Cloverland Green v. PA Milk Marketing Bd , 462 F.3d 249 ( 2006 )


Menu:
  •                                                                                                                            Opinions of the United
    2006 Decisions                                                                                                             States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    9-1-2006
    Cloverland Green v. PA Milk Marketing Bd
    Precedential or Non-Precedential: Precedential
    Docket No. 05-2336
    Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2006
    Recommended Citation
    "Cloverland Green v. PA Milk Marketing Bd" (2006). 2006 Decisions. Paper 402.
    http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2006/402
    This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 2006 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
    PRECEDENTIAL
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    No. 05-2336
    CLOVERLAND-GREEN SPRING DAIRIES, INC.,
    Appellant
    THOMAS E. MCGLINCHEY; GERTRUDE GIORGINI;
    SUE A. SPIGLER, (“Milk Consumers”) (Intervenors in D.C.)
    v.
    PENNSYLVANIA MILK MARKETING BOARD;
    BOYD WOLFF*, in his capacity as member of the Board;
    LUKE F. BRUBAKER, Individually and
    as member of the Board;
    BARBARA GRUMBINE*, in her capacity as
    member of the Board;
    BOYD WOLFF, Individually;
    BARBARA GRUMBINE, Individually
    PENNSYLVANIA ASSOCIATION OF MILK DEALERS
    (Intervenors in D.C.)
    (*Amended - See Clerk’s Order dated 6/29/05)
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Middle District of Pennsylvania
    (D.C. Civil Action No. 99-cv-00487)
    District Judge: Honorable Yvette Kane
    Argued June 8, 2006
    Before: AMBRO, FUENTES
    and NYGAARD, Circuit Judges
    (Opinion filed: September 1, 2006)
    Scott T. Wyland, Esquire (Argued)
    Kevin J. McKeon, Esquire
    Hawke, McKeon, Sniscak & Kennard
    100 North Tenth Street
    P.O. Box 1778
    Garrisburg, PA 17105
    Counsel for Appellant
    Wendy M. Yoviene, Esquire
    Charles M. English, Jr., Esquire (Argued)
    Glenn C. Kennett, Esquire
    Thelen, Reid & Priest LLP
    701 Eighth Street, N.W.
    Washington, D.C. 20001
    Counsel for Appellees
    
    2 Allen C
    . Warshaw, Esquire
    Buchanan Ingersoll & Rooney PC
    17 North Second Street, 15th Floor
    Harrisburg, PA 17101
    Counsel for Intervenors
    PA Assoc. of Milk Dealers
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    AMBRO, Circuit Judge
    This case, on appeal for the second time to our Court,
    concerns whether Pennsylvania’s minimum wholesale prices for
    fluid milk violate the dormant Commerce Clause of our
    Constitution. In our first opinion, we held that the District Court
    improperly granted summary judgment to the Pennsylvania Milk
    Marketing Board (“Board”),1 and remanded to the District Court
    for a trial. See Cloverland-Green Spring Dairies, Inc. v. Pa.
    Milk Mktg. Bd., 
    298 F.3d 201
    (3d Cir. 2002) (hereafter
    “Cloverland I”). The District Court then conducted a six-day
    1
    Although the members of the Board have been sued
    individually in their official capacities, we refer to them as the
    “Board”. We also note that the Pennsylvania Association of
    Milk Dealers intervened as a defendant in the District Court in
    support of the Board, and filed an appellee’s brief on this appeal.
    For simplicity, we shall refer to all appellees as the “Board”.
    3
    bench trial and ruled in favor of the Board. We now affirm.
    I. Milk Economics
    Before addressing the facts of this case, we believe it
    helpful (if not necessary) to explain how milk pricing works.
    On the surface, the path of milk from the cow to the consumer
    seems simple. A farmer (commonly called a “producer”) sells
    raw milk to a processor (or “handler”). The handler processes
    the raw milk into fluid milk or other dairy products, packages it,
    and sells the product to a retailer. The retailer, in turn, sells to
    the consumer.
    Yet this apparent simplicity is deceptive. Federal and
    state regulations regarding the sale of milk make “Byzantine” an
    apt, and none too pejorative, description. See, e.g., Lansing
    Dairy, Inc. v. Espy, 
    39 F.3d 1339
    , 1344 (6th Cir. 1994) (“[T]he
    system established by [federal law] to regulate the sale of milk
    is of labyrinthine complexity.”); Kenneth W. Bailey, Marketing
    and Pricing of Milk and Dairy Products in the United States 109
    (1997) (noting that the rules governing milk prices are “mind-
    boggling”);2 Jim Chen, Around the World in Eighty Centiliters,
    2
    We note that Professor Bailey testified as an expert witness
    for the Board in the District Court. We do not, of course, cite
    his textbook herein as a substitute for his testimony, but rather
    as a reference for the workings of the federal milk pricing
    system, which the parties do not dispute.
    4
    15 Minn. J. Int’l L. 1, 6 (2006) (describing the federal milk
    pricing structure as “outlandishly complex”).3 This complexity,
    3
    As Judge Jerome Frank of the United States Court of
    Appeals for the Second Circuit once observed (in terms more
    gilded than our era musters):
    [T]he ‘milk problem’ is exquisitely
    complicated. The city-dweller or
    poet who regards the cow as a
    symbol of bucolic serenity is
    indeed naive. From the udders of
    that placid animal flows a bland
    liquid indispensable to human
    health but often provoking as much
    human strife and nastiness as strong
    alcoholic beverages. . . . The[se]
    difficulties have given rise to much
    legislation and are reflected in
    many judicial decisions. . . . The
    milk problem is so vast that fully to
    comprehend it would require an
    almost universal knowledge
    ranging from geology, biology,
    chemistry and medicine to the
    niceties of the legislative, judicial
    and administrative processes of
    government. It affects an industry
    immense in scope, for dairying is
    [one of] the largest . . . branch[es]
    of agriculture in this country.
    5
    and the large sums of money at stake,4 have spawned an
    extraordinary amount of litigation. It has been estimated that
    “no other commodity in the United States has been involved in
    as many legal challenges in regard to how it is marketed” as
    milk. 
    Bailey, supra, at 3
    .
    Two systems of milk price regulation concern us on this
    appeal: the federal system and Pennsylvania’s state system. We
    describe each in turn.
    A.     Federal Milk Price Regulation
    1.     Unique Nature of Milk
    Milk is a unique agricultural commodity. The Supreme
    Court has recognized “two distinctive and essential phenomena
    of the milk industry[:] a basic two-price structure that permits a
    higher return for the same product, depending on its ultimate
    use, and the cyclical characteristic of production.” Zuber v.
    Allen, 
    396 U.S. 168
    , 172 (1969); see also Lehigh Valley
    Farmers v. Block, 
    829 F.2d 409
    , 411 (3d Cir. 1987) (same). The
    Queensboro Farms Prods. v. Wickard, 
    137 F.2d 969
    , 974-75 (2d
    Cir. 1943).
    4
    In 2003, for example, U.S. dairy farmers sold about 19.7
    billion gallons of milk for more than $21 billion. Gen.
    Accounting Office, Dairy Industry: Information on Milk Prices,
    Factors Affecting Prices, and Dairy Policy Options 1 (2004).
    6
    first phenomenon derives from the fact that raw milk may be put
    to two general uses by handlers: fluid milk for drinking and
    manufactured dairy products such as cheese, butter, and ice
    cream. See 
    Zuber, 396 U.S. at 172
    . Fluid milk is more
    expensive for handlers to produce and market because it is
    highly perishable (a gallon of milk must ordinarily be marketed
    to the consumer within two days of milking), requires more
    sanitation and processing than other dairy products, and is
    heavier and thus more expensive to transport. See 
    id. at 173
    n.3;
    
