Lepages Inc v. MN Mining Mfg Co ( 2002 )


Menu:
  •                                                                                                                            Opinions of the United
    2002 Decisions                                                                                                             States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    1-16-2002
    Lepages Inc v. MN Mining Mfg Co
    Precedential or Non-Precedential:
    Docket 0-1368
    Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2002
    Recommended Citation
    "Lepages Inc v. MN Mining Mfg Co" (2002). 2002 Decisions. Paper 20.
    http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2002/20
    This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 2002 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
    Volume 1 of 2
    Filed January 14, 2002
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    Nos. 00-1368 and 00-1473
    LEPAGE'S INCORPORATED;
    LEPAGE'S MANAGEMENT COMPANY, LLC,
    Appellees/Cross-Appellants
    v.
    3M (MINNESOTA MINING AND MANUFACTURING
    COMPANY); KROLL ASSOCIATES, INC.
    Minnesota Mining and Manufacturing Company,
    Appellant
    On Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Eastern District of Pennsylvania
    (D.C. Civ. No. 97-03983)
    District Judge: The Honorable John R. Padova
    Argued July 12, 2001
    BEFORE: SLOVITER, ALITO, and GREENBERG,
    Circuit Judges
    (Filed: January 14, 2002)
    Barbara W. Mather (argued)
    Jeremy Heep
    Pepper Hamilton LLP
    3000 Two Logan Square
    18th and Arch Streets
    Philadelphia, PA 19103-2799
    Peter Hearn
    Peter Hearn, P.C.
    519 Pine Street
    Philadelphia, PA 19106
    Mark W. Ryan
    Kerry Lynn Edwards
    Donald M. Falk
    Robert L. Bronston
    David A.J. Goldfine
    Mayer, Brown & Platt
    1909 K Street, N.W.
    Washington, D.C. 20006-1101
    Attorneys for Appellees/
    Cross-Appellants
    M. Laurence Popofsky
    Stephen V. Bomse (argued)
    Paul Alexander
    Marie L. Fiala
    Heller Ehrman White & McAuliffe
    333 Bush Street
    San Francisco, CA 94104
    John G. Harkins, Jr.
    Harkins Cunningham
    2800 One Commerce Square
    2005 Market Street
    Philadelphia, PA 19103
    Attorneys for Appellant/
    Cross-Appellee
    2
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    GREENBERG, Circuit Judge.
    This matter comes on before the court on defendant 3M's
    (Minnesota Mining and Manufacturing Company) appeal
    from an order of the district court entered March 14, 2000,
    partially granting and partially denying its motion for
    judgment as a matter of law and denying 3M's motion for
    a new trial and on plaintiff LePage's Incorporated's cross-
    appeal from the order partially granting 3M's motion for
    judgment as a matter of law.1 LePage's brought this
    antitrust action asserting that 3M used its monopoly over
    its "Scotch" tape brand to gain a competitive advantage in
    the private label tape portion of the transparent tape
    market in the United States through the use of 3M's multi-
    tiered "bundled rebate" structure, which offered higher
    rebates when customers purchased products in a number
    of 3M's different product lines. LePage's also alleged that
    3M offered some LePage's customers large lump-sum cash
    payments, promotional allowances and other cash
    incentives to encourage them to enter into exclusive dealing
    arrangements with 3M.
    After the jury found in 3M's favor on LePage's's claims for
    unlawful agreements in restraint of trade and exclusive
    dealing but against 3M on LePage's's monopolization and
    attempted monopolization claims, 3M filed its motions for
    judgment as a matter of law and for a new trial, arguing
    that its rebate and discount programs and its other alleged
    conduct of which LePage's complained did not constitute
    the basis for a valid antitrust claim as a matter of law and
    that, in any event, the court's charge to the jury was
    insufficiently specific and LePage's's damages proof was
    speculative.2 The district court granted 3M's motion for
    _________________________________________________________________
    1. The plaintiffs in this action are LePage's Incorporated and LePage's
    Management Company, LLC, and both are appellees and cross-
    appellants. Inasmuch as we can discern no distinction between their
    interests, we refer to them simply as LePage's singularly.
    2. 3M unsuccessfully had moved for a judgment as a matter of law at the
    close of LePage's's case and after the close of the entire case.
    3
    judgment as a matter of law on LePage's's "attempted
    maintenance of monopoly power" claim but denied 3M's
    motion for judgment as a matter of law in all other respects
    and denied its motion for new trial. See LePage's Inc. v. 3M,
    No. Civ. A. 97-3986, 
    2000 WL 280350
     (E.D. Pa. Mar. 14,
    2000). The court subsequently entered a judgment for
    trebled damages of $68,486,679 to which interest was to be
    added, and this appeal and cross-appeal then followed.
    We will affirm the district court's order granting the
    motion for judgment as a matter of law with respect to the
    "attempted maintenance of monopoly" claim but will reverse
    the district court's order denying the motion for judgment
    as a matter of law in all other respects. Thus, we will
    remand the case to the district court to enter judgment in
    favor of 3M.
    I. BACKGROUND
    A. FACTUAL BACKGROUND
    3M, founded in 1902, introduced transparent tape for
    home and office use over 70 years ago. The readers of this
    opinion no doubt will recognize that 3M's Scotch products
    have become a familiar brand, and, in fact, 3M dominated
    the United States transparent tape market with a market
    share above 90% until the early 1990s. LePage's, founded
    in 1876, has sold a variety of office products and, around
    1980, decided to sell "second brand" and private label tape,
    i.e., tape sold under the retailer's, rather than the
    manufacturer's name. This endeavor was successful to the
    extent that LePage's captured 88% of private label tape
    sales in the United States by 1992. Moreover, changing
    distribution patterns and consumer acceptance of"second
    brand" and private label tape accounted for a shift of some
    tape sales from branded tape to private label tape. These
    changes were attributable to the rapid growth of office
    superstores such as Staples and Office Depot and mass
    merchandisers such as Wal-Mart and Kmart, as many of
    these retailers wanted to use their "brand names" to sell
    stationery products including transparent tape. Not
    surprisingly, during the early 1990s, 3M also entered the
    private label business.
    4
    LePage's claims that, in response to the growth of this
    competitive market, 3M engaged in a series of related,
    anticompetitive acts aimed at restricting the availability of
    lower-priced transparent tape to consumers. It also claims
    that 3M devised programs that prevented LePage's and the
    other domestic company in the business, Tesa Tuck, Inc.,
    from gaining or maintaining large volume sales and that 3M
    maintained its monopoly by stifling growth of private label
    tape and by coordinating efforts aimed at large distributors
    to keep retail prices for Scotch tape high.3 LePage's claims
    that it barely was surviving at the time of trial and that it
    suffered large operating losses from 1996 through 1999.
    1. Rebate program
    This case centers on 3M's programs that, beginning in
    1993, involved offers by 3M of "package" or"bundled"
    discounts for various items ranging from home care and
    leisure products to audio/visual and stationery products.
    Customers could earn rebates by purchasing, in addition to
    transparent tape, a variety of products within 3M's
    stationery division, such as Post-It Notes and packaging
    products. These programs created incentives for retailers to
    purchase more 3M products and enabled customers to
    have single invoices, single shipments and uniform pricing
    programs for various products in its consumer products
    division. The size of the rebate, however, was linked to the
    number of product lines in which the customers met the
    targets, an aggregate number that determined the rebate
    percentage the customer was to receive on all of its 3M
    purchases across all product lines. Therefore, if customers
    failed to meet growth targets in multiple categories, they
    received no rebate, and if they failed to meet the target in
    one product line, 3M reduced their rebates substantially.
    These requirements are at the crux of the controversy here,
    as LePage's claims that customers could not meet these
    growth targets without eliminating LePage's as a supplier.
    In practice, 3M's rebate program evolved so that it offered
    three different types of rebates: Executive Growth Fund,
    _________________________________________________________________
    3. It appears that at least at the times material to this action, there
    were
    no other domestic manufacturers of transparent tape. There were,
    however, foreign manufacturers.
    5
    Partnership Growth Fund and Brand Mix Rebates. 3M
    developed a "test program" called Executive Growth Fund
    ("EGF ") for a small number of retailers, 11 in 1993 and 15
    in 1994. Under EGF, 3M negotiated volume and growth
    targets for each customer's purchases from the six 3M
    consumer product divisions involved in the EGF program.
    A customer meeting the target in three or more divisions
    earned a volume rebate of between 0.2-1.25% of total sales.
    Beginning in 1995, 3M undertook to end the EGF test
    program and institute a rebate program called Partnership
    Growth Fund ("PGF ") for the same six 3M consumer
    products divisions. Under this program, 3M established
    uniform growth targets applicable to all participants.
    Customers who increased their purchases from at least two
    divisions by $1.00 and increased their total purchases by at
    least 12% over the previous year qualified for the rebate,
    which ranged from 0.5% to 2%, depending on the number
    of divisions (between two to five divisions) in which the
    customer increased its purchases and the total volume of
    purchases. Under both the EGF and PGF programs,
    customers could use their rebates as they saw fit.
    In 1996 and 1997, 3M offered price incentives called
    Brand Mix Rebates to two tape customers, Office Depot and
    Staples, to increase purchases of Scotch brand tapes. 3M
    imposed a minimum purchase level for tape set at the level
    of Office Depot's and Staples's purchases the previous year
    with "growth" factored in. To obtain a higher rebate, these
    two customers could increase their percentage of Scotch
    purchases relative to certain lower-priced orders.
    2. The Major Customers
    The evidence at trial focused on the parties' actual
    experience with a limited number of customers which we
    thus discuss at length.
    Wal-Mart
    Before 1992, Wal-Mart bought private label tape only
    from LePage's but, in August 1992, decided to buy private
    label tape from 3M as well. In response, LePage's lowered
    its prices and increased its sales to Wal-Mart. In 1997, Wal-
    Mart stopped buying private label tape but offered
    6
    LePage's's branded tape as its "second tier" offering. In
    1998, however, Wal-Mart told LePage's that it was going to
    switch to a tape program from 3M. LePage's's president
    then visited Wal-Mart following which Wal-Mart changed its
    plans and retained LePage's as a supplier. Afterwards, Wal-
    Mart designed a test comparing LePage's's brand against a
    3M Scotch utility tape to determine who would win Wal-
    Mart's "second tier" tape business. LePage's added more
    inches (approximately 20% more) to its rolls of tape and
    won the test. 3M continued, however, to sell other Scotch
    brand tapes to Wal-Mart, and LePage's saw its sales to Wal-
    Mart decline to approximately $2,000,000 annually by the
    time of trial. LePage's claims that Wal-Mart cut back on its
    tape purchases to qualify for 3M's bundled rebate of
    $1,468,835 in 1995.
    Kmart
    Kmart accounted for 10% of LePage's's annual tape sales
    when LePage's lost its business to 3M in 1993. Kmart
    asked its suppliers, including 3M, to provide a single bid on
    its entire private label tape business for the following year.
    LePage's's president believed, however, that Kmart was "too
    lazy to make a change," and that it would "never put their
    eggs in one basket" by giving all the business to 3M.
    LePage's offered the same price it had offered the previous
    year but also offered a volume rebate. 3M offered a lower
    price and won the bid. Kmart asked for rebates and
    "market development" funds as part of the private label
    tape bid process. 3M offered $200,000 for promotional
    activities and a $300,000 volume rebate if Kmart purchased
    $10,000,000 of 3M's Stationery Division products.
    LePage's claims that 3M offered Kmart $1,000,000 to
    eliminate LePage's and Tesa as suppliers and to make 3M
    its sole tape supplier. LePage's points to a 3M document
    outlining 3M's goal for Kmart to exceed $15,000,000 in 3M
    purchases with the reward being that Kmart would receive
    $75,000 in each of the first two quarters and $100,000 in
    the last two quarters for promotional activities and would
    receive $650,000 as a volume rebate if the sales exceeded
    $15,000,000. If the sales were less, the rebate would be
    decreased accordingly, e.g., a $400,000 rebate for
    $13,000,000 of sales. LePage's claims that, as a practical
    7
    matter, Kmart had to eliminate LePage's and Tesa to reach
    the growth 3M required in order to qualify for the rebate.
    LePage's asserts that, despite its efforts to regain the
    private label business from Kmart, one Kmart buyer told it
    that he could not talk to LePage's about tape products for
    the next three years. See Br. of Appellee at 9.
    Staples
    Staples had been a LePage's customer for several years.
    From 1990 to 1993, LePage's increased its sales to Staples
    by 440%, growing from $357,000 to $1,954,000. In 1994,
    Staples considered reducing suppliers and asked LePage's
    and 3M for their best offers in 1994. LePage's assumed that
    if 3M did make a good offer, LePage's would have a chance
    to make a better proposal. LePage's did not make its lowest
    offer, and 3M won the account. When LePage's went back
    to Staples with a new price, it was told that the decision
    had been made. LePage's claims that 3M offered an extra
    1% bonus rebate on Scotch products if Staples eliminated
    LePage's as a supplier (a "growth" rebate that only could be
    met by converting all of LePage's's private label business to
    3M). 3M paid Staples an advertising allowance in four
    payments totalling $1,000,000 in 1995 and gave it
    $500,000 in free merchandise delivered during Staples's
    fiscal year 1994. 3M refers to a "$1.5 million settlement"
    with Staples and refers to multiple payments for different
    purposes. LePage's, however, implies that these payments
    bore some connection to Staples's award of its second-tier
    tape business to 3M. Br. of Appellee at 10.
    Office Max
    In 1998, after a dispute between Office Max and LePage's,
    Office Max accepted 3M's offer that matched but did not
    beat LePage's's price. LePage's objected to 3M's matching
    whatever price LePage's offered, and also objected to 3M's
    "clout" payment. Office Max required its suppliers to make
    payments to help advertise the Office Max name, and
    LePage's had paid this "clout" payment in the years
    previous to 1998 when it refused to pay it because of its
    dispute with Office Max. Nevertheless, the buyer for Office
    Max testified that its decision to give its business to 3M
    was not related to its pricing and rebate program but rather
    to the consistency of its service.
    8
    Walgreens
    Walgreens had purchased private label tape from
    LePage's from 1992 until 1998, when it decided to import
    tape from Taiwan. LePage's's chief executive officer
    acknowledged that LePage's did not lose the account due to
    3M's activities.
    American Stores
    Until 1995, LePage's's sales of private label tape to
    American Stores exceeded $1,000,000 annually. According
    to LePage's, a month after American Stores decided that it
    would try to maximize 3M's PGF rebate, it shifted its tape
    business to 3M. In 1995, American Stores decided to stop
    buying LePage's tape, principally because of quality
    concerns. In a letter to James Kowieski, Senior Vice
    President of Sales at LePage's, Kevin Winsauer, the
    manager of the private label department at American,
    wrote: "After much deliberation comparing the pros and
    cons of LePage's program and 3M's program, I have decided
    to award the business to 3M. 3M's proposal was very
    competitive and I am sure LePage's would meet their costs
    to retain the business. However, the decision to move to 3M
    is primarily based on Quality." SJA 2050-51 (emphasis in
    original). When American Stores decided to purchase from
    3M, it was not participating in any rebate programs, and
    Winsauer testified that he was not aware that there were
    rebate programs. He also testified that even without the
    volume incentive programs, 3M's price was still slightly
    lower than LePage's's.
    Dollar General, CVS, and Sam's Club
    LePage's lost Dollar General's private label business to a
    foreign supplier but later won the business back. According
    to LePage's's president, Dollar General used the bid for
    import tape to leverage a price reduction from LePage's. 3M
    bid on the CVS account, but LePage's retained CVS as a
    customer by lowering its prices and increasing its rebate. At
    Sam's Club, LePage's tape had been selling well when its
    buyers were directed by senior management to "maximize"
    all purchases from 3M to maximize the EGF/PGF rebate.
    Subsequently, Sam's Club stopped purchasing from
    LePage's.
    9
    Other distributors and buying groups
    LePage's claimed that 3M's pricing practices prevented or
    hindered it from selling private label tape to certain
    companies:
    (1) Costco. Costco, however, never has sold private label
    tape. (2) Office Depot. Office Depot also never has sold
    private label tape. LePage's tried to convince Office Depot to
    buy private label tape in 1991 or 1992 (before 3M
    implemented the rebate programs), but Office Depot
    decided to continue purchasing 3M brand tape. (3) Pamida
    and Venture Stores. LePage's claimed that 3M offered these
    stores discounts conditioned on exclusivity, thereby
    preventing LePage's from selling private label tape to them.
    LePage's lost Venture Stores' business in 1989, five years
    before 3M provided the discount at issue. (4) Office Buying
    Groups. 3M offered an optional 0.3% price discount to
    National Office Buyers ("NOB") and UDI if they exclusively
    promoted certain 3M products in their catalogs. If the
    buying group carried a lower value brand alternative to
    3M's main brand (its second line), then the group would
    receive a lower annual volume rebate. LePage's viewed
    these kind of contract provisions as a "penalty" that coerced
    buying group members to purchase tape only from 3M. For
    example, if a buying group promoted the products of a
    competitor, it lost rebates for purchases in three categories
    of products. See Br. of Appellee at 20. 3M argues that
    LePage's could have offered its own discount or rebate but
    instead refused to pay the standard promotional fee that
    UDI charged suppliers for inclusion in its catalog.
    B. PROCEDURAL BACKGROUND
    LePage's began this action on June 11, 1997, alleging
    that 3M had engaged in predatory pricing,4 tying, full-line
    forcing, monopoly leveraging, and exclusive dealing in
    violation of sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.
    SS 1, 2, and/or section 3 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. S 14.
    _________________________________________________________________
    4. LePage's in its original complaint alleged on information and belief
    that 3M's "bundled rebates, promotional allowances and other cash
    incentives across its home and office product line .. . in the aggregate
    lower the . . . net price for 3M's tape below 3M's cost."
    10
    After 3M filed a motion to dismiss, LePage's dropped its
    allegations of full-line forcing and tying because the
    necessary element of coercion was not present. LePage's
    filed two amended complaints and ultimately alleged that
    3M:
    (1) began targeting LePage's['s] customers with private-
    label tape programs in order to deprive LePage's of
    sales revenue, efficient volume distribution, and
    transactional efficiency (2) sought to drive LePage's
    from the [m]arket through use of `bundled rebates' (3)
    offered a multi-tiered rebate to its customers across its
    product line . . . thereby forcing customers to give up
    buying from LePage's; and (4) offered some of
    LePage's['s] largest customers large lump-sum cash
    payments, promotional allowances, inventory
    repurchase, and other cash incentives to encourage
    them to enter into an exclusive dealing arrangement
    with 3M.
    Br. of Appellant at 3-4.
    3M moved for summary judgment after discovery,
    claiming that its conduct was permissible as a matter of
    law. In this regard, 3M argued that its rebates were in effect
    an element of pricing and that its prices were above its
    costs. Thus, it contended that LePage's's case failed for in
    Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp.,
    
