Lattera v. Commissioner IRS ( 2006 )


Menu:
  •                                                                                                                            Opinions of the United
    2006 Decisions                                                                                                             States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    2-14-2006
    Lattera v. Commissioner IRS
    Precedential or Non-Precedential: Precedential
    Docket No. 04-4721
    Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2006
    Recommended Citation
    "Lattera v. Commissioner IRS" (2006). 2006 Decisions. Paper 1506.
    http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2006/1506
    This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 2006 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
    PRECEDENTIAL
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    No. 04-4721
    GEORGE LATTERA; ANGELINE LATTERA,
    Appellants
    v.
    COMMISSIONER OF INTERNAL REVENUE
    Appeal from the Decision of the
    United States Tax Court
    Docket No. 03-4269
    Tax Court Judge: Honorable Juan F. Vasquez
    Argued January 9, 2006
    Before: BARRY and AMBRO, Circuit Judges,
    and DEBEVOISE,* District Judge
    *
    Honorable Dickinson R. Debevoise, Senior District
    Court Judge for the District of New Jersey, sitting by
    (Opinion filed February 14, 2006)
    Mark E. Cedrone, Esquire (Argued)
    Cedrone & Janove
    150 South Independence Mall West
    Suite 940 Public Ledger
    Building, 6 th & Chestnut Streets
    Philadelphia, PA 19106
    Counsel for Appellants
    Eileen J. O’Connor
    Assistant Attorney General
    Regina S. Moriarty, Esquire (Argued)
    Richard Farber, Esquire
    United States Department of Justice
    Tax Division
    P.O. Box 502
    Washington, DC 20044
    Counsel for Appellee
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    designation.
    2
    AMBRO, Circuit Judge
    Lottery winners, after receiving several annual
    installments of their lottery prize, sold for a lump sum the right
    to their remaining payments. They reported their sale proceeds
    as capital gains on their tax return, but the Internal Revenue
    Service (IRS) classified those proceeds as ordinary income. The
    substitute-for-ordinary-income doctrine holds that lump-sum
    consideration substituting for something that would otherwise
    be received at a future time as ordinary income should be taxed
    the same way. We agree with the Commissioner of the IRS that
    the lump-sum consideration paid for the right to lottery
    payments is ordinary income.
    I. Factual Background and Procedural History
    In June 1991 George and Angeline Lattera turned a one-
    dollar lottery ticket into $9,595,326 in the Pennsylvania Lottery.
    They did not then have the option to take the prize in a single
    lump-sum payment, so they were entitled to 26 annual
    installments of $369,051.
    In September 1999 the Latteras sold their rights to the 17
    remaining lottery payments to Singer Asset Finance Co., LLC
    for $3,372,342. Under Pennsylvania law, the Latteras had to
    obtain court approval before they could transfer their rights to
    future lottery payments, and they did so in August 1999.
    3
    On their joint tax return, the Latteras reported this sale as
    the sale of a capital asset held for more than one year. They
    reported a sale price of $3,372,342, a cost or other basis of zero,
    and a long-term capital gain of the full sale price. The
    Commissioner determined that this sale price was ordinary
    income. In December 2002 the Latteras were sent a notice of
    deficiency of $660,784.1
    In March 2003 the Latteras petitioned the Tax Court for
    a redetermination of the deficiency. The Court held in favor of
    the Commissioner. The Latteras now appeal to our Court.
    II. Jurisdiction and Standard of Review
    The Tax Court had subject matter jurisdiction under
    I.R.C. § 7442. Because its decision was final, we have appellate
    jurisdiction under I.R.C. § 7482(a)(1). The Latteras reside in
    our Circuit, so venue is proper under I.R.C. § 7482(b)(1)(A).
    We review the Tax Court’s legal determinations de novo,
    but we do not disturb its factual findings unless they are clearly
    erroneous. Estate of Meriano v. Comm’r, 
    142 F.3d 651
    , 657 (3d
    Cir. 1998).
    1
    The parties’ stipulation of facts states this number as
    $660,748, but the notice of deficiency reads $660,784.
    4
    III. Discussion
    The lottery payments the Latteras had a right to receive
    were gambling winnings, and the parties agree that the annual
    payments were ordinary income. Cf. Comm’r v. Groetzinger,
    
    480 U.S. 23
    , 32 n.11 (1987) (calling a state lottery “public
    gambling” in a case treating gambling winnings as ordinary
    income). But the Latteras argue that when they sold the right to
    their remaining lottery payments, that sale gave rise to a long-
    term capital gain.
