Ellis v. Fidelity Management Trust , 883 F.3d 1 ( 2018 )


Menu:
  •           United States Court of Appeals
    For the First Circuit
    No. 17-1693
    JAMES ELLIS; WILLIAM PERRY,
    Plaintiffs, Appellants,
    v.
    FIDELITY MANAGEMENT TRUST COMPANY,
    Defendant, Appellee.
    APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF MASSACHUSETTS
    [Hon. William G. Young, U.S. District Judge]
    Before
    Kayatta, Circuit Judge,
    Souter, Associate Justice,*
    and Selya, Circuit Judge.
    Garrett W. Wotkyns, with whom Schneider Wallace Cottrell
    Konecky Wotkyns LLP was on brief, for appellants.
    Jonathan D. Hacker, with whom Brian D. Boyle, Gregory F.
    Jacob, Meaghan VerGow, Bradley N. Garcia, O'Melveny & Myers LLP,
    John J. Falvey, Jr., Alison V. Douglass, and Goodwin Procter LLP
    were on brief, for appellee.
    * Hon. David H. Souter, Associate Justice (Ret.) of the
    Supreme Court of the United States, sitting by designation.
    February 21, 2018
    KAYATTA, Circuit Judge.          Plaintiffs James Ellis and
    William    Perry   brought   this    certified    class      action   under   the
    Employee     Retirement    Income    Security     Act   of    1974    ("ERISA"),
    alleging that Fidelity Management Trust Company, the fiduciary for
    a fund in which plaintiffs had invested, breached its duties of
    loyalty and prudence in managing the fund.              Fidelity won summary
    judgment and plaintiffs appealed.             Because the district court
    correctly concluded that plaintiffs failed to adduce evidence
    necessary to proceed to trial, we affirm.
    I.
    "On review of an order granting summary judgment, we
    recite the facts in the light most favorable to the nonmoving
    party" to the extent that they are supported by competent evidence.
    Walsh v. TelTech Sys., Inc., 
    821 F.3d 155
    , 157–58 (1st Cir. 2016)
    (quoting Commodity Futures Trading Comm'n v. JBW Capital, 
    812 F.3d 98
    , 101 (1st Cir. 2016)); see Burns v. State Police Ass'n of Mass.,
    
    230 F.3d 8
    , 9 (1st Cir. 2000) (noting that competent evidence is
    necessary to defeat summary judgment).            We take these facts from
    the parties' summary judgment filings in the district court and
    from   the   record   at   large    where    appropriate.       See     Evergreen
    Partnering Grp. v. Pactiv Corp., 
    832 F.3d 1
    , 4 n.2 (1st Cir. 2016).
    A.
    Plaintiffs    were    participants    in   the    Barnes    &   Noble
    401(k) plan, which allowed participants to allocate their savings
    - 3 -
    among an array of investment alternatives depending on their
    objectives.     Department of Labor regulations encourage employers
    who create plans of this type to offer at least one relatively
    safe investment vehicle, described as an "income producing, low
    risk,       liquid"       investment.             
    29 C.F.R. § 2550
    .404c-
    1(b)(2)(ii)(C)(2)(ii).         A stable value fund is an example of such
    an investment vehicle.         In this instance, Barnes & Noble chose to
    offer its employees a stable value fund run by Fidelity and known
    as the Managed Income Portfolio ("MIP").
    Three typical features of stable value funds are salient
    here.       First,    a   stable   value   fund    generally    consists   of   an
    underlying portfolio of high-quality, diversified, fixed-income
    securities.      Second, a stable value fund generally utilizes a
    "crediting rate" that takes into account gains and losses over
    time and determines what amount of interest will be credited to
    investors, and at what intervals this will occur.               Third, a stable
    value fund often utilizes "wrap insurance," a form of insurance
    providing that, subject to exclusions, when a stable value fund is
    depleted such that investors cannot all recover book value,1 the
    insurance provider will cover the difference.              Because the entity
    providing the wrap insurance hopes it will not have to make good
    1
    "Book value" is the value of principal invested by each
    participant, plus the interest credited to the participant as
    determined by the crediting rate.
