U.S. v. All Star Industries ( 1992 )


Menu:
  •                  UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FIFTH CIRCUIT
    ______________________________
    No. 91-2439
    ______________________________
    UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
    Plaintiff-Appellee,
    versus
    ALL STAR INDUSTRIES, ET AL.,
    Defendants,
    MIDCO PIPE & TUBE CO.,
    RICHARD A. BRAZZALE,
    MANNESMANN INTERNATIONAL
    ALLOYS, INC. (MIA),
    Defendants-Appellants.
    ___________________________________________________
    Appeals from the United States District Court
    for the Southern District of Texas
    ___________________________________________________
    (May 28, 1992)
    Before BROWN, GARWOOD, and EMILIO M. GARZA, Circuit Judges.
    EMILIO M. GARZA, Circuit Judge:
    Mannesmann International Alloys, Inc. (MIA), Midco Pipe &
    Tube, Inc. (Midco), and Richard A. Brazzale--former vice-
    president of sales at MIA--appeal their convictions for violating
    section 1 of the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    , and for aiding and
    abetting, 
    18 U.S.C. § 2
    , by conspiring to fix the prices of
    specialty pipe sold through Texas Pipe Bending Company (TPB).
    Specifically, these defendants assert that the district court
    erred in instructing the jury and abused its discretion in
    ordering restitution.   Finding no error, we affirm.
    I
    This case involves an alleged conspiracy between six
    corporations1 and three individuals2 to fix the prices of
    specialty pipe sold to TPB for purchase by TPB's customers under
    a cost-plus contractual arrangement--a violation of section 1 of
    the Sherman Act3 and the aiding and abetting statute.4
    Specifically, the indictment alleges that TPB and its
    distributors conspired to eliminate competition on specialty pipe
    bids submitted to TPB for its cost-plus contracts.5
    1
    They are (1) TPB; (2) Capitol Pipe and Steel Products,
    Inc. (Capitol), (3) U.S. Metals, Inc. (U.S. Metals), (4) All Star
    Industries, Inc. (All Star), (5) MIA, and (6) Midco.
    2
    They are (1) Carlton H. Bartula, (2) Richard A.
    Brazzale, and (3) Ronald S. Palma.
    3
    
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    .
    4
    
    18 U.S.C. § 2
    .
    5
    Specialty pipe is used in oil refineries and power
    plants to transport materials when carbon steel pipe is
    ineffective--for example, when the materials are corrosive or of
    extremely high or low temperatures. This specialty pipe often
    needs to be bent into shape and welded to fit the configurations
    of a particular project--an endeavor that is generally done more
    economically at a pipe fabricator's shop than at a job site.
    When the precise quantities of each size and grade of pipe are
    unknown at the time of contract, contracts with fabricators for
    specialty pipe generally call for the fabricators to purchase
    pipe from distributors on a cost-plus basis. In this situations,
    specialty pipe purchasers pay fabricators (1) the invoice price
    of the pipe plus (2) a bargained-upon percentage of that price as
    the fabricator's markup.
    Because prices for specialty pipe are volatile and it is
    difficult for specialty pipe purchasers to predict their needs,
    purchasers expect this cost-plus arrangement to bring about a
    lower overall cost than the alternative--paying a pipe fabricator
    a fixed price which would include a contingency for assuming the
    market risk. Specialty pipe purchasers generally believe that
    the fixed-price method would inflate bids to the point of making
    the present specialty pipe market system--that is, reliance on
    -2-
    2
    A
    At trial, twelve alleged co-conspirators--including a former
    MIA sales manager, a former MIA executive vice-president, and two
    former Midco vice-presidents--described the conspiracy and their
    participation in it.   According to these witnesses, when TPB was
    awarded a fabrication job on a cost-plus basis, Bartula--TPB's
    head purchasing agent--decided which distributors should submit
    bids.    These distributors included All Star, Midco, MIA, Capitol,
    Guyon, and U.S. Metals.   Bartula or another TPB employee would
    then ask Palma6 to "quarterback" the job--that is, to act as a
    go-between among the distributors and TPB by discussing the
    prospective bids, allocating various material among the bidders,
    and working with the bidders to decide the prices each would
    submit to TPB.
    Specifically, Bartula or Palma would call selected bidders
    to inform them that (1) they would be receiving a request for a
    quotation on a cost-plus job, (2) Palma would quarterback the
    job, and (3) the job was to be handled on a "code 5", "10", or
    "15" basis--meaning that the job was to be rigged and TPB would
    independent pipe fabricators who do the work off site--
    uneconomical. To assure that they receive competitive prices,
    purchasers generally require pipe fabricators to solicit and
    submit competitive bids from three or more distributors.
    Between 1981 and 1984, there were only 5-7 of these
    specialty pipe distributors in the market. However, fabricators
    such as TPB sometimes carried their own specialty pipe inventory
    and were able to bid against the pipe distributors. See infra
    note 15 and accompanying text.
    6
    Palma worked for Capitol in 1981 and 1982, and then for
    his own company--All Star--in 1983 and 1984.
    -3-
    3
    receive either a five, ten, or fifteen percent kickback.     The
    distributors then padded their bids accordingly, adding this
    five-to-fifteen percent onto their bids and rebating the money to
    TPB in the form of a "credit memo" or check.   TPB and its
    distributors sometimes referred to this scheme as TPB's "volume
    discount program."
    As quarterback, Palma would discuss the bidders' preferences
    and agree on an allocation among them of the materials needed.
