Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York ( 2023 )


Menu:
  • 20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Second Circuit
    August Term 2021
    No. 20-3366-cv
    COMMUNITY HOUSING IMPROVEMENT PROGRAM; RENT
    STABILIZATION ASSOCIATION OF N.Y.C., INC.; CONSTANCE NUGENT-
    MILLER; MYACK ASSOCIATES, LLC; VERMYCK LLC; M&G MYACK LLC;
    CINDY REALTY LLC; DANIELLE REALTY LLC; FOREST REALTY, LLC,
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    NEW YORK TENANTS AND NEIGHBORS; COMMUNITY VOICES HEARD;
    COALITION FOR THE HOMELESS,
    Intervenors,
    v.
    CITY OF NEW YORK; RENT GUIDELINES BOARD, DAVID REISS, ARPIT
    GUPTA, ALEX SCHWARZ, CHRISTIAN GONZALEZ-RIVERA, CHRISTINA
    DEROSE, ROBERT EHRLICH, CHRISTINA SMYTH, SHEILA GARCIA, ADÁN
    SOLTREN, *
    Defendants-Appellees.
    *Several new members have been added to the Rent Guidelines Board since this case was
    filed and have thus been automatically substituted for the former members as the
    defendants in this case pursuant to Fed. R. App. P. 43(c)(2).
    1
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Eastern District of New York
    No. 19 Civ. 4087 (ERK), Eric R. Komitee, District Judge, Presiding.
    (Argued February 16, 2022; Decided February 6, 2023)
    Before:         CALABRESI, PARKER, and CARNEY, Circuit Judges.
    Plaintiffs-Appellants, individuals who own apartment buildings in New
    York City subject to the relevant Rent Stabilization Law (RSL), appeal from
    a judgment of the United States District Court for the Eastern District of
    New York (Komitee, J.). The court dismissed the complaint pursuant to Rule
    12(b)(6). Plaintiffs-Appellants alleged that the RSL, as amended in 2019,
    effected, facially, an unconstitutional physical and regulatory taking. The
    District Court held that Plaintiffs-Appellants failed to state claims for
    violations of the Takings Clause. We AFFIRM.
    ANDREW J. PINCUS (Timothy Bishop (Chicago),
    Reginald R. Goeke (Washington D.C.), Robert
    William Hamburg (New York City), on the brief),
    Mayer Brown LLP, for Plaintiffs-Appellants.
    ESTER MURDUKHAYEVA, Deputy Solicitor General
    for the State of New York, Letitia James, Attorney
    General for the State of New York, Barbara D.
    Underwood, Solicitor General, Steven C. Wu,
    Deputy Solicitor General, Caroline A. Olsen,
    Assistant Solicitor General, Of Counsel, New York,
    N.Y., for Defendant-Appellee RuthAnne Visnauskas,
    CLAUDE S. PLATTON, Assistant Corporation Counsel
    for the City of New York, James E. Johnson,
    Corporation Counsel for the City of New York,
    Richard Dearing, Jesse A. Townsend, Of Counsel,
    2
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    New York, N.Y., for Defendants-Appellees City of
    New York, Rent Guidelines Board, David Reiss, Arpit
    Gupta, Alex Schwarz, Christian Gonzalez-Rivera,
    Christina DeRose, Robert Ehrlich, Christina Smyth, ,
    Sheila Garcia, Adán Soltren, RuthAnne Visnauskas,
    CAITLIN J. HALLIGAN (Sean P. Baldwin, Michael
    Duke, Babak Ghafarzade, Sophie Lipman, on the
    brief, Selendy & Gay PLLC), for Intervenors.
    BARRINGTON D. PARKER, Circuit Judge:
    The New York City Rent Stabilization Law (“RSL”) was first enacted in 1969
    as part of a decades-long legislative effort to address the myriad problems
    resulting from a chronic shortage of affordable housing in the City. The RSL is
    designed to prevent excessive rent levels and to ensure that property owners can
    earn a reasonable return by, among other things, capping rent increases and
    limiting the legal grounds for evictions. Over time, however, the Legislature has
    amended the law in response to changing political and economic conditions.
    Sometimes the statute has provided stronger protections for tenants and at other
    times for property owners. The RSL was most recently amended by the Housing
    Stability and Tenant Protection Act of 2019 (“HSTPA”). The constitutionality of
    this amendment and of the RSL as amended are the subject of this appeal.
    3
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    The Appellants (the “Landlords”) are individual property owners and not-
    for-profit trade associations whose members include managing agents and
    property owners of both rent-stabilized and non-rent-stabilized properties. They
    sued to invalidate the RSL and the HSTPA on the grounds that their provisions
    are unconstitutional because they, facially, effect a physical as well as a regulatory
    taking in violation of the Fifth Amendment. The Landlords further claim that the
    RSL and New York City’s 2018 emergency declaration triggering rent stabilization
    are irrational in violation of the Substantive Due Process Clause of the Fourteenth
    Amendment. The United States District Court for the Eastern District of New York
    (Komitee, J.) held that the RSL was constitutional and dismissed the Complaint.
    See FED. R. CIV. P. 12(b)(6). This appeal followed.
    BACKGROUND
    In an entirely unregulated market, rent levels are governed solely by the law
    of supply and demand. 1 See Brief for Nat’l Ass’n of Realtors as Amicus Curiae at 19.
    Such a market, however, can be unforgiving. It has little regard for the
    consequences it produces, whether they are inadequate returns on investment,
    1The history of rent stabilization discussed here constitutes a matter of public record of
    which we are entitled to take judicial notice. See Caha v. United States, 
    152 U.S. 211
    , 222,
    (1894). Since this history is not part of the underlying Complaint, it does not form the
    basis of our Fed. R. 12(b)(6) analysis.
    4
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    exorbitant rents, housing shortages, deteriorating housing stock, or homelessness.
    To address these problems, the City, State, and federal governments have, over
    the past century, regulated the New York City rental market.