    - 4 -
    on its promise, wrap contracts will often contain investment
    guidelines imposing limitations on the composition of a stable
    value fund's portfolio.     For example, a wrap provider might demand
    that a certain portion of a portfolio's underlying securities be
    treasury   bonds   or   similar     investments   that    sacrifice     higher
    returns in favor of increased safety in preserving capital.
    Fidelity     described    to   putative    investors   the    MIP's
    investment   objective     as   follows:       "The    primary    investment
    objective of the Portfolio is to seek the preservation of capital
    as well as to provide a competitive level of income over time
    consistent with the preservation of capital."            As a benchmark, the
    MIP used the Barclay's Government/Credit 1-5 A- or better index
    ("1-5 G/C index") throughout the relevant time period.2                  On a
    quarterly basis, Fidelity made available to all plans that offered
    the MIP fact sheets disclosing investment allocations, current
    crediting rate, investment durations, and the MIP's returns.             More
    than 2,500 employers, including several sophisticated Wall Street
    employers, made the MIP available to their employees throughout
    the class period.
    In the wake of the 2007–2008 financial crisis and the
    ensuing economic decline, Fidelity fund managers expressed concern
    2 According to plaintiffs' expert, this index consists of
    public government and corporate securities, rated A or better,
    with maturities between one and five years.
    - 5 -
    about the availability of wrap insurance for Fidelity's various
    funds, including the MIP, going forward.                        For example, a 2009
    PowerPoint noted a "[d]earth of new wrap capacity."                     During this
    time period, several major wrap providers for the MIP, including
    AIG, Rabobank, and at a later point, JP Morgan, forecasted an
    intention      to   leave    the     wrap    market.        Further    illustrating
    Fidelity's concern is a 2011 e-mail from an attorney for Fidelity,
    noting that JP Morgan had been "shed[ding]" wrap capacity, that
    there were a "dwindl[ing]" number of new entrants into the wrap
    market, and that Fidelity ran the risk of being "left out in the
    cold" if the number of insurers of stable value funds was limited,
    as he expected it to be.            Ultimately, Fidelity secured sufficient
    wrap coverage; certain providers either remained in the market or
    transferred their wrap business to other entities and Fidelity
    also obtained wrap coverage from a new source.
    B.
    During the years covered by this lawsuit, the MIP fully
    achieved its objective of preserving the investors' capital.                    The
    rate of return earned by investors, however, lagged behind that of
    many   other    stable      value    funds       offered   by    competitors.   The
    immediate cause of these lower returns is undisputed:                      Fidelity
    allocated MIP investments away from higher-return, but higher-risk
    sectors (e.g., corporate bonds, mortgage pass-throughs, and asset-
    backed securities) and toward treasuries and other cash-like or
    - 6 -
    shorter duration instruments.                While these allocations made the
    MIP a safer bet and thus more attractive to wrap providers, they
    also positioned the MIP less favorably in the event that markets
    improved.    Markets did improve, the added safety turned out not to
    be    required,    and      competitors        whose      investments      were    more
    aggressive achieved both asset protection and higher returns.                       As
    a result, Fidelity saw its assets under management and its market
    share fall until 2014. It was not until 2015 that Fidelity managed
    to    achieve     the      approximate        average      returns    realized      by
    competitors' stable value funds.
    Of course, such is what occurs in most markets, and
    certainly most investment markets.                 Fund managers make different
    predictions about future market performance, and the differences
    ultimately generate a distribution curve of returns as some funds
    do better than others.           Every year, by definition, one quarter of
    funds fall into the bottom quartile and one quarter fall in the
    top   quartile,    even     if    all   fund      managers   are   loyal    to    their
    investors and prudent in their decisions.
    Plaintiffs, though, say that something else was at work
    here.    They say that the MIP's relatively low returns as compared
    to those of many other stable value funds were the result of
    disloyalty and imprudence in violation of section 404(c)(1) of
    ERISA.      
