A D Bedell Wholesale v. Philip Morris Inc , 263 F.3d 239 ( 2001 )


Menu:
  •                                                                                                                            Opinions of the United
    2001 Decisions                                                                                                             States Court of Appeals
    for the Third Circuit
    6-19-2001
    A D Bedell Wholesale v. Philip Morris Inc
    Precedential or Non-Precedential:
    Docket 00-3410
    Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2001
    Recommended Citation
    "A D Bedell Wholesale v. Philip Morris Inc" (2001). 2001 Decisions. Paper 133.
    http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2001/133
    This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 2001 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
    University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    ___________
    No. 00-3410
    ___________
    A.D. BEDELL WHOLESALE COMPANY, INC.;
    TRIANGLE CANDY & TOBACCO CO., on behalf of
    themselves and all others similarly situated,
    Appellants
    v.
    PHILIP MORRIS INCORPORATED;
    R.J. REYNOLDS TOBACCO COMPANY, INC.;
    BROWN AND WILLIAMSON TOBACCO CORP.
    _______________________________________________
    On Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Western District of Pennsylvania
    D.C. Civil Action No. 99-cv-00558
    (Honorable Donetta W. Ambrose)
    ___________________
    Argued December 14, 2000
    Before:    SCIRICA, FUENTES and GARTH, Circuit Judges
    (Filed: June 19, 2001)
    DAVID F. DOBBINS, ESQUIRE (ARGUED)
    Patterson, Belknap, Webb & Tyler
    1133 Avenue of the Americas
    New York, New York 10036
    WILLIAM M. WYCOFF, ESQUIRE
    Thorp, Reed & Armstrong
    One Oxford Centre
    301 Grant Street
    Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania 15219
    ALAN R. WENTZEL, ESQUIRE
    Windels, Marx, Lane & Mittendorf
    156 West 56th Street
    New York, New York 10019
    Attorneys for Appellants
    DOUGLAS L. WALD, ESQUIRE (ARGUED)
    Arnold & Porter
    555 12th Street, N.W.
    Washington, D.C. 20004
    BERNARD D. MARCUS, ESQUIRE
    Marcus & Shapira
    One Oxford Centre, 35th Floor
    301 Grant Street
    Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania 15219
    Attorneys for Appellee,
    Philip Morris Incorporated
    GREGORY G. KATSAS, ESQUIRE (ARGUED)
    Jones, Day, Reavis & Pogue
    51 Louisiana Avenue, N.W.
    Washington, D.C. 20001
    JOHN E. IOLE, ESQUIRE
    Jones, Day, Reavis & Pogue
    500 Grant Street, 31st Floor
    Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania 15219
    Attorneys for Appellee,
    R.J. Reynolds Tobacco Company, Inc.
    TIMOTHY P. RYAN, ESQUIRE
    Eckert, Seamans, Cherin & Mellott
    600 Grant Street, 44th Floor
    Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania 15219
    Attorney for Appellee,
    Brown and Williamson Tobacco Corp.
    ERIK S. JAFFE, ESQUIRE (ARGUED)
    5101 34th Street, N.W.
    Washington, D.C. 20008
    THOMAS C. O'BRIEN, ESQUIRE
    36 West 5th Street
    Corning, New York 14830
    Attorneys for Amici Curiae-Appellants,
    The Cato Institute, The Competitive Enterprise Institute,
    and The National Smokers Alliance
    JOEL M. RESSLER, ESQUIRE
    Office of Attorney General of Pennsylvania
    Strawberry Square, 15th Floor
    Harrisburg, Pennsylvania 17120
    Attorney for Amici Curiae-Appellees,
    Attorneys General of Pennsylvania, California, Alaska,
    American Samoa, Arizona, Arkansas, Colorado, Connecticut,
    Delaware, Georgia, Hawaii, Idaho, Illinois, Indiana, Iowa, Kansas,
    Kentucky, Louisiana, Maine, Maryland, Massachusetts, Michigan,
    Minnesota, Mississippi, Missouri, Montana, Nebraska, Nevada,
    New Hampshire, New Jersey, New Mexico, New York, North Carolina,
    North Dakota, Ohio, Oklahoma, Oregon, Rhode Island, South Carolina,
    South Dakota, Tennessee, Utah, Vermont, Virginia, Washington,
    West Virginia, and Wyoming
    __________________
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    __________________
    SCIRICA, Circuit Judge.
    This is an appeal from the dismissal under Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6)
    of claims
    brought under the Sherman Antitrust Act attacking the multi-billion dollar
    national
    tobacco settlement. Endeavoring to recoup billions of dollars in public
    health care costs
    and to reduce cigarette smoking, several states brought suit against the
    leading United
    States tobacco manufacturers. In view of the magnitude of potential
    liability and the
    prospect of multiple actions, the parties asked Congress to resolve the
    suits through a
    national legislative remedy. After congressional efforts stalled, forty-
    six states forged a
    settlement with the tobacco manufacturers known as the Multistate
    Settlement
    Agreement. Plaintiffs, who are cigarette wholesalers, challenge the
    Multistate Settlement
    Agreement as a violation of   1 and   2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act.
    The District Court held that plaintiffs failed to state a claim under
    the Sherman
    Act because the tobacco companies were immune from antitrust liability
    under both the
    Noerr-Pennington and Parker immunity doctrines. We agree they are immune
    under
    the Noerr-Pennington doctrine but not under the Parker doctrine. We will
    affirm.
    I.
    Facts and Procedural History
    A.D. Bedell, a cigarette wholesaler, brought this class action on
    behalf of itself
    and 900 similarly situated wholesalers seeking damages and a permanent
    injunction of
    the Multistate Settlement Agreement. Defendants, Philip Morris, Inc.,
    R.J. Reynolds
    Tobacco Co., Inc., and Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., are cigarette
    manufacturers
    who were original signatories to the Multistate Settlement Agreement.
    Along with
    Lorillard Tobacco Co., the fourth largest cigarette producer, they are
    collectively known
    as the major tobacco companies or the Majors. The Majors are responsible
    for 98% of
    cigarette sales in the United States. Bedell, as a wholesaler, bought
    directly from the
    Majors.
    In the mid 1990's, individual states commenced bringing law suits
    against the
    Majors to recoup healthcare costs and reduce smoking by minors. As one
    state Attorney
    General declared, "'[The] lawsuit is premised on a simple notion: you
    caused the health
    crisis; you pay for it.'" Janofsky, Mississippi Seeks Damages from
    Tobacco Companies,
    N.Y. Times, May 24, 1994, at A12 (quoting Mississippi Attorney General
    Mike Moore).
    The States alleged a wide range of deceptive and fraudulent practices by
    the tobacco
    companies over decades of sales. Faced with the prospect of defending
    multiple
    actions nationwide, the Majors sought a congressional remedy, primarily in
    the form of a
    national legislative settlement. In June 1997, the National Association
    of Attorneys
    General and the Majors jointly petitioned Congress for a global
    resolution.
    The proposed congressional remedy (1997 National Settlement Proposal)
    for the
    cigarette tobacco problem resembled the eventual Multistate Settlement
    Agreement, but
    with important differences. For example, although the congressional
    proposal would
    have earmarked 1/3 of all funds to combat teenage smoking, no such
    restrictions appear
    in the Multistate Settlement Agreement. 1997 National Settlement
    Proposal, Title VII,
    available at http://www.cnn.com/us/9705/tobacco/docs/proposal.html (last
    visited June
    18, 2001). In addition, the congressional proposal would have mandated
    Food & Drug
    Administration oversight and imposed federal advertising restrictions. It
    also would
    have granted immunity from state prosecutions; eliminated punitive damages
    in
    individual tort suits; and prohibited the use of class actions, or other
    joinder or
    aggregation devices without the defendant's consent, assuring that only
    individual
    actions could be brought. See 
    id. at Title
    V(A), VIII(A), VIII(B). The
    congressional
    proposal called for payments to the States of $368.5 billion over twenty-
    five years. 1997
    National Settlement Proposal, Title VI. By contrast, assuming that the
    Majors would
    maintain their market share, the Multistate Settlement Agreement provides
    baseline
    payments of about $200 billion over twenty-five years. See Multistate
    Settlement
    Agreement,     IX(a), (b), (c).
    Significantly for our purposes, the congressional proposal included
    an explicit
    exemption from the federal antitrust laws. See 1997 National Settlement
    Proposal, App.
    IV(C)(2) (stating cigarette manufacturers would have been permitted to
    "jointly confer,
    coordinate or act in concert, for this limited purpose [of achieving the
    goals of the
    settlement]"). The Multistate Settlement Agreement contains no
    corresponding
    exemption from the federal antitrust laws.
    Congress rejected the proposed settlement in the spring of 1998.
    Undeterred, the
    State Attorneys General and the Majors continued to negotiate and on
    November 23,
    1998, they executed the Multistate Settlement Agreement. Afterwards,
    twenty other
    tobacco manufacturers, representing 2% of the market, joined the
    settlement as
    Subsequent Participating Manufacturers (SPMs). The addition of the
    Subsequent
    Participating Manufacturers meant that nearly all of the cigarette
    producers in the
    domestic market had signed the Multistate Settlement Agreement. Their
    addition was
    significant. The Majors allegedly feared that any cigarette manufacturer
    left out of a
    settlement (Non-Participating Manufacturers or NPMs) would be free to
    expand market
    share or could enter the market with lower prices, drastically altering
    the Majors' future
    profits and their ability to increase prices to pay for the settlement.
    Plaintiffs brought suit challenging sections of the Multistate
    Settlement
    Agreement allegedly designed to maintain market share and restrict entry.
    The
    challenged sections of the Multistate Settlement Agreement are the so-
    called "Renegade
    Clause," the settlement's primary mechanism for allocating payment
    responsibilities
    based on production levels, and the provision calling for "Qualifying
    Statutes," which are
    state laws passed as a result of commitments made in the Multistate
    Settlement
    Agreement that require Non-Participating Manufacturers to pay into state
    escrow
    accounts for each sale made. Plaintiffs claim the Multistate Settlement
    Agreement and
    resulting state implementing statutes create an output cartel that imposes
    draconian
    monetary penalties for increasing cigarette production beyond 1998 levels
    and effectively
    bars new entry into the cigarette market.
    The Renegade Clause allegedly was designed to prevent current
    cigarette
    manufacturers from decreasing prices to increase market share and to bar
    new entrants
    from the market. One part of the Renegade Clause affects tobacco
    companies (SPMs)
    that later join the Multistate Settlement Agreement. This section creates
    strong
    disincentives for Subsequent Participating Manufacturers to increase their
    production
    and market share. If a Subsequent Participating Manufacturer exceeds its
    1998 market
    share (or exceeds 125% of 1997 market share if that is greater), then it
    must pay into the
    settlement fund. By maintaining historic market share, it would owe
    nothing to the
    settlement fund. For every carton of cigarettes sold in 1999 over its
    1998 level, a SPM
    would have to pay $.19/pack into the settlement fund. Plaintiffs contend
    this equaled
    75% of the wholesale price, which defendants do not contest. See Br. of
    Appellants at
    14 (applying MSA   IX(C)); MSA Ex. E. This mechanism allegedly
    discourages
    Subsequent Participating Manufacturers from underpricing the Majors to
    increase market
    share, even if they could efficiently do so.
    Another part of the Renegade Clause affects Non-Participating
    Manufacturers
    (NPMs), cigarette companies that never sign the Multistate Settlement
    Agreement. Non-
    Participating Manufacturers include potential new entrants into the
    tobacco market. See
    MSA    IX(d). But as noted, between the SPMs and the Majors, about 99% of
    the current
    cigarette producers signed the Multistate Settlement Agreement. The
    strictures of the
    Multistate Settlement Agreement affecting NPMs were largely responsible
    for such
    participation. Potential new entrants into the cigarette market would
    bear the burden of
    the Renegade Clause's future effects.
    Under the Renegade Clause, if Non-Participating Manufacturers gain
    market
    share (thereby reducing the Majors' market share) the Majors may decrease
    their
    principal payments to the settlement fund. If the Majors lose market
    share to NPMs, the
    payments to the settlement fund are not merely reduced proportionately.
    See MSA
    IX(d)(1)(A) & (B). For example, if a participating tobacco company lost
    10% of its
    market share to a new entrant or other company that did not sign the
    Multistate
    Settlement Agreement, it may be able to reduce its payments by as much as
    24%. See
    Hanoch Dagan & James J. White, Governments, Citizens, and Injurious
    Industries, 75
    N.Y.U. L. Rev. 354, 381 (2000) (making hypothetical calculations based on
    the formulas
    in MSA   IX(d)).
    By enacting the Qualifying Statute set forth in the Multistate
    Settlement
    Agreement, see MSA Ex. T, a state can preclude reduced payments. The
    model statute
    provides,
    Any tobacco product manufacturer selling cigarettes to
    consumers within the State . . . after the date of enactment of
    this Act shall do one of following:
    (a) become a participating manufacturer (as
    that term is defined in
    section II(jj) of the Master Settlement Agreement) and
    generally
    perform its financial obligations under the Master
    Settlement
    Agreement; or
    (b) (1) place into a qualified escrow fund .
    . . the following amounts
    . . . .
    
