tenth Circuit
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS                    September 19, 2017
    Elisabeth A. Shumaker
    FOR THE TENTH CIRCUIT                         Clerk of Court
    _________________________________
    In re: COX ENTERPRISES, INC. SET-
    TOP CABLE TELEVISION BOX
    ANTITRUST LITIGATION
    ------------------------------                          Nos. 15-6218 & 15-6222
    RICHARD HEALY,
    Plaintiff - Appellant/Cross-
    Appellee,
    v.
    COX COMMUNICATIONS, INC.,
    Defendant - Appellee/Cross-
    Appellant.
    _________________________________
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Western District of Oklahoma
    (D.C. No. 5:12-ML-02048-C)
    _________________________________
    Todd M. Schneider (Jason H. Kim and Kyle G. Bates Schneider Wallace Cottrell
    Konecky Wotkyns, LLP, Emeryville, California, Rachel Lawrence Mor, Rachel
    Lawrence Mor, P.C., Oklahoma City, Oklahoma, Michael J. Blaschke, Michael J.
    Blaschke, P.C., Oklahoma City, Oklahoma, S. Randall Sullivan, Randall Sullivan, P.C.,
    Oklahoma City, Oklahoma, A. Daniel Woska, WoskaLawFirm, PLLC, Oklahoma City,
    Oklahoma, Allan Kanner and Cynthia St. Amant, Kanner & Whiteley, LLC, New
    Orleans, Louisiana, Garrett W. Wotkyns, Schneider Wallace Cottrell Konecky Wotkyns,
    LLP, Scottsdale, Arizona, Joe R. Whatley, Jr., Whatley Kallas, LLP, New York, New
    York, W. Tucker Brown, Whatley Kallas, LLP, Birmingham, Alabama, Henry C.
    Quillen, Whatley Kallas, LLP, Portsmouth, New Hampshire, with him on the briefs),
    Schneider Wallace Cottrell Konecky Wotkyns, LLP, Emeryville, California, for Plaintiff-
    Appellant/Cross-Appellee.
    Margaret M. Zwisler (J. Scott Ballenger, Jennifer L. Giordano, Andrew J. Robinson,
    Latham & Watkins LLP, Washington, D.C., Alfred C. Pfeiffer, Jr., Latham & Watkins
    LLP, San Francisco, California, and D. Kent Meyers, Crowe & Dunlevy, P.C., Oklahoma
    City, Oklahoma, for Defendant-Appellee/Cross-Appellant.
    _________________________________
    Before BRISCOE, EBEL, and PHILLIPS, Circuit Judges.
    _________________________________
    PHILLIPS, Circuit Judge.
    _________________________________
    Cox Cable subscribers cannot access premium cable services—features such as
    interactive program guides, pay-per-view programming, and recording or rewinding
    capabilities—unless they also rent a set-top box from Cox. Dissatisfied with this
    arrangement, a class of plaintiffs in Oklahoma City (“Plaintiffs”) sued Cox under the
    antitrust laws. They alleged that Cox had illegally tied cable services to set-top-box
    rentals in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act, which prohibits illegal restraints of trade.
    See 15 U.S.C. § 1.
    Though a jury found that Plaintiffs had proved the necessary elements to establish
    a tying arrangement, the district court disagreed. In granting Cox’s Fed. R. Civ. P. 50(b)
    motion, the court determined that Plaintiffs had offered insufficient evidence for a jury to
    find that Cox’s tying arrangement “foreclosed a substantial volume of commerce in
    Oklahoma City to other sellers or potential sellers of set-top boxes in the market for set-
    top boxes.” Healy v. Cox Commc’ns, Inc. (In re Cox Enters., Inc. Set-Top Cable
    2
    Television Box Antitrust Litig.), No. 12–ML–2048–C, 
    2015 WL 7076418
    , *1 (W.D.
    Okla. Nov. 12, 2015).1
    In assessing the district court’s ruling, we first examine how the Supreme Court’s
    treatment of tying arrangements has evolved. Next, we turn to how we and other circuit
    courts have applied this precedent and how tying law has evolved in the circuit courts.
    Finally, we analyze the district court’s assessment of what the evidence showed in light
    of the evolving state of the law. Ultimately, we agree with the district court that Plaintiffs
    failed to show that Cox’s tying arrangement foreclosed a substantial volume of commerce
    in the tied-product market, and therefore the tie did not merit per se condemnation.
    Because we agree with the district court on the foreclosure element, we affirm.
    1
    The district court also concluded that Plaintiffs had failed to show
    anticompetitive injury, meaning that Plaintiffs’ evidence was insufficient for the jury
    to conclude “that loss or injury arose from the competition-reducing aspect of
    [Cox’s] behavior.” In re Cox Enters., 
    2015 WL 7076418
    , at *2. On appeal, the parties
    dispute whether Plaintiffs needed to show antitrust injury, which we have defined as
    “injury of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from
    that which makes defendant’s acts unlawful.” Elliot Indus. Ltd. P’ship v. BP Am.
    Prod. Co., 
    407 F.3d 1091
    , 1124 (10th Cir. 2005) (quoting Reazin v. Blue Cross &
    Blue Shield of Kan., Inc., 
    899 F.2d 951
    , 962 n.15 (10th Cir. 1990)). We need not
    reach that question, however, because we agree with the district court that Plaintiffs
    failed to meet their burden to show that Cox foreclosed a substantial amount of
    competition, the fourth element of a per se tying claim.
    Similarly, because we affirm the district court, we decline to address the issues
    that Cox raises in its cross-appeal. Specifically, Cox asked us to review Plaintiffs’
    failure to define a viable tying product, the proper geographic market for the tying
    product, and a valid theory of damages, as well as Plaintiffs’ failure to address the
    impact of the National Cooperative Research and Production Act, whether certain
    class members should have been excluded from the claim, whether the “verdict in
    this case provides a permissible basis for awarding damages to the individual class
    members,” and whether we must remand for a new trial “because the jury instructions
    did not accurately convey the essential elements of a tying claim.” Appellee’s
    Response Br. at 4.
    3
    DISCUSSION
    I.     Standard of Review
    We review de novo a district court’s ruling on a Rule 50(b) motion, drawing all
    reasonable inferences in favor of the nonmoving party and applying the same standard as
    applied in the district court. Lantec, Inc. v. Novell, Inc., 
    306 F.3d 1003
    , 1023 (10th Cir.
    2002). The standard of review for Rule 50 motions “mirrors the standard” for summary-
    judgment motions under Rule 56(c). Farthing v. City of Shawnee, 
    39 F.3d 1131
    , 1139
    n.10 (10th Cir. 1994) (quoting Anderson v. Liberty Lobby, Inc., 
    477 U.S. 242
    , 250
    (1986)). Under Rule 50(b), the district court may allow judgment on the jury’s verdict,
    order a new trial, or enter judgment as a matter of law for the moving party. We may
    grant judgment as a matter of law only when “a party has been fully heard on an issue
    during a jury trial and the court finds that a reasonable jury would not have a legally
    sufficient evidentiary basis to find for the party on that issue.” Fed. R. Civ. P. 50(a)(1). In
    other words, “[j]udgment as a matter of law is appropriate only if the evidence points but
    one way and is susceptible to no reasonable inferences which may support the
    nonmoving party’s position.” Auraria Student Hous. at the Regency, LLC v. Campus Vill.
    Apartments, 
    843 F.3d 1225
    , 1247 (10th Cir. 2016) (quoting Elm Ridge Expl. Co. v. Engle,
    