    Bailey, supra, at 3
    4, 46, 109-10; Alden C. Manchester & Don P.
    Blayney, Econ. Research Serv., U.S. Dep’t of Agric., Milk
    Pricing in the United States 2 (2001), available at
    http://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/aib761/aib761.pdf. Fluid
    milk for drinking therefore costs the consumer more per pound
    than milk that has been manufactured into other dairy products,
    and the partial inelasticity of demand for fluid milk (viewed as
    a dietary staple by many Americans) means profit margins on
    fluid milk sales may also be higher. See 
    Bailey, supra, at 3
    4;
    see also Smyser v. Block, 
    760 F.2d 514
    , 516 (3d Cir. 1985)
    (“Milk that is ultimately used for fluid purposes has traditionally
    commanded a higher price than milk of the same grade and
    quality used for manufactured products. This difference is not
    entirely accounted for by differences in cost.”).
    Farmers also produce two “grades” of marketable raw
    milk. Grade A milk is fit for drinking, and therefore can be
    processed into fluid milk or manufactured products, while Grade
    B milk is not fit for drinking but may be used in other dairy
    7
    products. Manchester & 
    Blayney, supra, at 2
    ; David L. Baumer,
    Federal Regulation of Milk Production and Sale is Growing at
    the Expense of State Authority, 12 J. Agric. Tax. & L. 36, 38-39
    (1990). Not surprisingly, in an entirely unregulated market,
    handlers would have an incentive to produce manufactured dairy
    products using Grade B milk and reserve as much Grade A milk
    as possible for the more lucrative fluid milk market. At the
    same time, farmers would want to be paid a higher price for
    their Grade A milk than for Grade B milk, but handlers would
    want to pay less for Grade A milk they intended to put to use in
    manufactured dairy products (i.e., surplus Grade A milk they
    cannot sell as fluid milk).
    The complexity deepens when we consider the second
    phenomenon identified in Zuber: the cyclical nature of milk
    production. Demand for fluid milk, though somewhat inelastic
    with respect to price, is temporally cyclic, with demand higher
    in the fall and winter months than in the spring and summer
    months. See 
    Zuber, 396 U.S. at 172
    -73; 
    Bailey, supra, at 3
    4; see
    also John R. Snyder, A Summary: Political and Economic
    Analysis of Milk Marketing, 1980-81 Agric. L.J. 297, 310-11.
    Unfortunately, cows do not work this way, and produce more
    milk in the spring and summer (known as the “flush” season)
    than in the fall and winter (the “short-supply” season).
    Manchester & 
    Blayney, supra, at 2
    ; 
    Snyder, supra, at 310-11
    .
    Thus, “it [is] necessary to coordinate a supply that is rising when
    fluid milk demand is falling.” Manchester & 
    Blayney, supra, at 2
    . Otherwise, handlers would attempt to “take advantage of this
    8
    surplus to obtain bargains [from producers] during glut periods,”
    which would lead farmers to increase production to maintain a
    steady income, “and the disequilibrium snowballs.” 
    Zuber, 396 U.S. at 173
    ; 
    Smyser, 760 F.2d at 516
    (“In an unregulated market
    ‘cutthroat’ competition for more profitable fluid milk sales can
    lead to an overall decline in prices.”); see also 
    Bailey, supra, at 110
    (explaining that the unique characteristics of the milk
    industry, if unregulated, lead to “chaotic marketing conditions”).
    2.      The Federal System
    Federal regulation of the nation’s dairy industry began in
    earnest in the 1930s, when falling prices caused by the Great
    Depression led to “utter chaos” in the milk market. 
    Zuber, 396 U.S. at 174
    . The first attempt at regulation was the Agricultural
    Adjustment Act (“AAA”) of 1933, 48 Stat. 31, which
    empowered the Secretary of Agriculture to promulgate
    emergency licensing requirements in the dairy industry to
    regulate output and price. See 
    Zuber, 396 U.S. at 174
    -75. The
    Supreme Court’s decision in A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v.
    United States, 
    295 U.S. 495
    (1935), however, struck down a
    similarly broad delegation of rulemaking authority under the
    National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933, 48 Stat. 195, and
    Congress acted to protect regulation of the dairy market by first
    amending the AAA and then enacting the Agricultural
    Marketing Agreement Act (“AMAA”) of 1937, 50 Stat. 246,
    which replaced the emergency measures with a permanent
    system of milk regulation. See 
    Zuber, 396 U.S. at 175-76
    ;
    9
    Defiance Milk Prods. Co. v. Lyng, 
    857 F.2d 1065
    , 1066-67 (6th
    Cir. 1988).
    Under the AMAA, the Secretary of Agriculture is
    empowered to regulate the nation’s milk markets by issuing
    “orders” that regulate prices in defined geographic areas. See 7
    U.S.C. § 608c(1); 
    Defiance, 857 F.2d at 1067
    ; Lehigh 
    Valley, 829 F.2d at 411
    . These orders are meant to ensure “a sufficient
    quantity of pure and wholesome milk to meet current needs and
    further to assure a level of farm income adequate to maintain
    productive capacity sufficient to meet anticipated future needs.”
    7 U.S.C. § 608c(18). Although their number has varied over the
    years, there are currently ten federal milk marketing order
    areas.5 See 7 C.F.R. pts. 1001-1135; U.S. Dep’t of Agric.,
    5
    These are the Northeast, Appalachian, Southeast, Florida,
    Mideast, Upper Midwest, Central, Southwest, Arizona, and
    Pacific Northwest orders.        See U.S. Dep’t of Agric.,
    Consolidated Milk Marketing Order Areas, available at
    http://www.ams.usda.gov/dairy/dymap.htm. There are also
    several parts of the country that are not regulated by a federal
    order, including parts of Idaho, New York, Pennsylvania, and
    North and South Dakota, and most or all of California, Maine,
    Montana, Nevada, Utah, Virginia, and Wyoming. 
    Id. Confusingly, the
    orders are often referred to by a number
    that corresponds to the implementing regulation that defines the
    order. So, for example, the Northeast order (encompassing all
    or part of Vermont, New Hampshire, Massachusetts, Rhode
    Island, Connecticut, New York, Pennsylvania, New Jersey,
    10
    Consolidated Milk Marketing Order Areas, available at
    http://www.ams.usda.gov/dairy/dymap.htm.          Within these
    orders, the Secretary sets prices at which raw milk may be sold.
    There are two main features of this pricing structure that merit
    explanation.
    Handlers pay for their milk according to a classified
    pricing arrangement. See 7 U.S.C. § 608c(5)(A). Grade A raw
    milk is classified according to its end use. Class I milk is fluid
    milk for drinking, while other classes (II, III, and IV) are
    assigned to raw milk used in various manufactured products. 7
    C.F.R. § 1000.40; see West Lynn Creamery, Inc. v. Healy, 
    512 U.S. 186
    , 189 n.1 (1994). It is not necessary for our purposes to
    explain in detail the pricing mechanism for each class, see, e.g.,
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.50; we simply note that handlers pay more for
    Grade A raw milk they intend to put to use as Class I milk than
    they do for Grade A raw milk they intend to put to use as Class
    II, III, or IV milk.6 See Lansing 
    Dairy, 39 F.3d at 1344
    ; Smyser,
    Delaware, Maryland, and the District of Columbia, as well as a
    few counties in Northern Virginia) is defined in 7 C.F.R. part
    1001, and is known commonly as “Order 1”. The Mideast order
    (encompassing all or part of Michigan, Indiana, Ohio, Kentucky,
    West Virginia, and Pennsylvania) is defined in 7 C.F.R. part
    1033, and is known commonly as “Order 33”.
    6
    To be clear, however, the different classes are merely
    administrative distinctions to take account of the fact that
    handlers charge different wholesale prices for fluid milk and
    
    11 760 F.2d at 516
    .
    Producers do not, however, receive more or less money
    for raw milk based on the handler’s use. Instead, producers
    receive a uniform “blend” price that is essentially a weighted
    average of the price of all classes of milk sold in the region. See
    7 U.S.C. 608c(5)(B); 
    Zuber, 396 U.S. at 177
    ; Lehigh 
    Valley, 829 F.2d at 411
    . This system “eliminate[s] the potential
    situation where one producer, who sold milk to a fluid
    processor, would get a higher milk price than his neighbor who
    sold to a cheese plant.” 
    Bailey, supra, at 113
    ; see also Lehigh
    
    Valley, 829 F.2d at 411
    -12 (“By mandating that producers
    within a market area receive a uniform price based on the use of
    milk within the area, the [AMAA] eliminates the incentive for
    dairy farmers to attempt to compete with their neighbors through
    lowering their prices.”).
    Of course, this would ordinarily lead to a situation in
    which handlers dealing mostly in lower classes of milk
    essentially subsidize those dealing mostly in Class I milk,
    because the blend price paid to the producer will be more than,
    say, the classified price of Class IV milk, but lower than the
    classified price of Class I milk. To compensate for this, the
    regulations establish a “Producer Settlement Fund,” into which
    manufactured products. The raw milk is all Grade A, and is
    alike in all respects except the artificially created class
    distinction that depends on the use to which the milk is put.
    12
    handlers who have underpaid contribute an amount equal to the
    difference between the blend price and classified price, which is
    then distributed to handlers who have overpaid. See 7 C.F.R.
    § 1000.70; Lansing 
    Dairy, 39 F.3d at 1344
    ; 
    Smyser, 760 F.2d at 516
    .
    By charging handlers less for Grade A raw milk used in
    storable dairy products like cheese and butter than for raw milk
    used as Class I drinking milk, while assuring that producers are
    paid the same no matter the use to which the raw milk is put,
    handlers have an incentive to use surplus Grade A milk in
    manufactured products during the glut months, and producers
    maintain a more stable income year-round. This, in turn, guards
    against overproduction in the flush season. Moreover, the
    Producer Settlement Fund relieves pressures on handlers to deal
    exclusively in fluid milk to the detriment of other dairy
    products.
    B.     Pennsylvania Milk Price Regulation
    Although state control of milk markets has declined
    significantly in the wake of federal regulation, particularly
    through court challenges, it survives in a few states, including
    Pennsylvania. See 
    Bailey, supra, at 205
    , 210; see generally
    