    Id. The model
    Qualifying Statute would impose a tax on new tobacco entrants of
    approximately $.27/pack in the year 2001, rising to $.36/pack by the year
    2007. See
    MSA Ex. T. A Non-Participating Manufacturer only can recover its
    deposited funds: (1)
    if it is forced to pay a judgment or settlement in connection with a claim
    brought by the
    state, or (2) after the passage of twenty years free from any such
    judgments. See 
    id. Because the
    Non-Participating Manufacturers are not part of the
    settlement, they have no
    immunity and would be subject to similar suits brought by the State
    Attorneys General
    against the Majors (for fraudulent concealment, misrepresentation,
    conspiracy, etc.). To
    encourage and assist the States in bringing these suits, the Multistate
    Settlement
    Agreement created a $50 million Enforcement Fund (paid for by the Majors)
    to
    investigate and sue NPMs to enforce the settlement. See MSA     VIII(c).
    Because of the
    Qualifying Statutes, a Non-Participating Manufacturer must decide either
    to join the
    Multistate Settlement Agreement and abide by the same restrictions on
    market share
    facing a SPM (which for new manufacturers would be costly because they
    would have a
    baseline production level of zero), or face litigation and pay a tax into
    a state established
    escrow account for any potential adverse judgments.
    Together, the Renegade Clause, the Qualifying Statutes and the
    Enforcement
    Fund allegedly create severe obstacles to market entry, or to increasing
    production and
    market share. This is not accidental. The Multistate Settlement
    Agreement explicitly
    proclaims its purpose to reduce the ability of non-signatory cigarette
    manufacturers to
    seize market share because of the competitive advantage accruing from not
    contributing
    to the settlement. It declares that the agreement "effectively and fully
    neutralizes the cost
    disadvantages that the Participating Manufacturers experience vis-a-vis
    Non-
    Participating Manufacturers with such Settling States as a result of the
    provisions of this
    Agreement." MSA    IX(d)(2)(E).
    It is these barriers to entry and increased production that
    plaintiffs claim form an
    output cartel that violates the antitrust laws. Because output is
    restricted and because of
    the inelastic demand for cigarettes, in part due to their addictive
    nature, the Multistate
    Settlement Agreement allegedly permitted the Majors to raise their prices
    to near
    monopoly levels Ä levels allegedly above those necessary to fund the
    settlement
    payments. For example, assert plaintiffs, the settlement could have been
    funded by only
    a $.19/pack increase in price, but the Majors immediately raised prices by
    $.45/pack, and
    subsequently by another $.31/pack. When this lawsuit was filed, the
    Majors had
    already raised the wholesale price of cigarettes $.76/pack since the
    adoption of the
    Multistate Settlement Agreement. Rapid price increases of this magnitude
    would
    ordinarily permit competitors to maintain or reduce prices or prompt new
    competitors to
    enter the market. But neither occurred, assert plaintiffs, because the
    barriers erected by
    the Multistate Settlement Agreement effectively barred entry and
    discouraged tobacco
    companies from maintaining a lower price because of the penalties for
    increased
    production.
    Defendants contend the Multistate Settlement Agreement did not
    violate the
    antitrust laws, but even if so, they are immune under both the Noerr-
    Pennington doctrine,
    which protects petitioning activity, and the Parker doctrine, which
    protects sovereign acts
    of states from antitrust liability. We turn first to the antitrust
    issues.
    II.
    Antitrust Injury
    The defendants argue the express terms of the Multistate Settlement
    Agreement do
    not constitute an agreement to limit output in violation of the antitrust
    laws. Plaintiffs
    counter that the Multistate Settlement Agreement's Renegade Clause,
    Qualifying
    Statutes, and Enforcement Fund, have the "unequivocal purpose and effect"
    to
    "effectuate a cartel limiting the output of cigarettes, thereby allowing
    the Majors to
    maintain supracompetitive prices," which is a per se violation of the
    antitrust laws. Br.
    of Appellants at 29.
    To maintain a cause of action under the Sherman Act, "[p]laintiffs
    must prove
    antitrust injury, which is to say (1) injury of the type the antitrust
    laws were intended to
    prevent and (2) that flows from that which makes defendants' acts
    unlawful." Brunswick
    Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 489 (1997) (emphasis in
    original). The
    antitrust injury requirement "ensures that the harm claimed by the
    plaintiff corresponds to
    the rationale for finding a violation of the antitrust laws in the first
    place, and it prevents
    losses that stem from competition from supporting suits by private
    plaintiffs." 2 Philip E.
    Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law   362 (Rev. ed. 1997).
    Here, the losses plaintiffs allege resulted from explicit provisions
    of the Multistate
    Settlement Agreement, not from competition. Plaintiffs allege the major
    tobacco
    companies formed and enforced a cartel to restrict output through the
    Multistate
    Settlement Agreement. As a result, plaintiffs claim the Majors "imposed
    artificially high
    prices on direct purchasers," without fear of competition. See Complaint
    2. Although
    this result would affect cigarette prices for retailers and consumers, as
    well as for
    wholesalers like plaintiffs, the Supreme Court has determined that direct
    buyers are the
    only parties with standing to assert damage claims under the antitrust
    laws for
    overcharges based on an output cartel. Ill. Brick Co. v. Illinois, 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 734
    (1977) ("[T]he antitrust laws will be more effectively enforced by
    concentrating the full
    recovery for the overcharge in the direct purchasers rather than by
    allowing every
    plaintiff potentially affected by the overcharge to sue only for the
    amount it could show
    was absorbed by it."). Although plaintiffs, as wholesalers, have alleged
    an injury, they
    must also demonstrate that the conduct which caused the injuries violated
    the antitrust
    laws.
    An agreement which has the purpose and effect of reducing output is
    illegal under
    1 of the Sherman Act. Cal. Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 
    526 U.S. 756
    , 777
    (1999) (output
    restrictions are anticompetitive); Nat'l Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Bd.
    of Regents of
    Univ. of Okla., 
    468 U.S. 85
    , 99 (1984) (where "the challenged practices
    create a
    limitation on output; our cases have held that such limitations are
    unreasonable restraints
    of trade") (citing United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 
    405 U.S. 596
    ,
    608-09 (1972));
    United States v. Sacony Vacuum Oil Co., 
    310 U.S. 150
    , 223 (1940). In
    California
    Dental, the Court restated that output restrictions are anticompetitive.
    At the same time,
    it refused to apply a "quick look analysis" where a local professional
    association had
    restricted certain types of advertising, but it was not obvious that the
    restrictions would
    be anticompetitive. Remanding for further analysis, the Court
    acknowledged that a
    reduction in output was an antitrust violation. Cal. Dental 
    Ass'n, 526 U.S. at 777
    , 781.
    The Court cited with approval a case from the Court of Appeals of the
    Seventh Circuit
    which held that if "'firms restrict output directly, price will rise in
    order to limit demand
    to the reduced supply. Thus, with exceptions not relevant here, raising
    price, reducing
    output, and dividing markets have the same anticompetitive effects.'" 
    Id. at 777
    (quoting
    General Leaseways, Inc. v. Nat'l Truck Leasing Ass'n, 
    744 F.2d 588
    , 594-95
    (7th Cir.
    1984)). The Court has made clear that a pure restriction on output is
    anticompetitive and
    in the absence of special circumstances, would violate the antitrust laws.
    