    The City’s first rent regulations were passed in response to severe housing
    shortages around the time of World War I. 2 The war caused new construction to
    fall and rents to soar. 3 In response, renters organized rent strikes, and escalating
    confrontations between landlords and tenants ensued. 4 Ultimately, the State
    Legislature stepped in and passed the City’s first rent control program in 1920,
    which capped rent increases and prevented evictions without cause. 5 The regime,
    which expired after ten years, was the subject of ongoing litigation. 6 The housing
    2 Robert M. Fogelson, The Great Rent Wars: New York, 1917–1929 18 (2013).
    3 Robert W. De Forest & Lawrence Veiller, The Tenement House Problem 369 (1903);
    “Workmen Need Homes,” New York Times, June 9, 1918 at R92.
    4 See e.g., Woman Accused of Calling Tenants in Apartment ‘Scabs,’” New York Times, July
    18, 1919 at 6; “20,000 Organize for Rent Strike,” New York Times, April 24, 1920 at 1; “The
    Threatened Rent Strike,” New York Times, April 28, 1920 at 10; “4,500 Bronx Tenants Go
    on Rent ‘Strike,’” New York Times, Dec. 3, 1920 at 2.
    5 See e.g., “Mayor Supports Rent Control Bill,” New York Times, Mar. 11, 1920 at 17; “1,800
    Go To Albany for Rent Fight,” New York Times, Mar. 23, 1920 at 3; “Rent Laws in Practice,”
    New York Times, April 9, 1920 at 12.
    6 See, e.g., “Testing the Rent Laws,” New York Times, Oct. 21, 1920 at 11.
    5
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    problems responsible for the legislation and the litigation abated somewhat as a
    consequence of a resurgence of housing construction in the mid-1920s. 7
    The next regime of rent control was enacted by the federal government. In
    1942, President Franklin D. Roosevelt signed into law the Emergency Price Control
    Act (EPCA). 8 The EPCA was passed in response to inflationary pressures brought
    about in part by World War II and created a nationwide system of price controls.
    The law froze New York City rents at 1943 levels for several years until Congress
    allowed it to expire, replacing it with the Federal Housing and Rent Act of 1947.9
    Under that statute, buildings constructed after February 1, 1947, were exempted
    from controls while older buildings remained covered.
    A few years later, Congress passed the 1949 Federal Housing Act, which
    permitted States to take control of rent regulation. 10 Then, in 1950, New York
    created the Temporary State Housing Rent Commission, which regulated
    landlord-tenant relationships—including over 2 million rental units in the City. 11
    7  See e.g., “Building Revival Breaking Records,” New York Times, July 16, 1922 at R1.
    “Housing Crisis Over, Surplus of Homes, Realty Men Argue,” New York Times, Oct. 18,
    1923 at 1; Final Report of the Joint Legislative Committee on Housing, 1923 at Ch. 1-6.
    8 See 
    56 Stat. 23
     (repealed 1947).
    9 Pub. L. No. 129, 80th Cong., 1st Sess. (June 30, 1946).
    10 Pub. L. No. 171, 81st Cong., 1st Sess. (July 15, 1949).
    11 Morton J. Schussheim, High Rent Housing and Rent Control in New York City (Apr.
    1958).
    6
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    Those regulations touched upon, among other things, rent levels and legal
    grounds for evictions.
    The City’s modern regime of rent regulations was introduced in 1969 by the
    RSL. The RSL established the Rent Guidelines Board (“RGB”)—an official body
    whose members represent the interests of landlords, tenants, and the public—
    which was charged with setting the amounts by which rents could be increased. 12
    In carrying out this function, the RGB was obligated to consider the economic
    condition of the housing market, certain costs for which landlords were
    responsible, the returns generated to landlords, the housing supply, and increases
    to the cost of living. 13
    The RSL has been amended several times. In 1971, for example, the State
    passed the Emergency Tenant Protection Act (“ETPA”), which permits the City to
    renew the protections of the RSL when it declares a “housing emergency” based
    upon a set of statutory criteria. N.Y. Unconsol. Law tit. 23 8623.a (McKinney).
    Later, in the 1980s, tenants’ protections were extended to their successors. 14 In
    12 23 
    N.Y. Unconsol. Laws § 26-510
    (a).
    13 23 
    N.Y. Unconsol. Laws § 26-510
    (b).
    14 9 NYCRR 2520.6 (1987).
    7
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    1993, the law was again amended to permit the deregulation of apartments that
    either housed high-income tenants or became vacant. 15
    Recently, the RSL was amended by the HSTPA, 16 which was passed in
    “response to an ongoing housing shortage crisis, as evidenced by an extremely
    low vacancy rate” that caused tenants to “struggle to secure safe, affordable
    housing” and municipalities to “struggle to protect their regulated housing stock.”
    Sponsor’s Mem., 2019 N.Y. Laws ch. 36. The HSTPA limited landlords’ capacity to
    charge excess rent attributed to major capital improvements and individual
    apartment improvements. See 2019 N.Y. Laws ch. 36, Part K. The law repealed
    vacancy decontrol and high-income decontrol, which had removed units from
    regulation when the rent or tenant’s income reached a specified level. The law also
    repealed certain vacancy and longevity increases, which had permitted landlords
    to raise rents above the otherwise allowable amounts if a unit became vacant or if
    a tenant had remained in place for an extended period. See 
    id.,
     Parts B & D. In
    addition, the law limits landlords to recovering one rent-stabilized unit per
    building for personal use upon a showing of necessity, with additional restrictions
    15   See generally Roberts v. Tishman Speyer Props., 
    13 N.Y.3d 270
    , 279 (2009).
    16   2019 N.Y. Laws ch. 36, available at https://perma.cc/TH4B5WNQ.
    8
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    when the affected tenant is a senior citizen or disabled. See 
    id.,
     Part I. These
    amendments are the main subject of this appeal.
    This regulatory regime has all along been the subject of sharp
    disagreements: landlords believed that their investment returns were too low and
    that they retained too little control over their properties while tenants believed that
    their rents were too high. Landlords in particular have consistently contended the
    regulations impeded their ability collect sufficient rents to fund required
    maintenance and improvements and to generate reasonable investment returns.