    29 U.S.C. § 1104
    (a)(1).            While   plaintiffs'      precise
    explanations      for   how      this   is   so    have    moved   throughout     this
    - 7 -
    litigation like a toy mole in an arcade game, the constant and
    essential fact to which they point is Fidelity's conduct in
    procuring wrap coverage for the MIP.                Specifically, plaintiffs
    claim    that   Fidelity   agreed    to   overly    conservative       investment
    guidelines in a failed effort to lock up all wrap coverage so that
    its competitors would not be able to obtain such coverage, allowing
    Fidelity to corner the stable value market and generate business
    for its many other stable value funds even if the MIP suffered.
    Additionally,     plaintiffs       argue    that        Fidelity    was
    imprudent in structuring and operating the MIP by being overly and
    unnecessarily conservative.           Specifically, a prudent Fidelity
    would    have   (say   plaintiffs)   negotiated      less     restrictive      wrap
    guidelines, picked a more aggressive benchmark, and invested in
    higher-risk, higher-return instruments.
    The   district   court    denied    a    motion    to    dismiss    and
    certified a class.      After the parties completed an ample amount of
    discovery, the district court found plaintiffs' arguments to lack
    the evidentiary support needed to survive summary judgment.                    See
    Ellis v. Fidelity Mgmt. Tr. Co., 
    257 F. Supp. 3d 117
    , 119 (D. Mass.
    2017).    This appeal followed.
    II.
    On appeal, plaintiffs claim two distinct errors.               First,
    they contend that in evaluating their loyalty claim, the district
    court applied the wrong standard, thus committing an error of law.
    - 8 -
    Second, they submit that the district court impermissibly weighed
    evidence at the summary judgment stage, where such weighing is
    inappropriate.     Had it credited their version of events, they say,
    it would have found triable issues and denied summary judgment.
    We consider each argument in turn.
    A.
    The choice of the standard by which to evaluate a claim
    is a question of law, which we review de novo.                   United States v.
    Maldonado-Rivera, 
    489 F.3d 60
    , 65 (1st Cir. 2007).                     Here, the
    district court stated that "ERISA . . . requires an ERISA fiduciary
    to honor the duty of loyalty by 'discharging his duties with
    respect to a plan solely in the interest of the participants.'"
    Ellis, 257 F. Supp. 3d at 126 (quoting 
    29 U.S.C. § 1104
    (a)(1)
    (brackets omitted)).         The district court went on to cite our
    decision in Vander Luitgaren v. Sun Life Assurance Co. of Canada,
    
    765 F.3d 59
       (1st    Cir.   2014),      for   the   proposition    that   "an
    accompanying benefit to the fiduciary is not impermissible -- it
    more simply 'require[s] . . . that the fiduciary not place its own
    interests ahead of those of the Plan beneficiary.'"                 Ellis, 257 F.
    Supp. 3d at 126 (alteration in original) (quoting Vander Luitgaren,
    765 F.3d at 65).
    Plaintiffs    do    not   dispute     that    the    district   court
    accurately quoted the statutory language.                 Nor do they expressly
    contend that Vander Luitgaren does not set forth the controlling
    - 9 -
    law.     Instead, in their opening brief, plaintiffs devote much
    attention   to   an   opinion   of   the   Second   Circuit,   Donovan   v.
    Bierwirth, 
    680 F.2d 263
     (2d Cir. 1982).       That opinion says that an
    ERISA fiduciary's decisions "must be made with an eye single to
    the interests of the participants and beneficiaries."          
    Id. at 271
    .
    Plaintiffs seem to read this phrase as meaning that a fiduciary
    can only be motivated by a beneficiary's interests, even if that
    interest aligns with the fiduciary's own interests.            Plaintiffs
    submit that the district court should have applied that reading of
    Donovan and denied summary judgment because record evidence could
    have supported the conclusion that Fidelity's operative motive was
    to further its own interests.
    This is all a bit of a puzzler because plaintiffs never
    mentioned Donovan or the "eye single" language to the district
    court.    Moreover, in their reply brief, plaintiffs concede that
    Donovan and Vander Luitgaren do not conflict.            This of course
    raises the question:     How did the district court apply the wrong
    standard by expressly relying on a recent opinion of this court
    that does not conflict with plaintiffs' preferred earlier decision
    of another court?