    NCAA, 486 U.S. at 85
    (recognizing that output restrictions may be permissible if
    required in order to
    market the product at all). By limiting production, the cartel is able to
    raise prices above
    competitive levels.
    Federal Trade Commission/Department of Justice Guidelines also
    recognize that
    agreements to reduce output violate the antitrust laws. See FTC/DOJ
    Guidelines
    Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors,    3.2,
    reprinted in 4 Trade
    Reg. Rep. (CCH)    20 (2000) (citing Broadcast Music Inc. v. Columbia
    Broad. Sys., 
    441 U.S. 1
    , 19-20 (1979)). These regulations define output agreements as
    "hard core cartel
    agreements" and violators are prosecuted criminally without regard to
    "claimed business
    purposes, anticompetitive harms, procompetitive benefits, or overall
    competitive effects."
    
    Id. Plaintiffs allege
    the agreement between the States and the Majors
    purposefully
    creates powerful disincentives to increase cigarette production.
    Although the Multistate
    Settlement Agreement contains no explicit agreement to raise prices or
    restrict market
    share, any signatory who increases production beyond historic levels
    automatically will
    increase its proportionate share of payments to the Multistate Settlement
    Agreement.
    Normally, a company which lowers prices would be expected to increase
    market share.
    But the penalty of higher settlement payments for increased market share
    would
    discourage reducing prices here. For this reason, signatories have an
    incentive to raise
    prices to match increases by competitors. It appears this incentive
    structure has proven
    true. The Majors' prices increased dramatically and simultaneously after
    signing the
    Multistate Settlement Agreement. As noted, this included a $.45/pack
    increase just days
    after the settlement was announced, an $.18/pack increase less than a year
    later, and a
    $.13/pack increase in January of 2000. The initial $.45 increase alone
    was more than
    double what some analysts considered necessary to fund the settlement's
    first two annual
    payments. See Stuart Taylor Jr., All for Tobacco and Tobacco for All, 23
    Legal Times
    40, Oct. 9, 2000.
    Defendants contend an antitrust analysis is unnecessary if we find
    either Noerr-
    Pennington or Parker immunity applies. But plaintiffs argue that immunity
    cannot attach
    to per se antitrust violations. We disagree. Recently we recognized
    immunity attached
    even where the plaintiff alleged a boycott regarded as illegal per se.
    Armstrong Surgical
    Ctr. Inc., v. Armstrong Mem'l Hosp., 
    185 F.3d 154
    , 157-58 (3d Cir. 1999)
    (applying
    Parker and Noerr-Pennington immunity where complaint alleged a threat of a
    boycott
    which would have constituted an antitrust violation in the absence of
    immunity), cert.
    denied, 
    530 U.S. 1261
    (2000). Similarly, in Pennington, the alleged
    conduct granted
    immunity would have been a per se violation of the antitrust laws. United
    Mine Workers
    v. Pennington, 
    381 U.S. 657
    , 660-61 (1965).
    Our review at this stage is limited to the allegations in plaintiffs'
    complaint. On a
    motion to dismiss under Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6), the issue is whether
    plaintiffs have
    properly pleaded an antitrust violation. Plaintiffs allege that
    defendants formed an
    output cartel through the Multistate Settlement Agreement that restricts
    production and
    effectively bars entry to the cigarette tobacco market. Plaintiffs also
    allege the cartel
    injured the tobacco wholesalers by charging artificially high prices.
    We hold that plaintiffs have properly pleaded an antitrust violation
    by alleging
    defendants agreed to form an output cartel through the Multistate
    Settlement Agreement
    that violates   1 and   2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act. But we will
    affirm if the parties
    to the Multistate Settlement Agreement are immune under the Noerr-
    Pennington or the
    Parker doctrines. We turn now to that question.
    III.
    Antitrust Immunity
    Defendants contend they are immune from antitrust liability under
    both the Noerr-
    Pennington doctrine, which immunizes parties involved in petitioning the
    government,
    and under the Parker doctrine, which immunizes sovereign state action.
    Although
    distinct doctrines, there is substantial overlap as both "work at the
    intersection of
    antitrust and governance." The two doctrines share a fundamental
    similarity. The
    Supreme Court has stated they are "complementary expressions of the
    principle that the
    antitrust laws regulate business, not politics; Parker protects the
    States' acts of
    governing, and Noerr the citizens' participation in government." City of
    Columbia v.
    Omni Outdoor Adver. Inc., 
    499 U.S. 365
    , 383 (1991). The District Court
    found
    defendants immune under both. We must affirm if defendants are immune
    under either
    doctrine.
    A. Noerr-Pennington Immunity
    Under the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, "[a] party who petitions the
    government for
    redress generally is immune from antitrust liability." Cheminor Drugs,
    Ltd. v. Ethyl
    Corp., 
    168 F.3d 119
    , 122 (3d Cir.), cert. denied, 
    528 U.S. 871
    (1999).
    Petitioning is
    immune from liability even if there is an improper purpose or motive. See
    E. R.R.
    Presidents Conference v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 
    365 U.S. 127
    , 138
    (1961) (holding
    that even if the petitioner's sole purpose was to destroy its competition
    through passage
    of legislation, petitioner would be immune); Prof'l Real Estate Investors,
    Inc. v.
    Columbia Pictures Indus., Inc., 
    508 U.S. 49
    , 56 (1993) (same). Rooted in
    the First
    Amendment and fears about the threat of liability chilling political
    speech, the doctrine
    was first recognized in two Supreme Court cases holding federal antitrust
    laws
    inapplicable to private parties who attempted to influence government
    action - even
    where the petitioning had anticompetitive effects. See Noerr, 
    365 U.S. 127
    ; United Mine
    Workers v. Pennington, 
    381 U.S. 657
    (1965). Under the Noerr-Pennington
    doctrine,
    "mere attempts to influence the Legislative Branch for the passage of laws
    or the
    Executive Branch for their enforcement" are given immunity from the
    Sherman Act and
    other antitrust laws. Cal. Motor Transp. Co. v. Trucking Unlimited, 
    404 U.S. 508
    , 510
    (1972). The immunity reaches not only to petitioning the legislative and
    executive
    branches of government, but "the right to petition extends to all
    departments of the
    Government," including the judiciary. 
    Id. Noerr-Pennington immunity
    applies to actions which might otherwise
    violate the
    Sherman Act because "[t]he federal antitrust laws do not regulate the
    conduct of private
    individuals in seeking anticompetitive action from the government." 
    Omni, 499 U.S. at 379-80
    . The antitrust laws are designed for the business world and "are
    not at all
    appropriate for application in the political arena." 
    Noerr, 365 U.S. at 141
    . This was
    evident in Noerr, where defendant railroads campaigned for legislation
    intended to ruin
    the trucking industry. Even though defendants employed deceptive and
    unethical means,
    the Supreme Court held that they were still immune. This is because the
    Sherman Act is
    designed to control "business activity" and not "political activity." 
    Id. at 129.
    With this
    underpinning, the Court stated, "[Because] [t]he right of petition is one
    of the freedoms
    protected by the Bill of Rights, . . . we cannot, of course, lightly
    impute to Congress an
    intent to invade these freedoms." 
    Noerr, 365 U.S. at 136
    . The antitrust
    laws were
    enacted to regulate private business and do not abrogate the right to
    petition.
    The scope of Noerr-Pennington immunity, however, depends on the
    "source,
    context, and nature of the competitive restraint at issue." Allied Tube &
    Conduit Corp.
    v. Indian Head, Inc., 
    486 U.S. 492
    , 499 (1988). If the restraint directly
    results from
    private action there is no immunity. See 
    id. at 500
    (where the "restraint
    upon trade or
    monopolization is the result of valid governmental action, as opposed to
    private action,"
    there is immunity). Passive government approval is insufficient. Private
    parties cannot
    immunize an anticompetitive agreement merely by subsequently requesting
    legislative
    approval.
    Under the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, private parties may be immunized
    against
    liability stemming from antitrust injuries flowing from valid petitioning.
    This includes
    two distinct types of actions. A petitioner may be immune from the
    antitrust injuries
    which result from the petitioning itself. See 
    Noerr, 365 U.S. at 143
    (finding trucking
    industry plaintiffs' relationships with their customers and the public
    were hurt by the
    railroads' petitioning activities, yet the railroads were immune from
    liability). Also, and
    particularly relevant here, parties are immune from liability arising from
    the antitrust
    injuries caused by government action which results from the petitioning.
    See
    