    Landlords have consistently contended that the RSL has failed to achieve its stated
    goal of increasing the availability of housing to low- and moderate-income
    residents. 17
    The Appellees, on the other hand, contend that the RSL did not go far
    enough to enable people of modest incomes to live in the City.18 They further
    contend that in enacting the RSL, New York’s elected representatives were well
    aware of the role that rent stabilized housing played in increasing the supply of
    apartments for low- and moderate-income residents and reducing community
    17 See, e.g., Brief for Nat’l Apt. Ass’n and Nat’l Multifamily Hous. Council as Amicus Curiae
    23.
    18 See, e.g., Brief for Nat’l Hous. Law Project et al. as Amicus Curiae 12.
    9
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    disruption resulting from frequent turnover, tenant dislocation, and eviction.
    These RSL protections, they argue, enable families to establish long-term homes
    and, in turn, allow neighborhoods to flourish. 19
    The City contends that the vast majority of those who benefit from rent
    stabilization are low- and middle-income people. In 2016, the median income for
    rent stabilized households was $44,560, one third lower than the median income
    for private, non-regulated households. 20 Of the city’s 946,000 rent stabilized
    apartments, 189,000 units (20%) were occupied by families living below the
    poverty line. And more than 600,000 units (64%) were occupied by families who
    qualify under HUD classifications as low-income, very low-income, or extremely
    low-income. Eliminating rent stabilization, the Appellees contend, would
    undoubtedly result in a surge of homelessness. It would also result in a dynamic
    whereby large swaths of essential workers who help maintain our vibrant City,
    19 The Appellees argue that “[i]f the rent-regulated housing stock in New York continues
    to diminish, the homeless population will grow to unimagined levels . . . [and the]
    elimination of the rent laws would lead to a wave of evictions and homelessness unseen
    in New York since the Great Depression.” Testimony of The Coalition for the Homeless
    before the NY State Assembly Committee on Housing, January 2011, available at
    https://www.coalitionforthehomeless.org/wp-
    content/uploads/2014/07/TestimonyRentRegulationJan202011.pdf.
    20 N.Y.C. Dep’t of Hous. Pres. & Dev., Sociodemographics of Rent Stabilized Tenants 4
    (2018), available at
    https://www1.nyc.gov/assets/hpd/downloads/pdfs/services/rent-regulation-memo-
    1.pdf
    10
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    including police officers, teachers, healthcare workers, and emergency service
    personnel, would be unable to afford to live here.21 See generally Brief of District
    Council 37 as Amicus Curiae. Who has the better of these arguments is not an issue
    on this appeal.
    Throughout its life, this regulatory regime has been the subject of continual
    attention in the State and City Legislatures. This is hardly surprising. Striking an
    appropriate balance between the sharply diverging interests of landlords and
    tenants involves negotiation and compromise over a very long list of complicated
    and difficult questions. Resolving such questions is a quintessential function of a
    legislature. At the end of the day, it is highly probable—indeed, virtually certain—
    that no interested party will be entirely satisfied by what the legislature does.
    Rent regulation in the City has also been the subject of decades of litigation.
    Property owners have challenged New York rent control and stabilization
    regulations on a host of grounds, contending that it violates the Takings Clause,
    21The City also argues that while sudden rent increases of any size can be difficult to
    absorb for tenants across income levels, even a minimal increase can be catastrophic for
    low-income tenants. In recent years, approximately 175,000 households in rent stabilized
    housing were unable to afford even a $25 increase in their monthly rent. The State and
    City Legislatures determined that the RSL helps guard against the dislocation of
    hundreds of thousands of New Yorkers. See Oksana Mironova, Testimony: NYC Needs a
    Rent     Freeze,   Cmty.      Serv.    Soc’y    (May     5,   2020),     available     at
    https://www.cssny.org/news/entry/testimony-nyc-rgb-rent-freeze.
    11
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    the Contracts Clause, the Equal Protection Clause, and the Due Process Clause. See
    Harmon v. Markus, 
    412 F. App’x 420
     (2d Cir. 2011); W. 95 Hous. Corp v. N.Y.C. Dep’t
    of Hous. Pres. & Dev., 
    31 F. App’x 19
     (2d Cir. 2002); Fed. Home Loan Mortg. Corp. v.
    New York State Div. of Hous. & Cmty. Renewal, 
    83 F.3d 45
     (2d Cir. 1996); Rent
    Stabilization Ass’n of City of New York v. Dinkins, 
    5 F.3d 591
     (2d Cir. 1993); Greystone
    Hotel Co. v. City of New York, 
    13 F. Supp. 2d 524
     (S.D.N.Y. 1998); Silberman v.
    Biderman, 
    735 F. Supp. 1138
     (E.D.N.Y. 1990); Tonwal Realties, Inc. v. Beame, 
    406 F. Supp. 363
     (S.D.N.Y. 1976); Somerset-Wilshire Apts., Inc. v. Lindsay, 
    304 F.Supp. 273
    (S.D.N.Y. 1969); Rent Stabilization Ass’n of New York City, Inc. v. Higgins, 
    83 N.Y.2d 156
     (1993); Teeval Co. v. Stern, 
    301 N.Y. 34
     (1950). Each of these challenges failed.
    PROCEDURAL HISTORY
    After the passage of the HSTPA, the Landlords sued the Appellees in the
    United States District Court for the Eastern District of New York. They alleged that
    the newly amended RSL effected, facially, a physical as well as a regulatory taking
    and that it violated the Fourteenth Amendment’s Due Process Clause. While the
    Landlords initially raised facial and as-applied claims, the latter were abandoned.
    Therefore, the only claims that remain are facial challenges. A companion case, 74
    Pinehurst LLC v. New York, addresses as-applied claims brought by other landlords.
    12
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    An opinion deciding that case also issues today. The defendants moved under
    Rule 12(b)(6) to dismiss the Complaint, and Judge Komitee granted the motion in
    a thorough and well-reasoned opinion. The court held that a physical taking
    occurs when there is a deprivation of the “entire bundle of property rights” in the
    property interest in question. That bundle includes the “rights to possess, use and
    dispose of [the property].” Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New
    York, 
    492 F. Supp. 3d 33
    , 43 (E.D.N.Y. 2020). The court reasoned that because the
    RSL restricts only the plaintiffs’ right to use the property—but not to possess or
    dispose of it—the claims failed to make out a physical taking.