    We agree with plaintiffs' reply brief that there is
    actually no material difference relevant to this case between our
    standard as articulated in Vander Luitgaren and the "eye single"
    standard as actually applied in Donovan.        This is not to say that
    - 10 -
    either case (and certainly not Vander Luitgaren) would deem a
    fiduciary liable for disloyalty merely because it took action aimed
    at furthering an objective it shared with the beneficiaries.
    Donovan involved plan trustees who committed themselves to use
    plan assets to buy company stock without carefully considering
    whether it was in the interest of plan participants to do so.
    Indeed, the Second Circuit found it foreseeable that the purchase
    would       harm   plan   participants.   The   court   found   it   "almost
    impossible to believe that the trustees['] . . . motive . . . was
    for any purpose other than blocking [a hostile tender offer]."
    Donovan, 
    680 F.2d at 275
    .        In other words, the trustees in Donovan
    did precisely what Vander Luitgaren prohibits -- they placed
    "[their] own interests ahead of those of the Plan beneficiary."
    Vander Luitgaren, 765 F.3d at 65.3
    In any event, for present purposes the question is
    whether the district court employed the correct legal test in its
    evaluation of the evidence.          The foregoing should make it clear
    that by quoting the statute and relying on the language and holding
    of Vander Luitgaren, the district court did so.         In so concluding,
    we acknowledge a theoretical question posed in plaintiffs' brief
    on appeal:         What if a fiduciary whose interests are aligned with
    3
    For this reason, plaintiffs' claim that the Supreme Court's
    unelaborated reference to Donovan in Pegram v. Herdrich, 
    530 U.S. 211
    , 235 (2000), provides no benediction for the interpretation
    plaintiffs would have us glean from the case.
    - 11 -
    the   beneficiaries'   interest    takes   action    that    a   loyal   but
    indifferent fiduciary might well take, but does so only "with an
    eye" toward the benefits that it will sustain?              As a practical
    matter, in most such circumstances it would be difficult to divine
    such a parsing of motives given the aligned interests of the
    fiduciary and beneficiaries.        One might also posit that most
    beneficiaries would prefer a trustee whose self-interests align
    with their own, rather than one who is personally indifferent to
    the beneficiaries' success.       In any event, we need not venture
    further into this abstract discussion because plaintiffs never
    argued such a theory of loyalty below, contending only that
    Fidelity was motivated by conflicting interests (which is indeed
    the redoubt to which plaintiffs retreat in their reply brief).            So
    we turn now to whether the evidence justified a trial based on
    that contention.
    B.
    "We   review   the   district   court's    grant      of   summary
    judgment de novo."     Cherkaoui v. City of Quincy, 
    877 F.3d 14
    , 23
    (1st Cir. 2017).   A grant of summary judgment is proper only where
    "there is no genuine dispute as to any material fact and the movant
    is entitled to judgment as a matter of law."            Fed. R. Civ. P.
    56(a).   "A dispute is 'genuine' if the evidence about [the issues
    in dispute] is such that a reasonable jury could resolve the point
    in the favor of the non-moving party."      Cherkaoui, 877 F.3d at 23–
    - 12 -
    24 (quoting Sanchez v. Alvarado, 
    101 F.3d 223
    , 227 (1st Cir. 1996)
    (internal quotation marks omitted)).         While this is not a high bar
    to clear, we have also held that "[t]he test for summary judgment
    is steeped in reality. . . .       We have interpreted Rule 56 to mean
    that the evidence illustrating the factual controversy cannot be
    conjectural or problematic . . . .            [S]ummary judgment may be
    appropriate if the nonmoving party rests merely upon conclusory
    allegations, improbable inferences, and unsupported speculation."
    Medina-Munoz v. R.J. Reynolds Tobacco Co., 
    896 F.2d 5
    , 8 (1st Cir.
    1990) (internal quotation marks, citations, and brackets omitted).
    1.