    721 F.3d 1199
    , 1216 (10th Cir. 2013)).
    II.    Background
    Considering its expansive reach, the Sherman Act contains remarkably little text
    and hasn’t been amended since it was enacted in 1890. Thus, antitrust law’s various
    doctrines are almost entirely judge-made; courts have created these doctrines based on
    4
    their own interpretations of the Sherman Act’s statutory language and background. For
    this reason, the statute’s limited language goes only so far, and theory must fill in the
    gaps. So to understand how and why tying arrangements came to be condemned by
    antitrust law, we must dive into their theoretical underpinnings.
    A tie exists when a seller exploits its control in one product market to force buyers
    in a second market into purchasing a tied product that the buyer either didn’t want or
    wanted to purchase elsewhere. Jefferson Par. Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    , 12
    (1984), abrogated on other grounds by Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 
    547 U.S. 28
    (2006). For example, “[a] supermarket that will sell flour to consumers only if they
    will also buy sugar is engaged in tying. Flour is referred to as the tying product, sugar as
    the tied product.” 
    Id. at 33
    (O’Connor, J., concurring). Courts typically apply a per se rule
    to tying claims.2 See Int’l Salt Co. v. United States, 
    332 U.S. 392
    (1947), abrogated on
    other grounds by Ill. Tool Works Inc., 
    547 U.S. 28
    . Under a per se rule, plaintiffs prevail
    simply by proving that a particular contract or business arrangement—in this case, a tie—
    exists; no further market analysis is necessary, and defendants may not present any
    defenses. See 9 Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1720a (3d ed.
    2
    Only some types of antitrust claims receive per se treatment; all others are
    analyzed using a rule of reason. See Fortner Enters., Inc. v. U.S. Steel Corp., 
    394 U.S. 495
    , 499–500 (1969) (plaintiffs who fail to establish a per se tying violation
    “can still prevail on the merits whenever [they] can prove, on the basis of a more
    thorough examination of the purposes and effects of the practices involved, that the
    general standards of the Sherman Act have been violated”). Under the rule of reason,
    plaintiffs must prove “the actual effect of the [tying arrangement] on competition.”
    Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 29
    .
    5
    2003) (“The paradigmatic per se rule condemns a readily identified practice without
    proof of power, effect, or intention and without weighing possible justifications.”).
    Early in the Sherman Act’s history, the Supreme Court decided that “tying” two
    products together disrupted the natural functioning of the markets and violated antitrust
    law. See Int’l 
    Salt, 332 U.S. at 396
    . It analyzed tying claims under the per se rule: if a
    plaintiff could show that a tying arrangement existed, the tie was illegal per se. 
    Id. But the
    way courts view ties has evolved substantially since tying arrangements first attracted
    attention in antitrust law. Thus, today’s per se rule against tying is dramatically more
    nuanced than the typical per se rule. See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1720a
    (explaining the per se tying rule’s multitude of deviations from typical per se rule
    application). Though the typical antitrust per se rule requires no analysis of market
    conditions or effects, the Supreme Court has declared that the per se rule for tying
    arrangements demands a showing that the tie creates “a substantial potential for impact
    on competition.” Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 16
    . Today’s plaintiffs must therefore do
    more than show that a tie exists to trigger the application of the per se rule; they must also
    meet certain threshold requirements—including that the tie had the substantial potential
    to harm competition in the market for the tied product.
    III.   The Evolution of Tying Law
    From the Supreme Court’s tying cases, circuit courts have pulled several elements
    needed to prove per se tying claims, though these elements differ across the circuits. To
    succeed on a per se tying claim in the Tenth Circuit, a plaintiff must show that “(1) two
    separate products are involved; (2) the sale or agreement to sell one product is
    6
    conditioned on the purchase of the other; (3) the seller has sufficient economic power in
    the tying product market to enable it to restrain trade in the tied product market; and (4) a
    ‘not insubstantial’ amount of interstate commerce in the tied product is affected.” Suture
    Express, Inc. v. Owens & Minor Distrib., Inc., 
    851 F.3d 1029
    , 1037 (10th Cir. 2017)
    (quoting Sports Racing Servs., Inc. v. Sports Car Club of Am., Inc., 
    131 F.3d 874
    , 886
    (10th Cir. 1997)).
    If a plaintiff fails to prove an element, the court will not apply the per se rule to the
    tie, but then may choose to analyze the merits of the claim under the rule of reason. See
    Fortner Enters, Inc. v. U.S. Steel Corp., 
    394 U.S. 495
    , 500 (1969) (explaining that failure
    to satisfy per se requirements isn’t always fatal to a tying claim and that a plaintiff “can
    still prevail on the merits whenever he can prove, on the basis of a more thorough
    examination of the purposes and effects of the practices involved, that the general
    standards of the Sherman Act have been violated”). The fight in this case is over the
    fourth element. Plaintiffs claim that “this element only requires consideration of the gross
    volume of commerce affected by the tie,” and that they “met this requirement by the
    undisputed evidence that Cox obtained over $200 million in revenues from renting [set-
    top boxes] during the class period.” Appellants’ Opening Br. at 29. In other words,
    Plaintiffs would have us infer that because Cox makes a substantial amount of money on
    set-top-box rentals, the tie necessarily has the requisite potential for anticompetitive
    effects in the set-top-box market. But both Cox and the district court maintain that this
    element requires a showing that the tie actually foreclosed some amount of commerce, or
    some current or potential competitor, in the market for set-top boxes.
    7
    Plaintiffs’ argument reflects an outdated view of the law. As we explain below,
    recent developments in the way courts treat tying arrangements validate the district
    court’s order and support Cox’s interpretation of tying law’s foreclosure element.
    A.     The Supreme Court’s Per Se Rule & the Evolution of Tying Law
    Two Supreme Court cases, Jefferson Parish and Fortner Enterprises, establish
    that proof of foreclosure is necessary to prove a per se tying claim. But when the
    Supreme Court first addressed tying arrangements, it concluded that they served “hardly
    any purpose beyond the suppression of competition.” E.g., Standard Oil Co. of Cal. v.
    United States, 
    337 U.S. 293
    , 305 (1949). At that time, the Court placed tying
    arrangements in the class of “agreements or practices which because of their pernicious
    effect on competition and lack of any redeeming virtue are conclusively presumed to be
    unreasonable and therefore illegal without elaborate inquiry as to the precise harm they
    have caused or the business excuse for their use.” N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 5 (1958). Still, even at this early juncture, the Court seemed to recognize that,
    unlike price-fixing and market division between competitors, “there is nothing inherently
    anticompetitive about packaged sales.” Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 25
    . So, without
    claiming to modify its per se rule, the Supreme Court stated that tying arrangements are
    “unreasonable in and of themselves,” but only “when[] a party has sufficient economic
    power with respect to the tying product to appreciably restrain free competition in the
    market for the tied product and a ‘not insubstantial’ amount of interstate commerce is
    affected.” Fortner 
    Enters., 394 U.S. at 499
    (quoting N. Pac. Ry. 
    Co., 356 U.S. at 6
    ).
    8
    This case primarily concerns the foreclosure element of tying claims, which stems
    from Fortner. In Fortner, the Supreme Court stated that “[t]he requirement that a ‘not
    insubstantial’ amount of commerce be involved makes no reference to the scope of any
    particular market or to the share of that market foreclosed by the 
    tie.” 394 U.S. at 501
    .
    But the Court then clarified that “normally the controlling consideration is simply
    whether a total amount of business, substantial enough in terms of dollar-volume so as
    not to be merely de minimis, is foreclosed to competitors by the tie.” 
    Id. To reach
    this
    holding, the Court relied on an earlier case in which it stated that “it is ‘unreasonable, per
    se, to foreclose competitors from any substantial market’ by a tying arrangement.” 
    Id. (quoting Int’l
    Salt, 332 U.S. at 396
    ).
    After Fortner, the Court again addressed tying claims in Jefferson Parish.
    There, the Court modified its view of tying arrangements. It explained that the rule
    prohibiting ties aims to prevent sellers from using their power in one market to gain
    control in a separate 
    market. 466 U.S. at 12
    . It also emphasized that antitrust law
    protects competition, not competitors or even consumer choice or price. 
    Id. at 14–15.
    As the Court stated,
    [T]he law draws a distinction between the exploitation of market power
    by merely enhancing the price of the tying product, on the one hand, and
    by attempting to impose restraints on competition in the market for a
    tied product, on the other. When the seller’s power is just used to
    maximize its return in the tying product market . . . the competitive
    ideal of the Sherman Act is not necessarily compromised. But if that
    power is used to impair competition on the merits in another market, a
    potentially inferior product may be insulated from competitive
    pressures. This impairment could either harm existing competitors or
    create barriers to entry of new competitors in the market for the tied
    product, and can increase the social costs of market power by
    9
    facilitating price discrimination, thereby increasing monopoly profits
    over what they would be absent the tie.
    
    Id. (footnote and
    citations omitted); see also Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1726c
    (“Interference with customer choice is not itself the concern of tying law; rather, the
    relevant interference is the one that results from an anticompetitive effect in the tied
    market—namely, from the threat of increased concentration, higher prices, or perhaps
    an increase in the social costs of preexisting power in the tying market.”). Thus, the
    Court realized “that every refusal to sell two products separately cannot be said to
    restrain competition.” Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 11
    .
    Attempting to screen out tying arrangements that posed no danger to
    competition, the Jefferson Parish Court enumerated several threshold requirements
    necessary to trigger application of the per se rule against tying. From these
    requirements, circuit courts have shaped the elements required for per se claims.
    These requirements included a seller’s power in the tying market, the tying of two
    distinct products, and, most importantly for our purposes, the likelihood of
    anticompetitive conduct. 
    Id. at 15–16.
    Discretely amending its approach from
    previous cases such as Fortner and International Salt, the Court also required as a
    threshold matter a “substantial potential for impact on competition” before it would
    apply its per se rule to a tying arrangement. 
    Id. at 16.
    Even though the Court said that
    “[t]he rationale for per se rules in part is to avoid a burdensome inquiry into actual
    market conditions in situations where the likelihood of anticompetitive conduct is so
    great as to render unjustified the costs of determining whether the particular case at
    10
    bar involves anticompetitive conduct,” it simultaneously “refused to condemn tying
    arrangements unless a substantial volume of commerce is foreclosed thereby.” 
    Id. at 15
    n.25, 16. It went on to explain that “[o]nce this threshold is surmounted, per se
    prohibition is appropriate if anticompetitive forcing is likely.” 
    Id. at 16
    (emphasis
    added). So, not only must plaintiffs demonstrate the existence of certain threshold
    conditions, they must also show that anticompetitive forcing is likely because of the
    tie. In this way, the Court acknowledged that some ties have little or no potential to
    harm competition, and therefore shouldn’t trigger the per se rule.
    So, as outlined above, Jefferson Parish modified Fortner. And most recently,
    the Supreme Court modified the law even further by prohibiting courts from inferring
    market power over the tying product from a seller’s patent on that product. Ill. Tool
    Works 
    Inc., 547 U.S. at 31
    . Though that decision isn’t factually relevant to our case
    and bears on a different element, it signifies that “[o]ver the years, . . . [the Supreme]
    Court’s strong disapproval of tying arrangements has substantially diminished.” 
    Id. at 35.
    This attitude is on display in Jefferson Parish, where the Court stated without
    qualification that “we have refused to condemn tying arrangements unless a
    substantial volume of commerce is foreclosed 
    thereby.” 466 U.S. at 16
    .
    So, even if tying plaintiffs show that a tie affected a substantial dollar volume of
    sales, they must still show that the tie meets Jefferson Parish’s threshold requirements to
    trigger the per se rule. In other words, the tying arrangement must be the type of tie that
    could potentially harm competition in the tied-product market. If “no portion of the
    market which would otherwise have been available to other sellers has been foreclosed,”
    11
    then no amount of tied sales could cross the threshold to per se condemnation. Id.;
    Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1721d (explaining that if there are no rival sellers of the
    tied product or if the buyer would not have bought the tied product even from a different
    seller, then, “[n]otwithstanding a substantial dollar volume of sales . . . the foreclosure is
    zero and therefore fails to cross the per se ‘threshold.’” (quoting Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 16
    )). Thus, though the per se rule against tying doesn’t require an exhaustive analysis
    into a tie’s anticompetitive effects in the tied product market, the rule “can be coherent
    only if tying is defined by reference to the economic effect of the arrangement.” Jefferson
    
    Par., 466 U.S. at 21
    n.33.
    B.     Per Se Tying Law in Other Circuit Courts
    Circuit courts have undergone a similar theoretical shift. They first picked up on
    the peculiar nature of tying claims in Coniglio v. Highwood Servs., Inc., 
    495 F.2d 1286
    ,
    1292 (2d Cir.), cert. denied, 
    419 U.S. 1022
    (1974). See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra,
    ¶ 1722b. In that case, the Second Circuit began explicitly requiring “anticompetitive
    effect[s]” as an element of a per se tying claim. 
    Coniglio, 495 F.2d at 1292
    . The plaintiff
    complained that the Buffalo Bills forced fans to buy tickets to exhibition games along
    with regular-season home games in season-ticket packages, and that he had no interest in
    going to the exhibition games. 
    Id. at 1288–89.
    Without declaring that it was creating a
    new requirement for tying claims, the court announced that the plaintiff’s claim failed
    because he couldn’t show any anticompetitive effects in the tied-product market. 
    Id. at 1291–92.
    Because the Buffalo Bills necessarily had a monopoly over regular-season
    games as well as exhibition games, “there were neither actual nor potential competitors to
    12
    the Bills in the professional football market.” 
    Id. at 1291
    (footnote omitted). Thus, noting
    that the plaintiff had completely failed “to demonstrate any adverse effect on
    competition, actual or potential,” the court affirmed the district court’s grant of summary
    judgment to Highwood Services (the owner and operator of the Buffalo Bills). 
    Id. at 1293.
    Other circuits have since taken up this mantle—some have done so explicitly and
    others implicitly. See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1722a (listing circuits requiring
    anticompetitive effects to succeed on tying claims). The Fifth Circuit explicitly required
    Coniglio’s anticompetitive effects in Driskill v. Dallas Cowboys Football Club, Inc., 
    498 F.2d 321
    , 323 (5th Cir. 1974), in which a Dallas Cowboys fan brought the exact same
    claim as the plaintiff in Coniglio. The Eleventh Circuit then cited Driskill in granting
    summary judgment to a condominium vendor that required condominium buyers to lease
    individual interest in common areas. Commodore Plaza at Century 21 Condo. Ass’n v.
    Saul J. Morgan Enters., Inc., 
    746 F.2d 671
    , 672 (11th Cir.), cert. denied, 
    467 U.S. 1241
    (1984). The court stated, “In this case, as in Driskill, the plaintiffs failed to make any
    showing of coercion or anticompetitive effects.” 
    Id. Building on
    this growing trend, the First Circuit has stated that tying claims “must
    fail absent any proof of anti-competitive effects in the market for the tied product.” Wells
    Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Bd. of Realtors, 
    850 F.2d 803
    , 815 (1st Cir.), cert.
    denied, 
    488 U.S. 955
    (1988). The court moderated this holding, stating that plaintiffs
    need not prove “the actual scope of anti-competitive effects in the market,” but ultimately
    adopted Jefferson Parish’s reasoning in stating that “as a matter of practical inferential
    13
    common sense,” the plaintiff had to “make some minimal showing of real or potential
    foreclosed commerce caused by the tie.” 
    Id. at 815
    n.11.
    Similarly, the Seventh Circuit has declined to apply the per se rule to condemn ties
    that pose no danger to competition. See Ohio-Sealy Mattress Mfg. Co. v. Sealy, Inc., 
    585 F.2d 821
    (7th Cir.), cert. denied, 
    440 U.S. 930
    (1978). In Ohio-Sealy, the court
    acknowledged that it was “not free to inquire whether such tying in any given case
    injures market competition,” but still stated that “if a given tying arrangement has no
    potential to foreclose access to the tied product market, it does not exemplify the vice that
    led the [Supreme] Court to declare tying a [p]er se [o]ffense.” 
    Id. at 835.
    So, like the Supreme Court, the circuit courts generally recognize that a tie should
    not be condemned under the per se rule unless it has the potential to harm competition.
    C.     Per Se Tying Claims in the Tenth Circuit
    Similarly, we have acknowledged that even under a per se rule, we must at least
    make a threshold determination of potential harm to competition before we can condemn
    a tying arrangement under the Sherman Act. In Fox Motors, Inc. v. Mazda Distributors
    (Gulf), Inc., 
    806 F.2d 953
    , 955 (10th Cir. 1986), we integrated this caveat to the per se
    rule into the fourth element of a per se tying claim. There, a company that imported
    Mazda cars and distributed them to car dealerships refused to sell the dealerships a
    popular car model, the RX-7, unless the dealers sold a sufficient amount of the less-
    popular car model, the GLC. 
    Id. at 955–56.
    The dealerships sued, alleging that the
    distributor’s allocation method constituted a per se illegal tie under § 1 of the Sherman
    Act. 
    Id. at 956.
    While acknowledging that the Supreme Court has deemed certain tying
    14
    arrangements illegal per se, we specified that tying arrangements pose no risk of
    foreclosing competition in the tied-product market unless certain elements are present.
    See 
    id. at 957.
    Specifically, we held that tying arrangements must “foreclose to competitors of the
    tied market a ‘not insubstantial’ volume of commerce.” 
    Id. at 957
    (emphasis added)
    (quoting 
    Fortner, 394 U.S. at 499
    ). In Fox Motors, “[t]he record contain[ed] no
    indication that the alleged tying arrangement, as distinct from consumer demand,
    influenced the level” of competition in the tied-product market. 
    Id. at 958.
    Therefore,
    even though proof of anticompetitive effects was not an explicit element of tying claims
    in the Tenth Circuit, we still concluded that the tying arrangement “simply [did] not
    imply a sufficiently great likelihood of anticompetitive effect.” 
    Id. Because the
    tie failed
    to foreclose any competing car manufacturers, it didn’t meet Jefferson Parish’s threshold
    requirements for per se treatment. 
    Id. Thus, we
    incorporated proof of actual or likely
    anticompetitive effect into the foreclosure element of tying claims. In doing so, we
    heeded Jefferson Parish’s warning that some tying arrangements simply don’t pose the
    same level of risk as those behaviors whose potential to harm competition is so
    pronounced as to deserve per se condemnation without regard to their actual impact on
    the market.
    D.     Per Se Tying Law & Technology
    Courts have also acknowledged that some industries or products are sufficiently
    distinct that per se treatment is inappropriate. This is especially true in the world of
    15
    technology, where courts are often unfamiliar with the products and market structure, and
    thus can’t be certain of the potential for anticompetitive effects.
    Per se rules of antitrust illegality are reserved for those situations where
    logic and experience show that the risk of injury to competition from the
    defendant’s behavior is so pronounced that it is needless and wasteful to
    conduct the usual judicial inquiry into the balance between the behavior’s
    procompetitive benefits and its anticompetitive costs.
    Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 486–87 (1992) (Scalia, J.,
    dissenting). The D.C. Circuit applied this principle in United States v. Microsoft Corp.,
    