    Whether the sale of a right to lottery payments by a
    lottery winner can be treated as a capital gain under the Internal
    Revenue Code is one of first impression in our Circuit. But it is
    not a new question. Both the Tax Court and the Ninth Circuit
    Court of Appeals have held that such sales deserve ordinary-
    income treatment. United States v. Maginnis, 
    356 F.3d 1179
    ,
    1181 (9th Cir. 2004) (“Fundamental principles of tax law lead
    us to conclude that [the] assignment of [a] lottery right produced
    ordinary income.”); Davis v. Comm’r, 
    119 T.C. 1
    , 1 (2002); see
    also Watkins v. Comm’r, 
    88 T.C.M. 390
    , 393 (2004);
    Clopton v. Comm’r, 
    87 T.C.M. 1217
    , 1217 (2004);
    Boehme v. Comm’r, 
    85 T.C.M. 1039
    , 1041 (2003).
    The Ninth Circuit’s reasoning has drawn significant
    criticism, however. See Matthew S. Levine, Case Comment,
    Lottery Winnings as Capital Gains, 114 Yale L.J. 195, 197–202
    (2004); Thomas G. Sinclair, Comment, Limiting the Substitute-
    5
    for-Ordinary Income Doctrine: An Analysis Through Its Most
    Recent Application Involving the Sale of Future Lottery Rights,
    
    56 S.C. L
    . Rev. 387, 421–22 (2004). In this context, we propose
    a different approach. We begin with a discussion of basic
    concepts that underlie our reasoning.
    A.     Definition of a capital asset
    A long-term capital gain (or loss) is created by the “sale
    or exchange of a capital asset held for more than 1 year.” I.R.C.
    § 1222(3). Section 1221 of the Internal Revenue Code defines
    a capital asset as “property held by the taxpayer (whether or not
    connected with his trade or business).” This provision excludes
    from the definition certain property categories, none of which is
    applicable here.2
    2
    Section § 1221, as it read when the Latteras sold their
    lottery rights, contained five exceptions (stock in trade of the
    taxpayer, depreciable trade or business property, copyrights,
    accounts receivable acquired in the ordinary course of trade or
    business, and Government publications). The provision was
    amended in December 1999 to exclude also commodities
    derivative financial instruments held by dealers, hedging
    transactions, and supplies used or consumed in trade or business.
    Tax Relief Extension Act of 1999, Pub. L. No. 106-170, tit. V,
    § 532(a), 113 Stat. 1860, 1928–30. These exclusions are not
    applicable to this case; the amendments did not apply to
    transactions entered into before December 17, 1999, see 
    id. § 532(d),
    113 Stat. at 1931, and the Latteras sold their lottery
    6
    A 1960 Supreme Court decision suggested that this
    definition can be construed too broadly, stating that “it is evident
    that not everything which can be called property in the ordinary
    sense and which is outside the statutory exclusions qualifies as
    a capital asset.” Comm’r v. Gillette Motor Transp., Inc., 
    364 U.S. 130
    , 134 (1960). The Court noted that it had “long held
    that the term ‘capital asset’ is to be construed narrowly in
    accordance with the purpose of Congress to afford capital-gains
    treatment only in situations typically involving the realization of
    appreciation in value accrued over a substantial period of time,
    and thus to ameliorate the hardship of taxation of the entire gain
    in one year.” 
    Id. But the
    Supreme Court’s decision in Arkansas
    Best Corp. v. Commissioner, 
    485 U.S. 212
    (1988), at least at
    first blush, seems to have reversed that narrow reading.
    Arkansas Best suggests instead that the capital-asset definition
    is to be broadly construed. See 
    id. at 218
    (“The body of § 1221
    establishes a general definition of the term ‘capital asset,’ and
    the phrase ‘does not include’ takes out of that broad definition
    only the classes of property that are specifically mentioned.”).
    B.      The substitute-for-ordinary-income doctrine
    The problem with an overly broad definition for capital
    assets is that it could “encompass some things Congress did not
    intend to be taxed as capital gains.” 
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1181
    . An overly broad definition, linked with favorable capital-
    rights in September 1999.
    7
    gains tax treatment, would encourage transactions designed to
    convert ordinary income into capital gains. See 
    id. at 1182.