    Baumer, supra
    . Parts of Pennsylvania are federally regulated —
    the southeast and southcentral parts of the Commonwealth are
    under the Northeast order, and the western part of the
    Commonwealth is under the Mideast order — while other parts
    13
    are not regulated by the federal system. Pennsylvania’s system
    covers the entire Commonwealth, however.
    Under Pennsylvania’s Milk Marketing Law, 31 Pa. Cons.
    Stat. § 700j, the Board is granted “power to supervise,
    investigate and regulate the entire milk industry of th[e]
    Commonwealth, including the production, transportation,
    disposal, manufacture, processing, storage, distribution,
    delivery, handling, bailment, brokerage, consignment, purchase
    and sale of milk and milk products in th[e] Commonwealth.” 31
    Pa. Cons. Stat. § 700j-301. The statute requires that all handlers
    operating in Pennsylvania be licensed by the Board, see 
    id. § 700j-401,
    and empowers the Board to set minimum prices paid
    to producers, handlers, and retailers to “benefi[t] . . . the public
    interest [and] best protect the milk industry of the
    Commonwealth and insure a sufficient quantity of pure and
    wholesome milk to [its] inhabitants.” 
    Id. § 700j-801.
    In-state handlers who buy raw milk from in-state
    producers for in-state use must pay “over-order” prices — which
    include a premium above the applicable Class I milk prices —
    to assure producers a “reasonable return” based on the
    “conditions affecting the milk industry in each marketing area.”7
    7
    According to the Board, “the state-mandated premium has
    resulted in over 335 million additional dollars being paid to
    Pennsylvania farmers” since 1988. Pa. Milk Mktg. Bd., Fiscal
    Year Report, 2003-2004 10 (2004), available at http://
    14
    Id.; see also 
    id. § 700j-803
    (“The [B]oard shall fix, by official
    order, the minimum prices or a formula for setting of minimum
    prices to be paid by milk dealears or handlers to producers for
    milk or milk components sold or delivered or made available on
    consignment or otherwise by producers to dealers or handlers.”).
    The over-order premium only applies to sales of Class I milk.
    See Pa. Milk Mktg. Bd., Order No. A-913 (2001) (establishing
    the method for calculating the over-order premium, and
    specifying that the premium “shall be based on milk that is
    produced, processed, and utilized as Class I milk in
    Pennsylvania”).8
    Pennsylvania also exports raw milk to other states. The
    over-order price, however, does not apply to sales to out-of-state
    handlers.
    www.mmb.state.pa.us/mmb/lib/mmb/2003-2004.pdf. From July
    2003 to June 2004, the over-order premium resulted in
    Pennsylvania farmers receiving $30.8 million more than they
    would otherwise have received. 
    Id. at 13.
        8
    The Board has promulgated a complex mathematical
    formula for calculating the over-order premium. See Pa. Milk
    Mktg. Bd., Order No. A-913 (2001). It is not necessary to
    explain that process here. As of this writing, in all Pennsylvania
    milk marketing areas handlers must add $1.60 per
    hundredweight (approximately 11.6 gallons) to the price of
    Class I milk. See Pa. Milk Mktg. Bd., Order No. A-938 (2006).
    15
    All handlers who sell milk to retailers in Pennsylvania
    must do so at minimum wholesale prices that also guarantee a
    “reasonable return,” which state law defines as between 2.5%
    and 3.5% of net sales. 31 Pa. Cons. Stat. § 700j-801; see also 
    id. § 700j-802
    (“The [B]oard shall fix, by official order . . ., the
    minimum wholesale and retail prices, and may fix, by official
    order, the maximum wholesale and retail prices, to be charged
    and received by milk dealers or handlers for milk sold,
    delivered, handled or consigned within any milk marketing area
    of the Commonwealth.”).
    The Board has divided Pennsylvania into six milk
    marketing areas. Areas 1 and 4 (the Areas at issue in this
    appeal) consist of the counties in southeast and southcentral
    Pennsylvania that are also covered by the federal Northeast
    order. Area 5 consists of the counties in western Pennsylvania
    that are also covered by the federal Mideast order. The
    remaining Areas (2, 3, and 6) consist of the counties that are not
    regulated by the federal order system. See Pa. Milk Mktg. Bd.,
    Fiscal Year Report, 2003-2004 10 (2004), available at
    http://www.mmb.state.pa.us/mmb/lib/mmb/2003-2004.pdf. The
    Board sets minimum wholesale and retail prices, as well as over-
    order premiums, in each Area based on the circumstances of that
    region, and enforces the minimum prices by regular audits of
    handlers’ books. 
    Id. Anyone who
    sells milk (raw or processed)
    at a price below the mandatory minimums set by the Board is
    subject to criminal penalties, including fines or imprisonment.
    31 Pa. Cons. Stat. § 700j-1001 & 1002.
    16
    The United States Department of Agriculture (“USDA”)
    has identified several important differences between the
    Pennsylvania system and the federal orders. First, Pennsylvania
    divides milk into only two classes when calculating the price
    handlers must pay, as opposed to the four classes applicable to
    prices under federal orders. See Milk in the New England and
    Other Marketing Areas, 64 Fed. Reg. 16,026, 16,056 (Apr. 2,
    1999). As in the federal system, Class I milk in Pennsylvania is
    primarily fluid milk for drinking, but Class II milk encompasses
    all other dairy products. Second, the location where milk is
    distributed for sale determines the applicable minimum price in
    Pennsylvania, while under federal orders the price is determined
    based on the handler’s plant location. 
    Id. Third, blend
    prices
    paid to farmers under the Pennsylvania system are calculated
    based on the individual handler’s usage, and not the use of the
    various milk classes in the wider market. Id.; see also 7 Pa.
    Code § 143.11 (“Dealers shall pay their producers on a weight
    and butterfat basis as determined by the utilization of the milk
    received at each plant or receiving station.”). This includes, of
    course, the over-order premium, which is added to the Class I
    price and then (as part of the Class I price) blended with the
    Class II price to yield the handler’s “plant blend” price paid to
    its producers.
    II. Facts and Procedural History
    With this background in mind, we proceed to the facts of
    this case. Appellant Cloverland-Green Spring Dairies, Inc.
    17
    (“Cloverland”) is a milk handler located in Maryland. It buys
    approximately 90% of its raw milk from Pennsylvania
    producers, but does not sell processed fluid milk in
    Pennsylvania. In March 1999, Cloverland brought suit against
    the Board’s members in their official capacities under 42 U.S.C.
    § 1983, alleging that Pennsylvania’s milk pricing scheme
    eliminates competition based on price and, as such, nullifies
    Cloverland’s competitive advantages, thereby effectively
    barring it from Pennsylvania’s market. This, it argues, violates
    the Constitution’s dormant Commerce Clause (described in Part
    III.A below). Three individual milk consumers in Pennsylvania
    intervened as plaintiffs in the suit, and the Pennsylvania
    Association of Milk Dealers intervened as a defendant in
    support of the minimum prices.
    A.     Summary Judgment and Appeal
    The District Court granted summary judgment to the
    Board, see Cloverland-Green Spring Dairies, Inc. v. Pa. Milk
    Mktg. Bd., 
    138 F. Supp. 2d 593
    (M.D. Pa. 2001), and
    Cloverland appealed. We affirmed the grant of summary
    judgment with respect to Pennsylvania’s minimum retail prices
    (i.e., prices charged to consumers, which are not at issue on this
    appeal), but reversed with respect to the minimum wholesale
    prices. Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 205
    . Viewing all facts in the
    light most favorable to Cloverland — as required at that stage of
    the proceedings, see 
    id. — we
    held that a reasonable trier of fact
    could find (on the facts presented) that Pennsylvania’s minimum
    18
    wholesale milk prices were unconstitutional, thus precluding
    summary judgment for the Board. Specifically, we noted that
    Cloverland indicated it had evidence that it could offer prices
    below Pennsylvania’s wholesale floor. Although, based on the
    limited record available at that stage of the proceedings, it was
    not entirely clear to us why Cloverland could offer lower prices,
    