    The court next turned to the substantial difficulties associated with facial
    regulatory takings challenges. It observed that the Landlords were unable to
    identify a case where a facial challenge to rent-control-related legislation had
    succeeded. The court acknowledged the possibility that the RSL could effect an as-
    applied regulatory taking, but noted that “it is unlikely that [it] will be identified
    in the context of a facial challenge.” 
    Id. at 45
    .
    Next, applying factors set forth in Penn Central Transp. Co. v. City of New
    York, 
    438 U.S. 104
    , 124 (1978)—economic impact, interference with investment-
    backed expectations, and character of the governmental action—the court
    13
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    dismissed the facial regulatory takings claim. It reasoned that the Landlords had
    not demonstrated that the RSL was unconstitutional in all of its applications. This
    appeal followed. We review de novo the district court’s dismissal for failure to state
    a claim under Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6).
    DISCUSSION
    I
    A
    The Landlords have leveled a facial challenge to the RSL. To prevail on a
    facial challenge, the plaintiff must “establish that no set of circumstances exists
    under which the [challenged] Act would be valid.” United States v. Salerno, 
    481 U.S. 739
    , 745 (1987). In other words, the plaintiff must show that the statute “is
    unconstitutional in all of its applications.” Wash. State Grange v. Wash. State Rep.
    Party, 
    552 U.S. 442
    , 449 (2008). Facial challenges to the RSL have regularly fallen
    short of this high bar. See, e.g., Rent Stabilization Ass’n v. Dinkins, 5 F.3d at 595; W.
    95 Hous. Corp., 31 F. App’x at 21. The Landlords suggest, however, that this is no
    longer the correct standard to apply to the facial challenges they bring. They
    contend that, instead of applying Salerno’s well-established standard, this Court
    should utilize one of two more lenient approaches to striking down statutes on a
    facial challenge. We disagree.
    14
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    They first argue that because “‘[t]he proper focus of the constitutional
    inquiry is the group for whom the law is a restriction, not the group for whom the
    law is irrelevant,’” the facial challenge should focus on the law’s effect on only
    those landlords who wish not to comply with its strictures. Appellants’ Br. at 35
    (quoting City of Los Angeles v. Patel, 
    576 U.S. 409
    , 418 (2015)). A close reading of
    Patel makes clear that, when the Supreme Court referenced “the group for whom
    the law is a restriction,” it meant those to whom the law actually applies, not those
    for whom it has no plausible application—that is, those for whom the law is
    “irrelevant.” Patel, 576 U.S. at 419.
    In Patel, the Supreme Court considered a facial challenge to a statute
    authorizing certain warrantless searches. Id. at 417. In response to the challenge,
    the City cited situations in which a warrant was not required under already
    established law: that is, “situations where police are responding to an emergency,
    where the subject of the search consents to the intrusion, and where police are
    acting under a court-ordered warrant.” Id. at 417–18. It argued that those situations
    showed that a warrantless search was permissible in some circumstances, and so
    the   new      law    permitting       certain    warrantless   searches   could   not   be
    “unconstitutional in all of its applications,” as Salerno required. Id. The Court
    15
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    rejected this argument, reasoning that when faced with exigent circumstances or
    a court-ordered warrant, “the subject of the search must permit it to proceed
    irrespective of whether it is authorized by statute.” Id. at 418–19. The Court
    distinguished the City’s examples as “irrelevant to our analysis because they do
    not involve actual applications of the statute.” Id. at 419. Thus, by defining the
    focus of a facial challenge as resting on its effect on those “for whom the law is a
    restriction,” the Supreme Court merely clarified that facial challenges to a statute
    must establish its unconstitutionality in all “applications of the statute in which it
    actually authorizes or prohibits conduct.” Id. at 418 (emphasis added). The Court’s
    decision in Patel, therefore, only clarified the scope of Salerno’s standard for facial
    challenges. It did not reject or relax the Salerno standard.
    As a separate basis for avoiding the rigors of Salerno, the Landlords rely on
    United States v. Stevens, 
    559 U.S. 460
     (2010), arguing that to succeed on their facial
    challenge, they need only establish either “‘that no set of circumstances exists
    under which [the statute] would be valid, or that the statute lacks any plainly
    legitimate sweep.’” Appellants’ Br. at 35 (quoting Stevens, 
    559 U.S. at 472
    )
    (emphasis in brief). The Landlords contend that, in its use of the phrase “plainly
    legitimate sweep,” the Stevens Court held that a facial challenge in any legal
    16
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    domain can succeed by meeting either one of these two standards. Again, we are
    not persuaded.
    In Stevens, a criminal defendant challenged the statute of his conviction—
    criminalizing the creation, sale, or possession of depictions of animal cruelty—as
    facially invalid under the First Amendment. 
    559 U.S. at
    464–65, 467. But in
    assessing the challenge, the Supreme Court stated that the choice between the two
    standards under discussion (valid in “no set of circumstances” or “lacking any
    plainly legitimate sweep”) was “a matter of dispute that we need not and do not
    address.” 
    Id. at 472
    . Thus, it did no more than recognize that “[i]n the First
    Amendment context,” it has determined that “a law may be invalidated as
    overbroad if ‘a substantial number of its applications are unconstitutional, judged
    in relation to the statute’s plainly legitimate sweep.’” 
    Id. at 472
     (quoting Wash. State
    Grange, 
    552 U.S. at
    449 n.6).
    We understand Stevens, then, not as rejecting Salerno’s demanding
    standards for facial challenges generally, but as reinforcing the principles that (i)
    Salerno provides the prevailing standard for facial challenges to statutes outside
    the context of the First Amendment, and (ii) a different, more challenge-friendly
    standard has developed in the context of statutes affecting First Amendment
    17
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    rights. Neither Stevens nor any other case the Landlords cite has applied this
    relaxed standard outside of the First Amendment context, nor supports its
    extension beyond that setting. Indeed, in observing that “[f]acial challenges are
    disfavored for several reasons,” the Supreme Court reminded us that “facial
    challenges threaten to short circuit the democratic process by preventing laws
    embodying the will of the people from being implemented in a manner consistent
    with the Constitution.” Wash. State Grange, 
    552 U.S. at 451
    . Especially where, as
    here in the rent stabilization context, the regulatory regime at issue has both
    persisted and been adjusted over time, reflecting finely tuned, legislative
    judgments, we must exercise caution in entertaining facial challenges. Neither
    Patel nor Stevens, thus, lower the high bar the Landlords must satisfy to assert a
    facial challenge.