    Pennington, 381 U.S. at 671
    (holding plaintiffs could not recover damages
    resulting from
    the state's actions); Mass. Sch. of Law at Andover, Inc. v. Am. Bar
    Assoc., 
    107 F.3d 1026
    , 1037 (3d Cir. 1997) (holding Noerr gave immunity for any damages
    stemming
    from state adoption of requirements for bar admission to petitioners who
    lobbied for their
    adoption); 1 Areeda & 
    Hovenkamp, supra, at 202c
    . Therefore, if its
    conduct
    constitutes valid petitioning, the petitioner is immune from antitrust
    liability whether or
    not the injuries are caused by the act of petitioning or are caused by
    government action
    which results from the petitioning. Here, we must determine whether a
    settlement
    agreement between private parties and sovereign states fits within the
    context of
    protected petitioning envisioned by the Noerr-Pennington doctrine.
    Finding that negotiating the settlement was akin to petitioning the
    government, the
    District Court held defendants immune under Noerr-Pennington.
    Specifically, it held
    that the "concerted effort by defendants to influence public officials,
    i.e., the states'
    Attorneys General, to accept a settlement in exchange for dismissing the
    numerous
    lawsuits pending against defendants is among the activities protected by
    the Noerr-
    Pennington doctrine." A.D. 
    Bedell, 104 F. Supp. 2d at 506
    . We agree that
    defendants
    engaged in petitioning activity with sovereign states and are immune under
    the Noerr-
    Pennington doctrine.
    1.
    The importance of the right to petition has been long recognized. As
    early as
    1215, the Magna Carta granted barons the right to petition the King of
    England for
    redress. See Julie M. Spanbauer, The First Amendment Right to Petition
    Government
    for a Redress of Grievances: Cut From a Different Cloth, 21 Hastings
    Const. L.Q. 15, 17
    (1993) (detailing history of the right to petition from 1215 through
    colonial times, the
    constitutional convention, and today). During our colonial period, the
    right to petition
    was widely used. The importance of this right was fundamental - it
    guaranteed not
    merely expression but the preservation of democracy. "The very idea of
    government,
    republican in form, implies a right on the part of its citizens to meet
    peaceably for
    consultation in respect to public affairs and to petition for a redress of
    grievances."
    United States v. Cruikshank, 
    92 U.S. 542
    , 552 (1875).
    Because of the importance of the right to petition the government
    freely, and
    because "[a]ntitrust law was . . . not intended to impose a barrier
    between the people and
    their government," Noerr-Pennington immunity extends beyond filing formal
    grievances
    directly with the government. Balt. Scrap Corp. v. David J. Joseph Co.,
    