    id. at 207,
    we observed that Cloverland (as an out-of-state
    handler) is exempt from paying the over-order premium on
    Class I milk purchased from Pennsylvania producers, and thus
    its raw milk costs could be lower than similarly situated
    Pennsylvania handlers. 
    Id. at 213.
    As such, “a reasonable trier
    of fact could find that Pennsylvania’s minimum wholesale prices
    eliminate a competitive advantage enjoyed by out-of-state
    dealers like Cloverland,” which would trigger heightened
    scrutiny under the dormant Commerce Clause. 
    Id. at 213.
    Moreover, there was no evidence (at that time) that there were
    Pennsylvania firms more efficient than Cloverland, and thus the
    minimum price floors did not necessarily affect all in-state and
    out-of-state firms equally. Id.9
    9
    Indeed, on the facts Cloverland offered, it appeared to us
    that “[b]y calibrating wholesale price floors for a particular milk
    marketing area to the operating costs of average dealers in that
    area, the Commonwealth enables Pennsylvania dealers to
    operate less efficiently without fearing losses to lower-cost
    competitors like Cloverland. This aspect of Pennsylvania’s
    scheme appears to run afoul of the cardinal rule that states may
    not shield in-state businesses from out-of-state competitors.”
    Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 214
    n.17.
    19
    Even if the District Court were to conclude that
    heightened scrutiny did not apply, we held that “the record . . .
    amply supports a finding that the wholesale floors
    . . . incidentally burden interstate commerce by making it more
    difficult for out-of-state dealers to attract new business in a
    market dominated by in-state dealers,” 
    id. at 215,
    and thus the
    District Court would have to employ the balancing test set forth
    in Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 
    397 U.S. 137
    (1970), to determine
    whether the burdens on interstate commerce substantially
    outweighed the putative local benefits. Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 215
    . We held that the “the purpose asserted in the
    [Pennsylvania Milk Marketing Law’s] text deserve[d] little
    deference” in identifying the law’s benefits because no
    Pennsylvania milk processors objected to the minimum prices
    (indeed, the Pennsylvania Association of Milk Dealers
    intervened in support of the law), and the price scheme therefore
    “appear[ed] to [burden] only . . . out-of-state dealers.” 
    Id. at 216.
    Moreover, we found only “meager evidence” that the
    minimum prices were necessary to sustain Pennsylvania’s dairy
    industry — since “the federal producer price floors [appear to]
    provide ample protection against predatory pricing” in other
    states, and the Pennsylvania dairy industry was quite successful
    (indeed, it exported most of its raw milk) — and thus it seemed
    to us unlikely that the minimum prices were necessary to secure
    a supply sufficient to meet the needs of Pennsylvania’s
    residents. 
    Id. at 216-17.
    Moreover, the burdens on interstate
    commerce appeared substantial: Cloverland’s stated evidence
    suggested it was “virtually impossible to displace incumbent
    20
    dealers in Pennsylvania without offering prices below the
    Board-mandated floors.” 
    Id. at 217.
    Thus, construing all the
    facts in the light most favorable to Cloverland, the
    Commonwealth’s minimum wholesale milk prices could fail the
    Pike balancing test.
    C.     Second District Court Proceeding
    On remand, the District Court permitted full discovery
    and held a bench trial at which numerous witnesses testified.
    Based on this evidence, the Court made detailed findings of fact
    that largely contradicted the facts (viewed in the light most
    favorable to Cloverland) on which we relied in our earlier
    decision. The District Court found that Cloverland — which,
    again, buys about 90% of its raw milk from Pennsylvania
    suppliers — purchases about 35% of this milk from dairy farm
    cooperatives, which negotiate prices with Cloverland equal to
    the over-order price charged to Pennsylvania processors.
    Cloverland-Green Spring Dairies, Inc. v. Pa. Milk Mktg. Bd.,
    No. 1:CV-99-487, slip op. at 5 (M.D. Pa. 2005) (hereafter
    “Cloverland II”). The other 65% is purchased from independent
    Pennsylvania farmers, who do not charge the over-order
    premium to Cloverland because, as an out-of-state handler, it is
    exempt. 
    Id. at 6.
    The Board nonetheless offered expert
    testimony that Cloverland actually had higher raw milk costs
    and was less efficient than three of four sample dairies, which
    the Court accepted because Cloverland did not produce
    21
    sufficient countervailing evidence.10 
    Id. at 6,
    15. Thus, the
    Court found that “[a]lthough Cloverland can sell milk at a cost
    below the minimum wholesale price floor established by the
    Board, Cloverland does not have an out-of-state price or
    efficiency comparative advantage.” 
    Id. at 6.
    Indeed, the Court concluded that, even if Cloverland’s
    exemption from the over-order premium conferred an advantage
    because it is an out-of-state firm, that advantage “arises from the
    very Milk Law pricing structure [Cloverland] seeks to partially
    invalidate,” and thus, if Cloverland’s suit were successful, its
    advantage would be “ephemeral.” 
    Id. at 16.
    In the Court’s
    view, the invalidation of the wholesale price would necessarily
    lead to the abandonment of the over-order premium, which
    would make it economically unfeasible for small dairy farms to
    remain in business and thus would force them into cooperatives
    (which negotiate prices with out-of-state processors equal to the
    over-order price). 
    Id. at 15-16.
    The District Court also found that, although “[m]ost
    processors sell at or around the wholesale floor price, [thus]
    precluding appreciable amounts of competition based upon
    price,” 
    id. at 6-7,
    Cloverland failed to show that competition on
    non-price factors did not exist. Indeed, the Court found
    10
    The District Court expressly found the Board’s expert on
    milk pricing to be more credible than Cloverland’s. Cloverland
    II, slip op. at 6 n.4.
    22
    “competition among processors in quality, service, and the
    ability to bundle the delivery of non-milk based drinks,” and
    “[a]lthough price is a significant factor in competing for
    business within the Pennsylvania dairy market, twice as many
    retailers choose name recognition as the number one factor
    informing their choice of supplier.” 
    Id. at 7.
    Thus, even if
    Cloverland could compete on the basis of price, the Court found
    that it failed to prove it could penetrate the Pennsylvania market.
    Id.11 Indeed, the Court noted that Cloverland only attempted
    11
    At one point in its opinion, the District Court stated that
    “Cloverland has established that it can compete with
    Pennsylvania dealers only by selling milk at prices below the
    wholesale milk floor,” Cloverland II, slip op. at 7 (emphasis
    added), but we do not believe the Court meant what it literally
    said. In the same paragraph, the Court explained that robust
    competition exists in the Pennsylvania market on a variety of
    non-price factors, and “even were Cloverland able to establish
    that it could sell milk for the lowest price, [it] would not enjoy
    a competitive advantage that would enable it to penetrate the
    Pennsylvania dairy market.” 
    Id. (emphasis added).
    The Court
    expressly found “that the minimum price floor does not have the
    practical effect of preventing Cloverland from entering the
    Pennsylvania milk market,” 
    id. (emphasis added),
    and later
    observed that Cloverland “offered no credible evidence that it
    could in fact compete in the Pennsylvania marketplace, absent
    of the Milk law.” 
    Id. at 20.
            Under these circumstances, we are confident that the
    District Court, by typographical error or otherwise, misstated the
    intended proposition when it said Cloverland did establish the
    23
    (and failed) to solicit business from three retailers in Area 4 and
    none in Area 1, and provided no evidence that these retailers
    rejected it because of price. 
    Id. at 6,
    20.
    Thus, the District Court concluded that Cloverland failed
    to prove that the Pennsylvania Milk Marketing Law nullified
    any competitive advantage it enjoyed by virtue of being an out-
    of-state firm, and thus heightened scrutiny did not apply.
    The Court then considered whether the minimum pricing
    scheme’s incidental burdens on interstate commerce
    substantially outweighed the putative local benefits, as required
    by the Pike balancing test. It concluded that minimum
    wholesale prices confer substantial benefits on Pennsylvania’s
    dairy industry, because the federal minimums “ha[ve] not
    adequately guaranteed enough income to protect Pennsylvania
    dairy farms since 1988,” when federal deregulation lowered the
    minimums. 
    Id. at 8,
    26. Minimum wholesale prices allow
    handlers a sufficient return to enable them to pay the over-order
    premium, which in turn allows Pennsylvania’s independent
    dairy farms to survive. 
    Id. at 8,
    24. Based largely on evidence
    produced at trial regarding the abolition of minimum prices in
    California, the District Court concluded that if Pennsylvania’s
    market were dominated by a few large players, “[c]onsumer
    prices would fall in the short term, but rise heavily in the long
    term.” 
    Id. at 9,
    25. And, if small farms went out of business,
    very thing it repeatedly explained Cloverland did not establish.
    24
    the Court concluded that the “agricultural infrastructure” that
    supports the dairy industry — including “dealers, feed stores,
    veterinarians, and other business[es]” — might suffer.12 
    Id. at 9,
    26.
    In contrast, the Court found only incidental burdens on
    interstate commerce: the minimum prices simply placed
    Cloverland on the same footing as every other handler doing
    business in Pennsylvania, did not prevent interstate competition
    on non-price factors, and the dominance of incumbent handlers
    could be attributed to Pennsylvania retailers’ preference for
    doing business with local handlers “independent of regulatory
    pressures.” 
    Id. at 22.
    Thus, the Court held that, under the Pike
    test, Cloverland failed to prove a violation of the dormant
    Commerce Clause, and granted judgment in the Board’s favor.
    Cloverland appeals.13
    12
    These conclusions were based largely on the testimony of
    the Board’s experts, which the District Court expressly found
    more credible than Cloverland’s expert. Cloverland II, slip op.
    at 27.
    13
    The District Court had subject matter jurisdiction over this
    case pursuant to 28 U.S.C. §§ 1331 and 1332, and we have
    jurisdiction over the appeal pursuant to 28 U.S.C. § 1291. Our
    review of the District Court’s decision is subject to familiar
    standards: we review findings of fact for clear error (meaning
    we will reverse only if we are “left with a definite and firm
    conviction that a mistake has been committed”), and exercise
    25
    III. Analysis
    Cloverland raises two issues on appeal. It contends its
    competitive advantages require heightened scrutiny, regardless
    whether those advantages derive from its status as an out-of-
    state firm, and that the mandatory minimum wholesale prices are
    the only reason it cannot compete in the Pennsylvania market.
    Even if heightened scrutiny does not apply, Cloverland argues
    that under the Pike test the burdens on interstate commerce
    clearly outweigh any putative benefits.
    A.     The Dormant Commerce Clause
    Under the federal Constitution’s Commerce Clause,
    Congress has explicit power to “regulate Commerce . . . among
    the several States.” U.S. Const. art. I, § 8, cl. 3. This clause
    also has an implied requirement (often called the “negative” or
    “dormant” aspect of the clause) that states not “mandate
    differential treatment of in-state and out-of-state economic
    interests that benefits the former and burdens the latter.”
    Granholm v. Heald, 
    544 U.S. 460
    , 472 (2005) (internal
    quotation marks omitted); West Lynn 
    Creamery, 512 U.S. at 192-93
    (same). Under the dormant Commerce Clause, it is
    “[a]xiomatic . . . that a state cannot impede free market forces to
    shield in-state businesses from out-of-state competition.”
    plenary review over legal conclusions. Gordon v. Lewiston
    Hosp., 
    423 F.3d 184
    , 201 (3d Cir. 2005).
    26
    Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 210
    . This includes “forcing [out-of-
    state businesses] to ‘surrender whatever competitive advantages
    they may possess’” as the price of doing business in the state.
    
