United States of America v. Aetna Inc. , 240 F. Supp. 3d 1 ( 2017 )


Menu:
  •                                        UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
    UNITED STATES OF AMERICA, et al.,
    Plaintiffs,
    v.                                                          Civil Action No. 16-1494 (JDB)
    AETNA INC., et al.,
    Defendants.
    MEMORANDUM OPINION
    INTRODUCTION......................................................................................................................... 1
    BACKGROUND ........................................................................................................................... 3
    I.   The Parties and Proposed Merger ...................................................................................... 3
    II. Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage ..................................................................... 6
    III. The Public Exchanges ...................................................................................................... 14
    IV. Procedural History............................................................................................................ 15
    LEGAL STANDARD ................................................................................................................. 18
    ANALYSIS .................................................................................................................................. 20
    I. Medicare Advantage ......................................................................................................... 20
    A. Market Definition.......................................................................................................... 20
    1. Competition Between Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage ........................ 23
    2. Brown Shoe Factors & Ordinary Course of Business Documents ........................... 26
    3. Defendants’ Counter Arguments .............................................................................. 37
    4. Econometric Evidence .............................................................................................. 43
    5. Summary ................................................................................................................... 56
    B. Competitive Effects ...................................................................................................... 58
    C. Government Regulation ................................................................................................ 67
    D. Entry.............................................................................................................................. 75
    1. Applicable Law ......................................................................................................... 76
    2. Analysis..................................................................................................................... 76
    (a) Likelihood of New Entry...................................................................................... 78
    (b) Sufficiency of New Entry ..................................................................................... 84
    (c) Timeliness of New Entry...................................................................................... 86
    3. Summary ................................................................................................................... 87
    E. Molina Divestiture ........................................................................................................ 88
    1. Applicable Law ......................................................................................................... 88
    2. Background on Molina ............................................................................................. 90
    3. Whether the Divestiture Will Occur ......................................................................... 94
    4. Analysis..................................................................................................................... 95
    (a) Defendants’ Affirmative Arguments .................................................................... 96
    (b) The Purchase Price ........................................................................................... 110
    (c) Molina’s History in the Individual Medicare Advantage Market ..................... 111
    (d) Expert Testimony ............................................................................................... 112
    5. Summary ................................................................................................................. 113
    F. Conclusion Regarding Medicare Advantage .............................................................. 113
    II. The Public Exchanges ..................................................................................................... 114
    A. Legal Framework ........................................................................................................ 115
    1. Actual Competition Versus Potential Competition................................................. 115
    2. Whether Aetna’s Reasons for Withdrawal Matter .................................................. 121
    B. Analysis....................................................................................................................... 124
    1. Aetna Withdrew From the Complaint Counties to Improve its Litigation Position 124
    (a) Public Exchange Participation as Connected to the Merger ............................ 125
    (b) Aetna’s Decision-Making Process .................................................................... 127
    (c) The Florida Market President’s Reaction ......................................................... 131
    (d) Aetna’s Explanation That It Made a Business Decision ................................... 132
    2. Aetna Is Likely to Compete in Florida After 2017 ................................................. 137
    3. The Proposed Merger Would Cause Anticompetitive Effects in Florida ............... 141
    C. Conclusion .................................................................................................................. 146
    III.   Efficiencies ................................................................................................................. 147
    CONCLUSION ......................................................................................................................... 155
    INTRODUCTION
    Before the Court is an antitrust challenge to the merger of Aetna Inc. and Humana Inc.,
    two of the largest health insurance companies in the country. Aetna and Humana entered into a
    merger agreement on July 2, 2015. They subsequently provided notification of their planned
    merger to the Department of Justice as required by the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements
    Act of 1976, 15 U.S.C. § 18a. Following an investigation, the Department of Justice, eight states,
    and the District of Columbia (collectively, the government) filed this action asserting that the
    merger “may . . . substantially . . . lessen competition” in violation of section 7 of the Clayton Act,
    15 U.S.C. § 18, in two distinct product lines: individual Medicare Advantage plans and individual
    commercial health insurance plans offered on the public exchanges. The government identified
    364 counties across 21 states where it argues that concentration in the Medicare Advantage market
    would rise above the presumptively unlawful level if the merger proceeds, and 17 counties across
    3 states where that would be true in the public exchange markets. Moreover, the government
    argues, additional evidence indicates that the companies compete head-to-head in both markets—
    competition that would be lost following the merger, to the significant detriment of consumers.
    Unsurprisingly, Aetna and Humana disagree. For Medicare Advantage, they argue that the
    relevant product market must include both Original Medicare (Medicare benefits offered directly
    by the government) as well as Medicare Advantage (Medicare benefits offered by private
    insurance entities). In this market, properly defined, Aetna and Humana argue that post-merger
    concentration would not be high enough to be presumptively unlawful. Furthermore, they offer
    three reasons why, even in a market limited to Medicare Advantage, the proposed merger would
    not substantially lessen competition. According to defendants, the government’s regulatory
    authority over Medicare Advantage, the threat of entry by new competitors, and defendants’
    1
    proposed divestiture of a portion of their Medicare Advantage business to another insurance
    company, Molina Healthcare, Inc., would combine to render any competitive harm unlikely.
    In response to the government’s public exchange allegations, Aetna and Humana argue
    that there is no current competition between the two companies in the 17 complaint counties,
    because Aetna has decided not to compete in those counties in 2017. If there is no current
    competition between them, they argue, there can be no substantial lessening of that competition
    post-merger. Alternatively, they argue that even if the Court looks back to the competition
    between Aetna and Humana in 2016 and predicts future competition on that basis, it is likely that
    Humana’s market share in the public exchanges will be so reduced in 2017 and later years that a
    merger would not increase market concentration to a presumptively unlawful level.
    Additionally, Aetna and Humana argue that the efficiencies created by the merger and then
    passed on to consumers would counteract any anticompetitive effects in both the Medicare
    Advantage and public exchange markets.
    The government responds that the relevant product market is indeed Medicare Advantage
    only, and that none of these arguments is sufficient to rebut the presumption of unlawfulness based
    on the levels of market concentration and the evidence that Aetna and Humana compete head-to-
    head in both markets. In the public exchange context, the government contends that Aetna decided
    not to compete in the 17 complaint counties in 2017 in response to this litigation in an effort to
    evade judicial review of the merger. Thus, the government argues, the Court should ignore this
    manipulation and instead analyze the competitive effects of the proposed merger as if Aetna
    planned to continue competing in the public exchanges in all of the 17 complaint counties as it did
    in 2016.
    2
    The Court concludes that the proposed merger is likely to substantially lessen competition
    in Medicare Advantage in all 364 complaint counties and in the public exchanges in the three
    complaint counties in Florida. Aetna and Humana compete in a Medicare Advantage product
    market that does not include Original Medicare, as both contemporary business documents and
    econometric evidence confirm. In that market, which is the primary focus of this case, the merger
    is presumptively unlawful—a conclusion that is strongly supported by direct evidence of head-to-
    head competition as well. The companies’ rebuttal arguments are not persuasive.
    In the public exchanges, the Court finds that Aetna withdrew from competing in the 17
    complaint counties for 2017 specifically to evade judicial scrutiny of the merger. Although the
    Court does not adopt the government’s view that this means the Court should assume that Aetna
    will continue to compete everywhere it competed in 2016, the Court will give Aetna’s withdrawal
    decision for 2017 little weight in predicting where Aetna will compete in later years. The Court
    finds that Aetna is likely to offer plans on the exchanges only in the three complaint counties in
    Florida in 2018 and beyond, and that the merger is likely to substantially lessen competition in
    those counties. And as in the Medicare Advantage market, the Court concludes that defendants’
    proffered efficiencies do not offset the anticompetitive effects of the merger.
    BACKGROUND
    I.   The Parties and Proposed Merger
    Aetna and Humana are large health insurance companies with national footprints. Both
    offer a range of health insurance products, including the two products at issue in this litigation:
    individual Medicare Advantage plans and individual insurance sold on the public exchanges. Both
    are also regarded by industry participants as members of the “Big 5” health insurers, along with
    competitors UnitedHealth, Anthem, and Cigna.
    3
    Humana is “viewed as a leader in Medicare Advantage.” Tr. 1837:22–23 (Broussard). 1
    In 2016, Humana was one of the two largest Medicare Advantage insurers, boasting more than 2.5
    million individual Medicare Advantage members. 2 PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 40. Humana’s
    Medicare Advantage offerings are available to 91% of Medicare beneficiaries nationally. Tr.
    253:6–7 (Cocozza). Humana’s position atop the Medicare Advantage market has been obtained
    through impressive recent growth. Between 2013 and 2016, Humana added more seniors to its
    individual Medicare Advantage plans than any of its rivals. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 40.
    Aetna, although historically oriented more toward the sale of commercial health insurance,
    has also been growing rapidly in Medicare Advantage. In the last four years, Aetna has expanded
    its Medicare Advantage plans into 640 new counties; the next most aggressive entrant entered into
    less than half that many. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 218 & Ex. 18. Some of Aetna’s momentum
    was derived from its 2013 acquisition of Coventry Health Care, itself a significant player in
    Medicare Advantage. Tr. 1330:20–1331:1 (Bertolini). Now the fourth-largest seller of individual
    Medicare Advantage in the country, Aetna has plans for continued rapid growth. Today, Aetna
    plans are available to approximately 50% of Medicare beneficiaries; within five years, through
    continued geographic expansion, Aetna hopes to increase that figure to 70%. Tr. 1331:2–22
    (Bertolini).
    1
    Citations to the trial transcript include the witness’s last name in parenthesis. Where exhibits are cited with
    page numbers, the page number refers to the last three digits of the exhibit-stamp page number, where available. For
    example, Plaintiffs’ Exhibit 100 at page 1 is cited as “PX0100-001.” If that pagination is not available, the last three
    digits of the Bates-stamp number are used. Expert reports are cited by paragraph number, where available.
    2
    Based on a measure of enrollment that excludes group Medicare Advantage plans sold to employers, the
    government’s economist, Dr. Aviv Nevo, asserted that Humana was the largest individual Medicare Advantage insurer
    in the country. Humana’s answer admits only to being the second-largest Medicare Advantage insurer, without any
    reference to “individual” Medicare Advantage. See Humana’s Answer [ECF No. 63] ¶ 7. For present purposes, it is
    not necessary to resolve this discrepancy. It is enough to observe that Humana has been a very large and successful
    player in the individual Medicare Advantage market—whether or not it is technically the largest one.
    4
    Aetna and Humana are also two of the largest insurers in the individual commercial
    insurance market on the public exchanges. The exchanges, created by the Affordable Care Act,
    create a marketplace where individuals who do not receive health insurance through their employer
    or through a government program can purchase individual insurance plans. At the time the
    complaint was filed, Aetna sold insurance on the public exchanges in 15 states and had described
    itself as being “highly successful” in enrollment. See Tr. 1360:14–17 (Bertolini); PX0285 at 4.
    Humana also offered plans in 15 states in 2016, and planned to continue offering insurance on the
    exchanges in 11 states for 2017. See Humana Ans. [ECF No. 63] ¶ 42. The two companies
    competed on the public exchanges in more than 100 counties.
    On July 2, 2015, Aetna and Humana announced their merger agreement, under which
    Aetna would acquire Humana for $37 billion. The firms’ respective CEOs, Mark Bertolini and
    Bruce Broussard, both expressed excitement about the merger’s potential. They believe that the
    merger will combine two philosophically compatible firms—both focused on providing
    individualized, value-based care in local communities—into one that can more effectively
    implement their shared vision for the future of healthcare. See Tr. 1399:17–1401:19 (Bertolini);
    Tr. 1838:5–1840:19 (Broussard). Although the companies are enthusiastic about their merger,
    they have also planned for the possibility that it will not occur. If it is not consummated by a
    specified date—now February 15, 2017—then Aetna must pay Humana a $1 billion break-up fee.
    The government imputes a different rationale to the Aetna-Humana transaction, seeing it
    as part of “an industry-wide rush to consolidate.” Pls.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions [ECF
    No. 275] at 7. Industry participants, including Bertolini, have indeed referred to a “merger frenzy”
    among health insurers in recent years. Tr. 1319:24–1320:3 (Bertolini). The “frenzy” culminated
    with the announcements of this merger and another between Anthem and Cigna. That would
    5
    combine four of the five largest health insurers into two companies. But in the run-up to those
    announcements, the Big 5 insurers had explored a number of different merger possibilities: on at
    least two occasions, UnitedHealth had approached Aetna about a potential acquisition, and on
    other occasions Aetna had made indirect inquiries about acquiring Cigna. See Tr. 1321:8–1322:17
    (Bertolini). This degree of merger-related activity, the government contends, tends to undercut
    the notion that there is something particularly valuable about the Aetna-Humana transaction.
    Ultimately, of course, the outcome of this case does not hinge on these competing
    characterizations of the merger. Instead, as the parties recognize, the outcome here must depend
    on a detailed analysis of the likely effects of the merger in the challenged markets. The best place
    to begin that analysis is with a summary of the government programs central to this case: Original
    Medicare, Medicare Advantage, and the public exchanges created by the ACA.
    II.   Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage
    Individuals aged 65 or over are eligible for Medicare, through which the federal
    government provides certain health insurance benefits to seniors. The core of the program is
    Medicare Parts A and B. Part A covers inpatient hospital services; Part B covers doctors’ services
    and outpatient care. See PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶¶ 17, 18. Together, Medicare Parts A and B are
    often called “Original Medicare.” Under Original Medicare, healthcare providers are paid on a
    fee-for-service basis. When a healthcare provider performs a particular service, it is paid by the
    government according to a fee schedule determined by the Center for Medicare and Medicaid
    Services (CMS), an office within the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS). Original
    Medicare enrollees may obtain care from any healthcare provider that accepts Original Medicare
    rates. Because the overwhelming majority of providers do so, seniors who enroll in Original
    Medicare can effectively obtain care from any provider, anywhere in the country.
    6
    But Original Medicare does not cover the full cost of seniors’ medical care. For example,
    in 2016 Part A included a $1,288 per year inpatient hospital deductible. PX0553 (Frank Report)
    ¶ 17. Part B likewise comes with some out-of-pocket costs. Last year, Original Medicare enrollees
    paid monthly Part B premiums of about $105. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 19. They also paid a
    deductible of $166 per benefit period, and a 20% coinsurance rate for most covered services.
    PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 18. Moreover, Original Medicare does not cover the cost of the
    outpatient prescription drugs prescribed by many providers and taken by many seniors. Tr. 110:4–
    9 (Frank). Collectively, these premiums, deductibles, coinsurance payments, and drug prescription
    payments may impose significant medical costs on an Original Medicare enrollee—but Original
    Medicare places no cap on such out-of-pocket expenses. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 19.
    To contain those possibly significant out-of-pocket costs, many seniors purchase a
    Medicare Supplement (known as “MedSupp” or “Medigap”) plan from a private insurer. 3 These
    plans are regulated by state departments of insurance and sold by private insurers in a number of
    standardized varieties, each denoted by a letter. Tr. 728:4–8 (Wooldridge); DX0130-83. One of
    the most popular varieties, called a MedSupp Plan F, covers 100% of an Original Medicare
    enrollee’s deductibles and copayments, with no out-of-pocket limit, in exchange for a monthly
    premium of about $150. See DX0130-83; Tr. 671:8–10 (Wooldridge). But MedSupp plans do
    not offer coverage for prescription drugs. Tr. 105:23–106:1 (Frank). To obtain prescription drug
    coverage, an Original Medicare enrollee must purchase a Medicare Part D plan from a private
    3
    Before purchasing a MedSupp plan, some seniors may be subject medical underwriting. Depending on
    their answers to a health questionnaire, some seniors—like those with certain pre-existing conditions—may ultimately
    be denied MedSupp coverage. Tr. 106:11–17 (Frank); Tr. 429:9–17 (Cocozza). But when a senior has “guaranteed
    issue rights,” he or she cannot be subject to medical underwriting. Seniors have “guaranteed issue rights” when they
    age into Medicare for the first time, if their Medicare Advantage plan recently withdrew from the market, or if they
    move out of the coverage area of their Medicare Advantage plan. Tr. 430:8–22 (Cocozza); Tr. 722:13–20
    (Wooldridge).
    7
    insurer. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 22. The average Part D premium is $39 per month. PX0553
    (Frank Report) ¶ 22.
    Rather than enrolling in Original Medicare (with or without a MedSupp or Part D plan), a
    senior may choose to enroll in a Medicare Advantage plan sold by a private insurer. Under the
    Medicare Advantage program, which was created in approximately its current form by the
    Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003, Pub. L. No. 108–173,
    117 Stat. 2066, private insurers are paid by the government to provide health insurance to
    Medicare-eligible seniors. Participating insurers enter into contracts with CMS; then, pursuant to
    each contract, the insurers can offer a number of Medicare Advantage plans to seniors. The
    Medicare Advantage program was intended to “[e]nrich the range of benefit choices available to
    enrollees” and to “increase[e] efficiency in the overall health care system.”         Final Rule,
    Establishment of the Medicare Advantage Program, 70 Fed. Reg. 4,588 (Jan. 28, 2005). To
    achieve those goals, Medicare Advantage harnesses “open season competition” between Medicare
    Advantage plans. 
    Id. This competition
    occurs within parameters set by the federal government. By statute, all
    Medicare Advantage plans must provide coverage for Medicare Parts A and B. Additionally,
    unlike Original Medicare, Medicare Advantage plans must cap an enrollee’s out-of-pocket
    spending at $6,700 per year. Tr. 107:12–17 (Frank). The federal government, through CMS, also
    oversees the annual Medicare Advantage bid process, which is used to determine how much a
    Medicare Advantage organization (MAO) will be paid by the government. The starting point for
    that calculation is the CMS “benchmark.” Each April, CMS publishes a “benchmark” for every
    county in the United States, based on the cost to Original Medicare of providing Part A and B
    benefits to an average enrollee in that county in the prior year. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 27. The
    8
    benchmark represents the maximum amount that the government will pay an MAO to provide
    Original Medicare benefits to an enrollee in a particular county. MAOs are thus paid on a capitated
    basis, not on a fee-for-service basis: CMS will not pay the MAO more for seniors who consume
    more healthcare services. Accordingly, the capitation payment provides MAOs with an incentive
    to control their enrollees’ healthcare costs.
    For each Medicare Advantage plan, the MAO submits a “bid” against the benchmark. If
    an MAO bids above the benchmark, it will be paid the benchmark rate for each enrollee. Those
    seniors who enroll in that plan must pay a premium equal to the difference between the bid and
    the benchmark. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 28. But if an MAO is confident about its ability to
    control costs, and to thereby provide Part A and B benefits to its enrollees for less than Original
    Medicare, it might submit a bid below the benchmark. In that case, the MAO will be paid its bid,
    plus an additional amount sometimes called the “rebate.” PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 29. The rebate
    is calculated as a percentage of the difference between the bid and the benchmark. The remainder
    of the difference is retained by CMS as a benefit for taxpayers. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 29. Any
    rebates earned by the MAO must be used to lower out-of-pocket costs or increase benefits for the
    plan’s enrollees. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 30. Many MAOs use rebates to lower enrollees’ Part
    B premiums, to reduce the plan’s cost sharing requirements (that is, copays, coinsurance, or
    deductibles), or to add benefits that are not available through Original Medicare, such as vision,
    dental, hearing, or fitness benefits (known as “silver sneakers” benefits).
    The amount of an MAO’s capitation payment also depends in part on “star ratings.”
    Ranging in half-star increments between one and five, star ratings are intended to be a
    comprehensive measure of plan quality, reflecting factors like clinical outcomes, patient
    satisfaction, and access to care. See PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 31; PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 68 &
    9
    n.97. CMS assigns star-ratings at the contract level; thus, all the plans under a particular contract
    between CMS and an MAO will have the same star rating. Tr. 618:6–13 (Wheatley). Star ratings
    directly affect the amount of an MAO’s capitation payment in two ways. First, plans with higher
    star ratings bid against a higher benchmark. Plans rated with four or more stars can bid against an
    amount that is 105% of the normal county benchmark. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 32. Second,
    higher-rated plans earn higher rebates in percentage terms. For example, a plan with 3 stars or
    below receives as a rebate 50% of the difference between the bid and the benchmark; a plan with
    4.5 stars receives 70% of that difference. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 32. Star ratings, therefore,
    attempt to reinforce the relationship between plan quality and competitive success—high quality
    plans achieve high star ratings; high star ratings increase benchmarks and rebates; increased
    benchmarks and increased rebates are used to make plans more attractive; and more attractive
    plans translate into higher enrollment.
    The Medicare Advantage plans that emerge from the CMS bidding system tend to share a
    number of characteristics. The most fundamental of these is that, unlike Original Medicare,
    Medicare Advantage plans tend to be managed care plans with limited provider networks. Faced
    with the need to bid below the CMS benchmark, Medicare Advantage organizations, including
    Aetna and Humana, strive to build networks of providers who will work with them to coordinate
    patient care and control healthcare costs. 4 See Tr. 421:21–422:3 (Cocozza); Tr. 543:21–25
    (Wheatley). In some cases, these relationships are rooted in value-based contracts, which pay
    4
    Health maintenance organizations (HMOs) and preferred provider organizations (PPOs) are both types of
    limited-network plans. HMOs typically require seniors to obtain a referral from their primary care physician before
    seeing a specialist. This is sometimes described as the primary care physician serving as a “gatekeeper.” With limited
    exceptions, HMOs also do not reimburse seniors for care they receive outside their provider network. PPOs are usually
    somewhat less restrictive. PPOs generally do not require seniors to obtain a referral before seeing a specialist and will
    provide partial—but generally not full—reimbursement for care received outside the provider network.
    10
    providers based on various measures of care quality and patient outcomes rather than on the
    amount of care that they provide. Tr. 435:1–6 (Cocozza); Tr. 549:6–15 (Wheatley).
    When these cost-control efforts are successful, MAOs funnel the savings back into their
    plans in the form of reduced out-of-pocket costs or additional benefits. For example, in 2016, 61%
    of Medicare Advantage plans included annual limits on an enrollee’s out-of-pocket spending that
    were less than the statutory cap of $6,700. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 54. That same year, about
    half of Medicare Advantage enrollees were in zero-premium plans, meaning that they paid no
    premium other than the standard Part B premium. PX0348 at 7. On the benefits side, 89% of
    Medicare Advantage plans included prescription drug benefits, which must be purchased
    separately by enrollees in Original Medicare. PX 551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 55. Many Medicare
    Advantage plans also offer vision, dental, hearing, or fitness benefits that are unavailable through
    Original Medicare.     Tr. 107:21–25 (Frank).        Together, these features—limited networks,
    coordinated care, out-of-pocket maximums, and supplemental benefits—drive the Medicare
    Advantage value proposition.
    But Medicare Advantage plans do not appeal to everyone. In fact, for as long as Medicare
    Advantage has existed, a majority of seniors have selected Original Medicare (often with a
    MedSupp and Part D plan) instead. Most seniors first choose during a seven-month initial election
    period surrounding their 65th birthday. Those who fail to make a timely choice between the two
    default into Original Medicare. Tr. 408:2–7 (Cocozza). Each year, seniors may re-evaluate their
    choice during an annual enrollment period running from October 15 to December 7. During that
    period, “any [Medicare] beneficiary can make a different election for the upcoming year.” Tr.
    418:3–5 (Cocozza).     Seniors are thus free to switch from Original Medicare to Medicare
    Advantage or vice-versa, or from one Medicare Advantage plan to another. Seniors may also
    11
    switch from Medicare Advantage to Original Medicare during another annual window, running
    from January 1 to February 14. During that period, however, seniors may not switch out of
    Original Medicare or between Medicare Advantage plans. DX0130-077.
    Medicare Advantage plans are subject to CMS regulation applied primarily in connection
    with the bid process. Each insurer must submit a bid for every Medicare Advantage plan it intends
    to offer the following year. In April, along with the county benchmarks, CMS publishes two
    documents: a “call letter” describing the terms of the Medicare Advantage program, and a set of
    instructions about bid submission. See DX0014 (call letter); DX0349 (bid instructions). These
    documents impose a number of requirements on MAOs. Some, like the limit on increases in “total
    beneficiary cost,” relate directly to plan pricing. CMS will deny bids when “it determines the bid
    proposes too significant an increase in cost sharing or decrease in benefits from one plan year to
    the next.” DX0014-163. For plan year 2017, CMS maintained the total beneficiary cost threshold
    at $32 per member per month. DX0014-165. Bids proposing increases in amounts greater than
    the threshold were subject to denial. But even bids complying with the threshold were not
    necessarily free from scrutiny, because “CMS reserves the right to further examine and request
    changes to a plan bid even if a plan’s [total beneficiary cost] is within the required amount.”
    DX0014-164. Sean Cavanaugh, the Director of the Center for Medicare, the office within CMS
    that regulates Medicare Advantage, was not aware of any bids being rejected for violation of the
    rules on total beneficiary costs during his tenure. Tr. 1144:12–25 (Cavanaugh); see also Tr. 453:9–
    10 (Cocozza). Instead, CMS typically informs the MAO of the violation, and the MAO revises
    the bid into compliance. Tr. 1146:12–20 (Cavanaugh). Even then, however, the MAO may still
    be the subject of a CMS compliance notice. Tr. 1942:8–17 (Paprocki).
    12
    Some provisions of the bid instructions relate to MAO margins. The MAO must forecast
    the margin that it expects to earn on each of its plans. At the individual bid level, CMS seeks to
    guarantee that bids “provide benefit value in relation to the[ir] margin level[s].” DX0349-027.
    But most margin restrictions are “Aggregate-Level Requirements” that apply above the bid level.
    DX0349-028. Each bid is made at the plan level; each plan is part of a contract between CMS and
    the legal entity offering the plan; and most contracts cover multiple plans—perhaps as many as
    fifty. See Tr. 2008:12–21 (Paprocki). Some legal entities also have multiple contracts. Tr.
    2572:10–15 (Coleman). Above all these bids, contracts, and legal entities sit parent organizations,
    like Aetna and Humana, which might have multiple contracts with CMS through multiple affiliated
    legal entities. See Tr. 1948:2–12, 2008:10–11 (Paprocki). CMS regulation allows MAOs to
    decide whether to apply the aggregate-level margin requirements at the level of the contract, the
    legal entity, or the parent organization. DX0349-028; see also Tr. 2004:16–20 (Paprocki).
    The bid instructions require that the aggregate margins forecasted for the coming plan year
    are consistent with the actual ones from previous years. DX0349-029. And the aggregate margins
    that an MAO forecasts for its Medicare Advantage business must be within 1.5% of the margins
    on its overall business. DX0349-029. Aetna applies this requirement at the parent organization
    level, the highest level of aggregation permitted by CMS rules. Tr. 2004:16–2005:5 (Paprocki).
    Finally, outside of the bid process, CMS imposes limits on an MAO’s “medical loss ratio.”
    By statute, MAOs must spend at least 85% of the revenue obtained through a particular contract
    with CMS on medical services. See 42 U.S.C. § 1395w-27(e)(4); Tr. 1147:2–6 (Cavanaugh). Like
    the margin rules, the medical loss ratio regulations are applied above the level of individual bids—
    here, at the contract level. But unlike the margin rules, they apply retroactively to actual results
    rather than prospectively to forecasts. If CMS determines that, pursuant to a particular contract in
    13
    a particular year, an MAO spent less than 85% of its revenue on medical costs (meaning that it
    kept more than 15% of its revenue as profit or to cover administrative costs), CMS can require the
    MAO to refund the excess amount to beneficiaries. An MAO that remains out of compliance for
    three consecutive years may be barred from enrolling new members. Tr. 1148:6–13 (Cavanaugh).
    So far, however, no such penalties have been imposed. The medical loss ratio rules were
    introduced to Medicare Advantage by the Affordable Care Act, and CMS is only now preparing
    to release the first year of medical loss data. Tr. 1148:14–17 (Cavanaugh).
    III.   The Public Exchanges
    The ACA created the public exchanges as online marketplaces where consumers could
    purchase health insurance. Tr. 2638:24–2639:14 (Counihan); PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 73. (The
    exchanges are sometimes referred to as “Health Insurance Exchanges,” or “HIX” in the record.
    Tr. 1486:11–12 (Lynch)). Their basic structure is uncontested. The exchanges first opened in
    2013 for consumers to purchase plans for the 2014 year. See Tr. 138:21–139:25 (Frank).
    Individuals who do not receive health insurance through some other means—such as through their
    employer or through a government program like Medicare, Medicaid, or Tricare—are required to
    purchase health insurance or pay a tax, sometimes referred to as a penalty. PX0553 (Frank Report)
    ¶ 73. These individuals may purchase health insurance through the public exchanges (on-
    exchange) or directly from an insurer or a broker (off-exchange). PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 271.
    Health insurers who offer plans on-exchange in a given state must offer the same plans off-
    exchange in that state. Tr. 1532:15–1533:3 (Mayhew). However, health insurers may offer
    products off-exchange that they do not offer on-exchange. Tr. 1533:4–10 (Mayhew). CMS, along
    with each state, has oversight responsibility for the exchanges. Tr. 2587:22–2588:2 (Counihan).
    14
    The ACA also created certain obligations for insurers who offer plans on the exchanges.
    For example, insurers may not deny coverage based on preexisting conditions, or charge a different
    premium based on an individual’s perceived health status. Tr. 141:6–8 (Frank); PX0553 (Frank
    Report) ¶ 73. On-exchange plans are grouped into five tiers based on the level of coverage they
    provide: there are four “metal” tiers (bronze, silver, gold, and platinum) and there is one
    catastrophic tier. Tr. 1674:14–19 (Nevo). The “metal” tiers are based on the percentage of total
    expected healthcare spending the plan covers. Bronze plans cover 60% of expected healthcare
    spending, silver plans cover 70%, gold plans 80%, and platinum plans 90%. Tr. 142:8–13 (Frank).
    Individuals who purchase insurance on-exchange and who earn less than 400% of the
    federal poverty level are generally eligible to receive subsidies. Tr. 143:10–18 (Frank); PX0553
    (Frank Report) ¶¶ 82–83; 26 C.F.R. § 601.105, IRS Revenue Procedure 2016-24, § 2.01. These
    subsidies vary by location and income level, and can take the form of both premium subsidies and
    reductions in cost-sharing payments (that is, deductibles, copayments, and coinsurance). Tr.
    143:10–18 (Frank); PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶¶ 82–83. The subsidies are provided as tax credits,
    and are tied to the cost of the second lowest-cost silver plan in the individual’s geographic region.
    Tr. 143:5–9 (Frank). Because the silver plans are the most cost-effective—given the subsidy—
    approximately 70% of individuals choose silver plans. Tr. 2631:20–2632:7 (Counihan); Tr.
    142:14–21 (Frank).     Approximately 85% of all individuals who purchase insurance on the
    exchanges receive a subsidy. Tr. 144:6–8 (Frank); Tr. 1546:24–1547:4 (Mayhew). And because
    the amount of the subsidy is tied to the price of on-exchange plans, higher premiums increase the
    cost both to the consumer and the taxpayer. See Tr. 140:23–141:1 (Frank).
    IV.    Procedural History
    15
    On July 21, 2016, the United States, along with Delaware, the District of Columbia,
    Florida, Georgia, Illinois, Iowa, Ohio, Pennsylvania, and Virginia, filed a complaint seeking to
    permanently enjoin the Aetna-Humana merger. 5 See Compl. [ECF No. 1] ¶ 69. The government
    alleged that the transaction violates Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18, because its effect
    “may be to substantially lessen competition” in a number of markets: (1) the market for individual
    Medicare Advantage plans in 364 counties across 21 states; and (2) the market for individual
    insurance sold on the public exchanges in 17 counties across three states (Florida, Georgia, and
    Missouri). In the government’s estimation, the merger would adversely affect 1.6 million people
    in Medicare Advantage and 700,000 more in the public exchanges. See Compl. ¶¶ 10, 12.
    In the weeks following the government’s complaint, the companies took steps that
    introduced additional issues into the case. First, on August 2, 2016, Aetna and Humana each
    entered into a separate Asset Purchase Agreement with Molina Healthcare, under which they have
    agreed to sell Molina some of their Medicare Advantage plans if their merger is consummated and
    if the Court believes that a divestiture is necessary to counteract the merger’s anticompetitive
    effects. The proposed divestiture would transfer responsibility for approximately 290,000 seniors
    from Aetna or Humana to Molina, and would include seniors in all 364 complaint counties.
    Second, on August 15, 2016, Aetna announced that it no longer planned to offer plans on the public
    exchanges in 11 states where it had offered plans in 2016, including those that cover all 17 counties
    in the complaint. See Tr. 1360:14–16 (Bertolini); PX0133; DX0031. The motivation for—and
    legal consequence of—Aetna’s decision to withdraw have been sharply disputed by the parties.
    5
    On the same day, the government filed a second complaint seeking to enjoin the Anthem-Cigna merger,
    citing alleged anticompetitive effects in markets that are mostly different than those at issue here. See Compl., Case
    No. 16-1493 [ECF No. 1]. Because the government filed the cases as related, both were initially assigned to this
    judge. The Court held a joint status conference on August 4, 2016. After concluding that the cases did not raise
    enough common issues to be truly related, and that the public would be better served if these complex and important
    cases seeking expedited relief were assigned to different judges, the Court referred the Anthem-Cigna merger for
    random reassignment. See Aug. 5, 2016, Order [ECF No. 39].
    16
    In the months preceding the trial, the parties exchanged millions of documents, conducted
    dozens of depositions, and generally worked together in a collaborative and professional manner.
    They were greatly aided in those efforts by the court-appointed Special Master, retired Judge
    Richard A. Levie, who facilitated a smooth discovery process and helped make the compressed
    timeline in this case feasible. In late October and early November, the parties submitted their
    expert reports—sixteen in all, totaling more than a thousand pages—for the Court’s review. They
    also submitted helpful pretrial briefs previewing the evidence and arguments at trial. During the
    final week before trial, the Court, Judge Levie, and the parties worked to resolve any outstanding
    evidentiary or confidentiality issues. A final pretrial conference was held on December 2, with
    trial set to begin on December 5, 2016.
    The trial began on schedule and lasted for 13 trial days. The Court received hundreds of
    exhibits addressing the businesses of Aetna, Humana, and Molina; their plans for the merger and
    divestiture; their dealings with CMS; and several other topics. The Court also heard testimony
    from more than thirty helpful and knowledgeable witnesses, including executives and employees
    from Aetna, Humana, and Molina; officials from CMS; and independent brokers. The parties also
    put forward a number of distinguished experts to testify on a variety of subjects. Dr. Richard
    Frank, formerly the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation at HHS, provided testimony
    on the role of competition in both Medicare Advantage and the public exchanges. Dr. Gary Ford
    testified about survey design and, in particular, the value of an internal survey conducted by
    Humana regarding which insurance options seniors leaving Humana Medicare Advantage plans
    choose. Dr. Lawton Burns testified about the Molina divestiture. Two experts, Rajiv Gohkale and
    Christine Hammer, provided testimony on the efficiencies that might result from the Aetna-
    Humana merger.      And finally, economists Dr. Aviv Nevo and Jonathan Orszag provided
    17
    compelling, detailed, and—most importantly—comprehensible testimony on the probable
    economic effects of the merger. The Court is appreciative of all these witnesses, and of the
    attorneys who elicited their testimony.
    On December 29, 2016, the parties submitted their proposed findings of fact and
    conclusions of law. The following day, on December 30, the Court heard final argument over
    several hours. Now, having carefully considered all of the evidence and the parties’ arguments,
    the Court has reached the following conclusions.
    LEGAL STANDARD
    Section 7 of the Clayton Act prohibits mergers “where in any line of commerce or in any
    activity affecting commerce in any section of the country, the effect of such acquisition may be
    substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly.” 15 U.S.C. § 18. Two aspects
    of the statutory text are worth highlighting. First, by using the word “may,” Congress indicated
    that its “concern was with probabilities, not certainties.” Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 323 (1962). Hence, mergers with “probable anticompetitive effect[s]” are prohibited by
    the Clayton Act. 
    Id. The government
    need not prove the alleged anticompetitive effects “with
    ‘certainty.’” FTC v. H.J. Heinz Co., 
    246 F.3d 708
    , 719 (D.C. Cir. 2001). Second, the Clayton Act
    protects “competition,” rather than any particular competitor. United States v. Baker Hughes Inc.,
    