    253 F.3d 34
    (D.C. Cir. 2001). Though the factual circumstances of that case are quite
    different from our own, we find the D.C. Circuit’s reliance on Eastman Kodak and
    Jefferson Parish illuminating. There, the court faced a novel tying arrangement in which
    Microsoft had integrated the internet web browser, Internet Explorer, into Windows, its
    computer operating system. 
    Id. at 45.
    Noting that some business relationships “represent
    entire, novel categories of dealings,” the court concluded that “simplistic application of
    per se tying rules” would be inappropriate. 
    Id. at 84.
    The court acknowledged that tying
    arrangements can impact buyers’ independent judgment in the tied-product market, but it
    went on to state that when “competitive firms always bundle the tying and tied goods,”
    the tie should not trigger the per se rule. 
    Id. at 86.
    “Indeed, if there were no efficiencies
    from a tie (including economizing on consumer transaction costs such as the time and
    effort involved in choice),” consumers would always purchase a product’s component
    parts separately. 
    Id. at 87.
    Thus, because even firms without market power integrated
    internet web browsers and computer operating systems, and the court was dealing with a
    16
    relatively novel tying arrangement, the court refused to apply the per se rule to condemn
    the tying arrangement. 
    Id. at 93.
    A recent Second Circuit case, Kaufman v. Time Warner, 
    836 F.3d 137
    (2d Cir.
    2016), builds on Microsoft and is even more relevant to our analysis because it concerns
    the same tie by a different cable company. Similar to our case, the plaintiffs were a class
    of Time Warner Cable subscribers who were forced to rent set-top boxes to receive
    premium cable services. Though tying claims in the Second Circuit differ from ours by
    explicitly requiring a showing of anticompetitive effects in the tied-product market, the
    court’s analysis in Kaufman is still very useful. See 
    id. at 141.
    The court thoroughly
    explained the technology behind premium cable and set-top boxes and demonstrated why
    the tying arrangement at issue didn’t trigger the application of the per se rule.3
    To start, the court explained that cable providers sell their subscribers the right to
    view certain packages of programming. 
    Id. at 144.
    But the content creators—companies
    like HBO that produce television shows—require the cable companies to prevent viewers
    from stealing their content. 
    Id. Set-top boxes
    solve this problem—cable providers “code
    their signals to prevent theft,” and cable boxes receive the providers’ coded signals and
    “unscramble” them. 
    Id. “Unsurprisingly, providers
    do not share their codes with cable
    box manufacturers. . . . Therefore, to be useful to a consumer, a cable box must be cable-
    provider specific, like the keys to a padlock.” 
    Id. 3 Though
    the Second Circuit rejected the plaintiffs’ claim because set-top
    boxes and premium cable services aren’t two distinct products, its analysis supports
    the conclusion we reach here today—namely, that the tie at issue doesn’t meet the per
    se rule’s threshold requirements.
    17
    After explaining the function of set-top boxes, the Second Circuit turned to the
    regulatory environment and the history of the cable industry’s use of set-top boxes.
    Significantly, the court pointed out that “[a]ntitrust analysis must always be attuned to the
    particular structure and circumstances of the industry at issue” because “the existence of
    a regulatory structure designed to . . . perform[] the antitrust function” might “diminish[]
    the likelihood of major antitrust harm.” 
    Id. at 145
    (second and third alterations in
    original) (quoting Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 
    540 U.S. 398
    , 411–12 (2004)). The court described the Federal Communication
    Commission’s (“FCC”) attempts over the past twenty years to disaggregate set-top boxes
    from the delivery of premium cable, and stated that the FCC’s failure is at least partly
    attributable to shortcomings in the new technologies designed to make premium cable
    available without set-top boxes. See 
    id. at 146
    (“[A] new approach that would work with
    two-way services [failed because it] was not sophisticated enough to meet content
    companies’ content protection demands.” (alterations in original) (quoting Expanding
    Consumers’ Video Navigation Choices; Commercial Availability of Navigational
    Devices, 81 Fed. Reg. 14,033, 14,033–04 (Mar. 16, 2016))).
    The court also pointed out that one FCC regulation actually caps the price that
    cable providers can charge customers who rent set-top boxes.4 See 47 C.F.R. § 76.923(f)–
    (g). Under the regulation, cable companies must calculate the cost of making such set-top
    4
    Neither Healy nor Cox addresses this regulation. Still, it is relevant to the
    issue at hand because it limits the amount of power Cox can obtain in the tied-
    product market.
    18
    boxes functional and available for consumers, and must charge customers according to
    those costs, including only a “reasonable profit” in their leasing rates. 
    Id. § 76.923(c).
    The Second Circuit ultimately concluded that the plaintiffs’ factual allegations against
    Time Warner couldn’t survive summary judgment because they didn’t trigger the
    application of the per se tying rule. 
    Id. at 147.
    In sum, it is now clear that before applying the per se rule to tying arrangements,
    courts must carefully analyze the tie to ensure that it meets Jefferson Parish’s threshold
    requirements. If it does not, the court may further analyze the tie using the rule of reason
    to determine whether it actually harms or threatens to harm competition.5
    IV.    Analysis
    A.     Foreclosure of a Substantial Volume of Commerce
    This case comes down to what it means to foreclose a “not insubstantial” volume
    of commerce. As we discussed, a per se tying claim has four elements, and we have
    concluded that the fourth element—foreclosure—requires proof of actual or potential
    anticompetitive effects in the tied-product market. Based on the Supreme Court’s tying
    cases and our own precedent, Plaintiffs failed to show that the tie had the substantial
    potential to foreclose competition. See Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 15
    –16; Fox 
    Motors, 806 F.2d at 957
    –58.
    5
    Courts need apply a rule-of-reason analysis to a per se tying claim only if
    plaintiffs argue that the tie is illegal under the rule of reason as well. See Fox 
    Motors, 806 F.2d at 959
    n.3 (“Because the challenged allocation system was not unlawful
    under the per se rule and because plaintiffs have not challenged its legality under the
    Rule or [sic] Reason, we need not consider whether the evidence of a conspiracy
    between defendants was sufficient.”).
    19
    The jury found that Plaintiffs had met their burden of showing that Cox’s tie had
    foreclosed a substantial amount of commerce in the set-top-box market. The jury-verdict
    form asked, “Has the alleged tying arrangement foreclosed a substantial volume of
    commerce in the Oklahoma City subsystem to other sellers or potential sellers of set-top
    boxes in the market for set-top boxes?” Joint App. vol. III at 614. The jury circled “Yes.”
    