    We begin with the theory underlying plaintiffs' loyalty
    claim.    As best we can tell, it goes something like this:             After
    the financial crisis of 2007–2008 and during the market decline
    thereafter, there was limited wrap capacity available on the
    market.   Fidelity, which stood to earn more money the greater the
    total amount of its assets under management, swooped in to scoop
    up as much wrap capacity as possible, agreeing to excessively
    conservative    guidelines    in   the    process,   in   order   to   prevent
    competitors from obtaining wrap insurance and thereby preventing
    them from entering the stable value fund market.                  With fewer
    competitors    in   the   stable   value    fund   market,   Fidelity   would
    increase its assets under management and in turn increase the fees
    it collected.       Central to plaintiffs' theory is the allegation
    - 13 -
    that Fidelity's "primary goal here was to prevent competitor access
    to wrap capacity to enable Fidelity to grow, for example, its
    separate account business [assets under management] at the expense
    of competitors, not to secure wrap capacity for the MIP."
    The most obvious problem for plaintiffs' argument is
    that   we,   like   the   district    court,   have   examined   plaintiffs'
    Statement of Disputed Facts and find no evidence that the MIP
    itself did not face a threat of insufficient wrap coverage between
    2009 and 2012. After a full round of discovery, plaintiffs adduced
    no evidence to this effect, nor did their expert so conclude.
    Plaintiffs point only to the fact that the MIP was "open to new
    funds" during the period.      Plaintiffs see this fact as leading to
    the inference that Fidelity knew that the MIP was not going to
    lose its existing wrap coverage, on the assumption that if it
    risked the loss of such coverage, it would not leave the fund open
    to new investors until that risk was eliminated.           This is quite a
    reach.   A fund manager might easily perceive a need to find new
    wrap coverage yet leave the fund open to new investors based on an
    expectation that the manager will one way or another find new
    coverage. Even if plaintiffs' touted inference might be reasonable
    at the pleading stage and allow a case to survive a Rule 12(b)(6)
    motion to dismiss, it becomes unreasonable when confronted with a
    summary judgment motion after a full round of discovery producing
    - 14 -
    undisputed proof that existing wrap providers were threatening to
    exit the market in the wake of AIG's dance with failure.
    Plaintiffs' theory of how Fidelity behaved disloyally
    suffers from the added disability of making little sense.                 To
    believe that Fidelity's competitors could be driven out of the
    market due to Fidelity's capture of available wrap insurance, one
    must also believe that wrap insurance at the relevant times was a
    scarce and limited resource.     Were that the case, though, it would
    make no sense to posit that Fidelity had no reason to try hard to
    secure new wrap coverage for the MIP if its existing suppliers
    hinted at possible exit announcements.          Conversely, if Fidelity
    knew that the supply of wrap insurance was not finite, attempts to
    purchase excessive quantities of it so as to deny competitors
    access would be equally illogical; one cannot consume all of a
    good where its quantity is effectively unlimited.           Viewed thusly,
    plaintiffs' theory of a loyalty breach based on aggressive pursuit
    of wrap coverage requires that we infer that Fidelity embarked on
    a course that was not only against both its interests and the
    interests of its investors, but was also plainly illogical.           Such
    an inference, without more to support it, is too speculative to
    carry a claim forward.
    At oral argument, plaintiffs contended that there was a
    third state of the world; namely, that wrap coverage was indeed a
    finite   good,   but   that   Fidelity   did   not   need   to   pursue   it
    - 15 -
    aggressively because other insurance products, suitable for the
    MIP but not suitable for Fidelity's competitors, were available.
    Plaintiffs pointed to guaranteed investment contracts, or GICs, as
    an example.           Thus, in plaintiffs' view, Fidelity's aggressive
    pursuit of wrap coverage was both unnecessary to protect MIP
    investors and consistent with attempts to freeze out Fidelity's
    competitors.          There are multiple problems with this argument, the
    first being that plaintiffs did not raise it in their briefing
    before the district court.            See McCoy v. Mass. Inst. of Tech., 
    950 F.2d 13
    , 22 (1st Cir. 1991) ("It is hornbook law that theories not
    raised squarely in the district court cannot be surfaced for the
    first time on appeal.").4 Even if we were to consider the argument,
    however, it would not persuade us.               To succeed with this argument,
    plaintiffs would need to convince a reasonable factfinder that
    (a) GICs         or   other    insurance    products    were   an   available    and
    appropriate option for the MIP and (b) the same insurance products
    were       not   equally      available    to   or   appropriate    for   Fidelity's
    4
    In a letter filed with the court pursuant to Federal Rule
    of Appellate Procedure 28(j), plaintiffs insist that they did, in
    fact, raise this theory before the district court. In support of
    their claim, however, plaintiffs point only to three separate
    paragraphs from their Local Rule 56.1 statement, not to any portion
    of their brief opposing summary judgment.     It is not enough to
    have offered some facts which could support a particular theory of
    a case; a party must actually make an argument based on the facts.