    The bidders who were designated winners would then determine
    their prices.   In addition to the five-to-fifteen percent added
    to the bid price for TPB's kickback, these bid prices included
    higher than normal markups resulting in prices generally 20
    percent--and as much as 75 percent--higher than competitive
    prices.   Palma would then pass these inflated prices onto the
    other bidders who would protect them by bidding higher.    Work was
    usually awarded according to the allocation agreed upon by the
    distributors.
    B
    TPB, Capitol, and U.S. Metals entered into plea agreements.
    All Star, MIA, Midco, Bartula, Brazzale, and Palma went to trial
    and were convicted by a jury on March 19, 1990.   Judgments of
    conviction were entered on May 20, 1991:   The district court
    fined each of the corporate defendants $250,000 and, as a
    condition of probation, ordered them jointly and severally liable
    for restitution in the amount of $859,935; Bartula was sentenced
    to three years imprisonment, with all but the first six months
    -4-
    4
    suspended; Brazzale and Palma received suspended sentences and
    were placed on probation for five years.        MIA, Midco, and
    Brazzale appeal their convictions.
    II
    Defendants challenge both the district court's (A) jury
    instruction and (B) its award of restitution.        Defendants' jury
    instruction challenge fractures into assertions that the district
    court erred in:
    (1) instructing the jury under the per se rule
    analysis,
    (2) refusing to instruct the jury on "rule of reason"
    analysis, and
    (3) refusing to instruct the jury on the theories of
    defense (that is, good faith and lack of specific
    intent).
    As for its award of restitution, MIA asserts that the district
    court abused its discretion by:
    (1) ordering restitution for injuries outside the
    limitations period,
    (2) failing to credit MIA for payments made to settle
    related civil claims, and
    (3) making restitution joint and several.
    A
    1-2
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides in part that "[e]very
    contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or
    conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several
    States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be
    illegal . . . ."   
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    .       Despite the scope of its
    -5-
    5
    literal meaning, the Supreme Court has always recognized that
    section 1 was "intended to prohibit only unreasonable restraints
    of trade."    Business Electronics v. Sharp Electronics, 
    485 U.S. 717
    , 723, 
    108 S. Ct. 1515
    , 1519 (1988) (emphasis added).
    Therefore, "[o]rdinarily, whether [a] particular concerted action
    violates § 1 of the Sherman Act is determined through case-by-
    case application of the so-called rule of reason--that is, `the
    factfinder weighs all of the circumstances of a case in deciding
    whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as imposing
    an unreasonable restraint on competition.'"   Id. (citation
    omitted).
    However, the Court has also introduced a shortcut around
    case-by-case rule of reason analysis:   the Court has found
    certain agreements to be so egregiously anticompetitive "that
    they are conclusively presumed illegal without further
    examination under the rule of reason generally applied in Sherman
    Act cases."   Broadcast Music, Inc., v. Columbia Broadcasting
    System, Inc., 
    441 U.S. 1
    , 7-8, 
    99 S. Ct. 1551
    , 1556 (1979); see
    also Business Electronics, 
    485 U.S. at 723-24
    , 
    108 S. Ct. at 1519
    ("Certain categories of agreements, however, have been held to be
    per se illegal, dispensing with the need for case-by-case
    evaluation.").7   "[A]greements among competitors to fix prices on
    7
    The policy undergirding this per se unreasonableness
    approach is to avoid "the necessity for an incredibly complicated
    and prolonged economic investigation into the entire history of
    the industry involved, as well as related industries, in an
    effort to determine at large whether a particular restraint has
    been unreasonable--an inquiry so often wholly fruitless when
    undertaken." Broadcast Music, 
    441 U.S. at 8, n.11
    , 99 S. Ct. at
    -6-
    6
    their individual goods or services are among those concerted
    activities that the Court has held to be within the per se
    category."   Broadcast Music, 
    441 U.S. at 8
    , 
    99 S. Ct. at 1556
    .8
    The district court found the price fixing arrangement between TPB
    and its distributors to be such an agreement and instructed the
    1556 n.11, quoting Northern Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 5, 
    78 S. Ct. 514
    , 518 (1958) (citations omitted). The
    standard test for determining application of this per se rule is
    whether the business practice "facially appears to be one that
    would always or almost always tend to restrict competition and
    decrease output. . . ." 
    Id. at 19-20
    , 
    99 S. Ct. at 1562
    , citing
    United States v. Gypsum Co., 
    438 U.S. 422
    , 436 n.13, 441 n.16, 
    98 S. Ct. 2864
    , 2873 n.13, 2875 n.16 (1978).
    8
    Id. at 9, 
    99 S. Ct. at 1557
     ("As generally used in the
    antitrust field, `price fixing' is a shorthand way of describing
    certain categories of business behavior to which the per se rule
    has been held applicable."); see Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales,
    Inc., 
    446 U.S. 643
    , 647, 
    100 S. Ct. 1925
    , 1927-28 (1980) (price
    fixing agreement among competitors is archetypal example of
    conduct that is illegal per se); Northern Pac. Ry. Co., 
    356 U.S. at 5
    , 
    78 S. Ct. at 518
     (price fixing is illegal per se "without
    elaborate inquiry as to the precise harm [it has] caused or the
    business excuse for [its] use."); United States v. MMR Corp., 
    907 F.2d 489
    , 495 (5th Cir.) (Where defendants were charged with bid
    rigging in violation of Sherman Act, holding that "[i]t is enough
    that the government shows that the defendants accepted an
    invitation to join in a conspiracy whose object was unlawfully
    restraining trade.") (citation omitted), cert. denied, 
    111 S. Ct. 1338
     (1990); United States v. Flom, 
    558 F.2d 1179
    , 1183 (5th Cir.