    Id. But a
    careful review of the record in light of post-Jefferson Parish law reveals that the
    record does not support the jury’s conclusion. Rather, just as the district court found,
    Cox’s tie didn’t foreclose any commerce, nor did it prevent or even discourage other
    competitors from entering the market. Therefore, Cox’s tie didn’t meet the foreclosure
    element’s threshold requirements necessary to trigger the per se rule against tying.
    B.     The Jury Instruction Was Correct
    Plaintiffs vehemently argue that they presented enough evidence to show that
    Cox’s tie affected a substantial volume of commerce. But before we can reach the
    evidence, we must address Plaintiffs’ claim that the law and the foreclosure-of-commerce
    jury instruction required them to show only that Cox’s set-top-box rental proceeds
    yielded more than a de minimis dollar amount. Plaintiffs argue that to satisfy this element
    of their claim, the jury instructions properly required them to show only that Cox’s set-
    top-box rental profits were more than de mimimis. They claim that neither the jury
    instruction nor the law required any further proof for them to meet their burden on this
    issue. Their argument fails because it emphasizes one line of the jury instruction at the
    expense of the remainder. When read as a whole, the jury instruction implements the
    overall goals of tying law and Jefferson Parish’s threshold requirements.
    20
    The jury instruction on the foreclosure-of-commerce element, Jury Instruction 19,
    contained two paragraphs:
    The fourth element that Plaintiff[s] must prove is whether, during the
    class period, [Cox] has foreclosed a substantial amount of commerce to
    other sellers or potential sellers of set-top boxes in the market for set-top
    boxes. This occurs when the tying of two products either prevents
    competitors from selling the tied product or limits the choice available to
    consumers in the purchase of the tied product.
    In determining whether [Cox] has foreclosed a substantial amount of
    commerce in the relevant market for set-top boxes, you should first
    consider the total dollar amount of [Cox’s] leases of set-top boxes in
    Oklahoma City achieved by the tying arrangement in absolute terms. If the
    dollar amount of [Cox’s] leases of set-top boxes was substantial, then you
    should find that [Cox] has foreclosed a substantial amount of commerce.
    Joint App. vol. III at 601 (emphasis added). Upon Cox’s renewed Rule 50(b) motion, the
    district court concluded that Plaintiffs had failed to prove the foreclosure element of their
    tying claim because “Plaintiff[s] failed to offer evidence from which a jury could
    determine that any other manufacturer wished to sell set-top boxes at retail or that Cox
    had acted in a manner to prevent any other manufacturer from selling set-top boxes at
    retail.” In re Cox Enters., 
    2015 WL 7076418
    , at *1.
    Plaintiffs contend that nothing in the jury instructions required them to offer such
    evidence. Instead, they seize upon the last sentence of the jury instruction, arguing that to
    prevail on the foreclosure element, they needed to show only that Cox made a substantial
    amount of money on its set-top-box leases. We acknowledge that reading the last
    sentence in isolation could lead a jury to believe that plaintiffs met the foreclosure
    element just by showing that the defendant made a substantial amount of money on the
    21
    tied product. But, though inartfully drawn, the instruction must be read as a whole.6 And
    when doing so, we believe it evident that Plaintiffs’ reading—elevating the last sentence
    above the rest of the instruction—is incorrect.7
    In fact, Plaintiffs’ interpretation of Jury Instruction 19 would render the entire first
    paragraph of the jury instruction meaningless. This paragraph is not merely explanatory;
    it defines the fourth element’s affirmative requirements. As a threshold matter, it provides
    that Plaintiffs must show not only that Cox has foreclosed a substantial volume of
    commerce, but that it has foreclosed this commerce “to other sellers or potential sellers of
    6
    A proper reading of the instruction does not cast off earlier requirements just
    because the instruction does not go to the trouble, and length, to repeat them in every
    sentence. When the last sentence is read as part of the whole instruction, it gives
    effect to earlier language, meaning this: “If the dollar amount of [Cox’s] leases of
    set-top boxes [achieved by the tying arrangement] was substantial, then you should
    find that [Cox] has foreclosed a substantial amount of commerce [to other sellers or
    potential sellers of set-top boxes in the market for set-top boxes].”
    7
    Plaintiffs argue that “[e]ven if . . . the jury instructions were incomplete or
    incorrect, the remedy is a new trial under correct instructions and not judgment in
    favor of Cox.” Appellants’ Response Br. at 23–24. But a new trial with a jury
    instruction that more clearly explained the foreclosure element wouldn’t change the
    outcome of this case.
    As we explained above, the foreclosure element of a per se tying claim in our
    circuit requires a showing that the tie had the potential to or actually did harm
    competition in the tied-product market. Having “been fully heard on [the] issue . . .
    there is no legally sufficient evidentiary basis for a reasonable jury to find for
    [Plaintiffs]” under the law. Fed. R. Civ. P. 50(a)(1). In other words, the record shows
    that Cox’s tie was not the sole—or even the primary—reason that Plaintiffs couldn’t
    purchase set-top boxes or their alternatives from other manufacturers. See In re Cox
    Enters., 
    2015 WL 7076418
    , at *1 (“Plaintiff[s] failed to offer evidence from which a
    jury could determine that any other manufacturer wished to sell set-top boxes at retail
    or that Cox had acted in a manner to prevent any other manufacturer from selling set-
    top boxes at retail.”). Therefore, the tie didn’t foreclose competition in the tied-
    product market and the district court properly granted Cox judgment as a matter of
    law under Rule 50(b).
    22
    set-top boxes.” Joint App. vol. III at 601 (emphasis added). The paragraph then goes on
    to explain that in a tying claim, plaintiffs must show that the tying arrangement caused
    the foreclosure—either by preventing new competitors from entering or by driving
    existing competitors out of the tied-product market.
    When read in context, the first paragraph of Jury Instruction 19 restricts the
    meaning of its last sentence. The dollar amount of Cox’s set-top-box leases that is
    relevant to the foreclosure element must have been achieved by the tie. This is
    important—the foreclosure must result from the tie itself, not from any other
    anticompetitive conduct (which would be a different claim altogether), or from any
    external factors unrelated to the tie. But the total dollar amount of the leases doesn’t
    matter if Cox’s tie wasn’t the reason its customers leased set-top boxes from Cox. In
    other words, Jury Instruction 19 properly explains that making money from a tying
    arrangement doesn’t violate § 1 of the Sherman Act unless the defendant, by doing so,
    has actually or potentially foreclosed or injured competition in the tied-product market.
    This interpretation of the jury instruction accords with the Supreme Court’s tying-
    law precedent. See Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 15
    –16 (“Per se condemnation—
    condemnation without inquiry into actual market conditions—is only appropriate if the
    existence of forcing is probable. Thus, application of the per se rule focuses on the
    probability of anticompetitive consequences. Of course, as a threshold matter there must
    be a substantial potential for impact on competition in order to justify per se
    condemnation.”). It also accords with our own tying-law precedent. See Fox 
    Motors, 806 F.2d at 959
    (declining to condemn the alleged tying arrangement because it didn’t
    23
    foreclose competing manufacturers and therefore “cannot be characterized as a tying
    arrangement of the kind presumptively condemned under the antitrust laws”).
    As we discussed above, the question of whether to apply the per se rule to tying
    claims has become increasingly complex as courts have begun to question whether tying
    arrangements actually deserve per se condemnation. See Ill. Tool 
    Works, 547 U.S. at 35
    (noting that “strong disapproval of tying arrangements has substantially diminished”);
    Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 35
    (O’Connor, J., concurring) (“The time has . . . come to
    abandon the ‘per se’ label and refocus the inquiry on the adverse economic effects, and
    the potential economic benefits, that the tie may have.”). Because tying claims often
    present little or no potential to harm competition—and thus, no antitrust concerns—
    plaintiffs alleging per se unlawful tying arrangements must do more to meet the
    foreclosure element than point to a dollar amount. See Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 15
    –16.
    They must show that the alleged tying arrangement had the potential to or actually did
    injure competition. Thus, even before we reach the application of the per se rule, the
    plaintiffs must show that this is the type of tie that threatens to harm competition such
    that it deserves per se treatment. Here, the jury instruction properly required the Plaintiffs
    to do so, and the Plaintiffs failed to meet their burden.
    C.     Plaintiffs Failed to Show Foreclosure
    Turning to the district court’s order granting Cox’s Rule 50(b) motion, the district
    court found that Cox hadn’t foreclosed any commerce because, through no fault of Cox’s,
    no manufacturers sold or even wanted to sell set-top boxes directly to consumers. In re
    Cox Enters., 
    2015 WL 7076418
    , at *1. Plaintiffs argue that they presented more than
    24
    enough evidence to show that the lack of competition in the set-top-box market resulted
    from Cox’s tying arrangement. We acknowledge that we must not disregard the jury’s
    verdict. But in light of our analysis of the foreclosure element, we agree with the district
    court that Plaintiffs failed to present evidence sufficient to show that Cox’s alleged tie
    foreclosed a substantial volume of commerce in the market for set-top boxes. In other
    words, “the evidence points but one way and is susceptible to no reasonable inferences
    which may support [Plaintiffs’] position.” Auraria Student 
    Hous., 843 F.3d at 1247
    (quoting Elm Ridge Expl. 
    Co., 721 F.3d at 1216
    ). We therefore conclude that the tie did
    not trigger the application of the per se rule.
    Similar to Fox Motors and Microsoft, our case simply doesn’t merit per se
    condemnation. Four factors support our conclusion. First, Cox was an intermediary
    between set-top-box manufacturers and cable customers. Second, Cox had no competitors
    in the set-top-box market. Third, all cable companies similarly tie premium cable services
    to set-top-box rentals, suggesting that net efficiencies and technological constraints—
    rather than desire to gain monopoly power in the tied-product market—necessitated the
    tie. Finally, the FCC’s regulatory involvement in set-top boxes further diminishes the
    possibility that Cox’s tie could harm competition in that market.
    We begin with the significant fact that Cox does not manufacture the set-top boxes
    that it rents to customers. On appeal, Plaintiffs completely failed to address this unique
    market structure. Cox acts as an intermediary between the set-top-box manufacturers and
    the consumers that use them. That Cox purchases the boxes from manufacturers—and
    does not make the boxes itself—means that what it later does with the boxes has little or
    25
    no effect on competition between set-top-box manufacturers in the set-top-box market.
    See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1709e4 (when sellers simply buy a product from
    existing manufacturers and resell them to tied customers at a profit, “the tie neither limits
    the marketing opportunities of the several manufacturers of the second product nor
    impairs the vitality of competition in their market. Each of those manufacturers remains
    free to compete for the patronage or blessing of the tying defendant . . . .”).
    In fact, competition in the set-top-box market might continue to be robust because
    set-top-box manufacturers must continue to innovate and compete with each other to
    maintain their status as the preferred manufacturer for as many cable companies as
    possible. 
    Id. As a
    prominent antitrust scholar has noted, “a foreclosure is of doubtful
    significance when the tying seller does not make the tied product but merely purchases it
    from independent suppliers,” 
    id. ¶ 1709a,
    because “[a] tie cannot bring the defendant
    power in a market that it does not inhabit. . . . [S]uch a defendant does not itself ‘invade’
    or ‘dominate’ the market for the tied product,” 
    id. ¶ 1726d1
    (citing Carl Sandburg Vill.
    Condo. Ass’n No. 1 v. First Condo. Dev. Co., 
    758 F.2d 203
    , 207 (7th Cir. 1985); Ohio-
    