    B
    The Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment provides that “private
    property [shall not] be taken for public use, without just compensation.” U.S.
    Const. amends. V, XIV, § 1. That requirement applies to all physical appropriations
    of property by the government. See Horne v. Dep’t of Agriculture, 
    576 U.S. 350
    , 360
    (2015). When the government effects a physical appropriation of private property
    18
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    for itself or another—whether by law, regulation, or another means—a per se
    physical taking has occurred. Cedar Point Nursery v. Hassid, 
    141 S. Ct. 2063
    , 2071
    (2021). Examples of physical takings include using eminent domain to condemn
    property, see United States v. General Motors Corp., 
    323 U.S. 373
    , 374–75 (1945);
    taking possession of property without taking title to it, see United States v. Pewee
    Coal Co., 
    341 U.S. 114
    , 115–17 (1951); and occupying property by, for example,
    building a dam that causes recurring flooding, see United States v. Cress, 
    243 U.S. 316
    , 327–28 (1917).
    The Supreme Court has, over the years, considered various Takings Clause
    challenges to government actions. See e.g., Griggs v. Allegheny Cnty., Pa., 
    369 U.S. 84
     (1962); Nollan v. California Coastal Comm’n, 
    483 U.S. 825
     (1987); Arkansas Game &
    Fish Comm’n v. United States, 
    568 U.S. 23
     (2012). In Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan
    CATV Corp., 
    458 U.S. 419
     (1982), the Supreme Court considered a statute requiring
    landlords to permit cable companies to install equipment on the landlords’
    properties. The Court held that such a mandatory invasion amounted to a
    permanent physical occupation by a third party—the cable companies—of the
    landlords’ properties and was therefore a per se physical taking. In addition, the
    19
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    Court concluded that such a physical occupation deprived landlords of the entire
    “bundle of rights” associated with owning property. 
    Id. at 435
    .
    A decade later, in Yee v. City of Escondido, 
    503 U.S. 519
     (1992), the Court
    declined to apply to this logic to rent-control laws and rejected a Takings Clause
    challenge. Yee involved a mobile-home rent control ordinance that set rent at
    below-market rates. The Court held that the ordinance—even considered in
    conjunction with other state laws effectively permitting tenants to remain at will—
    was not a physical taking. It reasoned that the statutes did not facially require
    landlords to rent their properties in perpetuity because evictions were permitted
    in some conditions, 
    id. at 528
    , and because the “tenants were invited by petitioners,
    not forced upon them by the government,” 
    id.
     The Court further noted that States
    have wide latitude to regulate the landlord-tenant relationship, such as by placing
    “ceilings on the rents the landowner can charge or requiring the landowner to
    accept tenants he does not like.” 
    Id. at 529
     (cleaned up).
    In Horne, in contrast, the Court found that a physical taking had occurred.
    In that case the Court considered a challenge to a Department of Agriculture
    marketing order requiring raisin growers to hand over a percentage of their crop
    to the government. 576 U.S. at 350. The Court held that the statute effected a
    20
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    physical taking because raisins are physically transferred from the growers to the
    government and title is passed, thereby depriving owners of the entire bundle of
    rights to their property. Id. at 361. The Court also held that the government cannot
    condition a party’s permission to engage in interstate commerce on complying
    with a regulation that effects a physical taking. Id. at 364–67.
    Most recently, in Cedar Point the Court evaluated a regulation granting labor
    organizations the “right to take access” to an agricultural employer’s property for
    up to 120 days a year to solicit support for unionization. 141 S. Ct. at 2069. The
    Court held that because the regulation granted a right to invade the grower’s
    property it amounted to a per se physical taking. Id. at 2072. Cedar Point, however,
    emphasized that “[l]imitations on how a business generally open to the public may
    treat individuals … are readily distinguishable from regulations granting a right
    to invade property closed to the public.” Id. at 2076–77.
    Our court has also considered various Takings Clause challenges to
    regulations, including some to earlier versions of New York’s RSL. See, e.g.,
    Southview Assocs., Ltd. v. Bongartz, 
    980 F.2d 84
    , 94–95 (2d Cir. 1992) (finding that
    denying a land use permit did not constitute a physical taking); Fed. Home Loan
    Mortg. Corp., 
    83 F.3d at 48
     (finding application of rent stabilization laws to a
    21
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    previously exempt building did not violate the Takings Clause); Harmon, 412 F.
    App’x at 422 (holding City’s rent stabilization law did not effect a permanent
    physical occupation of a landlords’ property in violation of Takings Clause).
    B
    Applying these principles, we conclude that no provision of the RSL effects,
    facially, a physical occupation of the Landlords’ properties. In Cedar Point, the
    Court held that the government may effect a physical occupation of property by
    granting a third party the right to invade “property closed to the public.” 141 S.
    Ct. at 2077. 22 That has not occurred here. Rather, the Landlords voluntarily invited
    third parties to use their properties, and as the Court explained in Cedar Point,
    regulations concerning such properties are “readily distinguishable” from those
    compelling invasions of properties closed to the public. Id. As the Supreme Court
    made pellucid in Yee, when, as here, “a landowner decides to rent his land to
    tenants” the States “have broad power to regulate housing conditions in general
    and the landlord-tenant relationship in particular without paying compensation
    22We reject Appellants’ reliance on the Supreme Court’s per curiam opinion in Pakdel v.