    Actual mention of GICs and other insurance products in their brief
    or at oral argument before the district court was sparse to non-
    existent. Thus, we cannot say that this argument was raised in
    the district court, let alone "squarely."
    - 16 -
    competitors.         The only portion of the record that plaintiffs'
    counsel cited at oral argument in support of this new theory was
    an   e-mail    from     a    Fidelity   lawyer,      which   discusses    a    single
    competitor, Galliard, and notes that Galliard is more willing to
    use alternative insurance products than Fidelity is.                   But this e-
    mail says nothing about whether GICs or other insurance products
    would have been an appropriate substitute for wrap coverage for
    the MIP.       It also undermines the second premise necessary for
    plaintiffs' theory to succeed -- that competitors would be unable
    to replace wrap coverage with GICs or other insurance products --
    because the e-mail specifically states that the one competitor it
    mentions does employ those products.                   Thus, even if we were
    inclined to consider plaintiffs' new theory on appeal, it would
    fail due to the lack of any competent evidence supporting it.
    Perhaps       recognizing   the     logical    weakness     of    their
    position,     plaintiffs       posit    that   the    district   court    erred    in
    determining that though there was an "accompanying benefit" to
    Fidelity,     this    benefit     was   not    the   motivator   for     Fidelity's
    decision making.        In plaintiffs' view, once the district court had
    found evidence of an accompanying benefit, it was required to leave
    to the trier of fact the decision as to whether this benefit was
    incidental to Fidelity or in fact motivated Fidelity's decisions.
    While we question the accuracy of plaintiffs' reading of the
    district court decision, the simple point is that this argument
    - 17 -
    merely    repackages    plaintiffs'    position   that    their    belatedly
    proffered reading of Donovan as applied to aligned interests of
    the fiduciary and beneficiaries should control.               Having already
    found that theory unpreserved, we leave it at that.
    Plaintiffs offer one other claim that plausibly sounds
    in the duty of loyalty:       that because the MIP's portfolio managers
    were compensated based on the degree to which performance exceeded
    the benchmark, they had an incentive to keep the benchmark unduly
    low.     We can assume, for the sake of argument, that the bonus
    structure was in fact based on the amount by which the fund's
    returns exceeded the benchmark and that the benchmark was quite
    conservative.
    We nevertheless balk at the notion that a fiduciary
    violates    ERISA's    duty    of   loyalty   simply     by   picking   "too
    conservative" a benchmark for a stable value fund.            Such funds are
    generally presented as one of the more conservative options for
    investors who prefer asset preservation to the risk of pursuing
    greater returns.      A conservative benchmark for a fund that places
    principal preservation as its primary goal warns the investor not
    to expect robust returns, and aligns expectations and results in
    a manner that is unlikely to harm or disappoint any investor who
    selects the fund.
    Plaintiffs' theory also ignores basic and obvious market
    incentives.     If Fidelity publishes a benchmark that implies no
    - 18 -
    greater    safety    but     lower    returns     than    those    implied   by   the
    benchmarks published by competing funds, it risks losing out as
    plan sponsors choose what options to offer plan participants.                     And
    if Fidelity wants to increase compensation for its fund managers,
    there are presumably many ways to do so without setting a lower
    benchmark, a tactic that risks making a fund uncompetitive with
    those offered by other companies.