    509 U.S. 209
    , 222, 
    113 S.Ct. 2578
    , 2587 (1993), the Court
    indicated that "a plaintiff seeking to establish competitive
    injury from a rival's low prices must prove that the prices
    complained of are below an appropriate measure of its
    rival's costs." 
    Id.,
     
    113 S.Ct. at 2587
    . Of course, 3M adheres
    to the same fundamental point on this appeal as it
    emphasizes that LePage's disavows any contention that
    3M's prices were predatory or below costs and that"[a]bove-
    costs pricing cannot give rise to an antitrust offense as a
    matter of law" inasmuch as in Brooke Group the Court held
    "that it is not unlawful to lower one's prices so long as they
    remain above cost." Br. of Appellant at 30, 36.
    Notwithstanding its original allegations to the contrary,
    LePage's answered that it did not claim in this case that 3M
    engaged in predatory pricing and that it could satisfy the
    11
    legal standards reflected in SmithKline Corp. v. Eli Lilly &
    Co., 
    575 F.2d 1056
     (3d Cir. 1978), so as to justify this
    action. The district court denied 3M's motion for summary
    judgment based on the court's view that LePage's might be
    able to prove a SmithKline intra-market monopoly
    leveraging claim depending on the structure of the program
    and the role of 3M's monopoly power in it. See LePage's Inc.
    v. 3M, No. Civ. A 97-3983, 
    1999 WL 346223
    , at *7 (E.D. Pa.
    May 14, 1999).
    The case was tried before a jury on the following claims:
    exclusive dealing and unreasonable restraint of trade under
    section 1 of the Sherman Act and section 3 of the Clayton
    Act and monopolization and attempted maintenance of
    monopoly power under section 2 of the Sherman Act. After
    a lengthy trial, the jury unanimously found for 3M on
    LePage's's claims for unlawful agreements in restraint of
    trade and exclusive dealing and for LePage's on its
    monopolization and attempted monopolization claims. The
    jury awarded LePage's damages of $22,828,899, which the
    court later trebled to $68,486,697 when it entered the
    judgment on April 6, 2000.
    On November 24, 1999, 3M moved for judgment as a
    matter of law and for a new trial. 3M argued that its rebate
    and discount programs and other allegedly predatory
    conduct did not give rise to a valid antitrust claim as a
    matter of law, that the jury charge was insufficiently
    specific, and that LePage's's damage proof was speculative
    and failed to relate damages to specific unlawful conduct.
    As we have indicated, the district court granted 3M's
    motion for judgment as a matter of law on the "attempted
    maintenance of monopoly power" claim but denied 3M's
    motion for judgment as a matter of law in all other respects
    and denied its motion for a new trial. See LePage's, 
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *12-13.
    3M filed a timely notice of appeal on April 25, 2000, and
    LePage's filed a timely notice of cross-appeal on its
    "attempted maintenance of monopoly power" claim on May
    5, 2000. LePage's has not appealed the jury's verdict that
    3M did not engage in exclusive dealing or otherwise violate
    section 1 of the Sherman Act or section 3 of the Clayton
    Act, and thus those claims no longer are directly in issue in
    12
    the case. Therefore, this appeal and cross-appeal concern
    only whether 3M violated section 2 of the Sherman Act by
    unlawfully maintaining a monopoly in the United States
    market for home and office transparent tape and for
    unlawful attempted maintenance of monopoly power in that
    market.
    II. DISCUSSION
    A. JURISDICTION
    The district court had jurisdiction over this case
    pursuant to 28 U.S.C. SS 1331 and 1337(a) because
    LePage's brought these claims under the Sherman and
    Clayton Acts. We have jurisdiction over this appeal
    pursuant to 28 U.S.C. S 1291.
    B. STANDARD OF REVIEW
    We exercise plenary review over an order granting or
    denying a motion for judgment as a matter of law. See
    Shade v. Great Lakes Dredge & Dock Co., 
    154 F.3d 143
    ,
    149 (3d Cir. 1998). When, as here, a defendant makes such
    a motion, a court should grant it "only if, viewing the
    evidence in the light most favorable to the nonmovant and
    giving it the advantage of every fair and reasonable
    inference, there is insufficient evidence from which a jury
    reasonably could find liability." Lightning Lube, Inc. v. Witco
    Corp., 
    4 F.3d 1153
    , 1166 (3d Cir. 1993). Thus, we review
    the evidence on the appeal in a light most favorable to
    LePage's and on the cross-appeal in a light most favorable
    to 3M. We note, however, that our opinion largely turns on
    legal determinations and the historical facts are not in
    sharp dispute. We review questions of law underlying the
    jury verdict on a plenary basis as well. See Bloom v.
    Consolidated Rail Corp., 
    41 F.3d 911
    , 913 (3d Cir. 1994).
    While the parties tender issues on this appeal relating to
    the review of an order denying a new trial and with respect
    to damages, we do not set forth a standard of review on
    these issues as we do not reach them.
    13
    C. MONOPOLIZATION CLAIM
    We will reverse the denial of 3M's motion for judgment as
    a matter of law on the monopolization claim. LePage's
    argues that 3M willfully maintained its monopoly through a
    "monopoly broth" of anticompetitive and predatory conduct.
    LePage's relies heavily on our opinion in SmithKline for its
    argument that a court can find that a company willfully has
    acquired and maintained monopoly power if it links a
    product on which it does not face competition with a
    product on which it faces competition. We conclude,
    however, that this case is distinguishable from SmithKline,
    which thus is not controlling. Rather, we agree with 3M
    that LePage's simply did not establish that 3M's conduct
    was illegal, as LePage's did not demonstrate that 3M's
    pricing was below cost and, in the absence of such proof,
    the record does not supply a basis on which we can uphold
    the judgment.
    There are two elements of a monopolization claim under
    section 2 of the Sherman Act: "(1) the possession of
    monopoly power in the relevant market and (2) the willful
    acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished
    from growth or development as a consequence of a superior
    product, business acumen, or historic accident." United
    States v. Grinnell Corp., 
    384 U.S. 563
    , 570-71, 
    86 S.Ct. 1698
    , 1704 (1966). Willful maintenance involves using
    anticompetitive conduct to "foreclose competition, to gain a
    competitive advantage, or to destroy a competitor." Eastman
    Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 482-83,
    
    112 S.Ct. 2072
    , 2090 (1992) (internal quotation marks
    omitted). LePage's contends that 3M's bundled rebates were
    anticompetitive and predatory. It also argues that 3M's
    other practices, such as exclusionary contracts and the
    timing of its rebates, were also anticompetitive and
    predatory.
    1. Bundled Rebates
    LePage's primarily complains of 3M's use of bundled
    rebates. While we have held that rebates on volume
    purchases are lawful, see Advo, Inc. v. Philadelphia
    Newspapers, Inc., 
    51 F.3d 1191
    , 1203 (3d Cir. 1995),
    LePage's seeks to avoid that principle by pointing out that
    14
    3M offered higher rebates if customers met their target
    growth rate in different product categories, in effect linking
    the sale of private label tape with the sale of other
    products, such as Scotch tape, which customers had to buy
    from 3M. Thus, LePage's explains:
    3M understood that, as a practical matter, every
    retailer in the country had to carry Scotch-brand tape
    . . . . It therefore decided to structure its rebates into
    bundles that linked that product with the product
    segment in which it did face competition from LePage's
    (second-line tape) . . . . To increase the leverage on the
    targeted segment, 3M further linked rebates on
    transparent tape with those for many other products
    . . . . The rival would have to `compensate' the
    customer for the amount of rebate it would lose not
    only on the large volume of Scotch-brand tape it had to
    buy, but also for rebates on many other products
    purchased from 3M.5
    Br. of Appellee at 40.
    As we have suggested, the principal case on which
    LePage's relies for support for its argument is SmithKline.
    _________________________________________________________________
    5. While LePage's does not label this argument"monopoly leveraging"
    and argued against the jury being instructed on the elements of a
    monopoly leveraging case (claiming that this is an"old fashioned
    monopoly case"), it is undeniable that the claim is similar to that
    advanced in the SmithKline, which has been labeled a monopoly
    leveraging case. See Advo, 
    51 F.3d at 1203
    ; Fineman v. Armstrong World
    Indus., Inc., 
    980 F.2d 171
    , 204 (3d Cir. 1992). In a monopoly leveraging
    case, however, there are two markets--one in which the company enjoys
    a monopoly and another in which it tries to leverage the former
    monopoly power. ERNEST GELLHORN & WILLIAM E. KOVACIC, ANTITRUST LAW AND
    ECONOMICS 152 (4th ed. 1994). In this case and in SmithKline, there was
    only one market (the transparent tape market in this case and the
    cephalosporin market in SmithKline). Consequently, our prior
    characterization of SmithKline may be problematical. LePage's's reference
    to customers' "inelastic" need for Scotch tape, see Br. of Appellee at 28,
    and its contention that, as a practical matter, stores had no choice but
    to carry Scotch tape, see id. at 40, does suggest that there may be either
    two separate markets or one market and one submarket. We do not
    address this point, however, because the parties treat this case as
    having only one market for the purposes of this appeal.
    Even if this were considered a monopoly leveraging case, however, then
    Fineman would control, and LePage's would not have established the
    15
    In that case, Eli Lilly & Co. had two products, Keflin and
    Keflex, on which it faced no competition, and one product,
    Kefzol, on which it faced competition from SmithKline's
    product, Ancef. See SmithKline, 
    575 F.2d at 1061
    . Lilly
    offered a higher rebate of 3% to companies that purchased
    specified quantities of any three (which, practically
    speaking, meant combined purchases of Kefzol, Keflin and
    Keflex) of Lilly's cephalosporin products. See 
    id.
     "Although
    hospitals were free to purchase SmithKline's Ancef with
    their Keflin and Keflex orders with Lilly, thus avoiding the
    penalties of a tie-in sale,6 the practical effect of that
    _________________________________________________________________
    requirements for 3M to be liable. See Fineman , 
    980 F.2d at 204
    . LePage's
    does not show that 3M had an actual or threatened monopoly in the
    leveraged market (private label tape). At the time of trial, LePage's
    still
    had 67% of the private label market, down from 88% previously. See Br.
    of Appellant at 8.
    Fineman involved a producer of a videotape magazine to be sold via
    distributors to retailers of floor covering products, which (with its
    principal) brought action against the floor covering manufacturer,
    alleging, inter alia, antitrust violations such as monopoly leveraging
    under the Sherman Act. See Fineman, 
    980 F.2d at 171
    . In Fineman, we
    declined to follow Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 
    603 F.2d 263
    , 275 (2d Cir. 1979), which involved a plaintiff that alleged that
    Kodak had leveraged its monopoly power in the camera and film markets
    to obtain a "competitive advantage" in the photofinishing equipment and
    services markets. In Berkey Photo the court held that the use of
    monopoly power attained in one market to gain a competitive advantage
    in another is a violation of section 2, even if there has not been an
    attempt to monopolize the second market. See 
    id. at 276
    . Noting that
    only the Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit has adopted the Berkey
    Photo reasoning, in Fineman we agreed that in order to prevail upon a
    theory of monopoly leveraging, a plaintiff must prove threatened or
    actual monopoly in the leveraged market. See Fineman, 
    980 F.2d at 205
    .
    That circumstance does not apply here.
    6. 3M also avoids the penalties of a tie-in sale, because its customers
    were free to purchase its Scotch tape by itself. To prove an illegal tie-
    in,
    a plaintiff must establish that the agreement to sell one product was
    conditioned on the purchase of a different or tied product; the seller
    "has
    sufficient economic power with respect to the tying product to
    appreciably restrain free competition in the market for the tied product
    and a `not insubstantial' amount of interstate commerce is affected."
    Northern Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 6, 
    78 S.Ct. 514
    , 518
    (1958).
    16
    decision would be to deny the Ancef purchaser the 3%
    bonus rebate on all its cephalosporin products." 
    Id.
    (internal footnote added). Because of Lilly's volume
    advantage, to offer a rebate of the same net dollar amount
    as Lilly's, SmithKline would have had to offer companies
    rebates ranging from 16% for average size hospitals to 35%
    for larger volume hospitals for their purchase of Ancef. See
    