    Sealy, 585 F.2d at 834
    –35).
    Though the risk of foreclosing competition increases when the seller’s
    customers—here, Cox’s premium cable subscribers—are the only purchasers of the tied
    product, the risk is offset in this case because if they chose to, set-top-box manufacturers
    could sell their wares directly to cable customers. But none do. If enough customers
    demanded to buy set-top boxes or set-top-box alternatives directly from manufacturers,
    the manufacturers could have chosen to sell them directly; Cox’s tie did not preclude
    26
    them from doing so. In fact, Cox presented testimony from the executives of several set-
    top-box manufacturers confirming that Cox had no impact on their decisions not to sell
    set-top boxes at retail or directly to consumers.
    Second, that no manufacturers chose to sell their products to consumers, either
    directly or at retail, means that Cox has no existing rivals in the set-top-box market (as
    the district court pointed out). Though Plaintiffs maintain that they don’t need to prove
    the existence of any competitors in the tied-product market, they allege that Cox’s tie
    likely caused the lack of competitors in the set-top-box market. Even if Cox had created
    an effective tie—and it very well might have done so—the lack of competitors in the set-
    top-box market doesn’t prove that the tie foreclosed commerce or harmed competition in
    that market.
    Plaintiffs alternatively argue that numerous actual and potential competitors
    existed in the retail market for set-top boxes. To support their claim, Plaintiffs point to
    evidence that many manufacturers were certified to offer CableCard-enabled products at
    retail. But in doing so, Plaintiffs again ignore that representatives of these manufacturers
    testified that they chose not to sell their set-top boxes at retail for reasons unrelated to
    Cox’s tie. Plaintiffs also argue that TiVo wanted to sell a set-top box at retail but couldn’t
    move forward with this plan due to a falsely manufactured “indemnification issue” on
    Cox’s part. Appellant’s Opening Br. at 25.
    But contrary to Plaintiffs’ contention, the record suggests instead that both Cox
    and TiVo thought their first attempt at TiVo boxes that integrated Cox’s premium cable
    services operated too slowly to offer to customers, and that after the indemnification issue
    27
    stalled their second project (which was not close to completion in any case), Cox and
    TiVo moved on to a third initiative to continue trying to make TiVo’s box compatible
    with Cox’s premium cable services. Finally, Plaintiffs point out that many other
    manufacturers were interested in the set-top-box market, and that a few companies
    offered Tru2Way products for sale at retail. But Plaintiffs failed to show that Cox’s tie, as
    opposed to consumer choice, defeated these products or kept their manufacturers from
    selling them.
    So here, we have no foreclosure, and zero-foreclosure ties present no antitrust
    concerns. See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1723a (“When there are no rival sellers of
    the tied product, then the alleged tie might affect a substantial volume of commerce in the
    tied product and yet not foreclose anyone.”). Because set-top-box manufacturers choose
    not to sell set-top boxes at retail or directly to consumers, “no rival in the tied market
    could be foreclosed by” Cox’s tie, and therefore “the alleged tie ‘does not fall within the
    realm of contracts “in restraint of trade or commerce” proscribed by Section 1 of the
    Sherman Act . . . .’” 
    Id. ¶ 1723b
    (quoting 
    Coniglio, 495 F.2d at 1292
    ).
    Plaintiffs contend that the zero-foreclosure rule applies only where consumers
    don’t want the tied product or where no other seller is capable of selling the tied product
    for reasons unrelated to the tie. This argument misreads the case law. Though some
    courts have found that no rival sellers exist when no other sellers are capable of selling
    the tied product, see 
    Coniglio, 495 F.2d at 1291
    , nowhere did those courts state that this
    was the only occasion where the lack of rival sellers would excuse a tie. Here, the record
    shows that Cox’s tie didn’t cause the lack of competitors in the set-top-box market
    28
    because several manufacturers testified that Cox’s actions had no impact on their decision
    to enter the retail market. This removes the tie from the category of tying claims
    deserving per se condemnation.
    Third, as the D.C. Circuit found so significant in Microsoft, all cable companies
    rent set-top boxes to consumers. See 
    Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 86
    ; see also 
    Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 144
    (“[T]he Complaint lacks any allegation that there have ever been separate
    sales of set-top boxes and cable services . . . in the United States, even in markets where
    cable providers face competition . . . .”). This suggests that tying set-top-box rentals to
    premium cable is simply more efficient than offering them separately. 
    Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 88
    (“[B]undling by all competitive firms implies strong net efficiencies.”); see
    also Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1729e2 (“[T]he most likely inference to be drawn
    from similar ties imposed by each firm in a market, whether concentrated or
    unconcentrated, is that competition rather than oligopoly has forced the tie.”). Here,
    technology requirements dictate that consumers rent or buy set-top boxes to receive all of
    Cox’s services. See 
    Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 144
    (“A cable box must be designed to receive
    the signal from a particular provider, which requires the provider’s cooperation. And
    because providers code their signals to prevent theft, a cable box must also be able to
    unscramble the coded signal of the particular provider.”). Plaintiffs point out that
    efficiency and technology aren’t the only reasons for Cox’s tying arrangement, because
    cable companies make a hefty profit on set-top-box rentals. But the mere fact that Cox
    profited from set-top-box rentals doesn’t justify applying the per se rule. See Carl
    
    Sandburg, 758 F.2d at 208
    (“[P]laintiff does not establish the requisite economic interest
    29
    in the tied product market merely by alleging that the tying seller is receiving a profit
    from the transaction as a whole.”). Tying law is concerned with protecting competition;
    “high prices standing alone are not the evil that antitrust tying law condemns.” Areeda &
    Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1724a.
    Still, Plaintiffs also suggest that this profit-making potential drove Cox to
    propagate its tie by refusing to support technologies that allowed or would allow
    customers to access Cox’s services without renting set-top boxes from Cox. Even if such
    support was required,8 the record simply fails to show that Cox withheld that support.
    Cox submitted abundant evidence that it supported both CableCard and Tru2Way
    technologies.9
    Plaintiffs don’t contest that evidence; they simply say that Cox’s efforts to open
    the set-top-box market to other competitors were insufficient. They claim that Cox didn’t
    do enough to inform its customers that it would support CableCard and Tru2Way.
    Assuming that this evidence is even relevant to whether Cox’s tie foreclosed competition
    in the set-top-box market, Plaintiffs’ argument fails. They argue that Cox sabotaged
    8
    Such support is not required. See 
    Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 144
    (“[T]he core
    issue is a cable provider’s right to refuse to enable cable boxes it does not control to
    unscramble its coded signal.”).
    9
    The former enabled Cox customers to receive one-way services without a set-
    top box, and the latter enabled them to receive two-way services without a set-top
    box. Importantly, though, both technologies still required additional hardware to
    work. The customer would need a CableCard- or Tru2Way-enabled television or a
    TiVo box to avoid having to purchase or rent a set-top box. As explained above, this
    functionality strongly indicates a need for the tie that is separate from Cox’s desire to
    profit from set-top-box rentals.
    30
    CableCard by not planning any “proactive marketing initiatives” to promote it.
    Appellant’s Opening Br. at 19 (internal citation and quotation marks omitted). But Cox
    had no obligation to promote CableCard, and when customers chose to use that
    technology, Cox did nothing to stop them. See Christy Sports, LLC v. Deer Valley Resort
    Co., 
    555 F.3d 1188
    , 1197 (10th Cir. 2009) (“The Sherman Act does not force [a business]
    to assist a competitor in eating away its own customer base . . .”). Cox’s communication
    to customers that they couldn’t access interactive cable services without renting a set-top
    box was simply a true statement based on the technological limitations of CableCard.
    Until Tru2Way was ready for release, the only interactive cable service available to Cox
    customers without a set-top box was pay-per-view, which customers could obtain by
    phone.10
    Moreover, when Tru2Way became available, Cox told customers in its annual
    notice that it was preparing to support, and then in a later notice that it did support, the
    technology. Plaintiffs fault Cox for hiding that information in brochures that no one
    reads, but we decline to hold Cox liable under the Sherman Act simply because
    customers failed to read Cox’s annual published statements. Moreover, Cox has no duty
    to support new technology by affirmatively pushing it on consumers. See Christy Sports,
    10
    Whether Cox should have required its sales force to explain to each
    customer exactly what was available with a set-top box versus CableCard technology
    is a different question that is irrelevant to whether the tie foreclosed a substantial
    amount of commerce. Cox supported the CableCard and Tru2Way technologies,
    meaning that it spent money to make its systems compatible with both technologies.
    When asked, Cox sales representatives accurately told customers what they could
    obtain by using CableCard.
    
    31 555 F.3d at 1197
    . Accepting that the CableCard and Tru2Way technologies—along with
    the televisions or TiVo boxes customers needed to use those technologies—qualified as
    substitutes for set-top boxes, we still could not say that Cox’s tie had any detrimental
    effect on their vitality. Consumers were free to pursue those technologies instead of
    renting set-top boxes from Cox, but even the FCC concluded that they failed for reasons
    unrelated to cable companies’ tying arrangements. See 81 Fed. Reg. at 14,033.
    Plaintiffs also point to evidence that Cox refused to support one customer who had
    purchased a set-top box on eBay. Their argument assumes that in doing so, Cox
    foreclosed what could have been a thriving, second-hand set-top-box market by refusing
    to provide cable to customers who purchased their set-top boxes from such marketplaces.
    We agree with Plaintiffs that this refusal implicates the concern of tying law: that by
    refusing to support a customer who actually did purchase a set-top box from someone
    other than Cox, the cable company used its monopoly power in the premier cable market
    to foreclose competition in the set-top-box market. But Cox, in turn, presented
    compelling evidence justifying its refusal. Based on Cox’s experience and knowledge, no
    set-top box manufacturers sold their wares directly to consumers, so it surmised that a
    customer had rented this set-top box from some other cable company and, instead of
    returning it, sold it on eBay. Therefore, for reasons other than the tie, Cox justifiably
    refused to enable the set-top box to decode its protected content.
    32
    Fourth, the regulatory environment of the cable industry precludes the possibility
    that Cox could harm competition with its tie.11 We agree with the Second Circuit that the
    “regulatory price control on the tied product makes the plaintiffs’ tying claim implausible
    as a whole.” 
    Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 146
    . After all, the regulatory cap on the profits that
    cable companies can procure in the set-top-box market diminishes the already-low
    likelihood that Cox is attempting to or could possibly obtain monopoly power in the set-
    top-box market. Moreover, cable companies’ obligation to protect the content they
    provide to their viewers justifies their refusal to enable set-top-box manufacturers to
    decode such content. As Cox pointed out, cable providers are accountable to content
    creators to protect such content; thus, their tie serves a functional purpose. Because “as a
    threshold matter there must be a substantial potential for impact on competition in order
    to justify per se condemnation,” Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 16
    , the tie in this case doesn’t
    trigger the application of tying’s per se rule. See 
    Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 147
    (“The
    insufficiency of the allegations of a separate market for bidirectional cable boxes, the
    inability of the FCC to create such a market, and the price regulation of the tied product
    further persuade us that the Complaint does not plead a plausible tying claim.”).
    11
    Plaintiffs point out that Congress passed the 1996 Telecommunication Act to
    “assure the commercial availability, to consumers . . . of . . . equipment used . . . to
    access multichannel video programming and other services offered over multichannel
    video programming systems, from manufacturers, retailers, and other vendors not
    affiliated with any multichannel video programming distributor.” Appellants’
    Opening Br. at 15 (quoting 47 U.S.C. § 549). But this law does nothing to help their
    cause. As Plaintiffs explain, this law led to the development of CableCard and
    Tru2Way, which both failed for technological reasons. 
    Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 146
    .
    33
    Plaintiffs do not contest the goals of antitrust tying law. Indeed, the fatal flaw in
    their argument is that it elevates form over function and fails to acknowledge the
    reasoning behind the Supreme Court’s threshold requirements for triggering the per se
    rule against tying. Instead of explaining why the tie is dangerous despite Cox’s lack of
    competitors in the set-top-box market, Plaintiffs insist that they need to show only that
    set-top-box rentals accounted for a substantial dollar amount. They insist that the “tying
    arrangement[] [is] illegal in and of [itself], without any requirement that the plaintiff
    make a showing of unreasonable competitive effect.” Foremost Pro Color, Inc. v.
    Eastman Kodak Co., 
    703 F.2d 534
    , 540 (9th Cir. 1983), overruling recognized by
    Chroma Lighting v. GTE Prods. Corp., 
    111 F.3d 653
    (9th Cir. 1997). They urge that we
    must presume anticompetitive effects based on nothing more than the dollar amount of
    Cox’s set-top-box sales. See Digidyne Corp. v. Data Gen. Corp., 
    734 F.2d 1336
    , 1338
    (9th Cir. 1984).
    But as thoroughly discussed above, “the Supreme Court has continued to add more
    real-market analysis to the requirements of a per se tying claim.” Suture 
    Express, 851 F.3d at 1038
    . In doing so, it has informed us that not all ties threaten to harm competition
    such that they must be declared illegal per se. And here, Cox’s tie has no potential to
    foreclose competition in the set-top-box market, and therefore fails to meet Jefferson
    Parish’s threshold requirements to trigger the per se rule against tying.12
    12
    We express no opinion here over whether Plaintiffs could have shown a
    “contract, combination . . ., or conspiracy, in restraint of trade” under § 1 of the
    Sherman Act. 15 U.S.C. § 1. Leaving aside testimony from set-top box manufacturers
    34
    D.     Application of the Rule of Reason
    Plaintiffs also contend that the district court improperly applied the rule of reason
    to their claim instead of using a per se analysis. As discussed above, the per se analysis
    for tying arrangements differs from other types of per se antitrust claims because tying
    arrangements often pose no risk to competition. Because we conclude this tie falls outside
    the realm of the traditional per se analysis, the district court rightly refused to condemn
    Cox’s tie as illegal per se. And we don’t have to apply the rule of reason unless Plaintiffs
    also argued that the tie was unlawful under a rule of reason analysis. See Fox 
    Motors, 806 F.2d at 959
    n.3. Because Plaintiffs argued that tying arrangements must be analyzed
    under the per se rule, we need not address whether Cox’s tie would be illegal under a rule
    of reason analysis.13
    CONCLUSION
    For the foregoing reasons, we affirm the district court’s order granting Cox
    judgment as a matter of law under Rule 50(b).
    that Cox had nothing to do with their decision not to sell directly to consumers, Cox
    could have engaged in nefarious conduct with other cable companies that diminished
    competition in the set-top-box market. To protect their profits, cable companies could
    have banded together to dissuade manufacturers from selling set-top boxes at retail.
    But Plaintiffs don’t make this claim, nor did they present evidence of any such
    behavior.
    13
    Still, we note that Plaintiffs’ claim would likely have failed either way.
    Because their claim failed under the more plaintiff-friendly per se analysis, it would
    also likely fail under the more demanding rule-of-reason analysis. See Areeda &
    Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1726f (explaining that when a seller purchases the tied product
    from a third party, “the very doubt that ousted per se treatment also makes it unlikely
    that an alleged tie of this character will be found to be unreasonable”).
    35
    Nos. 15-6218, 15-6222, Healy et al. v. Cox Communications, Inc.
    BRISCOE, Circuit Judge, dissenting.
    After a nine-day jury trial in this antitrust case, the district court instructed
    the jury as to the elements of a per se tying claim. Those instructions correctly
    stated the law. The jury found for plaintiffs on each element and awarded $6.313
    million in damages to the plaintiffs. The evidence presented at trial was
    sufficient to support the jury’s conclusion on each element. Nevertheless, the
    district court granted the defendant’s renewed motion for judgment as a matter of
    law, and the majority affirms that decision, vacating the jury’s verdict.
    I respectfully dissent. I would reverse the grant of judgment as a matter of
    law and reinstate the jury verdict against the defendant on the issue of liability.
    Were we to reach the issues raised by defendant in its cross-appeal, I would
    remand for a new trial as to damages under a package approach instruction.
    I
    According to the Supreme Court, the law is and always has been that
    “certain tying arrangements pose an unacceptable risk of stifling competition and
    therefore are unreasonable ‘per se.’” Jefferson Par. Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde,
    
