Toledo Mack Sales v. Mack Trucks Inc ( 2008 )


Menu:
  •                                                                                                                            Opinions of the United
    2008 Decisions                                                                                                             States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    6-17-2008
    Toledo Mack Sales v. Mack Trucks Inc
    Precedential or Non-Precedential: Precedential
    Docket No. 07-1811
    Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2008
    Recommended Citation
    "Toledo Mack Sales v. Mack Trucks Inc" (2008). 2008 Decisions. Paper 937.
    http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2008/937
    This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 2008 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
    PRECEDENTIAL
    IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    _______________
    No: 07-1811
    _______________
    TOLEDO MACK SALES & SERVICE, INC.,
    Appellant,
    v.
    MACK TRUCKS, INC.
    _______________
    On Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Eastern District of Pennsylvania
    (D.C. No. 02-cv-4373)
    District Judge: Honorable Ronald L. Buckwalter
    _______________
    Argued March 5, 2008
    Before: BARRY, JORDAN, and HARDIMAN, Circuit
    Judges.
    Filed: June 17, 2008
    _______________
    Robert L. Byer [ARGUED]
    Wayne A. Mack, Jr.
    J. Manly Parks
    James H. Steigerwald
    David A. Degnan
    Duane Morris, LLP
    30 S. 17 th Street
    Philadelphia, PA 19103-4194
    Counsel for Appellant
    Barbara M. Mather [ARGUED]
    Jeremy Heep
    Christopher J. Huber
    Barak A. Bassman
    Pepper Hamilton LLP
    3000 Two Logan Square
    Eighteenth & Arch Streets
    Philadelphia, PA 19103-2799
    Counsel for Appellee
    _______________
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    _______________
    JORDAN, Circuit Judge.
    Toledo Mack Sales and Service, Inc. (“Toledo”)
    appeals from an order of the United States District Court for
    the Eastern District of Pennsylvania granting judgment as a
    matter of law in favor of Mack Trucks, Inc. (“Mack”) on
    Toledo’s claim under § 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act
    2
    (“Sherman Act”). Toledo also appeals the District Court’s
    grant of summary judgment for Mack on Toledo’s claim
    under the Robinson-Patman Act (“RPA”), and its grant of
    judgment as a matter of law for Mack on Mack’s
    counterclaim for misappropriation of trade secrets. Because
    we conclude that Toledo presented at trial enough evidence to
    permit the Sherman Act claim to go to the jury, we will vacate
    the District Court’s disposition of that claim and remand for
    further proceedings. We will affirm the District Court in all
    other respects.
    I.     Jurisdiction and Standard of Review
    The District Court exercised jurisdiction over Toledo’s
    claims pursuant to 28 U.S.C. § 1331, and over Mack’s
    counterclaim pursuant to 28 U.S.C. §§ 1332 and 1367(a).
    We have jurisdiction under 28 U.S.C. § 1291. We exercise
    plenary review over a district court’s decision to grant
    judgment as a matter of law. Northview Motors, Inc. v.
    Chrysler Motors Corp., 
    227 F.3d 78
    , 88 (3d Cir. 2000).
    Judgment as a matter of law is appropriate “only if, viewing
    the evidence in the light most favorable to the nonmovant and
    giving it the advantage of every fair and reasonable
    inference,” a verdict in favor of the nonmovant cannot be
    supported by legally sufficient evidence. Fair Hous. Council
    v. Main Line Times, 
    141 F.3d 439
    , 442 (3d Cir. 1998)
    (citations omitted).
    Our review of a district court’s order granting
    summary judgment is also plenary. Assaf v. Fields, 
    178 F.3d 170
    , 171 (3d Cir. 1999). Summary judgment is appropriate if
    3
    “the pleadings, the discovery and disclosure materials on file,
    and any affidavits show that there is no genuine issue as to
    any material fact and that the movant is entitled to judgment
    as a matter of law.” Fed. R. Civ. P. 56(c). As in our review
    of an order granting judgment as a matter of law, we must,
    when reviewing a summary judgment order, view all of the
    evidence in the light most favorable to the non-moving party
    and draw all reasonable inferences in that party’s favor.
    Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 456 (1992).
    II.       Background
    A.   Mack and Toledo
    Mack manufactures a variety of heavy-duty trucks and
    is said to enjoy significant power within the market for such
    vehicles.1 It distributes and services its products primarily
    through a nationwide network of authorized dealers, each of
    which is assigned a geographic region called an “Area of
    Responsibility” (“AOR”). A dealer’s AOR is not exclusive,
    and Mack’s stated policy is that dealers are free to sell
    anywhere in the country.
    1
    For example, Toledo’s expert economist, Frank Gollop,
    testified that “Mack [has] market power in both the heavy
    duty vocational [low cab over engine truck market,] as well
    as conventional straight truck markets, whether you look at
    the U.S. as a whole or the U.S., excluding the west.” (App. at
    A1676; see infra note 16).
    4
    Most of Mack’s trucks are made to order from various
    chassis, engine, and transmission options. When a potential
    customer contacts a Mack dealer, the dealer obtains a list of
    specifications from the potential customer and submits the list
    to Mack. Mack then informs the dealer of the price at which
    it is willing to sell the requested truck to the dealer. An
    important aspect of that price is a transaction-specific
    discount known as “sales assistance.” The amount of sales
    assistance that Mack offers a dealer on a particular transaction
    varies according to the nature of the relationship between the
    dealer and the customer, the number of trucks ordered,
    potential competition, and other factors. Dealers’ requests for
    sales assistance are submitted to a Mack District Manager,
    who has the authority to grant sales assistance up to a certain
    dollar amount. Requests for additional sales assistance
    beyond that amount typically must be submitted for approval
    by a Regional Vice President. Requests for sales assistance
    beyond the amount that a Regional Vice President may
    authorize must be approved by Mack’s Controller. Of course,
    the greater the discount that Mack provides to the dealer, the
    lower the price that the dealer can profitably charge the
    customer. Once Mack tells the dealer how much the dealer
    will have to pay for a truck, the dealer then prepares a quote
    for the potential customer, using, among other things, the
    price it must pay Mack to fulfill the customer’s order. If the
    customer accepts the dealer’s quote, the dealer orders the
    truck from Mack and Mack custom-builds it according to the
    customer’s specifications. The dealer then buys the truck
    from Mack and sells it to the customer. However, if the
    customer does not accept the dealer’s quote, the dealer
    5
    usually does not buy the truck from Mack and no sale takes
    place.
    Often, potential customers will solicit bids from
    multiple Mack dealers as well as from Mack’s competitors.
    Accordingly, Mack dealers compete against both non-Mack
    dealers and, at least in theory, among themselves. Because
    the amount of sales assistance Mack offers to a dealer on a
    potential sale is a significant factor in determining the price at
    which the dealer will in turn offer to sell a truck to a potential
    customer, it is also a significant factor in determining whether
    a potential customer decides to accept a dealer’s quote.
    Toledo was an authorized Mack dealer located, as one
    might guess, in Toledo, Ohio. Dave Yeager has owned
    Toledo since 1982. After acquiring Toledo, Yeager
    implemented a business strategy that focused on offering the
    lowest possible price to his customers. Until Mack
    terminated Toledo’s status as an authorized dealer, Toledo
    aggressively pursued its low-price sales strategy throughout
    the country, competing on price against other Mack dealers
    for sales in other dealers’ AORs.
    B.     Toledo’s Sherman Act Claim
    Toledo alleges that, by competing on price against
    other Mack dealers, it began to undermine an unlawful
    conspiracy that Mack and the dealers had developed to keep
    6
    prices on Mack products artificially high.2 According to
    Toledo, this conspiracy has two parts. First, Toledo claims
    that, beginning in the mid-1980s, individual Mack dealers
    entered into “gentlemen’s agreements” not to compete with
    each other on price. Second, Toledo alleges that, beginning
    in 1989, Mack entered into an agreement with its dealers that
    it would delay or deny sales assistance to any dealer who
    sought to make an out-of-AOR sale, thereby protecting
    dealers that sell within their own AORs. Toledo argues that
    the combination of the horizontal collusion among dealers
    and the vertical collusion between Mack and the dealers
    violates § 1 of the Sherman Act because it prevents Mack
    dealers from competing with one another, thereby allowing
    Mack and its dealers to maintain artificially high prices on the
    sale of Mack trucks. Toledo also asserts that Mack’s decision
    to deny it sales assistance on out-of-AOR sales violates the
    prohibition on discriminatory pricing embodied in the RPA.
    2
    The present case is not the first time Toledo and Mack
    have sparred over the antitrust implications of Mack’s
    approach to providing sales assistance. Between March 1988
    and October 1990, Toledo’s attorney sent several letters to
    Mack claiming that Mack’s conduct violated § 1 of the
    Sherman Act. In 1991, Toledo and Mack signed a release
    which read: “Each of Mack and Toledo hereby fully releases
    ... the other ... from any and all claims, demands, losses,
    expenses, action, cause of action, or liabilities whatsoever
    arising out of or in connection with sales assistance ...
    claimed, requested, approved, paid, credited, or rescinded as
    of the date of this release ... .” (App. at A4460-61.)
    7
    At trial, Toledo presented evidence to show the existence of
    the alleged horizontal and vertical agreements.
    1.     Toledo’s Evidence of Agreements Among
    Mack Dealers
    Toledo offered testimony that Mack dealers agreed not
    to compete with one another. Yeager, Toledo’s owner,
    testified that, while he was attending a dealer meeting in the
    late 1980s, two Mack dealers from New Jersey approached
    him and told him that “the way it works” in New Jersey is
    that “dealers don’t compete on price.” (App. at A513.)
    Toledo also introduced deposition testimony by Jack Lusty, a
    former District Manager for Mack who had been responsible
    for supervising Toledo from 1998 to 2002. Lusty said that,
    despite Mack’s official policy of allowing dealers to sell
    anywhere, Mack dealers had unwritten agreements not to
    compete with each other. Finally, Toledo introduced copies
    of handwritten notes taken at a Mack sales meeting in 1999
    by a consultant named Hallie Giuliano. At that time,
    Giuliano was working on a project for Mack and, according
    to her notes and an affidavit she signed later, she heard Ron
    Gerhard, a Mack employee, say at the sales meeting that
    “there was a ‘gentlemen’s agreement’ among Mack truck
    dealers that they would sell only in their own areas of
    responsibility. [Gerhard] also stated that some Mack truck