    City and County of San Francisco, 
    141 S. Ct. 2226 (2021)
    . There, the district court had ruled
    on the merits of physical takings claims prior to the Supreme Court’s ruling in Cedar Point
    Nursery, and therefore the Court in remanding the case merely stated that the Ninth
    Circuit “may give further consideration to these claims in light of [the] recent decision in
    Cedar Point Nursery v. Hassid.” 141 S. Ct. at 2229 n. 1. That directive is of no moment here.
    22
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    for all economic injuries that such regulation entails.” 
    503 U.S. at
    528–29; see also
    Loretto, 
    458 U.S. at 440
     (“This Court has consistently affirmed that States have
    broad power to regulate housing conditions in general and the landlord-tenant
    relationship in particular without paying compensation for all economic injuries
    that such regulation entails.”); Home Building & Loan Ass’n v. Blaisdell, 
    290 U.S. 398
    (1934); Edgar A. Levy Leasing Co. v. Siegel, 
    258 U.S. 242
     (1922). The numerous cases
    that affirm the validity of rent control statutes are the necessary result of this long
    line of consistent authority. See, e.g., Bowles v. Willingham, 
    321 U.S. 503
     (1944); Block
    v. Hirsh, 
    256 U.S. 135
     (1921).
    Nor does the RSL compel the Landlords “to refrain in perpetuity from
    terminating a tenancy.” Yee, 
    503 U.S. at 528
    . The statute sets forth several grounds
    on which a landlord may terminate a lease. These include failing to pay rent,
    creating a nuisance, violating provisions of the lease, or using the property for
    illegal purposes. 9 NYCRR § 2524.3. It is well settled that limitations on the
    termination of a tenancy do not effect a taking so long as there is a possible route
    to an eviction. Cf. Yee, 
    503 U.S. at 528
     (concluding that a statute requiring that
    evictions be given with 6- or 12-months’ notice is not a compelled physical
    invasion in violation of the Takings Clause); Harmon, 412 F. App’x at 422 (finding
    23
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    New York’s rental stabilization law at the time did not give rise to a physical taking
    partially because the landlords retained the right to “evict an unsatisfactory
    tenant”); Higgins, 
    83 N.Y.2d at 172
     (family succession amendments to rent control
    and rent stabilization regulations did not effect unconstitutional taking where
    owner’s right to evict unsatisfactory tenant was not altered); Elmsford Apartment
    Assocs., LLC v. Cuomo, 
    469 F. Supp. 3d 148
    , 163 (S.D.N.Y. 2020) (finding that a
    temporary halt on evictions did not amount to a physical taking). 23
    All in all, as with previous versions, the RSL “regulates land use rather than
    effecting a physical occupation.” W. 95 Hous. Corp., 31 F. App’x at 21. The caselaw
    is exceptionally clear that legislatures enjoy broad authority to regulate land use
    without running afoul of the Fifth Amendment’s bar on physical takings. See Yee,
    
    503 U.S. at 527
    .
    C
    The Landlords contend that the RSL effects, facially, a physical taking
    because it requires them to offer tenants renewal leases, interferes with their ability
    to evict tenants and reclaim units for personal use, and allows tenancies to be
    23Because we conclude that the Landlords have not been deprived of their right to
    exclude, we agree with the District Court that they have not been deprived of their “entire
    bundle of rights” in their properties.
    24
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    transferred to successors. These provisions, according to the Landlords, amount to
    a permanent physical occupation compelled by the government.
    We disagree. None of these provisions involve unconditional requirements
    imposed by the legislature. Landlords, instead, must adhere to these provisions
    only when certain conditions are met. Consider, for example, the statute’s
    successorship provisions. No tenant enjoys an unfettered right to transfer tenancy
    rights to a successor. Instead, the successor must meet a host of requirements, such
    as, for example, being a member of the tenant’s family who has already lived in
    the apartment for two years. What is more, even assuming arguendo that the
    successorship provisions do unconditionally require landlords to rent to uninvited
    successors, that would deprive the Landlords only of the ability to decide who their
    incoming tenants are. That limitation, as the Supreme Court has recognized, has
    “nothing to do with whether [a law or regulation] causes a physical taking.” 
    Id.
     at
    530–31.
    Furthermore, none of the caselaw on which the Landlords rely lends any
    appreciable support to their contention that the RSL effects, facially, a physical
    taking. The Landlords’ reliance on Loretto, Horne, and Cedar Point, their main
    authority, is misplaced for a common reason: None of them concerns a statute that
    25
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    regulates the landlord-tenant relationship, and none restricts—much less
    upends—the State’s longstanding authority to regulate that relationship. 24
    Moreover, Yee, the only case on which the Landlords rely that does involve
    a statute regulating the landlord-tenant relationship, confirms our conclusion. Yee,
    as noted, involved a facial challenge to rent control statutes that limited owners’
    ability to terminate tenancies where the initial tenant had transferred her rights to
    another. 
    503 U.S. at
    523–24. Like the Landlords here, the petitioners argued that
    the law effectively forced property owners to rent the property out to these
    individuals and prevented owners from changing the use of their property. The
    Court upheld the law because it merely limited—but did not bar—an owners’
    ability to do both of these things. 
    Id.
     at 527–28. The same is true here.
    II
    The Landlords also mount a facial regulatory taking challenge to the RSL.
    Legislation effects a regulatory taking when it goes “too far” in restricting a
    landowner’s ability to use his own property. Horne, 576 U.S. at 360; Yee, 503 U.S. at
    24Nor is the Landlords’ position supported by their reliance on Horne for the proposition
    that the “voluntary participation in the market [cannot] excuse or absolve the government
    of liability for a taking.” Like the District Court, we reject Appellants’ claims not because
    we conclude that they have acquiesced in a physical taking, but because “no physical
    taking has occurred in the first place.”
    26
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    529; Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 
    260 U.S. 393
    , 415 (1922). In determining
    whether a use restriction effects a taking, we apply the balancing test set out in
    Penn Central Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 
    438 U.S. 104
     (1978), a case involving a
    challenge to New York City’s historical preservation law, N.Y.C. Admin. Code, ch.
    8–A, § 205–1.0 et seq. (1976). 25
    Penn Central instructs courts to engage in a flexible, “ad hoc, factual
    inquir[y]” focused on “several factors that have particular significance.” 