    Id. (quoting Brown-Forman
    Distillers Corp. v. N.Y. State Liquor
    Auth., 
    476 U.S. 573
    , 580 (1986)).
    In considering whether a state law violates the dormant
    Commerce Clause, the inquiry is twofold: a court considers first
    whether “heightened scrutiny” applies, and, if not, then
    considers whether the law is invalid under the Pike balancing
    test. See, e.g., Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 210
    -11.
    Heightened scrutiny applies when a law “discriminates
    against interstate commerce” in its purpose or effect. C & A
    Carbone, Inc. v. Town of Clarkstown, 
    511 U.S. 383
    , 390 (1994);
    Harvey & Harvey, Inc. v. County of Chester, 
    68 F.3d 788
    , 797-
    98 (3d Cir. 1995).14 The party challenging the statute has the
    burden of proving the existence of such discrimination, Harvey
    & 
    Harvey, 68 F.3d at 802
    , and the burden then shifts to the state
    to prove that “the statute serves a legitimate local purpose, and
    that this purpose could not be served as well by available
    nondiscriminatory means.” Maine v. Taylor, 
    477 U.S. 131
    , 138
    (1986); Harvey & 
    Harvey, 68 F.3d at 797
    (same). This standard
    14
    Notably, “in order to find a dormant Commerce Clause
    violation there is no requirement that discrimination must be the
    ‘primary’ purpose or effect” of the challenged state law. Harvey
    & 
    Harvey, 68 F.3d at 803
    .
    27
    renders all but the most unusual statute invalid. 
    Carbone, 511 U.S. at 393
    ; 
    Brown-Forman, 476 U.S. at 579
    (“When a state
    statute directly regulates or discriminates against interstate
    commerce, or when its effect is to favor in-state economic
    interests over out-of-state interests, we have generally struck
    down the statute without further inquiry.”); Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 210
    -11; see also Harvey & 
    Harvey, 68 F.3d at 797
    (referring to this standard as “strict scrutiny”).
    There are two general types of discrimination that a
    plaintiff may show to trigger heightened scrutiny (although they
    are not entirely distinct, and overlap in many ways). First, it
    may show that the challenged state statute has extraterritorial
    effects that adversely affect economic production (and hence
    interstate commerce) in other states, thereby forcing “producers
    or consumers in other States [to] surrender whatever competitive
    advantages they may possess” to “give local consumers an
    advantage over consumers in other states.” 
    Brown-Forman, 476 U.S. at 580
    ; see Baldwin v. G.A.F. Seelig, Inc., 
    294 U.S. 511
    ,
    521, 527 (1935) (“New York has no power to project its
    legislation into Vermont by regulating the price to be paid in
    that state for milk acquired there,” because such regulation
    “set[s] up what is equivalent to a rampart of customs duties
    designed to neutralize advantages belonging to the place of
    origin.”).
    Second, it may show that the “object [of the law] is local
    economic protectionism,” in that it disadvantages out-of-state
    28
    businesses to benefit in-state ones. 
    Carbone, 511 U.S. at 390
    ;
    see West Lynn 
    Creamery, 512 U.S. at 194-96
    (holding that a
    Massachusetts state law requiring milk processors, including
    out-of-state firms, to pay a premium to a state fund that was then
    disbursed only to in-state producers was “effectively a tax which
    makes milk produced out-of-state more expensive,” thus
    discriminating against out-of-state milk); Hunt v. Wash. State
    Apple Adver. Comm’n, 
    432 U.S. 333
    , 351-53 (1977)
    (overturning a North Carolina statute that forbade importing
    apples bearing a quality mark other than one issued by the
    USDA, because Washington’s apples bore a state quality mark
    and thus “the statute’s consequence [is] raising the costs of
    doing business in the North Carolina market for Washington
    apple growers and dealers, while leaving those of their North
    Carolina counterparts unaffected”); Polar Ice Cream &
    Creamery Co. v. Andrews, 
    375 U.S. 361
    , 375-77 (1964)
    (holding that a Florida statute requiring in-state milk processors
    to purchase raw milk from in-state producers unlawfully
    discriminated against interstate commerce).15
    15
    The Board argues that the Supreme Court’s decision in
    Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America v.
    Walsh, 
    538 U.S. 644
    (2003), stands for the proposition that two
    “separate and distinct” types of heightened scrutiny analysis
    exist (extraterritorial effect and discrimination), and that
    “extraterritorial effect” cases like Baldwin and Brown-Forman
    are not relevant to “discrimination” cases like Carbone and
    Harvey, and vice versa. Pa. Milk Mktg. Bd. Br. at 49-51.
    The Board substantially overreads Pharmaceutical
    29
    In deciding whether a state law discriminates against out-
    of-state businesses, it is immaterial whether the statute or
    ordinance also burdens some in-state businesses. See 
    Carbone, 511 U.S. at 391
    (“The ordinance is no less discriminatory
    because in-state or in-town processors are also covered by the
    prohibition.”); Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 214
    (noting that
    Carbone “‘explicitly rejected the argument that a disputed
    statute would have to favor all in-state businesses as a group —
    Research. The Supreme Court discussed the “extraterritorial
    effect” cases apart from other discrimination cases only because
    the petitioner framed its argument that way. See Pharm.
    Research, 
    538 U.S. 669-70
    . Nowhere did the Supreme Court
    suggest that the two lines of cases are mutually exclusive;
    indeed, so-called “discrimination” cases like Carbone, West
    Lynn Creamery, and Washington State Apple rely heavily on
    so-called “extraterritorial effect” cases like Baldwin, and vice
    versa. As we noted in Cloverland I, both types of cases may
    share the common element of “state laws that are facially neutral
    but have the effect of eliminating a competitive advantage
    possessed by out-of-state firms, [thus] trigger[ing] heightened
    
    scrutiny.” 298 F.3d at 211
    (citing Wash. State Apple, 
    432 U.S. 333
    , and Baldwin, 
    294 U.S. 511
    ); see also 
    id. at 212
    n.14
    (“[T]he problem with the law invalidated in Baldwin was not
    merely its extraterritorial reach, but that it had the practical
    effect of discriminating against out-of-state milk producers by
    eliminating their competitive advantage.”). Thus, while it may
    sometimes be useful to consider the two types of cases
    separately for ease of analysis, they are actually just two forms
    of discrimination, with significant overlap.
    30
    a statute may be invalid if it favors only a single or finite set of
    businesses’” (quoting Harvey & 
    Harvey, 68 F.3d at 798
    )).
    If the plaintiff does not succeed in showing that the
    purpose or effect of the state law discriminates against interstate
    commerce — but, rather, the statute “regulates even-handedly
    to effectuate a legitimate local public interest, and its effects on
    interstate commerce are only incidental” — the court must
    determine whether “the burden imposed on such commerce is
    clearly excessive in relation to the putative local benefits.” 
    Pike, 397 U.S. at 142
    ; Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 211
    (same). This
    balancing test is significantly less restrictive of state laws than
    heightened scrutiny.
    Often, “there is no clear line separating the category of
    state regulation that is virtually per se invalid under the
    Commerce Clause, and the category subject to the Pike v. Bruce
    Church balancing approach.” 
    Brown-Forman, 476 U.S. at 579
    ;
    see Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 211
    (“[S]ometimes the distinction
    between state laws subject only to Pike balancing and those that
    are nearly per se invalid is ‘hazy.’”). In determining whether
    heightened scrutiny should be applied instead of the Pike test,
    “the critical consideration is the overall effect of the statute on
    both local and interstate activity,” 
    Brown-Forman, 476 U.S. at 579
    , with special attention paid to whether a “facially neutral”
    state law “ha[s] the effect of eliminating a competitive
    advantage possessed by out-of-state firms” (which “trigger[s]
    heightened scrutiny”). Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 211
    .
    31
    B.     Heightened Scrutiny
    Cloverland’s argument against the District Court’s
    heightened scrutiny analysis may be distilled as follows. The
    District Court concluded that Cloverland has some advantages
    over some Pennsylvania firms — it is more efficient than some,
    it sells milk in Maryland for less than the minimum wholesale
    prices that exist in Pennsylvania, and its exemption from the
    over-order premium for raw milk purchased from independent
    Pennsylvania dairy farmers means its raw milk costs might
    theoretically be lower than its Pennsylvania competitors’ costs.
    Although these advantages may not derive necessarily from
    Cloverland’s status as an out-of-state handler,16 the argument
    proceeds, there is no question that Pennsylvania’s minimum
    prices level the playing field with Pennsylvania firms that have
    higher costs and are less efficient, thus nullifying Cloverland’s
    alleged competitive advantages. Since it is an out-of-state firm,
    Cloverland contends the pricing scheme necessarily restrains
    interstate commerce. Moreover, it asserts that Pennsylvania’s
    in-state processors are so entrenched (we noted previously that
    “in-state dealers dominate the wholesale milk market in
    Pennsylvania,” Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 217
    ), other means of
    competition are so lacking, and the wholesale minimums are set
    so high (such that they effectively set the actual price for all
    16
    Cloverland’s exemption from the over-order premium is
    due to its status as an out-of-state firm, but it argues this fact is
    not relevant to the heightened scrutiny analysis.
    32
    handlers), that no out-of-state firm can compete in the
    Pennsylvania market without offering a lower price. As we
    summarized the argument, “[p]reventing dealers from attracting
    customers by offering lower prices . . . helps in-state dealers
    maintain their traditional hegemony.” 
    Id. 1. Must
    a Competitive Advantage Arise from
    Cloverland’s Status as an Out-of-State
    Firm?
    Although Cloverland’s arguments were persuasive on the
    limited facts (construed in Cloverland’s favor) available in
    Cloverland I, they are less compelling in light of the factual
    record developed at trial. As a starting point, we note that
    Cloverland is incorrect that, at least on the facts of this case,
    state regulations that nullify a competitive advantage unrelated
    to the firm’s out-of-state status may nonetheless, on their own,
    trigger heightened scrutiny.
    As the District Court framed the issue, “courts have
    struggled with . . . the difficulty in examining laws which do not
    facially discriminate against out-of-state interests under
    [d]ormant Commerce Clause jurisprudence. When does a
    simple economic advantage rise to the level of [a] competitive
    advantage, within the heightened scrutiny context?” Cloverland
    II, slip op. at 16-17. The Supreme Court has never expressly
    33
    addressed this issue, but it has often stated that a state law that
    “cause[s] local goods to constitute a larger share, and goods with
    an out-of-state source to constitute a smaller share, of the total
    sales in the market” is unconstitutional “because it, like a tariff,
    ‘neutraliz[es] advantages belonging to the place of origin.’”
    West Lynn 
    Creamery, 512 U.S. at 196
    (quoting 
    Baldwin, 294 U.S. at 527
    ) (internal quotation marks omitted) (emphasis
    added); Polar Ice 
    Cream, 375 U.S. at 377
    (same with respect to
    a Florida law barring in-state handlers from buying raw milk
    from out-of-state producers); see also Wash. State 
    Apple, 432 U.S. at 351
    (noting that a North Carolina statute forbidding
    importing apples with a non-USDA quality mark “has the effect
    of stripping away from the Washington apple industry the
    competitive and economic advantages it has earned for itself
    though its expensive inspection and grading system”).
    We have observed that “[t]he Supreme Court’s opinions
    in Baldwin and Washington State Apple show that if a state
    regulation has the effect of protecting in-state businesses by
    eliminating a competitive advantage possessed by their out-of-
    state counterparts, heightened scrutiny applies. . . . [Here,] a
    reasonable trier of fact could find that Pennsylvania’s minimum
    wholesale prices eliminate a competitive advantage enjoyed by
    out-of-state dealers like Cloverland.” Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 212-13
    . By referencing a “competitive advantage enjoyed by
    out-of-state dealers” not shared by in-state dealers, we presumed
    the advantage would have something to do with the out-of-state
    status of the advantaged firms.
    34
    Cloverland argues, however, that it need not prove a cost
    advantage linked to its place of origin. It contends that the mere
    fact it has some efficiency advantage (for whatever reason) over
    at least one in-state firm means it can sell milk for less, and
    because Pennsylvania’s minimum wholesale prices nullify its
    ability to do so, they render meaningless its efficiency advantage
    and thus trigger heightened scrutiny.
    The ramifications of this argument are expansive.
    Cloverland’s proposed rule would eviscerate longstanding
    Supreme Court precedent that “price regulation [is not] an
    impermissible burden upon commerce” where “the burden on
    commerce is indirect and only incidental to the regulation of an
    essentially local activity,” Polar Ice 
    Cream, 375 U.S. at 378
    (citing Milk Control Bd. of Pa. v. Eisenberg Farm Prods., 
    306 U.S. 346
    (1939), and Highland Farms Dairy v. Agnew, 
    300 U.S. 608
    (1937)) — subject, of course, to the Pike balancing test.
    See Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 215
    -16. As the District Court
    noted, in any state with minimum price regulations, there will
    always be some out-of-state competitors (like Cloverland) that
    have some advantages over at least one in-state firm, even
    though those advantages may reflect differences in capacity,
    efficiency, workers, etc., that have nothing to do with the firm’s
    location (and indeed are shared with many in-state firms). See
    Cloverland II, slip op. at 16-17, 19. Thus, under Cloverland’s
    proposed rule, state milk price regulations will always be subject
    to heightened scrutiny (and thus nearly per se invalid), despite
    the fact we and the Supreme Court have clearly recognized this
    35
    is not always the case. If the neutralization of any advantage
    possessed by any out-of-state firm were enough to trigger
    heightened scrutiny, it is difficult to think of a state pricing
    regulation that could survive.
    The elimination of a particular competitive advantage
    belonging to the place of origin is not, of course, a determinative
    inquiry in every case. For example, where a state statute
    imposes an outright ban on competition by reserving all business
    for an in-state firm or firms and explicitly barring interstate
    commerce, see 
    Carbone, 511 U.S. at 391
    -93; Polar Ice 
    Cream, 375 U.S. at 376-77
    , or targets out-of-state firms for special
    burdens from which in-state firms are exempt, see West Lynn
    