    dealers did not honor the ‘gentlemen’s agreements’ and
    engaged in sales efforts in other Mack dealers’ territories.”
    (App. at A3537.)
    8
    2.     Toledo’s Evidence of an Agreement
    Between Mack and Mack Dealers
    Toledo also presented three categories of evidence to
    show that Mack agreed with its dealers that it would deny
    sales assistance on sales a dealer tried to make outside of that
    dealer’s AOR. First, Toledo introduced recordings and notes
    of conversations between Yeager and various Mack
    executives referring to an informal policy against out-of-
    AOR sales. Second, Toledo introduced evidence that, in
    1989, Mack adopted an official policy of denying sales
    assistance on out-of-AOR sales. Toledo also presented
    evidence that this policy was the result of a meeting between
    Mack executives and dealer representatives. Finally, Toledo
    presented evidence that, despite Mack’s claims to have
    abandoned its prior policy, Mack in fact continued to enforce
    that policy until at least the time Toledo filed suit in 2002.
    With respect to evidence of an informal policy, Toledo
    introduced at trial notes taken in July 1988 by Richard Tracht,
    the Mack District Manager responsible for overseeing Toledo
    at that time. According to Tracht’s notes, Yeager asked him
    whether Mack approved of Toledo’s practice of selling trucks
    outside its AOR. Tracht recorded that he told Yeager that
    “Mack did not like [Yeager’s] policy as he was selling the
    majority of his trucks to already established Mack customers
    and in doing so was breaking established profit structures ...
    [making] the Mack dealers look bad in customers [sic] eyes
    causing a lot of concern between customers and dealers.”
    (App. at A3963.)
    9
    Toledo also introduced a cartoon Tracht sent to
    Yeager featuring two shabbily dressed men sitting in front of
    a “poor house,” with one man saying to the other,“[m]y Mack
    Distributorship did more business than any others in the state.
    The trick was to undercut my competitor’s rates.” (App. at
    A3286.) At the top of the cartoon, Tracht had typed: “This
    could be what we are headed for if we do not stop selling
    against other Mack dealers and concentrate on the real
    competition. Think about it!!” 
    Id. In addition,
    Toledo introduced a recording of a
    December 1988 telephone conversation3 between Yeager and
    Dennis Wurzelbacher, Mack’s then-Parts Promotion
    Manager. During that conversation, Yeager and
    Wurzelbacher discussed the sales of Mack parts called “glider
    kits,” which are bare truck bodies without engines or
    transmissions. Wurzelbacher told Yeager that “[t]he ...
    problem we have is there are certain dealers that are sending
    [sic] glider kits in other people’s backyards and we are
    getting calls on it.” (App. at A3994.3) Yeager then asked
    Wurzelbacher what Mack’s written policy was on dealers
    competing with one another. Wurzelbacher responded that
    he was not aware of an official company policy but that it
    was his opinion that “there was a policy that would say, hey,
    3
    Over the course of several years, Yeager had secretly
    recorded a number of telephone conversations between
    himself and various Mack executives, and those recordings
    featured prominently in Toledo’s evidence at trial.
    10
    you’re only supposed to sell in your territory, okay?” (App.
    at A3994.4.)
    Toledo also introduced evidence that Mack adopted an
    official policy of denying sales assistance on out-of-AOR
    sales. In 1989, Mack issued Marketing Distribution Bulletin
    38-89 (“Bulletin 38-89”). Under this “major ... change in
    official truck pricing policy” (App. at A3147), Mack sought
    to “enhance the competitive strength of Mack distributors
    within their respective geographic areas of sales and service
    responsibility.” 
    Id. To that
    end, Mack eliminated sales
    assistance on sales by a dealer outside the dealer’s AOR. The
    express purpose of the policy was to create “increased profit
    margins for Mack distributors as well as the Company.”
    (App. at A3147.)
    Toledo introduced evidence at trial to show that
    Bulletin 38-89 was the result of an agreement between Mack
    and its National Distributor Advisory Council (“NDAC”) to
    prevent dealers from engaging in sales outside their AORs.4
    Specifically, Toledo introduced a recording of a July 1989
    phone call between Yeager and Dick Murphy, a Mack Vice
    President, during which Yeager asked Murphy whether the
    4
    The NDAC consists of two Mack executives and seven
    dealers. The NDAC’s dealer members are elected by their
    peers at an annual dealers meeting. Two of the seven dealer
    representatives serve as NDAC’s Chairman and Vice
    Chairman, and the remaining five serve as representatives for
    five geographic regions.
    11
    NDAC had unanimously recommended Bulletin 38-89.
    Murphy responded, “Oh yes. Oh very much so. Very much
    so. I mean, something as significant as this, it had to come
    from all walks.” (App. at A4025.) Murphy indicated that
    some dealers had complained about the new policy. He then
    said “if there’s something that would justify [changing the
    policy] we’ll get the [NDAC] together and perhaps we’ll
    consider it.” (App. at A4024.)
    Toledo also introduced a recording of another July
    1989 conversation between Yeager and Gary Johnson,
    Mack’s Vice President of Distributor Sales. During that
    exchange, Johnson explained that he was “kind of new on the
    job” and then went on to say that
    the one thing I can tell you that would be fair
    and legitimate advice is that I think this policy
    [i.e., Bulletin 38-89] came about to a large
    extent because of the voice of the distributor
    organization. ... And if it’s probably ever gonna
    be changed or modified, it will come about as a
    result of the voice of the dealer organization.
    (App. at A4058.)
    Johnson then stated, “I can tell you, and this probably
    is not a surprise, that when we talked about some of the
    problems that come from selling outside of the territory, I
    guess Toledo goes pretty close to the top of the list.” (App. at
    A4059.) After some additional discussion, Yeager stated
    that, “[a]s I understand what [the dealer network did,] they
    12
    did not recommend [a] restrictional territorial system. ...
    [A]nd if they did, it’s strictly a self-serving type of thing for
    the dealers that have a lot of geographical area.” (App. at
    A4062-63.) Johnson responded by simply saying “Um-
    hmm.”5 (App. at A4063.)
    5
    Of course, on this and other points, Mack introduced
    evidence to contradict Toledo’s evidence. For example, Mack
    provided evidence to support its argument that Bulletin 38-89
    was solely the product of Mack management’s decision-
    making, not the NDAC’s. Bob Nuss, who was the NDAC
    Chairman during 1989, testified that, on May 8, 1989, Mack
    presented a draft of Bulletin 38-89 to the dealers at an NDAC
    meeting. According to Nuss, the draft included provisions
    eliminating sales assistance for out-of-AOR sales and
    provisions providing that Mack would give dealers sales
    assistance on one- and two- truck deals. Nuss also testified
    that “[t]he new truck retail pricing policy was discussed
    thoroughly”(App. at A2197), and that while the dealers had
    insisted that Bulletin 38-89 include sales assistance on one-
    and two-truck deals, the decision to eliminate sales assistance
    on out-of-AOR sales was made by Mack alone. Finally, Nuss
    testified that, although Mack solicited comments on Bulletin
    38-89 from NDAC members, the final language in Bulletin
    38-89 which eliminated sales assistance on out-of-AOR sales
    was identical to the language in the draft proposal circulated
    at the May 8, 1989 meeting. Mack’s evidence, however, does
    not override our obligation to view the evidence in the light
    most favorable to Toledo. See Northview 
    Motors, 227 F.3d at 88
    (explaining that judgment as a matter of law is
    13
    In October 1989, shortly after it had adopted Bulletin
    38-89, Mack issued a revised policy, Marketing Distribution
    Bulletin Addendum 38-89A (“Bulletin 38-89A”). Bulletin
    38-89A provided that “[s]ales [a]ssistance shall be uniformly
    made available to ALL Mack distributors on an equal basis,
    actively and directly involved in prior negotiations with the
    retail customer for the purchase of new Mack vehicles.”
    (App. at A3982 original emphasis). Toledo presented
    evidence at trial, however, indicating that, despite the new
    policy, Mack and some of its dealers continued to work in
    concert to prevent other Mack dealers from selling outside
    their individually assigned AORs.
    Regarding the period from 1989 to 1998, Toledo
    introduced a recording of a January 1991 telephone
    conversation between Yeager and Kevin Flaherty, Mack’s
    Vice-President for Sales. During the conversation, Yeager
    and Flaherty discussed some difficulties Yeager was having
    selling three trucks Toledo had bought from Mack.6 Yeager
    appropriate “only if, viewing the evidence in the light most
    favorable to the nonmovant and giving it the advantage of
    every fair and reasonable inference, there is insufficient
    evidence from which a jury reasonably could find liability”)
    (citations and internal quotation marks omitted).
    6
    A Mack dealer would ordinarily have little difficulty
    selling a truck it had bought from Mack because, as we have
    explained, Mack trucks are specialized, custom-made goods
    and a dealer ordinarily does not purchase a truck from Mack
    14
    requested sales assistance to sell those trucks outside of his
    AOR. Flaherty told him, however, that “our policy has not
    changed” and that Mack would provide sales assistance if
    Yeager sold the trucks inside his AOR but would not “give a
    whole lot of hope” if the sales were outside of it. (App. at
    4085-86.) Flaherty emphasized, “[O]bviously, we’re looking
    to protect our distributors. That’s always been the backbone
    of Mack is to protect our distributors.” (App. at 4086.)
    During a second conversation between Yeager and Flaherty
    in June 1991, Flaherty stated that “[if] there’s ever a
    manufacturer that protected their distributor organization ...
    It’s the Mack truck company, to a fault.” (App. at 4128.)
    Toledo also introduced a recording of a conversation
    that took place in 1996 between Yeager and Bob Grussing,
    Mack’s Parts Manager. Grussing told Yeager that dealers
    “constantly want Mack to get involved in these territorial
    disputes ... and to protect them from one another. And right
    or wrong, we do that, you know.” (App. at A4147.)
    until a customer actually places an order with the dealer.
    However, Yeager explained to Flaherty during their
    conversation that Toledo had ordered the three trucks
    discussed above because Mack “was in bad need of orders at
    that time” and had “encouraged [Toledo] to place an order.”
    (App. at A4087.)
    15
    Grussing also stated that such protection was a “long standing
    tradition” and that “I don’t know if I can break that.” 
    Id. To establish
    that Mack continued to participate in an
    illegal conspiracy with its dealers from 1998 to 2002, Toledo
    points to various conversations between Jack Lusty, the Mack
    District Manager responsible for supervising Toledo during
    that time period, and Jeff Yelles, a Mack Regional Vice
    President who was Lusty’s immediate superior. Lusty
    testified that Yelles told him in 2002 that he “kn[ew] what