    id.
    We concluded that Lilly willfully acquired and maintained
    monopoly power by linking products on which Lilly faced no
    competition (Keflin and Keflex) with a competitive product,
    resulting in the sale of all three products on a non-
    competitive basis in what otherwise would have been a
    competitive market between Ancef and Kefzol. See id. at
    1065. Moreover, this arrangement would force SmithKline
    to pay rebates on one product equal to rebates paid by Lilly
    based on sales volume of three products. See id. Expert
    testimony and the evidence on pricing showed that in the
    circumstances SmithKline's prospects for continuing in the
    Ancef market were poor.
    Here, LePage's argues that it does not have to show that
    3M's package discounts could prevent an equally efficient
    firm from matching or beating 3M's package discounts. In
    its brief, LePage's argues that its expert economist
    explained that 3M's programs and cash payments have the
    same anticompetitive impact regardless of the cost
    structure of the rival suppliers or their efficiency relative to
    that of 3M. See Br. of Appellee at 43. LePage's alleges that
    the relative efficiency or cost structure of the competitor
    simply affects how long it would take 3M to foreclose the
    rival from obtaining the volume of business necessary to
    survive. See id. at 43. "Competition is harmed just the
    same by the loss of the only existing competitive
    constraints on 3M in a market with high entry barriers." Id.
    The district court stated that LePage's introduced
    substantial evidence that the anticompetitive effects of 3M's
    rebate program caused its losses. See LePage's , 
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *7-8.
    We disagree with LePage's and the district court. In
    SmithKline, it was important that SmithKline showed that
    it could not compete by explaining how much it would have
    17
    had to lower prices for both small and big customers to do
    so. SmithKline ascertained the rebates that Lilly was giving
    to customers on all three products and calculated how
    much it would have had to lower the price of its product if
    the rebates were all attributed to the one competitive
    product. In contrast, LePage's did not even attempt to show
    that it could not compete by calculating the discount that
    it would have had to provide in order to match the
    discounts offered by 3M through its bundled rebates, and
    thus its brief does not point to evidence along such lines.
    It also did not show the amount by which it lowered its
    prices in actual monetary figures or by percentage to
    compete with 3M and how its profitability thus was
    decreased, and once again, its brief does not point to
    evidence along such lines. Rather, LePage's merely
    maintains, through the use of an expert, that it would have
    had to cut its prices drastically to compete and thus would
    have gone out of business.
    Although we are not evaluating the expert's method of
    calculating damages,7 and indeed, we do not reach the
    damages issue, we cannot overlook the lack of evidence to
    prove that pricing was what caused the drop in LePage's's
    market share. Simply pointing to an expert to support the
    contention that the company would have gone out of
    business, without providing even the most basic pricing
    information, is insufficient. "Expert testimony is useful as a
    guide to interpreting market facts, but it is not a substitute
    _________________________________________________________________
    7. We note that LePage's has pointed out that case law supports its
    expert's use of the but-for model of calculating damages. See Zenith
    Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 
    395 U.S. 100
    , 117 n.11, 
    89 S. Ct. 1562
    , 1573 n.11 (1969); Rossi v. Standard Roofing, Inc., 
    156 F.3d 452
    , 484-87 (3d Cir. 1998). In Bonjorno v. Kaiser Aluminum & Chem.
    Corp., 
    752 F.2d 802
    , 812 (3d Cir. 1984), we stated that in constructing
    a hypothetical world free of defendants' exclusionary conduct, the
    plaintiffs are given some latitude in calculating damages, as long as
    their
    theory is not "wholly speculative." There we ruled that the implications
    of the expert's testimony were not so inconsistent with the plaintiffs'
    theory of liability as to warrant a new trial. See id. at 812. We also
    stated
    that once a jury has found that the unlawful activity caused the
    antitrust injury, the damages may be determined without strict proof of
    what act caused which injury, as long as the damages are not based on
    speculation or guesswork. See id. at 813.
    18
    for them." Brooke Group, 
    509 U.S. at 242
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 2598
    ; see also Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio
    Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    , 594 n.19, 
    106 S.Ct. 1348
    , 1360 n.19
    (1986); Advo, 
    51 F.3d at 1198-99
    ; Virgin Atlantic Airways
    Ltd. v. British Airways PLC, 
    69 F. Supp.2d 571
    , 579
    (S.D.N.Y. 1999) ("[A]n expert's opinion is not a substitute
    for a plaintiff 's obligation to provide evidence of facts that
    support the applicability of the expert's opinion to the
    case."), aff 'd, 
    257 F.3d 256
     (2d Cir. 2001). Without such
    pricing information, it is difficult even to begin to estimate
    how much of the market share LePage's lost was due to
    3M's bundled rebates. Furthermore, some experts have
    questioned the validity of attributing all the rebates to the
    one competitive product in situations such as these. 8 We do
    not need, however, to decide the validity of that method of
    _________________________________________________________________
    8. One court has mentioned a hypothetical situation where a low-cost
    shampoo maker could not match a competitor's package discount for
    shampoo and conditioner even though both products were priced above
    their respective costs. See Ortho Diagnostic Sys., Inc. v. Abbott Labs.,
    Inc., 
    920 F. Supp. 455
    , 467 (S.D.N.Y. 1996). In that case, the court
    suggested that the bundled price could be unlawful under section 2 even
    though neither item in the package was priced below cost. If the entire
    package discount were attributed to the one product where the two
    parties compete, the low-cost shampoo maker could not lower its prices
    on the product enough to match the total discount without selling below
    its cost. See 
    id. at 467-69
    . The Areeda treatise, however, suggests that
    this analysis is incorrect. See III PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP,
    ANTITRUST LAW: AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATI
    ON
    P 749, at 467 n.6 (rev. ed. 1996).
    One aspect of this method of calculation worth noting is that the
    volume of the products ordered has a drastic effect on how much the
    competitor would have to lower its prices to compete. For example,
    suppose in a similar rebate program, a company was the only producer
    of products A and B but faced competition in C. If a customer orders 100
    units each of A, B, and C at a price of $1.00 each, a 3% rebate would
    be $9.00 (3% of the total of $300.00). If the rebate on all three products
    were attributed to product C, then the competitor would have to lower its
    price to $0.91 in order to compete with it. The results would be starkly
    different, however, if a customer orders 100 units of A and B but only
    needs 10 units of C. Then the 3% rebate on the total purchase amount
    of $210.00 would be $6.30. If the rebate was attributed solely to product
    C, then a competitor would have to lower its price to $.37 on product C
    in order to match the company's price.
    19
    calculation, as LePage's does not even attempt to meet that
    less strict test by calculating how much it would have had
    to lower its prices to match the rebates, even if they all
    were aggregated and attributed to private label tape.9
    LePage's also has not satisfied the stricter tests devised
    by other courts considering bundled rebates in situations
    such as that here. In a case brought by a manufacturer of
    products used in screening blood supply for viruses, Ortho
    Diagnostic Systems, Inc. v. Abbot Laboratories, Inc. , 
    920 F. Supp. 455
     (S.D.N.Y. 1996), the district court held, inter
    alia, that the defendant's discount pricing of products in
    packages did not violate the Sherman Act. The defendant,
    Abbott Laboratories, manufactured all five of the commonly
    used tests to screen the blood supply for viruses. Ortho
    claimed that Abbott violated sections 1 and 2 of the
    Sherman Act by contracting with the Council of Community
    Blood Centers to give those members advantageous pricing
    if they purchased a package of four or five tests from
    Abbott, thereby using its monopoly position in some of the
    tests to foreclose or impair competition by Ortho in the sale
    of those tests available from both companies. See 
    id. at 458
    . The district court stated that to prevail on a
    monopolization claim in "a case in which a monopolist (1)
    faces competition on only part of a complementary group of
    products, (2) offers the products both as a package and
    individually, and (3) effectively forces its competitors to
    absorb the differential between the bundled and unbundled
    prices of the product in which the monopolist has market
    power," the plaintiff must allege and prove "either that (a)
    the monopolist has priced below its average variable cost or
    (b) the plaintiff is at least as efficient a producer of the
    competitive product as the defendant, but that the
    defendant's pricing makes it unprofitable for the plaintiff to
    continue to produce." 
    Id. at 469
    .
    Holding that the discount package pricing did not violate
    _________________________________________________________________
    9. The closest LePage's comes to supplying such information in its brief
    is its statement that "LePage's made repeated efforts to save its tape
    business with Staples, reducing its prices to 1990 levels, and then
    reducing them again, to keep its plant open and people working." Br. of
    Appellee at 11. This is not close enough.
    20
    the Sherman Act, the Ortho court explained that any other
    rule would involve too substantial a risk that the antitrust
    laws would be used to protect an inefficient competitor
    against price competition that would benefit consumers.
    See 
    id. at 470
     ("The antitrust laws were not intended, and
    may not be used, to require businesses to price their
    products at unreasonably high prices (which penalize the
    consumer) so that less efficient competitors can stay in
    business.") (internal quotation marks omitted).
    In this case, LePage's now does not contend that 3M
    priced its products below average variable cost, an
    allegation which, if made, in any event would be difficult to
    prove. See Advo, 
    51 F.3d at 1198-99
    .10 Moreover, LePage's's
    economist conceded that LePage's is not as efficient a tape
    producer as 3M. Furthermore, LePage's has not shown
    through an explanation of the prices it would have had to
    charge to match 3M's bundled rebates, that it would have
    been unprofitable for it to continue to produce.
    By its failure to show how much it would have to lower
    its prices before it would be driven out of business,
    LePage's effectively is arguing that it is the linkage of a
    monopoly product with a competitive one that is the
    significant factor to be considered rather than the pricing.
    Indeed, apparently this is also why LePage's insists that,
    while certain of 3M's actions were predatory, this is not a
    predatory pricing case. But if the mere act of offering a
    _________________________________________________________________
    10. 3M argues that Brooke Group provides that lowering the effective
    price of a product through price incentives cannot give rise to a section
    2 Sherman Act claim unless the price is lower than an appropriate
    measure of cost. In fact, the Court's language in Brooke Group does raise
    a serious question as to whether or not it limits the holding of
    SmithKline
    to situations where prices are below average variable cost. However,
    Brooke Group was a predatory pricing or primary-line price
    discrimination case in which none of the tobacco companies had a
    monopoly of the market. See Brooke Group, 
    509 U.S. at 221-22
    , 
    113 S.Ct. at 2587
    . But inasmuch as LePage's does not even present a case
    that fulfills the requirements to establish liability of SmithKline, we
    need
    not decide the effect of Brooke Group on SmithKline. In the
    circumstances, we emphasize that we are not holding that if LePage's
    had supplied pricing information similar to that SmithKline presented
    our result would be different.
    21
    bundled rebate can be condemned under section 2 of the
    Sherman Act without regard for the relative efficiency or
    cost structure of the competitor, then competitors unwilling
    to accept lower profits could use the law to insulate
    themselves from competition. For example, a competitor
    who would have to lower its prices by 1% in order to match
    a bundled rebate could file suit against the alleged
    monopolist and obtain relief merely because it does not
    want to accept lower profits. It is difficult to see how
    consumers are better off if bundled rebates are illegal
    regardless of how competition is affected. After all, the
    Sherman Act "directs itself not against conduct which is
    competitive, even severely so, but against conduct which
    unfairly tends to destroy competition itself." Spectrum
    Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 
    506 U.S. 447
    , 458, 
    113 S.Ct. 884
    ,
    892 (1993); see also United States v. Microsoft Corp., 
    253 F.3d 34
    , 58 (D.C. Cir.), cert. denied, 
    122 S.Ct. 350
     (2001).
    Furthermore, this is not a situation in which there is no
    business justification for 3M's actions. Inasmuch as it is
    difficult to distinguish legitimate competition from
    exclusionary conduct that harms competition, see Microsoft
    Corp., 253 F.2d at 58, some cases suggest that when a
    company acts against its economic interests and there is no
    valid business justification for its actions, then it is a good
    sign that its acts were intended to eliminate competition.
    For example, Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing
    Corp., 
    472 U.S. 585
    , 608, 
    105 S.Ct. 2847
    , 2860 (1985), sets
    forth the lack of a valid business reason as a basis for
    finding liability. In that case, the Court affirmed a jury
    verdict for the plaintiff under section 2 of the Sherman Act
    where the defendant monopolist had stopped cooperating
    with the plaintiff to offer a multi-venue skiing package for
    Aspen skiers. The Court held that because the defendant
    had acted contrary to its economic interests, by losing
    business and customers, there was no other rationale for
    its conduct except that it wished to eliminate the plaintiff
    as a competitor. See 
    id. at 608
    , 
    105 S.Ct. at 2860
    ; see also
    Eastman Kodak, 
    504 U.S. at 483
    , 
    112 S.Ct. at 2090
    (exclusionary conduct properly is condemned if valid
    business reasons do not justify conduct that tends to
    impair the opportunities of a monopolist's rivals or if a valid
    22
    asserted purpose would be served fully by less restrictive
    means).11
    Similarly, in Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp., 
    207 F.3d 1039
    , 1043, 1063 (8th Cir.), cert. denied, 
    531 U.S. 979
    , 
    121 S.Ct. 428
     (2000), where boat builders brought an
    antitrust action against a stern drive engine manufacturer,
    the court held, inter alia, that the evidence was insufficient
    to find that the engine manufacturer's discount programs
    restrained trade and monopolized the market. Brunswick
    offered a higher percentage discount when boat builders
    bought a higher percentage of their engines from it, but
    there was no allegation that its pricing was below cost. See
    id. at 1044, 1062. In Concord Boat the district court cited
    the district court opinion in this case when 3M filed its
    motion to dismiss. See LePage's Inc. v. 3M, No. Civ. A. 97-
    3983, 
    1997 WL 734005
     (E.D. Pa. Nov. 14, 1997). The
    Concord Boat district court agreed with the plaintiff that it
    was not the price (above cost or not) that was relevant but
    the "strings" attached to the price and that the district
    court here was correct to distinguish Brooke Group since
    there were no "strings" attached (bundled rebates) in that
    case. In Concord Boat, the strings attached were the
    _________________________________________________________________
    11. Microsoft also offers some guiding principles on monopolization under
    section 2. To be condemned as exclusionary, a monopolist's act must
    have an "anticompetitive effect," which means that it must harm the
    competitive process and thereby harm consumers. Harm to a competitor
    will not suffice. Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 58
    . Competitive conduct is
    acceptable, but conduct that destroys competition is not. See 
    id.
     As the
    burden of proof is on the plaintiff, it must demonstrate that the
    monopolist's conduct has the requisite anticompetitive effect. See 
    id. at 57-58
    . If a plaintiff establishes a prima facie case under section 2, then
    the monopolist may offer a "procompetitive justification" for its conduct
    (a nonpretextual claim that its conduct is indeed a form of competition
    on the merits because it involves greater efficiency or enhanced
    consumer appeal), after which the burden would shift back to the
    plaintiff to rebut that claim. See 
    id. at 59
    . And finally, if the
    monopolist's
    procompetitive justification is unrebutted, then the plaintiff must
    demonstrate that the anticompetitive harm outweighs the procompetitive
    benefits. See 
    id.
     Microsoft also indicates that in considering the
    monopolist's conduct, the focus is on the effect of the conduct rather
    than on the intent behind it, as intent is only relevant in that it helps
    a
    court understand the likely effect of the conduct. 
    Id.
    23
    exclusivity provisions. See Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick
    Corp., 
    21 F. Supp. 2d 923
    , 930 (E.D. Ark. 1998).
    The Court of Appeals for the Eighth Circuit, however,
    disagreed with the district court in Concord Boat. The court
    of appeal's opinion reflected an application of Brooke
    Group's strong stance favoring vigorous price competition
    and expressing skepticism of the ability of a court to
    separate anticompetitive from procompetitive actions when
    it comes to above-cost strategic pricing. See Concord Boat,
    
    207 F.3d at 1061
    . More importantly, the court perceived
    that Brooke Group should be considered even with claims
    based on pricing with strings. See 
    id.
     "If a firm has
    discounted prices to a level that remains above the firm's
    average variable cost, the plaintiff must overcome a strong
    presumption of legality by showing other factors indicating
    that the price charged is anticompetitive." 
    Id.,
     citing Morgan
    v. Ponder, 
    892 F.2d 1355
    , 1360 (8th Cir. 1989) (internal
    quotation marks omitted). The court stated that a section 2
    defendant's proffered business justification is the most
    important factor in determining whether its challenged
    conduct is not competition on the merits. See id. at 1062.
    The court, however, distinguished cases such as SmithKline
    and Ortho where products were bundled since they involved
    two markets. See id.
    Unlike the situation of the defendant in Aspen , 3M's
    pricing structure and bundled rebates were not necessarily
    contrary to its economic interests, as they likely increased
    its sales. Furthermore, other than the obvious reasons such
    as increasing bulk sales, market share and customer
    loyalty, there are several other potential "procompetitive" or
    valid business reasons for 3M's pricing structure and
    bundled rebates: efficiency in having single invoices, single
    shipments and uniform pricing programs for various
    products. See Br. of Appellant at 7. Moreover, the record
    demonstrates that, with the biggest customers, 3M's
    rebates were not eliminating the competitive process, as
    LePage's still was able to retain some customers through
    negotiation, and even though it lost other customers, the
    losses were attributable to their switching to foreign
    suppliers or changing suppliers because of quality or
    service without regard to the rebates.
    24
    In sum, we have concluded as a matter of law after an
    intensive analysis that 3M did not violate section 2 of the
    Sherman Act by reason of its bundled rebates. If we held
    otherwise, notwithstanding the effects of the challenged
    practices on 3M's competitors, we would risk curtailing
    price competition and a method of pricing beneficial to
    customers because the bundled rebates effectively lowered
    their costs.
    2. Other Methods
    LePage's also claims that, through a variety of other
    allegedly anticompetitive actions, 3M prevented LePage's
    from competing. LePage's asserts that 3M foreclosed
    competition by directly purchasing sole-supplier status. See
    Br. of Appellee at 45. There was some dispute as to whether
    the contracts were conditioned on 3M being the sole
    supplier, and 3M claims that there are only two customers
    for which there is any evidence of a sole supplier
    agreement. It appears that most of 3M's contracts with
    customers were not conditioned on exclusivity, but
    practically speaking, some customers dropped LePage's as
    a supplier to maximize the rebates that 3M was offering.
    Moreover, United Shoe Machinery Corp. v. United States,
    