    466 U.S. 2
    , 9 (1984). Of course, “not every refusal to sell two products
    separately can be said to restrain competition.” 
    Id. at 11.
    Thus, our inquiry is
    whether the alleged tie is one which merits per se condemnation. In fact, per se
    claims, by their nature, focus on the character of the alleged anticompetitive
    conduct, not on the actual market effects that conduct may or may not have
    caused. Per se illegal agreements or practices are those that, “because of their
    pernicious effect on competition and lack of any redeeming virtue are
    conclusively presumed to be unreasonable and therefore illegal without elaborate
    inquiry as to the precise harm they have caused or the business excuse for their
    use.” N. Pac. R.R. Co. v. United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 5 (1958). In cases alleging
    per se violations of the Sherman Act, unlike general claims that a particular
    practice unreasonably restrains trade, courts look to the nature of the agreement
    or practice, not the actual market effects of that conduct. See id.; Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 21
    (“The definitional question depends on whether the arrangement
    may have the type of competitive consequences addressed by the rule.”). If the
    challenged conduct, by its nature, is of the type that has been declared
    presumptively illegal, then the inquiry ends; courts need not, and should not
    consider the actual market effects. NCAA v. Board of Regents, 
    468 U.S. 85
    ,
    103–04 (1984) (“Per se rules are invoked when surrounding circumstances make
    the likelihood of anticompetitive conduct so great as to render unjustified further
    examination of the challenged conduct.” (emphasis added). In such cases, the
    harm to competition is presumed. 
    Id. (distinguishing between
    per se claims and
    general Sherman Act claims based on “whether the ultimate finding is the product
    of a presumption or actual market analysis” (emphasis added)).
    In Jefferson Parish Jefferson Hospital District Number 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    (1984), the Supreme Court stated unequivocally, “[i]t is far too late in the
    2
    history of our antitrust jurisprudence to question the proposition that certain tying
    arrangements pose an unacceptable risk of stifling competition and therefore are
    unreasonable ‘per se.’” Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 9
    . This rule has been
    endorsed by the Court many times since it was “first enunciated in International
    Salt Co. v. United States, 
    332 U.S. 392
    , 396 (1947),” and it “reflects
    congressional policies underlying the antitrust laws.” Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 9
    –11 (citing H.R. Rep. No. 627, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 10–13 (1914); S. Rep.
    No. 698, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 6–9 (1914)). Thus, our analysis must focus on the
    nature of the challenged conduct, not on a market analysis of the actual effects
    that conduct has had. In a per se tying claim “we must consider whether
    [defendants] are selling two separate products that may be tied together, and, if
    so, whether they have used their market power to force their [customers] to accept
    the tying arrangement.” 1 
    Id. at 18.
    1
    Despite the majority’s assertion that the Court “modified its view of tying
    arrangements” in Jefferson Parish, Maj. Op. at 9, the elements of a tying claim
    have always been, and continue to be, as they are stated in Jefferson Parish. See
    Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 461–62 (1992) (“A
    tying arrangement . . . violates § 1 of the Sherman Act if the seller has
    ‘appreciable economic power’ in the tying product market and if the arrangement
    affects a substantial volume of commerce in the tied market.’” (quoting Fortner
    Enters., Inc. v. United States Steel Corp. (Fortner I), 
    394 U.S. 495
    , 503 (1969)));
    Fortner 
    I, 394 U.S. at 499
    (“[Tying agreements] are unreasonable in and of
    themselves whenever a party has sufficient economic power with respect to the
    tying product to appreciably restrain free competition in the market for the tied
    product and a ‘not insubstantial’ amount of interstate commerce is affected.”
    (quoting Int’l Salt Co. v. United States, 
    332 U.S. 392
    , 396 (1947))); N. Pac. R.R.
    
    Co., 356 U.S. at 6
    (same); Times-Picayune Pub. Co. v. United States, 
    345 U.S. 3
    A.    Separate Products
    Our first inquiry is whether the products in question are actually separate
    products that may be illegally tied. This question has also been framed by the
    Supreme Court as a question of whether “a substantial volume of commerce is
    foreclosed” by the tie. 
    Id. at 16
    (citing Fortner Enters. v. United States Steel
    Corp. (Fortner I), 
    394 U.S. 495
    , 501–02 (1969); N. Pac. 
    R.R., 356 U.S. at 6
    –7;
    Times-Picayune Pub. Co. v. United States, 
    345 U.S. 594
    , 608–10 (1953); Int’l
    