    For
    example, a salary is taxed as ordinary income, and the right to be
    paid for work is a person’s property. But it is hard to conceive
    that Congress intends for taxpayers to get capital-gains treatment
    if they were to sell their rights (i.e., “property held by the
    taxpayer”) to their future paychecks. See 2 Boris I. Bittker &
    Lawrence Lokken, Federal Taxation of Income, Estates and
    Gifts ¶ 47.1 (3d ed. 2000).
    To get around this problem, courts have created the
    substitute-for-ordinary-income doctrine. This doctrine says, in
    effect, that “‘lump sum consideration [that] seems essentially a
    substitute for what would otherwise be received at a future time
    as ordinary income’ may not be taxed as a capital gain.”
    
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1182
    (quoting Comm’r v. P.G. Lake, Inc.,
    
    356 U.S. 260
    , 265 (1958)) (alteration in original).
    The seminal substitute-for-ordinary-income case is the
    1941 Supreme Court decision in Hort v. Commissioner, 
    313 U.S. 28
    (1941). Hort had inherited a building from his father,
    and one of the building’s tenants canceled its lease, paying Hort
    a cancellation fee of $140,000. 
    Id. at 29.
    Hort argued that the
    cancellation fee was capital gain, but the Court disagreed,
    holding that the cancellation fee was ordinary income because
    the “cancellation of the lease involved nothing more than
    relinquishment of the right to future rental payments in return
    8
    for a present substitute payment and possession of the leased
    premises.” 
    Id. at 32.
    The Supreme Court bolstered the doctrine in Lake. P.G.
    Lake, Inc. was an oil- and gas-producing company with a
    working interest in two oil and gas 
    leases. 356 U.S. at 261
    –62.
    It assigned an oil payment right “payable out of 25 percent of
    the oil attributable to [Lake’s] working interest in the two
    leases.” 
    Id. at 262.
    Lake reported this assignment as a sale of
    property taxable as capital gain. 
    Id. But the
    Court disagreed,
    holding that the consideration received was taxable as ordinary
    income. 
    Id. at 264.
    The Court’s reasoning gave full voice to the
    substitute-for-ordinary-income doctrine: “The lump sum
    consideration seems essentially a substitute for what would
    otherwise be received at a future time as ordinary income.” 
    Id. at 265.
    Our Court has rarely dealt with this doctrine. We have
    only cited Lake twice—once in 1958, Tunnell v. United States,
    
    259 F.2d 916
    , 918 (3d Cir. 1958), and once in 1974, Hempt
    Bros., Inc. v. United States, 
    490 F.2d 1172
    , 1176, 1178 (3d Cir.
    1974) (citing Lake with approval, but deciding the case under a
    § 351—nonrecognition of transfers of property for corporate
    stock—analysis).
    The Latteras argue that the substitute-for-ordinary-
    income doctrine, which takes “property held by the taxpayer”
    outside the statutory capital-asset definition, did not survive
    9
    Arkansas Best. But although Arkansas Best ostensibly cabined
    the exceptions to the statutory definition, it made clear that the
    Hort–Lake “line of cases, based on the premise that § 1221
    ‘property’ does not include claims or rights to ordinary income,
    ha[d] no application in the present context.” Arkansas 
    Best, 485 U.S. at 217
    n.5. The Tax Court has several times confirmed that
    Arkansas Best “in no way affected the viability of the principle
    established in the [Hort–Lake] line of cases.” 
    Davis, 119 T.C. at 6
    (citing cases). And the Ninth Circuit agrees. 
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1185
    . We follow suit, holding that the substitute-for-
    ordinary-income doctrine remains viable in the wake of
    Arkansas Best.
    But there is a tension in the doctrine: in theory, all capital
    assets are substitutes for ordinary income. See, e.g., William A.
    Klein et al., Federal Income Taxation 786 (12th ed. 2000) (“A
    fundamental principle of economics is that the value of an asset
    is equal to the present discounted value of all the expected net
    receipts from that asset over its life.”); see also 
    Lake, 356 U.S. at 266
    (noting that the lump-sum consideration—held to be
    ordinary income—paid for an asset was “the present value of
    income which the recipient would otherwise obtain in the
    future”). For example, a stock’s value is the present discounted
    value of the company’s future profits. See, e.g., 
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1182
    ; cf. United States v. Dresser Indus., Inc., 
    324 F.2d 56
    , 59 (5th Cir. 1963) (applying this concept to the value of
    land). “[R]ead literally, the [substitute-for-ordinary-income]
    doctrine would completely swallow the concept of capital
    10
    gains.” 