    258 U.S. 451
    , 465, 
    42 S.Ct. 363
    , 368 (1922), explained that
    a contract that does not contain specific agreements not to
    use the products of a competitor still will come within the
    Clayton Act as to exclusivity if its practical effect is to
    prevent such use.
    Even assuming, however, that 3M did have exclusive
    contracts with some of the customers, LePage's has not
    demonstrated that 3M acted illegally, as one-year exclusive
    contracts have been held to be reasonable and not unduly
    restrictive. See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Motion Picture
    Adver. Serv. Co., 
    344 U.S. 392
    , 395-96, 
    73 S.Ct. 361
    , 363-
    64 (1953) (holding that evidence sustained the
    Commission's finding that the distributor's exclusive
    screening agreements with theater operators unreasonably
    restrained competition, but stating that the Commission
    had found that the term of one-year exclusive contracts had
    become a standard practice and would not be an undue
    restraint on competition). See also Advo, 
    51 F.3d at 1204
    .
    In Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 
    365 U.S. 320
    ,
    25
    327, 
    81 S.Ct. 623
    , 627-28 (1961), the Court stated that
    even if in practical application a contract is found to be an
    exclusive-dealing arrangement, it does not violate section 3
    of the Clayton Act unless the court believes it probable that
    performance of the contract will foreclose competition in a
    substantial share of the line of commerce affected. Using
    that standard, although LePage's's market share in private
    label tape has fallen from 88% to 67%, it has not been
    established that, as a result of the allegedly exclusive
    contracts, competition was foreclosed in a substantial share
    of the line of commerce affected. Indeed, in view of
    LePage's's two-thirds share of the private label business, its
    attack on exclusivity agreements seems rather attenuated.
    There appear to be very few cases supporting liability
    based on section 2 of the Sherman Act for exclusive
    dealing, as some cases suggest that if, as is the case here
    under the jury's findings, there is no liability under section
    3 of the Clayton Act, it is more difficult to find liability
    under the Sherman Act since its scope is more restricted.12
    In any event, the record shows only two allegedly exclusive
    contracts (with the Venture and Pamida stores), and
    "[b]ecause an exclusive deal affecting a small fraction of a
    market clearly cannot have the requisite harmful effect
    upon competition, the requirement of a significant degree of
    foreclosure serves a useful screening function." Microsoft,
    
    253 F.3d at 69
    . The Microsoft court explained that although
    exclusive contracts are commonplace, particularly in the
    field of distribution, in certain circumstances the use of
    exclusive contracts may give rise to a section 2 violation
    even though the contracts foreclose less than the roughly
    40 to 50% share usually required to establish a section 1
    violation. See 
    id. at 69-70
    . In this case, it cannot be
    concluded that the two contracts with Venture and Pamida
    were responsible for the total drop in LePage's's market
    share. Furthermore, even if all 3M's contracts were
    considered exclusive, LePage's's total drop in market share
    was only 21%, and some of this loss was shown in the
    _________________________________________________________________
    12. It is more common for charges of exclusive dealing to be brought
    under section 1 of the Sherman Act or the Clayton Act, which the jury
    found that 3M did not violate. See, e.g ., Barr Labs., Inc. v. Abbott
    Labs.,
    
    978 F.2d 98
    , 110 (3d Cir. 1992).
    26
    record to be due to quality or service consistency concerns
    rather than to 3M's tactics. Therefore, there was not
    enough foreclosure of the market to have an
    anticompetitive effect.
    LePage's also claims that by calculating the rebates only
    once a year, 3M made it more difficult for a purchaser to
    pass on the savings to its customers, thereby making it
    harder for companies to switch suppliers and keeping retail
    prices and margins high. See Br. of Appellee at 39-40. As
    discussed above, one-year contracts may be considered
    standard, and even if they make it more unlikely that
    rebates are passed on in the form of lower retail prices, the
    discounts could be applied towards lowering retail prices
    the following year or towards other costs by companies that
    are factored into the retail prices (such as advertising). In
    the circumstances, we conclude that this conduct does not
    qualify as predatory or anticompetitive so as to establish
    liability under section 2 of the Sherman Act.
    LePage's also alleges that 3M entered the retail private
    label tape portion of the market to destroy the market and
    thereby increase its sales of branded tape, but the case law
    does not support liability under section 2 for this type of
    action. In Brooke Group, 
    509 U.S. at 215
    , 113 S.Ct. at
    2584, Liggett/Brooke Group alleged that Brown &
    Williamson Tobacco Corporation ("B&W") sold generic
    cigarettes in order to decrease losses of sales in its branded
    cigarettes. B&W sold generic cigarettes at the same list
    price as Liggett but also offered large volume rebates to
    certain wholesalers so they would buy their generic
    cigarettes from B&W. See id. at 216, 113 S.Ct. at 2584.
    B&W wanted to take a larger part of the generic market
    from Liggett and drive Liggett to raise prices on generic
    cigarettes, which B&W would match, thereby encouraging
    consumers to switch back to branded cigarettes. See id. at
    216-17, 113 S.Ct. at 2584. The Court held that because
    B&W had no reasonable prospect of recouping its predatory
    losses and could not inflict the injury to competition that
    antitrust laws prohibit, it did not violate the Robinson-
    Patman Act or the Sherman Act. See id. at 243, 113 S.Ct.
    at 2598. In this case, however, 3M did not use below
    average variable cost pricing (LePage's does not charge
    27
    predatory pricing) and therefore 3M did not have predatory
    costs to recoup.
    We recognize that LePage's attempts to distinguish
    Brooke Group on the ground that "3M used other
    techniques [i.e., techniques other than predatory pricing] to
    extinguish the private-label category subjecting itself to
    different legal standards," Br. of Appellee at 55, but we
    nevertheless reject LePage's's argument on this point. While
    LePage's does not contend that 3M engaged in predatory
    pricing, it does contend that the goal of 3M's other conduct
    was "to extinguish the private-label category, subjecting
    itself to different legal standards" than those applicable in
    Brooke Group. See id. Moreover, though 3M denies that it
    was attempting to eliminate the private label category of
    transparent tape, the record supports a finding that it had
    that intent.13 We are satisfied, however, that its efforts to
    eliminate the private label aspect of the transparent tape
    market are not unlawful as, "examined without reference to
    its effects on competitors," it is evident that in view of 3M's
    dominance in brand tape, that it was rational for it to want
    the sale of tape to be concentrated in that category of the
    market. See Stearns Airport Equip. Co. v. FMC Corp., 
    170 F.3d 518
    , 523 (5th Cir. 1999).14
    Accordingly, we find that 3M's actions in the record,
    including the bundled rebates and other elements of the
    "monopoly broth," were not anticompetitive and predatory
    as to violate section 2 of the Sherman Act.
    _________________________________________________________________
    13. It is not possible from the verdict to know how the jury found on this
    point, and thus we assume for purposes of this opinion that 3M was
    trying to eliminate the private label category of the transparent tape
    market. Therefore, if we concluded, which we do not, that a verdict could
    be upheld on the basis of that finding, we would order a new trial as the
    verdict nevertheless might, in fact, have been predicated on other
    theories that could not be justified.
    14. We do not understand why 3M's brief misquotes Stearns at 
    170 F.3d at
    523 by substituting the words "A finding of predatory conduct" in a
    direct quotation for "a finding of exclusionary conduct." Br. of Appellant
    at 35 n.23.
    28
    D. ATTEMPTED MAINTENANCE OF MONOPOLY
    We will affirm on LePage's's cross-appeal of the district
    court's grant of 3M's motion for judgment as a matter of
    law on the "attempted maintenance of monopoly power"
    claim, although we believe that the district court erred in
    its reasoning in reaching its result. Section 2 of the
    Sherman Act does not create a cause of action for an
    "attempt to maintain a monopoly." Section 2 of the
    Sherman Act provides: "Every person who shall monopolize,
    or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any
    other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the
    trade or commerce among the several States, or with
    foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony." 15
    U.S.C. S 2. Therefore, there can be claims for an attempt to
    monopolize and claims for monopolization, which include:
    "(1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant
    market and (2) the willful acquisition or maintenance of
    that power as distinguished from growth or development as
    a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or
    historic accident." Grinnell Corp., 
    384 U.S. at 570-71
    , 
    86 S.Ct. at 1704
    ; see also Houser v. Fox Theatres Mgmt. Corp.,
    
    845 F.2d 1225
    , 1229 (3d Cir. 1988). But even if we treat its
    claim as an attempted monopolization claim, LePage's has
    not presented proofs establishing the elements of such a
    claim.
    It is not clear what LePage's intended when it filed an
    "attempted maintenance of monopoly power" claim. If
    LePage's wanted to establish liability for 3M's conduct in
    maintaining a monopoly, then its claim would be covered
    by the "willful maintenance" part of the "monopolization"
    offense and would have been encompassed adequately by
    the monopolization count on appeal. Because 3M long has
    had monopoly power,15 any violation it committed would be
    actual monopolization as opposed to attempted
    _________________________________________________________________
    15. LePage's repeatedly states throughout its brief that 3M concedes that
    it enjoys monopoly power with a 90% share of the overall relevant
    market (the United States transparent tape market). See Br. of Appellee
    at 3. Monopoly power can be defined as the power to control prices and
    exclude competition regarding a particular product and within a
    particular geographic market. See Borough of Lansdale v. Philadelphia
    Elec. Co., 
    692 F.2d 307
    , 311 (3d Cir. 1982).
    29
    monopolization inasmuch as attempted monopolization is
    defined as an unsuccessful attempt to achieve
    monopolization, see American Tobacco Co. v. United States,
    
    328 U.S. 781
    , 785, 
    66 S.Ct. 1125
    , 1127 (1946), and
    requires "(1) that the defendant has engaged in predatory or
    anti-competitive conduct with (2) a specific intent to
    monopolize and (3) a dangerous probability of achieving
    monopoly power." Spectrum Sports, 
    506 U.S. at 456
    , 113
    S.Ct. at 890-91; see also Ideal Dairy Farms, Inc. v. John
    Labatt, Ltd., 
    90 F.3d 737
    , 750 (3d Cir. 1996).
    The district court construed LePage's's "attempted
    maintenance of monopoly power" claim as reflecting a third
    cause of action (besides monopolization and attempted
    monopolization) but found it inherently illogical. See
    LePage's, 
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *2-3. The court explained
    that "[a]ny `attempt claim' rests on the underlying theory
    that the defendant has failed to achieve its goal, which in
    this case is maintenance of monopoly power. But, if the
    defendant has failed to achieve its goal of maintaining
    monopoly power, then it follows that the defendant lacks
    monopoly power. Lacking any monopoly power to maintain,
    the defendant cannot be held liable for `attempted
    maintenance of monopoly power.' " Id. at *2. We believe,
    however, that the district court erred in its reasoning that
    if a party failed in its goal to maintain monopoly power,
    then it lacked monopoly power and therefore could not have
    any monopoly power to maintain. After all, a company
    could have a legal monopoly and attempt to maintain that
    monopoly through anticompetitive acts but fail and no
    longer have a monopoly. It then would have attempted to
    maintain its monopoly but would not have succeeded in its
    attempt. This does not mean, however, that it lacked
    monopoly power and therefore could not have any
    monopoly power to maintain.
    The district court concluded that this "attempted
    maintenance" concept was actually a standard attempted
    monopolization claim -- that the defendant does not have
    monopoly power but eventually would achieve monopoly
    power if it continued to engage in predatory conduct. Id. at
    *2-3. LePage's also argues on this appeal that the attempt
    to maintain a monopoly should fall under the "attempted
    30
    monopolization" offense and points to cases to support its
    point of view. Therefore, LePage's opposes the view that
    because 3M long has had a monopoly, its actions would
    fall under monopolization rather than attempted
    monopolization. It argues that a company can succeed in
    possessing a monopoly and still be held liable for
    "attempted monopolization."16 In Lorain Journal Co. v.
    _________________________________________________________________
    16. However, it seems to make more sense that in an attempt case the
    party did not succeed in achieving the monopoly. Indeed, early
    statements on attempts to monopolize characterize it as "conduct that
    closely approaches but does not quite attain completed monopolization,
    plus a wrongful intent to monopolize." GELLHORN at 153. Gellhorn and
    Kovacic state, "[B]y definition, an attempt case involves prosecution of
    the unsuccessful monopolist, which increases judicial caution." GELLHORN
    at 154. They add that, as LePage's claims, a defendant can be convicted
    of both monopolization and an attempt to monopolize, but the more
    common view is that the attempt merges into the offense of
    monopolization. See id. at n.15. Similarly, the Areeda treatise adds that
    despite the rhetoric of some cases, exclusionary conduct by a monopolist
    within its own market, whether successful or not, is best treated as an
    aspect of the full monopolization offense. IIIA A REEDA P 806a. The Areeda
    treatise also states that to say that one who has monopolized also has
    attempted to monopolize is "redundant and adds nothing to the scope of
    available remedies." Id. at P806f4. Therefore, the attempt to monopolize
    should be merged into the completed offense. See id. In Multiflex, Inc. v.
    Samuel Moore & Co., 
    709 F.2d 980
    , 990 (5th Cir. 1983), the court stated
    that "it is only the failure of the scheme that keeps the [attempted
    monopolization] charge from becoming actual monopolization."
    Indeed, in the case that LePage's cites to support the claim that a
    party can be held liable for both attempted monopolization and
    monopolization, American Tobacco Co., 
    328 U.S. at 783
    , 
    66 S.Ct. at 1126
    , the Court states that the attempted monopolization count was
    merged into the monopolization claim. See 
    id.
     In that case, the jury
    instructions defined "attempt to monopolize" as
    the employment of methods, means and practices which would, if
    successful, accomplish monopolization, and which, though falling
    short, nevertheless approach so close as to create a dangerous
    probability of it, which methods, means and practices are so
    employed by the members of and pursuant to a combination or
    conspiracy formed for the purpose of such accomplishment.
    