    [Toledo] [was] trying to do. [Toledo] wants to establish
    discounts and sell trucks all over the place. We are not going
    to let this happen.” (App. at A2824.) Lusty also testified that
    Yelles told him that Yeager was “just soliciting customers on
    price; ... we have to beat the living shit out of him. ... [H]e is
    a son of a bitch.” (App. at A2818.) Yelles also allegedly told
    Lusty, in a profanity-laced burst of anger, that Toledo was not
    “play[ing] by the rules” and that someone “should take
    [Yeager] out.” (App. at A2825.)
    Toledo presented evidence that Yelles took affirmative
    steps to prevent Toledo from selling outside its AOR. Lusty
    testified that, in 2000, Yelles instructed him to tell Toledo to
    stop competing against another Mack dealer for a particular
    sale to a customer located outside Toledo’s AOR. Yelles told
    Lusty to tell Toledo that Mack would not release sales
    assistance on any sale by Toledo to that customer.
    Accordingly, Lusty sent Yeager a fax instructing him to
    “cease his predatory approach to customer prospecting.”
    (App. at 2812.) Yelles himself admitted at trial that, on at
    least one occasion in 2003, he asked Mack’s Controller, Steve
    16
    Polzer, to delay approving Toledo’s request for sales
    assistance so that another Mack dealer could get the
    customer’s business instead.
    Finally, Lusty testified that, after 1998, Mack used the
    sales assistance process to “control dealers.” After rescinding
    the 1989 policy, Mack implemented a system of “cross-
    checks” which were ostensibly designed to ensure that, in a
    situation where an out-of-AOR dealer competed with an in-
    AOR dealer, both dealers received the same amount of sales
    assistance from Mack. The system was presented by Mack as
    requiring equal treatment. Supposedly, a dealer who wished
    to make an out-of-AOR sale had to indicate to its District
    Manager the area into which the dealer wished to make the
    sale before it could receive sales assistance. The dealer’s
    District Manager would then conduct a cross-check by
    contacting the District Manager responsible for that AOR and
    informing him or her of the potential sale. If it turned out that
    the dealer into whose AOR the sale would be made was
    competing for the same deal, then the in-AOR District
    Manager and the out-of-AOR District Manager were to
    ensure that both dealers received equal amounts of sales
    assistance.
    Despite the stated purpose of the cross-checks,
    however, Lusty testified that from 1999 to 2003, the cross-
    checks were often used as an “early warning system” to let an
    in-AOR dealer know when an out-of-AOR dealer was
    attempting to make a sale inside the in-AOR dealer’s territory.
    (App. at A2877.) Lusty explained that District Managers
    would often grant requests for sales assistance verbally rather
    17
    than using Mack’s computer system, so that in-AOR dealers
    could give a potential customer a quote before an out-of-AOR
    dealer could obtain a quote on the same deal. Lusty also said
    that, because there was no record of verbal grants of sales
    assistance, District Managers would sometimes use this tactic
    to extend a discount to a dealer without conducting a cross-
    check.
    C.     Toledo’s RPA Claim
    Toledo also introduced expert testimony at trial to
    support its contention that Mack had offered it less favorable
    sales assistance than it provided to other dealers. That
    testimony was based on a comparison of the average amount
    of sales assistance Mack offered to Toledo as compared with
    the average amount of sales assistance Mack had offered to
    other dealers located in the same general geographic area.
    Toledo’s expert testified that this comparison demonstrated
    that Toledo received far less sales assistance than other
    similarly situated Mack dealers. However, the expert did not
    compare the amount of sales assistance Mack offered to
    Toledo and to other dealers when Toledo and another dealer
    competed directly against one another for a sale to the same
    customer. Therefore, the expert was unable to offer an
    opinion about whether Mack had discriminated against
    Toledo in sales involving head-to-head competition with
    another Mack dealer.
    18
    D.     Mack’s Counterclaim for Misappropriation of
    Trade Secrets
    Once sued, Mack fired back with a counterclaim
    alleging that Toledo had misappropriated a proprietary
    software program called MACSPEC 2001, which contained
    detailed parts specifications for every truck part that Mack
    manufactures. Mack had provided a copy of that program to
    Toledo so that it could adequately assist customers who
    needed replacement parts or repair work. However,
    according to Mack, Toledo gave a copy of MACSPEC 2001
    to PAI Industries, Inc., one of Mack’s competitors.
    Contending that Toledo had violated both its obligation not
    to misappropriate trade secrets and the terms of the
    MACSPEC 2001 license agreement, Mack terminated
    Toledo’s distributorship agreement. Toledo responded with a
    protest to the Ohio Vehicle Dealer’s Board, which ruled in
    favor of Toledo. Mack unsuccessfully appealed to the
    Franklin County Court of Common Pleas. Mack then further
    appealed to the Tenth Appellate District of the Ohio Court of
    Appeals. That court reversed and held that Mack was
    justified in terminating Toledo’s distributorship agreement
    because the MACSPEC 2001 software was a proprietary
    trade secret which Toledo had misappropriated by
    transferring it to a Mack competitor without Mack’s
    permission. Mack Trucks, Inc. v. Motor Vehicle Dealers Bd.,
    No. 05AP-768, 
    2006 WL 1495122
    , at *6-10 (Ohio Ct. App.
    June 1, 2006).
    19
    E.     Procedural History
    Toledo filed this case against Mack on July 7, 2002.7
    As already noted, Toledo’s complaint alleged that Mack and
    its distributors had entered into an illegal conspiracy in
    restraint of trade in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act, and
    that Mack had violated the RPA by engaging in
    discriminatory pricing. Again, as noted, Mack
    counterclaimed for misappropriation of trade secrets.
    Prior to the trial, the District Court granted summary
    judgment in favor of Mack on Toledo’s RPA claim,
    concluding that it was barred as a matter of law under Volvo
    Trucks North America, Inc. v. Reeder-Simco GMC, Inc., 
    546 U.S. 164
    (2006). At the close of evidence at trial, the District
    Court granted Mack’s motion for judgment as a matter of law
    on Toledo’s Sherman Act claim. The Court also granted
    Mack’s motion for judgment as a matter of law on the
    misappropriation of trade secrets counterclaim. As to the
    latter ruling, the Court concluded that the favorable judgment
    for Mack in the Ohio Court of Appeals was preclusive as to
    the issue of Toledo’s liability because the Ohio judgment
    encompassed every element necessary to show a
    misappropriation of trade secrets. The District Court then
    submitted Mack’s misappropriation counterclaim to the jury
    7
    Because of the 1991 release between it and Mack, (see
    supra note 2) Toledo limited its 2002 claims to “conduct by
    Mack subsequent to the date of the release.” (Appellant Br.
    at 16-17) (emphasis added).
    20
    on the issue of damages. The jury returned a verdict of
    $11.34 million.
    In an opinion and order denying Toledo’s post-trial
    motion for reconsideration, the District Court explained that
    Toledo’s § 1 claim was barred by the applicable four-year
    statute of limitations because “Yeager knew or had reason to
    know of the alleged conspiracy as early as 1989.” (App. at
    A5.) The District Court then presented a summary of
    Toledo’s evidence within the limitations period and, relying
    on Supreme Court cases discussing the special restrictions on
    the inferences that may permissibly be drawn from the
    evidence in antitrust cases, concluded that none of that
    evidence showed that an illegal conspiracy existed because
    “[t]he inferences [Toledo] wants to draw fall short of
    reasonable ones in the antitrust context.” (App. at A8.)
    Finally, the District Court reduced the jury’s damages award
    to $1.6 million, which Mack accepted. Toledo then filed this
    timely appeal.
    III.   Discussion
    Toledo raises three issues on appeal. First, it contends
    that it adduced sufficient evidence for its § 1 claim to go the
    jury and that, therefore, the District Court erred by granting
    judgment as a matter of law on that claim. Second, Toledo
    argues that the District Court erred in granting summary
    judgment in favor of Mack on its RPA claim because the
    database discussed at trial showed that Mack sold trucks to
    other dealers at favorable prices that it refused to extend to
    Toledo. Finally, Toledo contends that Mack’s counterclaim
    21
    for misappropriation of trade secrets is barred by
    Pennsylvania’s “gist of the action” doctrine. We discuss each
    of these arguments in turn.
    A.     Toledo’s Sherman Act § 1 Claim
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits “a conspiracy
    ... in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States
    ... .” 15 U.S.C. § 1. On appeal, the parties’ primary
    contentions concern whether Toledo’s evidence was sufficient
    to allow a jury to consider whether illegal agreements existed
    among Mack dealers and between Mack dealers and Mack
    itself.8 Before turning to the parties’ arguments on this point,
    8
    Collusion between a manufacturer and its dealers to keep
    a product’s price artificially high is likely to be an unusual
    phenomenon because other manufacturers and dealers of the
    same or substitute products can, simply by selling at a lower
    price, render the colluding parties’ agreement economically
    unwise. See Phillip E. Areeda, Herbert Hovenkamp,
    Fundamentals of Antitrust Law § 1603f (3d ed. 2007)
    (explaining that “[d]ealers cannot win excess profit through a
    distribution restraint unless a manufacturer who [agrees to
    assist] them has sufficient market power to make a restriction
    on output feasible and profitable.”). However, collusion
    between manufacturers and dealers is feasible when one
    manufacturer dominates the market, or when all
    manufacturers in the market enter into agreements with their
    dealers to keep prices artificially high. 
    Id. §§ 16.03f3,
    16.03f4. As discussed more fully herein, infra at 37-41, such
    22
    however, we address the District Court’s conclusion that
    Toledo’s suit was barred by the statute of limitations.
    1.      The Statute of Limitations
    Section 1 claims are subject to a four-year statute of
    limitations. 15 U.S.C. § 15b. In granting Mack’s motion for
    judgment as a matter of law on Toledo’s § 1 claim, the
    District Court declined to consider pre-1998 evidence of the
    existence of a conspiracy because it concluded that “Yeager
    knew or had reason to know of the alleged conspiracy as early
    as 1989 and thus the suit filed 13 years later [in 2002] was
    barred by the four-year statute of limitations.” (App. at A5.)
    The District Court then went on to examine whether evidence
    of events within the limitations period from 1998 to 2002 was
    sufficient to allow the jury to conclude that a conspiracy
    existed. The District Court concluded that the 1998 to 2002
    evidence was not sufficient because “the inferences [Toledo]
    wants to draw fall short of reasonable ones in an antitrust
    context.” (App. at A7 (citing In re Baby Food Antitrust Litig.,
    