    908 F.2d 981
    , 991 n.12 (D.C. Cir. 1990). To assess a merger’s probable effect on competition, the
    Court must undertake a “comprehensive inquiry” into the “future competitive conditions in a given
    market.” 
    Id. at 988.
    D.C. Circuit precedent creates a burden-shifting framework to guide that inquiry, which
    generally begins with defining a relevant antitrust market. 
    Id. at 982–83;
    see, e.g., FTC v. Sysco
    Corp., 
    113 F. Supp. 3d 1
    , 24 (D.D.C. 2015); United States v. H&R Block, Inc., 
    833 F. Supp. 2d 18
    36, 50 (D.D.C. 2011). If the government can “show that the merger would produce a firm
    controlling an undue percentage share of the relevant market, and would result in a significant
    increase in the concentration of firms in that market,” that creates “a presumption that the merger
    will substantially lessen competition.” 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 715
    (internal quotation marks and
    alterations omitted). By making such a showing, the government “establish[es] a prima facie case
    of anticompetitive effect.” Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 983
    .
    To rebut this presumption, “defendants must produce evidence that shows that the market-
    share statistics give an inaccurate account of the merger’s probable effects on competition in the
    relevant market.” 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 715
    (internal quotation marks and alterations omitted).
    “[E]vidence on a variety of factors can rebut a prima facie case.” Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 984
    .
    For example, defendants may produce evidence concerning the “ease of entry into the market, the
    trend of the market either toward or away from concentration,” the “continuation of active price
    competition,” or “unique economic circumstances that undermine the predictive value of the
    government’s statistics.” 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 715
    n.7 (internal quotation marks omitted); see also
    Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 985
    –86 (listing additional factors that can rebut the government’s prima
    facie case). But the “more compelling the prima facie case, the more evidence the defendant must
    present to rebut it successfully.” Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 991
    .
    “If the defendant successfully rebuts the presumption of illegality, the burden of producing
    additional evidence of anticompetitive effect shifts to the government, and merges with the
    ultimate burden of persuasion, which remains with the government at all times.” 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 715
    (internal quotation marks and alterations omitted). The government “has the ultimate
    burden of proving a Section 7 violation by a preponderance of the evidence.” H&R Block, 833 F.
    Supp. 2d at 49 (internal quotation marks omitted).
    19
    ANALYSIS
    I.    Medicare Advantage
    A. Market Definition
    Only an “examination of [a] particular market—its structure, history and probable future—
    can provide the appropriate setting for judging the probable anticompetitive effect of [a] merger.”
    United States v. Gen. Dynamics Corp., 
    415 U.S. 486
    , 498 (1974) (internal quotation marks
    omitted). The first question in this case is about the proper boundaries of that “particular market.”
    Antitrust markets have two dimensions: product and geographic area. FTC v. Arch Coal, Inc., 
    329 F. Supp. 2d 109
    , 119 (D.D.C. 2004). The parties here agree that the relevant geographic market
    is the county. 6 But they sharply dispute the boundaries of the relevant product market. Is the
    market properly limited to individual Medicare Advantage plans, as the government contends? Or
    are defendants correct that Original Medicare options—meaning Original Medicare paired with a
    MedSupp and/or a prescription drug plan—should also be included in the market?
    “The outer boundaries of a product market are determined by the reasonable
    interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and
    substitutes for it.” Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325
    . Both aspects of the Brown Shoe test “look to
    the availability of substitute commodities, i.e. whether there are other products offered to
    consumers which are similar in character or use,” and “how far buyers will go to substitute one
    commodity for another.” FTC v. Staples, Inc., 
    970 F. Supp. 1066
    , 1074 (D.D.C. 1997). “[T]he
    mere fact that a [product] may be termed a competitor in the overall marketplace does not
    necessarily require that it be included in the relevant product market for antitrust purposes.” 
    Id. at 1075.
    Markets “must be drawn narrowly to exclude any other product to which, within reasonable
    6
    The county is the relevant geographic market because seniors may enroll only in Medicare Advantage plans
    offered in the county where they live. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 88; Tr. 393:25–394:10 (Cocozza)
    20
    variations in price, only a limited number of buyers will turn.” Times-Picayune Publ’g Co. v.
    United States, 
    345 U.S. 594
    , 612 n.31 (1953). That general rule applies even to “functionally
    interchangeable” products, meaning those that can be used for the same purpose as the product at
    issue. See, e.g., H&R 
    Block, 833 F. Supp. 2d at 54
    –60 (excluding assisted tax preparation and do-
    it-yourself tax preparation from the market for digital do-it-yourself tax preparation software, even
    though all provide ways to complete a tax return); 
    Staples, 970 F. Supp. at 1074
    –81 (excluding
    consumable office supplies sold outside office supply superstores from the market, even though
    those supplies were functionally interchangeable with office supplies sold inside the superstores).
    This analytical approach guides antitrust courts in attempting to answer one “key
    question”: whether particular products “are sufficiently close substitutes” such that substitution to
    one could “constrain any anticompetitive . . . pricing” in the other. See H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 54. Products that meet that threshold generally belong in the product market. Once those
    products are grouped together, the “‘market can be seen as the array of producers of substitute
    products that could control price if united in a hypothetical cartel or as a hypothetical monopoly.’”
    FTC v. Whole Foods Market, Inc., 
    548 F.3d 1028
    , 1052 (D.C. Cir. 2008) (Kavanaugh, J.,
    dissenting) (quoting 2B Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 530a, at 226
    (3d ed. 2007)). That vision of the proper product market is incorporated into the “hypothetical
    monopolist test” as set out in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines and applied by the courts in a
    number of cases. See Fed. Trade Comm’n & U.S. Dep’t of Justice Horizontal Merger Guidelines
    § 4.1.1 (2010) 7; see also 
    Sysco, 113 F. Supp. 3d at 33
    –34; H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 51–52.
    To determine whether a group of products could be an antitrust market, the hypothetical
    monopolist test asks whether a hypothetical monopolist of all the products within a proposed
    7
    Although the Guidelines are not binding, the D.C. Circuit and other courts have looked to them for guidance
    in previous merger cases. See, e.g., 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 716
    n. 9; 
    Sysco, 113 F. Supp. 3d at 38
    .
    21
    market would likely impose a “small but significant and non-transitory increase in price”
    (SSNIP)—typically of five or ten percent—on at least one product in the market, including one
    sold by the merging firms. See Guidelines §§ 4.1.1, 4.1.2. Whether the hypothetical monopolist
    can profitably impose the price increase depends, in part, on the amount of substitution outside the
    proposed market. “If enough consumers are able to substitute away from the hypothetical
    monopolist’s product to another product and thereby make a price increase unprofitable, then the
    relevant market cannot include only the monopolist’s product and must also include the substitute
    goods.” 
    Sysco, 113 F. Supp. 3d at 33
    . But if substitution outside the proposed market is relatively
    low, then the hypothetical monopolist would likely impose the price increase without sacrificing
    a large number of sales. In that case, the price increase might be profitable, and the hypothetical
    monopolist’s products would constitute the proper antitrust market. See 
    id. at 33;
    Whole 
    Foods, 548 F.3d at 1052
    (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting).
    The central market definition question in this case is about the nature and extent of any
    competition between Original Medicare options and Medicare Advantage. Phrased in terms of the
    hypothetical monopolist test, the question is whether a hypothetical monopolist of all the Medicare
    Advantage plans in a particular county could profitably impose a small but significant non-
    transitory increase in price on those plans—or whether substitution by seniors to Original Medicare
    options would make any attempted price increase unprofitable.
    In answering that question, the Court has a number of analytical tools at its disposal. The
    first is provided by the Supreme Court’s decision in Brown Shoe. There, the Court explained that
    the boundaries of a product market “may be determined by examining such practical indicia as
    industry or public recognition of the [relevant market] as a separate economic entity, the product’s
    peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices,
    22
    sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors.” Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325
    . These
    “practical indicia” can be useful “evidentiary proxies for direct proof of substitutability.” Rothery
    Storage & Van Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, Inc., 
    792 F.2d 210
    , 218 (D.C. Cir. 1986); see also H&R
    Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 51.        This makes intuitive sense: if two products have distinct
    characteristics, uses, customers, and prices, it is unlikely that a large number of customers would
    switch to one in response to a price increase in the other.
    When applying the Brown Shoe factors here, the Court pays “close attention to the
    defendants’ ordinary course of business documents.” H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 52. All
    market definition “must take into account the realities of competition.” Whole 
    Foods, 548 F.3d at 1039
    (Brown, J.). Ordinary course of business documents reveal the contours of competition from
    the perspective of the parties, who have been quite successful in the sale of individual Medicare
    Advantage plans and may be presumed to “‘have accurate perceptions of economic realities.’”
    Whole 
    Foods, 548 F.3d at 1045
    (Tatel, J.) (quoting Rothery 
    Storage, 792 F.2d at 218
    n.4).
    Finally, in addition to the practical indicia and the ordinary course of business documents,
    the Court will rely on testimony from experts in the field of economics. See Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 27. As is customary in merger cases, the parties have introduced a wealth of economic
    evidence through their economists, Dr. Aviv Nevo and Jonathan Orszag. Together, Nevo and
    Orszag have provided testimony on subjects relevant to market definition, including the extent of
    substitution between Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage, the proper methods for applying
    the hypothetical monopolist test, and the relationship between market concentration and prices in
    Medicare Advantage. All of this evidence will be evaluated in turn.
    1. Competition Between Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage
    23
    The Court will begin where seniors do: with the choice between Original Medicare and
    Medicare Advantage. By statute, Congress has provided that seniors can obtain Medicare benefits
    either “through the original medicare fee-for-service program,” or “through enrollment in a
    [Medicare Advantage] plan.” 42 U.S.C. § 1395w-21(a)(1). 8 Because Medicare Advantage plans
    are required to provide coverage for Medicare Parts A and B, the government agrees that
    “Medicare Advantage and Original Medicare are both ways for seniors to get their Medicare
    benefits.” Tr. 15:13–15 (opening statement). It is up to the individual senior to choose—and that
    same basic choice is presented no matter where seniors look. Every year, CMS sends a handbook
    called “Medicare & You” to each Medicare beneficiary. Tr. 1225:20–22 (Cavanaugh). The 2017
    version explains that there “are [two] main choices” for how seniors get Medicare coverage, then
    proposes a number of steps to help seniors select between them. See DX0130-017. Step one
    provides a binary choice between Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage. DX0130-017. The
    handbook also refers seniors to an online tool called the “Medicare Plan Finder,” which can be
    used to “sort plans by type” and “compare the coverage, benefits, and estimated costs” associated
    with each. DX0130-016. Plan Finder can be used to search for Medicare Advantage plans and
    compare them to Original Medicare. Tr. 412:13–15 (Cocozza).
    Some seniors turn to independent brokers or to corporate sales agents for advice about their
    healthcare options. Here, too, they are presented with the choice between Original Medicare
    options and Medicare Advantage. See, e.g., Tr. 1089:5–1090:1 (Fitzgerald) (independent broker);
    Tr. 2036:7–2040:5 (Kauffmann) (Humana sales manager); see also Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325
    (products sold by the same “vendors” may be in the same product market). Ultimately, a majority
    8
    Defendants contend this provision amounts to a Congressional determination, binding on this Court, “that
    Original Medicare is an appropriate and adequate substitute for Medicare Advantage for every Medicare-eligible
    consumer.” Defs.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions at 103. While the Court does not take this statutory language
    lightly, it does not consider the language determinative of the antitrust issues in this case.
    24
    of seniors choose Original Medicare (either with or without supplements). According to the
    government’s economist, in 2016 only 44% of those seniors who were ineligible for eligibility-
    restricted Medicare options decided to enroll in Medicare Advantage. 9 PX0551 (Nevo Report)
    ¶ 38 & Exs. 1, 2. The rest selected an Original Medicare option.
    Original Medicare also serves as a starting point for Medicare Advantage plan design. Alan
    Wheatley, Humana’s Retail Segment President with responsibility for Medicare Advantage,
    explained the general plan design process. When entering a new county with a Medicare
    Advantage plan, Humana knows that CMS is “going to pay [to the company] Original Medicare’s
    cost,” in the form of the county-level benchmark. Tr. 561:10–13 (Wheatley). For Humana to beat
    that benchmark and introduce a viable plan, it must find a way to “improve health and lower costs.”
    Tr. 561:20–21 (Wheatley). Those savings can then be used “to add some additional benefits to
    make [the Humana plan] attractive relative to the big competitors in that market.” Tr. 561:23–25
    (Wheatley). If the resulting plan has a better value than Original Medicare, Humana is willing to
    offer it in the market. Tr. 562:11–16 (Wheatley). In internal documents, Aetna and Humana
    reference the imperative to maintain a Medicare Advantage value proposition that is superior to
    the one offered by Original Medicare. See DX0479-002 (“[O]ur value proposition must stay
    competitive with Original Medicare.”); DX0484-002 (citing an “[a]spiration” to “[a]gressively
    grow membership by delivering superior value proposition vs. [Original Medicare]”); DX0514-
    021 (listing the drivers of Medicare Advantage “Value Beyond Traditional Medicare”).
    Together, these dynamics create a degree of competition between Medicare Advantage and
    Original Medicare. Because both offer Medicare Parts A and B, the two programs are, at least to
    9
    Some seniors, like those with certain disabilities or chronic conditions, may be eligible for eligibility-
    restricted Medicare options. Because they do not face the same choice between Original Medicare and Medicare
    Advantage as the average senior, they have largely been excluded from the analysis in this case. When these seniors
    are included in the analysis, the share of seniors in Original Medicare options grows larger.
    25
    some extent, functionally interchangeable. Every senior is given an option between the two and,
    historically, a majority of seniors have selected Original Medicare. Some degree of competition
    is also inherent in the CMS bid process. To be viable products, Medicare Advantage plans must
    control their costs—relative to Original Medicare—enough to offer beneficiaries more benefits or
    lower out-of-pocket expenses than Original Medicare does. For all these reasons, then, any
    assessment of the competitive conditions facing Medicare Advantage plans must take the role of
    Original Medicare into account.
    None of this, however, means that Original Medicare must be included in the relevant
    product market.     Not every competitor—not even every competitor with a functionally
    interchangeable product—must be included in the product market. See, e.g., H&R Block, 833 F.
    Supp. 2d at 54 (excluding two methods of tax preparation from the product market even though it
    was “beyond debate” that “all methods of tax preparation are, to some degree, in competition”).
    What matters is the extent to which competition from Original Medicare options would constrain
    the exercise of market power in Medicare Advantage. In a memorandum cited by the companies,
    Dr. Frank, the former Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation at HHS, wrote that “in
    principle” Original Medicare is “in a position to ‘discipline’ competition” in Medicare Advantage.
    DX0087-010. To see whether that occurs in practice, the Court looks first to Brown Shoe and
    defendants’ ordinary course of business documents.
    2. Brown Shoe Factors & Ordinary Course of Business Documents
    Compared to basic Original Medicare, the average Medicare Advantage plan has some
    distinct “characteristics and uses.” Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325
    . Unlike Original Medicare,
    which allows seniors to receive care from almost any provider, Medicare Advantage plans
    typically are HMOs or PPOs that come with limited provider networks. In exchange for accepting
    26
    the network limitations, enrollees receive benefits that Original Medicare does not offer, such as a
    cap on out-of-pocket expenses and, usually, a prescription drug benefit. They might also receive
    vision, dental, hearing, or fitness benefits that would have to be purchased separately under
    Original Medicare. Some seniors may decide that Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage are
    not reasonable substitutes. Those who want a limit on out-of-pocket expenses, or place a high
    value on supplemental benefits, would be unlikely to select Original Medicare. Those who value
    network flexibility, on the other hand, might not select Medicare Advantage.
    Seniors can narrow the divide between Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage by
    purchasing supplemental coverage. By purchasing a MedSupp plan, for instance, a senior can
    limit out-of-pocket expenses in exchange for a monthly premium. Seniors may also purchase
    stand-alone coverage for prescription drugs, or for another supplemental benefit often offered by
    Medicare Advantage plans. One might expect, therefore, that a purely marginal senior, trying to
    decide between Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage, would routinely compare particular
    Medicare Advantage plans to particular MedSupp plans within the context of a larger Medicare
    market. And if there were large numbers of such seniors, one might further expect Aetna’s and
    Humana’s businesses to be organized around efforts to cater to them.
    But that is not what the record reveals. The weight of the evidence presented at trial
    indicates “industry [and] public recognition” of a distinct market for Medicare Advantage. See
    Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325
    . Competition within that market, between Medicare Advantage
    plans, is far more intense than competition with the products outside of it, like MedSupp plans.
    This evidence tends to show that substitution between Medicare Advantage and Original Medicare
    options is not nearly as substantial as defendants now suggest.
    27
    Both Aetna and Humana report individual Medicare Advantage results separately in their
    annual financial reports. PX0303 at 13 (Humana reporting Medicare Advantage revenue); PX0503
    at 16 (Aetna reporting Medicare Advantage membership). According to Alan Wheatley, this
    separate reporting facilitates analysis by investors, who often compare one Medicare Advantage
    company against another. Tr. 482:8–19 (Wheatley). As defendants argue, this method of reporting
    is not determinative: just because “automakers track car sales by model does not suggest each
    model belongs in a separate market.” Defs.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions [ECF No. 274] at
    122. But neither is it irrelevant, because in this case the separate reporting reflects deeper
    divisions. At Aetna, more than three thousand employees work on Medicare Advantage and Part
    D, while about four hundred different employees are “dedicated to the Med Supp business.” Tr.
    261:9–14, 256:20–1 (Cocozza). Aetna also hosts the two businesses on separate IT platforms. Tr.
    255:10–14 (Cocozza). Similar distinctions can be seen at Humana, which maintains “separate
    business units” for Medicare Advantage and MedSupp. Tr. 475:19–476:13 (Wheatley). However,
    executives at both companies cautioned against over-interpreting the extent to which the Medicare
    Advantage and MedSupp businesses are segregated. Aetna’s dedicated MedSupp employees do
    not “work in a vacuum” fully divorced from Medicare Advantage. Tr. 256:20–257:1 (Cocozza).
    And various internal Humana functions, such as its service operations, might support both
    businesses. Tr. 475:16–19 (Wheatley).
    Fair enough. But in one important respect—pricing—defendants’ Medicare Advantage
    and MedSupp businesses seem to run on very different tracks. According to the government’s
    economist, if “there were significant movement of seniors between Medicare Advantage plans and
    [MedSupp] plans, then firms would consider the pricing of one plan when setting pricing for the
    other plan.” PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 128. There is little indication that Aetna and Humana do
    28
    so. Quite the opposite is true. Aetna maintains separate teams of actuaries for pricing its Medicare
    Advantage and MedSupp plans. Tr. 680:13–16 (Wooldridge) (MedSupp actuaries do not work on
    Medicare Advantage pricing); Tr. 1995:6–18 (Paprocki) (Medicare Advantage actuaries do not
    work with MedSupp actuaries). And when pricing particular MedSupp plans, Aetna does not
    assess the prices of Medicare Advantage plans in the locations where the MedSupp plan will be
    offered.   Tr. 257:23–1 (Cocozza).     This evidence is inconsistent with the claims of close
    competition between Medicare Advantage and Original Medicare with MedSupp.
    On the other hand, evidence of intense competition within Medicare Advantage is
    abundant. When Aetna and Humana refer to their “competitors,” they are almost always referring
    to other Medicare Advantage organizations—and usually to other members of the Big 5. See
    