    Id. at 785
    , 
    66 S.Ct. at 1127
    .
    31
    United States, 
    342 U.S. 143
    , 152-53, 
    72 S.Ct. 181
    , 186
    (1951), the Court stated, "It is consistent with that result to
    hold here that a single newspaper, already enjoying a
    substantial monopoly in its area, violates the `attempt to
    monopolize' clause of S 2 when it uses its monopoly to
    destroy threatened competition." 
    Id. at 154
    , 
    72 S.Ct. at 187
    . The Court, however, made reference to the publisher's
    attempt to regain its monopoly by forcing advertisers to
    boycott a competing radio station and also mentioned the
    publisher's attempt to regain its pre-1948 substantial
    monopoly over the mass dissemination of all news and
    advertising.
    Regardless of whether the attempted monopolization
    claim should merge into the monopolization claim in cases
    where the defendant has a monopoly, and even if the claim
    of "attempted maintenance of monopoly" was actually an
    "attempted monopolization" claim, as LePage's now claims,
    see Br. of Appellee at 87-90, it still would have to meet the
    requirements of the latter claim to establish liability.
    Spectrum Sports clarifies the requirements of an attempted
    monopolization claim--that the defendant engaged in
    predatory or anticompetitive conduct with a specific intent
    to monopolize and a dangerous probability of achieving
    monopoly power. See Spectrum Sports, 
    506 U.S. at 454-58
    ,
    113 S.Ct. at 890-91. LePage's could not create a separate
    cause of action under the attempted monopolization offense
    of section 2 and, by calling it "attempted maintenance of
    monopoly," avoid the standards of an attempted
    monopolization claim in an effort to establish liability.
    _________________________________________________________________
    Under those instructions, it seems logical that a company that actually
    achieved a monopoly could not be found liable for an attempt to
    monopolize, unless the reasons for the possession of its monopoly were
    not related to the unlawful conduct that was meant to achieve that
    monopoly. For example, suppose a company tried through
    anticompetitive means to achieve a monopoly and came dangerously
    close to doing so but failed. It nevertheless then obtained a patent and
    achieved a legal monopoly, following which its competitor filed suit
    against it for attempted monopolization. In such a circumstance, it
    would not be illogical to allow an attempt to monopolize claim even
    though the defendant had achieved an actual monopoly.
    32
    LePage's has not demonstrated that the facts support a
    conclusion that 3M engaged in conduct that established
    each element of an attempted monopolization claim.
    Although it argues throughout its brief that 3M's actions
    were predatory and anticompetitive, the attempted
    monopolization claim has a requirement of specific intent
    rather than general intent that LePage's did not argue
    specifically. See Advo, 
    51 F.3d at 1199
    . In any event, quite
    aside from the scope of the LePage's's arguments, in our
    analysis of the monopolization claim we have come to the
    conclusion that 3M's rebate program and the other
    elements of the alleged "monopoly broth" were not
    predatory and anticompetitive. In the circumstances,
    inasmuch as LePage's relies on this conduct to establish its
    attempted maintenance of monopoly claim, its claim must
    fail. Accordingly, we will affirm the district court's partial
    grant of the motion for judgment as a matter of law in favor
    of 3M, although not for the reasons the district court stated
    in its opinion.
    III. CONCLUSION
    For the foregoing reasons, we will affirm the district
    court's order granting 3M's motion for judgment as a
    matter of law on the attempted maintenance of monopoly
    claim and will reverse the district court's order denying its
    motion for judgment as a matter of law in all other
    respects. We will remand to the district court to enter
    judgment for 3M in accordance with this opinion. In view of
    our result, we do not reach the points 3M has raised in its
    motion for a new trial.
    33
    [This page intentionally left blank]
    34
    Volume 2 of 2
    35
    SLOVITER, Circuit Judge, dissenting:
    In overturning the jury's verdict for LePage's on its claim
    that 3M violated S 2 of the Sherman Act and reversing the
    District Court's denial of 3M's motion for judgment as a
    matter of law, the majority applies reasoning that would
    weaken S 2 of the Sherman Act to the point of impotence.
    While that may be a consummation greatly to be desired by
    the behemoths of industry, such as Microsoft or 3M, it
    would be an incalculable loss to business generally and to
    the consumer. Section 2, the provision of the antitrust laws
    designed to curb the excesses of monopolists and near-
    monopolists, is the equivalent in our economic sphere of
    the guarantees of free and unhampered elections in the
    political sphere. Just as democracy can thrive only in a free
    political system unhindered by outside forces, so also can
    market capitalism survive only if those with market power
    are kept in check. That is the goal of the antitrust laws. The
    alternative, government control of markets and regulation
    of prices, is unacceptable to most of us.
    The majority has accomplished its enervation ofS 2 by
    relying on theories and cases inapplicable here and by
    failing to consider the synergistic effect of 3M's conduct
    taken as a whole. In the process, it ignores the jury verdict,
    the District Court's careful analysis, and this court's
    directly applicable precedent. It is a development that calls
    for full en banc review.
    I.
    INTRODUCTION
    It has been well established, as the Supreme Court
    enunciated thirty-five years ago, that a defendant company
    who possesses monopoly power in the relevant market will
    be found in violation of S 2 of the Sherman Act if the
    defendant wilfully acquired or maintained that power.
    United States v. Grinnell Corp., 
    384 U.S. 563
    , 570-71
    (1966).
    In many S 2 cases, the parties spend much time and
    effort in seeking to define the market and to determine
    36
    whether the defendant has monopoly power. Fortunately, in
    this case we need devote no effort to these issues. It is
    agreed that the relevant product market is transparent
    tape, and the relevant geographic market is the United
    States.1 Moreover, as to the issue of monopoly power, 3M
    concedes it possesses monopoly power in the United States
    transparent tape market, with a ninety percent market
    share. In fact, the evidence showed that the household
    penetration of 3M's Scotch-brand tape is virtually one
    hundred percent.
    The sole remaining issue and our focus on this appeal is
    whether 3M took steps to maintain that power in a manner
    that violated S 2 of the Sherman Act. A monopolist wilfully
    acquires or maintains monopoly power when it competes on
    some basis other than the merits. Eastman Kodak Co. v.
    Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 482-83 (1992);
    Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 
    472 U.S. 585
    , 605 n.32 (1985). The District Court, in instructing the
    jury on Count I, LePage's claim of unlawful maintenance of
    monopoly power under S 2, explained:
    Count I in this case is unlawful maintenance of
    monopoly power.
    LePage's alleges that it was injured by 3M's unlawful
    monopolization in the United States market for
    invisible and transparent tape for home and office use.
    To win on their claim of monopolization, LePage's
    must prove each of the following elements by a
    preponderance of the evidence.
    First, that 3M had monopoly power in the relevant
    market.
    Secondly, that 3M willfully maintained that power
    through predatory or exclusionary conduct. . . .
    _________________________________________________________________
    1. Although 3M originally challenged LePage's selection of the United
    States as the relevant geographic market, App. at 7, the District Court
    held that LePage's had introduced sufficient evidence from which the
    jury could properly find that the relevant geographic market is the
    United States and 3M does not challenge that market definition on
    appeal.
    37
    And thirdly, that LePage's was injured in its business
    or property because of 3M's restrictive or exclusionary
    conduct.
    App. at 5663-64.
    The jury was given the following questions on Count I.
    (1) Do you find that LePage's has proven, by a
    preponderance of the evidence, that the relevant
    market is invisible and transparent tape for home and
    office use in the United States?
    (2) Do you find that LePage's has proven, by a
    preponderance of the evidence, that 3M unlawfully
    maintained monopoly power as defined under the
    instructions for Count I?; [and]
    [(3)] Do you find that LePage's has proven, as a matter
    of fact and with a fair degree of certainty, that 3M's
    unlawful maintenance of monopoly power injured
    LePage's business or property as defined in these
    instructions?
    App. at 6523. The jury answered "yes" to each of the three
    questions. It awarded LePage's more than $22 million
    before trebling.
    Our review of a jury's verdict is limited to determining
    whether some evidence in the record supports the jury's
    verdict. Swineford v. Snyder County, 
    15 F.3d 1258
    , 1265
    (3d Cir. 1994) ("A jury verdict will not be overturned unless
    the record is critically deficient of that quantum of evidence
    from which a jury could have rationally reached its
    verdict."). This is essentially the same inquiry that the
    District Court made. In considering whether to overturn the
    jury's verdict, this court must view the evidence in the light
    most favorable to the verdict winner, here LePage's.
    Lightning Lube, Inc. v. Witco Corp., 
    4 F.3d 1153
    , 1166 (3d
    Cir. 1993). We must accord LePage's "the advantage of
    every fair and reasonable inference." 
    Id.
    LePage's alleges that 3M wilfully maintained its monopoly
    in the transparent tape market primarily by bundling its
    rebates and by exclusionary conduct, such as by contracts
    that expressly or effectively required dealing virtually
    38
    exclusively with 3M. 3M does not argue that it did not
    engage in this conduct. It agrees that it offered bundled
    rebates and entered into some exclusive dealing contracts.
    Instead, 3M argues that its conduct was legal as a matter
    of law because it never priced its transparent tape above its
    cost. For this argument, it relies on the Supreme Court's
    decision in Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson
    Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
     (1993). The majority in
    essence agrees. But Brooke Group did not deal with a
    monopolist and the antitrust claim in that case was
    predatory pricing, which is not one that LePage's raised
    here.
    The majority discusses bundled rebates and exclusive
    dealing separately. I view that as a serious error. That is
    because in determining whether a monopolist competes on
    some basis other than the merits, which as noted is the
    definition of monopolistic behavior, almost all courts,
    including this one, have looked to the monopolist's conduct
    taken as a whole rather than considering each aspect in
    isolation. See, e.g., Cont'l Ore Co. v. Union Carbide &
    Carbon Corp., 
    370 U.S. 690
    , 699 (1962) (stating"in a case
    like the one before us [alleging S 1 andS 2 violations], the
    duty of the jury was to look at the whole picture and not
    merely at the individual figures in it") (citation and
    quotation omitted); SmithKline Corp. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 
    575 F.2d 1056
    , 1061 n.3 (3d Cir. 1978) (determining that
    although defendant's anticompetitive scheme "lack[ed] the
    element of coercion necessary for liability under the theory
    of tie-ins [under S 1]," the evidence of tying was "sufficient
    to establish the offense of monopolization underS 2 of the
    Sherman Act"); City of Anaheim v. So. Cal. Edison Co., 
    955 F.2d 1373
    , 1376 (9th Cir. 1992) ("[I]t would not be proper
    to focus on specific individual acts of an accused
    monopolist while refusing to consider their overall
    combined effect. . . . We are dealing with what has been
    called the `synergistic effect' of the mixture of the
    elements."); Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp. v. Aspen Skiing
    Co., 
    738 F.2d 1509
    , 1522 n.18 (10th Cir. 1984) ("Each of
    the six [aspects of defendant's exclusionary conduct2]
    _________________________________________________________________
    2. The six aspects referred to by the court were"(1) forcing plaintiff out
    of the four-area ticket by requiring that revenues be divided below
    39
    viewed in isolation need not be supported by sufficient
    evidence to amount to a S 2 violation. It is enough that
    taken together they are sufficient to prove the
    monopolization claim."), aff 'd on other grounds, 
    472 U.S. 585
     (1985); City of Groton v. Conn. Light & Power Co., 
    662 F.2d 921
    , 928 (2d Cir. 1981) (" `It is the mix of the various
    ingredients of utility behavior in a monopoly broth that
    produces its unsavory flavor.' ") (quoting City of Mishawaka
    v. Am. Elec. Power Co., Inc., 
    616 F.2d 976
    , 986 (7th Cir.
    1980)); Northeastern Tel. Co. v. AT&T, 
    651 F.2d 76
    , 95 n.28
    (2d Cir. 1981) (following Continental Ore to consider
    defendants' various activities as a whole, although
    concluding proof of violation "utterly lacking"); cf. United
    States v. Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d 34
    , 78 (D.C. Cir. 2001)
    (avoiding issue because district court "did not point to any
    series of acts, each of which harms competition only
    slightly but the cumulative effect of which is significant
    enough to form an independent basis for liability"); 2 Philip
    E. Areeda, Roger D. Blair & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust
    Law P 310, at 147 (2d ed. 2000) ("In a monopolization case,
    conduct must always be analyzed `as a whole.' A
    monopolist bent on preserving its dominant position is
    likely to engage in repeated and varied exclusionary
    practices. Each one viewed in isolation might be viewed as
    de minimis . . . , but the pattern gives increased plausibility
    to the claim.").
    In concluding that there was an insufficient basis to
    support the jury's verdict, the majority fails to consider
    whether the synergistic effect of the conduct considered as
    a whole is anticompetitive. As will be seen, even considered
    individually the evidence underlying each of LePage's claims
    supports the jury's verdict. When 3M's conduct is
    considered as a whole, the conclusion is inescapable that
    the synergistic effect of 3M's conduct was anticompetitive.
    _________________________________________________________________
    plaintiff 's market share; (2) substituting defendant's three area ticket
    for
    a four area ticket; (3) marketing and advertising its three mountains in
    a manner designed to convince consumers that Aspen had only three
    mountains, not mentioning Aspen Highlands; (4) making an agreement
    with a tour operator to sell defendant's tickets to the exclusion of
    plaintiffs; (5) refusing to accept plaintiff 's coupons during the 1978-79
    season; and (6) raising ticket prices for a single-day lift ticket thus
    eliminating plaintiff 's ability to offer a multi-area ticket." Id. at
    1517.
    40
    II.
    DISCUSSION
    A.
    Bundled Rebates
    Through a sophisticated program of rebates,
    denominated Executive Growth Fund and Partnership
    Growth Fund, 3M induced customers to eliminate or
    substantially reduce their purchases from LePage's. Rather
    than relying on volume discounts which often reflect cost
    savings, 3M offered discounts to customers for purchases
    spanning six of 3M's diverse product lines. Those covered
    by the rebate program were: Health Care Products, Home
    Care Products, Home Improvement Products, Stationery
    Products (including transparent tape), Retail Auto Products,
    and Leisure Time. Sealed App. at 2979. Both of 3M's rebate
    programs set customer-specific target growth rates in each
    product line. The size of the rebate was linked to the
    number of product lines in which targets were met, and the
    number of targets met by the buyer determined the rebate
    it would receive on all of its purchases.
    The rebates were considerable. For example, Kmart
    received $926,287 in 1997, Sealed App. at 2980, and in
    1996 Wal-Mart received more than $1.5 million, Sam's
    Club received $666,620, and Target received $482,001.
    Sealed App. at 2773. A failure to meet the target for a single
    product line would diminish the rebate received across all
    product lines. Thus, there was a substantial incentive for
    each customer to meet the targets across all product lines
    to maximize its rebates.
    1. Applicability of SmithKline
    In discussing 3M's bundled rebates, the majority
    recognizes that it must address our decision in SmithKline
    Corp. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 
    575 F.2d 1056
     (3d Cir. 1978), where
    this court held that conduct substantially identical to 3M's
    was anticompetitive and sustained the finding of a violation
    of S 2. SmithKline concerned sales to hospitals by Eli Lilly &
    41
    Company, the pharmaceutical manufacturer, of three of its
    cephalosporins which it sold under the trade names Kefzol,
    Keflin and Keflex. Cephalosporins, which are broad
    spectrum antibiotics, were at that time indispensable to
    hospital pharmacies. Lilly had a monopoly on both Keflin
    and Keflex because of its patents. However, those drugs
    faced competition from the generic drug cefazolin which
    Lilly sold under the trade name Kefzol and which
    SmithKline sold under the trade name Ancef.
    Lilly's profits on the patented Keflin were far higher than
    those on Kefzol where its pricing was constrained by the
    existence of a competitor (SmithKline). Thus, Lilly sought to
    preserve its market position in Keflin and discourage sales
    of Ancef and even its own Kefzol. 
    Id. at 1061
    . To do this,
    Lilly instituted a rebate program that provided a 3% bonus
    rebate for hospitals that purchased specified quantities of
    any three of Lilly's five cephalosporins. SmithKline brought
    a S 2 monopolization claim, alleging that Lilly used these
    multi-line volume rebates to maintain its monopoly over the
    nonprofit hospital market for cephalosporins.
    The district court (Judge A. Leon Higginbotham, later a
    member of this court) found that Lilly's pricing policy
    violated S 2. SmithKline Corp. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 
    427 F. Supp. 1089
     (E.D. Pa. 1976). We affirmed by a unanimous
    decision. Although customers were not forced to select
    which cephalosporins from Lilly's stable they purchased, we
    recognized that the effect of the rebate program was to
    induce hospitals to conjoin their purchases of Kefzol with
    Keflin and Keflex, Lilly's "leading sellers." SmithKline, 
    575 F.2d at 1061
    . As we stated, "[a]lthough eligibility for the 3%
    bonus rebate was based on the purchase of specified
    quantities of any three of Lilly's cephalosporins, in reality it
    meant the combined purchases of Kefzol and the leading
    sellers, Keflin and Keflex." 
    Id.
     The gravamen of Lilly's S 2
    violation was that Lilly linked a product on which it faced
    competition with products on which it faced no
    competition. 
    Id. at 1065
    .
    The effect of the 3% bundled rebate was magnified by the
    volume of Lilly products sold, so that "in order to offer a
    rebate of the same net dollar amount as Lilly's, SmithKline
    had to offer purchasers of Ancef rebates of some 16% to
    42
    hospitals of average size, and 35% to larger volume
    hospitals." 
    Id. at 1062
    . Lilly's rebate structure combining
    Kefzol with Keflin and Keflex "insulat[ed] Kefzol from true
    price competition with [its competitor] Ancef." 
    Id. at 1065
    .
    LePage's private-label and second-tier tapes are, as Kefzol
    and Ancef were in relation to Keflin, less expensive but
    otherwise of similar quality to Scotch-brand tape. Indeed,
    before 3M instituted its rebate program, LePage's had
    begun to enjoy a small but rapidly expanding toehold in the
    transparent tape market. 3M's incentive was thus the same
    as Lilly's in SmithKline: to preserve the market position of
    Scotch-brand tape by discouraging widespread acceptance
    of the cheaper, but substantially similar, tape produced by
    LePage's.
    3M bundled its rebates for Scotch-brand tape with its
    second-tier and private-label tape in much the same way
    that Lilly bundled its rebates for Kefzol with Keflin and
    Keflex. In both cases, the bundled rebates reflected an
    exploitation of the seller's monopoly power. Just as
    "[cephalosporins] [were] carried in . .. virtually every
    general hospital in the country," SmithKline , 
    575 F.2d at 1062
    , Scotch-brand tape is indispensable to any retailer in
    the transparent tape market.
    In light of the manifest comparability between the facts in
    SmithKline and here, this court's analysis of S 2 of the
    Sherman Act in SmithKline and our conclusion in that case
    is not only directly relevant but controlling. Speaking
    through Judge Aldisert, we said:
    With Lilly's cephalosporins subject to no serious
    price competition from other sellers, with the barriers
    to entering the market substantial, and with the
    prospects of new competition extremely uncertain, we
    are confronted with a factual complex in which Lilly
    has the awesome power of a monopolist. Although it
    enjoyed the status of a legal monopolist when it was
    engaged in the manufacture and sale of its original
    patented products, that status changed when it
    instituted its [bundled rebate program]. The goal of
    that plan was to associate Lilly's legal monopolistic
    practices with an illegal activity that directly affected
    43
    the price, supply, and demand of Kefzol and Ancef.
    Were it not for the [bundled rebate program] the price,
    supply, and demand of Kefzol and Ancef would have
    been determined by the economic laws of a competitive
    market. [Lilly's bundled rebate program] blatantly
    revised those economic laws and made Lilly a
    transgressor under S 2 of the Sherman Act.
    