    Creamery, 512 U.S. at 194-95
    ; Wash. State 
    Apple, 432 U.S. at 350-51
    , the problem is more blatant: the out-of-state firms are
    subjected to overt discrimination or an outright ban on
    competition. But Cloverland does not allege those barriers here.
    Rather, it alleges more subtle discrimination, stemming from a
    law and regulatory scheme that are not facially discriminatory.
    Hence, a nexus between the advantage that has been neutralized
    and the firm’s out-of-state status is necessary.
    We therefore hold that, if Cloverland is to succeed in
    demonstrating that heightened scrutiny applies because its
    competitive advantages have been neutralized by the
    Pennsylvania Milk Marketing Law, it must establish that those
    advantages arise by virtue of its out-of-state status.
    36
    2.     Does Cloverland Have an Out-of-State
    Competitive Advantage?
    The question becomes, then, whether the Pennsylvania
    Milk Marketing Law operates to neutralize competitive
    advantages belonging to Cloverland’s place of origin. The
    record reveals only one such potential advantage vis-a-vis
    Cloverland’s Pennsylvania competitors — its potential raw milk
    cost advantage due to its exemption from the over-order
    premium.
    a.     Legal Errors in the District Court’s
    Analysis
    We note at the outset two legal errors in the District
    Court’s opinion that cannot form the basis for a determination
    of whether Cloverland’s exemption from the over-order
    premium should trigger heightened scrutiny.
    (1)     Nexus Between the
    Challenged State Law and
    Cloverland’s Advantage
    We are unpersuaded by the District Court’s reasoning
    that because Cloverland’s exemption arises from Pennsylvania
    law, any cost advantage it has is “ephemeral” — the argument
    being that if the minimum wholesale prices were invalidated (as
    Cloverland desires), its purported raw milk cost advantage
    37
    would disappear because the over-order premium would no
    longer be viable. We assume, without deciding, that if the
    minimum wholesale prices themselves conferred an advantage
    on Cloverland due to its out-of-state status, it could not rely on
    that advantage to challenge those prices because invalidating the
    prices would necessarily nullify the advantage (though, of
    course, Cloverland would have no incentive to challenge the
    prices in that event). Here, however, Cloverland’s purported
    cost advantage arises from the operation of a different aspect of
    the regulatory scheme — the over-order premium — that is not
    challenged in this suit.
    The District Court concluded, based on the Board’s
    evidence, that if the minimum wholesale prices were
    invalidated, the over-order premium would fall. But this is not
    a question susceptible to definitive proof by the Board’s experts.
    It may well be that invalidating the minimum wholesale prices
    would place pressure on the Commonwealth’s legislature to
    repeal the over-order premium or extend it to out-of-state
    purchasers (both of which would nullify Cloverland’s supposed
    advantage). The cost disadvantage to Pennsylvania handlers of
    paying the over-order premium and then competing against out-
    of-state handlers without the protection of minimum wholesale
    prices might make the over-order premium less feasible or
    encourage them to purchase out-of-state milk to avoid the
    premium. But we note that, under the current system,
    Pennsylvania handlers already have an incentive to purchase
    out-of-state milk to maximize their profit margins, yet the over-
    38
    order premium remains strong. Moreover, even assuming
    Pennsylvania could constitutionally impose over-order
    premiums on sales of milk to out-of-state purchasers (an issue
    we do not decide here), doing so would presumably damage the
    Commonwealth’s ability to export milk by essentially adding a
    surcharge on exports. And the Board has gone to great lengths
    (as explained below) to demonstrate several legal options
    handlers use to sell milk at below minimum wholesale prices in
    Pennsylvania, which suggests that invalidating the minimum
    wholesale prices would not necessarily harm the handlers’
    ability to pay the over-order premium to producers.
    If the minimum wholesale prices were invalidated, the
    Pennsylvania legislature would be faced with these thorny
    policy questions and would have to weigh the competing
    considerations to determine whether the over-order premium
    provisions of 31 Pa. Cons. Stat. § 700j remain viable. There is
    simply no way to determine, at this stage, whether the over-
    order premium would necessarily be repealed or extended to
    out-of-state purchasers of Pennsylvania milk. At best, the
    Board’s evidence and the District Court’s opinion establish that
    such an event would be likely. We hold, though, that the
    possible removal of Cloverland’s purported out-of-state
    advantage if it is successful on this appeal is insufficient to
    render that advantage irrelevant to our heightened scrutiny
    analysis.
    (2)    Availability of Non-Price
    39
    Competition
    We also are unpersuaded by the District Court’s reliance
    on the availability of non-price competition in the Pennsylvania
    market. As we explain below, if Cloverland proves that its
    exemption from the over-order premium confers a cost
    advantage over Pennsylvania handlers that is neutralized by the
    Commonwealth’s minimum wholesale prices, heightened
    scrutiny applies. The fact that Cloverland might be able to
    compete for some retailer accounts on non-price bases is
    irrelevant, because even if there are other potential paths into the
    Pennsylvania market that may allow an out-of-state handler
    successfully to obtain some business, neutralizing an out-of-
    state price advantage alone offends the dormant Commerce
    Clause (especially since the record amply demonstrates that
    price is — or, at least, would be if competition on price were
    allowed — an important factor retailers consider in choosing a
    supplier). See Wyoming v. Oklahoma, 
    502 U.S. 437
    , 455
    (1992) (holding that a state may not insulate part of its market
    from out-of-state competition while leaving other parts open,
    because this “measures only the extent of the discrimination; it
    is of no relevance to the determination whether a State has
    discriminated against interstate commerce”).17
    17
    Indeed, the Board’s argument (which the District Court
    accepted) is similar conceptually to the one advanced
    unsuccessfully by the State of Oklahoma in Wyoming. There,
    Oklahoma argued that it “set[] aside only a ‘small portion’ of the
    40
    If Cloverland proves its Maryland residency confers a
    cost advantage it wishes to exploit in the Pennsylvania market,
    but Pennsylvania law neutralizes that advantage (and thus
    unlawfully shields in-state handlers from price competition),
    heightened scrutiny will apply regardless of the existence of
    other competitive means that Pennsylvania has not neutralized.
    In demonstrating that heightened scrutiny should apply to a state
    law, a plaintiff like Cloverland need only prove that its out-of-
    state residency confers competitive advantages that are
    neutralized by the state law under review, thus preventing
    competition in the area in which the plaintiff enjoys an
    advantage. The plaintiff need not prove it is prevented from
    entering the market through competition on all possible bases.
    Oklahoma coal market” for in-state coal producers, “without
    placing an ‘overall burden’ on out-of-state coal producers doing
    business in Oklahoma.” 
    Wyoming, 502 U.S. at 455
    . Here, the
    Board essentially contends there is no “overall burden” on
    handlers (including out-of-state handlers) because they may
    compete for business on non-price factors, even though at least
    part of the market would surely be more receptive to Cloverland
    if it were allowed to exploit its alleged out-of-state cost
    advantage to offer a lower price on wholesale milk. The fact
    that Cloverland may compete on bases in which it does not
    enjoy an advantage (and on which it would, therefore, have
    considerable difficulty displacing an incumbent handler from an
    established account with a retailer, especially a retailer that is
    primarily concerned with price) resolve the constitutional
    problem.
    41
    b.     Factual Support for District Court’s
    Decision
    Notwithstanding these errors in the District Court’s
    analysis, we conclude it was not clearly erroneous for the Court
    to find that Cloverland did not sustain its burden of proving an
    actual raw milk cost advantage belonging to its place of origin.
    Cloverland’s proof of its alleged cost advantage consisted
    primarily of testimony from Lawrence Webster, Cloverland’s
    general manager, and Robert Havemeyer, a management
    consultant who testified as an expert in the costs of processing
    and delivering milk. Webster testified that, by not adding the
    over-order premium to the 65% of raw milk it purchases from
    independent Pennsylvania farmers, Cloverland saves about five
    cents per gallon, which would allow Cloverland to lower its
    wholesale prices enough to gain a significant price advantage
    over Pennsylvania competitors. Havemeyer testified that, based
    on a survey of Cloverland’s costs during a 13-week period in the
    fall of 1998 (when demand was at its peak), and updated in
    2002, Cloverland’s variable costs (i.e., costs that vary with the
    volume of production) allowed it to sell its milk in Pennsylvania
    below wholesale minimum prices.
    Notably absent from Cloverland’s offer of proof,
    however, was any comparison to actual Pennsylvania
    competitors’ costs, despite the fact this was crucial to
    demonstrating a cost advantage vis a vis those competitors. At
    most, Cloverland proved it was capable of selling milk for less
    42
    than the wholesale minimum, but (as explained above) this is
    not in itself sufficient to trigger heightened scrutiny.
    Carl Herbein, who testified for the Board as an expert in
    milk cost accounting, conducted the comparison with
    Pennsylvania handlers that Cloverland’s expert did not, and
    concluded that Cloverland’s total costs rendered it less efficient
    than three of the four sample handlers. Herbein explained, and
    the District Court agreed, that Havemeyer’s calculations were
    unreliable because they used an unreasonably small time frame,
    relied only on Cloverland’s variable costs (rather than looking
    at total costs),18 and considered a time when demand was at its
    18
    We observed in Cloverland I that, based solely on
    Cloverland’s evidence, it appeared that “fixing prices based on
    average total costs” — which includes variable costs and fixed
    costs “such as equipment, office space, and other ‘overhead’
    expenses” — “significantly increases dealers’ profits because it
    will be in their economic interest to sell additional units of milk
    at any price above their average variable costs, even if below
    their total costs. Outside Pennsylvania, in contrast, milk dealers
    generally offer prices based on their average variable 
    costs.” 298 F.3d at 208
    . Herbein and Havemeyer presented conflicting
    evidence on this point at trial, and the District Court agreed with
    Herbein that an analysis of total costs is necessary to take into
    account fully the costs of production. Since this conclusion is
    supported by Herbein’s testimony, and Cloverland has not
    shown that the testimony is demonstrably untrue, the District
    Court’s conclusion is not clearly erroneous.
    43
    peak rather than a period representative of the full year.
    Herbein, and other witnesses offered by the Board, also
    explained that the cost advantage resulting from Cloverland’s
    exemption from the over-order premium vis a vis a particular
    Pennsylvania competitor may be mitigated by the fact that
    Cloverland pays a slightly higher federal price for raw milk
    because it is located in Maryland,19 and many Pennsylvania
    handlers avoid paying minimum wholesale prices by entering
    tolling agreements20 and taking advantage of allowable
    19
    Although Pennsylvania Areas 1 and 4 and the State of
    Maryland are all under the Northeast federal order, there are
    numerous price differentials that set various minimum prices
    throughout the order. See, e.g., U.S. Dep’t of Agric., Northeast
    States Class I Differentials, available at
    http://www.fmmone.com/New_Zone_Diffs/
    NEZoneDiffMap.pdf.
    20
    A tolling agreement is a state-approved service contract
    whereby a handler contracts with a large retailer that is
    vertically integrated (i.e., processes its own milk) to process,
    package, and deliver milk to the retailer. Essentially, the
    handler acts as a proxy for the retailer’s milk processing
    operation, and thereby avoids charging minimum wholesale
    prices.
    We have previously held that “out-of-state dealers’
    ability to enter into tolling agreements [does not] meaningfully
    mitigate[] the burden on interstate commerce,” because only
    about one-third of wholesale milk sales in Pennsylvania are
    made pursuant to tolling, and “[t]he dormant Commerce Clause
    44
    discounts for high volume sales, partial service (i.e., delivering
    the milk to a retailer but not stocking it in the cooler or ordering
    future inventory), and multi-store customers. None of this was
    reflected in Cloverland’s offer of proof at trial, which relied on
    a straightforward comparison between the price of raw milk
    with the over-order premium and the price of milk without it.
    Cloverland argues strenuously that the Board’s data is
    flawed. It contends, first, that the Board purposely selected
    sample handlers with lower operating costs than Cloverland, and
    argues specifically against the inclusion of “Dealer 4”,21 which
    does not allow Pennsylvania to hamper out-of-state dealers in
    two-thirds of its wholesale market on the ground that they may
    compete freely in the remaining third.” Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 218
    (citing 
    Wyoming, 502 U.S. at 455
    ). We adhere fully to
    this holding. Thus, the Board’s evidence at trial, and argument
    on appeal, that tolling is available to Cloverland as a means to
    avoid minimum wholesale prices do not defeat Cloverland’s
    dormant Commerce Clause challenge. But, as explained below,
    the plaintiff in a case like this must prove an out-of-state
    advantage over similarly situated in-state handlers, and in
    conducting this comparison the plaintiff must take account of
    the circumstances of the in-state handlers over which it claims
    to have an advantage. Since Cloverland did not analyze
    Pennsylvania handlers’ costs, the District Court did not clearly
    err in relying on the Board’s comparison.
    21
    The relative costs of milk handlers are trade secrets, and
    thus the sample dairies are referenced by pseudonyms.
    45
    is not located within a federal order area and moves less than
    25% of its total Class I milk volume into that area, and thus is
    only partially regulated by federal law. See 7 C.F.R. § 1001.7;
    see also Sani-Dairy, Div. of Penn Traffic Co, Inc. v. Espy, 
    939 F. Supp. 410
    , 412 (W.D. Pa. 1993) (same under earlier federal
    order regulations). Herbein testified, and Cloverland does not
    dispute, that a partially regulated handler like Dealer 4 need not