    Staples, 970 F. Supp. at 1079
    (“In document after document, the parties refer to, discuss, and make
    business decisions based upon the assumption that ‘competition’ refers to other office superstores
    only.”). For example, in a March 2015 email, Cocozza compares Aetna’s Medicare Advantage
    business to its “peers.” PX0007. Humana, she says, is Aetna’s “most formidable competitor,”
    before addressing UnitedHealth, Cigna, and Anthem in turn. PX0007-847. There is no mention
    of Original Medicare or MedSupp, which is typical. See, e.g., DX0283-003 (listing Aetna’s “top
    competitors” as Humana, UnitedHealth, Cigna, and Anthem); PX0063-446 (email to Humana
    CEO comparing the enrollment growth of UnitedHealth, Cigna, Aetna, Anthem, and WellCare).
    To compare themselves to these competitors, defendants calculate market shares of a
    Medicare Advantage market—on the national, state, and county levels. See PX0036-429 (Aetna
    document calculating national “market share growth” of UnitedHealth, Humana, Aetna, Cigna,
    and Anthem); PX0583-210 (Humana document dividing national “individual [Medicare
    Advantage] enrollment market share” between Humana, UnitedHealth, Aetna, Cigna, Anthem,
    29
    and “Other”); PX0155-454 (Humana document dividing North Carolina Medicare Advantage
    market share between “Major Competitor[s]” Humana, BlueCross BlueShield of North Carolina,
    UnitedHealth, Aetna, Cigna, and “Other”); PX0022-603 (Humana document collecting county-
    level membership data of Humana, Aetna, UnitedHealth, BlueCross BlueShield of Kansas City,
    and “Others” in the Kansas City area). 10
    Aetna and Humana prepare exceptionally detailed assessments of the competition between
    various Medicare Advantage plans. These documents were ubiquitous at trial. For example, a
    2015 email to Aetna general managers solicited specific information about the cost-sharing and
    benefit structures of the plans being offered by their “true competition.” PX0057-717. A proposed
    template included columns for UnitedHealth, Humana, Cigna, and “Etc.” PX0057-718–19. Two
    Humana documents reflect a similar exercise. In one—a July 2015 “Competitor Analysis” of
    Aetna and Cigna—Humana conducted “Market Comparisons” in 17 local markets across the
    country. PX0012-355. Within each local market, it calculated Medicare Advantage market shares,
    then compared the various Humana, Aetna, and Cigna plans by type, monthly premium, limit on
    out-of-pocket costs, primary care physician and specialist copays, and prescription drug plans.
    See, e.g., PX0012-357 (San Antonio/Corpus Christi Market Analysis). A second 2015 Humana
    document contains a similar market-by-market, plan-by-plan analysis addressing 24 markets
    where Humana “deteriorated” and UnitedHealth or Aetna “will likely grow” and another 15
    markets where Humana “held stable” but UnitedHealth or Aetna “were aggressive.” PX0023-
    628–29. Within each market, Humana compared its competitors’ individual plans on a variety of
    metrics, including whether the plan had increased its premium. See, e.g., PX0023-632. Such
    documents reflect clearly the scope and intensity of the competition within Medicare Advantage—
    10
    The place for “Other[s]” in these documents refers to other Medicare Advantage providers, not to Original
    Medicare or MedSupp.
    30
    and, more specifically, between members of the Big 5. None of these documents focus on
    competition with Original Medicare.
    Defendants have identified a limited number of documents that do refer to competition
    between Medicare Advantage and Original Medicare with MedSupp. Some refer to competition
    only in a very general manner. A 2015 Humana presentation, for instance, observes that “[o]ur
    main competitor is the traditional Medicare program. Beat them and we win big!” DX0501-003.
    An Aetna strategic planning document noted as a “Key Market Trend” the “[g]rowing role of
    Medicare Supplement” as an alternative to Medicare Advantage. DX0290-114. But a few
    documents give off a glimmer of more concrete, localized competition between Medicare
    Advantage and MedSupp. 11 A draft Medicare Advantage strategy within Humana proposes that
    the firm “increasingly migrate existing members” from MedSupp to Medicare Advantage.
    DX0484-002. An Aetna document about Washington state observes that increasing MedSupp
    premiums might offer a “wedge opportunity” for one of Aetna’s Medicare Advantage plans.
    DX0313-091. Another market-specific Humana document about Southern Ohio graphs “Market
    Membership by Product” and includes both Medicare Advantage products and MedSupp.
    DX0510-005. But see PX0155-454 (Humana document dividing “MAPD” market shares “By
    Product Type” but not including MedSupp). Perhaps the most concrete evidence regarding
    competition between Medicare Advantage and MedSupp relates to the “Med Supp killer,” a
    Medicare Advantage plan designed by Aetna to compete directly for MedSupp customers.
    11
    Many of defendants’ documents concerning Medicare Advantage reference a “penetration rate,” which
    reflects the share of Medicare-eligible seniors who select Medicare Advantage over Original Medicare in a particular
    location. Usually, however, these references do not herald concrete competitive steps to be taken vis-à-vis some
    specific MedSupp plan or other Original Medicare option. As a result, in the Court’s view, penetration rates are more
    appropriately interpreted as a statistic used to assess the size of the Medicare Advantage market.
    31
    DX0035-002; Tr. 2094:9–2095:5 (Follmer). Because the plan has been unsuccessful, Aetna now
    incentivizes brokers not to sell it. See Tr. 2096:18–2098:1 (Follmer).
    But these documents are too few and too general to carry much weight. It is evident from
    the clear majority of the documents reviewed here that Aetna and Humana spend an enormous
    amount of time, money, and manpower assessing the offerings of competing Medicare Advantage
    plans. They make those assessments on a market-by-market, plan-by-plan basis, focusing on
    details concerning premiums, out-of-pocket costs, networks, and benefits. The passing references
    in the record to competition with Original Medicare or with MedSupp do not suffice to undercut
    the strong inference that must be drawn from the ordinary course of business documents—that
    Aetna and Humana focus most of their competitive efforts within the market for Medicare
    Advantage rather than on products outside of it, like MedSupp.
    That focus makes sense, the government contends, if Medicare Advantage plans generally
    attract a set of “distinct customers.” See Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325
    . The government has
    indeed introduced a good deal of evidence showing that at least some seniors have a “durable
    preference” for Medicare Advantage relative to Original Medicare options. See Pls.’ Proposed
    Findings & Conclusions at 38. The most persuasive of this evidence is switching data—that is,
    data about how often seniors leave Medicare Advantage plans and where they go when they do.
    The switching data presents a clear picture: Medicare Advantage enrollees rarely switch plans, but
    when they do, they overwhelming stay within Medicare Advantage.
    The switching data evidence comes from a variety of sources. Using data from 2013 and
    2014, the Kaiser Family Foundation concluded that 78% of Medicare Advantage enrollees
    remained with their plan during that period. Tr. 113:16–114:1 (Frank). In that same period, 11%
    of Medicare Advantage enrollees voluntarily left their plan in favor of a different Medicare
    32
    Advantage plan; only 2% of enrollees voluntarily left Medicare Advantage for an Original
    Medicare option. Tr. 114:1–8 (Frank). Of the voluntary switchers from Medicare Advantage,
    therefore, more than 80% switched to a different Medicare Advantage plan. According to Frank,
    this proportion has remained relatively stable, between 80 and 85%, in recent years. Tr. 115:9–16
    (Frank); see also PX0554 (Frank Reply Report) Ex. 5 (presenting data for 2007 to 2014).
    The pattern holds for seniors who voluntarily left their Medicare Advantage plan in
    response to a premium increase. Again using 2013 and 2014 data, the Kaiser Family Foundation
    concluded that 25 to 33% of Medicare Advantage enrollees left their existing plan in response to
    a premium increase of $20 per month—but no more than 13% of them switched to an Original
    Medicare option. PX0554 (Frank Reply Report) ¶ 32. A 2014 study commissioned by Humana
    reached similar results. 12 Out of a sample of 250 seniors who disenrolled from a Humana Medicare
    Advantage plan, 85% switched to a different Medicare Advantage plan. PX0015-879. Because
    many seniors cited costs, including high premiums, co-pays, or deductibles, as a reason for
    switching, the survey concluded that “[c]osts play a huge rule in [Medicare Advantage] members
    defecting.” PX0015-853. Both Cocozza and Wheatley acknowledged that most seniors who leave
    an Aetna or Humana Medicare Advantage plan switch to a different Medicare Advantage plan, not
    to Original Medicare. Tr. 288:13–16 (Cocozza); Tr. 524:16–21 (Wheatley).
    Switching within Medicare Advantage also dominates among seniors who must
    involuntarily switch from their Medicare Advantage plans, perhaps because their existing plan was
    cancelled. These seniors “overwhelmingly” return to Medicare Advantage. Tr. 116:2–6 (Frank);
    see also PX0554 (Frank Reply Report) ¶ 31 (citing a paper finding that between 83 and 95% of
    seniors whose Medicare Advantage plans were terminated switched to another Medicare
    12
    The government offered expert testimony by Dr. Gary Ford, who was retained to assess the reliability of
    this Humana study. According to Ford, the study is reliable. Tr. 912:22–913:1 (Ford).
    33
    Advantage plan). After Humana discontinued one of its Medicare Advantage plans in the San
    Antonio area, Raul Gonzalez, a local broker, helped about 200 clients obtain new coverage. Only
    about 12 to 14 switched to Original Medicare plus MedSupp. Tr. 1034:24–1035:8 (Gonzalez).
    “For the most part,” the others switched to an Aetna Medicare Advantage plan. Tr. 1033:1–
    1035:10 (Gonzalez); see also Tr. 1077:17–1080:14 (Fitzgerald). If seniors do not select a new
    plan when their existing plan is cancelled, they are defaulted back to Original Medicare. One 2015
    paper cited by Frank finds that 89% of the seniors involuntarily moved to Original Medicare by
    default later chose to return to Medicare Advantage. PX0554 (Frank Reply Report) ¶ 32.
    Nevo analyzed switching data from several sources and arrived at similar conclusions.
    First, he analyzed 2015 CMS data from the annual open-enrollment period, when any senior can
    switch between any Medicare options, including between Medicare Advantage and Original
    Medicare. Second, he analyzed a subset of that data, which focused only on those seniors who
    had their plan cancelled in 2015. And finally, he analyzed three years’ worth of data from Aetna
    and Humana—unlike the CMS open-enrollment data, this data includes information concerning
    the annual “disenrollment period,” when seniors can switch from Medicare Advantage to Original
    Medicare but not between Medicare Advantage plans. All else equal, including seniors who
    switched from Medicare Advantage during the disenrollment period might be expected to increase
    the overall share switching into Original Medicare options. But in all three instances, more than
    85% of seniors who left one Medicare Advantage plan switched to another instead of to an Original
    Medicare option. See Tr. 1587:20–1592:18 (Nevo); see also PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) Ex. 7.
    The switching data makes clear that there is a group of seniors with a distinct preference
    for Medicare Advantage relative to Original Medicare. Testimony by the government’s broker
    witnesses generally supports the same conclusion. See, e.g., Tr. 1071:11–17 (Fitzgerald) (after
    34
    receiving an overview of Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage, seniors begin “asking more
    questions about one side or the other”). A preference for Medicare Advantage may be based on a
    number of factors, including a senior’s comfort with managed care plans or desire to receive all of
    his or her benefits from one source. See Pls.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions at 37 (collecting
    support for those propositions). But one important factor is cost. See Tr. 1023:24–1024:8
    (Gonzalez) (questions about cost can “quickly determine” whether a senior chooses Medicare
    Advantage or MedSupp). The weight of the evidence suggests that, on average, Medicare
    Advantage plans have much lower out-of-pocket costs than Original Medicare plus MedSupp and
    prescription drug plans. See Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 325
    (noting that “distinct prices” may be
    considered in assessing the boundaries of a market).
    All Medicare Advantage plans come with a statutory limit on annual out-of-pocket
    expenses and most include coverage for prescription drugs. To recreate those benefits on the
    Original Medicare side, a senior would have to purchase MedSupp and prescription drug plans
    from a private insurer—and would likely end up paying significantly more in monthly premiums.
    The average Medicare Advantage enrollee pays $142 in monthly premiums, while the average
    senior enrolled in Original Medicare plus MedSupp and a prescription drug plan pays double that
    amount. PX0554 (Frank Reply Report) ¶ 26 & Ex. 4. But as the companies are correct to observe,
    monthly premiums are only part of the story. A senior with MedSupp coverage will likely not
    incur monthly out-of-pocket expenses in addition to his or her monthly premium. A senior in
    Medicare Advantage, on the other hand, may still have to pay various cost-sharing requirements
    in exchange for receiving medical care. His or her monthly out-of-pocket expenses, then, will
    depend on the amount of care received, in addition to the monthly premium. Even so, Medicare
    Advantage enrollees are still likely to enjoy lower out-of-pocket costs. Using national 2010 data,
    35
    a paper cited by Frank concluded that out-of-pocket costs for Original Medicare exceed those for
    Medicare Advantage by between $130 and $167 per month. PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 42; see also
    PX0554 (Frank Reply Report) ¶ 27.
    The government does not have to prove that preferences for Medicare Advantage overlap
    with any demographic indicators. But here, there is evidence suggesting that Medicare Advantage
    plans tend to attract seniors with lower incomes. That trend has been observed by academics; by
    defendants’ executives, competitors, and Molina; and by independent brokers. See Tr. 112:14–18
    (Frank) (“[T]here’s been quite a bit of research on this, and that research generally shows that
    people with lower incomes, lower levels of education, tend to join Medicare Advantage plans
    disproportionately to the rest of the population”); Tr. 1341:9–16 (Bertolini) (agreeing that the
    senior who chooses Medicare Advantage “tends on the average to be somewhat lower income than
    the population as a whole” because of Medicare Advantage’s “total out-of-pocket costs”);
    PX0011-895 (Anthem executive noting that Medicare Advantage “attracts the lower/lower-middle
    income beneficiaries that can’t afford Med Supp”); Tr. 2345:5–7 (Dr. Molina) (Molina CEO
    asserting that “the majority of people” in “Medicare Advantage are actually of lower income”);
    Tr. 1024:20–1025:1 (Gonzalez) (broker explaining that “it’s much more difficult” for lower
    income people “to go with the Medicare Supplement and pay the higher costs”). But see DX0034-
    006; Tr. 715:3–7 (Wooldridge) (60% of Aetna’s MedSupp customers make less than $35,000 a
    year). That lower-income seniors tend to select Medicare Advantage is circumstantial evidence
    that its out-of-pocket costs tend to be lower than comparable Original Medicare options.
    Based on the Brown Shoe factors and the parties’ ordinary course of business documents,
    the government has made a strong evidentiary showing in support of the Medicare Advantage
    product market. The switching data shows that there are some seniors with durable preferences
    36
    for Medicare Advantage. These seniors would be less likely than average to switch to a (often
    more costly) Original Medicare option in the event of a small but significant non-transitory
    increase in Medicare Advantage prices, and perhaps much less likely if they are low-income.
    Given the average cost differential between Medicare Advantage and comparable Original
    Medicare options, there may be room for a hypothetical monopolist of all Medicare Advantage
    plans in a particular county to profitably impose such a price increase without driving large
    numbers of seniors to Original Medicare. That will depend in part on the number of seniors who
    sit on the margin between Medicare Advantage and Original Medicare. But the parties’ ordinary
    course of business documents, viewed through the lens of Brown Shoe, suggest that there are not
    as many of these seniors as one might imagine. Evidence abounds of intense, local competition
    between Medicare Advantage plans.         Evidence of similar competition between Medicare
    Advantage plans and MedSupp is much scarcer. Collectively, the evidence tends to establish the
    existence of a market for the sale of individual Medicare Advantage plans.
    3. Defendants’ Counter Arguments
    Aetna and Humana raise several counter arguments. They argue that the government has
    oversimplified the health-insurance market and the choices that seniors make.            Medicare
    Advantage plans, they point out, can vary on a number of metrics, including the breadth of provider
    networks, benefits provided, total out-of-pocket costs; some plans, they continue, actually have
    higher estimated out-of-pocket costs or fewer benefits than a competing Original Medicare option.
    See Defs.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions at 18–19. As a result of this overlap, defendants
    believe that “a Medicare Advantage plan’s closest cousins are often one or more Original Medicare
    options instead of other Medicare Advantage plans. Excluding all Original Medicare options in
    37
    order to create an MA-only market would ignore the ample overlap between the two types of
    plans.” 
    Id. at 115–16
    (internal citation omitted).
    What’s more, defendants contend, the government has mischaracterized the manner in
    which seniors make healthcare choices. Each chooses among the available Medicare Advantage
    and Original Medicare options based on highly individualized preferences that are based on factors
    such as cost, medical condition, comfort with limited provider networks, and convenience.
    Preferences may change over time, and are not predetermined by demographic factors like income.
    See 
    id. at 22–28.
    Defendants conclude “it is [too] difficult to generalize about the kinds or types
    of beneficiaries who will select one product over the other.” 
    Id. at 123.
    Taking the second contention first, the Court agrees that seniors make individualized
    healthcare decisions. That does not mean, however, that all generalization is futile. Indeed Aetna
    and Humana, who have a vested financial interest in accurately assessing the competitive
    landscape, have not always so scrupulously avoided generalizing about seniors’ healthcare
    decisions. For example, a draft presentation prepared for a Humana board retreat includes a slide
    addressing “Why Consumers Select Products,” which differentiates between Medicare Advantage
    and MedSupp customers. Because Original Medicare plus MedSupp is “the most expensive plan
    combo,” seniors who select it are “[w]illing to pay more for a flexible network of physicians and
    comprehensive coverage.” DX0514-023. Medicare Advantage, on the other hand, attracts those
    seniors who want “additional health coverage, but [are] willing to sacrifice having a flexible
    network to keep costs low.” DX0514-023; see also PX0045-196 (Humana sales director opining
    that low Medicare Advantage penetration levels likely means that “there are higher income
    eligibles in the area who are more inclined to have [MedSupp] policies versus MA plans”);
    PX0025-920 (2016 Aetna presentation describing the “Typical Med Supp Customer” based on
    38
    income and geography); PX0021-017 (Aetna executive explaining that Medicare Advantage and
    Med Supp are “apples and oranges,” that “the nature of MA and Med Supp focuses on different
    areas,” and that “an area cannot be both a good Med Supp and a good MA area.”).
    Aetna and Humana have also historically been willing to generalize about the costs and
    benefits of Medicare Advantage compared to Original Medicare options. Internal documents
    claim that Medicare Advantage provides “[b]etter benefits [and] lower cost” than Original
    Medicare, either with or without supplemental coverage. See DX0480-006; see also DX0514-021
    (Humana document noting that Medicare Advantage offers “[m]ore benefits & less out of pocket
    payments than Original Medicare”). Humana makes similar claims. In its 2016 Presentation on
    Medicare Advantage and Prescription Drug Plans, Humana notes that Medicare Advantage plans
    generally “have lower out-of-pocket costs” than Original Medicare and may come with “[e]xtra
    benefits.” DX0111-023; see also Tr. 2061:6–16 (Kauffman) (Humana sales manager confirming
    that she shares this information during meetings with seniors).
    Nor is the Court convinced that an Original Medicare option is the “closest cousin” for
    many Medicare Advantage plans. If that is indeed the case, it is not reflected in the record. CMS’s
    Medicare & You Handbook advises seniors to make a threshold choice between Medicare
    Advantage and Original Medicare, not to choose from a continuum of intermingled Medicare
    Advantage and Original Medicare options. PX0519-017. A “Decision Tree” created by Humana
    presents a senior’s decision in a similar fashion. Before assessing a plan’s network, costs, or
    supplemental benefits, the senior is asked to decide whether she is willing to “accept network
    restrictions”; if so, she is deemed a good fit for Medicare Advantage, but if not, she is deemed a
    good fit for MedSupp. DX0490-045. If Medicare Advantage plans were routinely competing with
    a “closest cousin” from the Original Medicare side of the family, one would expect to find evidence
    39
    of that competition in the ordinary course of business documents. But for the most part, it is not
    there. Aetna and Humana frequently compare their Medicare Advantage offerings to other
    Medicare Advantage plans, but they rarely, if ever, compare them to particular MedSupp plans.
    Seniors, it seems, do not make that comparison either. In eight years selling Medicare products,
    broker Robert Fitzgerald has never compared a particular Medicare Advantage plan to a particular
    MedSupp plan—at a senior’s request or otherwise. Tr. 1073:18–1074:1 (Fitzgerald).
    Aetna and Humana contend that any differences that do exist between Medicare Advantage
    and Original Medicare have been and will be narrowed by various legislative and regulatory
    changes. They cite two of note. First, the Affordable Care Act linked Medicare Advantage
    reimbursement rates to Original Medicare provider costs, resulting in a substantial reduction in
    county-level benchmarks phased in over a period of six years.           See Tr. 1127:13–1128:20
    (Cavanaugh). These reductions, defendants contend, have reduced “the reimbursements MAOs
    receive from CMS, decreasing their revenues, and increasing competition between Original
    Medicare and Medicare Advantage plans.” Defs.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions at 20.
    The companies also believe that Accountable Care Organizations, or ACOs, will bring
    Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage closer. ACOs, which were created by the Affordable
    Care Act, are groups of providers who join together in an attempt to coordinate care, control costs,
    and improve health outcomes; those that succeed in holding down costs may be paid a financial
    bonus by CMS. PX0554 (Frank Reply Report) ¶ 42. By responding to these incentives and
    providing value-based care within Original Medicare, defendants argue, ACOs will help convert
    Original Medicare from a fee-for-service model into one more like Medicare Advantage. In fact,
    defendants say, this conversion is already underway. See Tr. 1174:16–1175:2 (Cavanaugh)
    (discussing efforts to move Original Medicare away from fee-for-service payment model).
    40
    But these policy changes have little impact on the market definition analysis in this case.
    The Court does not doubt that the benchmark reductions made the basic Medicare Advantage value
    proposition of lower costs and additional benefits somewhat more difficult to deliver. See
    DX0508-033 (slide deck for Humana Board of Directors Meeting observing that “Benchmark
    Reductions are reducing MA Value Add” and that “MA Value Add drives Penetration Rate”). But
    because these reductions will be fully phased in by the end of 2017, see Tr. 1128:21–24
    (Cavanaugh), their impact has largely already been felt. Moreover, MAOs have largely succeeded
    in maintaining the Medicare Advantage value proposition by controlling costs, bidding below the
    benchmarks, and offering supplemental benefits not provided by Original Medicare. See PX0551
    (Nevo Report) ¶ 67; Tr. 1130:3–12 (Cavanaugh).          Thus, the differences between Medicare
    Advantage and Original Medicare options have been preserved.
    The argument concerning ACOs is also unpersuasive. The market definition analysis
    “focuses solely on demand substitution factors,” 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 718
    (internal quotation marks
    omitted)—i.e., “customers’ ability and willingness to substitute away from one product to another
    in response to a price increase” or “reduction in product quality or service,” Guidelines § 4. It is
    not clear what impact the advent of ACOs would have on the extent of this substitution. As an
    initial matter, it is the provider, not the senior, who decides whether to participate in an ACO;
    seniors are often “passively attributed” to them, sometimes even without their knowledge. PX0554
    (Frank Reply Report) ¶ 46. Hence, there is no choice by the senior customer to use an ACO. And
    for the most part, ACOs do not diminish the essential differences between Medicare Advantage
    and Original Medicare. Perhaps a senior who has been attributed to an ACO would receive some
    of the care coordination ordinarily associated with Medicare Advantage. But unlike Medicare
    Advantage enrollees, Original Medicare enrollees assigned to ACOs are not penalized for seeking
    41
    care outside the network. Tr. 133:22–134:5 (Frank). Nor would they receive additional coverage
    or cost reductions for participating in the ACO. PX0554 (Frank Reply Report) ¶ 44. Ultimately,
    then, ACOs have almost “nothing to do with a comparison of the benefits of traditional Medicare
    or Medicare Advantage.” Tr. 1132:3–6 (Cavanaugh). And as a result, they also have little to do
    with defining the product market in this case.
    The companies’ third argument, though, fares better. Aetna and Humana argue that an
    exclusive focus on the behavior of switch-outs—those seniors who have already enrolled in a
    Medicare Advantage plan—is “misguided.” Every day, approximately 10,000 seniors “age in”
    and become eligible for Medicare, and are thus presented with the choice between Original
    Medicare options and Medicare Advantage. 13 Aetna and Humana argue that Medicare Advantage
    organizations must compete for these age-ins, in addition to seniors already enrolled in Medicare
    Advantage or Original Medicare options.
    The companies argue that the parties’ recent Medicare Advantage enrollment data makes
    this clear. In 2015 only 45% of Aetna’s and Humana’s Medicare enrollees switched from a
    different MAO; the remaining 55% enrolled either as they aged into Medicare (21%) or switched
    from an Original Medicare option (34%). Tr. 3044:7–20 (Orszag). Focusing just on the behavior
    of seniors who have already selected a Medicare Advantage plan is like standing outside a Ford
    dealership and asking those who emerge with Ford keys “What do you think about Fords?” Tr.
    3646:15–18 (closing argument). That survey would reveal that some drivers have a preference for
    Fords, but it would also obscure the broader competitive picture. Here, defendants insist, the
    broader competitive picture shows that a hypothetical monopolist of all Medicare Advantage plans
    13
    Seniors who are still employed when they turn 65 may not have to make an individualized choice between
    Medicare Advantage and Original Medicare. Instead, they may be offered a group plan by their employer, which falls
    on one side of the line or the other. See Tr. 116:18–24 (Frank) (describing employer-provided MedSupp plans that
    wrap around Original Medicare); Tr. 1119:14 – 20 (Cavanaugh) (describing group Medicare Advantage plans).
    42
    could not impose a price increase. If it tried, some Medicare Advantage enrollees may remain
    within the market; but the age-ins would turn to Original Medicare options in sufficient numbers
    to make the price increase untenable. See Tr. 48:21–49:13 (opening statement).
    In the Court’s view, Aetna and Humana understate the importance of the switching data,
    which indicates not only that some seniors opt for Medicare Advantage, but that those seniors stick
    with it in the face of price increases or plan exits. Their argument implies that age-ins are as a
    group somehow closer to the margin between Medicare Advantage and Original Medicare options
    than seniors who have already made an initial selection. But there is little evidentiary support for
    that contention. Despite the unrelenting torrent of age-ins, Aetna and Humana focus their
    competitive efforts primarily within the Medicare Advantage market. Still, the companies’ basic
    point is well-taken: the market definition analysis in this case must rest on a complete assessment
    of the demand for individual Medicare Advantage. For that assessment, the Court now turns to
    the economists.
    4. Econometric Evidence
    The government’s economist, Dr. Aviv Nevo, analyzed whether the proposed market for
    the sale of individual Medicare Advantage plans would satisfy the hypothetical monopolist test.
    As set out in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines, that test asks whether
    a hypothetical profit-maximizing firm, not subject to price
    regulation, that was the only present and future seller of those
    products (“hypothetical monopolist”) likely would impose at least a
    small but significant and non-transitory increase in price (“SSNIP”)
    on at least one product in the market, including at least one product
    sold by one of the merging firms.
    Guidelines § 4.1.1. If so, the candidate market may be the relevant product market. See 
    Sysco, 113 F. Supp. 3d at 33
    –34; H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 51–52. Because Medicare Advantage
    43
    passed under all formulations of his hypothetical monopolist tests, Nevo concluded that individual
    Medicare Advantage plans constitute a relevant product market. Tr. 1610:16–21 (Nevo).
    Nevo’s analysis began with his demand model, which provides several key inputs for his
    hypothetical monopolist test. Nevo used 2011 to 2016 CMS data on Medicare Advantage plan
    enrollment, premiums, and characteristics. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶¶ 152–53. The CMS data
    thus reflects the choices made by millions of seniors—including age-ins, those who chose Original
    Medicare options, and those who chose Medicare Advantage. Tr. 1603:6–21, 1604:9–15 (Nevo).
    Like other economists who have studied demand for Medicare Advantage products, Nevo used a
    “nested logit model.” See PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 150. Nested logit models are appropriate
    “where some consumers may prefer a group, or ‘nest,’ of choices to the other choices” available
    to them. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 148. Applied here, the nested logit model can be used to test
    whether, and to what degree, a senior might prefer “a Medicare Advantage plan because it is a
    Medicare Advantage plan.” PX0051 (Nevo Report) ¶¶ 147, 148.
    The model incorporates a “nesting parameter” that reflects the presence and strength of any
    such preference. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶¶ 148, 149. The nesting parameter can vary from zero
    to one, although any positive nesting parameter indicates that some seniors “have a distinct
    preference for [Medicare Advantage] plans as a group.” Tr. 1602:4–9 (Nevo). Nevo’s nested logit
    model yielded a nesting parameter of .65, indicating that many seniors do have a distinct preference
    for Medicare Advantage compared to other coverage options. Tr. 1602:4–9, 1602:25–1603:5
    (Nevo). Nevo’s work is in line with the academic literature, which has consistently estimated
    positive nesting parameters when studying demand for Medicare Advantage. See PX0551 (Nevo
    Report) ¶ 150 & Ex. 9 (reporting that earlier studies’ “preferred nesting parameter estimate[s]”
    ranged between 0.32 and 0.84, “with all but one being greater than 0.50”).
    44
    The size of the nesting parameter has implications when examining measures of consumer
    substitution. The nesting parameter can be used to calculate an “aggregate diversion ratio” for a
    particular product, which applied here, “represents the share of seniors who would respond to a
    price increase on their current Medicare Advantage plan by choosing another Medicare Advantage
    plan.” PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 164. The higher the nesting parameter, the higher the aggregate
    diversion ratio; and the higher the aggregate diversion ratio, “the more closely Medicare
    Advantage plans compete with each other rather than with other coverage options.” PX0551
    (Nevo Report) ¶ 165. Using his nesting parameter of .65, Nevo calculated an aggregate diversion
    ratio of 70%—that is, 70% of seniors leaving a Medicare Advantage plan in response to a price
    increase would switch to a different Medicare Advantage plan. Tr. 1605:1–3 (Nevo). As a check
    on his analysis, Nevo compared his aggregate diversion ratio to the switching data summarized
    above. Because that data generally shows that more than 80% of seniors leaving one Medicare
    Advantage plan switch to another, Nevo believes that his estimated aggregate diversion ratio is
    actually conservative. Tr. 1604:16–16:05:12 (Nevo); PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 57 & Ex. 7.
    Armed with his demand estimates, Nevo turned to the hypothetical monopolist test. In
    deciding whether to impose a price increase, the hypothetical monopolist is trying to balance two
    effects. On the one hand, the price increase will likely drive away some consumers, thereby
    costing the monopolist a number of sales and the associated profit; but on the other hand, the
    monopolist will make higher profits on sales it retains, so that whether the price increase would be
    profitable depends on the relative sizes of those effects. Tr. 1608:24– 1609:6 (Nevo). To simulate
    those effects, an economist needs measures relating to the number of customers who would leave
    the hypothetical monopolist’s product in response to the price increase (elasticities), the number
    who would remain within the market rather than leave it (the aggregate diversion ratio), and the
    45
    profit associated with each sale (margins). See PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 177; see also Tr.
    1611:15–21 (Nevo). Nevo’s elasticities were derived from his nested logit model. His margins
    were computed using those elasticities and what Nevo has described as a “standard model of
    competition.” See PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 177; Tr. 1611:22–1612:1 (Nevo).
    Nevo ran two versions of the hypothetical monopolist test. The first asked whether a
    hypothetical monopolist of all the Medicare Advantage plans in a particular county could increase
    profits by imposing a SSNIP on at least one Aetna or Humana plan. Tr. 1611:2–4 (Nevo); see also
    Guidelines § 4.1.3 (describing this inquiry as a “[c]ritical loss analysis”). Using his demand
    estimates, Nevo concluded that the hypothetical monopolist could impose a SSNIP of five or ten
    percent on at least one Aetna or Humana Medicare Advantage plan in all 364 complaint counties.
    Tr. 1612:6–15 (Nevo); see also PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 178 & Ex. 12. Nevo’s second version of
    the hypothetical monopolist test was based on a “merger simulation.” Tr. 1615:9–15 (Nevo).
    There, instead of raising prices only on one plan, the hypothetical monopolist is permitted to
    simultaneously raise prices on all of the Medicare Advantage plans being offered in a particular
    county. The test then asks whether the monopolist, empowered to set a profit-maximizing price
    for every Medicare Advantage plan, would increase the price of at least one plan by a SSNIP. Tr.
    1614:21–1615:8 (Nevo); see also PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 181.                         Again, using his demand
    estimates, Nevo concluded that the candidate market passed the hypothetical monopolist test. In
    all 364 complaint counties, the hypothetical monopolist would impose a SSNIP on at least one
    Aetna or Humana plan. Tr. 1618:5–8 (Nevo); see also PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 187 & Ex. 14.
    Under his tests, Nevo concluded that individual Medicare Advantage plans constitute a relevant
    product market. 14 Tr. 1619:8–9 (Nevo).
    14
    Before embarking on his economic analysis, Nevo reviewed much of the relevant evidence in this case,
    including the parties’ ordinary course of business documents and the switching data. It is not necessary to summarize
    46
    Aetna and Humana, relying largely on their economist, Jonathan Orszag, attempt to
    undermine Nevo’s analysis in various ways. They first lodge technical criticisms of Nevo’s
    econometric methods. Like Nevo, Orszag used a nested logit model to assess demand for Medicare
    Advantage products. And like Nevo’s, Orszag’s model predicted positive nesting parameters. But
    his nesting parameters were lower than Nevo’s, ranging from .23 to .35. Tr. 3145:16–19 (Orszag);
    DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 94. The comparatively lower nesting parameters, in turn, translate into
    comparatively lower aggregate diversion ratios. Whereas Nevo found that, in response to a price
    increase in Medicare Advantage, the aggregate diversion to other Medicare Advantage plans
    would be 70%, Orszag estimates it at only 49%. Tr. 3142:2–6 (Orszag). He attributes these
    differences primarily to differences between the models’ instrumental variables, an econometric
    tool used to disentangle correlation from causation. Tr. 3157:8–11 (Orszag). Digging into the
    models yet further, Orszag offered a number of reasons why, in his view, Nevo’s method for
    constructing instrumental variables lacked “a good intuition” and thus distorted his results. Tr.
    3165:13–14 (Orszag); see generally Tr. 3157:8–3167:11 (Orszag).
    Orszag also opines that certain of the inputs and assumptions undergirding Nevo’s analysis
    are inconsistent with how the market operates in practice. In particular, Orszag criticizes Nevo for
    basing his calculations on an average economic margin of 24%, even though medical-loss
    regulations require MAOs to spend 85% of the revenue associated with a particular contract on
    medical care (thus leaving a maximum of 15% for administrative costs and profit). 15 Tr. 3177:5–
    Nevo’s conclusions regarding that evidence. It will suffice to note that Nevo believes that evidence also points to the
    existence of a market for individual Medicare Advantage plans. See Tr. 1618:13–1619:9 (Nevo).
    15
    The parties agree that “margin” is a somewhat fraught concept, which can vary depending on the context.
    As explained by several witnesses, there are important differences between economic margins, underwriting margins,
    and profit margins, so one must be careful about drawing quick comparisons between “margin” figures. Aware of
    that danger here, Orszag has not simply compared Nevo’s “economic margin” estimates to the “margin” cap in the
    medical loss regulations and decided that Nevo’s margins are too high. Instead, he has constructed an argument that
    the medical loss regulations imply a cap on economic margins of 15%. See Tr. 3186:2–16 (Orszag).
    47
    17 (Orszag).       Orszag further faults Nevo for assuming in his merger simulation that the
    hypothetical monopolist would set prices at the county-level, despite the fact that Medicare
    Advantage organizations typically set a plan-level price that applies in all the various counties
    where the plan is offered. See Tr. 3168:11–3169:20 (Orszag); see also Tr. 1723:9–16 (Nevo)
    (acknowledging that Medicare Advantage organizations “offer plans at a service area level”).
    When these flaws are assessed together, Orszag contends, the whole of Nevo’s economic
    analysis is fatally undermined: both versions of his hypothetical monopolist test—critical loss
    analysis and merger simulation—rely on erroneously high diversion ratios and margins which,
    once incorporated, bias his results toward the adoption of a Medicare Advantage only market. The
    version using the merger simulation is doubly flawed, Orszag believes, because it also incorporates
    unrealistic assumptions about the manner in which MAOs set plan prices. Tr. 3186:17–3187:13
    (Orszag). Aetna and Humana therefore assert that Nevo’s conclusions regarding market definition
    are faulty and they urge the Court to disregard them.
    In his rebuttal testimony, Nevo has offered defenses of his instrumental variables, his
    margin figures, and the assumptions in his merger simulation. Fortunately, however, the Court
    does not need to referee to resolution this econometric battle of the experts. By performing much
    of his analysis using Orszag’s estimates, in addition to his own, Nevo has largely insulated his
    work from defendants’ critiques. 16 Specifically, Nevo performed his first hypothetical monopolist
    test, the critical loss analysis, using estimates derived from eight different specifications of
    Orszag’s demand model. Tr. 3503:3–9 (Nevo); see also PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 38. These
    estimates included Orszag’s elasticities, the margins implied from those elasticities, and diversion
    16
    Nevo also performed his critical loss analysis using estimates derived from the academic paper that found
    the lowest nesting parameter. The Medicare Advantage product market also passed these iterations of the hypothetical
    monopolist test. See PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 180 & n.251.
    48
    ratios derived from Orszag’s nesting parameters. See Tr. 3598:19–3599:3 (Nevo); see also
    PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) Note to Ex. 2. No matter which set of estimates Nevo used, and no
    matter whether he imposed a SSNIP of 5% or 10%, the candidate market—Medicare Advantage—
    passed the hypothetical monopolist test for the majority—and usually for the overwhelming
    majority—of the complaint counties. See PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 39 & Ex. 2. That was
    true even for those iterations of the test where Nevo used economic margin figures below the 15%
    ceiling that Orszag believes is implied by regulation. Tr. 3509:11–24 (Nevo).
    Nevo likewise performed his second hypothetical monopolist test, which relies on his
    merger simulation, using estimates derived from the eight specifications of Orszag’s model. Once
    again, the Medicare Advantage only market passed the hypothetical monopolist test in the
    overwhelming majority of the complaint counties. Tr. 3503:16–20 (Nevo); PX0552 (Nevo Reply
    Report) ¶¶ 40–41 & Ex. 3. Thus, it seems that Nevo’s analysis is largely unaffected by defendants’
    technical critiques. The companies have not really attempted to argue otherwise, either in their
    proposed findings and conclusions or during their closing arguments. See Defs.’ Proposed
    Findings & Conclusions at 120–21; Tr. 3762:8–3763:7 (post-trial argument). As a result, the Court
    is comfortable moving past these criticisms and focusing instead on defendants’ other arguments. 17
    Again relying on Orszag, Aetna and Humana next argue that Nevo has misapplied the
    Horizontal Merger Guidelines when performing his hypothetical monopolist test. The crux of
    Orszag’s argument is that, in response to a price increase on a particular Medicare Advantage plan,
    there are likely to be Original Medicare options that enjoy greater diversion than the plan’s most
    17
    It is true that, when Nevo uses Orszag’s estimates, a small number of complaint counties do not pass the
    hypothetical monopolist test with a Medicare Advantage market. If these iterations of Nevo’s tests were the only
    market definition evidence in the record, the Court might conclude that the government had not proven a valid market
    with respect to those counties. But these iterations of the test are not the only evidence in the record. The ordinary
    course of business documents and Brown Shoe factors point strongly to the existence of a Medicare Advantage market.
    So do Nevo’s preferred iterations of the hypothetical monopolist test, which are all the more persuasive given that
    their results are generally unchanged by the use of Orszag’s estimates.
    49
    distant Medicare Advantage substitute. Applying what he calls the “circle principle,” which he
    derives from “Example 6” of the Guidelines, Orszag argues that any such Original Medicare
    options must be included in the product market. By ignoring the circle principle, defendants assert,
    Nevo has defined an overly narrow and conceptually flawed product market.
    To assess this argument, the Court turns first to the language of the Guidelines:
    Groups of products may satisfy the hypothetical monopolist test
    without including the full range of substitutes from which customers
    choose. The hypothetical monopolist test may [therefore] identify a
    group of products as a relevant market even if customers would
    substitute significantly to products outside that group in response to
    a price increase.
    Guidelines § 4.1.1. In Example 5, the Guidelines provide an illustration of that principle. There,
    they posit a candidate market containing two products, A and B. In response to a price increase
    on either, two-thirds of the lost sales are diverted to products outside the market. Nonetheless,
    based on the margin assumptions included in the example, “economic analysis shows that a
    hypothetical profit-maximizing monopolist controlling Products A and B would raise both of their
    prices by ten percent.” 
    Id. Under these
    circumstances, the Guidelines conclude, a market of
    Products A and B satisfies the hypothetical monopolist test, even though “customers would
    substitute significantly to products outside that group in response to a price increase.” 
    Id. Broadly speaking,
    Example 5 is helpful for the government, since it means that a Medicare
    Advantage only market may satisfy the hypothetical monopolist test despite fairly significant
    diversion to Original Medicare options. But the Guidelines continue with language on which
    defendants rely:
    When applying the hypothetical monopolist test to define a market
    around a product offered by one of the merging firms, if the market
    includes a second product, the Agencies will normally also include
    a third product if that third product is a closer substitute for the first
    product than is the second product. The third product is a closer
    50
    substitute if, in response to a SSNIP on the first product, greater
    revenues are diverted to the third product than to the second product.
    
    Id. This “circle
    principle” is then illustrated in Example 6:
    Example 6: In Example 5, suppose that half of the unit sales lost by
    Product A when it raises its price are diverted to Product C, which
    [like Products A and B] also has a price of $100, while one-third are
    diverted to Product B. Product C is a closer substitute for Product
    A than is Product B. Thus Product C will normally be included in
    the relevant market, even though Products A and B together satisfy
    the hypothetical monopolist test.
    Defendants have made two attempts to identify an Original Medicare “Product C” that
    must intrude into the proposed Medicare Advantage only market. Both are grounded upon an
    analysis of diversion ratios. First, Orszag treated Aetna’s or Humana’s Medicare Advantage
    products as Product A and all Original Medicare options—that is, all the possible combinations of
    Original Medicare plus the various MedSupp and prescription drug plans—as Product C. Using
    the estimates from his own demand model, and applying the “circle principle,” he concluded that
    all Original Medicare options must be included in the market. See Tr. 3068:11–3069:10 (Orszag).
    If all Aetna Medicare Advantage plans are Product A, there is 23% diversion to Humana plans,
    49% diversion to all Medicare Advantage plans (including Humana’s), and 51% diversion to
    Original Medicare options. DX0418 (Orszag Reply Report) ¶ 53 & Table II-4. And if all Humana
    Medicare Advantage plans are Product A, there is 16% diversion to Aetna plans, 44% diversion to
    all Medicare Advantage plans (including Aetna’s), and 56% diversion to Original Medicare
    options. DX0418 (Orszag Reply Report) ¶ 53 & Table II-4. Original Medicare options, then, must
    be included in the market—even if one uses all other Medicare Advantage products as the
    operative Product B. Tr. 3068:11–18, 3069:7–10 (Orszag).
    The Court finds this application of the “circle principle” unpersuasive. In effect, Orszag
    has taken all the sales escaping the government’s proposed market, relabeled them as “Product C,”
    51
    and then asserted that, under that new moniker, they must be included in the product market. But
    as Example 5 makes clear, a market may satisfy the hypothetical monopolist test, and thus be
    considered as a proper antitrust product market, “even if customers would substitute significantly
    to products outside that group in response to a price increase.” Guidelines § 4.1.1. Endorsing
    Orszag’s first application of Example 6 would create an exception that completely swallows that
    rule. 18 In Example 5, two-thirds of diversion escapes the market. Here, even using Orszag’s lower
    diversion ratios, only slightly more than half does. That diversion fits squarely within Example 5,
    and Orszag’s first purported application of the “circle principle” will be rejected.
    So too will Orszag’s second proposed application, although for different reasons. Rather
    than treating all Original Medicare options collectively as one Product C, Orszag’s second
    application posits that each possible combination of Original Medicare, MedSupp, and Part D
    plans might constitute its own product. Neither Orszag nor Nevo calculated diversion ratios
    between every Medicare Advantage plan and every conceivable individual Original Medicare
    option. 19 Tr. 3070:7–13 (Orszag); Tr. 3567:5–20 (Nevo). But Orszag thinks it likely that some
    individual Original Medicare “Product Cs” are closer substitutes for some Medicare Advantage
    plans than their most distant Medicare Advantage competitors. His reasoning is as follows.
    Enrollment data reveals that there is basically no diversion between some sets of Medicare
    Advantage plans. The data also reveals that diversion from Aetna or Humana Medicare Advantage
    plans to Original Medicare as a whole is substantial—slightly more than 50% using Orszag’s
    estimates. He reasons that “by definition,” then, there must be some Original Medicare “products”
    that enjoy more diversion from Aetna and Humana Medicare Advantage plans than their most
    18
    It would also require (somewhat counter-intuitively) grouping together as one product all the possible
    combinations of Original Medicare, MedSupp, and Part D plans.
    19
    There is some indication in the record that, given the compressed schedule in this case (adopted largely at
    the companies’ request), CMS could not timely provide the data necessary to perform those calculations.
    52
    distant Medicare Advantage substitutes. Pursuant to the circle principle, Orszag concludes, any
    such products must be included in the market. Tr. 3070:25–3072:24 (Orszag).
    The problem with this more nuanced argument, however, is that it is almost entirely
    speculative. Orszag has not identified an Original Medicare product of the kind that he describes
    above, although Nevo has not proved that one does not exist. Defendants imply, but stop short of
    explicitly arguing, that this gap in the factual record should fall on the government as the party
    with the ultimate burden. When asked at closing arguments whether, in order to prove its candidate
    market was a valid product market, the government needed to “calculate a diversion ratio for every
    product that has a potential to be in the market,” counsel for defendants was somewhat non-
    committal. See Tr. 3764:1–11 (post-trial argument). Regardless, defendants plainly believe that
    the lack of a complete set of diversion ratios undermines the government’s ability to carry its
    burden on market definition.
    The Court disagrees. If taken to its logical conclusion, defendants’ position implies a
    purely econometric approach to market definition, requiring the government to calculate individual
    diversion ratios for all the products potentially in the market, rank them from highest to lowest,
    and, at some point, draw a line between those products that fall within the market and those
    products that fall outside. But that technical approach is not taken by the cases. Econometric
    evidence can be powerful evidence, but it is not the only evidence that courts consider in defining
    the relevant market. Indeed, the cases relied upon by both parties here have considered the Brown
    Shoe factors and ordinary course of business documents, in addition to econometric evidence,
    before reaching conclusions about the proper market definition. In this case, the government has
    marshalled a wide array of qualitative evidence. Most of it points to the existence of a Medicare
    Advantage only market. And none of it suggests frequent, close competition between Medicare
    53
    Advantage plans and particular Original Medicare “Product Cs.” That evidence cannot now be
    disregarded, simply because the government has not undertaken a particular bit of economic
    analysis. The qualitative evidence in this case is still persuasive—and largely supports the
    conclusion that the relevant product market is Medicare Advantage plans alone.
    Nor does the possible existence of a specific Original Medicare “Product C” require the
    Court to disregard the government’s econometric evidence. The Guidelines make clear that the
    hypothetical monopolist test does not aim to identify a “single relevant market.” See Guidelines
    § 4.1.1. Rather, the test “ensures that markets are not defined too narrowly” and, in so doing,
    identifies a market that will “illuminate the evaluation of competitive effects.” 
    Id. Within these
    parameters, the government “may evaluate a merger in any relevant market satisfying the
    [hypothetical monopolist] test,” and will “usually do so in the smallest” market that qualifies. Id.;
    see also Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 26 (adopting this “narrowest market” principle) (citing Arch
    
    Coal, 329 F. Supp. 2d at 120
    ); see also H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 59 (same).
    The government has operated within those parameters here. Based on the qualitative
    evidence, it has (properly, in the Court’s view) identified individual Medicare Advantage plans as
    a candidate product market in which to evaluate the merger’s competitive effects. Through
    multiple applications of the hypothetical monopolist test, the government’s expert determined that
    a hypothetical monopolist in that market could impose a SSNIP on at least one plan sold by Aetna
    or Humana. Admittedly, those tests would be even more persuasive if they conclusively foreclosed
    the existence of an Original Medicare “Product C.” But that does not mean that they are of no
    persuasive value. Like the rest of the government’s evidence, the hypothetical monopolist tests
    tend to establish the existence of a market for the sale of individual Medicare Advantage plans
    alone. The Court will not disregard that evidence, and risk broadening the market in violation of
    54
    the narrowest market principle, simply because one of the Guidelines’ examples says that a
    hypothetical Product C, if it exists at all, should “normally” be included. That is especially true
    here, where there is no showing whatsoever that such a Product C exists. Even if there are a limited
    number of as yet unidentified Product Cs that might be included in the market, moreover,
    defendants have not explained why that should suffice to bring in all Original Medicare options.
    Defendants’ final economic argument is based on quantitative analysis by Orszag, rather
    than on a critique of Nevo. Orszag’s economic analysis focused on the relationship between
    competition and prices in Medicare Advantage. To study that relationship, he used a regression
    that employed various measures of concentration and plan price. See DX0419 (Orszag Report)
    ¶ 108. Orszag’s regression identified no statistically significant relationship between the two. 20
    DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 108 & Table II-6. He believes that this analysis answers the same
    question as the various hypothetical monopolist tests run by Nevo. When real-world MAOs face
    decreases in competition, defendants contend, they do not increase prices. Therefore, Nevo’s
    abstract models notwithstanding, the government’s proposed market “does not pass the
    hypothetical monopolist test when you use a real-world test.” Tr. 3062:20–23 (Orszag).
    But defendants cannot so easily lay claim to the “real world.” To assess the relationship
    between Medicare Advantage competition and prices, Orszag himself used a model—and that
    model is not impervious to econometric critique. One persuasive criticism has been levied by
    Nevo. 21 Using what he calls “plan fixed effects,” Orszag’s model focuses exclusively on the
    changes to the prices of particular plans over time. Tr. 3191:3–8 (Orszag). The problem with that
    20
    Orszag also finds no correlation between concentration and MAO margins. Although the companies refer
    to this conclusion several times in multiple sections of their brief, they have not persuasively explained its relevance.
    In the Court’s view, the important part of Orszag’s analysis concerns the relationship between concentration and price.
    21
    The government also argues that Orszag’s regression is not a proper hypothetical monopolist test because
    it incorporates “supply side” factors like the effects of entry and the existence of regulation. Because the Court finds
    the government’s econometric critique to be persuasive, it need not address this argument.
    55
    approach, according to Nevo, is that it misses an important competitive dynamic: Medicare
    Advantage organizations sometimes introduce new plans or segment existing ones in response to
    competition, rather than adjusting price. Tr. 3513:5–23 (Nevo). The government has cited a
    number of documents where defendants contemplate segmenting plans in order to “target one or
    more counties” for a “different premium/cost-share” than the other counties currently covered by
    the plan. See PX0379-689 (Aetna “Bid Segmentation Concept Brief”); PX0035-808 (Humana
    document recommending segmenting a plan “to increase premium where competition allows”).
    When Nevo removes the “plan fixed effects” in order to account for that dynamic, he finds
    a statistically significant relationship between Medicare Advantage premiums and concentration
    in a particular county; as concentration increases, so do average premiums. PX0552 (Nevo Reply
    Report) ¶ 68 & Ex. 9; see also Tr. 3512:13–3513:9 (Nevo) (explaining his adjustments to Orszag’s
    model). In that respect, Nevo’s adjusted regression is consistent with the academic literature,
    which has generally concluded that decreased competition decreases the extent to which Medicare
    Advantage organizations pass benchmark increases through to beneficiaries as lower costs or
    better benefits. Tr. 129:14–130:18 (Frank); see also PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶¶ 58–63 (citing
    studies); PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 64 (same). The companies have presented the Orszag
    regression as powerful evidence regarding the incentives of the hypothetical monopolist that fully
    rebut the results of Nevo’s hypothetical monopolist tests. But in light of Nevo’s critique and the
    academic literature, the Court concludes that Orszag’s regression cannot bear that weight. On
    balance, then, the expert case too tilts clearly toward the government.
    5. Summary
    Considering the evidence collectively, the Court concludes that the government has
    established the existence of a product market including the sale of individual Medicare Advantage
    56
    plans but excluding Original Medicare options. Original Medicare and Medicare Advantage are
    functionally interchangeable as ways for a senior to receive basic health benefits. And, in some
    sense, Medicare Advantage plans compete with Original Medicare. As a prerequisite to offering
    a plan, an MAO must sufficiently differentiate it from Original Medicare.
    But most MAOs do that successfully, and create products different from Original Medicare
    in a number of important respects: they have a limited network, cap out-of-pocket spending,
    coordinate care, and generally offer supplemental benefits like prescription drug coverage. These
    differences limit the extent to which one is reasonably interchangeable with the other, although
    seniors can make Medicare Advantage and Original Medicare into closer substitutes by purchasing
    a MedSupp or prescription drug plan. In many cases, these options will be offered to the senior
    by the same vendor at the same time.
    That does not necessarily mean, however, that they all belong in the same product market.
    The evidence tends to show the opposite. The Brown Shoe factors generally point toward the
    existence of a Medicare Advantage market. And the ordinary course of business documents make
    plain that, rather than focusing their efforts on competition with Original Medicare, Aetna and
    Humana focus on competition with other Medicare Advantage organizations. To do so, they
    compile impressive amounts of local, plan-specific competitive intelligence about Medicare
    Advantage offerings in markets across the country. MedSupp plans rarely, if ever, figure into that
    assessment. Aetna’s and Humana’s focus on competition within Medicare Advantage, along with
    seniors’ observed strong tendency to switch from one Medicare Advantage plan to another when
    faced with a plan cancellation or price increase, make it unlikely that competition from Original
    Medicare options will suffice to discipline Medicare Advantage pricing.
    57
    The econometric analysis supports the same conclusion. Although the Court does not (and
    does not need to) adopt his analysis in every detail, Professor Nevo has performed a battery of
    tests that all point to the same conclusion: the sale of individual Medicare Advantage plans satisfies
    the hypothetical monopolist test and thus is a relevant product market. That result generally holds
    up whether Nevo uses a critical loss analysis or a merger simulation, and whether he uses his own
    estimates, Orzsag’s, or those from the academic literature.
    Ultimately, Aetna’s and Humana’s litigation position implies that competition between
    Medicare Advantage organizations is not needed to discipline Medicare Advantage plan prices or
    quality. Even in the 70 counties where the merged firm would be the only Medicare Advantage
    organization post-merger, the companies believe there is no competition problem. But the
    evidence in this case suggests otherwise. Based on careful consideration of all that evidence, the
    Court concludes that the proper markets for evaluating the merger are those for individual
    Medicare Advantage plans in the 364 complaint counties.
    B. Competitive Effects
    To establish its prima facie case, the government next attempts to show that the merger
    would “lead to undue concentration in the market” for individual Medicare Advantage plans in all
    364 complaint counties. See Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 982
    . Market concentration, which “is a
    function of the number of firms in a market and their respective market shares,” is often measured
    using the Herfindahl–Hirschmann Index, or HHI. See Arch 
    Coal, 329 F. Supp. 2d at 123
    –24. The
    HHI “is calculated by summing the squares of the individual firms’ market shares, and thus gives
    proportionately greater weight to the larger market shares.” Guidelines § 5.3. “Sufficiently large
    HHI figures establish the [government’s] prima facie case that a merger is anti-competitive.”
    