    Id. at 1065
    .
    The effect of 3M's rebates were even more powerfully
    magnified than those in SmithKline because 3M's rebates
    required purchases bridging 3M's extensive product lines.
    In some cases, these magnified rebates to a particular
    customer were as much as half of LePage's entire prior tape
    sales to that customer. For example, LePage's sales to
    Sam's Club in 1993 totaled $1,078,484, while 3M's 1996
    rebate to Sam's was $666,620. Similarly, LePage's 1992
    sales to Kmart were $2,482,756; 3M's 1997 rebate to Kmart
    was $926,287. 3M used its monopoly in transparent tape,
    backed by its considerable catalog of products, to squeeze
    out LePage's. 3M's conduct was at least as anticompetitive
    as the conduct which this court held violated S 2 in
    SmithKline.
    The majority makes several efforts to distinguish this
    case from SmithKline but they are unpersuasive. In one
    attempt, relegated to a footnote, the majority states that
    LePage's claim, like that of the plaintiff in SmithKline, is one
    of "monopoly leveraging" and as such must fail because a
    monopoly leveraging case requires two separate markets
    whereas the parties both treat this case as having only one
    market for purposes of the appeal. See Maj. Op. at 15 n.5.
    This is not a monopoly leveraging case, nor could it be.
    As Judge Mansmann explained in Fineman v. Armstrong
    World Industries, Inc., 
    980 F.2d 171
     (3d Cir. 1992), a
    leveraging claim entails an effort to convert monopoly power
    in one market into either a monopoly or a dangerous
    probability of monopoly in another market. 
    Id. at 203
    ; see
    also 3 Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust LawP 652, at 83
    (rev. ed. 1996) (defining monopoly leveraging as a situation
    where "the monopolist . . . `misuse[s]' or `abuse[s]' its
    monopoly power by `leveraging' it so as to give the
    44
    monopolist an unfair advantage in the secondary market,
    even though (a) the monopolist lacks significant power in
    the secondary market; and (b) there is no reasonable
    prospect that it will acquire monopoly power there"). The
    claim was unsuccessful in Fineman because, although
    defendant Armstrong probably could have been viewed as
    having dominance in the leveraging market, which was
    resilient floor covering, there was no evidence of a use of
    that market power to attempt to monopolize the video
    magazine market (producing a monthly videotape magazine
    for retailers of floor covering products). Significant is the
    fact that there were two separate non-competitive markets
    at issue--floor coverings and video magazines.
    Although there is some passing reference in Fineman
    categorizing SmithKline among monopoly leveraging claims,
    Fineman, 
    980 F.2d at 204
     ("[a]lthough monopoly leveraging
    claims are not entirely foreign to us, see Danny Kresky
    Enterprises, Corp. v. Magid, 
    716 F.2d 206
     (3d Cir. 1983),
    [and] SmithKline"), there was no further discussion of
    SmithKline in that context and no explication. 3
    Advo, Inc. v. Philadelphia Newspapers, Inc., 
    51 F.3d 1191
    (3d Cir. 1995), which the majority cites, is completely
    inapplicable here.4 In that case, the claim was an attempt
    to monopolize the market for delivering preprinted
    advertising circulars in the greater Philadelphia area, and
    plaintiff alleged that the defendant offered predatorily low
    prices to major purchasers of delivery services for circular
    advertising. It was not a market leveraging case.
    SmithKline never argued monopoly leveraging in its case
    and it never claimed predatory pricing. Even more
    important, LePage's did not claim that this was a monopoly
    _________________________________________________________________
    3. This court held in Fineman that the district court erred in granting a
    judgment notwithstanding the verdict but that there was sufficient
    evidence of anti-competitive conduct to warrant a new trial for violation
    of S 1 of the Sherman Act.
    4. The only reference in Advo to SmithKline is the statement that the
    quantity discounts offered by the defendant distinguished that case from
    SmithKline, "where we found that discounts tied to the purchase of
    specific items might amount to unlawful leveraging of monopoly power."
    
    51 F.3d at 1203
     (emphasis omitted).
    45
    leveraging case and, in fact, requested that the court not
    charge the jury on a monopoly leveraging theory. App. at
    5466-67. The court did not so charge. The majority has
    floated a red herring.
    Unlike the monopoly leveraging cases where the harm is
    the extension of monopoly power from one market to
    another, here 3M, if successful in eliminating competition
    from LePage's second-tier or private-label tape, would
    consolidate its monopoly in the transparent tape market. It
    would destroy any serious threat to the dominance of the
    Scotch-brand tape, as foreign competition was not viable
    and there were no incipient competitors on the horizon.
    Thus unrestrained, 3M could eliminate or reduce the
    rebates that it offered to favored customers, which it had
    introduced only after LePage's entry into the market with
    its lower priced options. This is not the scenario to which
    monopoly leveraging cases are directed. It is whatS 2 of the
    Sherman Act was designed to prevent.
    2. Anticompetitive Effect
    The importance of the fact that 3M can exercise
    monopoly power in the transparent tape market cannot be
    underestimated when considering the anticompetitive effect
    of its conduct. See, e.g., Robert Pitofsky, New Definitions of
    Relevant Market and the Assault on Antitrust, 
    90 Colum. L. Rev. 1805
    , 1807 (1990) ("In monopoly enforcement under
    section 2 of the Sherman Act, the pivotal inquiry is almost
    always whether the challenged party has substantial
    market power in its relevant market."). Monopoly power is
    "the power to control prices or exclude competition."
    SmithKline, 
    575 F.2d at 1065
     (quoting United States v. E.I.
    Du Pont de Nemours & Co., 
    351 U.S. 377
    , 391 (1956)); see
    also Borough of Lansdale v. Phila. Elec. Co., 
    692 F.2d 307
    ,
    311 (3d Cir. 1982).
    The District Court, recognizing that "this case presents a
    unique bundled rebate program that the jury found had an
    anti-competitive effect," Le Page's, Inc. v. 3M, No. 97-3983,
    
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *5 (E.D. Pa. Mar. 14, 2000), denied
    3M's motion for judgment as a matter of law (JMOL),
    stating:
    46
    Plaintiff introduced evidence that Scotch is a monopoly
    product, and that 3M's bundled rebate programs
    caused distributors to displace Le Page's entirely, or in
    some cases, drastically reduce purchases from Le
    Page's. Tr. Vol. 30 at 105-106; Vol. 27 at 30. Under
    3M's rebate programs, 3M set overall growth targets for
    unrelated product lines. In the distributors' view, 3M
    set these targets in a manner which forced the
    distributor to either drop any non-Scotch products, or
    lose the maximum rebate. PX 24 at 3M 48136. Thus,
    in order to qualify for the maximum rebate under the
    EGF/PGF programs, the record shows that most
    customers diverted private label business to 3M at
    3M's suggestion. Tr. Vol. 28 at 74-75; PX23, 28, 32,
    34, 715. Similarly, under the newer Brand Mix rebate
    program, 3M set higher rebates for tape sales which
    produced a shift from private label tape to branded
    tape. Tr. Vol. 31 at 79. PX 393 at 534906.
    Furthermore, Plaintiff introduced evidence of
    customized rebate programs that similarly caused
    distributors to forego purchasing from Le Page's if they
    wished to obtain rebates on 3M's products. Specifically,
    the trial record establishes that 3M offered Kmart a
    customized growth rebate and Market Development
    Funds payment. In order to reach the $15 million sales
    target and qualify for the $1 million rebate, however,
    Kmart had to increase its consumer stationary
    purchases by $5.5 million. Kmart substantially
    achieved this "growth" by dropping Le Page's and
    another private label manufacturer, Tesa. PX 51 at 3M
    102175, PX 121 at 156838. Likewise, 3M customized a
    program with Staples that provided for an extra 1%
    bonus rebate on Scotch tape sales "if Le Page's
    business is given to 3M." PX 98 at 3M 149794. Finally,
    3M provided a similar discount on Scotch tape to
    Venture Stores "based on the contingency of Venture
    dropping private label." PX 712 at 3M 450738. Thus,
    the jury could have reasonably concluded that 3M's
    customers were forced to forego purchasing Le Page's
    private label tape in order to obtain the rebates on
    Scotch tape.
    47
    
    Id.
    The majority's principal basis for overturning the jury's
    verdict and the District Court's denial of judgment as a
    matter of law is its disagreement with the District Court's
    finding that "[LePage's] introduced substantial evidence that
    the anti-competitive effects of 3M's rebate programs caused
    LePage's losses." Id. at *7. Glossing over the substantial
    evidence of loss and its connection to 3M's conduct, the
    majority imposes a new requirement on S 2 plaintiffs by
    holding that LePage's failed to "show that it could not
    compete by calculating the discount that it would have had
    to provide in order to match the discounts offered by 3M
    through its bundled rebates." Maj. Op. at 18. The majority
    cites no authority for this novel proposition. Moreover, it
    has no relationship to the record in this case.
    The jury was capable of calculating from the evidence the
    amount of rebate a customer of 3M would lose if it failed to
    meet 3M's quota of sales in even one of the bundled
    products. Thus, the majority's requirement to show"the
    discount that [LePage's] would have had to provide to
    match the discounts offered by 3M through its bundled
    rebates" can be measured by the discounts 3M gave or
    offered. For example, LePage's points out that in 1993
    Sam's Club would have stood to lose $264,900, Sealed App.
    at 1166, and Kmart $450,000 for failure to meet one of
    3M's growth targets in a single product line. Sealed App. at
    1110.
    Moreover, even using the majority's analysis, it is not the
    amount the customer would have lost had it stayed with
    LePage's without a comparable discount that is important
    but the effect of 3M's rebates on LePage's earnings, if
    LePage's had attempted to match 3M's discounts. That
    amount would represent the impact of 3M's bundled
    rebates on LePage's ability to compete, and that is what is
    relevant under S 2 of the Sherman Act.
    The impact of 3M's discounts was apparent from the
    chart introduced by LePage's that shows that LePage's
    earnings as a percentage of sales plummeted to below zero
    --to negative 10%--during 3M's rebate program. See App.
    at 7037; see also App. at 7044 (documenting LePage's
    48
    healthy operating income from 1990 to 1993, rapidly
    declining operating income from 1993 to 1995, and large
    operating losses suffered from 1996 through 1999).
    Demand for LePage's tape, especially its private-label tape,
    decreased significantly following the introduction of 3M's
    rebates. Although 3M claims that customers participating
    in its rebate programs continued to purchase tape from
    LePage's, the evidence does not support this contention.
    Most distributors dropped LePage's entirely.
    As the District Court found, "[LePage's] introduced
    evidence . . . that 3M's bundled rebate programs caused
    distributors to displace Le Page's entirely, or in some cases,
    drastically reduce purchases from Le Page's." Le Page's,
    
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *5. For example, LePage's lost key
    large volume customers, such as Kmart, Staples, American
    Drugstores, Office Max, and Sam's Club. App. at 943-44,
    2416-17. Other large customers, like Wal-Mart, drastically
    cut back their purchases. App. at 2417. In transparent tape
    manufacturing, large volume customers are essential to
    achieving efficiencies of scale. As 3M concedes in its brief,
    " `large customers were extremely important to [LePage's], to
    everyone.' . . . Large volumes . . . permitted `long runs'
    making the manufacturing process more economical and
    predictable." Br. of Appellant at 10 (quoting trial testimony
    of Les Baggett, LePage's former president and CEO, App. at
    234) (citation omitted). By March of 1997, LePage's was
    forced to close one of its two plants. App. at 2401. Making
    all inferences in LePage's favor, the conclusion is
    unavoidable that LePage's could not effectively compete.
    LePage's has more than satisfied even the majority's
    draconian standard.
    But perhaps more important, the majority's imposition of
    a requirement that plaintiffs demonstrate that they could
    not compete "by calculating the discount [the plaintiff]
    would have to provide . . . to match the [monopolist's
    bundled discounts]" is contrary to our precedent and that
    of the Supreme Court. If this is intended to make a
    plaintiff 's cost and efficiency the key factors in all S 2
    cases, it introduces a novel consideration into an analysis
    that should be directed to actions taken by a monopolist. In
    our opinion in SmithKline, we nowhere discussed
    49
    SmithKline's costs. The district court in SmithKline
    acknowledged that SmithKline was less efficient than Lilly,
    SmithKline, 
    427 F. Supp. at 1108
    , but it nonetheless held
    that SmithKline prevailed on its claim.
    Admittedly, LePage's must bear the initial burden of
    demonstrating that the defendant's conduct "produced
    adverse, anti-competitive effects within the relevant product
    and geographic markets." United States v. Brown Univ., 
    5 F.3d 658
    , 668 (3d Cir. 1993).5 There is no exclusive way to
    make that showing. We have stated that "[t]he plaintiff may
    [show anticompetitive effects] by proving the existence of
    actual anticompetitive effects, such as reduction of output,
    . . . increase in price, or deterioration in quality of goods or
    services." Brown, 
    5 F.3d at 668
     (citations omitted). But, as
    we observed in Brown, "[s]uch proof is often impossible to
    make . . . due to the difficulty of isolating the market effects
    of challenged conduct." 
    Id.
     (citing 7 Areeda, Antitrust Law
    P 1503, at 376 (1986)).
    We noted, however, that "[m]arket power, the ability to
    raise prices above those that would prevail in a competitive
    market . . . is essentially a `surrogate for detrimental
    effects.' " 
    Id.
     (quoting FTC v. Ind. Fed'n of Dentists, 
    476 U.S. 447
    , 460-61 (1986)). For example, in SmithKline , the
    district court, in an opinion which this court characterized
    as, "meticulous and comprehensive," SmithKline, 
    575 F.2d at
    1058 n.1, touched not only on the effect of Lilly's
    conduct on the plaintiff but equally, if not more
    importantly, the effect on competition generally. Judge
    Higginbotham observed, "[a]fter a review of the operation of
    [Lilly's rebate program] and its impact on SmithKline, and,
    more importantly, on the nonprofit hospital market for
    cephalosporins, I find Lilly guilty of the offense of
    monopolization in violation of section two of the Sherman
    Act." SmithKline, 
    427 F. Supp. at 1121
     (emphasis added).
    _________________________________________________________________
    5. Although Brown is a S1 rule of reason case, the legal frameworks for
    analyzing rule of reason violations of S 1 and monopolization claims
    under S 2 are similar. See, e.g., Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 59
    ; Mid-Texas
    Communications Sys., Inc. v. AT&T, 
    615 F.2d 1372
    , 1389 n. 13 (6th Cir.
    1980).
    50
    Ironically, the majority even quotes the well-accepted
    proposition that to be anticompetitive, conduct must harm
    competition itself-- "[h]arm to a competitor will not suffice."
    Maj. Op. at 23, n.11. Harm to a competitor becomes
    relevant to damages only after a violation is shown, but the
    majority disclaims reaching the damages issue. Maj. Op. at
    18. Inexplicably the majority fails to consider whether 3M's
    actions were harmful to competition, a sine qua non for a
    violation of S 2.
    LePage's presented powerful evidence that competition
    itself was harmed. The District Court recognized this in its
    opinion, when it said:
    The jury could reasonably infer that 3M's planned
    elimination of the lower priced private label tape, as
    well as the lower priced Highland brand, would
    channel consumer selection to the higher priced Scotch
    brand and lead to higher profits for 3M. Indeed,
    Defendant concedes that "3M could later recoup the
    profits it has forsaken on Scotch tape and private label
    tape by selling more higher priced Scotch tape . . . if
    there would be no competition by others in the private
    label tape segment when 3M abandoned that part of
    the market to sell only higher-priced Scotch tape."
    Le Page's, 
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *7.
    The plan that the District Court posited, that 3M sought
    to force LePage's from the market to eliminate the
    competition from LePage's second-tier tape, so that 3M
    could decrease its sales of its less profitable second-tier
    branded tape and force customers back to the higher priced
    Scotch-brand tape, was not implausible. Prior to the
    introduction of 3M's rebate program, LePage's share of the
    transparent tape market had been skyrocketing. For
    example, LePage's sales to Staples increased by 440% from
    1990 to 1993. App. at 1907-08. Following the introduction
    of 3M's rebate program which bundled its private-label tape
    with its other products, 3M's private-label tape sales
    increased 478% from 1992 to 1997.6 LePage's in turn lost
    _________________________________________________________________
    6. In 1992 3M's private-label tape sales were $1,142,000. By 1997, its
    private-label tape sales had increased to $5,464,222. Sealed App. at 489.
    51
    a proportional amount of sales.7 As a result, LePage's
    manufacturing process became less efficient and its profit
    margins declined. In 1997, the only other domestic
    transparent tape manufacturer, Tesa Tuck, Inc., bowed out
    of the transparent tape business entirely. App. at 3008-09.
    Had 3M continued with its program 3M could have
    eventually forced LePage's out of the market.
    3M could effectuate such a plan because there was no
    ease of entry. See Advo, 
    51 F.3d at 1200
     (commenting that
    ease of entry would prevent monopolist's predatory pricing
    scheme from succeeding); see also Edward A. Snyder &
    Thomas E. Kauper, Misuses of the Antitrust Laws: The
    Competitor Plaintiff, 
    90 Mich. L. Rev. 551
     (1991) (finding
    "barriers to entry" to be one of two necessary conditions for
    exclusionary conduct, the other being "market power").
    The District Court found that there was "substantial
    evidence at trial that significant entry barriers prevent
    competitors from entering the . . . tape market in the
    United States. Thus, this case presents a situation in which
    a monopolist remains unchecked in the market." Le Page's,
    