    166 F.3d 112
    , 124 (3d Cir. 1999)).)
    collusive agreements may be unlawful under the rule of
    reason analysis applied to vertical price restraints under § 1.
    See, e.g., Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc., v. PSKS, Inc.,
    
    127 S. Ct. 2705
    , 2717 (2007) (explaining that “[t]o the extent
    a vertical agreement setting minimum resale prices is entered
    upon to facilitate [a dealer] cartel, it ... would need to be held
    unlawful under the rule of reason”).
    23
    Toledo argues that the District Court erred by requiring
    it to show exclusively with post-1998 evidence that a
    conspiracy existed. Instead, Toledo contends that the District
    Court should have considered whether all of the evidence it
    presented, including evidence of events prior to 1998, was
    sufficient to allow a jury to conclude that, from 1998 until at
    least 2002, Mack and its dealers engaged in overt acts in
    furtherance of a continuing conspiracy that began before
    1998. We agree. Although Toledo claims that the conspiracy
    began in 1989, long before the limitations period, it presented
    evidence from which a rational jury could conclude that the
    unlawful agreements continued in effect through the time of
    trial in 2002. Toledo seeks damages only for acts committed
    in furtherance of the conspiracy from 1998 to 2002, within the
    limitations period, but it is entitled to present evidence from
    outside that period to sustain its burden of proof.
    The Supreme Court has held that “[g]enerally, a cause
    of action under § 1 accrues and the statute of limitations
    begins to run when a defendant commits an act that injures
    the plaintiff’s business.” Zenith Radio Co. v. Hazeltine
    Research, Inc., 
    401 U.S. 321
    , 338 (1971) (citation omitted).
    However, “[i]n the context of a continuing conspiracy to
    violate the antitrust laws, ... each time a plaintiff is injured by
    an act of the defendant[] a cause of action accrues to [it] to
    recover the damages caused by that act ... and ... as to those
    damages, the statute of limitations runs from the commission
    of the act.” 
    Id. (citations omitted);
    see also Hanover Shoe,
    Inc. v. United Shoe Mach. Corp., 
    392 U.S. 481
    , 502 n.15
    (1968) (concluding that the plaintiff could bring a § 1 claim in
    1955 for conduct which first began in 1912 because the
    24
    defendant’s actions were “conduct which constituted a
    continuing violation of the Sherman Act, and which inflicted
    continuing and accumulating harm on [the plaintiff]”).
    Consistent with that precedent, we have stated that “a
    conspiracy’s refusal to deal, which began outside the
    limitations period, may be viewed as a continuing series of
    acts upon which successive causes of action may accrue.” In
    re Lower Lake Erie Iron Ore Antitrust Litig., 
    998 F.2d 1144
    ,
    1173 (3d Cir. 1993) (citation and internal quotation marks
    omitted). Therefore, we hold that Toledo was not required to
    prove an illegal conspiracy with evidence restricted to the
    limitations period. Its burden was, rather, to present evidence
    sufficient to allow a rational jury to conclude that Mack and
    its dealers committed during the limitations period overt acts
    in furtherance of an illegal conspiracy or conspiracies, even if
    the conspiracies began before the limitations period.9 We turn
    9
    Both in its brief and at oral argument, Mack argued that
    the District Court’s decision was correct because Toledo’s
    evidence and the inferences that could be drawn from that
    evidence would not allow a jury to conclude that any illegal
    conspiracy ever existed or, alternatively, that any conspiracy
    continued in effect during the limitations period. By its own
    terms, however, that argument is about the sufficiency of
    Toledo’s evidence, not about the legal rules governing
    continuing conspiracy cases under § 1. In a related argument,
    Mack contends that the 1991 release between it and Toledo,
    see supra note 2, bars Toledo’s § 1 claim. We disagree. The
    release does not apply to claims for antitrust damages based
    25
    now to whether the evidence that Toledo presented at trial
    meets that standard.
    2.     The Sufficiency of Toledo’s Evidence
    At the outset, we are mindful that, under our standard
    of review, we must “expose the evidence to the strongest
    light favorable to the party against whom the motion [for
    judgment as a matter of law] is made and give [that party] the
    advantage of every fair and reasonable inference.” Raiczyk v.
    Ocean County Veterinary Hosp., 
    377 F.3d 266
    , 269 (3d Cir.
    2004) (citation omitted). In addition, we must not “tightly
    compartmentalize the evidence,” but review it “as a whole to
    see if it together supports an inference of concerted action.”
    Petruzzi’s IGA Supermarkets, Inc. v. Darling-Delaware, Co.,
    Inc., 
    998 F.2d 1224
    , 1230 (3d Cir. 1993).
    Of course, we must comply with those standards in the
    context of the precise language of § 1 and the cases
    on events which occur after the execution of the release. Cf.
    Three Rivers Motor Co. v. Ford Motor Co., 
    522 F.2d 885
    ,
    896 n.27 (3d Cir. 1975) (holding that parties may not waive
    liability for future antitrust violations). Although the release
    prevents Toledo from seeking damages for events that
    occurred before 1991, Mack cites no authority, nor have we
    found any, for the proposition that a release prevents a party
    from relying on events that occurred prior to the signing of
    the release to establish facts necessary to show a continuing
    conspiracy.
    26
    interpreting it. As noted, § 1 prohibits “[e]very contract,
    combination ... or conspiracy, in restraint of trade.” We have
    explained that “[d]espite its broad language, Section 1 only
    prohibits contracts, combinations, or conspiracies that
    unreasonably restrain trade.” In re Flat Glass Antitrust
    Litig., 
    385 F.3d 350
    , 356 (3d Cir. 2004) (original emphasis).
    Thus, to succeed on a § 1 claim, a plaintiff must meet two
    requirements. First, the plaintiff must show that the
    defendant was a party to a “contract, combination ... or
    conspiracy.” Second, the plaintiff must show that the
    conspiracy to which the defendant was a party imposed an
    unreasonable restraint on trade.
    In the present case, Toledo alleges that Mack dealers
    entered into an unlawful conspiracy among themselves to fix
    prices, and Toledo further alleges that Mack agreed to
    support that conspiracy by, among other things, denying sales
    assistance to a dealer that, like Toledo, attempted to compete
    against other Mack dealers on price. In what follows, we
    analyze both of those purported agreements – the horizontal
    agreement among the dealers, and the vertical agreement
    between Mack and the dealers – to determine whether Toledo
    presented sufficient evidence for a jury to decide that each
    agreement existed and that each agreement was a conspiracy
    that unreasonably restrained trade in violation of § 1. As
    explained more fully below, special rules govern our analysis
    of Toledo’s evidence for the existence of the agreements and
    their legality.
    27
    a.     Toledo’s Evidence of an Unlawful
    Agreement Between Mack Dealers
    Because § 1 of the Sherman Act by its terms requires
    concerted action, “unilateral activity, no matter what its
    motivation, cannot give rise to a § 1 violation.” Rossi v.
    Standard Roofing, Inc., 
    156 F.3d 456
    , 465 (3d Cir. 1998).
    To show concerted action, a plaintiff must produce evidence
    that would allow a jury to infer that “the alleged conspirators
    had a unity of purpose or a common design and
    understanding, or a meeting of the minds.” Monsanto Co. v.
    Spray-Rite Serv. Corp., 
    465 U.S. 752
    , 764 (1984). Regarding
    the types of evidence which may be used to show that the
    concerted action requirement is met, we have said that,
    [w]hile direct evidence, the proverbial
    ‘smoking-gun,’ is generally the most
    compelling means by which a plaintiff can
    make out his or her claim, it is also frequently
    difficult for antitrust plaintiffs to come by.
    Thus, plaintiffs have been permitted to rely
    solely on circumstantial evidence (and the
    reasonable inferences that may be drawn
    therefrom) to prove a conspiracy.
    