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 716
    . Under the Guidelines, a market is “highly concentrated” if it has an HHI
    58
    over 2,500. Guidelines § 5.3. If a merger would produce a highly concentrated market and
    “involve an increase in the HHI of more than 200 points,” then it “will be presumed to be likely to
    enhance market power.” 
    Id. Courts have
    adopted these thresholds in determining whether a
    merger is presumptively unlawful. See 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 716
    (applying a prior version of the
    Guidelines); FTC v. Staples, Inc., Civ. Action No. 15-2115 (EGS), 
    2016 WL 2899222
    , at *18
    (D.D.C. May 17, 2016) (Staples II) (applying the current version of the Guidelines); Sysco, 113 F.
    Supp. 3d at 52–53 (same).
    There is no suspense about the outcome of this HHI analysis here: the Aetna-Humana
    merger easily surpasses the Guidelines’ concentration thresholds in all 364 of the complaint
    counties. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 196; Tr. 1622:17–20 (Nevo). Indeed, in more than 75% of the
    counties, the post-merger HHI would be greater than 5,000, and in more than 70% of the counties,
    the merger would cause an HHI increase of more than 1,000 points. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 196.
    And in 70 counties where Aetna and Humana are the only MAOs currently in the market, the post-
    merger HHI would reflect a merger to monopoly. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 195; Tr. 1622:21–
    1623:2 (Nevo). Based on these compelling concentration figures, the government has established
    its prima facie case. Defendants do not attempt to argue otherwise. Tr. 3774:21–3775:4 (closing
    argument). Thus, the government is entitled to a presumption that the merger would substantially
    lessen competition in the sale of individual Medicare Advantage plans in all 364 complaint
    counties.
    The government, however, has not rested on that presumption. Instead, it has introduced
    evidence tending to show that the merger would substantially lessen competition. “Mergers that
    eliminate head-to-head competition between close competitors often result in a lessening of
    competition.” Staples II, 
    2016 WL 2899222
    , at *20; see also Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 61 (same)
    59
    (collecting cases); Guidelines § 6 (“The elimination of competition between two firms that results
    from their merger may alone constitute a substantial lessening of competition.”). That can be true
    even where the merging parties are not the only, or the two largest, competitors in the market. See
    Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 62 (citing 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 717
    –19; H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at
    83–84). Mergers between close competitors might have unilateral anticompetitive effects if “the
    acquiring firm will have the incentive to raise prices or reduce quality after the acquisition,
    independent of competitive responses from other firms.” H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 81.
    Anticompetitive effects are more likely still when “the merger would result in the elimination of a
    particularly aggressive competitor in a highly concentrated market.” 
    Staples, 970 F. Supp. at 1083
    .
    Aetna is just such a “particularly aggressive” Medicare Advantage competitor. Following
    its acquisition of Coventry in 2013, Aetna became the fourth largest Medicare Advantage insurer
    in the country. DX0290-113. And in the intervening years it has continued to aggressively expand
    its Medicare Advantage footprint, targeting many new counties for expansion each year. Tr.
    1330:2–19 (Bertolini). Between 2013 and 2016, Aetna expanded into 640 new counties—more
    than twice as many as the next most prolific entrant. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 218 & Ex. 18.
    When Aetna enters a new market, it generally does so with a focus on building a high value
    provider network and offering zero-premium plans. PX0036-427 (Aetna 2016 “Medicare Deep
    Dive Overview” noting a commitment to “[g]rowing [high value networks] to help sustain $0
    premiums”); see also Tr. 346:6–347:3 (Cocozza). Aetna considers its zero-premium plans as “a
    cornerstone in most markets to drive growth.” PX0046-324; see also Tr. 354:21–355:2 (Cocozza)
    (over 50% of Aetna enrollees are in zero-premium plans); Tr. 347:4–25 (Cocozza) (Aetna’s zero-
    premium PPO, since being introduced in 2014, has contributed to market-share growth in a number
    of local markets). Even without the Humana merger, Aetna intends to continue expanding its
    60
    geographic footprint and maintain its focus on building value-based networks. PX0036-427
    (Aetna 2016 “Medicare Deep Dive Overview” setting forward-looking targets).
    Aetna’s expansion has put it on a collision course with Humana. In 2011 Aetna and
    Humana competed in Medicare Advantage in just 79 counties, but by 2016, they competed in 675.
    PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶¶ 219–20 & Ex. 19; Tr. 1582:13–15 (Nevo) (Aetna and Humana
    collectively boast more than 59% of the 1.7 million Medicare Advantage enrollees in the complaint
    counties). That growing overlap is not merely geographical. It is also philosophical. At trial,
    Bertolini and Broussard discussed their shared outlook on the future of healthcare. See Tr. 1837:1–
    15 (Broussard) (“[Mark and I] almost finished each other’s sentences.”) Like Aetna, Humana has
    employed a strategy to “build networks around value-based arrangements.” Tr. 327:14–15
    (Cocozza); see also Tr. 2106:13–18 (Follmer) (acknowledging that, in Georgia, Humana has
    “value-based contracts with providers that are more advanced than other Medicare Advantage
    plans”). In a 2015 email, Cocozza touches on both these areas of overlap when assessing the
    nature of the competition between Aetna and Humana: “[Humana] was #1 in growth and is our
    most formidable competitor. We compete with them everywhere and they have momentum. They
    continue to lead in terms of aggressive pursuit of strategic provider relationships and are willing
    to deploy capital in many forms to secure preferred standing and exclusivity.” PX0007-847.
    The parties disagree about whether significant head-to-head competition is reflected in the
    econometric data. According to defendants, the data reveals that the head-to-head competition
    between Aetna and Humana is not special. For support, they rely on two regressions performed
    by Orszag. The first, already discussed above, purports to find no general relationship between
    competition and plan price in Medicare Advantage. Tr. 3087:10–24 (Orszag); DX0419 (Orszag
    Report) ¶¶ 117–18 & Table II-6.       The second, which focuses specifically on head-to-head
    61
    competition between Aetna and Humana, concludes that the presence of one defendant in a county
    has no statistically significant impact on the prices charged by the other. Tr. 3090:1–20 (Orszag);
    DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶¶ 121–24 & Tables II-7 & II-8.
    By focusing solely on changes in the price of a particular plan, however, both these
    regressions are susceptible to the same critique: namely, that they will fail to discern changes to
    competition that result from the introduction of new plans or the segmentation of old ones.
    PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 75. In the Court’s view, that limits the persuasive value of
    Orszag’s regressions. Moreover, when Nevo performs a similar regression focused instead on
    changes in market share, he finds evidence of substantial head-to-head competition between Aetna
    and Humana. Specifically, Nevo concludes that Aetna’s presence in a particular county depresses
    Humana’s market share by 9.4 percentage points—more than twice the effect associated with other
    insurers. PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶¶ 76–77 & Ex. 11; Tr. 3520–3521:3 (Nevo). Switching
    data also reveals close (and increasing) head-to-head competition between Aetna and Humana. In
    2014, Aetna Medicare Advantage products ranked as the ninth most popular option among seniors
    switching from Humana; in 2016, they ranked second. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 222. Thus, even
    if Orszag’s analysis was air-tight, Nevo’s (largely uncontroverted) analysis suggests that there is
    substantial competition between Aetna and Humana.
    Given Nevo’s analysis, it is not surprising to find significant evidence of head-to-head
    competition between Aetna and Humana throughout the country. See, e.g., PX0023-628–29 (2015
    Humana document comparing Aetna, United, and Humana plans in 15 markets where “Humana
    held stable” and United or Aetna was “aggressive”); PX0027-229 (Aetna document calling
    Humana “our primary MA competitor”); PX0397-647 (“Humana will be [Aetna’s] most serious
    threat [in Georgia] in the near future.”); PX0455-601 (“Today, Humana (~50k mbrs.) and Aetna
    62
    (~34k mbrs) dominate the Kansas City Market.”); PX0050-116 (Humana email referring to “[o]ur
    #1 NC Competitor Aetna”). They compete on multiple dimensions of Medicare Advantage plan
    design, including network and cost. For example, in anticipation of the upcoming 2015 annual
    enrollment period, Aetna compared its provider network to Humana’s in Alabama and
    recommended “some network fortification.” PX0394-862; see also PX0013-344. If one company
    fails to keep pace, the competitive consequences can be significant. In Georgia, for instance,
    Humana and United had the misfortune of raising premiums on their PPO plans in the same year
    as Aetna introduced its zero premium PPO. Tr. 2101:2–21 (Follmer). As a result, Aetna enjoyed
    a “bonanza.” PX0393-185.
    This head-to-head competition benefits seniors who shop for Medicare Advantage plans in
    the form of broader networks and lower costs. Two illustrations will suffice. The first relates to
    Aetna’s 2014 introduction of its zero-premium PPO in Raleigh (Wake County), North Carolina.
    At that time, Humana was selling an LPPO, a regional PPO, and an HMO in Wake County. Unlike
    Aetna’s PPO, Humana’s PPOs had premiums of $53 and $81 respectively. Tr. 770:2–4, 773:10–
    16 (Farley). Humana’s HMO had no premium, but that plan was built on a “coordinated care type
    of model,” which provided “less access to various hospitals and doctors.” Tr. 770:7–19 (Farley).
    Duke University Hospital was among those hospitals outside the Humana HMO’s network in
    Wake County. Tr. 773:17–19 (Farley). Aetna’s zero-premium PPO wedged between these various
    Humana offerings by combining a zero-premium price with a broader PPO network encompassing
    all the major hospital systems in Wake County, including Duke. See Tr. 773:20–23 (Farley).
    Upon learning of Aetna’s plan, one impressed Humana marketing employee remarked “Wow. A
    $0 premium on a PPO plan.” PX0024-129.
    63
    By late 2015, Aetna’s PPO was “dominating in [W]ake County.” PX0038-804. Humana’s
    HMO, on the other hand, “[was] not selling.” PX0038-804. Part of Aetna’s success lay in its
    ability to exploit the Humana HMO’s limited provider network. PX0295-285; Tr. 779:2–15
    (Farley). An Aetna employee in Wake County even emailed all the brokers in the area to say that
    Humana would not be continuing its affiliation with Duke in the coming year, predicting that the
    change would “help you boost all of your sales with the Aetna Product.” PX0050-119. Although
    the email was not accurate (Duke still accepted Humana’s PPO products), it is indicative of the
    competition between the companies. In response to the pressure from Aetna, Humana began
    actively recruiting new providers in order to expand its HMO network. PX0352-884; Tr. 819:5–
    20 (Farley).
    Another example comes from San Antonio, where Aetna and Humana offer competing
    HMO plans. For its 2016 bid, Aetna decided to improve the value proposition on its San Antonio
    HMO in order to “compete with United and Humana HMOs.” PX0039-711. In the ensuing annual
    enrollment period, broker Raul Gonzalez moved a number of his clients out of Humana’s HMO
    and into Aetna’s. Tr. 1040:11–20 (Gonzalez). He said that, “[f]or a lot of people, it was an easy
    transition”: while both plans had similar networks, the Aetna plan had a specialty co-pay that was
    $15 dollars lower. Tr. 1040:23–1042:2 (Gonzalez). For the following year, Humana dropped its
    specialty copay by $15 to match Aetna’s. Tr. 1042:3–9 (Gonzalez). 22
    Together, this evidence suggests that there is significant head-to-head competition between
    Aetna and Humana, that it drives improvements to plan cost and quality, and that—if the merger
    were consummated—that competition would be lost, with some resulting deterioration in the
    22
    Aetna and Humana note that they each compete with a number of other Medicare Advantage organizations
    in Raleigh and San Antonio, not only with one another. True enough. But that does not change the fact that these
    markets would be highly concentrated post-merger, nor does it directly rebut the government’s evidence that direct
    competition between them has previously driven plan improvements.
    64
    Medicare Advantage products offered. To predict the likely competitive effects of the proposed
    merger in a more quantitative manner, the government relies on a second merger simulation by
    Nevo. This merger simulation assumes that all Aetna and Humana Medicare Advantage plans are
    owned by one firm, which will set prices on each “in order to maximize total profits across all their
    plans within each county.” PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶¶ 208–09. The merged firm’s pricing
    behavior depends in part on seniors’ demand for various Medicare Advantage plans and Original
    Medicare options (modeled using the elasticities and aggregate diversion ratios derived from
    Nevo’s nested logit model). PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶¶ 207–08. Pricing behavior also depends on
    inputs regarding plan cost and profit margin. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 208. When Nevo performs
    his merger simulation using his own estimates, he predicts substantial annual competitive harm as
    a result of the merger: premiums in the complaint counties would increase by 60%, seniors would
    pay $360 million more in rebate-adjusted premiums, and taxpayers would pay an additional $140
    million in the form of higher payments from CMS to insurers. Tr. 1630:3–8, 1631:16–21 (Nevo).
    In sum, Nevo’s preferred version of the merger simulation predicts $500 million per year in
    combined anticompetitive harm to seniors and taxpayers. 23 Tr. 1631:21–1632:1 (Nevo).
    Aetna and Humana again object to Nevo’s newest merger simulation. Relying on Orszag,
    the companies argue that Nevo’s model has “debilitating flaws,” because it assumes that Medicare
    Advantage plans are priced at the county level, uses margin figures not consistent with observed
    margins, and predicts premium increases that are unreasonably high.                     See Defs.’ Proposed
    Findings & Conclusions at 51–52; see also 
    id. at 120–21;
    Tr. 3175:5–11 (Orszag). Defending his
    merger simulation on rebuttal, Nevo sounded a somewhat humbler note about its probative value.
    23
    When Nevo performs this merger simulation using estimates derived from Orszag’s nested logit model, he
    likewise predicts premium increases. All eight merger simulations predict premium increases of at least 9%. PX0552
    (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 84 & Ex. 12; Tr. 1630:9–17 (Nevo).
    65
    The merger simulation, he explained, is not meant as an “exact prediction model for pricing” at a
    county-by-county level. Tr. 3517:22 (Nevo). Instead, it aims to assess whether, and to what extent,
    the merged firm would have an incentive to raise prices after the merger. Tr. 3517:24–25 (Nevo).
    When interpreting the results, therefore, the focus should not be on “the exact number[s],” but
    rather on the “direction” of the changes. Tr. 3518:18–20 (Nevo). And here, Nevo concludes, all
    iterations of the merger simulation point toward a price increase following the merger.
    Although the merger simulation is “an imprecise tool,” it “nonetheless has some probative
    value in predicting the likelihood of a potential price increase after the merger.” H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 88; see also Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 67. Based on a comprehensive assessment
    of demand, and in its various iterations that include utilizing Orszag’s demand estimates, Nevo’s
    merger simulation predicts that the merged firm would have the incentive and ability to increase
    quality-adjusted premiums in the complaint counties. The Court considers the merger simulation
    as econometric evidence in support of that limited proposition, in part because its results are
    consistent with the other evidence regarding the likely competitive effects of the proposed merger.
    As reflected by the HHI scores, the merger would create 364 (very) highly concentrated markets,
    including 70 county-level monopolies, and hence must be presumed to substantially lessen
    competition. The merger would also extinguish the competitive fire generated by Aetna’s rapid
    expansion—through value-based networks and aggressively priced plans—into Humana’s
    Medicare Advantage territory. The observed competition between these Big 5 insurers is intense,
    encompasses various dimensions of plan design, and has greatly benefitted seniors. Freed from
    that competition, the merged firm may have an incentive to raise premiums—or, perhaps, to relent
    from lowering them and improving plan quality. The results of Nevo’s merger simulation, then,
    provide additional support for that inference.
    66
    Based on its market concentration figures, the government has established a prima facie
    case and is entitled to a presumption that the Aetna-Humana merger would substantially lessen
    competition in the market for individual Medicare Advantage plans in all 364 complaint counties.
    It is not a stretch to call the government’s prima facie case based on the HHI analysis under the
    Guidelines an overwhelming one, given how high the concentration figures are. The government
    has also introduced additional evidence supporting that presumption that could be used to carry its
    ultimate burden of persuasion, if Aetna and Humana are successful in rebutting the presumption.
    The Court turns next to Aetna’s and Humana’s rebuttal arguments.
    C. Government Regulation
    Aetna’s and Humana’s first attempt to rebut the presumption of anti-competitive effects
    focuses on the role played by CMS, and the federal government more generally, in regulating
    competition in Medicare Advantage. The companies do not contend that this system of federal
    regulation confers implied immunity from the antitrust laws. See Tr. 3725:20–23 (post-trial
    argument). It is unlikely that they could succeed in doing so, because “[i]mplied antitrust
    immunity is not favored, and can be justified only by a convincing showing of clear repugnancy
    between the antitrust laws and the regulatory system.” Nat’l Gerimedical Hosp. & Gerontology
    Ctr. v. Blue Cross of Kanas City, 
    452 U.S. 378
    , 388 (1981) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    There is no indication of such “repugnancy” here.
    Nonetheless, the government’s regulation of Medicare Advantage remains relevant.
    “Antitrust analysis must always be attuned to the particular structure and circumstances of the
    industry at issue.” Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 
    540 U.S. 398
    , 411 (2004); see also Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 321
    –22. “Part of that attention to economic
    context is an awareness of the significance of regulation.” 
    Trinko, 540 U.S. at 411
    . “One factor
    67
    of particular importance is the existence of a regulatory structure designed to deter and remedy
    anticompetitive harm.” 
    Id. at 412.
    Where such a structure exists, the likelihood of anticompetitive
    harm may be “significantly diminish[ed].”        
    Id. (internal quotation
    marks omitted) (quoting
    Concord v. Boston Edison Co., 
    915 F.2d 17
    , 25 (1st Cir. 1990) (Breyer, J.)).
    Aetna and Humana assert that federal regulation of Medicare Advantage leaves “no
    opening for the anticompetitive effects that the Government posits.” Defs.’ Proposed Findings &
    Conclusions at 129. The Court disagrees. Based on the evidence presented, the Court concludes
    that CMS regulation was not “designed to deter and remedy anticompetitive harm.” See 
    Trinko, 540 U.S. at 412
    . And because it is unlikely to do so here, its existence does not suggest that the
    government’s “prima facie case inaccurately predicts the [merger’s] probable effect on future
    competition.” Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 991
    .
    Many of the CMS rules and regulations at issue here are applied through the annual bid
    process. In June, a Medicare Advantage organization must submit a separate “bid” to CMS for
    each plan that they wish to offer in the following year. Tr. 1178:11–17 (Cavanaugh); Tr. 1910:22–
    1911:2 (Paprocki). Putting together a bid is an arduous task. Each bid must include detailed
    estimates of the plan’s revenue requirement, cost structure (including both medical and
    administrative costs), and margin projections, backed up by extensive data and calculations. Tr.
    1910:1–6, 1935:24–1936:2, 1958:8–15 (Paprocki). Every bid must also be certified by an actuary.
    Tr. 1952:21–25 (Paprocki). Each year, CMS produces two lengthy documents—a “call letter,”
    describing the terms of the Medicare Advantage program, and a set of instructions about bid
    submission—that together contain many of the applicable CMS rules and regulations. See
    DX0014 (call letter); DX0349 (bid instructions). Once the bids have been submitted, CMS, in
    collaboration with outside actuaries it retains, reviews the bids to ensure that they comply with all
    68
    these requirements.       Tr. 1178:20–23 (Cavanaugh); Tr. 1959:1–2 (Paprocki).                  That process,
    sometimes called the “desk review,” usually lasts from about mid-June until the end of July. Tr.
    1959:14–17 (Paprocki). Non-compliant bids will not be approved. Tr. 2554:12–14 (Coleman).
    When the desk review uncovers a problem with a bid, CMS will typically reach out to the
    MAO and explain its concerns. Tr. 1143:13–16 (Cavanaugh); Tr. 1991:22–1992:2 (Paprocki).
    Sometimes, the MAO has simply made a mistake, in which case it will correct the bid. 24 Tr.
    1992:24–1993:1 (Paprocki). But on other occasions, CMS and the MAO might disagree about
    whether a bid is compliant and discussion then ensues. The government characterizes that
    discussion as a “negotiation” where the MAO pushes back and, if it makes any changes at all, will
    make them in “baby steps” until CMS relents. See Pls.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions at 90–
    91; see also Tr. 2006:6–2007:12 (Paprocki). Defendants, on the other hand, see an interaction
    where CMS can instruct the MAO to make any changes it deems necessary, because CMS has all
    the leverage.     See Tr. 1991:16–1993:12 (Paprocki).             Whatever the proper characterization,
    however, the outcome is the same: the MAO usually revises the bid until CMS determines it
    complies with all requirements. Tr. 453:12–16 (Cocozza); Tr. 2554:20–22 (Coleman).
    Whether CMS regulation would be likely to ameliorate any competitive harm resulting
    from the merger depends on the particular regulatory tools at CMS’s disposal. In contending that
    these tools would be sufficient, Aetna and Humana ask the Court to consider “a truly ill-intentioned
    MAO” intent on exercising “its [market] power to the greatest extent possible,” but hemmed in on
    every side by CMS regulation.            See Defs.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions at 129–31.
    Significant competitive harm, however, could be caused by a (much) less rapacious firm.
    24
    Even after revising the bid, the MAO could still be the subject of a CMS compliance notice. Tr. 1942:8–
    17 (Paprocki).
    69
    Accordingly, the Court will focus more generally on the extent to which federal regulation would
    prevent the merged firm from increasing premiums or reducing benefits on particular plans.
    Some of the regulatory tools identified by the companies do not really address that issue.
    The companies think it important that the government, “an undeniably sophisticated entity,” can
    influence the amount that Medicare Advantage organizations are paid through its control over the
    benchmark. See 
    id. at 107.
    But the Court does not see how CMS could use the benchmark, which
    CMS merely calculates based on a statutory formula, to resist a change to a particular plan. Tr.
    1137:12–16 (Cavanaugh). Other regulatory tools are similarly unlikely to impose a constraint.
    There would be plenty of room for the merged firm to increase premiums without violating the
    statutory cap on beneficiary out-of-pocket costs, which is currently set at $6,700 per year. CMS’s
    rules about minimum network adequacy, which Aetna and Humana typically exceed, would
    likewise do little to stave off a premium increase. See Tr. 291:8–16 (Cocozza); Tr. 547:8–20
    (Wheatley). And the “meaningful difference rule,” which generally prohibits MAOs from offering
    two plans with substantially similar out-of-pocket costs in the same county, takes no position on
    what those estimated out-of-pocket costs must be. 25 See DX0014-161.
    Some regulatory tools are more closely related to premiums or plan quality, but still are
    not well-suited to preventing unwanted changes at the plan level. Limits on medical loss ratios
    fall into this category. By statute, MAOs must spend at least 85% of the revenue obtained under
    a contract (whether from CMS or from beneficiaries) on medical services, see 42 U.S.C. § 1395w-
    27(e)(4); Tr. 1147:2–6 (Cavanaugh), meaning that only 15% of that revenue may be retained as
    profit or to cover administrative costs. Revenue retained in excess of that amount must be returned
    to beneficiaries. And if an MAO remains out of compliance with the medical loss ratio for three
    25
    The meaningful difference rule does not apply to two plans of different types (for example, an HMO and
    a PPO) or plans offered under different contracts. See Tr. 2009:22–2012:5 (Paprocki).
    70
    consecutive years, it may be barred from enrolling new members. Tr. 1148:6–13 (Cavanaugh).
    All else equal, then, an increase in plan premium or a decrease in benefits may have the effect of
    decreasing a plan’s medical loss ratio—i.e., having it fall below 85%.
    However, these provisions are a poor tool for regulating plan price or quality. First, the
    medical loss ratio requirements are applied at the contract rather than at the plan level. Tr.
    2008:22–24 (Paprocki). Because contracts often cover multiple plans—indeed, sometimes as
    many as 30 or 40—a change to a single plan is likely to have only a highly attenuated impact on
    the medical loss ratio of the contract as a whole. See Tr. 2008:15–19 (Paprocki). Individual plans
    covered by larger contracts may thus have medical loss ratios less than 85%, thereby enabling
    greater profits—and, in fact, some of Aetna’s plans do. Tr. 2009:6–8 (Paprocki). And it is unlikely
    that CMS could use the medical loss ratio regulations to request changes to a particular bid.
    Medical loss ratios are not applied as part of the bid process at all. Instead, they are calculated
    after-the-fact, based on actual revenue and costs. Tr. 1147:10–16 (Cavanaugh). It would be
    largely up to the merged firm, therefore, to forecast whether a premium increase or benefit
    reduction would cause a contract to exceed the medical loss ratio regulations. 26 Hence, the medical
    loss ratio regulations have serious shortcomings as a tool for regulating the design of particular
    plans. And hanging over all of this is an additional layer of uncertainty: because CMS is only now
    preparing to release the first year of medical loss data, the Court and the parties can only speculate
    about how the regulations might operate in practice. Tr. 1148:14–17 (Cavanaugh).
    26
    The companies argue that they would strive to avoid creating plans with medical loss ratios less than 85%.
    To compensate for a plan below 85%, the merged company would need to have another plan in the same contract
    above 85%. That comparatively richer plan could in turn attract a high number of beneficiaries, ultimately costing
    the company money. See DX0014-162; Tr. 2017:15–2018:15 (Paprocki). That might be possible but, in the Court’s
    view, is far too remote to show that the medical loss ratio regulations impose a meaningful constraint on the prices of
    particular plans.
    71
    The CMS margin rules have similar limitations. Most of the margin restrictions are
    “Aggregate-Level Requirements,” meaning that they apply above—and sometimes far above—
    the bid level. DX0349-028. CMS regulations allow MAOs to decide whether to apply the
    aggregate-level margin requirements at the level of the contract, the legal entity, or the parent
    organization. DX0349-028; see also Tr. 2004:16–20 (Paprocki). Aetna chooses to apply them at
    the parent organization level, which incorporates “all of Aetna.” Tr. 2004:16–2005:5 (Paprocki).
    Applied in that way, the aggregate margin rules require that Aetna’s aggregate forecasted bid
    margins align with its actual margins from prior years and are within 1.5% of the margins on its
    overall business. See DX0349-029.
    To be sure, it is likely that an increase in premiums or a reduction in benefits would increase
    the margin forecasted for a particular plan. But that particular plan is just a drop in the ocean. For
    the 2017 plan year, Aetna submitted 239 bids and Humana submitted over 400 more. Tr. 1994:11–
    13 (Paprocki); see Tr. 491:15–16 (Wheatley) (noting Humana has more than 400 Medicare
    Advantage plans). Increased premiums on one plan, or even on several plans, would thus be
    unlikely to have much of an effect on the merged firm’s aggregated margin figures. Indeed, the
    evidence shows that a fairly low aggregate margin target can conceal wide variation (and much
    higher margins) at the regional or bid level. For example, even though Humana targets a margin
    of 4% at the parent organization level, it has submitted individual bids with margins as high as
    20%. Wheatley Apr. 22, 2016 Dep. 138:11–23, admitted at Tr. 579:25–580:6 (Wheatley); see also
    Tr. 2196:16–22 (Fernandez) (some Humana plans earn margins as high as 12 and 15%); Tr.
    2004:12–15 (Paprocki) (CMS has approved Aetna bids with margins of 13 and 14%). All of this
    makes it very unlikely that CMS could wield the aggregate margin rules in order to force a change
    to the design of a particular plan—even one projecting a relatively high margin.
    72
    The most precise regulatory tool at CMS’s disposal is its rule concerning total beneficiary
    cost. By statute, CMS is empowered to reject a bid “if it proposes significant increases in cost
    sharing or decreases in benefits offered under the plan.” 42 U.S.C. § 1395w-24(a)(5)(C)(ii).
    Pursuant to that authority, CMS limits an MAO’s ability to adjust from one year to the next a
    plan’s total beneficiary cost—a measure reflecting the Medicare Part B premium, the plan
    premium, and an estimate of the beneficiary’s out-of-pocket costs. DX0014-163. Under the most
    recent version of the call letter, bids proposing changes in total beneficiary costs greater than $32
    per member per month will be rejected. 27 DX0014-165.
    Although this rule would constrain somewhat the merged firm’s ability to increase
    premiums dramatically, it would not completely curtail it. Considerable leeway remains. For
    example, an MAO offering a plan with a $10 monthly premium could increase that premium by
    $10 (i.e. by 100%) without triggering the $32 threshold. Tr. 2013:25–2014:7 (Paprocki). In fact,
    because the threshold only measures changes from one year to the next, it would not prevent the
    MAO from imposing the same $10—or an even greater—price increase in subsequent years. Tr.
    1226:22–1227:3 (Cavanaugh); Tr. 2014:15–19 (Paprocki).                    Indeed, the average Medicare
    Advantage plan premium of $40, see PX0553 (Frank Report) ¶ 40, could be increased each year
    by close to 80% without running afoul of the total beneficiary cost rule. As a result, this regulation
    also provides CMS with only very limited influence over plan price and quality.
    At the start of trial, Aetna and Humana warned that the Court would likely hear from a
    “quite humble CMS” intent on downplaying the extent of its regulatory authority. Tr. 83:12–14
    (opening statement). Throughout the trial, however, the companies sought to highlight various
    provisions of CMS guidance that they believe illustrate the true breadth of the agency’s discretion
    27
    There is some indication in the record that CMS may have the discretion to change this threshold. Tr.
    1188:16–18 (Cavanaugh). But as far as the Court is aware, no such change is on the horizon.
    73
    and authority. In the call letter, for example, CMS explains that it “reserves the right to further
    examine and request changes to a plan bid even if a plan’s [total beneficiary cost] is within the
    required amount”—that is, below the $32 per member per month threshold. DX0014-164.
    Likewise, in the bid instructions’ section on margins, CMS warns that bids must “provide benefit
    value in relation to the[ir] margin level[s]” and that “[a]nti-competitive practices will not be
    accepted.” DX0349-027. These broadly worded provisions, defendants contend, give CMS,
    which already enjoys considerable leverage in the bid review process, the tools that it needs to
    fend off price increases or quality reductions at the bid level.
    But there is little historical precedent for CMS exercising such authority. By all accounts,
    CMS rarely questions the margins on specific bids. During the most recent bid cycle, for example,
    Aetna submitted 239 bids; CMS indicated that the margin was too high on three of them. Tr.
    1930:8–19 (Paprocki). At Humana, Wheatley is unsure whether CMS even has that authority at
    all: in a 2014 email, he expressed the view that Humana has “to fight CMS regarding their ability
    to regulate our individual bid margins.” PX0581; see also Tr. 576:24–577:21 (Wheatley). And as
    noted above, CMS has previously approved bids with fairly high margins. Tr. 2004:12–15
    (Paprocki) (CMS has approved Aetna bids with margins of 13 and 14%); Tr. 2196:16–22
    (Fernandez) (some Humana plans earn margins as high as 12 and 15%). Nor, it seems, is there
    precedent for CMS rejecting bids. Cavanaugh was not aware of a bid being rejected during his
    tenure at CMS. Tr. 1143:12–13 (Cavanaugh). Cocozza testified that an Aetna bid has never been
    rejected. Tr. 453:9–10 (Cocozza). In short, the record here suggests that CMS has not exerted
    considerable influence at the bid level before the proposed merger. That makes it very difficult
    for the Court to conclude that it would effectively do so after a merger.
    74
    Having reviewed the various regulatory provisions cited by the companies, and heard
    testimony from a number of CMS officials, the Court perceives little ability in CMS to prevent the
    merged firm from increasing its prices or reducing benefits. As several witnesses have testified,
    CMS regulations serve primarily to set “the boundaries or the contours” for competition between
    Medicare Advantage organizations. Tr. 3039:10–12 (Orszag); see also Tr. 138:10–13 (Frank)
    (CMS regulations define “the outer limits and the contours within which competition has to
    occur”); Tr. 1137:6–7 (Cavanaugh) (CMS creates “the framework that competition will happen
    within”). In that regard, regulation can be used to identify and correct a small number of plans
    that are “outliers.” Tr. 1146:19–20 (Cavanaugh). But competition between Medicare Advantage
    plans remains the motor driving the creation and constant improvement of attractive plans for
    seniors. Indeed, if there is little in the CMS regulations that would prevent an affirmative price
    increase or benefit reduction, there is even less that would prevent a slow erosion of plan quality
    or increase in premiums resulting from lessened competition over time. CMS regulation, then,
    does not “significantly diminish[] the likelihood of major antitrust harm.” 
    Trinko, 540 U.S. at 881
    (internal quotation mark omitted). Based on its significant HHI scores, the Aetna-Humana merger
    must be presumed to substantially lessen competition. The existence of some CMS regulation of
    Medicare Advantage does not rebut that presumption.
    D. Entry
    The companies also claim that entry by new competitors into the 364 complaint counties
    will counteract any anticompetitive effect of the merger. However, based on the applicable law,
    and an assessment of the expert and non-expert evidence for each specific element of the entry
    analysis, ultimately the Court concludes that new entry will not be “timely, likely, and sufficient”
    enough to counteract the anticompetitive effects of the merger.
    75
    1. Applicable Law
    As part of its rebuttal case, a defendant may introduce evidence that entry by new
    competitors will ameliorate the feared anticompetitive effects of a merger. See Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 983
    ; H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 73–77; FTC v. Cardinal Health, 
    12 F. Supp. 2d 34
    ,
    54–58 (D.D.C. 1998); see also United States v. Waste Mgmt., Inc., 
    743 F.2d 976
    , 983 (2d Cir.
    1984) (ease of entry, separate from actual entry, can constrain price). The Guidelines explain when
    new entry “alleviate[s] concerns about adverse competitive effects”: when that entry would be
    “timely, likely, and sufficient in its magnitude, character, and scope to deter or counteract the
    competitive effects of concern.” Guidelines § 9. Although the Guidelines are not binding, courts
    have frequently relied on their formulation of “timely, likely, and sufficient” to guide the analysis
    concerning entry. See, e.g., Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 988
    (discussing Guidelines regarding
    entry); Cardinal 
    Health, 12 F. Supp. 2d at 55
    –58 (discussing the “timely, likely, and sufficient”
    standard). Entry is timely, likely, and sufficient if it “fill[s] the competitive void that will result”
    from the merger. H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 73 (internal quotation marks omitted). Although
    the defendants bear the burden of production on this—and every other—element of their rebuttal
    case, the government bears the ultimate burden of persuasion. Id.; Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 983
    (citing Kaiser Aluminum & Chem. Corp. v. FTC, 
    652 F.2d 1324
    , 1340 & n.12 (7th Cir. 1981)).
    2. Analysis
    Aetna and Humana introduced evidence of recent new entry into several of the complaint
    counties. Conversely, the government introduced evidence that industry participants—when not
    preparing for or engaged in litigation—believe new entry into the individual Medicare Advantage
    market to be difficult. The parties also introduced expert analysis quantifying the likelihood,
    sufficiency, and timeliness of that entry based on data from past experience and econometric
    76
    models. The bulk of the evidence on this issue was presented through the testimony of Orszag and
    Nevo. Thus the Court begins there.
    Both experts analyzed historical data to predict the likelihood of new entry, the probability
    that new entrants would replace the lost competition of Aetna and Humana, and the time horizon
    during which that new entry would happen. Orszag and Nevo agree that three key differences in
    their definitions of entry drive the differences in their results. First, Orszag defines “entry” more
    stringently than Nevo. Orszag only considers an MAO an “entrant” once it achieves a 5% market
    share in the relevant county, whereas Nevo considers an MAO an “entrant” as soon as it begins
    offering plans within a county. Orszag described this as a “5% threshold.” He also counts the
    year in which the MAO achieved a 5% market share as the year in which it entered. He argues
    that including this 5% threshold focuses his calculations on competitively significant entry, rather
    than diluting his results with “competitively insignificant fluctuations” that are “not ‘real’ entry in
    any meaningful sense.” See DX0418 (Orszag Reply Report) ¶¶ 89–90. Nevo responds that
    employing the threshold overstates the likelihood of success of a new entrant and obscures the
    timeline—in other words, that the use of the threshold means that Orszag’s calculations answer
    the questions of how many MAOs entered and were moderately successful, and what market share
    those moderately successful MAOs achieved, rather than the questions of how many MAOs
    entered at all, how successful all MAOs were, and the timeliness of that entry. See PX0552 (Nevo
    Reply Report) ¶ 94.
    Because Orszag counts an MAO as an “entrant” at the moment it crossed the 5% threshold,
    he counts an MAO as an “entrant” multiple times if that MAO achieves a 5% market share, then
    falls below that threshold, but then once again surpasses the threshold. See PX0552 (Nevo Reply
    Report) ¶ 92 & n.108. In other words, such an MAO would count as a “new entrant” twice (or
    77
    perhaps more) even if it never left the relevant county. This also means that Orszag’s definition
    of entry counts an incumbent firm as a new entrant if the incumbent firm previously had less than
    a 5% market share, and then surpassed 5% in a subsequent year.
    Importantly, Orszag includes Aetna and Humana in the historical data he uses regarding
    entry, whereas Nevo does not. Nevo argues that Aetna and Human must be excluded from the
    data because “neither Aetna nor Humana will be among the entrants who are available to mitigate
    the effects of the merger.” PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 93. Orszag believes that keeping Aetna
    and Humana in the historical data allows more accurate forecasts because, were Aetna and Humana
    not present, another comparable MAO—presumably another large, sophisticated, well-funded
    MAO—would sense the same profit opportunity that Aetna and Humana would have and step into
    their shoes. See Tr. 3193:12–23 (Orszag).
    Nevo runs multiple calculations using Orszag’s data and definition of entry, but excluding
    Aetna and Humana from historical data, excluding incumbents, and using the actual year of entry
    (but still including the 5% threshold). He terms this “Orszag’s corrected definition.” PX0552
    (Nevo Reply Report) ¶¶ 93–95. The Court will use that terminology as well. The discussion below
    examines the results of the experts’ analysis as well as the non-expert evidence in the framework
    of determining the likelihood, sufficiency, and timeliness of entry.
    (a) Likelihood of New Entry
    When analyzing the likelihood of any entry at all, it makes sense to use Nevo’s definition
    of entry, that is, one without any threshold. Under this definition, on average only 13.3% of the
    complaint counties had any entry in a given year between 2012 and 2016, and more than half
    experienced no entry during that five-year period. See PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 253 & Ex. 25; Tr.
    1656:8–18 (Nevo). One would expect this number to be higher than an equivalent calculation that
    78
    used the 5% threshold, because using a threshold would necessarily exclude some entrants. And
    in fact it is higher. Nevo ran the same calculation using his “corrected” version of Orszag’s
    definition of entry (that is, including the 5% threshold, but excluding Aetna and Humana,
    excluding incumbent MAOs, and using the actual year of MAO entry), and found that under that
    definition, only 5.5% of complaint counties experienced any entry in a given year from 2012
    through 2016. See PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 98 & Ex. 14.
    But Orszag’s analysis—without any “corrections” from Nevo—yields a higher number.
    He calculates that 20.7% of complaint counties experienced entry, on average, within a given year
    between 2012 and 2016. DX0419 (Orszag Report) Table II-10; PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) Ex.
    14. However, as discussed above, this calculation includes both Aetna and Humana in its historical
    data. The Court finds that doing so is not appropriate. By definition, Aetna and Humana would
    not be available to offset the competitive effects of their proposed merger. Orszag’s decision to
    include them rests on the premise that were Aetna and Humana not present, another firm would
    take their place. See Tr. 3193:12–23 (Orszag). But that assumes the conclusion. The Court cannot
    rely on an analysis that assumes new competition will replace lost competition when trying to
    determine whether new competition will in fact replace the lost competition—to do so would be
    circular reasoning. Moreover, there is other evidence in the record to suggest that Aetna in
    particular is not a typical entrant—specifically, that Aetna is much more likely to enter new
    markets and succeed in those new markets than another market participant, even one of the Big 5.
    See, e.g., PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶¶ 218, 220–23, 225 & Ex. 18; Tr. 1330:2–19 (Bertolini). In
    fact, of the 398 entrants in the complaint counties between 2012 and 2016 identified by Orszag,
    191 of them (nearly half) are either Aetna or Humana. PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 93. This
    makes it especially inappropriate in assessing the likelihood of entry to rely on an analysis that
    79
    assumes a competitor will take Aetna and Humana’s place once they are no longer available as
    potential new entrants.
    Orszag also presents a more granular analysis of the potential entrants in the complaint
    counties that he argues shows that entry is more likely than the above numbers suggest. He
    identifies several types of potential entrants that, based on historical data, are particularly likely to
    enter: MAOs that offer individual Medicare Advantage plans in nearby counties (either in an
    adjacent county or elsewhere in the same state), MAOs that offer other types of Medicare
    Advantage plans in the relevant county (either special needs plans or group Medicare Advantage
    plans), or firms that offer commercial insurance in the relevant county. See DX0419 (Orszag
    Report) ¶¶ 147–148 & Table II-15 (showing probability that each of these types of MAOs would
    enter relevant county). Based on this analysis, Orszag identifies 1,684 potential entrants across all
    364 complaint counties that fit into these categories and are therefore particularly likely to enter.
    See DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 149. He shows that each complaint county has at least one or as
    many as twelve of these likely potential entrants; the average complaint county has five. See
    DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 149 & Figure II-4.
    This analysis by Orszag, moreover, aligns with the non-expert evidence Aetna and Humana
    introduced showing that some counties did experience new entry in recent years. Four of the eight
    MAOs offering plans in North Carolina—Cigna, Moses Cone Health, Gateway Health, and
    FirstHealth—entered within the past four years. Tr. 835:16–21 (Farley). At least three MAOs—
    Centene, Tenet Health, and United Health Services—either entered or expanded into new counties
    in the San Antonio market in recent years. Tr. 1046:18–1047:18 (Gonzalez); Tr. 2135:2–8,
    2145:11–2146:23 (Fernandez). Two new MAOs—Centene and Eon Health—entered in Georgia
    in the past year. Tr. 2089:8–10 (Follmer). These plans, like the Humana and Aetna plans in
    80
    Georgia, offer “rich” benefits—that is to say, low out-of-pocket costs for consumers, in the form
    of a “zero premium, zero PCP [primary care physician] plan, and zero co-pays for drugs.” Tr.
    2092:8–15 (Follmer). BlueCross BlueShield started offering a Medicare Advantage plan in
    Louisiana last year—the “[e]ntrants coming in and out of states . . . it’s part of the business, and it
    happens every year.” Tr. 2093:4–2093:9 (Follmer).
    But the Court does not find this more granular analysis persuasive. First, it suffers from
    the same weakness that Orszag’s basic entry analysis does: it includes Aetna and Humana in the
    historical data that forms the basis of the analysis. Once Aetna and Humana are removed, the
    number of likely potential entrants decreases dramatically. Nevo uses Orszag’s own model and
    data to show that, with Aetna and Humana removed, 99 of the 364 counties have less than a 5%
    chance of experiencing any entry, and the median county has only a 9% chance of experiencing
    any entry. See PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 100 & Ex. 15.
    Second, Orszag’s testimony during trial demonstrated that although he identified 1,684
    likely potential entrants, that number might significantly overstate how many of those MAOs
    would actually enter the complaint counties or achieve any substantial market share. For example,
    he identified Mecklenburg County, North Carolina (which includes Charlotte) as an example of a
    complaint county with three likely potential entrants: Cigna, Moses Cone Health, and FirstHealth.
    Tr. 3290:6–16 (Orszag). (This is consistent with Farley’s testimony, discussed above). But Orszag
    acknowledged that Cigna is currently under CMS sanction and cannot enroll new members in its
    Medicare Advantage plans; therefore, it is unable to expand into a new county until those sanctions
    are lifted. Tr. 3290:17–22 (Orszag); see also Tr. 329:20–330:4 (Cocozza) (explaining Cigna’s
    restrictions due to sanctions). Orszag also acknowledged that both Moses Cone and FirstHealth
    are provider-based plans tied to those providers’ specific hospital systems outside of the Charlotte
    81
    area, and to enter Mecklenburg County, they would likely need to contract with a hospital system
    in Charlotte. Tr. 3296:18–3299:19 (Orszag). There is evidence that would be unlikely. Thus,
    while Mecklenburg County has three potential entrants under Orszag’s analysis, none are actually
    likely to enter. Similarly, Orszag acknowledged that the fourth entrant in North Carolina (but not
    in Mecklenburg County) that Farley identified, Gateway Health, had only 54 members in Wake
    County, North Carolina, which Orszag would not even count as an “entrant” in that market. Tr.
    3300:13–3301:17 (Orszag). This casts some doubt on how many of the rest of Orszag’s 1,684
    likely potential entrants are truly likely to enter the complaint counties.
    Hence, based on the expert analysis that the Court finds persuasive—the analysis excluding
    Aetna and Humana from historical data on entry—either 13.3% or 5.5% of complaint counties
    have experienced new entry in any given year over the past five years. Case law does not provide
    a particular threshold above which entry is likely enough to allay fears of anticompetitive harm,
    nor did the parties provide one in their briefing or at closing arguments. But the core inquiry is
    whether entry is timely, likely, and sufficient enough to replace the lost competition from the
    merger. The Court finds that if only 13.3% or 5.5% of complaint counties experience any new
    entry per year, then entry is not likely enough to allay these concerns.
    This is corroborated by the non-expert testimony indicating that industry leaders believe
    there are significant barriers to entry in the individual Medicare Advantage market.          The
    government argues that the barriers to new entry are (1) the difficulty in building a competitive
    provider network, and the needs for (2) high star ratings, (3) a strong brand, and (4) Medicare
    Advantage-specific operational expertise and IT infrastructure. The President of Humana’s Retail
    Segment (the Humana division responsible for Medicare Advantage) testified that “[t]he hardest
    part about getting into this business is knowing how to build networks, knowing how to file
    82
    products, knowing how to manage CMS compliance, [and] knowing how to think about star
    ratings.” Tr. 631:13–16 (Wheatley). These barriers may be more applicable to competitors who
    are brand new to Medicare Advantage than to firms that offer Medicare Advantage in other
    counties and are considering expanding. Tr. 1206:11–13 (Cavanuagh) (“a company like Aetna
    that has more resources and can build a robust network might have an ability to be more
    competitive than a small regional provider”).
    In light of these barriers, the government introduced statements from industry participants
    indicating that industry members believe entry is difficult. The CEO of Humana has stated
    publicly that barriers to entry are increasing in the Medicare Advantage market, and therefore “the
    stronger will get stronger and the weaker will get weaker.” PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 251. A
    Humana business plan acknowledged some of Humana’s challenges in expanding Medicare
    Advantage into new regions, noting that “[n]ew market entry presents several challenges,
    including building local competitive intelligence, developing provider relationships, and
    understanding the nuances of local distribution.” DX0506-048. Aetna’s internal documents
    convey the same perspective. The President of Aetna’s Medicare product line has stated that
    “Medicare has unique aspects that require a clinical engagement approach, scorecard, stars element
    and coding/revenue attention that is different” from other forms of health insurance. PX0007-848.
    Another Aetna executive specifically acknowledged that the growth and increasing importance of
    value-based contracts “[c]reates barriers to entry to other payers.”      PX0603-358.     In-court
    testimony confirmed that Cocozza believes an insurer’s track record in operating “viable,
    successful Medicare Advantage plans” is important in convincing a provider to enter into a value-
    based contract—indicating that a new entrant might struggle to do so. See Tr. 348:1–18 (Cocozza).
    83
    The Court finds this evidence persuasive. These statements were primarily made in the
    ordinary course of business and are therefore likely to accurately reflect an unvarnished viewpoint.
    They express the opinion of knowledgeable industry leaders. And they are consistent with the
    expert analysis. Together, the expert analysis and the other evidence paint a picture of new entry
    not being particularly likely, and the barriers to entry being high.
    (b) Sufficiency of New Entry
    The analysis of the sufficiency of new entry is simpler because, despite the different
    conclusions that the experts draw, the actual data show that there is a relatively low probability
    that new entry would be sufficient to replace the lost competition of Aetna or Humana regardless
    of which expert approach is used.
    To determine how likely all new entrants (as a whole) are to replace the competition lost
    by the merger, one must first determine the market share of the smaller of the two defendants in
    each of the complaint counties. See PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 255. In 77% of the complaint
    counties, the smaller of Aetna or Humana has a market share above 10%. PX0551 (Nevo Report)
    ¶ 255. In fact, in nearly half of the counties, the smaller of Aetna or Humana has a market share
    of over 20%. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 255. These numbers are uncontested.
    Using Nevo’s definition of entry, nationwide 19.1% of new entrants gain a market share of
    above 10%. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 256. Nevo then calculated that, in the median complaint
    county, there is a 10.3% chance that all new entrants (combined) would replace competition lost
    by the merger, and a 9.9% chance that an individual new entrant would replace competition lost
    by the merger. PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) Ex. 27 (10.3% probability for all entrants combined)
    & Ex. 26 (9.9% probability for individual entrant). That calculation does not use a 5% threshold,
    and therefore one would expect the result to be lower than the corresponding one calculated by
    84
    Orszag. In fact, that is the case. Using Orszag’s full definition of entry—with the 5% threshold,
    with Aetna and Humana’s historical data, with incumbents, and using the year that an entrant
    surpassed 5% as the year of entry—an entrant who achieves a 5% market share goes on to achieve
    a 33% mean market share within three years, and a 27% median market share within three years.
    DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 134 & Table II-11. But again, it is illogical to include Aetna and
    Humana’s historical data, for the reasons discussed earlier. Excluding Aetna and Humana
    historical data from the calculation and using the actual year of entry, but otherwise employing
    Orszag’s definition of entry, an entrant who achieves a 5% market share goes on to achieve only
    a 16% mean market share within three years, and a 7% median market share within three years.
    PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 109. This results in a median probability of only 10.2% that an
    individual new entrant would replace the competition lost by the merger in a given county.
    PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 112 & Ex. 17. 28 This analysis is persuasive, and alone is enough
    to conclude that entry is not likely to be sufficient.
    But even using Orszag’s full definition of entry with no alterations, in the median complaint
    county there is only a 25.5% chance that new entrants will replace the lost competition from the
    merger. So, even if the Court were to fully embrace Orszag’s definition of entry and reject Nevo’s,
    the Court would still find that new entrants would not be sufficient to “fill the competitive void”
    from the merger. H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 73 (internal quotation marks omitted). 29
    28
    Neither of Nevo’s reports used Orszag’s “corrected” definition, with a 5% threshold, to calculate the
    probability that all new entrants combined would replace the lost competition.
    29
    The government points out that Orszag used 2012 through 2016 data when determining the likelihood of
    entry, but only used 2013 through 2016 data when evaluating the success of that entry. Pls.’ Proposed Findings &
    Conclusions at 129. The government argues that this is Orszag’s attempt to present the data in a misleading manner:
    2012 saw more entry than most subsequent years, and 2012 entrants failed at a significantly higher rate than entrants
    in subsequent years. Id.; DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 128 & Table II-10 (more entrants in 2012 than in most subsequent
    years); Tr. 3287:5–3288:14 (Orszag) (acknowledging that he did not use 2012 data and that those entrants failed at a
    higher rate). But for the complaint counties, there were fewer entrants in 2012 than in subsequent years, making the
    effect of excluding 2012 from the data unclear. See DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 128 & Table II-10. Regardless, it is
    not necessary to evaluate the implications of omitting 2012 data from some of Orszag’s analyses.
    85
    (c) Timeliness of New Entry
    Orszag built a model to “quantif[y] the likelihood that another MAO will enter in one, two,
    or three years” when the number of MAOs in a given county is below the equilibrium number of
    MAOs for that county. DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 138. He defines equilibrium within a county
    as when “it is not profitable for any MAO to exit or enter.” DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 140. He
    calculates the equilibrium number of MAOs in a given county based on the number of MAOs
    present in a particular year, the number of MAOs present in past years, and certain characteristics
    of that county that are correlated with profitability. DX0419 (Orszag Report) ¶ 141. Once he has
    calculated an equilibrium number of MAOs for a given county, he can then calculate the rate at
    which the actual number of MAOs converged on the equilibrium number. DX0419 (Orszag
    Report) ¶¶ 143–44. Based on this model, he ultimately concludes that within three years, 87% of
    the gap between the actual and equilibrium number of MAOs will be closed. DX0419 (Orszag
    Report) ¶ 145 & Table II-14.
    Nevo does not build his own countervailing model. Rather, he critiques Orszag’s model
    as uninformative because it is built on circular logic: it estimates an equilibrium number of MAOs
    based on the number of actual MAOs present, and then tries to predict how many and how quickly
    MAOs will enter to achieve that number in the future. See PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 104.
    Nevo describes this model as “non-standard.” PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 104 n.129. Instead,
    he looks to the historical experience following the Humana-Arcadian merger in 2012. He finds
    that, following that merger, only 33% of the counties that met the presumption of unlawfulness
    based on market concentration—presumably, prime candidates for entry—experienced any entry
    in the four years following the merger. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶ 238. Of the 33% of presumption
    86
    counties that had any entrants, 73% of them only received their first entrant during year 3 or year
    4 after the merger. PX0552 (Nevo Reply Report) ¶ 108.
    The Court finds Nevo’s critique of Orszag’s model for equilibrium and timely entry to be
    persuasive. Orszag’s model only yields informative results with respect to timeliness if its
    estimates of the equilibrium number of MAOs are correct. But there is no evidence, either in this
    record or in academic literature brought to the Court’s attention, to support the theory that an
    equilibrium number of MAOs can be deduced from the current number of firms. Orszag did testify
    that the concept of an equilibrium number of firms, and the rate at which a market adjusts to reach
    that number, is a common economic concept. See Tr. 3098:3–3099:13 (Orszag). But he presented
    no specific citations or other evidence to explain when or how models estimating an equilibrium
    number of firms overcome the circularity concern, and how this particular model does so. The
    Court, therefore, will not rely on the timeliness calculations resulting from Orszag’s model. The
    Court finds Nevo’s analysis of the timeliness of entry following the Humana-Arcadian merger
    more informative, although only somewhat persuasive. The parties presented evidence on whether
    the Humana-Arcadian merger is comparable for the purpose of evaluating the effects of divestiture,
    but little evidence on how the relevant counties might compare to the complaint counties here with
    respect to new entry. See, e.g., Tr. 3128:12–3129:19 (Orszag). Ultimately, then, the Court is
    reluctant to draw conclusions from what may or may not be an appropriate historical analogue.
    Thus, the Court cannot draw firm conclusions on the timeliness of new entry were this merger to
    occur.
    3. Summary
    Given the analysis of sufficiency and likelihood, the Court finds that, overall, new entry
    would not be timely, likely, and sufficient to replace the competition lost by the merger. The most
    87
    persuasive expert analysis demonstrates that entry is likely to occur in, at most, an average of
    13.3% of the complaint counties per year. Moreover, using the analysis most favorable to the
    defendants, there is just a 25.5% chance that new entrants will replace the lost competition in the
    median county.      That number drops dramatically—to approximately 10%—if one excludes
    Aetna’s and Humana’s past performance from the historical data used to create a projection. So,
    even under the most generous of the plausible calculations the median county has a 13.3% chance
    of experiencing any entry, and a 25.5% chance that this new entry will be sufficient to replace the
    lost competition. There is therefore a relatively small chance overall of replacing the competition
    lost by the proposed merger. This rebuttal argument based on entry therefore fails.
    E. Molina Divestiture
    Defendants’ next rebuttal argument is that the proposed divestiture of certain assets to
    Molina Healthcare would counteract any anticompetitive effects of the merger. Molina 30 is a
    health insurer that has historically focused on offering Medicaid, and Medicaid-related, insurance
    plans. This section first explains the applicable law, and then provides background on Molina, the
    process by which Aetna, Humana, and Molina agreed to the divestiture, the terms of the divestiture
    agreement, and the barriers to the divestiture. Next, it summarizes and evaluates the evidence as
    to whether Molina would successfully replace the competition lost by the merger—including the
    statements made by Molina executives and board members at the time, Molina’s history in the
    Medicare Advantage market, and the purchase price. Finally, it briefly considers the expert
    testimony, before reaching the ultimate conclusion that the proposed divestiture would not replace
    the competition lost due to the merger.
    1. Applicable Law
    30
    This opinion uses the term “Molina” to refer to the corporate entity. The Court heard testimony from
    Molina’s CEO, Dr. Mario Molina (Dr. Molina), and the CFO, John Molina (Mr. Molina).
    88
    In rebuttal, a defendant may introduce evidence that a proposed divestiture would “‘restore
    [the] competition’” lost by the merger counteracting the anticompetitive effects of the merger. See
    Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 72 (quoting Ford Motor Co. v. United States, 
    405 U.S. 562
    , 573 (1972)).
    A divestiture must “effectively preserve competition in the relevant market.” U.S. Dep’t of Justice,
    Antitrust Division Policy Guide to Merger Remedies 1 (2011) (“Remedies Guide”). In other
    words, the divestiture must “replac[e] the competitive intensity lost as a result of the merger.”
    Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 72 (internal quotation marks omitted). Like the Merger Guidelines, the
    Remedies Guide is frequently used by courts to guide their analysis, although it is not binding law.
    