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *7. In the time period at issue here,
    there has never been a competitor that has genuinely
    challenged 3M's monopoly and it never lost a significant
    transparent tape account to a foreign competitor. App. at
    4272.
    The significance of entry barriers is emphasized in
    Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp., 
    207 F.3d 1039
     (8th
    Cir. 2000), a case cited by the majority. In that case the
    court reviewed a multimillion dollar jury verdict on behalf
    of plaintiff boat builders who alleged that the dominant
    stern drive engine manufacturer violated S 7 of the Clayton
    Act and SS 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act. The Court of
    _________________________________________________________________
    7. According to the majority, some of these losses were attributable to
    quality or service issues. Maj. Op. at 26-27. That evidence is in dispute.
    Given the existence of evidence to the contrary, the majority's reading of
    the facts is simply not consistent with this court's precedent, which the
    majority cites with approval, see Maj. Op. at 13, that, when considering
    whether to overturn the jury's verdict, this court must view the evidence
    in the light most favorable to the verdict winner. Lightning Lube, Inc. v.
    Witco Corp., 
    4 F.3d 1153
    , 1166 (3d Cir. 1993).
    52
    Appeals overturned the S 7 verdict as barred by the statute
    of limitations and the Sherman S 1 verdict because the
    expert opinion on which it was based was not supported by
    the facts. It also reversed the Sherman S 2 verdict, but here
    the opinion shows the difference between the facts in that
    case and those here. First, the court noted that the boat
    builders "did not show that significant barriers to entry
    existed in the stern drive market." Id. at 1059. It
    commented that "[i]f entry barriers to new firms are not
    significant, it may be difficult for even a monopoly company
    to control prices through some type of exclusive dealing
    arrangement because a new firm or firms easily can enter
    the market to challenge it." Id. It continued, "[i]f there are
    significant entry barriers in the market, a potential
    competitor would have difficulty entering in order to
    challenge a firm that is charging supracompetitive high
    prices." Id. In this case, 3M does not dispute that there are
    significant barriers to entry in the transparent tape market,
    as the District Court found.
    Second, in holding that the plaintiff boat builders had not
    shown that Brunswick's engine price was below cost, the
    court relied on the decision in Brooke Group where the
    Court held that a predatory pricing claim could not be
    grounded on above-cost discounting. The Concord court
    distinguished other S 2 cases, including an earlier decision
    of the District Court in this case, LePage's, Inc. v. 3M, No.
    97-3983, 
    1997 WL 734005
     (E.D. Pa. 1997), on the ground
    that in Brunswick "there are no allegations of tying or
    bundling with another product." Concord, 
    207 F.3d at 1062
    . Of course, the bundled rebates offered by 3M occupy
    a central place in LePage's case.
    Finally, in its decision the Eighth Circuit noted that
    "Brunswick's discount programs were not exclusive dealing
    contracts and its customers were not required either to
    purchase 100% from Brunswick or to refrain from
    purchasing from competitors in order to receive the
    discount." 
    Id. at 1062-63
    . The court noted that its
    customers could purchase up to forty percent of
    requirements from other sellers without foregoing the
    discount. That situation is far different from 3M's bundled
    rebate programs, as there was ample evidence that its
    53
    discount was, in effect, available only if the customer
    bought all of its transparent tape requirements from 3M. In
    summary, unlike the Brunswick situation, here there were
    significant barriers to entry, 3M bundled its rebates, and
    3M imposed exclusive dealing requirements on some of its
    principal customers.
    As the majority concedes, Maj. Op. at 28, there was
    evidence from which the jury could have determined that
    3M intended to force LePage's from the market, and then
    cease or severely curtail its own private-label and second-
    tier tape lines. For example, by 1996, 3M had begun to
    offer incentives to some customers to increase purchases of
    its higher priced Scotch-brand tapes over its own second-
    tier brand. The Supreme Court has made clear that intent
    is relevant to proving monopolization, see Aspen Skiing Co.
    v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 
    472 U.S. 585
    , 602 (1985),
    and attempt to monopolize, Lorain Journal Co. v. United
    States, 
    342 U.S. 143
    , 155 (1951).
    3M's interest in raising prices is well-documented in the
    record. LePage's expert testified that the price of Scotch-
    brand tape has increased since 1994, after 3M instituted its
    rebate program. App. at 3246-47, 5392-95. In its opinion,
    the District Court cited the deposition testimony of a 3M
    employee acknowledging that the payment of the rebates
    after the end of the year discouraged passing the rebate on
    to the ultimate customers. App. at 2092. The District Court
    thus observed, "the record amply reflects that 3M's rebate
    programs did not benefit the ultimate consumer." Le
    Page's, 
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *7. The record contained
    sufficient evidence for the jury to conclude the long-term
    effects of 3M's conduct were anticompetitive.
    3. Relevance of Brooke Group
    Running throughout the majority's opinion is the theme
    that because 3M's prices on transparent tape were not
    below its average variable cost it could not have violated S 2
    of the Sherman Act. This is the principal argument made
    by 3M on appeal. 3M argues that "[a]bove-cost pricing
    cannot give rise to an antitrust offense as a matter of law,
    since it is the very conduct that the antitrust laws wish to
    promote in the interest of making consumers better off." Br.
    54
    of Appellant at 30. It cites for this proposition the Supreme
    Court's decision in Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown &
    Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 222 (1993). Every
    decision on S 2 since 1993 must deal with Brooke Group,
    but that case does not hold that a claim of monopolizing or
    attempting to monopolize will be unsuccessful unless
    plaintiff shows below-cost predatory pricing.
    In Brooke Group, Liggett, a cigarette manufacturer
    responsible for the "innovative development" of generic
    cigarettes, claimed that Brown & Williamson, which
    introduced its own line of generic cigarettes, "cut prices on
    generic cigarettes below cost and offered discriminatory
    volume rebates to wholesalers to force Liggett to raise its
    own generic cigarette prices and introduce oligopoly pricing
    in the economy segment [of the national cigarette market]."
    
    Id. at 212
    . Brown & Williamson's deep price discounts or
    rebates were concededly discriminatory (Liggett's claim
    included violation of the Robinson- Patman Act), not cost
    justified, and resulted in substantial loss to it. The
    Supreme Court majority held that defendant was entitled to
    judgment as a matter of law because there was no evidence
    of injury to competition. The Court also held that the
    evidence did not show that Brown & Williamson's alleged
    scheme "was likely to result in oligopolistic price
    coordination and sustained supracompetitive pricing in the
    generic segment of the national cigarette market. Without
    this, Brown & Williamson had no reasonable prospect of
    recouping its predatory losses and could not inflict the
    injury to competition the antitrust laws prohibit." 
    Id. at 243
    .8
    The Brooke Group opinion is premised on the national
    cigarette market at that time, which was composed of six
    manufacturers whose prices for cigarettes "increased in
    lockstep" and who "reaped the benefits of prices above a
    competitive level." 
    Id. at 213
    . Brown & Williamson's share
    _________________________________________________________________
    8. In contrast, the District Court here noted that 3M had conceded that
    it "could later recoup the profits it has forsaken on Scotch tape and
    private-label tape by selling more higher priced Scotch tape . . . if
    there
    would be no competition by others in the private-label tape segment
    when 3M abandoned that part of the market to sell only higher-priced
    Scotch tape." Le Page's, 
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *7 (omission in original).
    55
    of the oligopolistic market was described in the opinion as
    twelve percent. Thus, its conduct and pricing were at all
    times constrained by the presence of competitors who
    could, and did, react to its conduct by undertaking similar
    price cuts or pricing behavior.9
    In contrast, 3M is a monopolist. It is a tenet of antitrust
    law that a monopolist is not permitted to take certain
    actions that a company in a competitive (or even
    oligopolistic market) may take, because there is no
    constraint on a monopolist's behavior. See, e.g. , Aspen
    Skiing, 
    472 U.S. at 601-04
    . Even if Brooke Group could be
    read for the proposition that all pricing action is legal if the
    company's prices are not below its costs, nothing in the
    Supreme Court's decision suggests that its discussion of
    the issue is applicable to a monopolist with its
    unconstrained market power. And nothing in that opinion
    gives the imprimatur of approval to bundled rebates, the
    conduct by 3M that the jury found violated S 2.
    Even if 3M had not engaged in other exclusionary
    conduct, the jury's conclusion that 3M unlawfully
    maintained its monopoly power is amply supported by the
    evidence of 3M's bundled rebate programs.
    B.
    Exclusive Dealing
    3M did not confine its monopolization actions to its
    bundled rebate programs. LePage's produced substantial
    evidence of exclusionary conduct by 3M, much of it
    designed to achieve sole-source supplier status, either
    facially or indirectly.10 Even though exclusivity
    _________________________________________________________________
    9. The Brooke Group opinions, both for the majority and the dissent,
    discuss the responses by members of the oligopoly to the introduction of
    discounted cigarettes. Id. at 239-40; id. at 247-48 (Stevens, J.,
    dissenting).
    10. The jury's finding against LePage's on its exclusive dealing claim
    under S 1 of the Sherman Act and S 3 of the Clayton Act does not
    preclude the application of evidence of 3M's exclusive dealing to support
    56
    arrangements are often analyzed under S 1, such
    exclusionary conduct may also be an element in aS 2
    claim. U.S. Healthcare, Inc. v. Healthsource, Inc., 
    986 F.2d 589
    , 593 (1st Cir. 1993) (observing that exclusivity may
    also play "a role . . . as an element in attempted or actual
    monopolization"). When evaluating a plaintiff 's exclusive
    dealing claim under S 1, this court has looked to the
    increase in the defendant's market share, the effects of
    foreclosure on the market, benefits to customers and the
    defendant, and the extent to which customers felt they were
    precluded from dealing with other manufacturers. Barr, 
    978 F.2d at 110-11
    . There is no reason why these factors would
    not be equally applicable under S 2.
    According to LePage's, 3M's exclusionary "tactics
    foreclosed the competitive process by preventing rivals from
    competing to gain (or maintain) a presence in the market."
    Br. of Appellee at 45-46. The District Court instructed the
    jury that for purposes of finding a S 2 violation,
    " `exclusionary' comprehends . . . behavior that not only (1)
    tends to impair the opportunities of rivals, but also (2)
    either does not further competition on the merits or does so
    in an unnecessarily restrictive way." App. at 6490. The
    instruction followed the applicable legal principles
    enunciated in Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs.,
    Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 482-83 (1992). See also Aspen Skiing,
    
    472 U.S. at
    605 n.32. In fact, one of the foremost antitrust
    treatises approvingly cites an unreported opinion by the
    District Court in this case as an example of how discounts
    conditioned on exclusivity are "problematic""when the
    defendant is a dominant firm in a position to force
    manufacturers to make an all-or-nothing choice." 11
    Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law P 1807b, at 117 n.7 (1998)
    (citing LePage's, 
    1997 WL 734005
     (E.D. Pa. 1997)).
    _________________________________________________________________
    LePage's S 2 claim. See, e.g., Barr Labs. v. Abbott Labs., 
    978 F.2d 98
    ,
    110-11 (3d Cir. 1992) (considering S 2 of the Sherman claims after
    rejecting claims based on the same evidence underS 1 of the Sherman
    Act and S 3 of the Clayton Act); SmithKline, 
    427 F. Supp. at 1092
    , aff 'd,
    
    575 F.2d 1056
     (imposing S 2 Sherman Act liability for exclusionary
    conduct, after rejecting an exclusive dealing claim under S 3 of the
    Clayton Act).
    57
    In Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 
    365 U.S. 320
    (1961), which the majority cites and which dealt with S 3 of
    the Clayton Act, not S 2 of the Sherman Act, the Court took
    cognizance of arrangements which, albeit not expressly
    exclusive, effectively foreclosed the business of competitors.
    It has been noted that even quantity discounts may
    foreclose a substantial portion of the market. See, e.g., 11
    Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law P 1807a, at 115-16. As
    Professors Areeda and Hovenkamp recognize, "unilaterally
    imposed quantity discounts can foreclose the opportunities
    of rivals when a dealer can obtain its best discounts only by
    dealing exclusively with the dominant firm. This is
    particularly true when the discounts are cumulative over
    lengthy periods of time--for example, one year--and where
    no obvious economies result from giving lower prices in,
    say, August on the basis of large purchases made in
    January." 3A Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law P 768b3,
    at 151 (1996).
    Because some of 3M's rebates were "all or nothing"
    discounts, customers maximized their discounts only if
    they dealt exclusively with the dominant market player, 3M,
    and they were severely penalized financially for failing to
    meet their quota in a single product line. Only by dealing
    exclusively with 3M in as many product lines as possible
    could customers enjoy the substantial discounts.
    The majority acknowledges only two exclusive dealing
    contracts, those with the Venture and Pomida stores.
    However, LePage's introduced evidence that the jury could
    well have believed rendered other arrangements exclusive.
    Many of LePage's former customers refused to even meet
    with LePage's sales representatives. App. at 1925, 1451. Of
    more significance, a buyer of Kmart, LePage's largest
    customer, which accounted for ten percent of its business,
    told LePage's "I can't talk to you about tape products for
    the next three years" and "don't bring me anything 3M
    makes." App. at 302, 764-65. Kmart switched to 3M
    following 3M's offer of a $1 million "growth" reward which
    the jury could have understood to require that 3M be its
    sole supplier. Similarly, Staples was offered an extra one
    percent bonus rebate if it gave LePage's business to 3M.
    The majority accepts 3M's argument that LePage's did not
    58
    try hard enough to retain Kmart, its customer for twenty
    years, but the evidence is to the contrary.11 In any event,
    this was an issue for the jury which, by its verdict, rejected
    3M's argument.
    In internal memoranda introduced into evidence by
    LePage's, 3M executives boasted that the large retailers like
    Office Max and Staples had no choice but to adhere to 3M's
    demands. Sealed App. at 2585 ("Either they take the [price]
    increase . . . or we hold orders . . . ."); see also Sealed App.
    at 2571 (3M's directive when Staples objected to price
    increase was "orders will be held if pricing is not up to date
    on 1/1/98"). Judge Posner, well known for his familiarity
    with economic doctrine, wrote in a case dealing with
    exclusive contracts that in order to show that an exclusive-
    dealing agreement is unreasonable, a plaintiff "must prove
    that it is likely to keep at least one significant competitor of
    the defendant from doing business in a relevant market
    . . . . [and] must prove that the probable (not certain) effect
    of the exclusion will be to raise prices above (and therefore
    reduce output below) the competitive level, or otherwise
    injure competition." Roland Mach. Co. v. Dresser Indus.,
    Inc., 
    749 F.2d 380
    , 394 (7th Cir. 1984).
    According to the majority, "there was not enough
    foreclosure of the market to have an anticompetitive effect,"
    because "LePage's total drop in market share was only
    21%." Maj. Op. at 26.12 The majority summarily concludes,
    "[I]n view of LePage's two thirds share of the private label
    _________________________________________________________________
    11. At trial, LePage's presented the testimony of James Kowieski, its
    former senior vice president of sales, who described LePage's efforts
    following Kmart's rejection of its bid. LePage's made a desperate second
    sales presentation attended by its president, App. at 957 ("I felt that it
    was very critical to our company's success or failure, so I insured that
    Mr. Les Baggett, our president, attended the meeting with me."), where
    LePage's vainly offered additional price concessions, App. at 959 ("We
    went through the cost savings, the benefits, and we came up with some,
    again, price concessions, and some programs of a special buy once a
    year, because, I mean, as far as we were concerned, we were on our last
    leg.").
    12. In fact, LePage's market share dropped 35% from 1992 to 1997. In
    1992, LePage's net sales constituted 14.44% of the total transparent tape
    market. By 1997, LePage's sales has fallen to 9.35%. Sealed App. at 489.
    59
    business, its attack on exclusivity agreements seems rather
    attenuated." Id. at 26.
    The first problem with this conclusion is that the
    "market" share to which the majority refers is LePage's
    market share in private-label tape. Maj. Op. at 26. But the
    agreed upon relevant market is for transparent tape in the
    United States. In that market, where 3M is a monopolist
    enjoying better than a ninety percent share, LePage's had a
    much smaller share -- approximately nine percent by 1997.
    In that market, LePage's claim of exclusion does not at all
    appear "rather attenuated."
    Furthermore, the majority's conclusion is inconsistent
    with both this court's decision in Barr and the Supreme
    Court's decision in Tampa Electric, on which both Barr and
    the majority rely. In Barr, we observed"the degree of
    market foreclosure is only one of the factors in determining
    the legality of an exclusive dealing arrangement." Barr, 978
    F.3d at 111. The Barr court looked for the additional factors
    in the qualitative substantiality test enunciated by the
    Supreme Court in Tampa Electric. The majority entirely
    omits analysis of the qualitative substantiality test.
    According to that test,
    [I]t is necessary to weigh the probable effect of the
    contract on the relevant area of effective competition,
    taking into account the relative strength of the parties,
    the proportionate volume of commerce involved in
    relation to the total volume of commerce in the relevant
    market area, and the probable immediate and future
    effects which pre-emption of that share of the market
    might have on effective competition therein.
    Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 329
    ; see also Barr, 
    978 F.2d at 111
     (quoting same). Had the majority applied this test, it
    would have been far more difficult for it to conclude 3M's
    conduct was not anticompetitive.
    Finally, the majority approvingly quotes the statement in
    the Microsoft opinion of the Court of Appeals for the District
    of Columbia that "[b]ecause an exclusive deal affecting a
    small fraction of a market clearly cannot have the requisite
    harmful effect upon competition, the requirement of a
    significant degree of foreclosure serves a useful screening
    60
    function." Maj. Op. at 26 (quoting United States v. Microsoft
    Corp., 
    253 F.3d 34
    , 69 (D.C. Cir. 2001)). However, in the
    Microsoft opinion, the court had concluded that Microsoft,
    a monopolist in the operating system market, also
    foreclosed rivals in the browser market from a "substantial
    percentage of the available opportunities for browser
    distribution," through the use of exclusive contracts with
    key distributors. Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 70
    . Microsoft kept
    usage of its competitor's browser below "the critical level
    necessary for [its rival] . . . to pose a real threat to
    [Microsoft's] monopoly." 
    Id. at 71
    . The Microsoft opinion
    does not specify what percentage of the browser market
    Microsoft locked up -- merely that, in one of the two
    primary distribution channels for browsers, Microsoft had
    exclusive arrangements with most of the top distributors.
    