    1977) ("An agreement that one company would not submit a bid
    lower than another is price fixing of the simplest kind and is a
    per se violation. . . .") (citation omitted). Thus, "[i]n cases
    involving behavior such as bid rigging . . . the Sherman Act
    will be read as simply saying: `An agreement among competitors to
    rig bids is illegal.'" United States v. Koppers Co., 
    652 F.2d 290
    , 294 (2d Cir.), cert. denied, 
    454 U.S. 1083
    , 
    102 S. Ct. 639
    (1981), quoting United States v. Brighton Bldg. & Maint. Co., 
    598 F.2d 1101
    , 1106 (7th Cir.), cert. denied, 
    444 U.S. 840
    , 
    100 S. Ct. 79
     (1979).
    -7-
    7
    jury accordingly, thereby rejecting the rule of reason
    instructions proposed by defendants.9
    The government asserts a conspiracy among distributors to
    fix the price of specialty steel and pass that non-competitive
    price onto end users.   To diminish the importance of their
    horizontal agreement to rig specialty steel bidding, defendants
    emphasize the vertical component of the conspiracy--that is,
    TPB's involvement--by proffering a hostage ("TPB made us do it")
    theory:
    The unique fact of this case is that the pipe
    distributors did not, as in a conventional case, come
    together voluntarily to fix prices on products to be
    sold to their customers. Rather, directions flowed the
    other way. It was the suppliers' customer, Texas Pipe
    Bending . . . , which directed its suppliers in the
    scheme. TPB dictated the prices in the bids it
    expected to receive from suppliers. TPB then purchased
    and took title to the goods, which were passed on to
    the end users.10
    9
    The district court's jury instructions are discussed
    and quoted infra at notes 19-20 and accompanying text.
    10
    Reply Brief for Appellant Midco Pipe & Tube, Inc. at 3,
    United States v. All Star, No. 91-2439 (5th Cir. filed Dec. 12,
    1991) ["Midco Reply Brief"]. Defendants rely upon Sitkin
    Smelting & Refining Co. v. FMC Corp., 
    575 F.2d 440
     (3d Cir.),
    cert. denied, 
    439 U.S. 866
     (1978), to argue that this case simply
    involves "sham bidding" orchestrated by a buyer, and, therefore,
    is not a per se violation of the Sherman Act. Specifically,
    defendants cite Sitkin, 575 F.2d at 447, for the proposition that
    the mere existence of sham bidding does not create a presumptive
    violation of the Sherman Act, and United States v. Fischbach &
    Moore, Inc., 
    750 F.2d 1184
    , 1196 (3d Cir. 1984), cert. denied sub
    nom., 
    470 U.S. 1029
    , 
    105 S. Ct. 1397
     (1985), for the proposition
    that no antitrust violation can arise if a customer--defendants
    allege that TPB, not the specialty steel end users, was their
    customer--acquiesces in the transaction or conspiracy. We find
    Sitkin easily distinguishable, however, for in that case there
    was no horizontal collusion among competing buyers or sellers.
    See Sitkin, 575 F.2d at 446-48. As the court explained, "The
    price-fixing within the scope of the per se prohibition of § 1 .
    -8-
    8
    In sum, defendants would have us believe that (1) they dealt only
    with TPB and not with each other, (2) TPB told them what to bid
    and, for the sake of staying in business, they did what they were
    told, and, (3) after their deals were done, TPB went forth on its
    own to cheat its customers, the specialty pipe end users, with
    inflated prices.11   However, the record stages a very different
    . . is an agreement to fix the price to be charged in
    transactions with third parties, not between the contracting
    parties themselves." Id. at 446 (emphasis added).
    11
    Specifically, MIA and Brazzale assert that:
    The indictment describes a scheme whereby TPB, a
    customer of Mannesmann and other pipe distributors,
    directed them to submit prearranged bids to it for its
    use in satisfying cost-plus contracts between TPB and
    its own customers--the "end users"--when the contracts
    require competitive bidding. No antitrust injury
    results from this conduct.
    * * *
    What the government has done is turn a business tort by
    TPB against its customers into a criminal antitrust
    conspiracy against those customers by parties who did
    not contract with them but only with TPB, parties who
    did not tell TPB what to do with its pricing and who
    had no relationship with TPB's customers.
    Brief of Defendants-Appellants Mannesmann International Alloys,
    Inc. and Richard A. Brazzale at 10, 17, United States v. All Star
    Industries, No. 91-2439 (5th Cir. filed Oct. 16, 1991) ["MIA
    Brief"].