    Id. Divestiture of
    an “existing business entity” might be more likely to “effectively preserv[e] the
    competition that would have been lost through the merger,” because it would have the “personnel,
    customer lists, information systems, intangible assets, and management infrastructure” necessary
    to competition, but divestiture of some lesser set of assets might be appropriate when the purchaser
    already has, or could easily attain, the other capabilities needed to compete effectively. See
    Remedies Guide 8–9.        Courts are skeptical of a divestiture that relies on a “‘continuing
    relationship[] between the seller and buyer of divested assets” because that leaves the buyer
    susceptible to the seller’s actions—which are not aligned with ensuring that the buyer is an
    effective competitor. Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 77 (quoting FTC v. CCC Holdings, Inc., 605 F.
    Supp. 2d 26, 59 (D.D.C. 2009)); see also White Consol. Indus. v. Whirlpool Corp., 
    781 F.2d 1224
    ,
    1227–28 (6th Cir. 1986).
    Defendants in a merger challenge bear the burden of producing evidence tending to rebut
    the government’s prima facie case. See Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 982
    ; 
    Staples, 970 F. Supp. at 1089
    . Part of that burden of production includes producing evidence that the divestiture will
    actually occur. Cf. FTC v. Arch Coal, Inc. No. 04-0534 (JDB), slip op. at 5 (D.D.C. July 7, 2004).
    89
    Obviously, defendants cannot produce evidence showing that the divestiture would create an
    effective competitor unless they first produce evidence that the divestiture is likely to occur. But,
    of course, antitrust deals in “probabilities, not certainties.” Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 323
    . Hence,
    the divestiture need not be iron clad for a court to consider it. Rather, once the divestiture is
    sufficiently non-speculative for the court to evaluate its effects on future competition, then further
    evidence about the likelihood of the divestiture goes to the weight of the evidence regarding the
    divestiture’s effects.
    2. Background on Molina
    Although the parties hotly contest the effect of the proposed divestiture to Molina, they do
    not contest the basic facts about Molina. Molina’s core business is Medicaid. Tr. 2336:21–2337:2
    (Dr. Molina). It was founded in 1980 by the father of the current CEO, Dr. Mario Molina, and the
    current CFO, John Molina. Tr. 2200:23–2201:12 (Dr. Molina). It was initially founded as a
    medical clinic for Medicaid enrollees, and then expanded into providing health insurance in 1994.
    Tr. 2200:24–2201:21 (Dr. Molina). It became a publicly traded company in 2003. Tr. 2205:19–
    23 (Dr. Molina).
    Today, the bulk of its members are in Medicaid plans. At the time of trial, Molina had
    approximately 4.2 million members. Tr. 956:4–6 (Mr. Molina). 31 Of that total, approximately
    550,000 are enrolled in individual commercial plans through the public exchanges. Tr. 958:1–4
    (Mr. Molina). Another approximately 100,000 are enrolled in plans for persons who are eligible
    for both Medicare and Medicaid, known as dual-eligibles. Tr. 1010:2–5 (Mr. Molina); 2214:6–13
    31
    There are some discrepancies in Molina’s enrollment data, stemming from whether data for the 2015 plan
    year is used, or more recent but unverified data from the 2016 plan year is used. For example, Molina’s 2015 annual
    report stated it had 3.5 million members, PX0230 at 2, while Mr. Molina testified that it currently has 4.2 million
    members, Tr. 956:4–6 (Mr. Molina), and Dr. Molina testified that it has 4.3 million members, Tr. 2204:19–25 (Dr.
    Molina). These discrepancies are not important to the analysis.
    90
    (Dr. Molina). Molina offers two types of these plans: a dual-eligible special needs plan (D-SNP)
    and a Medicare-Medicaid Plan (MMP). A D-SNP is a type of Medicare Advantage plan, but is
    not an individual Medicare Advantage plan in the market at issue in this case. An MMP is a
    demonstration plan, that is, a pilot program run by CMS. See Tr. 960:1–3 (Mr. Molina).
    Approximately half of those 100,000 members are in MMPs, and half are in D-SNPs. Tr. 1010:6–
    10 (Mr. Molina). Molina has only approximately 424 enrollees in individual Medicare Advantage
    plans. Tr. 1010:11–14 (Mr. Molina). Approximately 3.5 million are enrolled in Medicaid plans.
    Molina offers its plans in 12 states plus Puerto Rico. 32 Tr. 955:24–956:3 (Mr. Molina). It
    offers Medicaid plans in all of those locations, and commercial plans through the exchanges in
    nine of those states. Tr. 2349:14–25 (Dr. Molina). Molina also serves as the Medicaid claims
    processing contractor for five states. Tr. 2233:4–8 (Dr. Molina). In 2016, it offered individual
    Medicare Advantage plans in only six counties across two states: California and Utah. PX0559
    (Burns Report) ¶ 559, Exs. 1 & 3; see also Tr. 960:21–961:4 (Mr. Molina). For 2017, it will only
    offer individual Medicare Advantage plans in Utah. Tr. 2293:9–2294:3 (Dr. Molina).
    Much of Molina’s growth has occurred in recent years. Molina’s membership has more
    than doubled in the past three years, from 1.9 million members in 2013 to 4.2 million at the end of
    2016. Tr. 956:4–6 (Mr. Molina); PX0230 at 2. Obviously, none of that growth has been in
    individual Medicare Advantage plans. Molina’s revenue has also increased four-fold over the past
    five years, from $4.2 billion in 2011 to near $17 billion in 2016. Tr. 2203:11–15 (Dr. Molina);
    PX0230 at 2. Much of that growth is through acquisitions: in 2015 alone, it had approximately 10
    acquisitions. Tr. 1000:5–8 (Mr. Molina); Tr. 2260:9–12 (Dr. Molina); DX0133; DX0140-014–16.
    32
    Again, other documents, including Molina’s 2015 annual report, state that Molina offers plans in 11 states
    plus Puerto Rico. See PX0230 at 2.
    91
    It currently has a market capitalization of $3.09 billion, and is a Fortune 500 company. 33 Tr.
    2207:6–11, 2382:24–2383:4 (Dr. Molina).
    Despite focusing on Medicaid, Molina has made forays into the individual Medicare
    Advantage market in the past. None have succeeded, although the parties disagree as to why.
    Throughout its history, Molina has sold individual Medicare Advantage plans in a total of 63
    counties. PX0559 (Burns Report) ¶ 42. Its most significant expansion into Medicare Advantage
    started in 2008. PX0092-680. By 2011, it had enrolled only 4,620 members across eight states in
    these plans. PX0092-680. And by early 2012, it had decided to exit from all of those states except
    New Mexico. See PX0249-923; PX0559 (Burns Report) ¶ 46. As explained in a 2011 memo from
    Lisa Rubino, the Molina executive responsible for its Medicare business, the plans were losing
    money because the “benefits, network and formulary” for pharmacy benefits were “average to
    below average” as compared to competitors. PX0092-681; see also PX0242 (internal email
    discussing same); PX0107-710 (internal email discussing same). Molina later withdrew from New
    Mexico as well for similar reasons. PX0559 (Burns Report) ¶¶ 46–48.
    Another of Molina’s experiences in individual Medicare Advantage came when it acquired
    a health insurer in Wisconsin called Abri in 2010. See Tr. 2303:5–15 (Dr. Molina). A year later,
    Molina exited the individual Medicare Advantage portion of that business. Dr. Molina testified
    that Abri’s individual Medicare Advantage plans were struggling when Molina made the
    acquisition, and Molina was not permitted to run the plans directly because the contract required
    that they continue to be operated by a third party. Tr. 2386:3–20 (Dr. Molina). Thus the company
    made a strategic decision to cease offering those plans. Tr. 2386:3–20 (Dr. Molina). Molina’s
    most recent effort to expand into Medicare Advantage began in 2014, when it started offering the
    33
    The transcript also states “$3.09 million” but that is a transcription error. See Tr. 2295:8–11 (Dr. Molina).
    92
    individual Medicare Advantage plan in Utah that it still operates today (although with only about
    400 members). See Tr. 2375:8–13 (Dr. Molina).
    Molina’s effort to expand into Medicare Advantage through this divestiture began in June
    2016. Aetna and Human approached 14 potential buyers about a sale of certain Aetna and Humana
    assets. PX0536 at 7. Ultimately, only five potential buyers submitted initial bids. PX0536 at 7;
    Tr. 1346:7–14 (Bertolini). Of those, just three submitted bids for all of the divestiture assets:
    Molina, InnovaCare, and WellCare. PX0536 at 7. InnovaCare operates only in Puerto Rico. Tr.
    392:11–20 (Cocozza).     WellCare had trouble with law enforcement, as well as with CMS
    compliance. Tr. 393:8–14 (Cocozza). Aetna and Humana selected Molina as the divestiture
    purchaser. See PX0433 (Aetna analysis of divestiture bids). Molina ultimately paid approximately
    $401 per member acquired, or $1,400 per member including statutory capital (that is, the capital
    that an insurer must set aside to maintain its insurance license). Tr. 2252:9–14 (Dr. Molina);
    DX0262-234; DX0264-230.
    Aetna and Humana each entered into an Asset Purchase Agreement (APA) and
    Administrative Services Agreement (ASA) with Molina. See DX0262 (Humana and Molina);
    DX0264 (Aetna and Molina). Under the agreements, the defendants will transfer to Molina certain
    Medicare Advantage plans that include approximately 290,000 members in as many as 437
    counties. See DX0262-019, 218–22; DX0264-019, 216–19. The divested plans cover 21 states,
    and all 364 complaint counties. See DX0262-218–22; DX0264-216–19. Under the ASA, Aetna
    and Humana will continue to operate the divested plans for the remainder of the calendar year in
    which the merger closes. If it closes in 2017, then Molina has the option to extend the ASA for
    up to two 6 month periods. DX0262-110; DX0264-109; Tr. 2462:10–15 (Rubino). During that
    time, all plan administration services, such as IT, claims processing, and broker services, will be
    93
    managed by Aetna and Humana. DX0262-095; DX0264-094. Their contracts with providers will
    still be in place, and members may continue to see their own providers. Tr. 2459:7–17 (Rubino);
    Tr. 2510:15–20 (Buckingham); DX0017. However, a provider may be able to withdraw from that
    network during the period of the ASA, depending on the terms of that provider’s contract with
    Aetna or Humana. See Tr. 3747:6–15 (post-trial argument). After the ASA expires, the divested
    plans will be fully operated by Molina.
    3. Whether the Divestiture Will Occur
    The parties disagree over how likely the divestiture is to happen, and the implication of
    that assessment. The government identifies several hurdles—including ones outside of the parties’
    and Molina’s control—to the divestiture. First, CMS must approve the novation, that is, the
    transfer of CMS’s contracts with Aetna and Humana to Molina. See 42 C.F.R. § 422.550(c)
    (defining novation); DX0262-063 (novation a condition of closing); DX0264-063 (same).
    Although CMS has a policy against approving novations that are not an entire “book of business,”
    so as to prevent insurers from selling off portions of plans, this policy is sub-regulatory and not
    binding on the agency. See Tr. 1153:11–1154:10 (Cavanaugh); PX0104 at 538–39, ch. 12 § 30.3
    (CMS Medicare Managed Care Manual describing “entire book of business” policy). CMS
    approved a novation of less than an entire book of business in the Humana-Arcadian merger in
    2012, when a court permitted the merger if it was accompanied by a divestiture, and a CMS official
    testified that CMS was likely to do so again here if necessary. See Tr. 2573:11–2575:23
    (Coleman). Thus, the novation requirement does not appear to be an insurmountable barrier to the
    divestiture proceeding, even though it raises some doubt.
    Second, Molina has the opportunity to withdraw from the divestiture agreement if CMS
    does not give “reasonable adequate assurances” that the plans’ star ratings will transfer to Molina.
    94
    DX0262-064 (APA § 6.02(e)); DX0264-063–64 (APA §6.02(e)). Such a transfer would be
    contrary to CMS’s usual practice of assigning the purchaser’s new contract with CMS the average
    star rating of that purchaser (i.e., of Molina). See DX0151-026–27; DX0349-009. However,
    Molina has expressed an interest in continuing with the divestiture even if the star ratings do not
    transfer over. Tr. 987:4–13 (Mr. Molina); Tr. 2388:16–2389:9 (Dr. Molina).
    Finally, state insurance regulators have expressed concern with the merger and divestiture.
    See PX0476 ¶ 22 (Florida Office of Insurance Regulation noting that divestiture “is not in the best
    interest of policyholders in the state of Florida”); PX0076 (Missouri Department of Insurance
    preliminary order blocking merger). As Dr. Molina acknowledged, the merger is “not a done
    deal.” Tr. 2381:9–22 (Dr. Molina).
    However, the Court need not reach a conclusion on whether the divestiture would occur if
    the Court approved the merger accompanied by the divestiture. Rather, Molina has shown that it
    is sufficiently likely to occur for the Court to at least consider evidence of the effect of the merger:
    CMS does not seem likely to block the novations, and the remaining barriers are largely within
    Aetna, Humana, and Molina’s control. This is sufficient for the Court to consider the effects of
    the divestiture, and to consider the likelihood that it would not occur as a factor going to the weight
    of the evidence. Ultimately, however, given that the Court finds that the divestiture would not
    counteract the loss of competition from the proposed merger even if it were to occur as planned,
    there is no need for the Court to further consider the divestiture’s likelihood.
    4. Analysis
    Aetna and Humana have advanced four affirmative arguments for why Molina would be a
    successful competitor in the Medicare Advantage market following the divestiture. The Court
    95
    considers these in turn, then considers the low purchase price, Molina’s history in the individual
    Medicare Advantage market, and the expert testimony.
    (a) Defendants’ Affirmative Arguments
    Defendants argue, first, that Molina has the capability to provide care management to
    lower-income populations; second, it will be able to build competitive provider networks; third, it
    has the internal capacity to manage the divested health plans; and fourth, it will be able to use
    marketing and brokers to retain members (i.e., the 290,000 divested members) and attract new
    members.        However, although defendants advance much evidence of Molina’s capabilities,
    ultimately each of these arguments is undermined by other contradictory evidence presented at
    trial, especially statements made by Molina executives and board members while the deal was
    being negotiated.
    i.     Care Management
    Defendants assert that a key reason Molina will be successful in the Medicare Advantage
    market is its skill in providing care management in the Medicaid market. See Tr. 2231:25–2232:10
    (Dr. Molina). Molina’s Medicaid population tends to have particularly complex health needs. Its
    dual-eligible members have, on average, 4.5 chronic medical conditions, as opposed to one chronic
    medical condition for its individual Medicare Advantage members. Tr. 2230:24–2231:5 (Dr.
    Molina). Molina’s Medicaid and dual-eligible members often have other barriers to good health
    as well, such as drug abuse and homelessness. Tr. 2231:6–24 (Dr. Molina). Defendants argue that
    if Molina can successfully manage this population, then it is well suited to manage care for the
    healthier, more affluent Medicare Advantage population. See Tr. 632:21–633:4 (Wheatley).
    The government does not dispute Molina’s care management experience in the Medicaid
    and dual-eligible populations or the importance of care management to successfully operating
    96
    Medicare Advantage plans. See Tr. 1232:8–1233:8 (Burns) (care management as one of the six
    engines of a successful MAO). Indeed, as discussed above, the core value proposition of Medicare
    Advantage is that private MAOs can coordinate care better than Original Medicare, and therefore
    provide better quality care at a lower price.
    Instead the government contests whether Molina will be able to transfer this care
    management expertise in Medicaid and dual-eligible plans over to Medicare Advantage. The
    government argues that because of Molina’s lack of provider networks—and specifically value-
    based provider networks—in nearly all of the complaint counties, it will not be able to provide that
    care coordination to the acquired members. And because Molina has never offered a PPO, the
    argument goes, it does not know how to provide care management in that context. See Tr. 983:14–
    17 (Mr. Molina) (acknowledging that Molina has never offered a PPO). A PPO generally gives a
    member access to a broader network of providers, and does not require the primary care physician
    to serve as a “gatekeeper.” Approximately 60% of the divested plans are PPOs. Tr. 983:18–21
    (Mr. Molina); Tr. 2397:13–17 (Rubino). This fact surprised Mr. Molina when he first learned it.
    In an email to Rubino on August 16, 2016—approximately two weeks after Molina agreed to the
    divestiture—Mr. Molina stated “[H]ow did we miss this?!” PX0247; Tr. 983:24–984:17 (Mr.
    Molina). Indeed, there is some evidence that Molina has in the past avoided trying to attract
    members from PPO plans. See PX0250 (October 2011 email from Rubino stating as to PPO
    members that “I don’t think we need to go after them”).
    ii.   Provider Networks
    There is no dispute that provider networks are an essential component of offering a
    competitive Medicare Advantage plan. See PX0559 (Burns Report) ¶ 69; Tr. 292:1–5, 292:24–
    293:8, 318:3–7 (Cocozza); PX0102-449 (email from Rubino stating that if Molina loses essential
    97
    providers, it “will lose members in droves”); PX0015-846, -856 (Humana disenrollment survey
    identifying provider network as a key reason members leave plans); Tr. 296:10–21 (Cocozza)
    (members often leave plans if their provider is no longer in-network).                        But there is sharp
    disagreement over whether Molina will be able to build provider networks to serve the 290,000
    members acquired in the divestiture. Molina has no presence in 89% of the complaint counties,
    and no Medicare presence in 95% of them. PX0650 (Burns Reply Report) ¶ 5. Currently, Molina
    has some presence in 39 of the 364 complaint counties, and 114 of the 437 divestiture counties
    overall. Tr. 1243:15–24 (Burns). 34 Of those 39 counties, it only has any Medicare presence
    (through its dual-eligible plans) in 15 counties. Tr. 1244:3–7 (Burns). And although Molina has
    a network of non-dual Medicare Advantage providers in six counties, these are not part of the
    divestiture counties or complaint counties. Tr. 1244:13–18 (Burns).
    Molina is not acquiring Aetna’s or Humana’s provider contracts. Tr. 380:5–9 (Cocozza);
    Tr. 2538:9–23 (Buckingham). It therefore will need to build its non-dual Medicare Advantage
    provider network essentially from scratch in all 364 complaint counties, in 325 of which it has no
    presence whatsoever.
    Although Molina does not dispute these numbers, it views them differently. Rubino
    testified that of the 290,000 members in the divestiture plans, 90% of them are in 12 states. Tr.
    2402:16–24 (Rubino). Molina has some presence in 6 of those 12. Tr. 2403:12–25 (Rubino).
    Rubino also identified the top 20 hospitals and 50 providers in the divestiture plans—based on
    information from Aetna and Humana—and determined that Molina already has some sort of
    relationship with a significant number in those 6 states. Tr. 2404:14–2405:13 (Rubino); see
    34
    Burns notes that Aetna is not offering Medicare Advantage plans in 2017 in 2 of the 364 complaint counties.
    See PX0559 (Burns Report) ¶ 11 n.1. This opinion continues to use the number 364, rather than 362, for clarity and
    consistency. Burns’ reports, and some portions of the transcript, refer to 362 rather than 364 counties.
    98
    DX0145 (Molina analysis of network overlap). Thus, although Molina has no Medicare presence
    in the vast majority of the complaint counties, Rubino believes that it already has relationships
    with a large portion of the key providers.
    The parties also disagree on whether Molina can build adequate provider networks in the
    time available. Rubino testified that in a market where Molina has some presence, it might only
    take two to three months, while in a new market it might take four to six months. Tr. 2400:6–17
    (Rubino). Renee Buckingham, the Humana executive responsible for managing the divestiture
    testified that building a network in a new market might take seven to eight months. See Tr.
    2521:16–2522:3 (Buckingham) (“late summer or early fall” through February). She also stated
    that value-based contracts that include downside risk for the provider—that is, the possibility of
    losing money based on poor performance—take “much longer to negotiate.” Tr. 2521:7–14
    (Buckingham). The president of Aetna’s Medicare business testified that it can take up to 18
    months to build a provider network that meets CMS network adequacy requirements in a new
    market. Tr. 342:6–13 (Cocozza). She also testified that it could take up to a year even in a market
    where Aetna has a pre-existing relationship with providers. Tr. 342:14–17 (Cocozza).
    Under CMS’s network adequacy requirement, each plan must have a sufficient network
    before it can be offered to consumers. Tr. 1140:6–16 (Cavanaugh). This network adequacy
    requirement is “robust” and “very stringent,” and the companies try to build networks that are
    broader than what CMS requires. See Tr. 291:8–16 (Cocozza); Tr. 547:8–20 (Wheatley). An
    MAO must submit network information for adequacy review in February of the year prior to the
    plan. Tr. 341:21–342:5 (Cocozza). Therefore, if the divestiture occurs in early 2017 and Molina
    99
    extends the ASA as long as possible—through the end of 2018—Molina would have
    approximately one year to create provider networks that would meet the adequacy requirement. 35
    There was conflicting testimony about the difficulty of building provider networks. Rubino
    testified that the process of building provider networks is “quite easy” in Medicare Advantage
    where the rates cluster closely around Original Medicare rates. See Tr. 2398:7–10, Tr. 2403:3–11
    (Rubino) (Medicare Advantage rates are 95-100% of Original Medicare rates); see also Tr.
    2515:8–2516:5 (Buckingham) (Medicare Advantage rates similar to Original Medicare rates). In
    Medicaid rates are often as low as 70% of the Medicare rates, leading to more difficult contract
    negotiations. See Tr. 2263:16–22 (Dr. Molina). Buckingham testified that an MAO’s scale in a
    marketplace may not affect the provider rates it is able to negotiate, because Medicare Advantage
    provider rates are driven by Original Medicare provider rates.                          See Tr. 2515:8–2516:18
    (Buckingham). Defendants introduced evidence that the process of contracting with providers is
    straightforward, and consists largely of reaching out to physicians by mail or phone to sign
    standardized contracts, and meeting with hospitals in person. See Tr. 2398:7–2400:5 (Rubino);
    Tr. 2511:10–2512:14 (Buckingham).                  Buckingham also testified that Molina will be well
    positioned to create provider networks because it will already know which providers are in Aetna’s
    and Humana’s networks for the divestiture plans, and therefore which providers those 290,000
    members want. Tr. 2522:21–2523:2 (Buckingham); see also Tr. 2404:14–2405:13 (Rubino).
    In fact, Molina is so confident in its ability to build a provider network that Dr. Molina
    would prefer to develop new contracts with providers rather than take over existing Aetna or
    35
    One document suggests that for counties where Molina already has a Medicare network through its dual-
    eligible plans, it would not need to submit network adequacy information in February. See PX0090-195 (“The beauty
    of existing states and service areas [is] we avoid the Feb Firedrill[.] we just have to deliver by bid time[.]”). In that
    case, Molina would have approximately 16 months, rather than 12 months, to build a network in the 15 complaint
    counties where it has D-SNP and MMP plans. This would not change the Court’s analysis.
    100
    Humana contracts. See Tr. 2385:9–17 (Dr. Molina); but see Tr. 955:19–23 (Mr. Molina) (Molina
    is still interested in Aetna and Humana’s provider contracts “to the extent they can be assigned”).
    This is a change from the approach that Aetna, Humana, and Molina earlier took, when the
    companies tried to assign Aetna and Humana contracts to Molina. See Tr. 379:5–380:8 (Cocozza)
    (Aetna originally planned to assign contracts to the divestiture buyer but no longer intends to after
    discovering a low percentage are assignable). The implication the defendants draw from the
    testimony about the length of time it takes to build a provider network, the lack of variability in
    provider rates, the straight-forward process for contract negotiation, and Dr. Molina’s preference
    for creating new contracts is that Molina will have no trouble building a competitive provider
    network during the period the ASA applies.
    Defendants’ suggested conclusion, however, is undermined by their other arguments, and
    by contemporaneous emails sent by Molina executives. The evidence that provider rates in
    Medicare Advantage are closely tied to Original Medicare rates is relatively persuasive. But there
    is some evidence to the contrary. Defendants’ expert on efficiencies presented evidence that
    Humana and Aetna sometimes receive dramatically different rates in contracts with providers. See
    Tr. 2917:19–2918:6 (Gokhale). While he used this evidence to argue that the merger would result
    in efficiencies because the merged entity could use the lower of the two contracts, here this
    evidence simply means that there are some substantial differences between rates in Medicare
    Advantage contracts. Moreover, according to Board of Directors’ meeting minutes, Dr. Molina
    claimed that the acquisition “would provide additional negotiating leverage with respect to its
    provider contracts,” although at trial he disclaimed this statement. Compare PX0103-268 with Tr.
    2369:20–2370:3 (Dr. Molina). Mr. Molina made the same statement in an email exchange with a
    board member. PX0271-809. The government also presented evidence that some of Molina’s
    101
    contracts include rates significantly above Original Medicare rates. See PX0708; Tr. 2470:16–
    2473:12 (Rubino) (Molina’s contract with Hospital Corporation of America in Florida pays rates
    “considerably above” Original Medicare). It is unclear whether those numbers are outliers or
    indicate a systemic lack of bargaining power due to Molina’s smaller size. But the primary
    problem with defendants’ argument is that the conclusion that building provider networks is easy
    does not follow from the premise that negotiating provider rates is easy. There are significant non-
    rate terms in provider contracts—a fact that Molina, Aetna, and Humana executives highlighted
    elsewhere in their testimony.
    Specifically, defendants repeatedly emphasize Molina’s ability to provide sophisticated
    care management. See, e.g., Tr. 2231:25–2232:10, 2273:20–2275:19 (Dr. Molina). That requires,
    in part, engaging in value-based contracts with providers to align incentives for providers to
    manage their patients’ care and overall health. See Tr. 2262:23–2263:11 (Dr. Molina); PX0412-
    735 (Aetna internal document stating that “ability to drive provider performance to improve
    revenue, quality and outcomes” is core driver of success). Dr. Molina emphasized Molina’s
    strength in value-based contracting as a core reason why it would provide high quality care
    management to its Medicare Advantage members. Tr. 2216:11–22 (Dr. Molina). Other witnesses
    acknowledged that value-based contracts—the type that Molina believes important to success in
    this business—are significantly more difficult and time consuming to negotiate. See, e.g., Tr.
    2521:7–14 (Buckingham). Cocozza testified that Aetna’s scale and its history of “operat[ing]
    viable, successful Medicare Advantage plans” is important for negotiating value-based contracts
    with providers. Tr. 348:1–13 (Cocozza) (history of success); Cocozza Dep. 189:6–19, admitted at
    Tr. 344:25–345:8 (scale). Wheatley agreed, emphasizing that scale does matter in “get[ting] the
    providers’ attention” to form a value-based contract. Tr. 543:11–544:4 (Wheatley). Thus, even if
    102
    rate negotiations are not that difficult in Medicare Advantage, the Court does not accept that
    forming provider contracts as a whole is not difficult. Indeed, Rubino herself at one time agreed:
    she stated in an email sent while Molina was putting together its final bid that successfully
    implementing the divestiture would be a “big fricken lift.” PX0102-449; Tr. 2502:7–13 (Rubino).
    Rubino’s view is consistent with the evidence presented. Molina would have at most about
    a year, even if it extends the ASA to the maximum extent, to build a provider network before it
    would need to submit network information to CMS for adequacy review. It can take more than
    that—up to 18 months—to build a provider network in a new market, and can take even more time
    to build a value-based network. And without value-based networks, Molina will not be able to
    implement the care management that it believes is essential to success in Medicare Advantage.
    Based on all the evidence, then, the Court finds that Molina likely could not build a competitive
    Medicare Advantage provider network in all (or even most) of the 364 relevant counties in the
    timeframe available.
    iii.   Internal Capacity
    Defendants argue that Molina has the internal capacity—including IT infrastructure,
    personnel who can manage star ratings, and management and staff with relevant expertise—to
    successfully operate the divestiture plans, based on its experience with Medicaid, dual plans, and
    the public exchanges. They emphasize that Molina has the internal IT capacity to manage shifting
    290,000 members onto its platform. Molina is in the midst of a $50 million IT upgrade. Tr.
    990:22–991:5 (Mr. Molina). Because the company is already processing claims for “9 or 10
    million patients,” in its own plans and in its role as the Medicaid claims processor for five states,
    “adding 300,000 Medicare patients is not a stretch.” Tr. 2233:4–11 (Dr. Molina). And the period
    of the ASA—at most, just under two years—is sufficient to transfer those members onto Molina’s
    103
    IT platform. Tr. 954:24–955:1 (Mr. Molina). In fact, Rubino believes it can be accomplished in
    three to four months. Tr. 2455:12–2457:11 (Rubino). The government countered that Molina
    underestimates the difficulty of IT integration. For example, Aetna and Coventry merged in 2013,
    and now Aetna intends to fully integrate those systems by January 2019—six years after the
    merger. See Tr. 386:12–19 (Cocozza); see also Tr. 381:10–382:3 (Cocozza).
    Molina also emphasized that it has personnel with the necessary knowledge to manage star
    ratings. There are two ways in which star ratings could be important: higher star ratings might
    lead a senior to prefer a particular plan and might also affect the payments that MAOs receive from
    CMS (because they affect both benchmarks and rebates). The parties presented conflicting
    evidence as to whether star ratings really matter to seniors—with the companies presenting
    conflicting evidence themselves. Compare Tr. 1342:16–22 (Bertolini) (“all other things being
    equal” seniors will choose a plan with higher star ratings); with Tr. 2044:21–2045:4 (Kauffman)
    (Humana broker agreeing that she “cannot recall any senior expressing interest in star ratings”).
    But it is uncontroverted that star ratings matter for the latter purpose—increasing payments to an
    MAO. See Tr. 540:25–541:7 (Wheatley) (star ratings “absolutely impact [Humana’s] ability to
    keep premiums and benefits stable”); PX0008-329 (“Aetna’s star ratings are helping us to maintain
    our $0 premium Medicare Advantage plans as well as to preserve valuable supplemental benefits.
    . . . Through high star ratings, we are able to create and maintain solidly competitive MA plans.”);
    PX0102-449 (Molina “at risk of not being able to honor current benefits” if star ratings of divested
    plans do not transfer over to Molina). Indeed, Molina even insisted on the option of withdrawing
    from the divestiture agreement if CMS does not permit the star ratings of the divested plans to
    transfer to Molina. DX0262-064 (APA § 6.02(e)); DX0264-064 (APA §6.02(e)); Tr. 986:22–
    987:3 (Mr. Molina) (“We put that in there because we wanted to protect the star ratings.”); Tr.
    104
    2484:9–10 (Rubino) (Molina “repeatedly” requested that contract term). Molina now appears open
    to waiving this term. Tr. 987:4–13 (Mr. Molina); Tr. 2388:16–2389:9 (Dr. Molina)).
    Aetna and Humana argue that Molina has experience managing star ratings because its D-
    SNPs are subject to the same system. One of Molina’s D-SNPs has a 4 star rating; the rest have
    just 3.5 stars. Tr. 2358:9–15 (Dr. Molina); Tr. 978:5–8 (Mr. Molina). D-SNPs have, on average,
    half a star lower rating than comparable non-dual plans. Tr. 1166:5–1167:12 (Cavanaugh); see
    also Tr. 2269:15–20 (Dr. Molina). However, CMS already adjusts for this in the ratings assigned.
    Tr. 1167:7–12 (Cavanaugh). Molina has a division responsible for managing star ratings, which,
    it asserts, will be able to maintain high ratings on the divestiture Medicare Advantage plans. See
    DX0553-007 (Molina has a “Dedicated Unit” for “Quality and Star Ratings”); DX0134 (discussing
    Molina’s “Member Engagement Program,” which is “designed to improve overall member
    satisfaction and help increase quality measure scores”); Tr. 2270:15–20 (Dr. Molina); Tr. 2457:17–
    2458:21 (Rubino).
    Defendants also contend that Molina has the necessary personnel and management
    expertise to be a successful competitor following this divestiture. Molina intends to hire 1,500–
    2000 more employees, including actuaries and employees with finance and Medicare experience.
    Tr. 991:24–992:14 (Mr. Molina). The company has hired a regional president with Medicare
    Advantage experience, and is filling other management-level positions. Tr. 2452:5–23 (Rubino).
    Molina emphasizes that the period of the ASA gives Molina an additional cushion of time to build
    its internal capacity as necessary. Tr. 2253:20–2254:7 (Dr. Molina).
    But statements made by Molina board members and executives prior to litigation—at the
    time that Molina was considering the deal—undermine the in-court claims about Molina’s
    capabilities. In a June 30, 2016, email, Dale Wolf—a Molina board member and former CEO and
    105
    CFO of Coventry—stated “this is a very different business from what we do, including commercial
    marketing, pricing, contracting, etc[.] Unless we can acquire some talent as part of the deal, I think
    we are woefully under-resourced to be able to take this on.” PX0083; see Tr. 967:19–968:17 (Mr.
    Molina). Mr. Molina, the CFO, responded: “Agree wholeheartedly. Our medical management
    team (at Corporate) has a great deal of experience with” Medicare Advantage, but “I think our
    poor performance on our current SNP business provides ample evidence that we need to beef up
    Medicare resources.” PX0083. On July 2, Richard Schapiro, another board member, listed several
    pros and cons of the deal, and stated “[w]e lack management with the requisite Medicare skills and
    the handful of people we have won’t cut it.” PX0084. Mr. Molina again responded: “I agree with
    you on all points” and “I would put more weight on the ‘con’cerns.” PX0084. The next day,
    another board member expressed a similar concern, stating “[t]he sales and marketing of MA is a
    really different process for us.” PX0271-807. And in a particularly colorful exchange between
    Schapiro and Dr. Molina, Schapiro described the divestiture as follows: “The image that comes to
    my mind here is the dog chasing the car and we are the dog. What happens if we catch it?”
    PX0086. Dr. Molina responded “I guess it depends on if it is a mini Cooper or a Suburban.”
    PX0086. Schapiro later stated that he and Wolf “both agree that we don’t have the internal talent
    to run it.” PX0086.
    At trial, Mr. Molina and Dr. Molina explained that those emails only represent the
    preliminary thoughts of a handful of board members who ultimately voted in favor of the
    divestiture, and therefore the Court should look to the board’s ultimate vote as evidence of a
    thorough decision-making process.        See Tr. 963:1–12 (Mr. Molina); Tr. 2242:6–2243:23,
    2246:16–2247:4 (Dr. Molina). Mr. Molina explained this his response to Wolf’s email that he
    “[a]gree[s] wholeheartedly” does not represent his real views; rather, he was merely placating a
    106
    board member before explaining his disagreement. Tr. 968:18–24 (Mr. Molina). He also stated
    that he was incorrect in his statement that Molina’s D-SNP plans are performing poorly. Tr.
    969:23–972:10 (Mr. Molina). (But in fact, Molina’s D-SNPs are not profitable, as Mr. Molina
    later testified at trial. Tr. 975:3–7 (Mr. Molina); see PX0106-077). Similarly, Mr. Molina
    described his apparent agreement with Schapiro on the pros and cons of the divestiture as not his
    true views, but just an attempt to softly disagree with a board member, rather than express his
    views more clearly. Tr. 976:22–977:10, 980:12–25 (Mr. Molina). Dr. Molina likewise explained
    his email exchange with Schapiro as merely “banter.” Tr. 2247:13–20 (Dr. Molina). He further
    testified that while he did not say so in the email, he disagreed with the statement that Molina
    doesn’t “have the internal talent” to manage the divestiture assets—in fact, he thinks the board was
    “ignorant of [Molina’s] capabilities” because he had failed at “making sure they’re better
    informed.” Tr. 2251:17–2252:4 (Dr. Molina).
    The Court is more persuaded by the contemporaneous email exchanges than by the in-court
    attempts to explain or disavow those documented exchanges. The totality of the evidence suggests
    that Molina is not likely to have the internal capacity—including IT, ability to manage star ratings,
    and necessary personnel and management—to successfully operate the divestiture plans so as to
    replace the competition lost by the merger. The emails are clear and blunt, and were made when
    the board, Dr. Molina, and Mr. Molina were deciding how to proceed. Although opinions can
    change and a single email is not determinative, taken as a whole these emails present a different
    view of Molina executives’ assessment of the company’s capacity to compete successfully than
    the view presented at trial. The explanations that Mr. Molina and Dr. Molina offered at trial—
    essentially, that they were not forthcoming in their communications with board members—are not
    credible. See Tr. 969:23–971:8 (Mr. Molina); Tr. 2251:17–2252:4 (Dr. Molina). And if those
    107
    explanations are true, then the Court would need to reject the fact that Molina’s board ultimately
    approved the transaction because by Mr. Molina’s and Dr. Molina’s own admissions, the board
    was being misinformed by senior executives. The Court cannot simultaneously consider the
    board’s ultimate approval of the transaction as evidence that Molina can compete successfully, yet
    disregard contemporaneous statements to the contrary.
    Moreover, while the ASA gives Molina some time to build its internal capabilities (and its
    provider networks), the ASA does not remedy Molina’s deficiencies. The Court will not rely too
    heavily on the ASA, because Aetna and Humana have no incentive to provide any assistance
    beyond the bare minimum during this period, lest they create too powerful a competitor. See
    Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 77; White Consol. 
    Indus., 781 F.2d at 1228
    . And more importantly, the
    ASA only gives Molina time to build its own capacity—it does nothing to provide Molina with
    the resources it would need to do so.
    In short, before even looking at Molina’s internal emails, there are reasons to doubt that it
    has the internal capabilities needed to manage the divestiture plans. Molina executives and board
    members have the same concerns, at least when expressing their views candidly at the time. It
    seems more likely that Molina and its board moved forward with the divestiture because, for the
    price, it was low-risk and high-reward for the company, despite their belief that Molina was not
    well positioned to be an effective competitor.
    iv.    Brand, Marketing, and Brokers
    Aetna and Humana argue that Molina will be able to retain many of the 290,000 members
    it acquires through the divestiture, and will be able to attract more members during the Annual
    Enrollment Period. The parties agree that Molina is not well-known in the Medicare Advantage
    space. Tr. 1350:3–9 (Bertolini); Tr. 2535:11–18 (Buckingham); Tr. 980:12–17 (Mr. Molina);
    108
    PX0271-809 (“I wonder how people will feel going from Aetna to a relatively unknown Molina
    in the [M]edicare space”). Defendants argue that brand name is often less important to retaining
    and attracting customers than network and plan benefits are. See Tr. 744:20–745:4 (Farley)
    (Humana able to compete successfully in markets where it did not have established brand); Tr.
    2514:13–2515:7 (Buckingham) (same); Tr. 2436:16–21 (Rubino) (brand is only one factor seniors
    consider); see also DX0419 ¶ 179 (national brand not correlated with success in a particular
    county). Perhaps, but there is contrary evidence in the record as well. See Tr. 289:15–22
    (Cocozza) (strong brand can compensate for other weaknesses); Tr. 794:25–795:12 (Farley)
    (Humana reputation strong enough to overcome $19 premium differential); Tr. 3340:4–3341:1
    (Orszag); PX0271-809. Defendants also argue that to the extent brand matters, Molina knows how
    to build its brand recognition due to its experience doing so in the public exchanges. See Tr.
    2208:15–21 (Dr. Molina); Tr. 2437:20–2438:17 (Rubino).           Molina contends that although
    Medicaid does not have individual enrollment like Medicare Advantage does, Molina has
    sufficient experience in its D-SNP and exchange plans to understand how to market itself to
    individuals. See Tr. 2236:18–2237:9 (Dr. Molina); see also Tr. 1242:16–21 (Burns) (Medicaid
    beneficiaries are automatically enrolled); Tr. 1214:20–1215:5 (Cavanaugh) (MMP members
    automatically enrolled). Finally, Molina argues that it knows how to build a broker network based
    on its experience in the exchanges, and will be able to successfully do so in Medicare Advantage.
    Tr. 2424:12–15, 2427:12–23, 2397:5–9 (Rubino); Tr. 967:1–2 (Mr. Molina), see also DX0136;
    DX0137.
    The Court concludes that brand is sometimes important to consumers and sometimes not,
    and that Molina does have some experience building its brand and finding brokers in new markets.
    Hence, the Court does not believe that lack of brand recognition, inexperience with marketing, and
    109
    lack of existing broker networks will be major barriers to Molina retaining and attracting new
    customers. However, based on all the evidence concerning Molina’s ability to successfully operate
    the divestiture Medicare Advantage plans, the Court finds that Molina is not likely to be able to
    replace fully the competition lost by the merger. Two other types of evidence—the low purchase
    price and Molina’s history in Medicare Advantage—also support this conclusion.
    (b) The Purchase Price
    The low purchase price raises concerns about whether Molina can be a successful
    competitor. There is no dispute that the price is extremely low. Dr. Molina testified that the usual
    purchase price for individual Medicare Advantage plans is $7,000–$10,000 per member, including
    statutory capital. Tr. 2250:9–14, 2251:8–13 (Dr. Molina). Mr. Molina wrote in an email that the
    usual price is $3,000–$5,000 per member, without statutory capital. See PX0100 (“Everyone
    acknowledges the bargain price paid- 400 per member vs normal px for these lives that seems to
    range from 3-5k”). Molina paid $1,400 per member with statutory capital, and $401 without. Tr.
    2251:9–14 (Dr. Molina); DX0262-234; DX0264-230. Indeed, Dr. Molina believes he got a
    “screaming good price,” as one of his board members described it. Tr. 2328:24–2329:6 (Dr.
    Molina); see also PX0100 (Mr. Molina describing it as a “bargain”). Defendants argue that the
    low price reflects the parties’ relative bargaining power: Aetna and Humana needed to find a
    divestiture buyer, and Molina knew that. The government counters that it reflects the riskiness of
    the transaction, and makes Molina more able to abandon many plans, counties, and members (i.e.,
    not adequately replace lost competition) while still making a profit given the modest outlay.
    The Remedies Guide acknowledges this possibility. It warns against the scenario where a
    divestiture purchaser is willing to buy assets at a “fire sale” price. Remedies Guide at 9. An
    extremely low purchase price reveals the divergent interest between the divestiture purchaser and
    110
    the consumer: an inexpensive acquisition could still “produce something of value to the purchaser”
    even if it does not become a significant competitor and therefore would not “cure the competitive
    concerns.” 
    Id. The Remedies
    Guide accurately captures the Court’s concern here. The emails
    sent by Molina executives and board members at the time of the divestiture agreement indicate
    their significant concerns with the viability of the divesture. They support the inference that the
    government urges the Court to draw from the low purchase price. Additional statements by Molina
    executives indicate that Molina might decide to withdraw from several of the divestiture counties
    in short order, and instead only compete in some—exactly as the Remedies Guide warns against.
    See, e.g., PX0090-195 (“[w]here there is low membership volume or potential we might reduce
    the county footprint”); Tr. 2493:8–2494:6 (Rubino) (confirming the same); Tr. 2403:16–2404:2
    (Rubino) (Molina will focus on building network in 12 top-tier states, before 9 second-tier states);
    PX0241-460 (identifying “key states”); PX0248-445 (identifying states for “immediate action”).
    The low purchase price thus further supports the conclusion that Molina has serious doubts about
    its own ability to manage all the divestiture plans but is willing to try given the low risk to the
    company reflected in the bargain price. That does not give the Court confidence in Molina’s ability
    to effectively replace the competition lost by the merger.
    (c) Molina’s History in the Individual Medicare Advantage Market
    Molina’s history in the individual Medicare Advantage market also raises concerns about
    its ability to successfully compete following the divestiture. Molina has repeatedly tried to enter
    the Medicare Advantage space but has not succeeded. Some of these efforts should have had the
    same advantages now submitted as reasons why Molina will succeed. For example, Molina began
    offering its individual Medicare Advantage plan in Utah in 2014, Tr. 2375:8–13 (Dr. Molina);
    PX707 at 1, where it had a Medicaid presence for 19 years and a D-SNP for 8 years, Tr. 2376:22–
    111
    2377:3 (Dr. Molina). Molina also launched this plan already having a relationship with a large
    provider, the University of Utah. PX707 at 1. But despite its existing brand presence, its
    relationship with a provider, its claimed care management knowledge, its capacity to build a strong
    provider network, and knowledge of marketing and brokers, the Utah plan has not been successful.
    It currently has just 400 members, and less than a 1% market share. Tr. 2380:17–2381:2 (Dr.
    Molina). Molina presents no explanation as to what would be different for the divestiture plans
    compared with the Utah plan. Much of the same is true for Molina’s individual Medicare
    Advantage plan in California, where Molina is headquartered, which has not succeeded and is no
    longer offered in 2017. While past performance is not perfectly predictive of the future, the Court
    gives some weight to Molina’s consistently unsuccessful attempts to enter Medicare Advantage,
    particularly since Molina’s theories for why this attempt would be different have not been borne
    out elsewhere.
    (d) Expert Testimony
    Finally, the Court’s conclusions are consistent with those of Dr. Burns, the government’s
    expert on divestitures. He testified regarding when divestitures fail and when they succeed, and
    concluded that the Molina divestiture does not have the characteristics of a successful divestiture.
    See generally PX0559 (Burns Report); PX0560 (Burns Reply Report). In his view, a successful
    health insurer has “six engines”: product development, sales and marketing, operations, member
    management, provider management, and care management. Tr. 1232:8–1233:8 (Burns). He
    testified that Molina did not have any of these, nor did the ASA provide it with them. Tr. 1238:21–
    1239:7 (Burns). Although the Court finds Burns’ framework helpful in understanding the evidence
    regarding the divestiture, ultimately the Court does not give significant weight to his analysis. He
    acknowledged that he conducted very little analysis specific to Molina or to this divestiture
    112
    agreement. See Tr. 1282:8–1283:18, 1285:17–1286:14 (Burns). Thus, while his framework is
    useful, for the most part his conclusions regarding Molina are not. Still, the Court’s conclusions,
    and the factors it has considered, are consistent with his analysis.
    5. Summary
    In sum, the Court finds that the divestiture would not “restore [the] competition” lost by
    the proposed merger. See Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 72; Remedies Guide at 1. Molina has
    demonstrated that the divestiture is likely enough for the Court to consider whether it would
    counteract the anticompetitive effects of the merger. But the evidence does not show that it would.
    Molina is primarily a Medicaid company. Although it has substantial experience serving
    the Medicaid population, the Court concludes that this experience will not transfer so as to enable
    it to be a successful competitor in the individual Medicare Advantage market. In particular, the
    Court finds persuasive the evidence that Molina would struggle to put together a competitive
    provider network in the available time frame. It would be especially difficult for Molina to create
    a value-based provider network—and Molina cannot effectively implement its care management
    capabilities without a value-based network. Internal Molina emails reveal the board, CFO, and
    CEO all doubted Molina’s ability to successfully operate the divestiture plans. That, combined
    with the extremely low purchase price, raises genuine concern about Molina’s prospects for broad
    success in the Medicare Advantage market. Finally, Molina’s history of unsuccessful attempts to
    expand into Medicare Advantage is telling, given that Molina has presented little explanation for
    why a different result is likely now. Ultimately, then, the Court concludes that the proposed
    divestiture would not ameliorate the anticompetitive effects of the merger.
    F. Conclusion Regarding Medicare Advantage
    113
    The government has established the existence of a product market for the sale of individual
    Medicare Advantage plans. When viewed within that market, and based on its significant HHI
    scores, the Aetna-Humana merger is presumptively unlawful in all 364 complaint counties. In
    further support of that presumption, there is clear evidence that the proposed merger would
    eliminate valuable head-to-head competition between two close rivals, one of which (Aetna) has
    been particularly aggressive in recent years. All of this evidence establishes that the merger is
    likely to substantially lessen competition. The companies’ rebuttal arguments are unpersuasive,
    whether assessed individually or altogether. Government regulation of Medicare Advantage does
    not preclude, or even substantially diminish, the likelihood of competitive harm. And neither entry
    by new competitors nor the proposed divestiture to Molina are likely to replace the competition
    eliminated by the merger. For all these reasons, the Court concludes that the merger of Aetna and
    Humana is likely to substantially lessen competition for the sale of individual Medicare Advantage
    plans in the 364 complaint counties in violation of section 7.
    II.   The Public Exchanges
    The government alleges that the effect of the merger between Aetna and Humana “may be
    to substantially lessen competition” in the public exchange markets in 17 counties in Florida,
    Georgia, and Missouri. 15 U.S.C. § 18; see Compl.¶ 47. The wrinkle here is that shortly after the
    complaint was filed, Aetna announced that it would no longer offer on-exchange plans for 2017 in
    any of those 17 counties. As discussed below, the parties vociferously disagree both as to why
    Aetna withdrew, and as to the legal implications of that decision. The market definition in this
    portion of the case is undisputed: each county is a separate geographic market, and on-exchange
    health plans is the relevant product market. But that’s where the agreement ends.
    114
    This section first discusses the difference between actual competition (the standard
    framework for analyzing antitrust claims) and potential competition (a never-embraced theory for
    antitrust liability), and concludes that the standard method of antitrust analysis is appropriate here.
    After a discussion of the legal implications of Aetna’s reasons for withdrawing from the 17
    counties, the Court assesses the evidence in order to answer the ultimate question whether the
    merger may substantially lessen competition in those markets.             For the merger to lessen
    competition, there must be competition to begin with. The Court finds that Aetna withdrew from
    the 17 counties to improve its litigation position. The Court further finds that Aetna is likely to
    compete in the public exchanges in only the three complaint counties in Florida after 2017, and
    that the merger may substantially lessen competition in those three counties.
    A. Legal Framework
    1. Actual Competition Versus Potential Competition
    The government argues that because Aetna decided not to offer plans on the exchanges in
    the 17 complaint counties for 2017 for the purpose of evading antitrust review of the proposed
    merger, the Court should act as if Aetna had not taken this action. Instead, the government
    proposes, the Court should look to the state of competition as it existed in 2016—when Aetna and
    Humana competed in all 17 counties—and project forward from there. It relies on a line of cases
    beginning with United States v. General Dynamics Corp., 
    415 U.S. 486
    , 504–05 (1974), that
    explain that a company’s post-merger behavior—specifically, decisions not to engage in
    anticompetitive activities while under government scrutiny—is a weak predictor of whether it will
    engage in anticompetitive actions in the future. This is for the “obvious” reason that companies
    could “stave off [enforcement] actions merely by refraining from aggressive or anticompetitive
    behavior when such a suit was threatened or pending.” Gen. 
    Dynamics, 415 U.S. at 504
    –05.
    115
    The companies, in contrast, argue that regardless of why Aetna chose not to offer plans on
    the exchanges in the 17 complaint counties in 2017, once the decision was made, that was the ball
    game. 36 They rely on the observation in International Shoe Co. v. FTC, 
    280 U.S. 291
    , 298 (1930),
    that an “acquisition will not produce the forbidden result if there be no pre-existing substantial
    competition to be affected.” Int’l 
    Shoe, 280 U.S. at 298
    . Rather, they argue, because Aetna is not
    offering plans on-exchange in 2017, the only possible lens through which the government could
    prove antitrust liability is the theory of “actual potential competition.” See Defs.’ Proposed
    Findings & Conclusions at 161. “Potential competition” is two separate theories: “perceived
    potential competition” and “actual potential competition.” United States v. Marine Bancorp., 
    418 U.S. 602
    , 623–625 (1974); see also Lewis A. Kaplan, Potential Competition and Section 7 of the
    Clayton Act, 25 Antitrust Bull. 297, 298–99 (1980) (explaining doctrines). The perceived potential
    competition theory posits that if market participants believe that a firm outside of the market is
    likely to enter, that perception can have a procompetitive effect on the market (whether or not that
    firm is actually likely to enter). See Marine 
    Bancorp., 418 U.S. at 624
    –25; United States v. Falstaff
    Brewing Corp., 
    410 U.S. 526
    , 537 (1973) (adopting doctrine). Thus, if the outside firm merges
    with a market participant, the elimination of that threat of entry can substantially lessen
    competition. Marine 
    Bancorp., 418 U.S. at 624
    –25. The actual potential competition theory
    asserts that a merger of a firm outside of the market with a firm inside of the market can
    substantially lessen competition if the outside firm would have entered the market anyway absent
    the merger. 
    Id. at 625.
    Whether actual potential competition is a viable theory of section 7 liability
    has not been answered by the Supreme Court. Id.; see also 
    Kaplan, supra, at 300
    –01. Indeed, the
    companies contend that it is a discredited legal theory, and thus the necessary implication of
    36
    The companies, of course, also contend that Aetna’s decision was not made to improve its ligation position.
    116
    adopting that framework here would be that the government’s case fails. See Defs.’ Proposed
    Findings & Conclusions at 161. Additionally, the companies argue that General Dynamics and its
    progeny are inapplicable because those cases are concerned with post-merger conduct, whereas
    the conduct here is pre-merger. 
    Id. at 152–57.
    Neither side’s analysis of the law is completely persuasive. Luckily, the case law itself
    provides clearer guidance.    The core question remains whether the proposed merger may
    substantially lessen competition.   See 15 U.S.C. § 18.       Antitrust law is concerned with a
    “company’s future ability to compete,” Gen. 
    Dynamics, 415 U.S. at 501
    , and deals in
    “probabilities, not certainties,” Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 323
    . While there can be no substantial
    lessening of competition if there is no pre-existing competition to begin with, see Int’l 
    Shoe, 280 U.S. at 298
    , the case law does not support defendants’ approach of viewing competition as an on-
    off switch where a merging party can simply switch it off entirely by withdrawing from a market
    (potentially temporarily). Rather, courts routinely view competitors that may have one foot in and
    one foot out of the market as actual competitors, and evaluate the anticompetitive effects of a
    merger using the standard tools of antitrust analysis. Supreme Court cases discussing the “actual
    potential competition” doctrine describe a situation wholly unlike the one present here, and thus
    are not the appropriate framework for evaluating this case.
    Other courts, including the Supreme Court, have viewed competitors who were marginally
    in the market as “actual competitors.” This line of cases begins with United States v. El Paso
    Natural Gas Co., 
    376 U.S. 651
    (1964). There, El Paso purchased Pacific Northwest Pipeline
    Corporation. 
    Id. at 652–53.
    In simplified terms, El Paso had a contract with the primary gas
    distributor for Southern California, effectively blocking Pacific Northwest out of the market. 
    Id. at 654–55.
    But Pacific Northwest had competed for that contract (unsuccessfully), and had made
    117
    other efforts to break into the California market in the past. 
    Id. The Court
    analyzed El Paso’s
    acquisition of Pacific Northwest as a merger between actual competitors, rather than a merger
    between one competitor and one potential competitor. 
    Id. at 659–662;
    see also Marine 
    Bancorp., 418 U.S. at 623
    (stating that El Paso was an actual competitor, not potential competitor, case).
    Two other cases from courts of appeals are instructive. In Polypore International, Inc. v.
    FTC, 
    686 F.3d 1208
    (11th Cir. 2012), the Eleventh Circuit considered whether a battery parts
    manufacturer (Microporous) was in the automotive battery market, or only in the motive battery
    market (motive batteries are used in industrial machinery). Polypore 
    Int’l, 686 F.3d at 1211
    .
    Microporous had made numerous attempts to enter the automotive battery parts market in recent
    years, including beginning contract negotiations with one buyer and entering a memorandum of
    understanding with another. 
    Id. at 1212.
    But at the time that Microporous was acquired by
    Polypore, it was not actually selling any products in the automotive battery market. 
    Id. at 1211.
    The court rejected Polypore’s argument that Microporous should be analyzed as a potential
    competitor, not an actual competitor. 
    Id. at 1213–16.
    It explained that, as in El Paso, although the
    “acquired company had not actually sold [any products] in the market,” section 7 is “concerned
    with probabilities, not certainties.” 
    Id. at 1214.
    Moreover, Microporous was already selling a
    similar product in the motive battery market, and had taken actions to try to shift that product line
    into the automotive battery market for the future—indicating that it was actually a competitor in
    the automotive battery market despite not yet making any sales in that market. 
    Id. at 1214–15.
    The Ninth Circuit reached a similar conclusion in a case that has some echoes of this one.
    In FTC v. Warner Communications, Inc., 
    742 F.2d 1156
    (9th Cir. 1984), Warner, the parent
    company of three record labels, proposed a joint venture and partial merger with Polygram
    Records, a smaller record company. 
    Id. at 1159.
    Polygram argued that it “intend[ed] to leave the
    118
    distribution market due to economic necessity,” 37 and thus the merger could not have an
    anticompetitive effect. 
    Id. at 1164.
    The court rejected this theory, holding “that a company’s
    stated intention to leave the market . . . does not in itself justify a merger.” 
    Id. at 1165.
    The companies’ favored line of authority involves entirely different scenarios. They urge
    this Court to apply Marine Bancorporation and Falstaff Brewing instead. These cases discuss the
    potential competition theory of antitrust liability.
    Aetna and Humana argue that the actual potential competition theory is the only legitimate
    lens through which to analyze the government’s case. But that ignores the facts of the two Supreme
    Court cases discussing the doctrine and how far distant they are from the scenario at hand. In
    Marine Bancorporation, the Supreme Court considered Marine, a bank with locations in the Seattle
    area, that proposed acquiring Washington Trust Bank, a bank with locations only in the Spokane
    area. Marine 
    Bancorp., 418 U.S. at 606
    –07. Marine never had any locations near Spokane, had
    never attempted to enter the Spokane market, had no plans to do so, and under state law, it would
    have been nearly impossible for it to enter the Spokane market de novo. 
    Id. at 624–639.
    Hence,
    the Court held that even assuming the actual potential competition doctrine is valid, there was no
    section 7 violation. 
    Id. at 639.
    Falstaff Brewing primarily concerned perceived potential entry, which is not at issue here.
    See Defs.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions at 161 (specifying “actual potential competition
    theory”). In that case, Falstaff, a beer brewing company with a presence across the nation but not
    in New England, acquired Narraganset, a local New England brewery. Falstaff 
    Brewing, 410 U.S. at 527
    –29. The district court found that Falstaff had decided not to enter the market de novo
    regardless of the acquisition. 
    Id. at 530–31.
    It did not consider the government’s perceived
    37
    Polygram was not asserting the “failing company” defense, which is an affirmative defense to a section 7
    violation. 
    Id. at 1164
    (citing Int’l 
    Shoe, 280 U.S. at 302
    ).
    119
    potential entrant theory. 
    Id. at 532–33.
    The Supreme Court explicitly did not reach the question
    whether the actual potential competition theory is valid, but instead remanded for the district court
    to consider the perceived potential competition theory. 
    Id. at 537–38.
    The facts here are unquestionably much closer to those in El Paso, Polypore, and Warner,
    than to those in Marine Bancorporation and Falstaff Brewing. None of the cases are on all fours
    with this one—indeed, it is hard to imagine there could be such a case given the idiosyncrasies of
    the health insurance market—but El Paso and its ilk are closer in relevant ways. Here, like
    Polygram’s past participation in the market in Warner, Aetna offered health insurance plans in all
    17 of the challenged markets in 2016 and before. Like Microporous in Polypore, Aetna continues
    to offer very similar products in adjacent markets—both geographically nearby (plans on other
    public exchanges) and conceptually nearby (off-exchange plans in all 17 counties, see Tr.
    1465:12–15 (Kelmar)). And similar to Pacific Northwest in El Paso, there are indications that
    Aetna will once again attempt to compete in the challenged markets in the near future. It is
    undisputed that Aetna could compete in those markets after 2017, see Tr. 1541:7–16 (Mayhew),
    and that at the time the merger agreement was entered and the complaint was filed, Aetna planned
    on competing in those markets in 2017 and subsequent years, see PX0112 at 10.
    This case is wholly unlike the facts described in Marine Bancorporation, where state laws
    blocked Marine from competing in the market of the firm it sought to acquire. Moreover, neither
    Marine nor Falstaff ever had a market presence in the relevant geographic market—the reason for
    their respective acquisitions was to expand into a new geographic market—which is just the
    opposite of Aetna and Humana, which both had a market presence in the 17 counties through 2016.
    120
    Regardless of why Aetna withdrew from the public exchanges in the 17 counties, then, this
    case is closer to El Paso than to Marine Bancorporation and Falstaff Brewing. 38 The Court will
    therefore employ the standard tools of section 7 analysis to ascertain the effects of the proposed
    merger on future competition, and determine whether the proposed merger will substantially lessen
    competition in the challenged markets. See Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 988
    (“[p]redicting future
    competitive conditions . . . calls for comprehensive inquiry”).
    Where the government has alleged that Aetna acted intentionally in order to evade judicial
    review, it would be especially inappropriate to apply a legal framework that would limit judicial
    inquiry. Courts appropriately guard their ability to ascertain the actual facts at issue, rather than
    allow a party to thwart judicial review through its own machinations. See, e.g., United States v.
    W.T. Grant Co., 
    345 U.S. 629
    , 632 (1953) (“voluntary cessation of allegedly illegal conduct does
    not deprive the tribunal of power to hear and determine the case” because “courts have rightly
    refused to grant defendants such a powerful weapon against public law enforcement”); United
    States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Ass’n, 
    166 U.S. 290
    , 309 (1897) (“The defendants cannot
    foreclose [the public’s] rights [under the Sherman Act] by any such action as has been taken in
    this case.”). Employing only the lens of the actual potential competition theory here would prevent
    the Court from undertaking its obligation to conduct a close analysis of the effects of the proposed
    merger on future competition. That would create incentives for firms to take similar actions in the
    future to evade antitrust review. This, then, is an independent reason not to adopt the companies’
    view that the only relevant legal framework is one of actual potential competition.
    2. Whether Aetna’s Reasons for Withdrawal Matter
    38
    The Court expresses no opinion on whether actual potential competition is a viable antitrust theory.
    121
    Once the Court’s analysis is guided by the El Paso line of cases, the framework for how to
    evaluate the implications of Aetna’s reasons for its withdrawal from the exchanges for 2017
    becomes clearer.     The ultimate question is whether the merger may substantially lessen
    competition on the public exchanges in the 17 counties. Again, for competition to be lessened,
    there must necessarily be competition to begin with. See Int’l 
    Shoe, 280 U.S. at 298
    . Thus, there
    can be no lessening of competition for 2017. The Court will not adopt the government’s proposed
    approach of simply ignoring the reality that Aetna is not offering plans for 2017 in the relevant
    markets, and pretend that the facts are frozen as they were in 2016.
    But the Court is not limited to looking just at 2017. Analyzing the anticompetitive effects
    of the proposed merger necessarily “focus[es] on the future.” See Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 991
    .
    None of the cases cited by either party indicate that the analysis is limited to one year. Indeed, no
    case identifies a specific timeframe at all, and even the defendants do not argue that the Court is
    limited to considering only one year. While predictions too far in the future risk becoming mere
    “ephemeral possibilities,” 
    Falstaff, 410 U.S. at 563
    , an assessment that only looks at one year fails
    to determine “the probable effect of the merger upon the future as well as the present which the
    Clayton Act commands the courts . . . to examine,” Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 333
    . Rather, the
    proper timeframe for evaluating the effects of the merger on future competition must be
    “functionally viewed, in the context of its particular industry.” See Brown 
    Shoe, 370 U.S. at 321
    –
    22. In the health insurance industry, firms routinely plan more than one year out, and the evidence
    the Court heard about a firm’s future behavior and the competitive effects of that behavior applies
    not just to the following year. See, e.g., PX0324 (“Vision 2020,” Aetna’s five-year plan including
    Humana acquisition). While the Court need not specify the exact time frame for considering the
    122
    competitive effects of the proposed merger, it must look at 2018, 2019, and 2020 because the firms
    make business decisions and projections over that time frame.
    The question then becomes whether Aetna will compete in the 17 counties after 2017, and
    whether the merger will substantially lessen that competition. “Predicting future competitive
    conditions in a given market, as the statute and precedents require, calls for a comprehensive
    inquiry.” Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 988
    . One piece of evidence is the fact that Aetna chose not
    to compete in the 17 complaint counties in 2017. If that decision was made for sound business
    reasons, the Court might consider it to be powerful evidence that Aetna would not compete in
    those markets in 2018 and beyond. But if that decision was made to improve Aetna’s litigation
    position, then it would be weak evidence of Aetna’s likely future conduct. The Supreme Court
    has recognized this simple proposition. See Gen. 
    Dynamics, 415 U.S. at 504
    –05. Lower courts
    have as well, and have expanded it to include evidence that “could arguably be subject to
    manipulation.” See Chicago Bridge & Iron Co. v. FTC, 
    534 F.3d 410
    , 435 (5th Cir. 2008) (some
    emphasis omitted); Hosp. Corp. of Am. v. FTC, 
    807 F.2d 1381
    , 1384 (7th Cir. 1986) (“We agree
    with the Commission that it was not required to take account of a post-acquisition transaction that
    may have been made to improve [defendant’s] litigating position.”); see also United States v.
    Bazaarvoice, Inc., No. 13-cv-00133-WHO, 
    2014 WL 203966
    , at *73 (N.D. Cal. Jan. 8, 2014).39
    The companies argue that these cases are inapposite because they concern a firm’s actions post-
    39
    The parties spend significant pages arguing about the import of FTC v. Libbey, Inc., 
    211 F. Supp. 2d 34
    (D.D.C. 2002). That case is only marginally relevant. In Libbey, the merging parties revised their agreement after
    the FTC decided to seek an injunction to identify a proposed divestiture in an attempt to alleviate some of the FTC’s
    