    The    bottom    line    here   is    that    Fidelity    offered      an
    investment vehicle for conservative investors in the wake of the
    2007-2008 market collapse, it published for its putative investors
    a cautious and unambitious benchmark, and then it consistently
    exceeded that benchmark.             Unless we are to say that ERISA plans
    may not offer very conservative investment options (such as money
    market funds or treasury bond funds), then we cannot say that plans
    may not offer different types of stable value funds, including
    those     that     are   intentionally       and    openly        designed   to     be
    conservative.       If informed plans or their participants do not want
    such funds, they will not select them over the innumerable options
    available.
    In the end, far from inappropriately weighing evidence
    against    plaintiffs,       the     district     court    correctly    held      that
    plaintiffs had presented no competent evidence at all to support
    critical elements of their theory of the breach of the duty of
    loyalty.    Instead, plaintiffs relied on repeated speculation that
    - 19 -
    sophisticated investment professionals behaved in a manner that
    makes no sense.     As a result, summary judgment was appropriately
    granted on plaintiffs' loyalty claims.
    2.
    In addition to their loyalty claims, plaintiffs also
    pressed prudence claims in the district court.             In large part,
    these prudence claims are the loyalty claims dressed in prudence's
    clothing,     and   thus   suffer    from    the   same   overreliance     on
    unreasonable and unsupported speculation.          Nonetheless, because it
    is certainly possible for conduct to be loyal but imprudent, we
    address each of these claims in their own guise.
    ERISA requires a fiduciary to act "with the care, skill,
    prudence, and diligence under the circumstances . . . that a
    prudent [person] acting in a like capacity and familiar with such
    matters would use in the conduct of an enterprise of a like
    character and with like aims."         
    29 U.S.C. § 1104
    (a)(1)(B).        "The
    test of prudence -- the Prudent [Person] Rule -- is one of conduct,
    and not a test of the result of performance of the investment.
    Whether a fiduciary's actions are prudent cannot be measured in
    hindsight."     Bunch v. W.R. Grace & Co., 
    555 F.3d 1
    , 7 (1st Cir.
    2009) (brackets, internal quotation marks, and citations omitted).
    Plaintiffs advance three theories of a violation of the duty of
    prudence:     (a) that it was imprudent to pursue wrap capacity as
    aggressively as Fidelity did and agree to the terms Fidelity agreed
    - 20 -
    to, (b) that Fidelity's use of the Barclays 1-5 G/C index as a
    benchmark was imprudent, and (c) that it was imprudent not to take
    corrective action in the face of returns that were lower than those
    of competitor funds.
    The first contention is easily dispensed with, largely
    for the same reasons that the loyalty claim failed.               Simply put,
    there is no evidence: (a) that the array of prudent options
    available in the relevant time period did not include aggressively
    pursuing wrap insurance in the context of a potential decrease in
    wrap   providers,    (b) that    Fidelity      took   on    any   excess     wrap
    insurance,    and   (c) that    Fidelity     unreasonably    passed    over   an
    available better deal for its supply of wrap insurance.                    Absent
    such evidence, plaintiffs' prudence claim fails to get out of the
    starting blocks.     See Celotex Corp. v. Catrett, 
    477 U.S. 317
    , 323
    (1986) (holding that "there can be no genuine issue as to any
    material   fact"    where   there   is   "a   complete     failure    of   proof
    concerning an essential element of the nonmoving party's case"
    (internal quotation marks omitted)).           While plaintiffs make much
    of internal Fidelity communications describing the terms it agreed
    to with JP Morgan as "overly stringent," this description cannot
    carry the weight plaintiffs assign to it.             That one party to a
    transaction believes the terms to be "overly stringent" proves too
    little unless there exists an alternative, more favorable option.
    - 21 -
    Plaintiffs' second theory fares no better.    They offer
    no authority, and we are aware of none, holding that a plan
    fiduciary's choice of benchmark, where such a benchmark is fully
    disclosed to participants, can be imprudent by virtue of being too
    conservative.   It is undisputed that the MIP's returns exceeded
    those of money market funds throughout the class period.      Were
    this case to proceed to trial, it is completely unclear by what
    standard a jury could find a disclosed choice of benchmark to be
    imprudent as "too conservative," particularly where plaintiffs
    make no argument that offering more conservative investments (such
    as money market funds) would constitute an ERISA violation.    The
    fact that plaintiffs on appeal criticize Fidelity for shying away
    from asset-backed securities in the wake of the 2007–2008 market
    collapse well demonstrates that plaintiffs' standard of prudence
    relies on hindsight.