    237 F.3d 394
    ,
    398 (4th Cir. 2001) (holding secret funding of a lawsuit brought against a
    potential
    competitor to maintain a monopoly was protected under Noerr-Pennington,
    even though
    the funding party was not a litigant).
    In a recent survey of the application of Noerr-Pennington immunity to
    non-
    traditional petitioning, Primetime 24-Joint Venture v. Nat'l Broad. Co.,
    Inc., 
    219 F.3d 92
    , 99-100 (2d Cir. 2000), the Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit
    noted the
    Supreme Court has extended Noerr immunity to actions before administrative
    agencies
    and the courts, Cal. Motor 
    Transp., 404 U.S. at 508
    , 510-11, and that
    other courts have
    extended Noerr-Pennington immunity to include efforts to influence
    governmental action
    incidental to litigation such as prelitigation threat letters. McGuire
    Oil Co. v. Mapco.,
    Inc., 
    958 F.2d 1552
    , 1560 (11th Cir. 1992); Coastal States Mktg., Inc. v.
    Hunt, 
    694 F.2d 1358
    , 1367-68 (5th Cir. 1982). There would seem to be no reason to
    differentiate
    settlement from other acts associated with litigation. See Columbia
    Pictures Indus., Inc.
    v. Prof'l Real Estates Investors, Inc., 
    944 F.2d 1525
    , 1528-29 (9th Cir.
    1991), aff'd, 
    508 U.S. 49
    (1993) (affirming, but not addressing whether settlement creates
    immunity
    because sham exception defeated immunity). The Court of Appeals for the
    Seventh
    Circuit has recognized the application of Noerr-Pennington immunity to
    settlements
    between private parties and state government. In Campbell v. City of
    Chicago, 
    823 F.2d 1182
    , 1186 (7th Cir. 1987), two cab companies were found immune from
    antitrust
    liability for their agreement to settle their lawsuits against the city in
    exchange for the
    passage of a favorable and arguably anticompetitive ordinance. The
    settlement in
    Campbell resonates favorably with the Multistate Settlement Agreement
    here.
    The Supreme Court has yet to speak definitively on extending
    petitioning
    immunity to settlement agreements with sovereign states. Relying on a
    statement in
    Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting Systems Inc., plaintiffs
    claim the
    Supreme Court refused to extend immunity to settlement agreements when it
    stated that a
    "consent judgment, even one entered at the behest of the Antitrust
    Division, does not
    immunize the defendant from liability for actions, including those
    contemplated by the
    decree, that violates the rights of nonparties." 
    441 U.S. 1
    , 13 (1979).
    "But in any event,
    [we are] bound by holdings, not language." Alexander v. Sandoval, 
    2001 WL 408983
    (U.S.). We believe this case is easily distinguished. There was no
    settlement agreement
    in Broadcast Music. Rather, Broadcast Music involved actions taken years
    after the
    resolution of a claim by private actors who claimed they were acting under
    the protection
    of a consent decree. The Supreme Court ruled that the consent decree did
    not immunize
    the anticompetitive actions taken by private parties. For the above
    quoted language,
    Broadcast Music relied upon Sam Fox Publishing Co. v. United States, 
    366 U.S. 683
    ,
    689 (1961), which did not involve Noerr-Pennington immunity. Sam Fox
    addressed
    whether a non-participant is bound by the outcome of government antitrust
    litigation. 
    Id. Neither Broadcast
    Music nor Sam Fox mentioned Noerr-Pennington immunity,
    and
    neither is applicable to the facts here.
    Plaintiffs claim a motivating purpose behind the Multistate
    Settlement Agreement
    was to create a cartel guaranteeing tobacco companies supracompetitive
    profits. Br. of
    Appellants at 49. Similarly, plaintiffs claim the States were motivated
    by a desire to
    share in these revenues. But the parties' motives are generally
    irrelevant and carry no
    legal significance. See 
    Noerr, 365 U.S. at 138
    . At the same time, it
    bears noting that
    the petitioning here invoked the States' traditional powers to regulate
    the health and
    welfare of its citizens. See, e.g., Great Atlantic and Pac. Tea Co., Inc.
    v. Hugh B.
    Cottrell, 
    424 U.S. 366
    , 370 (1976) ("[U]nder our constitutional scheme the
    States retain
    'broad power' to legislate protection for their citizens in matters of
    local concern such as
    public health.").
    In sum, we see no reason to distinguish between settlement agreements
    and other
    aspects of litigation between private actors and the government which give
    rise to
    antitrust immunity. The rationale is identical. Freedom from the threat
    of antitrust
    liability should apply to settlement agreements as it does to other more
    traditional
    petitioning activities. We hold the defendants are immune under the
    Noerr-Pennington
    doctrine.
    B. Parker Immunity
    Having found the defendants immune under Noerr-Pennington, our
    analysis could
    end here. But the District Court found Parker immunity, so we will
    address it as well.
    Antitrust laws do not bar anticompetitive restraints that sovereign
    states impose
    "as an act of government." Parker v. Brown, 
    317 U.S. 341
    , 352 (1943); see
    also Mass.
    Sch. of Law at Andover, Inc. v. Am. Bar Assoc., 
    107 F.3d 1026
    , 1035 (3d
    Cir. 1997).
    The Parker doctrine relies heavily on the clarity of the State's goals and
    actions.
    "[S]tates must accept political responsibility for the actions they intend
    to undertake."
    FTC v. Ticor Title Ins. Co., 
    504 U.S. 621
    , 636 (1992). The key question
    is whether the
    allegedly anticompetitive restraint may be considered the product of
    sovereign state
    action. If it is not, then even if sectors of state government are
    involved, the activity will
    not constitute "state action" under the Parker doctrine and will not
    receive immunity.
    "State action," as defined in cases granting Parker immunity, is
    qualitatively
    different from "state action" in other contexts such as the Fourteenth
    Amendment. See 1
    Areeda & 
    Hovenkamp, supra, at 221
    . While the Fourteenth Amendment can
    cover
    inadvertent or unilateral acts of state officials not
    acting
    pursuant to state policy . . . the term "state action" in
    antitrust
    adjudication refers only to government policies that are
    articulated with sufficient clarity that it can be said that
    these
    are in fact the state's policies, and not simply happenstance,
    mistakes, or acts reflecting the discretion of individual
    officials.
    
    Id. Because it
    is grounded in federalism and respect for state
    sovereignty, this interest in
    protecting the acts of the sovereign state, even if anticompetitive,
    outweighs the
    importance of a freely competitive marketplace, especially in the absence
    of contrary
    congressional intent.
    Without clear congressional intent to preempt, federal laws should
    not invalidate
    state programs. "In a dual system of government in which, under the
    Constitution, the
    states are sovereign, save only as Congress may constitutionally subtract
    from their
    authority, an unexpressed purpose to nullify a state's control over its
    officers and agents
    is not lightly to be attributed to Congress." Parker v. Brown, 
    317 U.S. 341
    , 351 (1943).
    While individual anticompetitive acts of state governments may be
    considered unwise or
    counterproductive, the decision to make such choices lies within the
    sovereign power of
    the states. Congress did not intend to override important state interests
    in passing the
    Sherman Act. "The general language of the Sherman Act should not be
    interpreted to
    prohibit anticompetitive actions by the States in their governmental
    capacities as
    sovereign regulators." City of Columbia v. Omni Outdoor Adver., 
    499 U.S. 365
    , 374
    (1991).
    The Sherman Act was enacted to address the unlawful combination of
    private
    businesses. See Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, 
    310 U.S. 469
    , 493 n.15 (1940)
    ("The
    history of the Sherman Act as contained in the legislative proceedings is
    emphatic in its
    support for the conclusion that 'business competition' was the problem
    considered and
    that the act was designed to prevent restraints of trade which had a
    significant effect on
    such competition."). "There is no suggestion of a purpose to restrain
    state action in the
    Act's legislative history." 
    Parker, 317 U.S. at 313
    . The Sherman Act was
    passed "in the
    era of 'trusts' and of 'combinations' of businesses and of capital
    organized and directed to
    control of the market by suppression of competition in the marketing of
    goods and
    services, the monopolistic tendency of which had become a matter of public
    concern."
    
    Apex, 310 U.S. at 493
    . Given its focus on the problems of private
    monopolies and
    combinations, it is not surprising that the Sherman Act does not set out
    to curb clearly
    defined anticompetitive state actions. See Cal. Retail Liquor Dealers
    Assoc. v. Midcal
    Aluminum, Inc., 
    445 U.S. 97
    , 104 (1980).
    When a state clearly acts in its sovereign capacity it avoids the
    constraints of the
    Sherman Act and may act anticompetitively to further other policy goals.
    See S. Motor
    Carriers Rate Conference, Inc. v. United States, 
    471 U.S. 48
    , 54 (1985).
    For example,
    state governments frequently sanction monopolies to ensure consistent
    provision of
    essential services like electric power, gas, cable television, or local
    telephone service.
    But "a state does not give immunity to those who violate the Sherman Act
    by authorizing
    them to violate it, or by declaring that their action is lawful." 
    Parker, 317 U.S. at 351
    (states cannot authorize private parties to set a price and then enforce
    those prices
    without any evaluation of their reasonableness). Only an affirmative
    decision by the state
    itself, acting in its sovereign capacity, and with active supervision, can
    immunize
    otherwise anticompetitive activity.
    When it is uncertain whether an act should be treated as state action
    for the
    purposes of Parker immunity, we apply the test set forth in California
    Retail Liquor
    Dealers Association v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 
    445 U.S. 97
    , 104 (1980), to
    "determine
    whether anticompetitive conduct engaged in by private parties should be
    deemed state
    action and thus shielded from the antitrust laws."   Patrick v. Burget,
    
    486 U.S. 94
    , 100
    (1988). Applying Midcal is unnecessary if the alleged antitrust injury
    was the direct
    result of a clear sovereign state act. Mass. Sch. of Law at Andover v.
    Am. Bar Assoc.,
    