    concerns. 211 F. Supp. 2d at 42
    n.21. The court noted that the revisions were not an attempt “to evade FTC and
    judicial review,” but rather to alleviate anticompetitive effects of the merger. 
    Id. at 46.
    Like the proposed divestiture
    to Molina in this case, the parties’ there attempted to alleviate the anticompetitive effects of the merger through a
    divestiture, and that proposed divestiture was then reviewed by the court. The Libbey court likewise noted that some
    parties might revise an agreement in an “unscrupulous[] attempt to avoid judicial review and FTC review,” but did
    not discuss how it would approach that problem given that it did not arise. See 
    id. at 46
    n.27. Thus, Libbey provides
    little guidance concerning the proper approach here.
    123
    merger, rather than after merger was agreed to but before it was consummated, as is the case here.
    That is a distinction without a difference. These cases embody the common-sense proposition that
    a firm’s behavior undertaken with the aim of persuading a court or the government regarding the
    legality of a merger may not be predictive of how that firm will behave once the court or the
    government are no longer engaged. This holds true whether the actions in question are after the
    merger was announced or after it was consummated. 40
    Thus, the Court considers the fact that Aetna is not offering plans in the 17 complaint
    counties in 2017 as one piece of evidence about whether Aetna will offer plans in the 17 complaint
    counties in 2018 and beyond. The Court will give that evidence the weight it deserves—less if
    Aetna withdrew for the purpose of improving its litigation position; more if Aetna withdrew for
    sound business reasons. Ultimately, if the Court finds that Aetna is likely to offer plans on the
    exchanges in any of the 17 complaint counties in 2018 and later, then the Court will assess whether
    the merger would substantially lessen competition in any of those counties.
    B. Analysis
    1. Aetna Withdrew From the Complaint Counties to Improve its Litigation Position
    Based on the facts presented at trial, the Court finds that Aetna withdrew from the 17
    complaint counties for 2017 at least in part for the purpose of improving its litigation position.
    There is significant evidence—primarily in the form of contemporaneous emails among senior
    Aetna executives—that Aetna thought of the 17 complaint counties as one unit, and that it
    withdrew from those 17 counties to improve its position in this lawsuit. The companies presented
    40
    The Hart-Scott-Rodino Act of 1976, 15 U.S.C. § 18a, requires firms to alert the Department of Justice and
    the FTC before certain mergers are consummated, and allow time for the government to conduct an investigation and
    seek an injunction pre-consummation. See Bazaarvoice, 
    2014 WL 203966
    , at *75 (explaining effect of Act). Pre-
    and post-merger suits are routinely analyzed identically. See, e.g., Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 987
    (relying on pre-
    and post-merger cases); H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 51–52.
    124
    evidence of how unprofitable the public exchanges around the country were, and argued that Aetna
    withdrew as a business decision. But while that evidence tends to show that Aetna had good
    business reasons for reducing its exchange footprint across the country, it does not show that Aetna
    withdrew from these specific counties for business reasons.
    A review of the timeline is a helpful place to start. The key dates to keep in mind are July
    21, 2016, when the complaint was filed, and August 15, 2016, when Aetna announced that it would
    not be offering on-exchange plans for 2017 in 11 of the 15 states where it had participated during
    2016. Prior to filing the complaint, DOJ conducted an investigation. During that time, Aetna
    executives had multiple meetings with both DOJ and HHS, where Aetna connected this lawsuit
    with its future participation in the exchanges. Also prior to the complaint being filed, starting on
    July 9, 2016, a team of senior Aetna executives was considering Aetna’s future participation in the
    exchanges across the country. It is the internal documents and emails that this team produced that
    are ultimately the most illuminating.
    (a) Public Exchange Participation as Connected to the Merger
    Aetna and its CEO, Mark Bertolini, have long been supporters of the public exchanges.
    Tr. 1350:13–19, Tr. 1386:21–1387:5 (Bertolini). Bertolini believes that “every American should
    be insured,” and that doing so through the exchanges is a good business opportunity. Tr. 1387:4–
    5, 1351:1–22 (Berolini); PX0112 at 4 (Aetna Q1 2016 earnings call); PX0162 at 6 (Aetna Q3 2015
    earnings call). He has consistently expressed a desire for Aetna to “have a seat at the table” and
    to help ensure everyone is covered.       Tr. 1473:15–19 (Kelmar); Tr. 1387:4–13, 1390:9–12
    (Bertolini).
    During the investigation but before the complaint was filed, Aetna tried to leverage its
    participation in the exchanges for favorable treatment from DOJ regarding the proposed merger.
    125
    On May 11, 2016, Bertolini was deposed in DOJ’s investigation. At that deposition, Aetna’s
    counsel stated that if Aetna was not “happy” with the results of an upcoming meeting regarding
    the merger, “we’re just going to pull out of all the exchanges.” Tr. 1353:6–10 (Bertolini). Bertolini
    affirmed his counsel, stating “Nice.” Tr. 1353:15–18 (Bertolini). The next day, Bertolini, Steven
    Kelmar (Aetna’s Executive VP and Bertolini’s Chief of Staff) and HHS Secretary Sylvia Burwell
    (among others) had a meeting. There, Kelmar told Secretary Burwell that if the merger was
    blocked, Aetna “would likely have to revisit its plans for and presence on the public exchanges.”
    Tr. 1354:2–6 (Bertolini); Tr. 1453:12–23 (Kelmar); PX0134 at 7 (Aetna’s third response to
    interrogatories). In a phone call on June 15, 2016, Bertolini told Secretary Burwell “if, by chance,
    you get a reach-out from the DOJ about us as a candidate for this merger, I would appreciate a
    good word for all that we’ve done with you.” Tr. 1356:21–23 (Bertolini); see also PX0134 at 7.
    In preparation for that call, Kelmar sent Bertolini talking points that drew the connection between
    Aetna’s participation in the exchanges and the merger more explicitly, stating: “By getting this
    deal done, I can make the commitment that we will expand our exchange footprint and continue
    to take a leadership position on expanding the value of exchanges to a greater part of the
    population,” and, conversely, “[i]f we can’t get to a good path forward on this deal the break-up
    fee of 1 billion dollars will significantly impact our business model and have some very tough
    consequences for us and the market.” PX0113; Tr. 1454:18–1456:2 (Kelmar).
    Ultimately, Bertolini expressed this sentiment in a July 5, 2016, letter to DOJ (and
    forwarded to Secretary Burwell) where he stated: “if the DOJ sues to enjoin the transaction, we
    will immediately take action to reduce our 2017 exchange footprint”; “we would also withdraw
    from at least five additional states”; and if the merger is blocked, “we believe it is very likely that
    we would need to leave the public exchange business entirely.” PX0117 at 2; Tr. 1357:19–
    126
    1358:24, Tr. 1359:20–1360:1 (Bertolini); PX0118. Bertolini expressed a similar sentiment in a
    later email with Ron Williams, the former CEO of Aetna, after the complaint was filed, where he
    wrote that “the administration has a very short memory, absolutely no loyalty and a very thin skin.”
    PX0131; Tr. 1365:22–1366:1 (Bertolini). When asked during his deposition what he meant by
    that, Bertolini explained that “it was about my involvement in helping them get the Affordable
    Care Act structured and properly done. And so that was our feeling was that we were doing good
    things for the administration and the administration is suing us.” Bertolini Oct. 11, 2016 Dep.
    127:20–128:6, admitted at Tr. 1367:9–15 (Bertolini).
    This evidence shows that Aetna and its CEO, Bertolini, viewed participation on the
    exchanges as closely connected to DOJ’s attempt to block the merger. Bertolini believed that DOJ
    should not block the merger in view of Aetna’s role in advancing the ACA and participating in the
    exchanges, and Aetna was willing to offer to expand its participation in the exchanges if DOJ did
    not block the merger, or conversely, was willing to threaten to limit its participation in the
    exchanges if DOJ did. This is persuasive evidence that when Aetna later withdrew from the 17
    counties, it did not do so for business reasons, but instead to follow through on the threat that it
    made earlier. But the most persuasive evidence is yet to come—internal Aetna documents and
    emails showing the factors that went into its decision-making process.
    (b) Aetna’s Decision-Making Process
    Starting in early July, Bertolini convened a team of senior executives to evaluate Aetna’s
    participation in the exchanges. Tr. 1360:17–22, 1362:5–1363:17 (Bertolini). This was prompted
    by information that Bertolini received on July 9 that Aetna had suffered large second quarter losses
    in its public exchange business. Tr. 1362:5–25 (Bertolini). The team included Karen Lynch,
    Aetna’s President, Sean Guertin, Aetna’s CFO, Jonathan Mayhew, the head of Aetna’s exchange
    127
    business, Fran Soistman, Aetna’s Executive Vice President and head of government services,
    Kelmar, and Tom Sabatino, Aetna’s General Counsel. Tr. 1363:1–17 (Bertolini); Tr. 1476:13–
    1477:6 (Lynch). This team ultimately put together a set of recommendations regarding how to
    reduce Aetna’s exchange footprint that Bertolini approved without alteration in mid-August. Tr.
    1449:21–1450:8 (Bertolini); Tr. 1473:23–1474:1 (Kelmar); Tr. 1497:19–24 (Lynch).
    The day the complaint was filed, Aetna employees were instructed to gather information
    regarding the 17 complaint counties. PX0220-290. The team evaluating Aetna’s exchange
    participation jumped into action as well. The following day, Soistman wrote in an email: “By the
    way, all bets are off on Florida and every other state given the DOJ rejected our transaction.”
    PX0121-106. Later, he wrote to Kelmar: “I also need to share with you what I’ve learned about
    the 17 counties in the DOJ’s complaint. We have a very narrow window of opportunity to affect
    changes in footprint particular with the off exchange business.” PX0122-638. Soistman forwarded
    that email to Lynch saying: “I need to share with you what I learned during my meeting. Did not
    want to involve you officially as it may get ugly.” PX0122-638. The following day, July 23,
    Kelmar asked Soistman: “Do the counties in the suit overlap with Humana’s recent announcement
    of withdraw [sic]?” PX0124-626. When Soistman responded that “Humana remains in all 17
    counties,” Kelmar wrote: “Then that makes it easy we need to withdraw from those.” PX0124-
    626 41; Tr. 1460:10–1461:6 (Kelmar). At the same time, Kelmar told Lynch: “Most of this is a
    business decision except where DOJ has been explicit about the exchange markets. There we have
    no choice.” PX0125; Tr.1462:4–13 (Kelmar). Lynch responded: “Agree.” PX0125.
    41
    On July 21, 2016, Humana announced that it would only offer on-exchange plans for 2017 in 11 states,
    rather than the 15 where it offered on-exchange plans in 2016. Humana’s announcement did not affect any of the
    counties identified in the complaint, and there is no allegation that Humana’s decision was related to this litigation.
    128
    The following day, the team took steps to update their recommendations to include the 17
    complaint counties, without a business analysis of the exchanges in those locations. Mayhew sent
    Lynch a draft document entitled (in part) “Strategic Options for 2017 Footprint.” PX0126 at 4;
    PX0127; Tr. 1481:9–1483:1 (Lynch); Tr. 1505:15–22 (Mayhew). Lynch responded, asking:
    “Does this include the 17 places in the DOJ complaint[?]” PX0127; Tr. 1483:2–11 (Lynch).
    In response, Mayhew began what would become a series of emails where Aetna executives
    tried to conceal from discovery in this litigation the reasoning behind their recommendation to
    withdraw from the 17 complaint counties. Mayhew explained: “I was told to be careful about
    putting any of that in writing. I will have the attorney client privilege ccd by tomorrow.” PX0127.
    Mayhew acknowledged at trial that he was told to include the reference to attorney-client privilege
    so as to prevent these documents from being produced in this litigation. Tr. 1508:3–7 (Mayhew).
    He agreed that the purpose of shielding these documents was to conceal how Aetna was handling
    the decisions about its exchange footprint. See Tr. 1509:7–11 (Mayhew). Lynch also relayed to
    Soistman the same concern. She told Soistman that bcc’ing her on an email “doesn’t protect” the
    document because “it shows on the scan,” which she explained referred to the scan “they do for
    discovery.”      PX0122-638; Tr. 1489:24–1491:24 (Lynch). 42                  Mayhew acknowledged Aetna
    executives instructed each other to call, rather than email, to avoid creating a written trail that
    could be revealed in discovery. Tr. 1509:7–11 (Mayhew); PX0122-638 (“Best we talk live.”);
    PX0124 (“Can you take another quick call?”).
    Despite these efforts, relevant documents were revealed in discovery. On Sunday, July
    24—after conferring with Soistman, Kelmar, and Lynch—Mayhew instructed his team to update
    42
    At trial, Lynch explained that this statement expressed her concern that Aetna should be transparent in its
    decision-making process, rather than reflecting an attempt to shield its decision-making process from discovery. Tr.
    1491:23–24 (Lynch). The Court does not credit this explanation.
    129
    the document reflecting options for Aetna’s exchange footprint with the 17 counties. PX0128-
    987; Tr. 1509:12–1511:18 (Mayhew). The newly updated document not only recommended
    exiting all 17 complaint counties, but also broke them out as a separate bullet point, rather than
    including the counties (or states) in a list with others that the team recommended exiting. See
    PX0129-243 (stating “Exit targeted service areas (17 counties in total; 3 states)”). A document
    from August 2, 2016 reflected this same difference in how the 17 counties were treated, compared
    with how every other geographic market was treated. In this summary spreadsheet describing one
    potential scenario for Aetna’s exchange footprint moving forward, a series of states and regions
    are listed, followed by one entry for “17 Counties.” PX0130 at 4.
    Other documents and testimony also indicate that the team of executives did not evaluate
    the profitability of the 17 counties in the same manner as it did for the other states from which
    Aetna was considering withdrawing. Lynch testified that the team never assessed the profitability
    of Aetna’s individual business in the 17 complaint counties. Tr. 1498:1–9 (Lynch). Had they done
    so, they would have seen that Aetna chose to withdraw from some profitable states and stay in
    some unprofitable ones. See DX0009-002. Aetna chose to remain on-exchange in Delaware,
    Iowa, Nebraska and Virginia—all projected to be unprofitable for 2016—yet withdrew from
    Florida, which is projected to be profitable on-exchange. DX0009-002. In fact, Florida is
    projected to be unprofitable off-exchange, and only profitable overall because of the strength of
    its on-exchange business. DX0009-002; Tr. 2758:6–2759:1 (Guertin). Florida was Aetna’s third
    most profitable state for its on-exchange business in 2015 and the first half of 2016. Tr. 2756:14–
    2757:18 (Guertin); DX0009-002. (Both Missouri and Georgia were projected to be unprofitable
    for 2016, on-exchange and overall. DX0009-002). Ultimately, the team recommended to Bertolini
    130
    that Aetna withdraw from Florida, Georgia, Missouri, and eight other states. 43 Tr. 1497:12–18
    (Lynch). Bertolini adopted this recommendation without change. Tr. 1449:21–1450:8 (Bertolini).
    The inescapable conclusion from these contemporaneous emails and documents is that the
    Aetna team making recommendations to Bertolini did not view withdrawing from the 17 complaint
    counties as a business decision. Rather, it saw the other potential withdrawal states as business
    decisions, but there was “no choice” about these 17 counties. The emails between Soistman,
    Mayhew, Kelmar, and Lynch demonstrate that each of them viewed the 17 counties as a separate
    bloc from the other locations under consideration. The documents regarding the recommendation
    to Bertolini reflect the same dichotomy between the 17 complaint counties (included for non-
    business reasons) and the other states (included for business reasons). Lynch’s admission that the
    team did not consider the profitability of those counties strongly supports the inference that Aetna
    withdrew from them for litigation-related reasons. And for the Florida on-exchange markets, the
    underlying data regarding profitability supports this inference as well. Moreover, although seeking
    advice of counsel and protecting documents under the attorney-client privilege does not by itself
    indicate malfeasance, repeated efforts to conceal a paper trail about this decision-making process
    (rather than to actually seek legal guidance) do give rise to such an inference. Collectively, then,
    the evidence provides persuasive support for the conclusion that Aetna withdrew from the on-
    exchange markets in the 17 complaint counties to improve its litigation position. The Court does
    not credit the minimal efforts of Aetna executives to claim otherwise.
    (c) The Florida Market President’s Reaction
    The reaction of Christopher Ciano, Aetna’s Florida Market President—who was not
    involved in the decision—demonstrates how far outside of normal business practice this decision
    43
    Due to time constraints, Aetna believed that if it wanted to withdraw from those 17 counties, it needed to
    withdraw from those three states entirely, and so, the team recommended it do so. Tr. 1518:12–1519:2 (Mayhew).
    131
    was. He wrote to Mayhew on August 4: “Really disappointed we are pulling the plug on Florida.”
    PX0132-565. Ciano followed up with “I just can’t make sense out of the Florida decision . . .
    Never thought we would pull the plug all together. Based on the latest run rate data . . . we are
    making money from the on-exchange business. Was Florida’s performance ever debated?”
    PX0132-565. Mayhew responded with a request to discuss via phone “instead of email.” PX0132-
    565. As Mayhew explained in court, these requests for phone calls were an attempt to avoid
    leaving a paper trail. Tr. 1509:7–11, 1508:3–7 (Mayhew). Ciano’s reaction to Aetna’s decision
    underscores that it was not a business decision. He specifically identifies that Florida is profitable,
    and that withdrawing from the whole state (rather than from underperforming counties, or less
    profitable off-exchange products) was never really discussed. Mayhew makes clear in his response
    that he does not want Aetna’s reasons to be known to DOJ.
    (d) Aetna’s Explanation That It Made a Business Decision
    Aetna argues that it in fact made a business decision to withdraw from the exchanges in
    the 17 counties for 2017. Aetna notes that it has been losing money in the public exchange markets
    nationally. It contends that there are structural problems that explain this, and that are unlikely to
    be fixed. And although until recently Aetna believed it was worth it to accept a short-term loss in
    this product line (assuming it would eventually turn a profit), the financial information received in
    July changed its perspective. This, Aetna argues, explains its turn-around and ultimate decision to
    withdraw from 11 states that include the 17 complaint counties.
    Aetna has been losing money on the exchanges since the beginning. In 2014, Aetna
    predicted it would lose $70 million, and instead lost $100 million. Tr. 2672:18–2673:23, 2675:9–
    15 (Guertin). Nevertheless, it concluded it would “keep going forward” despite the losses, because
    it expected that a new market would be unprofitable for an initial period Tr. 2672:18–2673:23,
    132
    2675:9–15 (Guertin); DX0038. For 2015, Aetna projected a $100 million profit, but ultimately
    lost $131 million. Tr. 2680:14–20, 2694:20–23 (Guertin). However, Aetna was more optimistic
    for 2016. Because the exchanges were so new, Aetna’s profit projections and plan pricing for
    2014 and 2015 were largely guesswork; but going into 2016, it had claims data and therefore
    expected to be able to make more accurate predictions. Tr. 2689:22–2690:5 (Guertin). Aetna
    expected to make a “modest profit” in the exchanges in 2016. Tr. 2689:18 (Guertin).
    In part, Aetna and Humana attribute thier financial loss to features of the exchange markets.
    For example, the requirement that all individuals purchase health insurance coverage was designed
    to ensure that the pool of individuals who purchased insurance on the exchanges included both
    healthier individuals who might be tempted to forego insurance, as well as sicker individuals. See
    Tr. 1830:17–19 (Broussard); Tr. 2675:21–2676:9 (Guertin); DX-0019-005; cf. Tr. 2617:16–
    2619:3 (Counihan). But because the penalties for failing to purchase insurance were set too low,
    many individuals paid the penalty rather than paying for insurance. DX0149-001; Tr. 2676:2–9
    (Guertin). Thus, the pool of individuals purchasing insurance was, on the whole, sicker (and
    therefore costlier) than expected. DX0004; DX0019-002; DX0032-011. 44
    The exchanges also include three programs designed specifically to ensure stability in the
    marketplaces, known colloquially as the “three Rs”: risk adjustment, risk corridors, and
    reinsurance.       As Kevin Counihan, the CMS official responsible for overseeing the public
    44
    There are other attributes of the markets that, the parties essentially agree, contributed to this costlier-than-
    expected pool of insurance purchasers. For example, under the “Keep What You Have Program,” consumers who
    purchased insurance pre-ACA were able to keep it, and thus did not enter the exchange markets. These consumers
    were largely healthier (in part because, pre-ACA, individual insurance was only available to relatively healthy
    individuals). See Tr. 2674:9–2675:6 (Guertin); Tr. 1379:20–1380:10 (Bertolini); Tr. 1829:21–1830:4 (Broussard);
    DX0150-001. Part of this program expires at the end of 2017. Tr. 2740:25–2741:17 (Guertin); Tr. 1436:1–5
    (Bertolini). Likewise, CMS adopted relaxed rules permitting consumers to purchase insurance during “special
    enrollment periods” outside of the annual open enrollment period. Tr. 1830:5–12 (Broussard); Tr. 1373:15–1374:16
    (Bertolini); DX0302-011; DX0019-005. This functionally allowed consumers to buy plans when they were sick and
    cancel them when they were healthy. See Tr. 1830:5–12 (Broussard). CMS has recently tightened these rules. Tr.
    1433:2–22 (Bertolini); Tr. 2650:9–2651:1 (Counihan); DX0158-002.
    133
    exchanges, explained, both risk corridors and reinsurance were designed to be temporary—they
    expired at the end of 2016—because they only compensate for the difficulties in accurately pricing
    insurance and predicting the risk pool for a new market. Tr. 2615:23–25 (Counihan). The risk
    corridor program was designed to limit insurers’ losses and gains to account for inaccurate
    premium-setting when insurers did not have sufficient data to properly price their plans. DX0547-
    003. The reinsurance program was designed to protect insurers who incurred unexpectedly high
    claims costs for individual enrollees who had higher-than-expected medical costs. Tr. 2613:18–
    21 (Guertin). The risk adjustment program is the only one that continues to operate after 2016. It
    is designed to spread risk among insurers by subsidizing insurers with sicker-than-average
    members through payments from insurers with healthier-than-average members. Tr. 2671:14–
    2672:13 (Guertin). However, it is a zero-sum program; thus, if all insurers have an overall
    membership that is costlier-than-expected, there are no funds to distribute. See Tr. 1375:9–21
    (Bertolini).
    But Congress has not funded these programs as expected, and therefore CMS has not paid
    out the anticipated amounts due to insurers—including Aetna—under these programs. For 2014,
    insurers as a whole requested $2.87 billion, but CMS only paid $362 million. Tr. 2612:11–20
    (Counihan). CMS has not made any risk corridor payments for 2015 or 2016. Tr. 2613:12–17
    (Counihan). For Aetna specifically, in 2015 it learned that CMS would only pay $12.5 million of
    the $100 million risk-corridor payment that Aetna was due for 2014. Tr. 2681:24–2682:11
    (Guertin); DX0003-007 (“Unlike many competitors, Aetna showed early and prudent caution
    regarding the [risk corridor] program and never booked an accrual.” (emphasis omitted)).
    This evidence persuasively explains some of the reasons that Aetna was losing money on
    the exchanges. CMS officials do not contest Aetna’s description of how these programs work, and
    134
    at least in broad terms, do not contest the specific failings of these programs. See Tr. 2591:8–
    2592:4, 2610:12–15, 2623:8–18, 2625:23–2626:24 (Counihan). Moreover, CMS officials do not
    contest that as a result of these features of the exchanges, several insurers had already or were
    planning to reduce their exchange footprint moving forward. DX0067 (CMS Administrator
    acknowledging “there’s a real possibility that the 2015 numbers are bad and the 2016 numbers
    won’t be better”); Tr. 2592:11–2597:16 (Counihan).
    But these failings of the marketplaces existed before Aetna chose to withdraw from the
    exchanges in August 2016. In fact, as late as July 19, 2016, Aetna was considering expanding into
    new exchange markets. In April 2016, Lynch and Guertin told investors that Aetna has a “very
    good” and “solid cost structure” in Florida and Georgia. PX0112 at 10. In June 2016, Aetna’s
    Operating Committee considered additional investment in Florida and Georgia. Tr. 2748:23–
    2749:2 (Guertin); see also PX0208-029 (July 6 email discussing the same). Also in June, Aetna
    was compiling a “large” list of states for possible expansion in 2018. Tr. 1505:9–14 (Mayhew);
    PX0264-121; see also PX0259-733 (March 2016 Aetna strategy document). At that time, Aetna
    “Remained Committed to a Measured Multi-Year Approach to our Participation on Public
    Exchanges.” PX0116-198 (circulated on June 29, 2016); see also PX0221-433, -435.
    Aetna explains its about-face in August of 2016 as a response to financial information it
    received at the end of the second quarter of 2016. On June 30, 2016, CMS released the 2015 risk-
    adjustment report. Tr. 2723:2–2724:9 (Guertin); DX0192-002. From that report, and industry
    data received from a consultant between July 8 and 11, Aetna learned that it could not expect any
    relief from the risk-adjustment program for the 2016 plan year. Tr. 2720:16–2721:8 (Guertin);
    DX0204. Aetna revised its projection of a $50 million profit for its individual commercial business
    (that is, on-exchange and off-exchange plans together) and instead projected a loss of over $300
    135
    million for 2016. Tr. 2727:16–24 (Guertin); DX0019. This led to Aetna taking a “premium
    deficiency reserve” of $65 million for 2016 after consulting with its external auditor. Tr. 2728:17–
    22 (Guertin). (A premium deficiency reserve is an accounting tool that acknowledges that a firm’s
    projected losses are greater than its projected premiums. See Tr. 1496:4–25 (Lynch); Tr. 2688:9–
    16 (Guertin)). By that point, Guertin had formed the opinion that Aetna should completely
    withdraw from the public exchanges in every state. Tr. 2730:18–25 (Guertin).
    But notwithstanding this new financial information, Aetna continued to view the exchange
    business positively. As late as July 19, Aetna still held open the possibility of entering additional
    public exchange markets, Tr. 1437:21–24 (Bertolini), and viewed its public exchange business as
    having “significant potential under the right conditions,” PX0120-746. In July 19 notes for a
    presentation to Aetna’s board, Soistman wrote that Aetna “will pursue a disciplined market
    participation strategy, targeting deliberate growth in on-exchange silver subsidized membership.”
    PX0120-749. His notes also indicate that Aetna still planned to expand to 20 states (combined on-
    and off-exchange) in 2017. PX0120-756. And although all members of the team assessing Aetna’s
    exchange footprint believed that Aetna should exit all exchanges across the country, two of them
    had believed that even prior to receiving the new financial information in July 2016. See Tr.
    1464:6–8 (Kelmar) (wanted to withdraw nationally since early 2016); Tr. 2739:10–2740:24
    (Guertin) (wanted to withdraw nationally since the end of 2014); Tr. 1497:21–22 (Lynch); Tr.
    1541:21 (Mayhew).
    The Court has no reason to doubt the financial information that Aetna presented, but it is
    not persuaded that this information explains why Aetna withdrew from the 17 counties identified
    in the complaint. The Court is persuaded that this financial information led Aetna to begin the
    process of rethinking and reducing its exchange footprint. Indeed, it is uncontested that this led
    136
    Bertolini to form a team of executives to draft recommendations regarding Aetna’s exchange
    footprint moving forward. It is even possible that, in the absence of this lawsuit, Aetna might have
    considered whether to continue its exchange participation in some counties in Florida, Georgia,
    and Missouri. But the documents that team put together clearly show that they did not approach
    the 17 complaint counties as part of the business decision. Those three states were not mentioned
    in the draft documents before the request to include the 17 counties. And once those counties were
    included in the recommendation documents, they were a separate bloc not evaluated by the same
    business criteria (e.g., profitability) as the other markets. Hence, while Aetna puts on a persuasive
    case that information received in July 2016 changed the value proposition for Aetna participating
    on the exchanges generally, the Court nonetheless finds on the basis of all the evidence that Aetna’s
    decision with respect to the 17 complaint counties was not based on that value proposition. Instead,
    Aetna’s decision not to offer on-exchange plans in the 17 counties for 2017 was a strategy to
    improve its litigation position.
    2. Aetna Is Likely to Compete in Florida After 2017
    The next question, then, is whether Aetna will compete in any of the 17 counties in 2018
    and beyond. Both experts testified that one expects firms to operate in markets where they expect
    to be profitable. See Tr. 3034:25–3035:2 (Orszag); Tr. 1676:4–8 (Nevo). One would therefore
    expect Aetna to again offer plans on-exchange in those 17 counties after 2017 if it expects that
    doing so would be profitable. Bertolini affirmed that Aetna intends to act according to this basic
    intuition. Tr. 1365:7–13 (Bertolini).
    Although the company was losing money in the exchanges overall, through July 2016
    Aetna believed it was worth it to remain in the exchanges. This is reflected in Aetna’s public
    statements and in its internal plans. See, e.g., PX0112 at 13 (describing exchanges as a “good
    137
    investment” despite current unprofitability). Lynch has described Aetna’s plans in Florida—which
    was profitable—as having “a very good cost structure,” PX0112 at 10, and in June 2016 Aetna
    discussed the possibility of further investment in Florida, Tr. 2748:23–2749:2 (Guertin); PX0208-
    029. Aetna’s past behavior is indicative of its future behavior. Aetna believed—as late as June
    2016—that participating in the exchanges was a profitable long-term endeavor despite present
    losses.
    The fact that Aetna withdrew from the 17 counties for the 2017 plan year is weak evidence
    of its future behavior. Because that behavior was not driven by what one would expect—a firm’s
    profit motive (including its leader’s long term assessment of its best interest)—it is not probative
    of how Aetna will behave in the future. Aetna’s decision regarding its participation in the 2017
    exchanges in the complaint counties was not only “arguably . . . subject to manipulation,” it was
    in fact manipulated. See Chicago Bridge & 
    Iron, 534 F.3d at 435
    (emphasis omitted). The Court
    therefore gives it little weight. See Gen. 
    Dynamics, 415 U.S. at 504
    –05; Hosp. Corp. of 
    Am., 807 F.2d at 1384
    ; Bazaarvoice, Inc., 
    2014 WL 203966
    , at *73.
    Indeed, there is some evidence that Aetna intends to once again offer plans in at least some
    of the 17 counties in the near future. Aetna withdrew in a manner specifically designed to allow
    it to compete in those markets within the next five years. If an insurer withdraws from a state
    entirely—that is, offers no on-exchange or off-exchange plans—then it cannot once again offer
    plans in that state for another five years under state laws. Tr. 1364:20–25 (Bertolini). However,
    if an insurer withdraws from on-exchange plans but remains selling off-exchange plans, then it
    may expand its presence in that state at any time. See Tr. 1364:20–25 (Bertolini); see also PX0262.
    This is known as a “dormant strategy.” Tr. 1501:3–19 (Mayhew). When Aetna decided to no
    longer offer on-exchange plans, it continued to offer off-exchange plans in all 17 counties. Tr.
    138
    1364:8–11 (Bertolini); Tr. 1520:11–16 (Mayhew). Aetna acknowledged that this was an effort to
    maintain its ability to offer on-exchange plans again within the next five years. Kelmar Oct. 27,
    2016, Dep. 65:3–7, admitted at 1466:25–1467:7 (Kelmar); Tr. 1467:11–13 (Kelmar); Tr. 1489:21–
    23 (Lynch). As Bertolini explained, Aetna wanted to maintain some presence because it “needed
    to remain in the game” and wanted “to remain at the table to have influence over where exchanges
    [go] in the future.” See Tr. 1387:11–12, 1412:6–7 (Bertolini).
    There is some evidence that Aetna is unlikely to offer any on-exchange plans in these 17
    counties in 2018. Three executives each testified that Aetna currently has no plans to compete in
    any of those counties in 2018. Tr. 1468:10–16 (Kelmar); Tr. 1489:11–15 (Lynch); Tr. 1541:3–16
    (Mayhew). Mayhew testified that although there are no regulatory barriers to Aetna offering on-
    exchange plans in 2018, there were practical ones: Aetna would need to file applications with the
    relevant state agencies by April 2017, which would require that Aetna have already begun the
    necessary preparatory work. Tr. 1541:7–16 (Mayhew). But there are no legal barriers to Aetna
    doing so, only practical ones. The government elicited some evidence that these practical ones
    would not be insurmountable: Aetna continues to have the internal infrastructure (including IT and
    personnel) to compete in these markets, and Aetna already has the necessary relationships with the
    state regulators and can meet the solvency requirements. Tr. 1520:17–19, 1520:23–25 (Mayhew);
    Tr. 2656:9–21 (Counihan). Moreover, Lynch recently expressed interest in meeting with CMS to
    improve its public exchange business (although that is not specific to these 17 counties). Tr.
    2655:15–2656:8 (Counihan)
    More important than the general evidence about Aetna’s future exchange participation is
    evidence specific to the complaint counties. In 2015, Aetna operated at a loss in both Georgia and
    Missouri on both the on-exchange and overall offerings. See DX0009-002. As of the second
    139
    quarter of 2016, Aetna predicted a loss in those states for 2016 as well. DX0009-002. Given that
    one can expect firms to operate in markets where they can achieve a profit, this is strong evidence
    that notwithstanding the reason for Aetna’s withdrawal, it is unlikely to compete in those markets
    in the near future. Because the merger “will not produce the forbidden result if there be no pre-
    existing substantial competition to be affected,” Int’l 
    Shoe, 280 U.S. at 298
    , the Court therefore
    concludes that there will be no substantial lessening of competition on the public exchanges in the
    14 counties in Missouri and Georgia.
    But the picture looks different for Florida. In Florida, Aetna operated at a profit both on-
    exchange and overall in 2015. Aetna projects that it will operate at a profit again both on-exchange
    and overall in 2016. In fact, Florida’s overall profit is due to the strength of its on-exchange
    offerings—Aetna’s off-exchange offerings in Florida lost money. This is strong evidence that
    Aetna is likely to compete on-exchange in Florida after 2017. The email exchange between
    Mayhew and Ciano supports this inference as well. Ciano is, presumably, knowledgeable about
    the Florida market, and he predicted that it would be in Aetna’s best interest to remain in Florida—
    as reflected by his incredulity that Aetna would withdraw from Florida. See PX0132-565.
    The Court finds that, given this profitability picture, Aetna is likely to offer on-exchange
    plans in Florida after 2017. The same is not true for Georgia and Missouri. Although Aetna’s
    decision to withdraw from those markets was not based on sound business reasons, those markets
    were operating at a clear loss, and were projected to continue to do so. Without any evidence that
    Aetna is likely to compete in those markets after 2017, the Court will not assume that Aetna will
    compete there simply because it has done so (unprofitably) in the past. 45
    45
    Defendants ask the Court to take notice of political uncertainty regarding potential legislative changes to
    the ACA. See, e.g., Exec. Order (January 20, 2017) “Minimizing The Economic Burden of the Patient Protection and
    Affordable Care Act Pending Repeal” (directing agencies to minimize regulatory burdens, but not identifying any
    specific legislative or executive actions to be undertaken). Although there may be political uncertainty and changes
    140
    3. The Proposed Merger Would Cause Anticompetitive Effects in Florida
    The government can establish its prima facie case by showing that the proposed merger
    would “lead to undue concentration in the market” for on-exchange plans in the three complaint
    counties in Florida. 46 See Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 982
    . A market concentration, as measured
    using the Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index (HHI), of above 2,500 and an increase in HHI of more
    than 200 points is sufficient to establish the government’s prima facie case. 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 716
    ; Guidelines § 5.3; Staples II, 
    2016 WL 2899222
    , at *18 (applying the current version of the
    Guidelines); Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 52–53 (same).
    Here, the government demonstrates that the proposed merger leads to presumptively
    anticompetitive levels of market concentration in the three complaint counties in Florida. See
    PX0551 (Nevo Report)) ¶¶ 312–13, Ex. 33, App’x. M; 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 716
    . Using the most
    recent 2016 market-share data available: Broward County would have an HHI of 6,633 and an
    increase in HHI of 887; Palm Beach County would have an HHI of 3,408 and an increase in HHI
    of 846; and Volusia County would have an HHI of 4,294 and an increase in HHI of 690. PX0551
    (Nevo Report) App’x. M, Lines 1-3. Thus, the government has established its prima facie case. 47
    But the government does not rest on the presumption—it also provides instances of specific
    head-to-head competition between Aetna and Humana in Florida. “Mergers that eliminate head-
    to the ACA may well be coming, it is always within Congress’ power to change the law. A court has no ability to
    predict Congress’s actions, nor is it the judiciary’s place to do so. See Worth v. Jackson, 
    451 F.3d 854
    , 862 (D.C. Cir.
    2006) (quoting Texas v. United States, 
    523 U.S. 296
    , 301 (1998)). This Court must apply the law to the facts at hand
    given the legal framework that exists now. Cf. United States v. Microsoft Corp., 
    253 F.3d 34
    , 50 (D.C. Cir. 2001)
    (potential for technological change to upend market “does not appreciably alter our mission in assessing the alleged
    antitrust violations”).
    46
    The government introduced evidence relevant to market concentration and anticompetitive effects in all 17
    complaint counties. Because the Court has not found that Aetna is likely to compete in the counties in Georgia or
    Missouri in the near future, the Court only considers the evidence relevant to the counties in Florida.
    47
    Nevo also conducted a regression analysis to demonstrate the relationship between market concentration
    and price. He found that premiums increase as market concentration increases, and that the relationship is statistically
    significant. PX0551 (Nevo Report) ¶¶ 322–23, Ex. 35; Tr. 1692:18–1693:8 (Nevo). Although this analysis confirms
    the rationale behind using HHI, demonstrating a relationship between price and concentration is not necessary to
    establishing the government’s prima facie case or to its ultimate burden of persuasion.
    141
    to-head competition between close competitors often result in a lessening of competition.” Staples
    II, 
    2016 WL 2899222
    , at *20; see also Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 61 (collecting cases); Horizontal
    Merger Guidelines § 6 (“The elimination of competition between two firms that results from their
    merger may alone constitute a substantial lessening of competition.”). Executives at Aetna
    regularly identify Humana as a key competitor in the public exchanges, and specifically in Florida.
    See, e.g., PX0108 (email to Mayhew stating that Humana is a “big competitor” in Florida); Tr.
    1524:3–1525:11 (Mayhew). A March 2016 Aetna presentation described Humana as one of four
    “Selected Competitors,” noting that Humana has “[s]trong brand recognition and community-type
    culture.” PX0259-743; see also PX0210-707, -709 (June 1, 2016, draft Aetna presentation noting
    that Humana has a “significant presence” in Florida); PX0267-542 (email from Humana executive
    identifying Aetna, Blue Cross and Blue Shield plans, United, and Centene as “[o]ur major
    competitors” in marketplaces).
    They also compete head-to-head on prices and product design in the complaint counties in
    Florida. For example, in an email discussing Aetna’s pricing for 2016 in Broward County, Aetna’s
    Florida market president stated that he was “concerned that we have dropped to #2 behind
    Humana” and recommended that Aetna lower its rates by 4% to “maintain #1 in Broward.”
    PX0263-987; Tr. 1528:5–1529:24 (Mayhew); see also PX0268 at 3 (Humana document describing
    Aetna as Humana’s “biggest competitor” in Broward County). And a Humana executive asked
    for information on “where Aetna’s footprint is a match and what they’re [sic] pricing looks like by
    metal tier and how their high level benefit design compares to ours.”          PX0266-341, -342
    (specifying multiple locations including the Florida counties); see also PX0116-201 (June 28,
    2016, slides comparing Aetna’s footprint to Humana’s footprint in public exchanges).
    142
    Thus, the government has made a very strong prima facie case that the proposed merger
    may substantially lessen competition in on-exchange health plans in the three complaint counties
    in Florida, relying on both the presumption based on market competition and on direct evidence
    of head-to-head competition. The “more compelling the prima facie case, the more evidence the
    defendant must present to rebut it successfully.” Baker 
    Hughes, 908 F.2d at 991
    .
    Aetna and Humana point to two rebuttal arguments in an attempt to show that “the market-
    share statistics give an inaccurate account of the merger’s probable effects on competition.” See
    