    Rossi, 156 F.3d at 465
    .
    Further, to avoid punishing lawful conduct, the
    Supreme Court has placed certain limits on the inferences that
    may be drawn from the evidence in antitrust cases. The
    Court has explained that certain evidentiary restrictions are
    28
    necessary in antitrust cases since “mistaken inferences ... are
    especially costly because they chill the very conduct the
    antitrust laws are designed to protect.” Matsushita Elec.
    Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    , 594 (1986).
    Therefore, “antitrust law limits the range of permissible
    inferences from ambiguous evidence in a § 1 case. ...
    [C]onduct as consistent with permissible competition as with
    illegal conspiracy does not, standing alone, support an
    inference of antitrust conspiracy.” 
    Id. at 588
    (citations
    omitted). In addition, “if the factual context renders the
    plaintiff’s claim implausible – if the claim is one that simply
    makes no economic sense – a plaintiff must come forward
    with more persuasive evidence to support its claim than
    would otherwise be necessary.” 
    Rossi, 156 F.3d at 466
    (quoting 
    Monsanto, 475 U.S. at 587
    ) (punctuation omitted).
    Finally, “in evaluating whether a genuine issue for trial exists,
    the antitrust defendants’ economic motive is highly relevant.
    If the defendants had no rational economic motive to
    conspire, and if their conduct is consistent with other, equally
    plausible explanations, the conduct does not give rise to an
    inference of conspiracy.” 
    Id. (quoting Monsanto,
    475 U.S. at
    596) (punctuation omitted). Nevertheless, we have held that
    those limits on inferences do not apply to a plaintiff’s direct
    evidence of an unlawful agreement under § 1.10 
    Id. 10 We
    have held that the strictures on circumstantial
    evidence in antitrust cases
    only appl[y] when the plaintiff has failed to put
    forth direct evidence of conspiracy. Thus, in
    29
    In the present case, Toledo presented several pieces of
    direct evidence for the existence of one or more agreements
    among Mack dealers not to compete with each other.
    Because we conclude that Toledo’s direct evidence is
    sufficient to allow a jury to conclude that a conspiracy not to
    compete existed among Mack dealers, we need not apply the
    rules restricting inferences drawn from circumstantial
    evidence.
    Toledo’s first piece of evidence of an agreement not to
    compete was Yeager’s testimony that, in the early 1980s,
    other Mack dealers told him bluntly that dealers “did not
    compete on price.” (App. at A513.) Second, Mack consultant
    Hallie Giuliano testified that in 1999, Ron Gerhard, a Mack
    direct evidence cases, the plaintiff need not
    adduce circumstantial evidence that tends to
    exclude the possibility that the alleged
    conspirators acted independently, and there
    need not be an inquiry into the plausibility of
    the defendants’ claim or the rationality of
    defendants’ economic motives. This is because
    when the plaintiff has put forth direct evidence
    of conspiracy, the fact finder is not required to
    make inferences to establish facts, and therefore
    the Supreme Court’s concerns over the
    reasonableness of inferences in antitrust cases
    evaporate.
    
    Rossi, 156 F.3d at 466
    .
    30
    employee, told her that “there was a ‘gentlemen’s agreement’
    among Mack truck dealers that they would sell only in their
    own AORs ... [but] that some Mack truck dealers did not
    honor the ‘gentlemen’s agreements’ and engaged in efforts in
    other Mack dealers’ territories.” (App. at A3537.) Finally,
    when Jack Lusty, Yeager’s district manager from 1998 to
    2002, was asked whether “some Mack dealers [had] unwritten
    understandings with other Mack dealers that they wouldn’t
    compete in each other’s AOR’s,” he responded that “[t]here
    were – there were some Mack dealers that – and I’ve heard
    them called gentlemen’s agreements, where they wouldn’t
    compete in other dealers’ areas ... .” (App. at A2877.)
    While admitting that the record before us contains
    statements about agreements between dealers, Mack argues
    that Toledo’s evidence is insufficient to give to a jury because
    the record does not reveal the exact extent of any such
    agreements. Viewing the evidence in the light most favorable
    to Toledo, Mack’s argument is unpersuasive. It may well be
    that Toledo’s inability to present the details of any agreement
    among dealers would leave a jury unpersuaded that such
    agreements did in fact exist. That, however, is not our
    inquiry. Instead, we must consider whether the evidence
    entitles Toledo to place that question before the jury at all.
    We believe it does. Simply put, Toledo’s evidence was
    sufficient because a jury considering it could believe it and
    reasonably conclude that agreements not to compete did exist
    31
    among Mack dealers.11 The possibility that a jury might not
    believe the direct evidence does not, in itself, mean that the
    jury should not consider it.
    Having concluded that Toledo’s evidence was
    sufficient to show the existence of a non-competition
    agreement among Mack dealers, we turn to whether the jury
    could conclude that the agreement was an unreasonable
    restraint of trade in violation of § 1. When considering the
    legality of an agreement under § 1, two different methods of
    analysis may be used, depending upon the nature of the
    agreement at issue. “Certain restraints of trade are per se
    unreasonable, while others require more searching analysis
    under the ‘rule of reason.’” Flat 
    Glass, 385 F.3d at 356
    . Per
    se restraints are “conclusively presumed to unreasonably
    restrain competition ‘without elaborate inquiry as to the
    precise harm [they have] caused or the business excuse for
    [their] use.’” 
    Id. (quoting Rossi,
    156 F.3d at 461). The
    limited categories of agreements subject to per se treatment
    include “horizontal price-fixing - i.e., where competitors at
    the same market level agree to fix or control the prices they
    will charge for their respective goods or services ... .” 
    Id. (citations and
    internal punctuation and quotation marks
    11
    Consistent with our earlier discussion of the principles
    governing continuing conspiracy cases, we note that Toledo’s
    evidence of agreements between dealers includes statements
    about events that took place in the 1980s, outside the
    limitations period, as well as later statements and evidence
    about the existence of horizontal agreements.
    32
    omitted); see also 
    Leegin, 127 S. Ct. at 2717
    (“A horizontal
    cartel among ... competing retailers that ... reduces
    competition in order to increase price is, and ought to be, per
    se unlawful.”). It is readily apparent that, if there were an
    agreement among Mack dealers as alleged, it involved
    horizontal competitors colluding to control prices and,
    therefore, would be per se unlawful. Thus, viewed in the
    light most favorable to Toledo, the evidence shows a
    horizontal agreement that violates § 1.
    b.     Toledo’s Evidence of an Unlawful
    Agreement Between the Dealers
    and Mack
    Obviously, evidence sufficient to allow a jury to
    conclude that illegal agreements existed among Mack dealers
    does not establish that Mack itself was a party to an
    agreement that violated § 1 of the Sherman Act. Toledo
    contends, however, that it presented sufficient evidence to
    allow a jury to conclude that Mack did enter into an illegal
    vertical agreement with its dealers. According to Toledo, it
    showed an agreement between the dealers and Mack that
    Mack would support the dealers’ illegal conspiracy to control
    prices, and that one tool Mack employed to that end was a de
    facto ban on out-of-AOR sales by dealers like Toledo that
    sought to compete with other dealers on price.
    Our analysis of the alleged vertical agreement between
    Mack and its dealers follows the same pattern we used when
    considering the alleged horizontal agreement among the
    33
    dealers. First, we consider Toledo’s evidence of the
    agreement, and second, we consider the agreement’s legality.
    Toledo presented direct evidence that Mack agreed
    with its dealers to support their anti-competitive agreements
    and that it did so by, among other things, refusing to offer
    sales assistance to dealers who sought to sell outside their
    AORs.12 Jack Lusty testified that Jeff Yelles told him in
    2002, during the time when Mack ostensibly permitted its
    dealers to sell everywhere, that he “kn[ew] what [Toledo]
    [was] trying to do. [Toledo] wants to establish discounts and
    sell trucks all over the place. We are not going to let this
    happen.” (App. at A2824.) Lusty also testified that Mack
    executives used sales assistance to “control dealers and that
    the real purpose of Mack’s system of cross-checks was to
    give an in-AOR dealer the advantage over an out-of-AOR
    dealer.”
    12
    We reiterate that, under Rossi, we need not apply the
    strictures on inferences drawn from ambiguous circumstantial
    evidence that would apply in the absence of direct evidence of
    a conspiracy. Nevertheless, in addition to Toledo’s direct
    evidence of an agreement between the dealers and Mack,
    Toledo had indirect evidence of that conspiracy, including its
    evidence that Mack acted contrary to its own stated policy of
    allowing out-of-AOR sales. Even under Monsanto’s
    limitations on inferences from circumstantial evidence, that
    evidence appears to have been sufficient to create a jury
    question as to whether there was an agreement between Mack
    and its dealers.
    34
    Moreover, Mack does not contest that, in 1989, it
    issued Bulletin 38-89, which eliminated sales assistance to
    dealers on sales outside their AORs. Importantly for purposes
    of showing a conspiracy under § 1, Toledo presented evidence
    that Bulletin 38-89 was the result of a collaboration between
    Mack and its dealers. According to that evidence, Mack’s
    NDAC, a group consisting of both Mack executives and
    dealer representatives, worked on a draft of Bulletin 38-89.
    In addition, when Yeager asked Dick Murphy whether
    NDAC’s approval of the new policy was a “unanimous kind
    of thing,” Murphy responded, “Oh yes. Oh very much so.
    Very much so. I mean, something as significant as this, it had
    to come from all walks.” (App. at A4025.) Mack’s Vice
    President of Distributor Sales, Gary Johnson, told Yeager that
    the one thing I can tell you that would be fair
    and legitimate advice is that I think this policy
    came about to a large extent because of the
    voice of the distributor organization ... . If it’s
    probably ever gonna be changed or modified, it
    will come about as a result of the voice of
    dealer organizations.
    (App. at A4058.)
    Mack’s attempts to discredit Johnson’s statement about
    the dealers’ role in creating Bulletin 38-89 only demonstrates
    why the jury should have been given a chance to consider
    Toledo’s § 1 claim. First, Mack argues that Johnson was
    mistaken because, immediately before explaining the origins
    of the policy, he stated that he was “new on the job.” While a
    35
    jury presented with that argument might conclude that
    Johnson’s statements are insufficient to establish that Mack
    and its dealers conspired, that does not mean that a jury could
    not believe Johnson and reach the opposite conclusion.
    Johnson stated unequivocally that Bulletin 38-89 “came about
    to a large extent because of the voice of the distributor
    organization.” (App. at A4058.) Because Bulletin 38-89 was
    issued as official Mack policy, a jury presented with
    Johnson’s statement, along with Murphy’s statement, could
    rationally conclude that Bulletin 38-89 was the result of an
    agreement between Mack and its dealers.
    Mack also attacks Johnson’s statement by citing our
    decision in Edward J. Sweeney & Sons, Inc. v. Texaco Inc.,
    