    Levine, supra, at 196
    ; accord 2 Bittker & Lokken,
    supra, ¶ 47.9.5, at 47-68 (“Unless restrained, the substitute-for-
    ordinary-income theory thus threatens even the most familiar
    capital gain transactions.”). Also, an “overbroad ‘substitute for
    ordinary income’ doctrine, besides being analytically
    unsatisfactory, would create the potential for the abuse of
    treating capital losses as ordinary.” 3 
    Levine, supra, at 197
    . The
    doctrine must therefore be limited so as not to err on either side.
    C.      The lottery cases
    Even before the Ninth Circuit decided Maginnis, the Tax
    Court had correctly answered the question of whether sales of
    lottery winnings were capital gains. In Davis v. Commissioner,
    lottery winners had sold their rights to 11 of their total 14 future
    lottery payments for a lump sum. 
    119 T.C. 3
    . The Tax Court
    found that the lump-sum payment to the lottery winners was the
    “discounted value . . . of certain ordinary income which they
    otherwise would have received during the years 1997 through
    2007.” 
    Id. at 7.
    The Court held, therefore, that (1) the purchaser
    of the lottery payment rights paid money for “the right to
    receive . . . future ordinary income, and not for an increase in the
    value of income-producing property”; (2) the lottery winners’
    right to their future lottery payments was not a capital asset; and
    (3) the lump-sum payment was to be taxed as ordinary income.
    3
    Note that our holding in this case does not consider the
    substitute-for-ordinary-income doctrine in loss transactions.
    11
    Id.; see also 
    Watkins, 88 T.C.M. at 393
    (following Davis,
    in a post-Maginnis decision); 
    Clopton, 87 T.C.M. at 1219
    (citing Tax Court cases following Davis).
    In 2004 the Ninth Circuit decided Maginnis, the first (and
    so far only) appellate opinion to deal with this question.
    Maginnis won $9 million in a lottery and, after receiving five of
    his lottery payments, assigned all of his remaining future lottery
    payments to a third party for a lump-sum payment of
    $3,950,000. 
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1180
    . The Ninth Circuit
    held that Maginnis’s right to future lottery payments was not a
    capital asset and that the lump-sum payment was to be taxed as
    ordinary income. 
    Id. at 1182.
    The Court relied on the substitute-for-ordinary-income
    doctrine, but it was concerned about taking an “approach that
    could potentially convert all capital gains into ordinary income
    [or] one that could convert all ordinary income into capital
    gains.” 
    Id. The Court
    opted instead for “case-by-case
    judgments as to whether the conversion of income rights into
    lump-sum payments reflects the sale of a capital asset that
    produces a capital gain, or whether it produces ordinary
    income.” 
    Id. It set
    out two factors, which it characterized as
    “crucial to [its] conclusion,” but not “dispositive in all cases”:
    “Maginnis (1) did not make any underlying investment of capital
    in return for the receipt of his lottery right, and (2) the sale of his
    right did not reflect an accretion in value over cost to any
    underlying asset Maginnis held.” 
    Id. at 1183.
    12
    But two commentators have criticized the analysis in
    Maginnis, especially the two factors. See 
    Levine, supra, at 197
    –202; 
    Sinclair, supra, at 421
    –22.                   The first
    factor—underlying investment of capital—would theoretically
    subject all inherited and gifted property (which involves no
    investment at all) to ordinary-income treatment. See 
    Levine, supra, at 198
    . It also does not explain the result in Lake, where
    the company presumably made an investment in its working
    interest in oil and gas leases, yet the Supreme Court applied
    ordinary-income treatment. 
    Id. The second
    factor also presents analytical problems. Not
    all capital assets experience an accretion in value over cost. For
    example, cars typically depreciate, but they are often capital
    assets. See 
    Sinclair, supra, at 421
    . Levine criticizes the second
    factor for “attempt[ing] to determine the character of a gain
    from its amount.” 
    Levine, supra, at 199
    . The Maginnis Court
    held that there was no accretion of value over cost in lottery
    winnings because there was no cost, as “Maginnis did not make
    any capital investment in exchange for his lottery 
    right.” 356 F.3d at 1184
    . But if Maginnis’s purchase of a lottery ticket had
    been a capital investment, would the second factor automatically
    have been satisfied? (That is, the “cost” in that scenario would
    have been $1, and the increase would have been $3,949,999.)