    Salt, 332 U.S. at 396
    . More recently the Court described it as “a threshold
    matter” of whether there is “a substantial potential for impact on competition in
    order to justify per se condemnation.” See Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 16
    .
    This threshold question is necessary because “[i]f only a single purchaser
    were ‘forced’ with respect to the purchase of a tied item, the resultant impact on
    competition would not be sufficient to warrant the concern of antitrust law.” 
    Id. “Similarly, when
    a purchaser is ‘forced’ to buy a product he would not have
    otherwise bought even from another seller in the tied-product market, there can be
    594, 608–09 (1953) (“When the seller enjoys a monopolistic position in the
    market for the ‘tying’ product, or if a substantial volume of commerce in the
    ‘tied’ product is restrained, a tying arrangement violates the narrower standards
    expressed in § 3 of the Clayton Act because from either factor the requisite
    potential lessening of competition is inferred. And because for even a lawful
    monopolist it is ‘unreasonable, per se, to foreclose competitors from any
    substantial market,’ a tying arrangement is banned by § 1 of the Sherman Act
    whenever both conditions are met.” (emphasis added)).
    4
    no adverse impact on competition because no portion of the market which would
    otherwise have been available to other sellers has been foreclosed.” 
    Id. According to
    the Supreme Court, “the answer to the question whether one
    or two products are involved turns not on the functional relation between them,
    but rather on the character of the demand for the two items.” 
    Id. at 19.
    Courts
    must determine whether the products are “distinguishable in the eyes of
    buyers” — whether there is “a sale involving two independent transactions,
    separately priced and purchased from the buyer’s perspective.” 
    Id. at 19–20.
    Courts should consider whether other sellers offer or could offer the products
    separately, whether customers are charged separately for the two products, and
    whether the tied product is fungible. 
    Id. at 22–23;
    id. at 23 
    n.39 (citing United
    States v. Jerrold Elecs. Corp., 
    187 F. Supp. 545
    (E.D. Pa. 1960), aff’d, 
    365 U.S. 567
    (1961) (per curiam)). Whether two products or services “are functionally
    linked . . . is not in itself sufficient” to answer the question. 
    Id. at 19
    n.30. The
    Court “ha[s] often found arrangements involving functionally linked products at
    least one of which is useless without the other to be prohibited tying devices.” 
    Id. (collecting cases).
    “In fact, in some situations the functional link between the
    two items may enable the seller to maximize its monopoly return on the tying
    item as a means of charging a higher rent or purchase price to a larger user of the
    tying item.” 
    Id. 5 Only
    once has the Supreme Court held that two products were not separate.
    “In Times-Picayune Publishing Co. v. United States, 
    345 U.S. 594
    (1953), the
    Court held that a tying arrangement was not present because the arrangement did
    not link two distinct markets for products that were distinguishable in the eyes of
    buyers.” Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 19
    . Specifically, in that case, the Court held
    that, although two newspapers were separate and distinct from the perspective of
    readers, that “d[id] not necessarily imply that advertisers bought separate and
    distinct products when insertions were placed in the [two papers].” 
    Id. at 19
    n.31.
    There was no evidence “that advertisers viewed the city’s newspaper readers,
    morning or evening, as other than fungible customer potential.” 
    Id. The Court
    “assume[d], therefore, that the readership ‘bought’ by advertisers in [one paper]
    was the selfsame ‘product’ sold by the [other paper] . . . .” 
    Id. “The common
    core of the adjudicated unlawful tying arrangements is the forced purchase of a
    second distinct commodity with the desired purchase of a dominant ‘tying’
    product, resulting in economic harm to competition in the ‘tied’ market.” 
    Id. (quoting Times-Picayune,
    345 U.S. at 613–14). The Court concluded, “two
    newspapers under single ownership at the same place, time, and terms sell
    indistinguishable products to advertisers; no dominant ‘tying’ product
    exists . . . no leverage in one market excludes sellers in the second, because for
    present purposes the products are identical and the market the same.” 
    Id. (quoting Times-Picayune,
    345 U.S. at 613–14). In short, if the tied and tying product
    6
    markets are in fact the same market, there can be no unlawful tie because the
    seller is not exploiting its power in one market to coerce buyer behavior in
    another.
    In addition, courts of appeals have found that tying arrangements are not
    deserving of per se condemnation when no other seller could potentially sell the
    product. These are cases in which the seller has a natural monopoly over both the
    tied and tying products. See, e.g., Coniglio v. Highwood Services, Inc., 
    495 F.2d 1286
    , 1291–92 (2d Cir. 1974) (concluding there was no illegal tie between tickets
    to regular season professional football games and tickets to exhibition football
    games because the seller of tickets had a natural monopoly in both the tying and
    the tied product markets); Driskill v. Dallas Cowboys Football Club, Inc., 
    498 F.2d 321
    , 323 (5th Cir. 1974) (following Coniglio and concluding that “the [seller
    has] a complete monopoly in the tied market . . . and there can thus be no adverse
    effect on any competitors, even if a tying scheme exists”); Ohio-Sealy Mattress
    Mfg. Co. v. Sealy, Inc., 
    585 F.2d 821
    , 835 (7th Cir. Ill. Oct. 11, 1978) (citing
    Coniglio and Driskill for the proposition that when the seller has a complete
    monopoly in both the tied and tying markets, there can “be no foreclosure of
    competitive access to the tied market resulting from the tie-in”). In these cases, it
    is not merely that potential sellers of the tied product were uninterested in selling
    the tied product due to any number of market realities, but that those potential
    sellers were incapable of selling the tied product because some other seller
    7
    already possessed a lawfully obtained monopoly in that market. If the seller has a
    natural monopoly in both the tying and tied product markets, a tying arrangement
    cannot harm competition in the tied product market, so there can be no illegal tie.
    Similarly, when the tied product is completely unwanted by the buyer such
    that no market exists for that product, there can be no per se illegal tying
    arrangement. See, e.g., Blough v. Holland Realty, Inc., 
    574 F.3d 1084
    , 1089 (9th
    Cir. 2009) (“Zero foreclosure exists where the tied product is completely
    unwanted by the buyer.”); Reifert v. S. Cent. Wisconsin MLS Corp., 
    450 F.3d 312
    , 323 (7th Cir. 2006) (“Despite Reifert’s desire to avoid purchasing a Realtors
    Association membership, without evidence of competitors in the market for
    services offered by the Realtors Association, there can be no foreclosure of
    competition.”); Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Bd. of Realtors, 
    850 F.2d 803
    , 815 (1st Cir. 1988) (“Wells has failed to demonstrate the slightest
    market for membership in real estate boards that might have been affected by the
    defendants’ alleged tying arrangement.”); 
    id. at 815
    n.11 (“Wells’ real error here
    was in failing to show that there was a ‘market’ at all for real estate board
    membership.”). These cases dealt with purported ties between a real estate listing
    service and membership in a realtors’ association, 
    Reifert, 450 F.3d at 323
    ; Wells
    Real 
    Estate, 850 F.2d at 805
    , or between sale of undeveloped lots and realtor’s
    commission for the sale of those lots, 
    Blough, 574 F.3d at 1088
    . In these
    circumstances, the “tied product” was not a separate product at all, but merely an
    8
    item tacked on by the seller to increase the total price for the primary product. 
    Id. at 1089–90.
    These arrangements have “nothing to do with gaining power in the
    [tied] market or upsetting competition there.” 
    Id. at 1090
    (quoting IX Phillip E.
    Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1724b, at 270(2004 & Supp.
    2009)). A buyer cannot purchase a realtor’s services separate from the purchase
    of land, and membership in a realtors’ association provides no benefits aside from
    the ability to use the multiple listing service, so the markets for those “products”
    did not exist. Instead, the “products” were merely an additional cost included in
    the desired product or service. See 
    id. If the
    market for the tied product does not
    exist at all, then competition cannot be harmed in that non-existent market, so
    there can be no illegal tie.
    Although courts have framed this inquiry as several various elements of a
    tying claim, the essential inquiry is the same: Has the seller linked two distinct
    product markets in a way that could impair competition in the tied market? This
    is the threshold inquiry described by the Supreme Court in Jefferson Parish.
    B.    Market Power
    When two separate products are tied, courts must next consider whether the
    seller has “sufficient economic power with respect to the tying product to
    appreciably restrain free competition in the market for the tied product.” N. Pac.
    R.R. 
    Co., 356 U.S. at 6
    . “[T]he essential characteristic of an invalid tying
    arrangement lies in the seller’s exploitation of its control over the tying product to
    9
    force the buyer into the purchase of a tied product that the buyer either did not
    want at all, or might have preferred to purchase elsewhere on different terms.”
    Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 12
    . This is because, when a seller conditions the sale
    of one commodity on the purchase of another, it “coerces the abdication of
    buyers’ independent judgment as to the ‘tied’ product’s merits and insulates it
    from the competitive stresses of the open market.” 
    Id. at 12–13.
    Thus, “when the
    seller has some special ability — usually called ‘market power’ — to force a
    purchaser to do something that he would not do in a competitive market,” 
    id. at 13–14,
    then “‘forcing’ is present, competition on the merits in the market for the
    tied item is restrained and the Sherman Act is violated,” 
    id. at 12.
    C.    Tenth Circuit Case Law
    The Supreme Court has instructed us to answer two questions: First, has
    the seller linked two separate product markets? Second, has the seller used its
    market power in the tying product market to coerce buyer behavior in the tied
    product market? Each Circuit, including ours, defines the elements of a tying
    claim slightly differently. We have required plaintiffs to show:
    (1) two separate products are involved; (2) the sale or agreement to
    sell one product is conditioned on the purchase of the other; (3) the
    seller has sufficient economic power in the tying product market to
    enable it to restrain trade in the tied product market; and (4) a “not
    insubstantial” amount of interstate commerce in the tied product is
    affected.
    10
    Suture Express, Inc. v. Owens & Minor Distrib., 
    851 F.3d 1029
    , 1037 (10th Cir.
    2017) (quoting Sports Racing Servs., Inc. v. Sports Car Club of Am., Inc., 
    131 F.3d 874
    , 886 (10th Cir. 1997)). In my view, our first, second, and fourth
    elements address whether two separate product markets have been tied together
    by the seller such that there is a substantial potential for impact on competition in
    order to justify per se condemnation; our third element addresses whether the
    seller has market power in the tying product market sufficient to enable it to
    coerce buyer behavior in the tied product market.
    II
    With that framework in mind, I turn to the evidence presented in this case.
    Because there is no small amount of disagreement as to what is meant by the
    Tenth Circuit’s expression of the elements, and because the Tenth Circuit’s
    expression of the test is presumptively within the bounds set by the Supreme
    Court, I will focus on the elements as the Supreme Court has described them. The
    evidence presented at trial was sufficient to support a jury finding that Cox linked
    the otherwise separate product markets for premium cable services 2 and set-top
    boxes, and that Cox used its market power in the market for premium cable
    services to coerce its customers into renting set-top boxes from Cox, thereby
    presumptively harming competition in the market for set-top boxes.
    2
    Plaintiffs defined the tying product as “premium cable.” Cox’s particular
    product was called “Advanced TV.”
    11
    A.    The Tie
    The evidence presented at trial was sufficient to support a jury finding that
    Cox conditioned the sale of Advanced TV services on rental of a set-top box from
    Cox. Throughout the relevant period, Cox’s website stated: “In order to receive
    interactive TV services offered by Cox, such as the interactive programming
    guide, on-demand, pay-per-view, and all-digital programming options, you must
    rent a digital receiver.” 3 J.A. vol. L, at 6165–66 (emphasis added). If consumers
    wanted to get interactive TV services from Cox, “they had to rent that set-top
    receiver from Cox.” 
    Id. at 6166.
    Further, Colleen Langer, Vice President of Marketing for Cox, testified that
    the Cox website for ordering cable “would force you to say what type of box do
    you want.” J.A. vol. XXVII, at 4014–15. When asked to elaborate, she stated:
    [The website] won’t let you go any further unless you click one of
    those — check one of those boxes. You can’t order advanced TV
    without having equipment. So at that point in time the system knows
    that in order to complete your order that this customer is going to
    need either a digital set-top box or advanced set-top box, which
    3
    Throughout the trial, there was much testimony designed to determine
    exactly which Advanced TV services were and were not available to consumers
    through other means, such as by ordering pay-per-view over the phone instead of
    through a set-top box. See, e.g., J.A. vol. L, at 6191; J.A. vol. LI, at 6366–67.
    Regardless of which or how many services consumers might have been able to
    acquire through other means, Cox conditioned the provision of Advanced TV on
    the rental of a set-top box. In order to acquire Advanced TV services, a consumer
    was forced to choose which type of set-top-box or cableCARD they wished to
    rent from Cox. There was no option to order Advanced TV without accepting
    equipment rental. J.A. vol. XXVII, at 4014–18.
    12
    would be the HD DVR and they would have to click on it and that
    price would show up.
    
    Id. at 4015
    (emphasis added). When asked, “[i]s there an option for ‘none of the
    above’ or ‘I don’t want a box’ for a customer to say they don’t want a box?,”
    Langer responded “[t]he only other option is if they want a CableCARD,”
    “[w]hich they would also have to rent from Cox.” 
    Id. at 4016.
    She also testified
    that there was no option for customers to order digital cable without also ordering
    equipment, specifically, “they cannot complete the order” without doing so; “[i]t
    would error.” 
    Id. at 4016–18.
    This coercion was not limited to internet sales. Charles Wise, Vice
    President of Customer Care for Cox, testified that, when customers call for
    services, “[t]he service representative communicates to the customer that the
    services that they desire either require a DCR or require a Set-Top box for those
    advanced features, and then they’re communicated to what the cost of the package
    is and what the cost of the equipment is.” 
    Id. at 4040
    (emphasis added). As a
    general matter, Steve Necessary, Vice President of Video Product Development
    and Management for Cox, testified that “[f]rom 2005 to 2012 in Oklahoma, to
    fully access all of the content and services . . . customers had to lease set-top
    boxes from Cox.” J.A. vol. LI, at 6416.
    13
    B.    Separate Products
    This arrangement, conditioning the provision of premium cable services on
    the rental of a set-top box, will merit per se condemnation only if premium cable
    services and set-top boxes are two separate products from the perspective of
    buyers. They are.
    As an initial matter, Cox stipulated that, based on the nature of consumer
    demand for premium cable services and set-top box rental, these were separate
    products. See J.A. vol. XXIII, at 3440; J.A. vol. II, at 276. The jury was
    instructed to find for the plaintiffs on this element. J.A. vol. III, at 588. At trial,
    Steve Necessary also testified that the set-top box and the service were separate
    products. J.A. vol. LI, at 6491–92. Because there is apparently some confusion
    as to what legal significance Cox intended this admission to have, I will address
    the separate products analysis by considering those factors the Supreme Court has
    instructed us to consider: whether other sellers offer or could offer the products
    separately, whether customers are charged separately for the two products, and
    whether the tied product is fungible
    First, there was evidence that other sellers did offer the products separately.
    Lawrence Harte testified as an expert witness for the plaintiffs and provided his
    conclusion that other cable companies did provide cable services separate from
    set-top box rental or purchase. 
    Id. at 6367.
    Specifically, he cited Rogers in
    Canada and Virgin Media in the U.K. 
    Id. Further, there
    was evidence that
    14
    numerous other sellers in the United States could also offer the products
    separately if they so chose. Harte testified that Cisco was already manufacturing
    a box that was technologically compatible with Cox’s Advanced TV service
    system — the very same box, in fact that Cox was buying from Cisco and then
    renting to its customers. 
    Id. at 6399–6400.
    According to the contract between
    Cox and Cisco, nothing prevented Cisco from selling those boxes directly to
    customers, separate from the provision of premium cable services. 
    Id. 6376. Further,
    Cisco’s conditional access security function, PowerKEY, was installed
    on Cisco’s set-top boxes and allowed content providers to limit the content
    accessible on a given box. 
    Id. at 6398–99.
    Cisco was free to license PowerKEY
    to other manufacturers and did in fact license it to at least Pioneer, Pace,
    Panasonic, and Motorola. 
    Id. at 6399–6400.
    Harte also testified that “Cox did
    have the technical ability to provide . . . support for customers to buy and use
    their own set-top boxes” because
    Cox was already allowing retail television devices, in particular,
    cable modems. You could buy a cable modem at a Best Buy or an
    Amazon. You could hook it up and get it activated on the Cox
    system, which is somewhat similar to a set-top box. In fact, it’s a
    form of set-top box, but it just doesn’t do television.
    