    438 U.S. at 124
    . Three of them are: (1) “the economic impact of the regulation on the
    claimant,” (2) “the extent to which the regulation has interfered with distinct
    investment-backed expectations,” and (3) “the character of the governmental
    action.” 
    Id.
     The Landlords assert that, taken together, these factors support their
    characterization of the RSL as a facial regulatory taking. We disagree.
    25We are unpersuaded by the Landlords’ argument that the appropriate standard under
    which to determine whether a taking has occurred comes from a dissent in Pennell v. City
    of San Jose, 
    485 U.S. 1
     (1988). As we have noted, “Justice Scalia’s [Pennell] dissent was just
    that; a majority of the Supreme Court has yet to adopt Justice Scalia’s reasoning.” Garelick
    v. Sullivan, 
    987 F.2d 913
    , 918 (2d Cir. 1993). This dissent, we have pointed out, is “in
    tension (if not conflict) with well established Fifth Amendment doctrine granting
    government broad power to determine the proper subjects of and purposes for regulatory
    schemes.” 
    Id.
     Accordingly, we decline to employ a test that has never been adopted by
    the Supreme Court.
    27
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    As to the economic impact of the regulation, the Landlords contend that the
    RSL has a direct and substantial negative economic impact on rent-stabilized
    properties in New York City because stabilized rents are on average 25% lower
    than market rents and permissible rent increases are outpaced by increases in
    operating costs. In short, the Landlords contend that the RSL forces property
    owners to choose between making losing investments or letting their properties
    deteriorate. They allege that rent-stabilized properties are worth 25% to 50% less
    than similar properties with market-rate units.
    The RSL may well have an appreciable economic impact on the profitability
    of some buildings subject to its provisions. When permissible rent increases are
    outpaced by operating cost increases, the result may be a reduction or, in some
    cases, the elimination of net operating income. We acknowledge that some
    property owners may be legitimately aggrieved by the diminished value of their
    rent-stabilized properties as compared with their market-rate units. Furthermore,
    we understand that many economists argue that rent control laws are an inefficient
    way of ensuring a supply of affordable housing. But while legislative judgments
    may take into account these varying policy perspectives, we are bound to follow
    the standard set forth for a facial regulatory taking under Penn Central. Appellants
    28
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    have simply not plausibly alleged that every owner of a rent-stabilized property
    has suffered an adverse economic impact that would support their facial
    regulatory takings claims. Thus, Appellants did not plausibly allege the economic
    impact factor on a facial basis, and this factor thus weighs against the conclusion
    that the RSL effects a regulatory taking on its face.
    Instead of alleging that every landlord has suffered an adverse economic
    impact, the Landlords principally rely on data purporting to show the average
    economic effects of the RSL. But these effects do not establish that the RSL can
    never be applied constitutionally, which is the requirement for a facial challenge.
    As the Supreme Court stated in Concrete Pipe & Prods. of Cal., the “mere diminution
    in the value of property, however serious, is insufficient to demonstrate a taking.”
    Concrete Pipe & Prods. of Cal. v. Constr. Laborers Pension Tr., 
    508 U.S. 602
    , 645 (1993);
    see also Park Ave. Tower Assocs. v. City of New York, 
    746 F.2d 135
    , 139–40 (2d Cir.
    1984) (collecting cases rejecting takings claims where property value declined by
    75% to 90%). We therefore conclude that the economic impact factor of the Penn
    Central analysis does not support the Landlords.
    With respect to the Landlords’ investment-backed expectations, once again,
    we can assume arguendo that some property owners may have had their
    29
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    investment-backed expectations thwarted by the current iteration of the RSL.
    Thus, we may assume some property owners may not have expected, for example,
    that the 2019 RSL would eliminate the possibility of preferential rent increases or
    sunset provisions. However, the Landlords have failed to establish that the RSL
    interferes with every property owner’s investment-backed expectations, which is
    required on a facial challenge, because such expectations can be assessed only on
    a case-by-case basis.
    Different landlords, who purchased properties at different times and under
    different RSL regimes, will necessarily have a range of differing expectations.
    Some may have been aggrieved by various provisions of the RSL, while others
    may not have been and, indeed, others may have seen the profitability of their
    investments rise. It is therefore impracticable to assess a class of owners’
    expectations without analysis on an individualized basis. Moreover, we must
    consider the reasonableness of alleged investment-backed expectations vis-à-vis
    those who can “demonstrate that they bought their property in reliance on a state
    of affairs that did not include the challenged regulatory regime.” Allen v. Cuomo,
    
    100 F.3d 253
    , 262 (2d Cir. 1996) (internal quotation marks omitted). We cannot
    make that analysis on a groupwide basis in a case where, as here, the challenged
    30
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    statute has been in place for half a century, and most, if not all, current landlords
    purchased their properties knowing they would be subject to the RSL. Given the
    RSL’s ever-changing requirements, no property owner could reasonably expect
    the continuation of any particular combination of RSL provisions. As the New
    York Court of Appeals has noted, “no party doing business in a regulated
    environment like the New York City rental market can expect the RSL to remain
    static.” Matter of Regina Metro. Co., LLC v. New York State Div. of Hous. & Cmty.
    Renewal, 
    35 N.Y.3d 332
    , 369 (2020). Accordingly, we conclude that the investment-
    backed expectations factor does not support the contention that the RSL has
    effected, facially, a regulatory taking.
    Turning to the character of the taking, a regulatory taking “may more
    readily be found when the interference with property can be characterized as a
    physical invasion by government.” Penn Central, 
    438 U.S. at 124
    . The Landlords
    argue that the RSL constitutes a physical invasion because it burdens property
    owners with non-removable tenants and, in so doing, eliminates landlords’ rights
    to determine the use of their property or to use it themselves. They contend that
    the RSL confers a local public assistance benefit on tenants that is inappropriately
    funded by a subset of New York City building owners rather than the government.