    Id. at 70-71
    . Significantly, the Microsoft court observed that
    Microsoft's exclusionary conduct violated S 2"even though
    the contracts foreclose less than the roughly 40% or 50%
    share usually required in order to establish a S 1 violation,"
    
    id. at 70
    , a point the majority appears to have overlooked.
    The Microsoft court properly treated exclusionary conduct
    by a monopolist as more likely to be anticompetitive than
    ordinary S 1 exclusionary conduct. The key exclusionary
    conduct inquiry in Microsoft was whether the monopolist's
    conduct excludes a competitor entirely from essential
    facilities13 which would permit it to achieve the efficiencies
    _________________________________________________________________
    13. This is a version of the bottleneck, or essential facilities problem,
    applied in the monopoly context. In one of the two distribution channels
    available for browsers, Microsoft had locked up almost all the high
    volume distributors. 
    Id.
     In the seminal Terminal Railroad case, an
    association of railroad operators locked up the cheapest route across the
    Mississippi river, the sole railroad bridge crossing at St. Louis. United
    States v. Terminal R.R. Ass'n, 
    224 U.S. 383
     (1912). The Supreme Court
    determined that the defendant's agreement to provide access to the
    bridge to other railroads on discriminatory terms violated S 1 of the
    Sherman Act.
    In the transparent tape market, superstores like Kmart and Wal-Mart
    provide a crucial facility to any manufacturer--they supply high volume
    sales with the concomitant substantially reduced distribution costs. By
    wielding its monopoly power in transparent tape and its vast array of
    product lines, 3M foreclosed LePage's from that critical bridge to
    consumers which superstores provide, namely, cheap, high volume
    supply lines.
    61
    of scale necessary to threaten the monopoly. Id. at 70-71;
    see, e.g., Thomas Krattenmaker & Steven Salop,
    Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Achieve
    Power Over Price, 
    96 Yale L.J. 209
    , 214 (1986) ("First one
    should ask whether the conduct of the challenged firm
    unavoidably and significantly increases the costs of its
    competitors. If so, one should then ask whether raising
    rivals' costs enables the excluding firm to exercise
    monopoly power."); see also Aspen Skiing, 
    472 U.S. at
    604-
    05 & n.31 (observing exclusionary conduct is
    anticompetitive when it disrupts distribution patterns,
    rendering competitors less efficient). In Microsoft, it was
    enough that Microsoft had foreclosed enough distribution
    links to undermine the survival of Netscape as a viable
    competitor. As discussed above, 3M's exclusionary conduct
    cut LePage's off from key retail pipelines necessary to
    permit it to compete profitably. This left 3M free to exercise
    its monopoly power unchallenged.
    As I noted at the outset, the effect of 3M's conduct in
    strengthening its monopoly position by destroying
    competition by LePage's in second-tier tape is most
    apparent when 3M's various activities are considered as a
    whole. For example, 3M's bundling of its products via its
    rebate programs reinforced the exclusionary effect of those
    programs. Together with 3M's conduct designed to achieve
    actual or virtual sole supplier status the conduct met the
    criteria for a S 2 violation. There is significant evidence to
    support the jury's verdict to that effect.
    C.
    Business Reasons Justification
    The majority seeks to excuse 3M's exclusionary conduct
    on the ground that it acted in furtherance of its economic
    interests. However, the fact that the Court looked at
    whether defendant's actions were carried out for"valid
    business reasons" in Eastman Kodak, 
    504 U.S. at 483
    ,
    does not mean that whatever is good for 3M is permissible
    under S 2 of the Sherman Act. As one Court of Appeals has
    explained:
    62
    In general, a business justification is valid if it relates
    directly or indirectly to the enhancement of consumer
    welfare. Thus, pursuit of efficiency and quality control
    might be legitimate competitive reasons . . . , while the
    desire to maintain a monopoly market share, or thwart
    the entry of competitors would not.
    Data Gen. Corp. v. Grumman Sys. Support Corp. , 
    36 F.3d 1147
    , 1183 (1st Cir. 1994) (citing Eastman Kodak , 
    504 U.S. at 483
    ; Aspen Skiing, 
    472 U.S. at 608-11
    ).
    The majority states that "[u]nlike the situation of the
    defendant in Aspen, 3M's pricing structure and bundled
    rebates were not necessarily contrary to its economic
    interests, as they likely increased its sales. " Maj. Op. at 24
    (emphasis added). Of course a monopolist seeks to further
    its economic interests, and may do so by increasing its
    sales. It is not surprising that a monopolist's sales, as
    measured by market share, may increase when it engages
    in exclusionary conduct. Thus, for example, exclusionary
    practice has been defined as "a method by which a firm . . .
    trades a part of its monopoly profits, at least temporarily,
    for a larger market share, by making it unprofitable for
    other sellers to compete with it." Richard A. Posner,
    Antitrust Law 28 (1976). Once a monopolist achieves its
    goal by excluding potential competitors, it can then
    increase the price of its product to the point at which it will
    maximize its profit. This price is invariably higher than the
    price determined in a competitive market. That is one of the
    principal reasons why monopolization violates the antitrust
    laws. The fact that 3M acted to benefit its own economic
    interests is hardly a reason to overturn the jury's finding
    that it violated S 2 of the Sherman Act.
    The defendant bears the burden of "persuad[ing] the jury
    that its conduct was justified by any normal business
    purpose." Aspen, 
    472 U.S. at 608
    . The majority
    hypothesizes what it terms "several other potential
    `procompetitive' or valid business reasons for 3M's . . .
    bundled rebates." Maj. Op. at 24 (emphasis added). It refers
    to the "efficiency in having single invoices, single shipments
    and uniform pricing programs for various products." 
    Id.
     The
    majority cites to no testimony or evidence in the fifty-five
    volume appendix that would support these "efficiencies,"
    63
    even though some customers may have found consolidated
    billing desirable. It is highly unlikely that transparent tape
    was shipped along with retail auto products or home
    improvement products to customers such as Staples or
    that, if it were, the savings stemming from the joint
    shipment approaches the multi-million dollars 3M returned
    to customers in bundled rebates.
    There is considerable evidence in the record that 3M
    entered the private-label market only to "kill it." See, e.g.,
    Sealed App. at 809 (statement by 3M executive in internal
    memorandum that "I don't want private label 3M products
    to be successful in the office supply business, its
    distribution or our consumers/end users"). The majority
    concedes that the record supports a finding that 3M"was
    attempting to eliminate the private label category of
    transparent tape" and that "in view of 3M's dominance in
    brand tape, . . . it was rational for it to want the sale of
    tape to be concentrated in that category of the market."
    Maj. Op. at 28.
    That is precisely what S 2 of the Sherman Act outlaws by
    covering conduct that maintains a monopoly. Maintaining a
    monopoly is not the type of valid business reason that will
    excuse exclusionary conduct. The majority usurps the
    jury's province to decide the facts, despite sufficient
    evidence to support the jury's verdict.
    3M used its market power over transparent tape, backed
    by its considerable catalog of products, to entrench its
    monopoly, to the detriment of LePage's, its only serious
    competitor. The jury's verdict reflects its view that 3M's
    bundled rebate programs and other exclusionary conduct
    made it difficult for LePage's to compete on the merits--that
    is to say, on price, quality, or customer service.
    III.
    ATTEMPTED MONOPOLIZATION
    The jury returned a verdict for LePage's against 3M on
    LePage's claim that 3M illegally attempted to maintain its
    monopoly. The District Court overturned the jury's
    64
    attempted monopolization verdict on the ground that"an
    attempted maintenance of monopoly power" is "inherently
    illogical." Le Page's Inc. v. 3M, No. 97-3783, 
    2000 WL 280350
    , at *2. The District Court reasoned that:
    [a]ny "attempt claim" rests on the underlying theory
    that the defendant has failed to achieve its goal, which
    in this case is maintenance of monopoly power. But, if
    the defendant has failed to achieve its goal of
    maintaining monopoly power, then it follows that the
    defendant lacks monopoly power. Lacking any
    monopoly power to maintain, the defendant cannot be
    held liable for "attempted maintenance of monopoly
    power."
    
    Id.
     The majority holds that the District Court's reasoning
    was erroneous but nonetheless affirms.
    I agree that the District Court erred in this respect.
    Courts and commentators have repeatedly found that
    defendants can be guilty of both monopolization and
    attempted monopolization claims arising out of the same
    conduct. See, e.g., Am. Tobacco Co. v. United States, 
    328 U.S. 781
    , 783 (1946) (affirming judgment that defendants
    were guilty of monopolization and attempted
    monopolization); Earl Kintner, 2 Federal Antitrust Law
    S 13.1 n.5 (1980). 3M does not dispute this point.
    The elements of a S 2 attempted monopolization claim
    are: (1) predatory or anticompetitive conduct; (2) specific
    intent to monopolize; and (3) dangerous probability of
    achieving monopoly power. See Ideal Dairy Farms, Inc. v.
    John Labatt, Ltd., 
    90 F.3d 737
    , 750 (3d Cir. 1996). The law
    is clear that a defendant possessing monopoly power can be
    found liable under S 2 for attempted monopolization where
    that defendant either has failed in its attempt to maintain
    its monopoly or has not yet succeeded in its attempt to
    maintain its monopoly. As I have discussed above, 3M (1)
    engaged in anticompetitive conduct, (2) specifically intended
    to monopolize and (3) had a dangerous likelihood of
    success.
    The analysis by the Supreme Court of the S 2 attempted
    monopolization claim in Lorain Journal Co. v. United States,
    
    342 U.S. 143
     (1951), is precisely applicable here. In that
    65
    case, the defendant newspaper had monopoly power and
    sought to use exclusive dealing contracts with advertiser-
    customers to destroy its budding rival, a local radio station.
    Although the defendant had not actually accomplished its
    objective, the Court held that "a single newspaper, already
    enjoying a substantial monopoly in its area, violates the
    `attempt to monopolize' clause of S 2 when it uses its
    monopoly to destroy threatened competition." 
    Id. at 154
    .
    Similar analysis was applied in the Fifth Circuit decision
    in Multiflex, Inc. v. Samuel Moore & Co., 
    709 F.2d 980
     (5th
    Cir. 1983), where the court characterized plaintiff 's S 2
    claim as charging defendant with "an unsuccessful attempt
    to maintain monopoly power through anticompetitive acts."
    
    Id. at 991
    . The court held that "[s]uch a claim could
    constitute the offense of actual monopolization under
    section 2 [but that] [i]t fails as actual monopolization only
    because [defendant's] efforts were unsuccessful." 
    Id.
    LePage's has charged defendant 3M with the same conduct,
    i.e. "attempted maintenance of monopoly power."
    The majority's efforts to distinguish these cases are
    unpersuasive.
    There appears to be some division in the courts as to
    whether an attempted monopolization claim merges into a
    monopolization claim when the defendant has been
    successful. The distinction is merely a semantic one. The
    key issue is whether a company with market power has
    taken steps, whether successful or unsuccessful, to destroy
    incipient competition. If it has, it violated S 2. That a
    competitor need not demonstrate actual effect on itself, but
    only show the danger of that effect, is seminal toS 2
    jurisprudence. As the Supreme Court observed over half a
    century ago, "[i]t is . . . unreasonable, per se, to foreclose
    competitors from any substantial market. . . . The antitrust
    laws are as much violated by the prevention of competition
    as by its destruction. . . . It follows a fortiori that the use
    of monopoly power, however lawfully acquired, to foreclose
    competition, to gain a competitive advantage, or to destroy
    a competitor, is unlawful." United States v. Griffith, 
    334 U.S. 100
    , 107 (1948) (quotations and citations omitted).
    I understand the majority's rejection of LePage's
    attempted monopolization claim to follow its rejection of
    66
    LePage's monopolization claim because the majority
    concludes that the rebates and exclusive dealing contracts
    were not predatory and anticompetitive. Because I disagree
    with the majority on this central issue, I also disagree with
    its disposition of LePage's attempted monopolization claim.
    IV.
    CONCLUSION
    The majority fails to look to 3M's conduct as a whole,
    imposes hurdles for plaintiffs in antitrust actions to the
    detriment of consumers and competition generally, and fails
    to acknowledge that sufficient evidence underlies the jury's
    verdict based on 3M's conduct. I would reinstate the jury's
    verdict on both LePage's monopolization and attempted
    monopolization claims.
    A True Copy:
    Teste:
    Clerk of the United States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    67
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 0-1368

Filed Date: 1/16/2002

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/13/2015

Authorities (51)

Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp. , 21 F. Supp. 2d 923 ( 1998 )

Data General v. Grumman Systems , 36 F.3d 1147 ( 1994 )

aspen-highlands-skiing-corporation-a-delaware-corporation-cross-appellant , 738 F.2d 1509 ( 1984 )

Virgin Atlantic Airways Limited v. British Airways Plc , 257 F.3d 256 ( 2001 )

Berkey Photo, Inc., Plaintiff-Appellee-Cross v. Eastman ... , 603 F.2d 263 ( 1979 )

U.S. Healthcare, Inc., Etc. v. Healthsource, Inc., Etc. , 986 F.2d 589 ( 1993 )

Smithkline Corporation v. Eli Lilly and Company , 575 F.2d 1056 ( 1978 )

Advo, Inc. v. Philadelphia Newspapers, Inc., D/B/A ... , 51 F.3d 1191 ( 1995 )

Elliot Fineman the Industry Network System, Inc. v. ... , 980 F.2d 171 ( 1992 )

Barr Laboratories, Inc. v. Abbott Laboratories , 978 F.3d 98 ( 1992 )

John D. Shade v. Great Lakes Dredge & Dock Company , 154 F.3d 143 ( 1998 )

joseph-rossi-rossi-florence-corp-rossi-roofing-inc-v-standard-roofing , 156 F.3d 452 ( 1998 )

Northeastern Telephone Company v. American Telephone and ... , 651 F.2d 76 ( 1981 )

city-of-groton-city-of-norwich-borough-of-jewett-city-second-taxing , 662 F.2d 921 ( 1981 )

Borough of Lansdale v. Philadelphia Electric Company , 692 F.2d 307 ( 1982 )

Jerald E. Bloom v. Consolidated Rail Corporation , 41 F.3d 911 ( 1994 )

houser-dennis-l-and-houser-natalie-a-dba-colonial-theatre , 845 F.2d 1225 ( 1988 )

danny-kresky-enterprises-corporation-and-cross-appellee-v-larry-magid , 716 F.2d 206 ( 1983 )

ideal-dairy-farms-inc-v-john-labatt-ltd-john-labatt-inc-tuscan-dairy , 90 F.3d 737 ( 1996 )

lightning-lube-inc-laser-lube-a-new-jersey-corporation-v-witco , 4 F.3d 1153 ( 1993 )

View All Authorities »