    Our first instinct is no. Moreover, the second factor does not
    seem to predict correctly the result in both Hort (where a
    building was inherited for no “cost”) and Lake (where the
    13
    working interest in the oil lease presumably had a “cost”), in
    both of which the taxpayer got ordinary-income treatment.
    Thus, while we agree with Maginnis’s result, we do not
    simply adopt its reasoning. And it is both unsatisfying and
    unhelpful to future litigants to declare that we know this to be
    ordinary income when we see it. The problem is that, “[u]nless
    and until Congress establishes an arbitrary line on the otherwise
    seamless spectrum between Hort–Lake transactions and
    conventional capital gain transactions, the courts must locate the
    boundary case by case, a process that can yield few useful
    generalizations because there are so many relevant but
    imponderable criteria.” 2 Bittker & Lokken, supra, ¶ 47.9.5, at
    47-69 (footnote omitted).
    We therefore proceed to our case-by-case analysis, but in
    doing so we set out a method for analysis that guides our result.
    At the same time, however, we recognize that any rule we create
    could not account for every contemplated transactional
    variation.
    D.     Substitute-for-ordinary-income analysis
    In our attempt to craft a rubric, we find helpful a Second
    Circuit securities case and a recent student comment. The
    Second Circuit dealt with a similarly “seamless spectrum” in
    1976 when it needed to decide whether a note was a security for
    purposes of section 10(b) of the 1934 Securities and Exchange
    14
    Act. See Exch. Nat’l Bank of Chi. v. Touche Ross & Co., 
    544 F.2d 1126
    , 1138 (2d Cir. 1976). The Court created a “family
    resemblance” test, (1) presuming that notes of more than nine
    months’ maturity were securities, (2) listing various types of
    those notes that it did not consider securities, and (3) declaring
    that a note with maturity exceeding nine months that “does not
    bear a strong family resemblance to these examples” was a
    security. 
    Id. at 1138,
    1137–38. The Supreme Court, adopting
    this test in 1990, added four factors to guide the “resemblance”
    analysis: the motivations of the buyers and sellers, the plan of
    distribution, the public’s reasonable expectations, and applicable
    risk-reducing regulatory schemes. Reves v. Ernst & Young, 
    494 U.S. 56
    , 65–67 (1990).
    We adopt an analogous analysis. Several types of assets
    we know to be capital: stocks, bonds, options, and currency
    contracts, for example. See, e.g., Arkansas 
    Best, 485 U.S. at 222
    –23 (holding—even though, as noted above, the value of a
    stock is really the present discounted value of the company’s
    future profits—that “stock is most naturally viewed as a capital
    asset”); see also 
    id. at 217
    n.5 (distinguishing “capital stock”
    from “a claim to ordinary income”); Simpson v. Comm’r, 
    85 T.C.M. 1421
    , 1423 n.7 (2003) (distinguishing “currency
    contracts, stocks, bonds, and options” from a right to receive
    lottery payments). We could also include in this category
    physical assets like land and automobiles.
    15
    Similarly, there are several types of rights that we know
    to be ordinary income, e.g., rental income and interest income.
    In Gillette Motor, the Supreme Court held that ordinary-income
    treatment was indicated for the right to use another’s
    property—rent, in other words. 
    See 364 U.S. at 135
    . Similarly,
    in Midland-Ross, the Supreme Court held that earned original
    issue discount should be taxed as ordinary income. See United
    States v. Midland-Ross Corp., 
    381 U.S. 54
    , 58 (1965). There,
    the taxpayer purchased non-interest-bearing notes at a discount
    from the face amount and sold them for more than their issue
    price (but still less than the face amount). 
    Id. at 55.
    This gain
    was conceded to be equivalent to interest, and the Court held it
    taxable as ordinary income. 
    Id. at 55–56,
    58.
    For the “family resemblance” test, we can set those two
    categories at the opposite poles of our analysis. For example,
    we presume that stock, and things that look and act like stock,
    will receive capital-gains treatment. For the in-between
    transactions that do not bear a family resemblance to the items
    in either category, like contracts and payment rights, we use two
    factors to assist in our analysis: (1) type of “carve-out” and (2)
    character of asset.4
    1.     Type of carve-out
    4
    We borrow these factors from Thomas Sinclair’s
    comment, see 
    Sinclair, supra, at 401
    –03, but we differ from him
    slightly in the way we apply the character factor.