    Midco asserts that, "[b]ecause TPB's arrangement with its
    distributors was vertical[--that is, TPB purchased specialty
    pipe as [Midco's] customer, fabricated it, and then resold it to
    the end users who were TPB customers--]and caused no demonstrable
    economic harm, the [district] court should have submitted [their]
    rule of reason instructions. At the very least, it should have
    submitted the case to the jury under the alternative theories of
    per se liability and rule of reason analysis." Brief for
    Appellant Midco Pipe & Tube at 24, United States v. All Star
    Industries, No 91-2439 (5th Cir. filed Oct. 11, 1991) ["Midco
    Brief"]. Midco relies upon Business Electronics v. Sharp
    Electronics, 
    485 U.S. 717
    , 
    108 S. Ct. 1515
     (1988), for the
    proposition that the agreement between specialty pipe
    distributors and TPB was vertical, thereby making the per se rule
    inapplicable. However, we find Sharp easily distinguishable
    since that case involved a wholly vertical restraint--an
    -9-
    9
    scenario:   where specialty pipe distributors, TPB, and specialty
    pipe end users were united by underlying cost-plus contracts,
    distributors who were normally horizontal competitors conspired
    to rig their bids with the explicit intention of inflating the
    cost aspect of cost-plus contracts and deceiving specialty steel
    end users.12   The conspiracy depended upon distributor
    agreement between a manufacturer and a dealer to terminate
    another dealer--without any agreement on price or price levels.
    
    Id. at 735-36
    , 
    108 S. Ct. at 1525
     ("In sum, economic analysis
    supports the view, and no precedent opposes it, that a vertical
    restraint is not illegal per se unless it includes some agreement
    on price or price levels.").
    12
    The record establishes that defendant distributors were
    fully aware of their role in the overall scheme contrived by TPB-
    -that is, they knew they were rigging bids only on cost-plus
    contracts that required TPB to obtain competitive bids and also
    required the end user-buyers to pay the full rigged priced for
    the specialty pipe plus TPB's markup. See infra notes 13-15 and
    accompanying text. As for the involvement of Midco and MIA in
    this conspiracy, consider the following:
    -- MIA's involvement in the conspiracy is captured by
    the testimony of Lorne Van Stone, former executive
    vice-president of MIA:
    Q    And what did Mr. Brazzale explain that he and Mr.
    Palma did to set price levels?
    A    Well, they told me that they would discuss the job
    and decide which items that International
    Alloys was going to get and that we would
    protect prices for the other competitors and
    we would get our share of the order.
    Q    And what did you understand "protect other
    competitors" to mean?
    A    To keep our prices high to protect their prices so
    that they would receive the job.
    Q    So would you explain to us how that would work as
    a
    mechanical matter on a Mannesmann bid as you
    understand that process?
    A    We would sell many times above our usual prices in
    order to protect the prices in the
    marketplace at Texas Pipe Bending. And where
    we were picked to take certain items, we
    would be low on those and somebody else would
    -10-
    10
    protect our prices.
    * * *
    A       My understanding was the three or four times that
    I
    remember that we got part of the jobs, not
    all of the jobs, we got part of the jobs
    after [Mr. Brazzale] would have had a meeting
    with Mr. Palma. That is my understanding.
    * * *
    Q       Did Mr. Brazzale ever explain to you how it came
    to
    be that Mannesmann would     win items on some of
    these bids to Texas Pipe     Bending where he and
    Mr. Palma were talking?
    * *   *
    A       They would get the other   distributors to raise
    their
    prices to protect ours on the items that we
    were to be given.
    Q       And did Mannesmann protect the other distributors
    on
    the rest of the items?
    A    Yes.
    * * *
    Q    Did Mr. Brazzale ever tell you the names of other
    competitors whose prices Mannesmann was
    protecting?
    A    Yes.
    Q    Whose names did he tell you?
    A    U.S. Metals
    * * *
    Q    Any other company?
    A    Gulf Alloys.
    Q    Any other company?
    A    Charles F. Guyon Alloys.
    Record on Appeal, vol. 37, at 8-55, 8-61 to 8-64, United
    States v. All Star Industries, No. 91-2439 (5th Cir.
    filed Aug. 6, 1991) ["Record on Appeal"].
    -- The record also contains testimony regarding Midco's
    involvement from Sam Rossetti, Midco's former vice-
    president and sales manager:
    Q    After Midco entered into this agreement with All
    Star and Mr. Palma, was there a change in
    Midco's ability to make sales to the Texas
    Pipe Bending Company?
    A    Yes, sir, very much so.
    Q    And what was that change?
    A    We had a hundred percent increase in business over
    and above what we used to do before.
    -11-
    11
    Q      Not to quibble with you, but if you had one sale
    before, a hundred percent increase would make
    it two sales. How big an increase was it?
    A      Astronomical.
    * * *
    Q      Did Midco pay--make payments to Texas Pipe Bending
    during the '83-'84 period pursuant to the
    volume discount arrangement?
    A      Yes, sir.
    * * *
    Q      Would you describe for us the substance or the
    gist
    of these calls that you had with Mr. Palma?
    A      He would tell me whether or not they were hard
    dollar jobs or whether or not they were 10 or
    15 percent jobs.
    * * *
    Q      Were you told the amount of the quality discount
    before or after Midco made up its bid to
    Texas Pipe Bending?
    A      Before.
    Q      Why were you told before?
    A      You would have to know how much to add into the
    price.
    Q      What do you mean you would have to know how much
    to
    add into the price?
    A      If we were giving Texas Pipe Bending 10 or 15
    percent, we would certainly have to cover it
    in the price we were quoting.
    Q      Did Midco--was there any profitability into the
    Midco quotes to Texas Pipe Bending for Midco
    in addition to whatever you were putting in
    for the Texas Pipe Bending Company?
    A      Yes.
    * * *
    Q      On the bids that Midco submitted to the Texas Pipe
    Bending Company during the 1983-'84 period,
    did the Midco bids show on their face the
    amount of the discount that was included?
    A      No.
    Q      Did the Midco bids in '83-'84 show on their face
    that All Star and Mr. Palma were acting as
    your sales agent?