    account to the Producer Settlement Fund, and is therefore able
    to pay producers more for raw milk (which gives it a price
    advantage over fully regulated handlers, and a corresponding
    cost advantage when the market price of raw milk is higher than
    the federal minimum). See 7 C.F.R. § 1000.76. Since
    Cloverland is fully regulated federally, and must account to the
    Producer Settlement Fund, it argues a comparison with the
    partially regulated Dealer 4 is irrelevant.
    Cloverland’s argument misses the mark. Dealer 4 would
    clearly be a competitor in the Pennsylvania market; although
    Dealer 4 cannot sell more than 25% of its total milk volume into
    a federal order area and remain partially regulated, it could still
    compete with Cloverland for retail outlets in Areas 1 and 4 with
    the milk it does move into the order area. Dealer 4 is not,
    therefore, a wholly irrelevant comparison. Cloverland’s
    argument is really addressed to whether Dealer 4 is a proper
    representative for comparison. Yet Cloverland had every
    opportunity to submit evidence of similarly situated
    Pennsylvania handlers with comparatively higher costs, and it
    failed to do so. As the Board was the only one to submit
    46
    evidence of comparative costs, the District Court did not clearly
    err in relying on the Board’s sample.
    Second, Cloverland argues Herbein erroneously relied on
    the “plant blend” cost of raw milk (i.e., the weighted average of
    the costs of different classes of milk used by the plant, which is
    paid to producers), rather than a segregated Class I price, in
    conducting his analysis of comparative costs. This, according
    to Cloverland, artificially lowered the costs of plants with less
    Class I usage than Cloverland. The Board counters that the
    plant blend method of calculating costs is the norm in the
    industry and comports with generally accepted accounting
    practices.
    Although Cloverland’s argument may have some merit,22
    22
    Herbein justified his reliance on the plant blend cost — as
    does the Board in its arguments on appeal — by noting that
    plant blend is an accepted method of pricing the cost of raw
    milk, and reflects the way handlers actually operate (i.e., by
    purchasing Grade A raw milk and only later deciding how it will
    be classified). While we have no doubt plant blend is
    recognized and accepted in the industry, here Cloverland
    contends that its exemption from the over-order premium (which
    applies only to purchases of Class I raw milk) gives it an
    advantage over other purchasers of Class I raw milk. Reliance
    on the plant blend cost in determining Cloverland’s advantage
    over other handlers makes sense only if Cloverland and the
    Pennsylvania handlers to which it is compared have the same
    47
    we note that it submitted no evidence that the sample handlers
    (which Herbein testified were “very similar” to Cloverland in
    terms of size, volume, and gross sales) had appreciably different
    Class I usage. Havemeyer provided evidence of Cloverland’s
    Class I costs, but did not compare these to any actual
    Pennsylvania competitors, and the District Court expressly
    found his study unreliable due to its limited time frame and
    examination of only variable costs. Again, under these
    circumstances, we cannot conclude that the District Court
    Class I usage. Otherwise, as Cloverland argues, the comparison
    will be flawed: because it has a high Class I usage, its plant
    blend cost will be artificially higher than a plant with lower
    Class I usage, even though the cost of its Class I milk alone may
    be lower than the Pennsylvania competitor.
    Of course, it may be difficult to calculate a discrete
    “Class I” cost because if (as the Board persuasively argued, and
    the District Court found) it is appropriate to consider the total
    costs of production — including fixed costs like capital
    investment, facilities, equipment, and other overhead — in
    deciding whether one handler has a cost or efficiency advantage
    over another, it would be an arduous task to separate out the
    portion of fixed costs attributable to the production of Class I
    milk, as many fixed costs are directed at processing raw milk
    regardless of its end use. It may be, then, that plant blend is an
    unavoidable consequence of the way handlers actually work,
    though we still think it most useful if the two handlers compared
    use roughly the same amount of raw milk as Class I. But, as we
    explain, in this case Cloverland’s failure of proof makes it
    unnecessary to resolve this question.
    48
    committed clear error by relying on the only comparative
    evidence before it.
    *    *    *    *   *
    To be sure, we do not mean to suggest that a defendant
    in a case such as this may defeat heightened scrutiny merely by
    showing that the plaintiff does not have a competitive advantage
    over some of its putative competitors. Such a rule would be at
    odds with the well-established principle that “‘a statute may be
    invalid if it favors only a single or finite set of businesses.’”
    Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 214
    (quoting Harvey & 
    Harvey, 68 F.3d at 798
    ). But this does not relieve a plaintiff like Cloverland
    of its burden of proving, as part of its prima facie case of
    discrimination, that it has an actual competitive advantage over
    some of its prospective competitors because it is an out-of-state
    firm. Cloverland should have established that its exemption
    from the over-order premium gave it a relevant cost advantage
    over similarly situated Pennsylvania competitors that translated
    into an ability to sell wholesale milk at a lower cost.23 Had it
    23
    Herbein’s testimony indicated that Cloverland had a cost
    advantage over one of the four sample dairies offered by the
    Board (which Herbein selected because they were similarly
    situated to Cloverland), but Cloverland offered no proof that this
    cost advantage arose because of its out-of-state status. In any
    event, given the totality of the Board’s evidence, the District
    Court did not clearly err in deciding (implicitly) that evidence of
    a cost advantage over one similarly situated Pennsylvania
    49
    done so, the Board could (of course) have attempted to rebut this
    proof by showing that Cloverland did not have an actual cost
    advantage over its competitors, or its cost advantage was not
    related to its out-of-state status. The District Court would then
    have had to weigh the evidence. But Cloverland’s evidence did
    not compare its costs to the costs of its competitors, and thus the
    Court did not commit clear error when it held that Cloverland
    failed to sustain its burden of proving an out-of-state
    competitive advantage vis a vis its Pennsylvania competitors
    that is neutralized by the Commonwealth’s mandatory minimum
    wholesale prices. In this context, we do not have facts calling
    for heightened scrutiny.
    C.      Pike Balancing
    Having concluded that Cloverland failed to prove the
    applicability of heightened scrutiny, we proceed to the Pike
    balancing test. 
    Pike, 397 U.S. at 142
    . As noted, when a law
    “effectuate[s] a legitimate local public interest, and its effects on
    interstate commerce are only incidental,” the court must
    determine whether “the burden imposed on such commerce is
    clearly excessive in relation to the putative local benefits.” 
    Id. The District
    Court concluded that Pennsylvania’s mandatory
    minimum wholesale milk prices survive this test.
    handler, owing possibly to Cloverland’s exemption from the
    over-order premium, was not sufficient to trigger heightened
    scrutiny.
    50
    Cloverland argues that the “benefits” conferred by the
    minimum wholesale prices are merely economic protectionism,
    “the very evil the Commerce Clause seeks to prohibit.”
    Appellant’s Br. at 40. The District Court disagreed, crediting
    the Board’s witnesses who testified that minimum wholesale
    prices make it easier for handlers to pay the over-order
    premium. The over-order premium, in turn, helps small,
    independent dairy farms remain profitable without joining
    cooperatives, which fosters market diversity and prevents a
    possible future rise in retail prices. Indeed, the District Court
    was persuaded by expert testimony offered by the Board that the
    abolition of minimum prices in California led to consolidation
    of farms and handlers into a few dominant market participants,
    resulting eventually in a sharp rise in consumer prices. The
    District Court also credited testimony offered by the Board that
    if small farms went out of business, “the agricultural
    infrastructure built around the industry will also be negatively
    affected, resulting in the loss of dealers, feed stores,
    veterinarians, and other business[es] that support the dairy
    industry.” Cloverland II, slip op. at 9, 26.
    Although Cloverland presented testimony tending to
    establish the opposite — that the abolition of minimum
    wholesale prices would have no adverse effect on the dairy
    industry, which would continue to thrive as it does in other
    states — the District Court was entitled to base its ultimate
    factual conclusion on the Board’s evidence. “As we have
    recognized, the clearly erroneous standard of review does not
    51
    permit an appellate court to substitute its findings for those of
    the trial court. It allows only an assessment of whether there is
    enough evidence on the record to support those findings. That
    a different set of inferences could be drawn from the record is
    not determinative. . . . Where there are two permissible views of
    the evidence, the factfinder’s choice between them cannot be
    clearly erroneous.” Scully v. US WATS, Inc., 
    238 F.3d 497
    ,
    506 (3d Cir. 2001) (citations and internal quotation marks
    omitted); see Anderson v. Bessemer City, 
    470 U.S. 564
    , 573-74
    (1985) (same).
    The next question, then, is whether the putative benefits
    of the Milk Law are outweighed by a significant incidental
    burden on commerce. Cloverland offered testimony that the
    minimum prices prevented it from competing in the
    Pennsylvania milk market, and thus the burdens on interstate
    commerce were substantial. As noted, the Board offered
    testimony that several other forms of competition exist in the
    Pennsylvania market,24 and therefore the minimum wholesale
    24
    Although we held above that evidence of other competitive
    outlets is not relevant to the question of whether heightened
    scrutiny applies — because, as explained, the only relevant
    inquiry in making that determination is whether an out-of-state
    competitive advantage is neutralized by Pennsylvania law — the
    presence of other forms of competition is one of many factors
    that may be taken into account under the Pike balancing test,
    where the inquiry concerns the magnitude of the incidental
    burden on commerce and the countervailing benefits of the law.
    52
    prices do not entirely prevent new competitors from challenging
    incumbent handlers and moving their milk interstate. As with
    the benefits of the law, the District Court was forced to choose
    between conflicting evidence, and we cannot say its choice was
    clearly erroneous. Thus, we affirm the District Court’s holding
    that Cloverland failed to sustain its burden of proving that the
    incidental burdens of Pennsylvania’s minimum wholesale milk
    prices outweigh the putative benefits.
    V. Conclusion
    In Cloverland I, we expressed our unease with the fact
    that Pennsylvania is the only state with mandatory price controls
    of the sort described in this case, while its milk industry
    (dominated by in-state firms) is flourishing. In our view, the
    Board’s argument that the price controls are the only thing
    preventing a vulnerable milk industry from complete collapse
    (and a concomitant disruption in the supply of milk to
    Pennsylvania’s residents) rings hollow in light of the undisputed
    evidence that Pennsylvania exports far more milk than its
    residents consume,25 and other states appear to do quite well
    25
    In Cloverland I, we noted that “Pennsylvania’s dairy
    industry is among our nation’s most productive. Milk
    production in the Commonwealth outpaces consumption by
    roughly 350%. Annual production per-capita [for Pennsylvania
    residents] is around 900 pounds; consumption [by Pennsylvania
    53
    without mandatory minimum prices. It is quite likely, as we
    stated on the limited factual record in Cloverland I, that
    preventing competition based on price works to the advantage
    of Pennsylvania’s resident handlers by helping maintain their
    dominance in the market. Indeed, there is apparently no
    political incentive for in-state handlers to resist the price
    controls, as evidenced by the fact that the Pennsylvania
    Association of Milk Dealers has intervened in support of the
    challenged law. Cf. West Lynn 
    Creamery, 512 U.S. at 200-01
    (“[O]ne would ordinarily have expected at least three groups to
    lobby against the order premium, which, as a tax, raises the
    price (and hence lowers demand) for milk: dairy farmers, milk
    dealers, and consumers. But because the tax was coupled with
    a subsidy, one of the most powerful of these groups,
    Massachusetts dairy farmers, instead of exerting their influence
    against the tax, were in fact its primary supporters. . . . [Thus,]
    [the] State’s political processes can no longer be relied upon to
    prevent legislative abuse.”).
    Cloverland failed to prove its case, however, and the
    District Court cannot be faulted for relying on the evidence
    presented at trial. But our opinion today does not settle the
    question of the Pennsylvania Milk Marketing Law’s
    constitutionality. Indeed, if another out-of-state plaintiff can
    prove it has competitive advantages over actual Pennsylvania
    competitors belonging to its place of origin (whether by virtue
    residents] per-capita is merely 200 
    pounds.” 298 F.3d at 206
    .
    54
    of its exemption from the over-order premium or otherwise),26
    and these advantages translate into an actual ability to sell milk
    for less than similarly situated Pennsylvania handlers that is
    neutralized by the minimum wholesale prices, heightened
    scrutiny would apply.27 Cloverland lost this case because its
    evidence was insufficient, but the constitutionality of
    Pennsylvania’s minimum wholesale prices remains unresolved.
    In this context, the District Court’s judgment is affirmed.
    26
    The District Court noted, for example, that “if . . . [a]
    competitive price advantage arose from [out-of-state] firms’
    ability to buy cheap local milk, the wholesale price floor would
    fall under a heightened scrutiny analysis.” Cloverland II, slip
    op. at 18 n.13.
    27
    We have already held that “[i]f they are subject to
    heightened scrutiny, the wholesale price floors cannot satisfy the
    dormant Commerce Clause” because Pennsylvania could
    “achieve its objective through alternative measures that do not
    discriminate against interstate commerce” — by acting as a
    market participant, for example. Cloverland 
    I, 298 F.3d at 215
    .
    This holding would, of course, apply in any future challenge to
    the minimum wholesale prices.
    55
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 05-2336