    16
    The notion of the carve-out, or partial sale, has
    significant explanatory power in the context of the Hort–Lake
    line of cases. As Marvin Chirelstein writes, the “‘substitute’
    language, in the view of most commentators, was merely a
    short-hand way of asserting that carved-out interests do not
    qualify as capital assets.” Marvin A. Chirelstein, Federal
    Income Taxation ¶ 17.03, at 369–70 (9th ed. 2002).
    There are two ways of carving out interests from
    property: horizontally and vertically. A horizontal carve-out is
    one in which “temporal divisions [are made] in a property
    interest in which the person owning the interest disposes of part
    of his interest but also retains a portion of it.” 
    Sinclair, supra, at 401
    . In lottery terms, this is what happened in Davis,
    Boehme, and Clopton—the lottery winners sold some of their
    future lottery payment rights (e.g., their 2006 and 2007
    payments) but retained the rights to payments further in the
    future (e.g., their 2008 and 2009 payments). See 
    Clopton, 87 T.C.M. at 1217
    –18 (finding that the lottery winner sold
    only some of his remaining lottery payments); 
    Boehme, 85 T.C.M. at 1040
    (same); Davis, 
    119 T.C. 3
    (same).
    This is also what happened in Hort and Lake; portions of the
    total interest (a term of years carved out from a fee simple and
    a three-year payment right from a working interest in a oil lease,
    respectively) were carved out from the whole.
    A vertical carve-out is one in which “a complete
    disposition of a person’s interest in property” is made. 
    Sinclair, 17 supra, at 401
    . In lottery terms, this is what happened in Watkins
    and Maginnis—the lottery winners sold the rights to all their
    remaining lottery payments. See 
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1181
    (noting that the lottery winner assigned his right to receive all
    his remaining lottery payments); 
    Watkins, 88 T.C.M. at 391
    (same).
    Horizontal carve-outs typically lead to ordinary-income
    treatment. See, e.g., 
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1185
    –86 (“Maginnis
    is correct that transactions in which a tax-payer transfers an
    income right without transferring his entire interest in an
    underlying asset will often be occasions for applying the
    substitute for ordinary income doctrine.”). This was also the
    result reached in Hort and Lake. 
    Lake, 356 U.S. at 264
    ; 
    Hort, 313 U.S. at 32
    .
    Vertical carve-outs are different. In Dresser Industries,
    for example, the Fifth Circuit distinguished Lake because the
    taxpayer in Dresser had “cut[] off a ‘vertical slice’ of its rights,
    rather than carv[ed] out an interest from the totality of its
    rights.” Dresser 
    Indus., 324 F.2d at 58
    . But as the results in
    Maginnis and Watkins demonstrate, a vertical carve-out does not
    necessarily mean that the transaction receives capital-gains
    treatment. See, e.g., 
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1185
    (holding “that
    a transaction in which a taxpayer sells his entire interest in an
    underlying asset without retaining any property right does not
    automatically prevent application of the substitute for ordinary
    income doctrine” (emphasis in original)); see also 
    id. at 1186.
    18
    Because a vertical carve-out could signal either capital-
    gains or ordinary-income treatment, we must make another
    determination to conclude with certainty which treatment should
    apply. Therefore, when we see a vertical carve-out, we proceed
    to the second factor—character of the asset—to determine
    whether the sale proceeds should be taxed as ordinary income or
    capital gain.
    2.      Character of the asset
    The Fifth Circuit in Dresser Industries noted that “[t]here
    is, in law and fact, a vast difference between the present sale of
    the future right to earn income and the present sale of the future
    right to earned income.” Dresser 
    Indus., 324 F.2d at 59
    (emphasis in original). The taxpayer in Dresser Industries had
    assigned its right to an exclusive patent license back to the
    patent holder in exchange for a share of the licensing fees from
    third-party licensees. 
    Id. at 57.
    The Court used this “right to
    earn income”/“right to earned income” distinction to hold that
    capital-gains treatment was applicable. It noted that the asset
    sold was not a “right to earned income, to be paid in the future,”
    but was “a property which would produce income.” 
    Id. at 59.
    Further, it disregarded the ordinary nature of the income
    generated by the asset; because “all income-producing property”
    produces ordinary income, the sale of such property does not
    result in ordinary-income treatment. 