    637 F.2d 105
    (3d Cir. 1980). In Sweeney, we held that
    testimony would not support an inference of conspiracy when
    a witness stated that he “believed [the defendant] changed
    [the plaintiff’s] hauling allowance because of ... retailer
    complaints,” but then admitted that his opinion “was just an
    unsupported 
    surmise.” 637 F.2d at 112
    . Seizing on the
    witness’s statement in Sweeney that his belief was an
    “unsupported surmise,” Mack argues that, because Johnson
    only told Yeager “what [he] th[ought] occurred,” his
    statement is insufficient to support an inference of conspiracy.
    We disagree. In the first place, Sweeney is inapposite because
    Johnson’s statement is direct evidence of collusion, which, if
    believed, requires no further inference. Second, unlike the
    witness in Sweeney, Johnson never stated that his belief about
    the origins of Bulletin 38-89 lacked support, and his position
    as Vice President of Distributor Sales buttresses the
    36
    conclusion that his statement was based on first-hand
    knowledge, not mere surmise.
    Mack’s argument that Murphy’s statements cannot be
    taken as showing a conspiracy is equally unpersuasive.
    Relying on Monsanto, Mack argues that the tape recording of
    Yeager’s conversation with Murphy shows, at most, that
    Mack responded to dealer complaints about Toledo. In
    Monsanto, the Supreme Court held that, to establish
    concerted action under § 1 using direct evidence, a plaintiff
    cannot simply show that the defendant received complaints
    about the plaintiff’s price cutting from other dealers, nor is it
    enough to show that the defendant received complaints and
    acted in 
    response. 465 U.S. at 764
    (citing 
    Sweeney, 637 F.2d at 111-12
    ). Instead, a plaintiff must produce evidence that
    would allow a jury to conclude that “the alleged conspirators
    had a unity of purpose or a common design and
    understanding, or a meeting of the minds.” 
    Id. The necessary
    “meeting of the minds” requires “more than a
    showing that the distributor conformed to the suggested
    price. It means as well that evidence must be presented both
    that the distributor communicated its acquiescence or
    agreement, and that this was sought by the manufacturer.” 
    Id. at 764
    n.9.
    Mack argues that Yeager’s conversation with Murphy
    does not meet Monsanto’s requirements because, even if
    believed, it shows only that Mack adopted Bulletin 38-89 in
    response to dealer complaints. However, in Monsanto itself,
    the Court held that a jury should be permitted to consider
    whether a conspiracy existed based on evidence of a meeting
    37
    between Monsanto and its distributors. During the meeting at
    issue in that case, the parties discussed “Monsanto’s efforts to
    get the market place in order,” 
    id. at 765
    (internal punctuation
    omitted), and also discussed how to ensure a “level
    playground” in which the decision of the “umpire” in
    enforcing the “rules of the game” would be final, 
    id. at 766.
    The Supreme Court agreed that the report of the meeting
    could be describing “the likely reaction to unilateral
    Monsanto pronouncements.” 
    Id. at 766
    n.11. Nevertheless,
    the Court explained that the report could also indicate that
    Monsanto and its distributors entered into an illegal
    agreement and that “the interpretation of [the] ... testimony ...
    properly was left to the jury.” 
    Id. In this
    case, Toledo presented evidence that Mack and
    its dealers met, discussed, and unanimously approved Bulletin
    38-89 before Mack issued it. One view of the evidence may
    be, as Mack insists, that the dealers at the NDAC meeting
    were reacting to unilateral pronouncements by Mack, but
    another view is possible and entirely reasonable. Under
    Monsanto, then, how to view that evidence should be left to
    the jury.
    Toledo also presented evidence that the conspiracy
    between Mack and its dealers continued from 1989 until well
    into the limitations period. As we have noted, in October
    1989, Mack amended Bulletin 38-89 with Bulletin 38-89A,
    which stated a policy purportedly permitting dealers to sell
    38
    everywhere.13 However, Toledo presented direct evidence in
    the form of statements by various Mack executives that
    Mack’s policy against out-of-AOR sales continued unchanged
    despite the amendment to Mack’s official policy. For
    example, when Toledo attempted to sell three trucks outside
    its AOR in 1991, Kevin Flaherty told Yeager that “our policy
    has not changed,” and he indicated that Mack would provide
    sales assistance if Toledo sold the trucks inside its AOR but
    not outside of it. (App. at A4086.) Similarly, Bob Grussing,
    Mack’s Parts Manager, told Yeager in 1996 that dealers
    “constantly want Mack to get involved in these territorial
    disputes ... and to protect them from one another. And right
    or wrong, we do that, you know.” (App. at A4147.)
    Grussing also stated that such assistance was a “long standing
    tradition” and that “I don’t know if I can break that.” 
    Id. Mack attacks
    the statements by Flaherty and Grussing
    in various ways. Mack argues that Flaherty’s statements do
    not show that Mack’s policy remained unchanged because
    Flaherty was actually trying to convince Yeager to provide
    him with the information necessary to conduct a cross-check
    so that Toledo could compete on an equal footing with any
    13
    Mack argues that its decision to withdraw Bulletin 38-89
    and replace it with an official policy permitting out-of-AOR
    sales demonstrates that it withdrew from any conspiracy that
    had existed earlier in 1989. Whether Mack withdrew from a
    conspiracy, however, is a jury question. Cf. United States v.
    Lowell, 
    649 F.2d 950
    , 956 (3d Cir. 1981) (“[T]he question of
    withdrawal is for the finder of fact.”).
    39
    other Mack dealer that might be attempting to make the same
    sale. Once again, Mack would have us view the evidence in
    the light most favorable to it, even though we are bound to do
    just the opposite at this point in the case. Moreover, Jack
    Lusty testified that, although Mack claimed that its system of
    cross-checks was used to ensure that all dealers competing
    for the same sale received equal sales assistance, the real
    purpose of cross-checks was to prevent dealers from
    competing effectively with one another. Because we must
    assume the truth of Lusty’s testimony at this stage, Mack’s
    characterization of Flaherty’s statements, even if correct,
    would not prevent a jury from concluding that a conspiracy
    existed. Further, as Toledo points out, Flaherty’s statement
    that “our policy has not changed” was made after Mack had
    ostensibly retracted its ban on sales assistance on out-of-AOR
    sales. See 
    Rossi, 156 F.3d at 452
    , 478 (noting that actions by
    a party that are inconsistent with its stated policy support an
    inference of concerted action).
    Mack’s attack on Grussing’s statement is also flawed.
    Mack argues that because Grussing’s expertise was parts
    rather than trucks, his statements do not show a conspiracy
    involving truck sales. Again, this is an argument suited for
    presentation to a jury, not this Court. In addition, Yelles
    made several comments to Lusty that support the conclusion
    that, during the limitations period, Mack continued a policy
    of preventing dealers from selling outside their AORs. Of
    particular note, Yelles stated that Yeager “was not playing by
    the rules.” (App. at A2825.) A jury could reasonably
    understand that the “rules” Yelles was talking about were an
    40
    agreement not to engage in price competition outside one’s
    own AOR.14
    Viewed in the light most favorable to Toledo, these
    statements by Mack executives are sufficient to allow a jury
    to decide whether an agreement between Mack and its dealers
    continued into the limitations period. Mack’s arguments to
    the contrary fall short because they fail to recognize the
    nature of our inquiry. Rather than determining whether Mack
    actually violated § 1, our function now is simply to decide
    whether Toledo’s evidence is sufficient to allow a jury to
    consider Toledo’s § 1 claim.
    Because Toledo’s evidence was sufficient to allow a
    jury to conclude that Mack entered into a competition-
    restricting agreement with its dealers, the only remaining
    question before us as to that agreement is whether, if proven,
    it violates § 1 of the Sherman Act. In contrast to horizontal
    14
    Lusty also testified that in 2001, Yelles told him that he
    “kn[ew] what [Toledo] [was] trying to do. [Toledo] wants to
    establish discounts and sell trucks all over the place. We are
    not going to let this happen.” (App. at A2824.) Lusty also
    testified that in 2002, Yelles told him that Yeager was “just
    soliciting customers on price ... we have to beat the living shit
    out of him. ... [H]e is a son of a bitch.” (App. at A2818.)
    Finally, Yelles himself testified that, on at least one occasion
    in 2003, he asked Mack’s Controller to delay approving
    Toledo’s request for sales assistance so that a different Mack
    dealer could make a sale.
    41
    price-fixing agreements between entities at the same level of a
    product’s distribution chain, the legality of a vertical
    agreement that imposes a restriction on the dealer’s ability to
    sell the manufacturer’s product is governed by the rule of
    reason. 
    Leegin, 127 S. Ct. at 2725
    . The rule of reason
    analysis applies even when, as in this case, the plaintiff
    alleges that the purpose of the vertical agreement between a
    manufacturer and its dealers is to support illegal horizontal
    agreements between multiple dealers. 
    Id. at 2717
    (“A
    horizontal cartel among competing manufacturers or
    competing retailers that decreases output or reduces
    competition in order to increase price is, and ought to be, per
    se unlawful. To the extent a vertical agreement setting
    minimum resale prices is entered upon to facilitate either type
    of cartel, it, too, would need to be held unlawful under the
    rule of reason.”) (citation omitted and emphasis added).15
    15
    We note that in Rossi we characterized the agreement at
    issue as horizontal and subject to per se analysis even though
    Rossi, like Toledo here, alleged that his direct competitors
    conspired with each other and with a common manufacturer
    to cut off his access to 
    customers. 156 F.3d at 458
    , 461-62.
    At that time, agreements to set minimum resale prices were
    per se unlawful under § 1. See 
    id. (“We agree
    with
    defendants that if this were simply a vertical conspiracy,
    between one horizontal competitor and one supplier or
    manufacturer, we would analyze it under the rule of reason
    unless there were some evidence of price fixing.”) (emphasis
    added). After Leegin, vertical agreements to set prices are no
    longer per se unlawful but subject to the rule of reason. 127
    42
    “When conducting a rule of reason inquiry, the
    factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in
    deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as
    imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition.” AT & T
    Corp. v. JMC Telecom, LLC,
    