    A      No.
    * * *
    Q      Would you explain for us what that notation means?
    A      Well, Texas Pipe Bending would be given 15 percent
    of the selling price of the order. And 25
    percent of the gross profit after all
    -12-
    12
    expenses would be paid to All Star
    Industries.
    Q    . . . was that a notation that went on documents
    that left the Midco Company?
    A    No.
    * * *
    A    [Mr. Palma] would tell me to protect certain
    prices
    on certain bids.
    * * *
    Q    And what did you do with the information when Mr.
    Palma told you to protect certain bids?
    A    I raised the prices that we were bidding.
    Record on Appeal, vol. 38, at 9-163 to 9-166, 9-168 to 9-
    172;
    see also Record on Appeal, vol. 39, at 10-31 to 10-32:
    Q    When Midco put in a bid with a protect number, was
    that a number that Midco chose as a
    competitive number?
    A    No.
    Q    Where did Midco get that number to bid above?
    A    From Mr. Palma.
    -- The testimony of Robert Cohn, Midco's former
    executive vice-president and president, further
    substantiates Midco's participation in the conspiracy:
    Q     What use did you make of the information that Mr.
    Palma gave you about protecting prices?
    A     We protected the prices by quoting a higher one
    than
    was mentioned.
    * * *
    Q     How accurate was Mr. Palma's information about
    which
    items Midco would get and not get?
    A     I can never remember them being in error.
    * * *
    Q     Did there come a point in time--did you ever learn
    whether or not All Star was bidding on the
    same jobs as Midco?
    A     We did. I did.
    * * *
    Q     Why did you continue to use All Star's services--
    excuse me, why did you continue to use Mr.
    Palma's and All Star's services after you had
    learned those factors?
    A     Because Midco--and we felt that whatever business
    we
    might get would be more than we would get
    otherwise.
    -13-
    13
    cooperation and participation, and the distributors obliged:
    -- Distributors knew that TPB was required to submit at
    least three competitive bids to its customers for their
    approval, and they took pains to make these bids look
    legitimate to the end users.13
    -- Distributors did not allocate jobs exactly evenly
    because knew that would look suspicious, meaning that
    the distributors made a deliberate effort to maintain
    the appearance of competitive bidding. See supra note
    12.
    -- Even on contracts for items they knew they would not
    be getting because they were protecting the prices of
    other bidders, the distributors would "develop" their
    prices by calling manufacturers to give them the
    impression that distributors were preparing competitive
    bids.14
    Record on Appeal, vol. 39, at 10-40 to 10-44.
    13
    This is substantiated by the testimony of James Dooner,
    who was employed by Capitol from 1966 through 1969 and its
    competitor, Guyon, from 1969 through 1985 as a sales supervisor
    for all southwestern states:
    Q    Now, Mr. Dooner, did you have some expectation about
    what percentage of the sales on rigged bids
    to TPB you were going to win?
    A    On a specific order?
    Q    Yes.
    A    The percentage varied. But the answer is yes
    because there are some items we didn't
    receive at all.
    Q    Did you expect to get a share equal to the other
    distributors on each sale?
    A    Yes.
    * * *
    Q    Did you always get -- if there were three bidders,
    did you always get 33 percent of
    the sales of a rigged bid?
    A    No.
    Q    Why not?
    A    The percentage varied because being an equal
    percentage would look as if it was pre-done.
    Record on Appeal, vol. 32, at 3-56 to 3-58.
    14
    This effort to make end users believe that the
    distributors' bidding was competitive is described by the
    testimony of Steve Scott, president of U.S. Metals:
    Q    If you could just tell the jury if you ever did
    -14-
    14
    Rather than merely being these distributors' customer who then
    went on to cheat its own customers, TPB was the distributors'
    conduit for passing their inflated, non-competitive specialty
    steel bids onto unsuspecting end users.   Moreover, in at least
    one instance, TPB was also the distributors' horizontal
    "competitor" who benefited from the conspiracy at their level.15
    Accordingly, we find that defendants cannot escape the per
    se rule simply because their conspiracy depended upon the
    anything, you personally ever did anything to
    make it look like you were competing on the
    jobs where quarterbacking was going on?
    A    By developing prices with all the manufacturers.
    Q    You developed prices with all the manufacturers,
    that is what you are saying?
    A    Yes.
    Q    Why would -- what was the purpose of that?
    A    Two-fold. To have an idea of the overall value of
    the project. And give the manufacturers that
    appearance that we were developing
    competitive prices on the whole job.
    Q    Now, Mr. Scott, you personally worked on bids to
    Texas Pipe Bending on sales that were
    quarterbacked; is that right?
    A    That is correct.
    Q    And you also submitted bids to Texas Pipe Bending
    on
    sales that weren't quarterbacked; is that
    right?
    A    That is correct.
    Record on Appeal, vol. 40, at 11-126. Therefore, while the
    "winning bidder" did not sell its product directly to the end
    user, it knew who its end user was and that it had successfully
    deceived that end user into paying a rigged price for its
    product. Id.
    15
    Government Exhibit 13a is a TPB breakdown listing
    materials needed to fulfill its cost-plus contracts with a "G",
    "C", or "M" beside the entries to indicate which company--Guyon,
    Capitol, or MIA--the work was designated to. Some of the entries
    are flagged "TPB stock protect", meaning that TPB had the
    materials in its inventory, would bid along with the
    distributors, and that bidding for these materials would be
    rigged so that TPB would win.