Citation Numbers: 462 F.3d 249

Filed Date: 9/1/2006

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/12/2023

Authorities (24)

Queensboro Farms Products v. Wickard , 137 F.2d 969 ( 1943 )

Alan D. Gordon, M.D. Alan D. Gordon, M.D., P.C., a ... , 423 F.3d 184 ( 2005 )

harvey-harvey-inc-v-county-of-chester-pennsylvania-department-of , 68 F.3d 788 ( 1995 )

smyser-robert-l-smyser-rodney-r-smysers-richlawn-farms-fetrow , 760 F.2d 514 ( 1985 )

cloverland-green-spring-dairies-inc-v-pennsylvania-milk-marketing-board , 298 F.3d 201 ( 2002 )

lehigh-valley-farmers-atlantic-processing-inc-dairylea-cooperative , 829 F.2d 409 ( 1987 )

A. L. A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States , 55 S. Ct. 837 ( 1935 )

Milk Control Board v. Eisenberg Farm Products , 59 S. Ct. 528 ( 1939 )

Defiance Milk Products Company, a Division of Diehl, Inc. v.... , 857 F.2d 1065 ( 1988 )

Baldwin v. G. A. F. Seelig, Inc. , 55 S. Ct. 497 ( 1935 )

Highland Farms Dairy, Inc. v. Agnew , 57 S. Ct. 549 ( 1937 )

mark-scully-v-us-wats-inc-kevin-ohare-individually-and-in-his-capacity , 238 F.3d 497 ( 2001 )

SANI-DAIRY, a DIV. OF PENN TRAFFIC CO. v. Espy , 939 F. Supp. 410 ( 1993 )

Cloverland—Green Spring Dairies, Inc. v. Pennsylvania Milk ... , 138 F. Supp. 2d 593 ( 2001 )

Polar Ice Cream & Creamery Co. v. Andrews , 84 S. Ct. 378 ( 1964 )

Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc. , 90 S. Ct. 844 ( 1970 )

Hunt v. Washington State Apple Advertising Comm'n , 97 S. Ct. 2434 ( 1977 )

Anderson v. City of Bessemer City , 105 S. Ct. 1504 ( 1985 )

Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America v. ... , 123 S. Ct. 1855 ( 2003 )

Granholm v. Heald , 125 S. Ct. 1885 ( 2005 )

View All Authorities »