    470 F.3d 525
    , 531 n.7 (3d Cir. 2006) (citations omitted). In
    Rossi, we identified four factors that are relevant to an
    analysis of a restraint under the rule of reason:
    (1) that the defendants contracted, combined or
    conspired among each other; (2) that the
    combination or conspiracy produced adverse,
    anti-competitive effects within the relevant
    product and geographic markets; (3) that the
    objects of and the conduct pursuant to that
    contract or conspiracy were illegal; and (4) that
    the plaintiffs were injured as a proximate result
    of that 
    conspiracy. 156 F.3d at 464-65
    (citation omitted).
    S. Ct. at 2725. In light of Leegin, we conclude that the rule of
    reason, not per se analysis, applies to the vertical agreement
    Toledo alleges was in existence here. Cf. United States v.
    Fisher, 
    502 F.3d 293
    , 296 (3d Cir. 2007) (citation omitted)
    (explaining that while a panel of this Court is ordinarily
    bound by the decision of a prior panel, a subsequent panel
    may depart from a previous panel’s decision if required to do
    so by an intervening Supreme Court decision).
    43
    In Leegin, the Supreme Court also identified
    additional issues relevant to the rule of reason inquiry. Two
    of those are particularly relevant to Toledo’s appeal. First,
    “[t]he source of the restraint may be an important
    consideration. If there is evidence retailers were the impetus
    for a vertical price restraint, there is a greater likelihood that
    the restraint facilitates a retailer cartel ... 
    .” 127 S. Ct. at 2719
    .
    Second, “that a dominant manufacturer or retailer can abuse
    resale price maintenance for anti-competitive purposes may
    not be a serious concern unless the relevant entity has market
    power.” 
    Id. at 2720.
    As to the first rule of reason factor we identified in
    Rossi, we have already explained that, viewed in the light
    most favorable to Toledo, the previously highlighted
    statements by Mack executives are sufficient to allow a jury
    to decide whether an agreement between Mack and its dealers
    continued into the limitations period. Further, we note that,
    consistent with Leegin, Toledo produced evidence that the
    agreement was the result of dealer pressure.
    Toledo also presented sufficient evidence to allow a
    jury to conclude that the agreement between Mack and its
    dealers produced anti-competitive effects in the relevant
    product and geographic markets. Toledo bears the burden of
    identifying those markets and showing the anti-competitive
    effect of the agreement between Mack and its dealers.
    Gordon v. Lewistown Hosp., 
    423 F.3d 184
    , 210 (3d Cir.
    2005). We have explained that proof of anti-competitive
    effects “can be achieved by demonstrating that the restraint is
    facially anticompetitive or that its enforcement reduced
    44
    output, raised prices or reduced quality. Alternatively,
    because proof that the concerted action actually caused
    anticompetitive effects is often impossible to sustain, proof of
    the defendant’s market power will suffice.” 
    Id. Market power
    is “the ability to raise prices above those that would
    prevail in a competitive market.” United States v. Brown
    Univ., 
    5 F.3d 658
    , 668 (3d Cir. 1993). At trial, Toledo
    presented expert testimony that Mack has power in two
    different product markets. The first of those markets is called
    the conventional straight truck market and includes vehicles
    that have an engine placed out in front of the driver’s cab.
    The second market consists of low cab over engine trucks, or
    LCOE trucks, which have an engine placed underneath the
    driver’s cab. Toledo’s expert testified that Mack “[has]
    market power in both the heavy duty vocational LCOE, as
    well as conventional straight truck markets, whether you look
    at the U.S. as a whole or the U.S., excluding the west.”16
    (App. at A1676.)
    Toledo also presented sufficient evidence that “the
    objects of and the conduct pursuant to th[e] contract or
    conspiracy were illegal.” 
    Rossi, 156 F.3d at 466
    . As
    explained, Toledo has alleged that Mack agreed to support the
    horizontal agreement among the dealers to control prices. In
    Leegin, the Supreme Court expressly condemned such
    
    agreements. 127 S. Ct. at 2717
    .
    16
    That assertion was supported by an analysis we need not
    recount here.
    45
    Finally, Toledo adduced evidence that it was injured
    as a result of the unlawful conspiracy. For example, Toledo
    presented evidence that, during the limitations period, Jeff
    Yelles asked Mack’s Controller to delay approving one of
    Toledo’s requests for sales assistance on an out-of-AOR sale
    so that another Mack dealer could make a sale. Toledo also
    presented evidence that, during the limitations period, Yelles
    refused to give sales assistance to Toledo on out-of-AOR
    sales.
    Applying the rule of reason analysis to Toledo’s § 1
    claim, we conclude that Toledo presented sufficient evidence
    of an illegal agreement between Mack and its dealers for a
    jury to find for Toledo. Therefore, we vacate and remand the
    District Court’s decision on that claim.
    B.     Toledo’s RPA Claim
    In addition to its § 1 claim, Toledo also argues that
    Mack’s conduct violates the RPA’s prohibition on
    discriminatory pricing. The relevant provision of the RPA
    provides that,
    [i]t shall be unlawful for any person engaged in
    commerce ... to discriminate in price between
    different purchasers of commodities of like
    grade and quality ... where the effect of such
    discrimination may be substantially to lessen
    competition ... or to injure, destroy, or prevent
    competition with any person who either grants
    or knowingly receives the benefit of such
    46
    discrimination, or with customers of either of
    them.
    15 U.S.C. § 13(a).
    Toledo argues that Mack engaged in discriminatory
    pricing by giving other Mack dealers more favorable
    discounts than were given to Toledo. At trial, Toledo
    presented expert testimony comparing the average amount of
    sales assistance Mack offered to Toledo with the average
    amount of sales assistance Mack offered other dealers located
    in the same general geographic area. Toledo’s expert testified
    that the comparison demonstrated that Toledo received far
    less sales assistance than other nearby Mack dealers.
    However, Toledo’s expert did not compare the amount of
    sales assistance Mack offered to Toledo and to other dealers
    when Toledo and another dealer actually competed against
    each other for a sale to the same customer. Therefore,
    Toledo’s expert was unable to offer an opinion about whether
    Mack had discriminated against Toledo in head-to-head
    competition.
    The RPA was originally enacted to “target the
    perceived harm to competition occasioned by powerful buyers
    rather than sellers; specifically, Congress responded to the
    advent of large chainstores, enterprises with the clout to
    obtain lower prices for goods than smaller buyers could
    demand.” Reeder-Simco GMC, 
    Inc., 546 U.S. at 175
    . In the
    Supreme Court’s recent decision in Reeder-Simco, the
    plaintiff was a Volvo dealer who, like Toledo, sold custom-
    made, specialized heavy-duty trucks. 
    Id. at 170-71.
    Like
    47
    Toledo, Reeder-Simco relied heavily on discounts offered by
    the truck manufacturer, in that case Volvo, to sell its trucks.
    
    Id. Finally, like
    Toledo, Reeder-Simco alleged that the
    manufacturer had violated the RPA by offering it less
    favorable discounts than were offered to other dealers. 
    Id. at 171-73.
    The Supreme Court noted that the alleged price
    discrimination did not implicate the original purpose of the
    RPA because “the allegedly favored purchasers are dealers
    with little resemblance to large independent department stores
    or chain operations, and the supplier’s selective price
    discounting fosters competition among suppliers of different
    brands.” 
    Id. at 181.
    Elsewhere in its opinion, the Court
    reinforced the need to interpret the RPA narrowly, explaining
    that “[i]nterbrand competition ... is the ‘primary concern of
    antitrust law.’” 
    Id. at 180
    (quoting Continental T.V., Inc. v.
    GTE Sylvania, Inc., 
    433 U.S. 36
    , 51 n.19 (1977)). The Court
    further explained that “[t]he [RPA] signals no large departure
    from that main concern. ... [W]e [will] resist interpretation
    geared more to the protection of existing competitors than to
    the stimulation of competition.” 
    Id. (emphasis in
    original).
    In short, the Court indicated that the RPA should be narrowly
    construed.
    In Crossroads Cogeneration Corp. v. Orange &
    Rockland Utilities, Inc., 
    159 F.3d 129
    , 142 (3d Cir. 1998), we
    were careful to keep the RPA confined. There, the defendant
    allegedly offered to sell electricity to certain customers at
    lower prices than it offered to its other customers, including
    Crossroads. 
    Id. We held
    that Crossroads’ RPA claim could
    not withstand a motion to dismiss because merely offering
    lower prices to a customer does not give rise to a price
    48
    discrimination claim. 
    Id. at 142.
    Instead, “a plaintiff must
    allege facts to demonstrate that (1) the defendant made at
    least two contemporary sales of the same commodity at
    different prices to two different purchasers; and (2) the effect
    of such discrimination was to injure competition.” 
    Id. (citation omitted).
    The Supreme Court in Reeder-Simco expressly
    declined to decide whether the RPA even applies to markets
    based on competitive bidding and special-order sales.
    