    Id. (This can
    be seen in the
    sale of stocks or bonds, both of which produce ordinary income,
    but the sale of which is treated as capital gain.)
    19
    Sinclair explains the concept in this way: “Earned income
    conveys the concept that the income has already been earned
    and the holder of the right to this income only has to collect it.
    In other words, the owner of the right to earned income is
    entitled to the income merely by virtue of owning the property.”
    
    Sinclair, supra, at 406
    . He gives as examples of this concept
    rental income, stock dividends, and rights to future lottery
    payments. Id.; see also Rhodes’ Estate v. Comm’r, 
    131 F.2d 50
    ,
    50 (6th Cir. 1942) (per curiam) (holding that a sale of dividend
    rights is taxable as ordinary income). For the right to earn
    income, on the other hand, “the holder of such right must do
    something further to earn the income. . . . [because] mere
    ownership of the right to earn income does not entitle the owner
    to income.” 
    Sinclair, supra, at 406
    . Following Dresser
    Industries, Sinclair gives a patent as an example of this concept.
    
    Id. Assets that
    constitute a right to earn income merit capital-
    gains treatment, while those that are a right to earned income
    merit ordinary-income treatment. Our Court implicitly made
    this distinction in Tunnell v. United States, 
    259 F.2d 916
    (3d Cir.
    1958). Tunnell withdrew from a law partnership, and he
    assigned his rights in the law firm in exchange for $27,500. 
    Id. at 917.
    When he withdrew, the partnership had over $21,000 in
    uncollected accounts receivable from work that had already been
    done. 
    Id. We agreed
    with the District Court that “the sale of a
    partnership is treated as the sale of a capital asset.” 
    Id. The sale
    of a partnership does not, in and of itself, confer income on the
    20
    buyer; the buyer must continue to provide legal services, so it is
    a sale of the right to earn income. Consequently, as we held, the
    sale of a partnership receives capital-gains treatment. The
    accounts receivable, on the other hand, had already been earned;
    the buyer of the partnership only had to remain a partner to
    collect that income, so the sale of accounts receivable is the sale
    of the right to earned income. Thus, we held that the portion of
    the purchase price that reflected the sale of the accounts
    receivable was taxable as ordinary income. 
    Id. at 919.
    Similarly, when an erstwhile employee is paid a
    termination fee for a personal-services contract, that employee
    still possesses the asset (the right to provide certain personal
    services) and the money (the termination fee) has already been
    “earned” and will simply be paid. The employee no longer has
    to perform any more services in exchange for the fee, so this is
    not like Dresser Industries’s “right to earn income.” These
    termination fees are therefore rights to earned income and
    should be treated as ordinary income. See, e.g., Elliott v. United
    States, 
    431 F.2d 1149
    , 1154 (10th Cir. 1970); Holt v. Comm’r,
    
    303 F.2d 687
    , 690 (9th Cir. 1962); see also Chirelstein, supra,
    ¶ 17.03, at 376–77 (noting that “courts have held consistently
    that payments made to an employee for the surrender of his
    employment contract are ordinary”).
    The factor also explains, for example, the Second
    Circuit’s complex decision in Commissioner v. Ferrer, 
    304 F.2d 125
    (2d Cir. 1962). The actor José Ferrer had contracted for the
    21
    rights to mount a stage production based on the novel Moulin
    Rouge. 
    Id. at 126.
    In the contract, Ferrer obtained two rights
    relevant here: (1) the exclusive right to “produce and present” a
    stage production of the book and, if the play was produced, (2)
    a share in the proceeds from any motion-picture rights that
    stemmed from the book. 
    Id. at 127.
    After a movie studio
    planned to make Moulin Rouge into a movie—and agreed that
    it would feature Ferrer—he sold these, along with other, rights.
    
    Id. at 128–29.
    Right (1) would have required Ferrer to have
    produced and presented the play to get income, so it was a right
    to earn income—thus, capital-gains treatment was indicated.
    Right (2), once it matured (i.e., once Ferrer had produced the
    play), would have continued to pay income simply by virtue of
    Ferrer’s holding the right, so it would have become a right to
    earned income—thus, ordinary-income treatment was indicated.
    The Second Circuit held as such, dictating capital-gains
    treatment for right (1) and ordinary-income treatment for right
    (2). 
    Id. at 131,
    134.5
    5
    One well-known result that these factors do not predict
    is the Second Circuit’s 1946 opinion in McAllister v.