    -15-
    15
    participation of a "middle-man", even if that middleman
    conceptualized the conspiracy, orchestrated it by bringing the
    distributors together around contracts it held with its buyers,
    and collected most of the booty.16    We find, therefore, that the
    district court did not err by instructing the jury in accordance
    with the per se rule and refusing defendants' rule of reason
    instruction.
    3
    Defendants also challenge the district court's jury
    instruction on the grounds that the district court should have
    instructed the jury on their theories of defense--that is, good
    16
    The government argues that the case before us is
    analogous to United States v. MMR Corp., 
    907 F.2d 489
     (5th Cir.
    1990), cert. denied sub nom., 
    111 S. Ct. 1388
     (1991)--a case in
    which defendants were also convicted of conspiracy to rig bids in
    violation of the Sherman Act after the district court applied the
    per se liability rule. There we considered a similar contention:
    defendants argued that, since MMR lacked the bonding capacity to
    successfully bid the project at issue and, therefore, could not
    successfully compete with other conspirators, MMR was not an
    actual competitor and per se liability rules did not apply. 
    Id. at 496-97
    . We rejected that contention, holding that:
    even if MMR is deemed not to be an actual or potential
    competitor of Fischbach and the other companies, the
    conspiracy was not a meaningless conspiracy between
    noncompetitors since [other actors] were
    competitors. . . . [A] noncompetitor can join a Sherman
    Act bid-rigging conspiracy among competitors. If there
    is a horizontal agreement between A and B, there is no
    reason why others joining that conspiracy must be
    competitors. . . . Second, the facts of this case
    illustrate how a company, although arguably unable in
    fact to carry out its competitive threat . . . can
    nonetheless further a conspiracy among competitors.
    
    Id. at 498
    . Applying our MMR holding to the case at issue,
    even if TPB is deemed not to be an actual competitor, the bid-
    rigging conspiracy was not a meaningless conspiracy between
    noncompetitors. The distributors were horizontal competitors
    and, at least on one occasion, TPB bidded along with them. See
    supra note 15.
    -16-
    16
    faith and lack of specific intent.    Specifically, they argue
    that, "[e]ven assuming, hypothetically, that this case involves a
    per se violation of the [S]herman [A]ct, there still must be
    evidence that the defendant intended to commit the specific
    intent offense charged."17
    We recognize that, "[w]hen a defendant properly requests an
    instruction on a theory of defense that is supported by some
    evidence, it is reversible error not to adequately present the
    theory."   United States v. Johnson, 
    872 F.2d 612
    , 622 (5th Cir.
    1989) (reviewing instruction as a whole and holding that
    instruction on defense theory of entrapment was adequate); see
    also United States v. Schmick, 
    904 F.2d 936
    , 943 (5th Cir. 1990)
    ("It has long been well established in this Circuit that it is
    reversible error to refuse a charge on a defense theory for which
    there is an evidentiary foundation and which, if believed by the
    jury, would be legally sufficient to render the accused
    innocent.") (citations omitted), cert. denied sub nom., 
    111 S. Ct. 782
     (1991).   However, when considering such a jury
    instruction challenge on appeal, we read the district court's
    instruction as a whole to determine whether it accurately
    reflects the law.   See United States v. Daniel, 
    957 F.2d 162
    , 169
    (5th Cir. 1992) (viewing jury instruction as a whole and holding
    that lack of good faith instruction and inclusion of instruction
    on deliberate ignorance does not constitute reversible error);
    United States v. Hagmann, 
    950 F.2d 175
    , 180 (5th Cir. 1992)
    17
    Midco Reply Brief at 16.
    -17-
    17
    ("When a charge is challenged on appeal, we evaluate it in its
    entirety, looking to see whether the charge as a whole was
    correct."); United States v. Featherson, 
    949 F.2d 770
    , 777 (5th
    Cir. 1991) ("The standard of review for jury instructions is
    usually whether the court's charge, as a whole, is a correct
    statement of the law and plainly instructs the jurors as to the
    principles of law applicable to the fact issues confronting
    them."), cert. denied sub nom., __ S. Ct. __ (1992).
    We have found that it was proper for the district court to
    instruct the jury in accordance with the per se rule.   See supra
    Part II.A.1-2.   Therefore, the government's only burden was to
    prove that the per se agreement alleged was in fact made and that
    -18-
    18
    defendants knowingly and intentionally joined that agreement.18
    The district court instructed the jury as follows:
    18
    A price fixing conspiracy under the Sherman Act is not
    a crime requiring proof of a "specific intent" to restrain trade
    or to violate the law. See American Tobacco Co. v. United
    States, 
    328 U.S. 781
    , 809-10, 
    66 S. Ct. 1125
    , 1139 (1946) ("No
    formal agreement is necessary to constitute an unlawful
    conspiracy. . . . Where the circumstances are such as to warrant
    a jury in finding that the conspirators had a unity of purpose or
    a common design and understanding, or a meeting of minds in an
    unlawful arrangement, the conclusion that a conspiracy is
    established is justified."); Interstate Circuit, Inc. v. United
    States, 
    306 U.S. 208
    , 227, 
    59 S. Ct. 467
    , 474 (1939) ("Acceptance
    by competitors, without previous agreement, of an invitation to
    participate in a plan, the necessary consequence of which, if
    carried out, is restraint of interstate commerce, is sufficient
    to establish unlawful conspiracy under the Sherman Act."). The
    intent element of a per se offense is established by evidence
    that the defendant agreed to engage in conduct that is per se
    illegal; the government is not required to prove that the
    defendant knew his actions were illegal or that he specifically
    intended to restrain trade or to violate the law. See United
    States v MMR Corp., 
    907 F.2d 489
    , 495 (5th Cir. 1990), cert.
    denied sub nom., 
    111 S. Ct. 1388
     (1991):
    The government . . . is not required to prove a formal,
    express agreement with all the terms precisely set out
    and clearly understood by the conspirators. . . . It
    is enough that the government shows that the defendants
    accepted an invitation to join in a conspiracy whose
    object was unlawfully restraining trade.