    31
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    We are not persuaded. The Supreme Court has instructed that in analyzing
    the “character” of the governmental action, courts should focus on the extent to
    which a regulation was “enacted solely for the benefit of private parties” as
    opposed to a legislative desire to serve “important public interests.” Keystone
    Bituminous Coal Ass’n v. DeBenedictis, 
    480 U.S. 470
    , 485–86 (1987). The character of
    the government action in Penn Central, for example, cut against a finding of a
    taking because the law was part of a “comprehensive plan to preserve structures
    of historic or aesthetic interest” and applied to hundreds of sites. 
    438 U.S. at 132
    .
    In reaching this conclusion, the Court relied on the “judgment of the New York
    City Council that the preservation of landmarks benefits all New York citizens and
    all structures, both economically and by improving the quality of life in the city as
    a whole.” 
    Id. at 134
    .
    Here too, the RSL is part of a comprehensive regulatory regime that governs
    nearly one million units. Like the broad public interests at issue in Penn Central,
    here, the legislature has determined that the RSL is necessary to prevent “serious
    threats to the public health, safety and general welfare.” N.Y.C. Admin. Code § 26-
    501. No one can seriously contend that these are not important public interests and
    courts are not in the business of second-guessing legislative determinations such
    32
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    as this one. The fact that the RSL affects landlords unevenly is of no moment
    because, as the Penn Central Court noted, “[l]egislation designed to promote the
    general welfare commonly burdens some more than others.” 
    438 U.S. at 133
    .
    Accordingly, the character of the regulation does not support the conclusion that
    the RSL effects a regulatory taking.
    Finally, the Landlords urge this Court to consider two additional, less
    commonly cited Penn Central factors that, they argue, tend to show that the RSL
    results in a regulatory taking: noxious use and a lack of a reciprocal advantage.
    Even assuming for the sake of argument that these factors apply, the claims fail.
    First, the Landlords assert that because the RSL does not address a safety
    issue or “noxious use” of a property, this factor supports the conclusion that a
    regulatory taking has occurred. This argument relies on a logical fallacy that
    because noxious use laws typically do not constitute takings, the RSL must be a
    taking because it does not govern noxious use. We have never held that only
    regulations of noxious uses can survive takings challenges. Merely because the
    existence of noxious use regulation can overcome a takings challenge does not
    mean that, conversely, the lack of noxious use regulation supports a takings
    challenge. Accordingly, this factor does not support the Landlords’ takings claim.
    33
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    The Landlords’ reliance on the “reciprocity of advantage” factor fares no
    better. Citing Justice Rehnquist’s dissent in Penn Central, they argue that the RSL
    effects a regulatory taking because the Fifth Amendment prohibits the placing of
    an inordinate share of a public burden on a private individual. With this argument,
    the Landlords urge us to read a dissent as providing us with governing law. We
    can’t do that. As the legislature has found, the RSL provides reciprocity of
    advantage: the RSL results in significant state- and citywide benefits—including
    to landlords—by preventing tenant dislocation and preserving neighborhood
    stability. Although what specific value a particular landlord receives from these
    benefits may be hard to quantify, that difficulty does not render the RSL a taking.
    As the Court said in Keystone Bituminous Coal Ass’n, “[t]he Takings Clause has
    never been read to require the States or the courts to calculate whether a specific
    individual has suffered burdens under this generic rule in excess of the benefits
    received.” 
    480 U.S. at
    491 n.21. Accordingly, a supposed lack of a reciprocal
    advantage does not render the RSL a regulatory taking.
    III
    Finally, the Landlords contend that they have plausibly alleged that the RSL
    and the 2018 City Council emergency declaration violate the Due Process Clause
    34
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    of the Fourteenth Amendment. Again, we disagree. The Landlords argue that the
    RSL is not “rationally related” to alleviating the housing shortage, securing
    housing for low-income residents, addressing rent profiteering, or promoting
    neighborhood stability. To the contrary, the Landlords say, the law reduces the
    housing supply, secures housing for the wealthy, increases rent for uncontrolled
    units, and discriminates in favor of tenants over owners. Supporting their view,
    the Landlords, as we have seen, point to various economists who argue that the
    RSL, in several respects, causes more harm than good.
    But as the Supreme Court has noted, the Due Process Clause cannot “do the
    work of the Takings Clause” because “where a particular Amendment provides
    an explicit textual source of constitutional protection against a particular sort of
    government behavior, that Amendment, not the more generalized notion of
    substantive due process, must be the guide for analyzing these claims.” Stop the
    Beach Renourishment, Inc. v. Fla. Dep’t of Envtl. Prot., 
    560 U.S. 702
    , 720–21 (2010)
    (cleaned up); see Albright v. Oliver, 
    510 U.S. 266
    , 273 (1994); Harmon, 412 F. App’x
    at 423. In any event, as the Court has noted, the liberties protected by due process
    “do not include economic liberties.” Stop the Beach, 560 U.S. at 721.
    35
    20-3366
    Community Housing Improvement Program v. City of New York
    Furthermore, even if a due process challenge were available, Appellants’
    arguments would still fail. In evaluating a due process challenge, we would
    conduct a rational-basis review, see Pennell, 
    485 U.S. at
    11–12, which requires a law
    to be “rationally related to legitimate government interests,” Washington v.
    Glucksberg, 
    521 U.S. 702
    , 728 (1997). A rational basis review is not a mechanism for
    judges to second guess legislative judgment even when, as here, they may conflict
    in part with the opinions of some experts. See, e.g., F.C.C. v. Breach Communications,
    Inc., 
    508 U.S. 307
    , 313–14 (1993) (“Where there are plausible reasons for Congress’
    action, our inquiry is at an end.”) (internal quotation marks omitted). Rather, it is
    a deferential standard that allows a law to survive if any of its justifications is valid.
    See Preseault v. I.C.C., 
    494 U.S. 1
    , 18 (1990). Here, the RSL was primarily enacted to
    permit low- and moderate-income people to reside in New York City when they
    otherwise could not afford to do so. See N.Y.C. Admin. Code § 26-501. It is beyond
    dispute that neighborhood continuity and stability are valid bases for enacting a
    law. See Nordlinger v. Hahn, 
    505 U.S. 1
    , 12 (1992). Appellants’ Due Process challenge
    thus fails.
    CONCLUSION
    For these reasons, we AFFIRM the judgment of the District Court.
    36