    Id. at 6367.
    Specifically, Harte testified that, during the period from 2005 to
    2012, Cox did have the technical “ability to bring a TiVo box online that provided
    two-way services” but that it did not do so. 
    Id. at 6372.
    15
    More directly to this point, there was an incident in which a customer
    acquired a Motorola set-top box on eBay and tried to use it to receive Cox
    Advanced TV services. Cox’s response to that incident indicates that it was
    capable of connecting the box, but decided not to do so. On March 5, 2009,
    Christine Martin sent an e-mail describing a customer complaint. She stated:
    They are claiming that we can and have to hook up outside boxes
    because of the FCC Act of 1996. They think we are holding out
    simply because we are greedy and want to collect “our $42 a month”.
    So, someone needs to call these folks and first of all find out what
    kind of box they have. I’m assuming that will solve the issue since it
    likely won’t be compatible with our system. And then we’ll need to
    talk them down and explain that we aren’t being greedy or breaking
    any rules.
    J.A. vol. XXXVII, at 5000. In a reply e-mail to Christine Martin that same day,
    Delbert Biggs wrote:
    As I understand, once a true “retail” box is available (which is not
    available at this time) we will connect with our cable card, but since
    this customer bought the box on e-bay, it belongs to some cable
    system as neither Motorola or SA are providing retail boxes at this
    time.
    
    Id. at 4999.
    The next day, March 6, 2009, Kevin Rider responded to the e-mail
    chain that the boxes the customer had purchased were boxes that had been
    purchased from Motorola by Advanced Media Technologies, Inc., and Time
    Warner Cable, Inc. 
    Id. at 4996.
    Then, on April 10, 2009, Terry Shorter wrote to
    the e-mail chain that the customer had contacted Advanced Media Technologies
    and Time Warner Cable. He stated, “Both DVR’s are no longer in the other cable
    16
    providers systems & they don’t want them back.” 
    Id. at 4993.
    Billy Hill then
    replied, “Kevin I was not on the last conference call but wasn’t it communicated
    that we would not support there boxes in our system?” 
    Id. Kevin Rider
    then
    confirmed, “At this time, other than a TIVO box, or cable card TV, no other
    device is designed for consumer purchase to operate in our system. It was
    mutually agreed on the conference call that we will not support these devices that
    [the customer] purchased on Ebay.” 
    Id. Whether or
    not we believe Cox’s
    argument that it did not want to connect the boxes because they were stolen, Cox
    stated that it was unwilling, not unable to connect the box as a technical matter.
    In sum, there was ample evidence in the record that sellers were capable of
    selling premium cable services and set-top boxes separately, and that, at least in
    Canada and the U.K., sellers did sell the products separately.
    Second, Cox charged customers separately for service and for set-top box
    rental. J.A. vol. LI, at 6326–27. And Cox viewed rental revenue and service
    revenue separately. J.A. vol. XLI, at 5328.
    Third, there was evidence that set-top boxes are not fungible. Harte offered
    testimony about the various features that set-top boxes can include, such as
    “Netflix and apps, programming guides with skipping the television commercials,
    multinetwork programming guides, the ability to download a movie on a flash
    drive and take that with you on the plane.” J.A. vol. LI, at 6371. Further, Percy
    Kirk, Senior Vice President and General Manager for Cox in Oklahoma, testified
    17
    that boxes were constantly being updated with new and better features and
    functionality. J.A. vol. L, at 6252. Steve Necessary also testified that different
    boxes displayed different interactive guides. 
    Id. at 6449.
    Given these various
    features and updates, consumers would not see all set-top boxes as equivalent.
    Because premium cable services and set-top boxes were sold separately by
    other sellers, could be sold separately by additional other sellers, were billed
    separately to buyers, and were not fungible, they were separate products, as Cox
    stipulated.
    To the extent the majority concludes otherwise, it appears to do so on the
    basis that, as a technical matter, it does not believe that Advanced TV from Cox
    cannot be provided without a set-top box from Cox. For this conclusion, it relies
    upon factual findings from the Second Circuit in Kaufman v. Time Warner, 
    836 F.3d 137
    (2d Cir. 2016). Specifically, the majority cites Kaufman for the
    propositions that (1) cable providers must “code their signals to prevent theft,”
    and “providers do not share their codes,” so, in order “to be useful to a consumer,
    a cable box must be cable-provider specific, like the keys to a padlock”; (2) that
    the FCC was unable to force a competitive retail market for set-top boxes, at least in part
    due to “shortcomings in the new technologies designed to make premium cable available
    without set-top boxes”; and (3) that “one FCC regulation actually caps the price that cable
    providers can charge customers who rent set-top boxes.” Maj. Op at 18–19 (citing
    
    Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 144
    , 146, 147).
    18
    Evidence supporting these findings presumably was presented to the court in
    Kaufman, but it was not presented to the court in this case. The majority notes that the
    FCC regulation capping set-top box rental prices is not addressed by either party in this
    case. Maj. Op. at 19 n.4. Further, there was evidence presented in this trial that Cisco
    could have sold or rented its set-top boxes directly to customers instead of selling only to
    Cox, that other manufacturers had licensed PowerKEY from Cisco, enabling them to also
    make boxes that would connect to Cox’s system, and that Cox was technologically
    capable of connecting set-top boxes to its system whether or not they were rented from
    Cox, but chose not to do so.
    The majority concludes, “plaintiffs failed to show that Cox’s tie, as opposed to
    consumer choice, defeated these products or kept their manufacturers from selling them.”
    Maj. Op. at 28. It asserts that “[i]f enough customers demanded to buy set-top boxes or
    set-top-box alternatives directly from manufacturers, the manufacturers could have
    chosen to sell them directly; Cox’s tie did not preclude them from doing so.” 
    Id. at 27.
    This characterization ignores the reality of tying arrangements. Cox’s customers could
    not demand boxes from manufacturers. As discussed above, if customers did acquire
    boxes from another source, Cox refused to connect them. Further, the nature of a per se
    tying claim entitles us to presume that the lack of consumer demand was a direct effect of
    Cox’s requirement that all its customers rent their set-top boxes from Cox rather than
    from any other source. Certainly such an arrangement is likely to increase barriers to
    entry for other potential sellers of set-top boxes because they must compete with a
    19
    monopolist who can benefit from economies of scale and who has already dominated the
    market-share. Fortner 
    I, 394 U.S. at 509
    ; see also Jefferson 
    Par., 466 U.S. at 14
    .
    The evidence presented to the jury was sufficient for it to conclude that premium
    cable services and set-top boxes were separate products from the perspective of buyers,
    and that this is not a case of “zero foreclosure” because other sellers were able to sell the
    products separately.
    C.     Market Power
    The plaintiffs also presented ample evidence that Cox controlled a substantial
    share of the market for video services in Oklahoma City. According to Cox’s
    calculations, from the third quarter of 2009 to the third quarter of 2011, Cox controlled
    between 68% and 71.5% of the market for video services in Oklahoma City. J.A. vol.
    XLII, at 5375–76. Those calculations did not take into account “over-the-top” services
    Cox provides, which are streaming video services such as Hulu and Netflix, but Jennifer
    Rich, Director of Competitive Strategy for Cox, testified that only 1.5% of customers had
    “chosen over-the-top video instead of paid TV.” J.A. vol. XXVII, at 4114. She also
    testified that 35% to 40% of Cox customers subscribed to over-the-top services in
    addition to cable services. 
    Id. at 4116–17.
    This indicates that consumers did not view
    over-the-top services as a substitute for cable services and, even if over-the-top services
    should have been included in the tying product market, the 1.5% of customers that chose
    over-the-top services instead of cable would not have a material effect on Cox’s 68% to
    71.5% market share.
    20
    III
    Satisfied that the evidence presented at trial was sufficient to support the jury
    verdict, I must make one additional point which perhaps explains why my views differ
    from those of the majority. When considering a motion for judgment as a matter of law,
    it is not our job to decide the case anew, but to uphold the jury verdict unless “the
    evidence points but one way and is susceptible to no reasonable inferences supporting the
    party for whom the jury found.” Weese v. Schukman, 
    98 F.3d 542
    , 547 (10th Cir. 1996)
    (quoting Ralston Dev. Corp. v. United States, 
    937 F.2d 510
    , 512 (10th Cir. 1991)). This
    is particularly true in light of the fact that “summary procedures should be used sparingly
    in complex antitrust litigation where motive and intent play leading roles.” Fortner 
    I, 394 U.S. at 503
    ; see also 
    id. at 505
    (“[S]ummary judgment in antitrust cases is disfavored.”);
    Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 467 (1992) (“This Court has
    preferred to resolve antitrust claims on a case-by-case basis, focusing on the ‘particular
    facts disclosed by the record.’” (quoting Maple Flooring Mfrs. Ass’n v. United States,
    
    268 U.S. 563
    , 579 (1925))); Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 
    547 U.S. 28
    , 43
    (rejecting a per se rule or rebuttable presumption of market power and instead requiring
    proof of market power in each case). We are not dealing here with a situation in which
    one party has asked us to review a grant of summary judgment before a jury has heard all
    the evidence. But rather, we are dealing with a situation in which the jury has heard that
    evidence and found for the plaintiff. Thus, when compared to our review of a grant of
    summary judgment, we should be more hesitant to overturn the verdict of a jury after it
    21
    has considered all the facts presented at trial. Our role on appeal is to determine only
    whether there was sufficient evidence in the record to support the jury’s decision. Here,
    there was.
    I respectfully dissent. I would reverse the grant of judgment as a matter of law,
    reinstate the jury’s verdict on the issue of liability, and remand for a new trial on the issue
    of damages.
    22
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 15-6218

Citation Numbers: 871 F.3d 1093

Filed Date: 9/19/2017

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/12/2023

Authorities (34)

Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Board of Realtors , 850 F.2d 803 ( 1988 )

Lantec, Inc. v. Novell, Inc. , 306 F.3d 1003 ( 2002 )

Weese v. Schukman , 98 F.3d 542 ( 1996 )

Sports Racing Services, Inc. v. Sports Car Club of America, ... , 131 F.3d 874 ( 1997 )

Ralston Development Corporation v. United States , 937 F.2d 510 ( 1991 )

Christy Sports, LLC v. Deer Valley Resort Co. , 555 F.3d 1188 ( 2009 )

Richard E. Driskill v. Dallas Cowboys Football Club, Inc. , 498 F.2d 321 ( 1974 )

Commodore Plaza at Century 21 Condominium Association, Inc.,... , 746 F.2d 671 ( 1984 )

Angelo F. Coniglio v. Highwood Services, Inc. , 495 F.2d 1286 ( 1974 )

jay-reifert-v-south-central-wisconsin-mls-corporation-realtors , 450 F.3d 312 ( 2006 )

Fox Motors, Inc., and Kae Myers Motors, Inc. v. Mazda ... , 806 F.2d 953 ( 1986 )

James R. Farthing v. City of Shawnee, Kansas , 39 F.3d 1131 ( 1994 )

walter-l-reazin-md-hca-health-services-of-kansas-inc-dba-wesley , 899 F.2d 951 ( 1990 )

Elliott Industries Ltd. Partnership v. BP America ... , 407 F.3d 1091 ( 2005 )

United States v. Microsoft Corp , 253 F.3d 34 ( 2001 )

foremost-pro-color-inc-a-california-corporation-individually-and-on , 703 F.2d 534 ( 1983 )

Blough v. Holland Realty, Inc. , 574 F.3d 1084 ( 2009 )

chroma-lighting-a-california-corporation-and-charles-t-von-der-ahe-an , 111 F.3d 653 ( 1997 )

digidyne-corporation-fairchild-camera-and-instrument-corporation , 734 F.2d 1336 ( 1984 )

ohio-sealy-mattress-manufacturing-company-sealy-mattress-company-of , 585 F.2d 821 ( 1978 )

View All Authorities »