    See also United States v. Young Brothers, Inc., 
    728 F.2d 682
    , 687
    (5th Cir.) ("In order to prove that appellant actually intended
    to enter into the bidrigging conspiracy, the government was
    required to show that appellant knowingly joined or participated
    in the conspiracy."), cert. denied, 
    469 U.S. 881
    , 
    105 S. Ct. 246
    (1984); United States v. Brown, 
    936 F.2d 1042
    , 1045-46 (9th Cir.
    1991) (holding that district court did not err in "holding that
    it was unnecessary to instruct the jury that intent to produce
    anticompetitive effects is an element of the offense of which
    [defendants] were convicted."); United States v. W.F. Brinkley &
    Sons Constr. Co., 
    783 F.2d 1157
    , 1161-62 (4th Cir. 1986) ("The
    word `knowingly' as that term has been used from time to time in
    these instructions means that the act was done voluntarily and
    intentionally and not because of mistake or accident."); United
    States v. Koppers Co., 
    652 F.2d 290
    , 294 (2d Cir.) ("In cases
    involving behavior such as bid rigging . . . the Sherman Act will
    be read as simply saying: `An agreement among competitors to rig
    bids is illegal.'") (citation omitted), cert. denied, 
    454 U.S. 1083
    , 
    102 S. Ct. 639
     (1981).
    -19-
    19
    To establish the required intent the Government
    must prove beyond a reasonable doubt that the
    defendants knowingly and willfully did something which
    the law forbids. In this case, that means that the
    Government must prove beyond a reasonable doubt that
    the defendants knowingly and willfully formed, joined
    or participated in a combination or conspiracy to rig
    bids. Since a combination or conspiracy to rig bids is
    unreasonable and illegal as a matter of law, the
    Government does not have to prove that the defendants
    specifically intended to unreasonably restrain trade or
    that such conduct is an unreasonable restraint of
    trade.19
    We find that, read as whole, this instruction accurately reflects
    the law--that is, the district court correctly instructed the
    jury that the government had to establish beyond a reasonable
    doubt that (1) the bid rigging conspiracy charged in the
    indictment was knowingly and willfully formed, (2) each defendant
    knowingly and willfully became a member of that conspiracy, and
    (3) the conspiracy affected or occurred in the flow of interstate
    commerce.20   Moreover, because the bid-rigging agreement alleged
    19
    Record Excerpts of Defendants-Appellants at tab 30,
    United States v. All Star Industries, Inc., No. 91-2439 (5th Cir.
    filed Oct. 16, 1991) (jury instruction No. 12) ["Record
    Excerpts"].
    20
    See Jury Instruction No. 9, in Record Excerpts at tab
    30. The district court also instructed the jury as to: the
    elements of a conspiracy (Jury Instruction No. 10) ("A conspiracy
    under Section I of the Sherman Act is an unlawful agreement by
    two or more persons or corporations to accomplish a common
    objective which would result in an unreasonable restraint of
    interstate commerce."); what constitutes "knowing" and "willful"
    and that "the Government must prove beyond a reasonable doubt
    that the defendants knowingly and willfully formed, joined or
    participated in a combination or conspiracy to rig bids (Jury
    Instruction Nos. 11-12); what constitutes bid rigging and the
    significance of such a finding (Jury Instruction No. 13) ("In
    this case, if you find beyond a reasonable doubt that a defendant
    was a member of a conspiracy to rig bids as alleged in the
    indictment, then you need not decide whether such conspiracy was
    -20-
    20
    by the government was per se illegal, defendants' other theories
    of defense--theories incorporated in defendants' proposed
    instructions which the district court rejected--were irrelevant,
    and we find that the district court did not err in rejecting
    them.21
    reasonable or unreasonable because . . . an agreement among
    competitors not to compete for contracts by submitting collusive
    bids is per se unreasonable and a violation of the Sherman
    Act."); that good faith is no defense (Jury Instruction No. 15:
    "A conspiracy to rig bids in or affecting interstate trade and
    commerce is unlawful, even though the conspiracy may be formed or
    engaged in for what appear to the conspirators to be laudable
    motives.") (Jury Instruction No. 20: ". . . the fact that a
    defendant may have believed, in good faith, that what was being
    done was not unlawful would not be a defense."). 
    Id.
    21
    Defendants assert that their actions caused no economic
    harm. Specifically, they assert that, "if the end users were
    unhappy with the bids that TPB solicited, they could reject them.
    Some did. If they were unhappy with the entire program, they
    could have negotiated for a fixed price contract. If offended by
    TPB's allocation, they could have proceeded against TPB for
    breach of contract." Midco Brief at 13. Defendants also assert
    that, even if end users were harmed, the distributors did not
    benefit from the price-rigging arrangement since TPB collected
    all the conspiracy profits: "If a price is raised 15% and then a
    15% rebate is made, the supplier would make no more profit than
    if none of that occurred." Midco Reply Brief at 8. They also
    assert that their "involvement in the alleged conspiracy . . .
    occurred after the end users had already reaped the benefits of
    competition, the negotiated low percentage plus on their cost-
    plus contracts. Therefore Midco's acts were not likely to cause
    harm, not plainly anticompetitive and not properly subject to per
    se analysis." 