    107 F.3d 1026
    , 1036 (3d Cir. 1997); Session Tank Liners, Inc. v. Joor
    Mfg., Inc., 
    17 F.3d 295
    , 299 (9th Cir. 1994) (finding immunity from antitrust liability
    where "injuries
    for which [the plaintiff] seeks recovery flowed directly from government
    action"). In
    Massachusetts School of Law, we held that where "the states are sovereign
    in imposing
    the bar admission requirements [the alleged anticompetitive restraints],
    the clear
    articulation and active supervision requirements . . . are 
    inapplicable." 107 F.3d at 1036
    .
    There is less need for scrutiny "[w]hen the conduct is that of the
    sovereign itself . . .
    [because] the danger of unauthorized restraint of trade does not arise."
    PTI, Inc. v. Philip
    Morris, Inc., 
    100 F. Supp. 2d 1179
    , 1196 (C.D. Ca. 2000). Similarly,
    concerns about the
    legitimacy of the action are reduced. Thus we must first decide if Midcal
    applies to the
    States' actions in negotiating and implementing the Multistate Settlement
    Agreement.
    The Supreme Court has recognized state legislative and judicial
    action as
    sovereign under Parker. But "[c]loser analysis is required" when the
    action is less
    directly that of the legislature or judiciary. Hoover v. Ronwin, 
    466 U.S. 558
    , 568 (1984)
    (relying in part on Midcal). One Court of Appeals has decided that
    executive officers
    and agencies "are entitled to Parker immunity for actions taken pursuant
    to their
    constitutional or statutory authority, regardless whether these particular
    actions or their
    anticompetitive effects were contemplated by the legislature," without the
    need for
    Midcal analysis. Charley's Taxi Radio Dispatch Corp. v. SIDA of Haw.,
    Inc., 
    810 F.2d 869
    , 876 (9th Cir. 1987). We have yet to address whether the acts of
    executive officials
    constitute state action that avoids Midcal analysis. Furthermore, in this
    case, we must
    determine whether the antitrust injuries were more attributable to private
    parties than to
    government action, as was the case in Midcal.
    1. Direct Application of Parker
    An argument can be made that the Multistate Settlement Agreement, and
    any of its
    anticompetitive effects, were the direct result of state government
    action. For each
    signatory state, there was active involvement by high ranking executive
    officials and the
    agreement was subject to state court approval. The Multistate Settlement
    Agreement was
    negotiated by Attorneys General from each state to settle existing and
    contemplated
    lawsuits. The Multistate Settlement Agreement required that,
    each Settling State that is a party to a lawsuit . . .
    and each
    Participating Manufacturer will:
    (A) tender this agreement to the Court in
    such Settling
    State for its approval; and
    (B) tender to the Court in such Settling
    state for
    entry of a consent decree conforming to the
    model consent decree attached hereto as Exhibit
    L.
    MSA   XIII(b)(1); see also 
    PTI, 100 F. Supp. 2d at 1196
    .
    In most cases, the state legislatures were involved as well.
    Although they lacked a
    direct role in forming or approving the Multistate Settlement Agreement,
    the legislatures
    were charged with, and responsible for, the enactment of the Qualifying
    Statutes which,
    although technically voluntary, enforce important components of the
    Multistate
    Settlement Agreement. See MSA    IX(d)(2)(E), (F) and (G). It is apparent
    that
    legislative enactment of the Qualifying Statutes signified state approval
    of the Multistate
    Settlement Agreement. See Cal. Aviation Inc. v. City of Santa Monica, 
    806 F.2d 905
    ,
    909 n.5 (9th Cir. 1986) (noting statutes passed afterwards can be evidence
    of pre-existing
    state policy to allow anticompetitive behavior). In a few states, the
    legislatures played an
    even greater role by applying pressure on the Attorney General or Governor
    to bring suit
    or by passing legislation authorizing the Attorney General to bring suit
    against the
    tobacco companies. Additionally, each branch of state government had a
    role in the
    execution or operation of the Multistate Settlement Agreement. Under this
    analysis, one
    could find direct state action foreclosing the application of Midcal.
    Under a different view, we focus not on the negotiation and
    consummation of the
    Multistate Settlement Agreement, but on its actual operation and resulting
    effects, since
    that is the true cause of the anticompetitive effects. This is how the
    Supreme Court
    analyzed the behavior in Midcal.
    In Midcal, the price setting structure that resulted in antitrust
    injury would not
    have existed but for the state regulation. Only because of state
    legislative enactments did
    California wine producers hold power over the wholesalers to engage in
    resale price
    maintenance. 
    Midcal, 445 U.S. at 105
    . Because the actual parties
    involved in the
    anticompetitive behavior were private parties, the Supreme Court
    determined the alleged
    violation of the antitrust laws was not obvious state action and devised
    what has come to
    be known as the Midcal test.
    We have found direct state action, without Midcal analysis, only when
    the
    allegedly anticompetitive behavior was the direct result of acts within
    the traditional
    sovereign powers of the state. See Mass. Sch. of 
    Law, 107 F.3d at 1036
    ;
    see also
    Zimomra v. Alamo Rent-A-Car, Inc., 
    111 F.3d 1495
    , 1500 (10th Cir. 1997).
    In
    Massachusetts School of Law, we held Midcal inapplicable because the state
    acted as
    sovereign in imposing bar admission 
    requirements. 107 F.3d at 1036
    (Massachusetts
    School of Law at Andover, Inc., an unaccredited law school, had challenged
    the state
    requirement that a student graduate from an ABA accredited law school as
    an
    anticompetitive restraint). We distinguished Midcal and its progeny as
    "inapplicable
    because they dealt with situations where private parties were engaging in
    conduct . . .
    which led directly to the alleged antitrust injury." 
    Id. Similarly, in
    Zimomra, the Court
    of Appeals for the Tenth Circuit held Midcal inapplicable in a challenge
    to rental car
    price fixing because the city and county, and not a private actor, had the
    ultimate
    responsibility for setting rental car daily use fees and the private
    parties "had no such
    discretionary 
    authority." 111 F.3d at 1500
    . In neither case was a
    private party
    responsible for the resulting anticompetitive act; and thus there was no
    need to apply the
    Midcal analysis.
    Although the Multistate Settlement Agreement was a negotiated
    settlement by
    State Attorneys General, and the state legislatures were responsible for
    passing the
    Qualifying Statutes to enforce important components of the agreement,
    these acts by the
    governmental parties were not the direct source of the anticompetitive
    injuries.
    Therefore, it would appear that, just as the injury in Midcal was caused
    by private parties
    taking advantage of the state imposed market structure, the
    anticompetitive injury here
    resulted from the tobacco companies' conduct after implementation of the
    Multistate
    Settlement Agreement, and not from any further positive action by the
    States. Even
    though, as defendants argue, the Multistate Settlement Agreement created
    the cartel, this
    fact makes the case analogous to Midcal, not different.
    The signing of the Multistate Settlement Agreement and the
    establishment of the
    output cartel are not purely private actions, nor are they entirely
    attributable to the state in
    the manner of a legislative act. As such, this case resembles a "hybrid
    restraint" as
    discussed by Justice Stevens in his concurrence in Rice v. Norman Williams
    Co., 
    458 U.S. 654
    , 666-67 (1982) (Stevens, J., concurring).    Hybrid restraints
    are not the type
    of sovereign state action found in Massachusetts School of Law or Zimomra,
    that avoid
    Midcal treatment. Instead, hybrid restraints involve a degree of private
    action which
    calls for Midcal analysis. See 
    Rice, 458 U.S. at 666
    ("Hybrid restraints
    of this character
    require analysis that is different from a public regulatory scheme on the
    one hand, and a
    purely private restraint on the other.") (citations omitted) (Stevens, J.,
    concurring).
    Therefore, to determine if the allegedly anticompetitive sections of the
    Multistate
    Settlement Agreement were "state action" under the Parker doctrine, we
    will apply the
    Midcal analysis.
    For the reasons expressed, namely that the antitrust injuries here
    were not caused
    by the solitary acts of the state acting in its traditional capacity, but
    were instead caused
    by hybrid acts involving private parties in the unique setting of a joint
    settlement, we
    believe this form of alleged anticompetitive restraint requires the Midcal
    analysis.
    2. Midcal
    To qualify as state action under the Midcal test, "the challenged
    restraint must be
    one 'clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed as state 
    policy.'" 445 U.S. at 104
    (quoting City of Lafayette v. La. Power & Light Co., 
    435 U.S. 389
    , 410
    (1978) (opinion
    of Brennan, J.)). A government entity need not "be able to point to a
    specific, detailed,
    legislative authorization" to assert a successful Parker defense.
    