    Commissioner, 
    157 F.2d 235
    (2d Cir. 1946). In that case, a
    widow was forced to sell her life estate in a trust to the
    remainderman. 
    Id. at 235.
    Thus, she received a lump-sum
    payment in exchange for her right to all future payments from
    the trust. Although this was a vertical carve-out, susceptible to
    both types of treatment, she gave up her right to earned income,
    because she would have continued receiving payments simply
    22
    E.     Application of the “family resemblance” test
    Applied to this case, the “family resemblance” test draws
    out as follows. First, we try to determine whether an asset is
    like either the “capital asset” category of assets (e.g., stocks,
    bonds, or land) or like the “income items” category (e.g., rental
    income or interest income). If the asset does not bear a family
    resemblance to items in either of those categories, we move to
    the following factors.
    by holding the life estate. Thus, the sale proceeds should have
    received ordinary-income treatment. The Court held instead that
    capital-gains treatment was indicated. 
    Id. at 236.
           But the result in McAllister has been roundly criticized.
    The Tax Court in that case had held that ordinary-income
    treatment was proper, 
    id. at 235,
    and Judge Frank entered a
    strong dissent, 
    id. at 237–41
    (Frank, J., dissenting). The
    McAllister Court relied on a case that did not even discuss the
    capital-asset statute. 
    Id. at 237
    (majority opinion). Chirelstein
    writes that the “decision in McAllister almost certainly was
    wrong.” Chirelstein, supra, ¶ 17.03, at 373. And a 2004 Tax
    Court opinion did not even bother to distinguish McAllister,
    stating simply that it was “decided before relevant Supreme
    Court decisions applying the substitute for ordinary income
    doctrine” (referring, inter alia, to Lake). Clopton, 87 T.C.M.
    (CCH) at 1219.
    We consider McAllister to be an aberration, and we do
    not find it persuasive in our decision in this case.
    23
    We look at the nature of the sale. If the sale or
    assignment constitutes a horizontal carve-out, then ordinary-
    income treatment presumably applies. If, on the other hand, it
    constitutes a vertical carve-out, then we look to the character-of-
    the-asset factor. There, if the sale is a lump-sum payment for a
    future right to earned income, we apply ordinary-income
    treatment, but if it is a lump-sum payment for a future right to
    earn income, we apply capital-gains treatment.
    Turning back to the Latteras, the right to receive annual
    lottery payments does not bear a strong family resemblance to
    either the “capital assets” or the “income items” listed at the
    polar ends of the analytical spectrum. The Latteras sold their
    right to all their remaining lottery payments, so this is a vertical
    carve-out, which could indicate either capital-gains or ordinary-
    income treatment. But because a right to lottery payments is a
    right to earned income (i.e., the payments will keep arriving due
    simply to ownership of the asset), the lump-sum payment
    received by the Latteras should receive ordinary-income
    treatment.
    This result comports with Davis and Maginnis. It also
    ensures that the Latteras do not “receive a tax advantage as
    compared to those taxpayers who would simply choose
    originally to accept their lottery winning in the form of a lump
    24
    sum payment,” something that was also important to the
    Maginnis Court. 
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1184
    .6
    IV. Conclusion
    The lump-sum consideration paid to the Latteras in
    exchange for the right to their future lottery payments is
    ordinary income.7 We therefore affirm.
    6
    We do not decide whether Singer, who purchased the
    right to lottery payments from the Latteras, would receive
    ordinary income or capital gain if it later decided to sell that
    right to another third party. See 
    Maginnis, 356 F.3d at 1183
    n.4.
    Such a determination would need to be made on the specific
    facts of the transaction. For example, if Singer bought and sold
    such rights as part of its business, the lottery payment rights
    could theoretically fall under the inventory exclusion to the
    capital-asset definition. Cf. Arkansas 
    Best, 485 U.S. at 222
    (suggesting that if Arkansas Best had been a dealer in securities,
    its bank stock might have fallen within § 1221’s inventory
    exclusion).
    7
    The Latteras appear to argue that their lottery ticket was
    itself a capital asset. We do not need to address this issue, as we
    note that the Latteras did not sell their winning ticket to Singer.
    Instead, they relinquished it in 1991 to the Pennsylvania State
    Lottery so they could claim their prize. They sold Singer eight
    years later not the physical lottery ticket but their right to the
    annual lottery payments.
    25