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 715
    (internal quotation marks and alterations omitted). First, they raise the
    weakened firm defense: that one of the merging parties (Humana) is in a weakened position such
    that its “market share [will] reduce to a level that would undermine the government’s prima facie
    case.” FTC v. Univ. Health, Inc., 
    938 F.2d 1206
    , 1221 (11th Cir. 1991). The companies argue
    that Humana’s price increases for 2017 indicate that Humana’s future market share will be too
    small for the merger to lead to an increase in market concentration that is presumptively unlawful.
    Humana increased its prices in the 17 complaint counties to be, on average, 58% above the lowest-
    priced silver plan in that county. DX0418 (Orszag Reply Report) ¶ 171; Tr. 3031:1–4 (Orszag);
    Tr. 1831:1–17 (Broussard). This was a reaction to losses on the exchanges, and an attempt to
    become profitable (or less unprofitable) in that market. See Tr. 1831:1–1832:18 (Broussard).
    Orszag did a regression analysis showing that such a large increase in price relative to its
    competitors’ prices will reduce Humana’s average share in these counties below 1-2%. Tr.
    3033:16–3034:18 (Orszag). He then conducted an HHI analysis assuming a 1-2% market share
    for Humana, and found that the proposed merger would not lead to an HHI or an increase in HHI
    above the presumptively unlawful levels in the 17 complaint counties. Tr. 3034:9–12 (Orszag);
    DX0418 (Orszag Reply Report) ¶¶ 170–74.
    143
    But there is insufficient evidence for the Court to conclude that this argument applies. The
    “weakened competitor” argument is only persuasive when the defendants “make[] a substantial
    showing that the acquired firm’s weakness, which cannot be resolved by any competitive means,
    would cause that firm’s market share to reduce to a level that would undermine the government’s
    prima facie case.” Univ. 
    Health, 938 F.2d at 1221
    (emphasis added). “Courts ‘credit such a
    defense only in rare cases.’” ProMedica Health Sys., Inc. v. FTC, 
    749 F.3d 559
    , 572 (6th Cir.
    2014) (quoting Univ. 
    Health, 938 F.2d at 1221
    ). Indeed, it has been described as “the Hail-Mary
    pass of presumptively doomed mergers,” ProMedica 
    Health, 749 F.3d at 572
    ; see also Arch 
    Coal, 329 F. Supp. 2d at 154
    (describing it as the “‘weakest ground of all for justifying a merger’”
    (quoting Kaiser Aluminum & 
    Chem, 652 F.2d at 1339
    )). This argument is disfavored because it
    fails to account for the fact that “financial difficulties not raising a significant threat of failure are
    typically remedied in a moderate length of time,” whereas a merger is a relatively permanent action
    that eliminates the potential for future competition between the merging parties. 4A Phillip E.
    Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 963a3 (4th ed. 2016). There is no argument here
    that Humana faces a “significant threat of failure”—if so, it could raise the failing firm defense (a
    separate, and entirely different, theory), which it does not.
    Indeed, Humana has indicated that it is remedying its current weakness in the exchange
    markets. Humana’s CEO testified that it is taking “corrective actions” to improve its business. Tr.
    1876:7–1878:6, 1880:21–1881:3 (Broussard); see also PX0407 at 12 (Humana press release). It
    has adopted “a more insurance focused approach,” is using narrower networks, and is featuring
    “leaner product design.” Tr. 1876:19–1877:6, 1879:8–12 (Broussard). It also recently met with
    CMS to learn about ways to improve this product line. Tr. 2653:14–2655:23 (Counihan). Thus,
    Humana expects to offer “a high-quality and ultimately stable individual commercial health plan”
    144
    despite the price increase. Tr. 1880:21–1881:3 (Broussard); see also PX0407 at 12. These are
    exactly the type of remedies one would expect a weakened, but not failing, firm to take—which is
    why the failing firm defense is only available if the firm “cannot resolve” its weaknesses. The
    defendants have not pointed to any evidence that Humana cannot remedy its current market
    weakness. Hence, the Court finds this rebuttal argument unpersuasive. 48
    Defendants’ second argument is that this market is too volatile, and has too much entry and
    exit, for HHI analysis to accurately predict the state of competition in the market in the future. A
    market may be so “new” and “volatile” that the “bare market concentration ratios or percentages”
    might not “accurately depict the economic characteristics of the market.” United States v. Siemens
    Corp., 
    621 F.2d 499
    , 506 (2d Cir. 1980) (internal quotation marks omitted). This argument fails
    because the companies do not point to any specific evidence to support it. It is true that this market
    is new: the exchanges have only operated since 2013 (for the 2014 plan year). PX0551 (Nevo
    Report) ¶ 273. It is also true that there is some volatility—or at least, some exits. Several insurers
    have exited the public exchanges for 2017. See Tr. 3025:13–3026:17 (Orszag) (for 2017, 36
    insurers have withdrawn nationwide or reduced their footprint); see also DX0352-004.
    But the companies do not present any evidence or argument for why the market’s youth or
    number of exits make HHI an inappropriate tool to project market concentration. As the Second
    Circuit acknowledged in Siemens, perhaps there are some markets where HHI is a poor indicator
    of concentration due to the market’s general unpredictability, 
    Siemens, 621 F.2d at 506
    , but
    defendants have not shown why this is one. Nor have they cited any cases explaining when youth
    or volatility (or here, exits) would make HHI too unreliable to form the basis of a prima facie case.
    Without any facts or law to go on, the Court is not persuaded by defendants’ argument.
    48
    The government also raises other criticisms of Orszag’s regression analysis and therefore his HHI
    calculation. Because the Court is not persuaded by this rebuttal argument, the Court does not reach those points.
    145
    C. Conclusion
    In sum, the Court concludes that competition is likely to be substantially lessened in the
    three complaint counties in Florida. The Court analyzes Aetna as an actual competitor, not an
    “actual potential competitor,” in the public exchanges because of its active participation in those
    markets even if it is not offering plans for 2017. See El Paso Nat. 
    Gas, 376 U.S. at 654
    –662;
    Polypore 
    Int’l, 686 F.3d at 1213
    –16; Warner 
    Commc’ns, 742 F.2d at 1165
    . Because the Court
    looks beyond 2017, the question necessarily becomes whether Aetna will compete in the 17
    complaint counties in 2018 and later years. After thoroughly reviewing the evidence, the Court
    concludes that Aetna withdrew from the public exchanges in the 17 complaint counties to evade
    judicial scrutiny of the proposed merger. It finds particularly persuasive the contemporaneous
    emails that reveal Aetna’s treatment of the 17 complaint counties as distinct from other locations
    where Aetna was considering withdrawal. Therefore, the Court gives that decision little weight as
    evidence of Aetna’s likely future participation in the public exchanges. See Gen. 
    Dynamics, 415 U.S. at 504
    –05.     However, notwithstanding the reasons for Aetna’s withdrawal, there is
    insufficient evidence for the Court to conclude that Aetna is likely to compete in the complaint
    counties in Georgia and Missouri in the near future. This is particularly true given that the public
    exchanges in Georgia and Missouri were not profitable for Aetna in 2015, and were not projected
    to be profitable in 2016. See DX0009-002.
    But the Court concludes that Aetna is likely to compete on the public exchanges in the
    three complaint counties in Florida after 2017. Florida’s on-exchange markets were profitable for
    Aetna in 2015, and were projected to be in 2016. See DX0009-002. The Court finds the proposed
    merger is likely to cause a substantial lessening of competition in these three counties in Florida.
    The government presented a strong prima facie case for the anticompetitive effects of the merger
    146
    based on market concentration as measured by HHI, and additional evidence of direct head-to-
    head competition between Aetna and Humana. Hence, the Court concludes that the proposed
    merger is likely to substantially lessen competition in violation of section 7 of the Clayton Act in
    the public exchange markets in the three complaint counties in Florida.
    III.   Efficiencies
    Finally, Aetna and Humana seek to defend the merger on the ground that it will create
    substantial, procompetitive efficiencies. “Although the Supreme Court has never recognized the
    ‘efficiencies’ defense in a Section 7 case, the [D.C. Circuit] as well as the Horizontal Merger
    Guidelines recognize that, in some instances, efficiencies resulting from the merger may be
    considered in rebutting the government’s prima facie case.” Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 81 (citing
    