    Lafayette, 435 U.S. at 415
    . But it must be evident that under the "clear articulation" standard
    the challenged
    restraint is part of state policy. As the Supreme Court has stated,
    "Midcal confirms that
    while a State may not confer antitrust immunity on private persons by
    fiat, it may
    displace competition with active state supervision if the displacement is
    both intended by
    the State and implemented in its specific details." FTC v. Ticor Title
    Ins. Co., 
    504 U.S. 621
    , 633 (1992).
    Here, the States' reasons for bringing suits against the Majors Ä to
    reduce teenage
    smoking, address public health concerns, and recoup state health care
    expenditures Ä
    were evident and clearly articulated. State Attorneys General and
    Governors made
    public pronouncements which received national coverage. Other suing
    states made
    similar announcements and cited to studies demonstrating the enormous
    impact of
    cigarette smoking on health and finances. The proclaimed goals of the
    States were
    clear.
    As noted, the State Attorneys General and the Governors were not the
    only state
    actors involved. The State Attorneys General took the lead in
    negotiations, but the state
    courts played an important role in approving the Multistate Settlement
    Agreement by
    issuing consent judgments and dismissing the lawsuits. This was required
    by the
    Multistate Settlement Agreement which provided that each signatory state
    would "tender
    to the Court in such Settling State for entry of a consent decree
    conforming to the model
    consent decree" included in the agreement. See MSA    XIII(b)(1). The
    lawsuits were
    dismissed under the consent agreements. The state legislatures also
    demonstrated their
    approval in most of the States by passing implementing legislation. See
    Cal. Aviation
    
    Inc., 806 F.2d at 909
    n.5 (noting that statutes passed afterwards are
    evidence of pre-
    existing state policy to allow anticompetitive behavior). Even before the
    settlement,
    legislatures of some states targeted the tobacco industry by putting
    pressure on the
    Attorney General or Governor to bring suit. In view of public
    pronouncements of the
    States' intentions and goals, along with active involvement from each
    branch of state
    government, it is evident the Multistate Settlement Agreement was backed
    by clearly
    articulated state policy.
    The second prong of the Midcal test is whether the resulting
    antitrust violation
    was "actively supervised" by the state. This standard is more
    problematic. The essential
    inquiry of the "actively supervised" prong is to determine if the
    "anticompetitive scheme
    is the State's own." FTC v. Ticor Title Ins. Co., 
    504 U.S. 621
    , 635
    (1992). The active
    supervision prong "requires that state officials have and exercise power
    to review
    particular anticompetitive acts of private parties and disapprove those
    that fail to accord
    with state policy." Patrick v. Burget, 
    486 U.S. 94
    , 101 (1988). "Absent
    such a program
    of supervision, there is no realistic assurance that a private party's
    anticompetitive
    conduct promotes state policy, rather than merely the party's individual
    interests." 
    Id. at 100-01.
    "Such active state review is clearly necessary where private
    defendants are
    empowered with some type of discretionary authority in connection with the
    anticompetitive acts (e.g. to determine price or rate structures)."
    
    Zimomra, 111 F.3d at 1500
    . Rubber stamp approval of private action does not constitute state
    action. A state
    must independently review and approve the anticompetitive behavior to
    satisfy this prong
    of the Parker doctrine. 
    Patrick, 486 U.S. at 101
    ("The active supervision
    requirement
    mandates that the State exercise ultimate control over the challenged
    anticompetitive
    conduct."); 
    Ticor, 998 F.2d at 1139
    .
    Here, plaintiffs allege the Multistate Settlement Agreement primarily
    furthers the
    private tobacco companies' interests and not those of the States. While
    we do not agree
    with this characterization, it is clear the Multistate Settlement
    Agreement empowers the
    tobacco companies to make anticompetitive decisions with no regulatory
    oversight by the
    States. Specifically, the defendants are free to fix and raise prices,
    allegedly without fear
    of competition. The question then is whether the Multistate Settlement
    Agreement, with
    all its duties and responsibilities, creates sufficient state supervision
    even though the
    pricing decisions are unregulated.
    The States actively and continually monitor the implementation of
    portions of the
    Multistate Settlement Agreement. See MSA      VII-VIII. After requiring a
    state court
    consent decree, the Multistate Settlement Agreement also mandates state
    courts to
    maintain continuing jurisdiction over enforcement of disputes between the
    States and the
    tobacco companies. See MSA      VII(a). Under the Multistate Settlement
    Agreement, the
    state courts may order compliance in the form of an Enforcement Order.
    See MSA
    VII(c)(3). If a State Attorney General believes a manufacturer has failed
    to comply with
    an Enforcement Order, it may seek an order for civil contempt or monetary
    sanction to
    force compliance. See MSA      VII(c)(4). Furthermore, for a period of
    seven years after
    settlement, the Attorney General of a Settling State may inspect all non-
    privileged
    records of the tobacco companies, and will have access to interview
    directors, officers
    and employees upon reasonable belief of a violation of the Multistate
    Settlement
    Agreement. See MSA     VII(g).
    The Multistate Settlement Agreement also establishes a $50 million
    fund to assist
    the States in enforcing the Multistate Settlement Agreement. See MSA
    VIII(c). This
    fund is to be used
    to supplement the States'
    (1) enforcement and implementation of the
    terms of [the Multistate
    Settlement Agreement] and consent decrees, and
    (2) investigation and litigation of
    potential violations of laws with
    respect to Tobacco Products.
    