    Plaintiffs' third and final theory -- that Fidelity
    breached the duty of prudence by failing to take corrective action
    to improve the MIP's returns -- fails as well, most fundamentally
    for the second reason elucidated by the district court:       that
    plaintiffs have not identified any particular act or omission in
    this regard that was imprudent.   See Ellis, 257 F. Supp. 3d at 131
    ("Further, as Fidelity notes, the Plaintiffs do not point to any
    specific decision violating the duty of prudence.").   This failure
    is particularly important given that, as plaintiffs' own expert
    - 22 -
    admitted, the MIP's managers did consider and increase its risk
    allocation throughout the class period. Plaintiffs did not specify
    in the district court, and do not specify now, a minimum risk level
    below   which       stable    value    funds    for   some    reason   cannot     go.
    Furthermore,        as   we   have    already    noted,   a   prudence    claim    is
    evaluated from the perspective of what a fiduciary reasonably knows
    ex ante.   See Bunch, 
    555 F.3d at 7
    .             The district court was correct
    in finding that, at bottom, plaintiffs lacked any evidence that
    any of the decisions made by the MIP's managers were unreasonable
    under the circumstances, particularly given that Fidelity had
    introduced      a    wealth     of    undisputed      evidence   supporting       the
    conclusion that it engaged in an evaluative process prior to making
    investment decisions.
    We pause, finally, to address plaintiffs' repeatedly
    played trump card: the e-mail, discussed supra, from one of
    Fidelity's in-house attorneys, written in March 2010.                    The e-mail
    states, in relevant part, as follows:
    It's not one thing with Galliard, it's
    several. They probably are more diversified
    than us. They're more willing to use every
    tool available to them -- traditional GICs,
    separate account GICs, Mutual of Omaha.
    They're certainly more flexible than we are.
    You'd think given our size and our resources
    that we could do anything, but with us
    everything has to be done our way. Galliard
    can also afford to put deposits into cash
    because their crediting rates don't suck. The
    biggest difference between us and Galliard
    though is that they care about this business
    - 23 -
    in a way that we don't. Stable value matters
    to them. We can talk all we want about how
    we're the best (and in some ways we are), but
    the fact is that while we were selling
    everything in the meltdown our competitors
    stuck to their guns.    As a result, in many
    cases they are better off than we are. When
    capacity opens up (assuming it does), we might
    get the first call, but Galliard won't be far
    behind.
    This   e-mail   has,   in   one   way    or   another,    anchored   most   of
    plaintiffs' arguments throughout this case.              Admittedly, it uses
    colorful language, and surely -- as plaintiffs argue -- most
    investors would not want to invest in a fund whose crediting rates
    "suck."    But this e-mail tells us much too little about whether
    Fidelity breached its duties under ERISA.                Rather, it shows a
    Fidelity   employee    looking    back   in   hindsight    and   noting   that
    Fidelity underperformed many competitors based on choices made in
    response to the financial crisis. One can only imagine the mirror-
    image e-mails of regret Fidelity's competitors would have written
    had the markets collapsed instead of rebounding.             And as we have
    made clear, hindsight regret cannot be the basis for an ERISA
    claim.    See id.
    Because plaintiffs failed to adduce evidence sufficient
    to proceed to trial on any of their theories of prudence, the
    district court was correct to reject plaintiffs' prudence claims.
    - 24 -
    III.
    Though the record in this matter is voluminous, the
    essential   issues   are   relatively    straightforward.   Plaintiffs
    failed to adduce evidence after ample discovery that would have
    provided reasonable, non-speculative support for their claims of
    disloyalty or imprudence.     The record shows, instead, an alignment
    between the interests of Fidelity and the MIP participants, and an
    investment strategy that lacked not prudence, but rather, a crystal
    ball.   The district court's grant of summary judgment is affirmed.
    - 25 -