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 720
    ); see also Guidelines § 10. The Court will therefore consider Aetna’s and
    Humana’s efficiencies defense, while keeping in mind that “the high market concentration levels
    present in this case require, in rebuttal, proof of extraordinary efficiencies.” 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 720
    ; see also Guidelines § 10 (“The greater the potential adverse competitive effect of a merger,
    the greater must be the cognizable efficiencies, and the more they must be passed through to
    consumers.”). Aetna and Humana must “substantiate” their efficiency claims. H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 89 (quoting Guidelines § 10).
    Efficiencies may benefit the economy insofar as they “enhance the merged firm’s ability
    and incentive to compete, which may result in lower prices, improved quality, enhanced service,
    or new products.” Guidelines § 10. Put differently, the companies must “demonstrate that their
    claimed efficiencies would benefit customers,” Sysco, 
    113 F. Supp. 3d
    at 82, and, more
    particularly, the customers in the challenged markets, see Guidelines § 10 (“[T]he Agencies
    consider whether cognizable efficiencies likely would be sufficient to reverse the merger’s
    147
    potential harm to customers in the relevant market.”); United States v. Phila. Nat’l Bank, 
    374 U.S. 321
    , 370 (1963) (“anticompetitive effects in one market” cannot be justified by “procompetitive
    consequences in another.”). When assessing whether efficiencies might diminish or outweigh the
    competitive harm resulting from a merger, courts will give weight only to efficiencies that are
    cognizable—i.e., “merger-specific efficiencies that have been verified and do not arise from
    anticompetitive reductions in output or service.” Guidelines § 10. “In other words, a ‘cognizable’
    efficiency claim must represent a type of cost saving that could not be achieved without the merger
    and the estimate of the predicted saving must be reasonably verifiable by an independent party.”
    H&R Block, 
    833 F. Supp. 2d
    at 89.
    To estimate the efficiencies that would result from their merger, Aetna and Humana
    undertook a wide-ranging review. The review was overseen by a team of executives from both
    companies, called the integration management office, which “sat in the middle of all the integration
    activities” and directed those efforts. Tr. 2769:17–18, 2769:25–2770:6, 2770:22–24 (Horst).
    Much of the detailed analysis was performed by 29 “functional teams.” Tr. 2768:18–19 (Horst).
    These teams were intended to assess how particular business functions worked at Aetna and
    Humana respectively, and then to estimate the efficiencies that might result from combining them.
    Tr. 2772:1–12 (Horst); see also DX0202-002 (listing the 29 functional teams and their leaders).
    At Aetna, more than 100 employees work full-time on integration, although many more have
    probably worked on the related analyses at various times. See Tr. 2792:10–16 (Horst); Tr.
    1420:13–14 (Bertolini) (“hundreds of people” are working on evaluating efficiencies). Third-party
    consultants were also retained to assist with the process, particularly when the review required
    analysis of confidential business information. Tr. 2783:19–2784:2 (Horst).
    148
    At the “very beginning” of the efficiencies review process, the integration management
    office instructed the functional teams to focus only on merger-specific efficiencies. Tr. 2777:15–
    2778:3 (Horst). For instance, one document used in the efficiencies review includes a slide asking
    “What is a valid synergy?” DX0043-013. Among those savings that are “NOT a Valid Synergy
    Hypothesis” are savings “that would occur regardless of the merger.” DX0043-013. At the
    conclusion of the review process, Aetna estimated that the transaction would produce $2.8 billion
    in annual efficiencies every year after 2020. Tr. 2819:20–23 (Horst); DX0030-003. Aetna is
    confident about its efficiencies estimates because of its experience with the 2013 acquisition of
    Coventry. Aetna’s efforts to estimate and achieve efficiencies through the Coventry acquisition
    were a “template” for its work on the Humana transaction: “[I]t’s really the same. I mean, it’s the
    same actions. It’s the same people. It’s the same process.” Tr. 2783:6–10 (Horst). Aetna claims
    to have achieved $1.1 billion in annual efficiencies through the Coventry acquisition, despite
    initially projecting only $400 million. Tr. 2799:6–12 (Horst).
    Aetna and Humana retained an expert, Rajiv Gokhale, to assess whether the $2.8 billion in
    claimed efficiencies “classify as merger-specific, verifiable, and cognizable” under the Guidelines.
    Tr. 2851:19–23, 2858:13–18 (Gokhale). Gokhale found $2 billion in cognizable efficiencies
    flowing to the combined company, and another $300 million that would flow directly to the
    government and consumers. 49 Tr. 2852:2–12 (Gokhale); DX0577 (Gokhale Reply Report) Ex.
    1-1.   However, the government’s expert, Christine Hammer, also evaluated the claimed
    efficiencies.   Not surprisingly, she raises a variety of issues with Aetna’s calculations and
    Gokhale’s conclusions, finding only $73.2 million in cognizable efficiencies. Tr. 3387:23–3388:8
    (Hammer).
    49
    Gokhale’s opinion relates only to those efficiencies claimed from 2020 onward. The companies do not
    claim savings prior to that date. Tr. 2923:1–7 (Gokhale); Tr. 3399:25–3400:3 (Hammer).
    149
    On balance, the Court is unpersuaded that the efficiencies generated by the merger will be
    sufficient to mitigate the transaction’s anticompetitive effects for consumers in the challenged
    markets. As an initial matter, testimony from Aetna’s and Humana’s economist indicates that, in
    this industry, only about 50% of reductions in marginal costs will be passed through to
    consumers. 50 Tr. 3109:7–21 (Orszag) (estimating a pass-through rate of just 42%). That matters
    because, as Orszag continued, “[w]e’re focused on the effects on consumers,” not “on profits of
    firms.” Tr. 3109:24–3110:1 (Orszag). Orszag’s analysis suggests that a significant amount—
    perhaps most—of the efficiencies generated by this merger will accrue to the merged firm rather
    than to consumers. It is not even clear what proportion of the efficiencies that are passed on to
    consumers will be shared with those in the three public exchange markets in Florida and the 364
    markets for Medicare Advantage. As Gokhale acknowledges, Aetna and Humana are both national
    insurers with commercial, Medicare, and Medicaid businesses. DX0420 (Gokhale Report) ¶ 12.
    Yet, according to Hammer, and as far as the Court can tell, Gokhale did not attempt to attribute
    portions of his claimed efficiencies to the specific product or geographic markets at issue in this
    case. See Tr. 3435:14–24, 3465:1–4 (Hammer).
    Aetna and Humana do not really argue otherwise. 51 Instead, they invoke an exception to
    the Guidelines’ general rule that efficiencies should be evaluated in the context of “the relevant
    50
    Reductions in fixed costs are even less likely to be passed on to consumers. According to the Guidelines,
    “[e]fficiencies relating to costs that are fixed in the short term are unlikely to benefit customers in the short term.”
    Guidelines § 10 n. 15. Moreover, efficiencies “such as those relating to procurement, management, or capital cost[]
    are less likely to be merger-specific or substantial, or may not be cognizable for other reasons.” 
    Id. at §
    10. The
    companies cite $919 million in these kinds of efficiencies, including the “efficiencies to be gained from eliminating
    overlapping infrastructure, like IT services, as well as eliminating overlap in procurement services and the lower costs
    obtained by moving the merged entity onto lower cost procurement contracts.” Defs.’ Proposed Findings &
    Conclusions at 98.
    51
    During Hammer’s cross-examination, counsel for Aetna asked her whether Exhibit 15 to Gokhale’s reply
    report represented an attempt to allocate efficiencies to the challenged markets. Tr. 3465:20–3466:12 (Hammer); see
    also DX0577 (Gokhale Reply Report) Ex. 15. Although Hammer agreed that Exhibit 15 did reflect such an attempt,
    Aetna and Humana make no use of this exchange or the underlying exhibit. Without further explanation of this
    exhibit’s significance, if any, the Court cannot rely on it here.
    150
    market.” Guidelines § 10. The exception provides that the agencies may, “in their prosecutorial
    discretion, . . . consider efficiencies not strictly in the relevant market, but so inextricably linked
    with it that a partial divestiture or other remedy could not feasibly eliminate the anticompetitive
    effect in the relevant market without sacrificing the efficiencies in the other market(s).” 
    Id. § 10
    n.14. These “[i]nextricably linked efficiencies are most likely to make a difference when they are
    great and the likely anticompetitive effect in the relevant market(s) is small so the merger is likely
    to benefit customers overall.” 
    Id. But that
    is not the situation here. As predicted by the post-
    merger HHI scores, the anticompetitive effects in the challenged markets are likely to be very
    substantial. And as a result, the companies must point to “proof of extraordinary efficiencies” in
    rebuttal. 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 720
    . Footnote 14 of the Guidelines does not help them to do so.
    These shortcomings alone severely diminish the force of the companies’ efficiency
    arguments. And when the Court looks to the efficiency claims themselves, further problems
    emerge. Hammer has raised valid issues regarding several categories of claimed efficiencies,
    including those arising out of pharmacy rebate maximization, network medical cost savings, and
    clinical services savings. See Pls.’ Proposed Findings & Conclusions at 168–70. Aetna and
    Humana tellingly do not attempt to defend their estimates in these areas, even after Hammer’s
    critique.
    First, consider the $202.8 million in cognizable efficiencies that Gokhale finds regarding
    pharmacy rebate maximization. See DX0577 (Gokhale Reply Report) Ex. 5-1. Some of these
    efficiencies were calculated using a “best of the two contracts” approach. Under that approach, if
    Aetna and Humana both contract with a manufacturer for a particular drug, then following the
    merger the company with the lower-rebate contract switches its purchases to the higher-rebate
    contract, thereby generating savings for the merged company. Tr. 2899:6–11 (Gokhale). To
    151
    calculate the rebate difference between the contracts, which ultimately drives the magnitude of the
    savings, Gokhale looked to the rebates at a particular point in time. See Tr. 2903:10–16 (Gokhale).
    But Hammer has criticized that approach. Because the rebates could vary over time, she
    contends, a more accurate assessment of the differential would be achieved by comparing average
    rebates over time, rather than rebates at any one time, which could produce results that are
    misleading.   Tr. 3405:13–25, 3406:19–22 (Hammer).           That error would be compounded,
    moreover, if savings based on that rebate differential are then predicted forward in perpetuity, as
    was done by Gokhale (and by the clean-room consultants who conducted the underlying analysis).
    Tr. 3403:4–10 (Hammer). Hammer supported her analysis with a series of illustrative examples
    that, in the Court’s view, raise real concerns about the reliability of the companies’ pharmacy
    rebate maximization efficiencies.
    The Court has similar concerns regarding the claimed $258.6 million in cognizable network
    efficiencies. See DX0577 (Gokhale Reply Report) Ex. 1-1. Most of these efficiencies were also
    calculated using a best of the two contracts approach, but here the emphasis was on provider
    contracts, like those with hospitals. Tr. 2917:19–2918:6 (Gokhale). In the provider context,
    however, there are real impediments to fully implementing a best of the two contracts approach,
    as the providers may object to being switched from a contract with a higher reimbursement rate to
    one with a lower rate. To evaluate this issue, a third-party consultant, PricewaterhouseCoopers,
    reviewed the underlying provider contracts and interviewed a number of Aetna and Humana field
    managers about the prospects for switching providers from one contract to another. Tr. 3430:25–
    3431:5 (Hammer). Some of the field managers sounded a pessimistic note about the willingness
    of providers to switch. PX0192-177 (“I would be surprised if the hospitals don’t initiate a
    terminat[ion] notice with us now that they’ve been through this process before.”); PX0141-154
    152
    (“We’ve had one hospital come to us and say they would proactively terminate [contracts] if either
    plan tries to realize a better rate.”).
    These issues may not be insurmountable but Gokhale did not wrestle with them by, for
    instance, reviewing the underlying provider contracts. Tr. 2936:3–12 (Gokhale). Instead, he noted
    that PricewaterhouseCoopers “took a very large hair-cut to the total savings estimated” and,
    without much analysis, he concluded that the savings were verifiable. DX0420 (Gokhale Report)
    ¶¶ 203, 206; see also PX0562 (Hammer Reply Report) ¶¶ 205–26. The Court is less sure. Without
    a more robust analysis, which the companies have not provided, the Court cannot conclude that
    these network efficiencies are verifiable and likely to be passed on to consumers.
    As a third example, Hammer has identified flaws with the $169.2 million of concurrent
    review efficiencies. See DX0557 (Gokhale Reply Report) Ex.6-1; see also PX0562 (Hammer
    Reply Report) ¶ 171. Concurrent review is a process by which insurers review patient cases in
    real time, and recommend against (or deny payment for) medical care above what is recommend
    by their clinical guidelines. Tr. 2827:8–18 (Horst). So, for instance, a treating physician might
    recommend that a patient be admitted to the hospital. But through the concurrent review process,
    and relying on its clinical guidelines, Aetna might deny payment for the hospitalization and
    recommend that the patient be “put into observation” instead. Tr. 2827:19–2828:2 (Horst). The
    companies’ efficiencies analysis assumes that, where Aetna and Humana have different denial or
    “conversion to observation” rates, the merged firm will adopt the higher rates. Tr. 2911:12–18
    (Gokhale). Gokhale found that these efficiencies were cognizable.
    But as Hammer points out, this analysis does not seem rooted in a search for a shared set
    of best-practices regarding concurrent review. If the “efficiency” is derived entirely from an
    increase in denial rates, it is not clear why that increase could not have been achieved without the
    153
    merger. Tr. 3428:1–3429:14 (Hammer); see also PX0562 (Hammer Reply Report) ¶¶ 184–90.
    Moreover, there is some tension between the claimed concurrent review efficiencies and the
    claimed network efficiencies. As both could take money out of providers’ pockets, there are
    challenges inherent in implementing them at the same time in the same place. Tr. 3432:6–17,
    3429:15–3430:8 (Hammer).        In an attempt to resolve that tension, PricewaterhouseCoopers
    recommended a strategy for leading with the network efficiencies in some locations, with the
    concurrent review efficiencies in others, and, in still other locations, proceeding with both
    simultaneously. PX0147-267; see also PX0562 (Hammer Reply Report) ¶¶ 232–38. That was not
    adopted. Instead, in the companies’ efficiency figures these complexities seem to have been dealt
    with through another largely unexplained “discount factor.” DX0420 (Gokhale Report) ¶ 175.
    Once again, without more concrete analysis, the Court is unable to conclude that these efficiencies
    are entirely verifiable.
    To conclude, the Court has some serious concerns regarding the companies’ efficiencies
    claims. It is very likely that a significant share of the claimed efficiencies may be retained by the
    merged firm rather than being passed on to consumers. Moreover, because Gokhale has not
    attributed the claimed efficiencies to the particular markets challenged in the complaint, the Court
    cannot be confident that the consumers who are likely to be harmed by the merger would also
    share in its benefits. But even assuming that some of the claimed efficiencies would reach these
    consumers, many of the companies’ claims are not cognizable. Hammer has identified a number
    of valid issues with the companies’ analyses—most of which have gone entirely unanswered—
    that serve to further undermine the reliability of the efficiency claims.
    Nor can the companies shore up their efficiency claims by comparisons to the Aetna-
    Coventry merger. Gokhale did not analyze whether the $1.1 billion in claimed efficiencies
    154
    resulting from the Coventry merger were actually cognizable. Tr. 2985:12–18 (Gokhale). And
    given the considerable flaws in Aetna’s current claims, the fact that the Coventry efficiencies were
    calculated by similar methods is of very limited comfort. No doubt Aetna and Humana have
    worked hard to identify efficiencies related to their proposed merger. But because they face a
    presumption of illegality based on very high concentration measures, they must marshal evidence
    of “extraordinary efficiencies” in rebuttal. 
    Heinz, 246 F.3d at 720
    . In the Court’s view, they have
    not done so. “[T]he critical question raised by the efficiencies defense is whether the projected
    savings from the merger are enough to overcome the evidence showing that possibly greater
    benefits can be achieved by the public through existing, continued competition.” Sysco, 113 F.
    Supp. 3d at 86 (alterations omitted) (quoting Cardinal 
    Health, 12 F. Supp. 2d at 63
    ). Here, Aetna
    and Humana have put forward very little evidence that would tempt a consumer in one of the
    challenged markets to choose the merger over continued competition. For that reason, their
    efficiency defense fails.
    CONCLUSION
    In this case, the government alleged that the merger of Aetna and Humana would be likely
    to substantially lessen competition in markets for individual Medicare Advantage plans and health
    insurance sold on the public exchanges. After a 13-day trial, and based on careful consideration
    of the law, evidence, and arguments, the Court mostly agrees.
    Most importantly, the merger would likely substantially lessen competition in the market
    for individual Medicare Advantage in all 364 complaint counties. This conclusion is based on
    identification of the proper product market, the overwhelming market concentration figures
    generated by the merger, and the considerable evidence of valuable head-to-head competition
    between Aetna and Humana, which the merger would eliminate.              The companies’ rebuttal
    155
    arguments are unpersuasive: federal regulation would likely be insufficient to prevent the merged
    firm from raising prices or reducing benefits, and neither entry by new competitors nor the
    proposed divestiture to Molina would suffice to replace competition eliminated by the merger.
    The merger would also be likely to substantially lessen competition on the public
    exchanges in three Florida counties. Because Aetna’s withdrawal from the public exchanges in
    the 17 complaint counties was to avoid antitrust scrutiny, the Court gives that evidence little weight
    in predicting whether Aetna will continue to compete on the exchanges in the future. The Court
    concludes that the merger is likely to substantially lessen competition on the exchanges in the three
    counties in Florida where Aetna is likely to compete in the future. The Court’s conclusion is again
    based on the level of market concentration and the evidence of substantial head-to-head
    competition between Aetna and Humana that would be lost. Neither of defendants’ rebuttal
    arguments is persuasive. There is insufficient evidence to conclude that Humana’s market share
    will decline such that the merger would not increase market concentration or that the markets are
    too volatile to reasonably predict the anticompetitive effects of the merger.
    Finally, the Court is unpersuaded that the efficiencies generated by the merger will be
    sufficient to mitigate the anticompetitive effects for consumers in the challenged markets.
    Therefore, for all these reasons, the proposed merger of Aetna and Humana will be
    enjoined. A separate Order has issued on this date.
    /s/
    JOHN D. BATES
    United States District Judge
    Dated: January 23, 2017
    156
    

Document Info

Docket Number: Civil Action No. 2016-1494

Citation Numbers: 240 F. Supp. 3d 1

Judges: Judge John D. Bates

Filed Date: 1/23/2017

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/13/2023

Authorities (32)

Town of Concord, Massachusetts v. Boston Edison Company , 915 F.2d 17 ( 1990 )

federal-trade-commission-v-university-health-inc-university-health , 938 F.2d 1206 ( 1991 )

white-consolidated-industries-inc-and-magic-chef-inc-v-whirlpool , 781 F.2d 1224 ( 1986 )

Hospital Corporation of America v. Federal Trade Commission , 807 F.2d 1381 ( 1986 )

united-states-of-america-plaintiff-appellee-cross-appellant-v-waste , 743 F.2d 976 ( 1984 )

United States v. Siemens Corporation and G. D. Searle & Co. , 621 F.2d 499 ( 1980 )

United States v. Microsoft Corp , 253 F.3d 34 ( 2001 )

FTC v. Whole Foods Market, Inc. , 548 F.3d 1028 ( 2008 )

Federal Trade Commission v. H.J. Heinz Co. , 246 F.3d 708 ( 2001 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Warner Communications Inc. , 742 F.2d 1156 ( 1984 )

United States v. Baker Hughes Inc., Eimco Secoma, S.A., and ... , 908 F.2d 981 ( 1990 )

Worth, Dennis R. v. Jackson, Alphonso , 451 F.3d 854 ( 2006 )

Rothery Storage & Van Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, Inc. , 792 F.2d 210 ( 1986 )

Kaiser Aluminum & Chemical Corporation v. Federal Trade ... , 652 F.2d 1324 ( 1981 )

International Shoe Co. v. Federal Trade Commission , 50 S. Ct. 89 ( 1930 )

United States v. Falstaff Brewing Corp. , 93 S. Ct. 1096 ( 1973 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Staples, Inc. , 970 F. Supp. 1066 ( 1997 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Arch Coal, Inc. , 329 F. Supp. 2d 109 ( 2004 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Libbey, Inc. , 211 F. Supp. 2d 34 ( 2002 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Cardinal Health, Inc. , 12 F. Supp. 2d 34 ( 1998 )

View All Authorities »