    Id. This includes
    prosecution of non-signatories for those underlying "torts"
    which initially
    led the States to sue the major tobacco companies.
    The largest responsibilities for the tobacco companies are financial.
    The
    Multistate Settlement Agreement details how and when the payments will be
    made to the
    settling states each year. See MSA    IX. In addition, there is a limited
    "most-favored nation" provision. In the event a State settles with a non-
    signatory
    tobacco company (NPM) on terms more favorable than the Multistate
    Settlement
    Agreement (a lower payment-per-pack amount), then all signatories will be
    entitled to a
    revision of the Multistate Settlement Agreement to at least match the new
    agreement.
    See MSA    XVIII(b)(2). There are also significant ongoing restrictions
    placed on the
    tobacco manufacturers. They are prohibited from taking "any action,
    directly or
    indirectly, to target Youth within any Settling State in the advertising,
    promotion, or
    marketing of Tobacco Products," MSA   III(a); they also agreed to refrain
    from using
    "any cartoon in the advertising, promoting, packaging or labeling of
    Tobacco products."
    MSA   III(b).
    Despite these factors, we are not convinced that the States satisfy
    Midcal's "active
    supervision" prong. This is because the States' supervision does not
    reach the parts of
    the Multistate Settlement Agreement that are the source of the antitrust
    injury. It is the
    conduct that violates the antitrust laws that states must "actively
    supervise" in order for
    Parker immunity to attach.
    As we recognized in Norman's on the Waterfront, Inc. v. Wheatley, "an
    arrangement sponsored by the state is not necessarily state action for the
    purposes of the
    antitrust laws." 
    444 F.2d 1011
    , 1017 (3d Cir. 1971) (citing Woods
    Exploration &
    Producing Co., Inc. v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 
    438 F.2d 1286
    , 1294 (5th Cir.
    1971) for
    the proposition that "it is not every governmental act that points a path
    to an antitrust
    shelter"). In Wheatley, we analyzed a series of Parker cases
    demonstrating the state must
    be actively involved in establishing the rules of the market as well as in
    the
    anticompetitive activity. Because "'states can neither authorize
    individuals to perform
    acts which violate the antitrust laws nor declare that such action is
    lawful,'" many of
    these cases of hybrid restraints turn on whether the state remains
    involved in the actual
    pricing by the regulated parties. 
    Wheately, 444 F.2d at 1017
    (quoting
    Asheville Tobacco
    Bd. of Trade, Inc. v. Fed. Trade Comm'n, 
    263 F.2d 502
    , 509 (4th Cir.
    1959)).
    Significantly, in Midcal, the State of California enacted a pricing
    system for the
    wine industry. Because the State did not exercise direct control over the
    resulting prices
    set by the private actors, and did not review the reasonableness of the
    prices, the
    Supreme Court found insufficient "active supervision" to qualify as state
    action. 
    Midcal, 445 U.S. at 105
    -06. Therefore, there was no immunity for setting
    anticompetitive prices
    under this system. 
    Id. In Midcal,
    the challenged "restraints" were state statutes on pricing
    and resale
    price maintenance. But there were several other ways in which the State
    of California
    regulated the wine industry. See, e.g., Cal. Bus & Prof. Stat. Ann.
    25600-67 (West
    1964). California actively supervised when, where, and to whom wine or
    other
    alcoholic beverages could be sold, the markings and signs on labels,
    penalties for
    underage use, and advertisements, including prohibiting advertising to
    minors. This
    "supervision" was not cited in Midcal because it did not constitute part
    of the
    anticompetitive restraint at issue. Under Parker, a comprehensive
    regulatory scheme
    would be immune from antitrust liability because the "State would
    'displace unfettered
    business freedom' with its own power," 
    Midcal, 445 U.S. at 106
    . But the
    Supreme Court
    in Midcal was silent about the impact of other regulatory provisions in
    the California
    Code denoting, we believe, the absence of a comprehensive regulatory
    scheme in this
    sense.
    Since Midcal, other courts have found that if a state creates or
    sanctions a
    monopoly or cartel through its sovereign powers, but does not regulate the
    resulting
    prices, the resulting anticompetitive behavior should not be granted
    immunity. In
    Wheately, we held that because the Virgin Islands Alcoholic Beverages Fair
    Trade Law
    did not grant the power to "approve, disapprove, or modify the prices
    fixed by private
    persons," the program could not meet the active supervision prong of
    Midcal and was not
    immune under Parker. In Asheville Tobacco, the Court of Appeals for the
    Fourth Circuit
    held that where a state statute authorized the creation of local tobacco
    boards to regulate
    tobacco sales at auctions, and where the states did not continue to
    supervise the decisions
    of these boards, the board's actions were not protected by Parker
    immunity. This
    principle has also been applied in state granted monopoly cases. In Gas
    Light Co. of
    Columbus v. Georgia Power Co., 
    440 F.2d 1135
    (5th Cir. 1971), the Court of
    Appeals
    for the Fifth Circuit found a utility which had been given a monopoly by
    the state was
    entitled to Parker immunity only because its prices were regulated
    extensively by the
    state through a process of full adversarial hearings.
    In each of these cases, the decision by the state to allow, or even
    to create, an
    anticompetitive scheme did not establish immunity. As a leading antitrust
    treatise has
    recognized, "A state may be free to determine for itself how much
    competition is
    desirable, provided that it substitutes adequate control wherever it has
    substantially
    weakened competition." Areeda & 
    Hovenkamp, supra, at 221
    (citing
    Wheatley,
    Asheville Tobacco, and Georgia Power). Under this jurisprudence, only
    when the state
    approves and actively supervises the results of the anticompetitive scheme
    does Parker
    immunity attach.
    As noted, some provisions of the Multistate Settlement Agreement
    actively
    regulate the tobacco companies, like those imposing advertising
    restrictions. But these
    provisions have no effect on pricing or production and thus do not
    regulate the challenged
    anticompetitive conduct. 
    Patrick, 486 U.S. at 101
    . In contrast, the
    anticompetitive
    restraints in the Multistate Settlement Agreement that permit the tobacco
    companies to
    maintain an output cartel are the Renegade Clause and, arguably, the
    resulting Qualifying
    Statutes.
    The States here are actively involved in the maintenance of the
    scheme, but they
    lack oversight or authority over the tobacco manufacturers' prices and
    production levels.
    These decisions are left entirely to the private actors. Nothing in the
    Multistate
    Settlement Agreement or its Qualifying Statutes gives the States authority
    to object if the
    tobacco companies raise their prices. In fact, it appears these increases
    have already
    happened. As noted, the Majors have raised their prices sharply and
    uniformly since the
    implementation of the Multistate Settlement Agreement Ä according to
    plaintiffs, by
    50% since 1997. See Complaint at    36. These price increases have not
    been monitored
    or regulated by the States. The Multistate Settlement Agreement imposes
    no restrictions
    on pricing or provisions to temper the effects of the output cartel.
    Under this set of
    facts, there is insufficient evidence of active supervision of the
    allegedly anticompetitive
    restraints to satisfy this prong of Midcal.
    Although the Multistate Settlement Agreement is the product of a
    "clearly
    articulated" state policy, because the States do not "actively supervise"
    the
    anticompetitive restraints, the participants are not entitled to Parker
    immunity.
    3.
    The question of Parker immunity's applicability is a difficult one.
    As noted, we
    hold we must apply the Midcal test. Although the States satisfy Midcal's
    "clear
    articulation" prong, they fail the second prong requiring them to actively
    supervise the
    anticompetitive restraints causing injury. Because private participants
    in state action
    enjoy Parker immunity only to the extent the States enjoy immunity, the
    defendants are
    not shielded by Parker. Therefore, consistent with the Supreme Court's
    treatment of
    hybrid restraints, we hold defendants are not immune under the Parker
    immunity
    doctrine.
    IV.
    Constitutional Claims
    In its brief, and again at oral argument, plaintiffs asked us to find
    the Multistate
    Settlement Agreement unconstitutional under the Commerce Clause or the
    Compact
    Clause of the United States Constitution. But plaintiffs did not allege
    constitutional
    violations in their amended complaint, nor did the District Court address
    them.
    Therefore, these claims will not be addressed on appeal. Mahone v.
    Addicks Utility
    Dist., 
    836 F.2d 921
    , 935 (5th Cir. 1988) ("It is black-letter law that
    '[a] motion to dismiss
    for failure to state a claim under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure
    12(b)(6) is to be
    evaluated only on the pleadings.'") (quoting O'Quinn v. Manuel, 
    773 F.2d 605
    , 608 (5th
    Cir.1985)); N.A.M.I. v. Essex County Bd. of Freeholders, 
    91 F. Supp. 2d 781
    ,
    787 n.7
    (D.N.J. 2000) ("This Court need not consider claims that have not been
    pleaded in the
    complaint."); 5A Charles Alan Wright & Arthur R. Miller, Federal Practice
    and
    Procedure    1356 (1990). "'Absent exceptional circumstances, an issue not
    raised in the
    district court will not be heard on appeal.'" Walton v. Mental Health
    Ass'n of
    Southeastern Pa., 
    168 F.3d 661
    , 671 (3d Cir. 1999) (quoting Altman v.
    Altman, 
    653 F.2d 755
    , 758 (3d Cir.1981)). When exceptional circumstances exist or to avoid
    "manifest
    injustice," issues not previously raised may be heard to protect the
    public interest. See 
    id. No such
    interests are present. Although the Cato Institute, amicus curiae
    for plaintiffs,
    argues the constitutional claims, "new issues raised by an amicus are not
    properly before
    the court" in the absence of exceptional circumstances. General Eng'g
    Corp. v. Virgin
    Islands Water and Power Auth. Caribbean Energy Co., Inc., 
    805 F.2d 88
    , 92
    (3d Cir.
    1986) (citing United Parcel Serv. v. Mitchell, 
    451 U.S. 56
    , 60 n.2
    (1981)). These
    constitutional claims are not properly before us.
    V.
    Conclusion
    The Multistate Settlement Agreement creates novel issues because of
    the
    uniqueness of the instrument Ä involving forty-six states and over 98% of
    an industry.
    Although plaintiffs have properly pleaded an antitrust injury, the right
    to petition the
    government is paramount. Therefore, we hold defendants immune from
    antitrust liability
    under the Noerr-Pennington doctrine. But we find no immunity under the
    Parker
    doctrine. We will not address the constitutional issues.
    We will affirm the judgment of the District Court.
    TO THE CLERK:
    Please file the foregoing opinion.
    /s/ Anthony J. Scirica
    Circuit Judge
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 00-3410

Citation Numbers: 263 F.3d 239

Filed Date: 6/19/2001

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/12/2023

Authorities (46)

david-charles-zimomra-on-behalf-of-himself-and-all-others-similarly , 111 F.3d 1495 ( 1997 )

mcguire-oil-company-berwick-oil-company-inc-and-diamond-gasoline , 958 F.2d 1552 ( 1992 )

No. 98-6004 , 168 F.3d 119 ( 1999 )

Sandra J. Walton v. Mental Health Association of ... , 168 F.3d 661 ( 1999 )

armstrong-surgical-center-inc-v-armstrong-county-memorial-hospital , 185 F.3d 154 ( 1999 )

primetime-24-joint-venture-v-national-broadcasting-company-inc-abc , 219 F.3d 92 ( 2000 )

Gas Light Company of Columbus v. Georgia Power Company and ... , 440 F.2d 1135 ( 1971 )

Randolph Mahone v. Addicks Utility District of Harris County , 836 F.2d 921 ( 1988 )

Asheville Tobacco Board of Trade, Inc., a Corporation v. ... , 263 F.2d 502 ( 1959 )

altman-sydney-a-v-altman-ashley-j-and-altman-ashley-j-of-the-estate , 653 F.2d 755 ( 1981 )

baltimore-scrap-corporation-formerly-known-as-brooklyn-salvage-corporation , 237 F.3d 394 ( 2001 )

normans-on-the-waterfront-inc-v-reuben-b-wheatley-commissioner-of , 444 F.2d 1011 ( 1971 )

Woods Exploration & Producing Company, Inc. v. Aluminum ... , 438 F.2d 1286 ( 1971 )

massachusetts-school-of-law-at-andover-inc-v-american-bar-association , 107 F.3d 1026 ( 1997 )

General Leaseways, Inc. v. National Truck Leasing ... , 744 F.2d 588 ( 1984 )

California Aviation, Inc. v. City of Santa Monica , 806 F.2d 905 ( 1986 )

charleys-taxi-radio-dispatch-corporation-a-hawaii-corporation-plaintiff , 810 F.2d 869 ( 1987 )

Sessions Tank Liners, Inc. v. Joor Manufacturing, Inc. , 17 F.3d 295 ( 1994 )

john-h-campbell-isadore-head-and-cornelius-e-scott-individually-and-on , 823 F.2d 1182 ( 1987 )

columbia-pictures-industries-inc-embassy-pictures-paramount-pictures , 944 F.2d 1525 ( 1991 )

View All Authorities »