    Reeder-Simco, 546 U.S. at 180
    . Our decision in Crossroads,
    however, suggests that the RPA does not apply in a case such
    as this, which involves a single sale of a customized good via
    a competitive bidding process. Although Mack dealers may
    compete with one another by bidding against each other for
    the same deal, and the amount of sales assistance Mack offers
    to each dealer may well determine whether a customer
    chooses to accept a bid from one Mack dealer or another,
    Mack does not sell a truck to the dealer until the customer
    actually selects a dealer’s bid. Because no sale takes place
    until a customer accepts a dealer’s bid, the amount of sales
    assistance Mack is willing to provide to a particular dealer is
    part of an offer by Mack to sell, not a sale. Regardless of any
    competition between the dealers during the bidding process,
    only a dealer whose bid is accepted by a customer will
    actually buy a truck from Mack. Therefore, only one sale, not
    two, actually results.17 Cf. M.C. Mfg. Co., Inc. v. Texas
    17
    One might complain that this reasoning elevates form
    over substance, but we are bound by precedent and think it no
    49
    Foundries, Inc., 
    517 F.2d 1059
    , 1065 (5 th Cir. 1975) (“[I]n
    order for there to be discrimination between purchasers
    violative of [the RPA] there must be actual sales at two
    different prices to two different actual buyers ... .” (internal
    quotation marks and citation omitted)) .
    Finally, we reject Toledo’s argument that Corn
    Products Refining Co. v. FTC, 
    324 U.S. 726
    (1945), requires
    us to abandon the two-sales requirement we articulated in
    Crossroads. Corn Products involved a claim under § 2(e) of
    the Clayton Act which prohibits discrimination “in favor of
    one purchaser against another purchaser or purchasers of a
    commodity bought for resale ... by ... contributing to ... any
    services in connection with ... the sale or offering for sale of
    such commodity ... upon terms not accorded to all purchasers
    on proportionally equal terms.” 15 U.S.C. § 13(d). In Corn
    Products, the Federal Trade Commission filed suit against a
    sugar supplier that had agreed to pay a large portion of the
    advertising expenses of the Curtiss Candy Company
    (“Curtiss”), one of its principal customers, but did not agree
    to a similar arrangement with another customer who bought
    the same products. 
    Id. at 743.
    The sugar supplier argued that
    it had not provided advertising services to a “purchaser” of its
    injustice to narrowly interpret the oft-questioned RPA. Cf.
    Antitrust Modernization Commission, Report and
    Recommendations, April 2007, at iii, 317-26
    (recommendation by statutory commission, whose members
    were appointed by the President and Congress, that the RPA
    be repealed in its entirety).
    50
    product because nothing in the contract between it and
    Curtiss required Curtiss to buy sugar in exchange for the
    advertising. 
    Id. The Court
    rejected that argument, noting
    that Curtiss had in fact purchased all of its sugar from the
    supplier even though the contract in question did not require
    it to do so, and that the supplier had not paid the advertising
    expenses of any of the other companies that bought its sugar
    products. 
    Id. at 744.
    Corn Products, decided long before our opinion in
    Crossroads, does not require us to abandon the two-sales
    requirement in RPA cases. Assuming arguendo that a claim
    of discriminatory advertising is analogous to a claim of
    discriminatory pricing, Corn Products, unlike Reeder-Simco
    and the present case, involved two actual sales to different
    customers, as opposed to mere offers to sell. In short,
    Toledo’s policy arguments based on Corn Products do not
    override the import of Reeder-Simco or our own binding
    precedent. We will therefore affirm the District Court’s grant
    of summary judgment for Mack on Toledo’s RPA claim.
    C.     Mack’s Misappropriation of Trade Secrets
    Counterclaim
    Toledo’s final argument is that the District Court erred
    in granting judgment as a matter of law in favor of Mack on
    Mack’s counterclaim for misappropriation of trade secrets.
    On appeal, Toledo argues that Mack’s counterclaim is
    actually for breach of the MACSPEC 2001 license agreement,
    and that, under Pennsylvania’s “gist of the action” doctrine,
    Mack cannot recover in tort for breach of contract. The “gist
    51
    of the action” doctrine is “designed to maintain the conceptual
    distinction between breach of contract claims and tort claims
    [by] precluding plaintiffs from recasting ordinary breach of
    contract claims into tort claims.” eToll Inc. v. Elias/Savion
    Advertising Inc., 
    811 A.2d 10
    , 14 (Pa. Super. Ct. 2002). The
    focus of an analysis under the “gist of the action” doctrine is
    whether “actions lie from a breach of the duties imposed as a
    matter of social policy” or “from the breach of duties imposed
    by mutual consensus.” Redevelopment Auth. of Cambria
    County v. Int’l Ins. Co., 
    685 A.2d 581
    , 590 (Pa. Super. Ct.
    1995). We agree with the District Court that Mack’s claim
    for misappropriation of trade secrets sounds primarily in tort,
    rather than contract law, and therefore the “gist of the action”
    doctrine does not bar Mack’s counterclaim.
    The Ohio Court of Appeals found that Mack took
    several steps independent of issuing a license agreement to
    insure that its dealers did not give copies of the MACSPEC
    2001 software to unauthorized persons. Those steps included
    the use of “unlock codes” during the installation process and
    prominent warning screens informing users that unauthorized
    use would subject them to civil and criminal penalties. Mack
    Trucks, Inc. v. Motor Vehicle Dealers Bd., No. 05AP-768,
    
    2006 WL 1495122
    , at *7 (Ohio Ct. App. June 1, 2006).
    Thus, Toledo’s duty to keep the software confidential did not
    arise simply from its license agreement with Mack but,
    instead, had roots in its independent duty to keep Mack’s
    trade secrets confidential, and the counterclaim can properly
    52
    be seen as sounding in tort.18 We therefore reject Toledo’s
    argument and affirm the District Court’s grant of judgment as
    a matter of law on the counterclaim.
    IV.        Conclusion
    Mack presented sufficient evidence to allow a jury to
    consider its claim under § 1 of the Sherman Act.
    Accordingly, we will vacate the District Court’s grant of
    judgment as a matter of law and remand that claim for further
    proceedings. We will affirm the District Court’s disposition
    of Toledo’s RPA claim and Mack’s counterclaim for
    misappropriation of trade secrets.
    18
    In addition, we note that Toledo initially denied the
    existence of the contract it now uses to invoke the “gist of the
    action” doctrine. Toledo cannot properly change its position
    now. Tops Apparel Mfg. Co. v. Rothman, 
    244 A.2d 436
    , 439
    n.8 (Pa. 1968) (“When a [party] alleges a fact in a court of
    justice, for [its] advantage, [it] shall not be allowed to
    contradict it afterwards.”)
    53
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 07-1811

Filed Date: 6/17/2008

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/13/2015

Authorities (26)

Eugene F. Assaf v. George C. Fields Gary E. Crowell , 178 F.3d 170 ( 1999 )

Three Rivers Motors Company v. The Ford Motor Company and ... , 522 F.2d 885 ( 1975 )

Northview Motors, Inc. v. Chrysler Motors Corporation ... , 227 F.3d 78 ( 2000 )

The Fair Housing Council of Suburban Philadelphia v. Main ... , 141 F.3d 439 ( 1998 )

gary-raiczyk-v-ocean-county-veterinary-hospital-dr-peter-m-falk-dr , 377 F.3d 266 ( 2004 )

At & T Corp. v. Jmc Telecom, LLC , 470 F.3d 525 ( 2006 )

Alan D. Gordon, M.D. Alan D. Gordon, M.D., P.C., a ... , 423 F.3d 184 ( 2005 )

Edward J. Sweeney & Sons, Inc., and Mission Gas Oil Company,... , 637 F.2d 105 ( 1980 )

Crossroads Cogeneration Corporation v. Orange & Rockland ... , 159 F.3d 129 ( 1998 )

united-states-v-brown-university-in-providence-in-the-state-of-rhode , 5 F.3d 658 ( 1993 )

1993-1-trade-cases-p-70293-39-fed-r-evid-serv-234-petruzzis-iga , 998 F.2d 1224 ( 1993 )

in-re-baby-food-antitrust-litigation-jacob-blinder-sons-inc-wiseway , 166 F.3d 112 ( 1999 )

in-re-lower-lake-erie-iron-ore-antitrust-litigation-mdl-no-587 , 998 F.2d 1144 ( 1993 )

UNITED STATES of America v. Arthur S. LOWELL, Appellant , 649 F.2d 950 ( 1981 )

Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc. , 112 S. Ct. 2072 ( 1992 )

Corn Products Refining Co. v. Federal Trade Commission , 65 S. Ct. 961 ( 1945 )

M. C. Manufacturing Company, Inc. v. Texas Foundries, Inc. , 517 F.2d 1059 ( 1975 )

in-re-flat-glass-antitrust-litigation-mdl-no-1200-brian-s-nelson-dba , 385 F.3d 350 ( 2004 )

Etoll, Inc. v. Elias/Savion Advertising, Inc. , 811 A.2d 10 ( 2002 )

Continental T. v. Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc. , 97 S. Ct. 2549 ( 1977 )

View All Authorities »