    Id. at 13
    .
    Where there is a per se illegal price-fixing agreement, it
    is no defense that the agreement at issue did not have
    anticompetitive effects, or that defendant's motives were
    benevolent. See N.C.A.A. v. Board of Regents of Univ. of Okl.,
    
    468 U.S. 85
    , 109-110, 
    104 S. Ct. 2948
    , 2964-65 (1984) (Holding
    that, "when there is an agreement not to compete in terms of
    price or output, `no elaborate industry analysis is required to
    demonstrate the anticompetitive character of such an
    agreement.'") (citation omitted); United States v. Socony-Vacuum
    Oil Co., 
    310 U.S. 150
    , 224 n.59, 
    60 S. Ct. 811
    , 845 n.59 (1940)
    (citation omitted):
    But that does not mean that both a purpose and a power
    -21-
    21
    to fix prices are necessary for the establishment of a
    conspiracy under § 1 of the Sherman Act. That would be
    true if power or ability to commit an offense was
    necessary in order to convict a person of conspiring to
    commit it. But it is well established that a person
    "may be guilty of conspiring, although incapable of
    committing the objective offense."
    See also United States v. Cargo Service Stations, Inc., 
    657 F.2d 676
    , 683-84 (5th Cir. 1981), cert. denied, 
    455 U.S. 1017
    , 
    102 S. Ct. 1712
     (1982) (defendants need only knowingly and intentionally
    join conspiracy to rig bids) (per se rule condemns conspiracies
    never implemented, as well as those that fail to achieve their
    objectives and produce no anticompetitive effects); 
    id. at 683
    ("We think it follows that if price fixing is inevitably an
    unreasonably restraint of trade, the intent to fix prices is
    equivalent to the intent to unreasonably restrain trade.").
    Moreover, there is evidence in the record that distributors
    ended up charging end users prices inflated 10 to 15 percent
    above competitive prices. Record on Appeal, vol. 37, at 8-34
    (testimony of Bruce Painchaud, an MIA employee from 1978 through
    1987). Although, as pointed out by defendants, the bidding
    arrangement between end users and TPB allowed the end users to
    reject the distributors' bids, we cannot fault the end users for
    accepting them. The end users took precautions to insure that
    the specialty steel bids incorporated into TPB contracts were
    competitive by requiring TPB to provide at least three bids--
    precautions which were overcome by conspiracy.
    And finally, although TPB may have reaped most of the
    rewards from this markup, the distributors still benefited from
    the bid-rigging arrangement in that their participation
    guaranteed them a share of the contracts:
    -- Consider the testimony of Robert Cohn, executive
    vice- president and then president of Midco during the
    years 1981-1984:
    Q    Why did you protect those prices as requested by
    Mr.
    Palma?
    A    Because Mr. Palma was our agent and he was on the
    scene and we assumed he knew what he was
    doing and we followed his instructions.
    * * *
    Q    Why did protecting another competitor's price help
    Midco get business with Texas Pipe?
    A    Well, I don't believe that every order would go to
    one single company because we, Midco couldn't
    get every piece of business. And someone
    else
    might have had a better inventory of a
    commodity or a better price.
    -22-
    22
    B
    As a condition of probation, the district court ordered the
    corporate defendants jointly and severally liable for restitution
    to the victims of their conspiracy in the amount of $859,935.22
    MIA now asserts that the district court abused its discretion by:
    Record on Appeal, vol. 39, 10-41.
    -- Rossetti's testimony further substantiates that the
    distributors benefited from the conspiracy arrangement:
    Q    Why did Midco put down protected numbers on some
    of
    its bids to Texas Pipe Bending Company?
    A    Well, we were told to, and the only way we would
    get
    business was by participating on this basis.
    * * *
    Q    How did you know this was the only way you would
    get
    business?
    A    Because this was the way it was happening and we
    were getting it on that basis.
    Record on Appeal, vol. 38, at 9-171 to 9-172; 
    id.
     at 9-
    163 (quoted more extensively supra note 12):
    Q    After Midco entered into this agreement with All
    Star and Mr. Palma, was there a change in
    Midco's ability to make sales to the Texas
    Pipe Bending Co?
    * * *
    Q    Not to quibble with you, but if you had one sale
    before, a hundred percent increase would make
    it two sales. How big an increase was it?
    A    Astronomical.
    22
    The district court ordered this restitution pursuant to
    section 3651 of the Probation Act. 
    18 U.S.C. § 3651
     (1985).
    While this section has been repealed, the Probation Act which
    predated the Sentencing Reform Act still applies to offenses
    committed before November 1, 1987. See United States v. Balboa,
    
    893 F.2d 703
    , 706 (5th Cir. 1990) (holding that, although
    probation statute was repealed by Sentencing Reform Act, old
    provision continued to apply to offenses which occurred before
    effective date of Act, Nov. 1, 1987).
    -23-
    23
    (1) ordering restitution that covers injuries occurring
    outside the limitations period for antitrust
    violations,
    (2) failing to credit Mannesmann for payments made to
    settle civil claims involving the same conduct and
    parties, and
    (3) making restitution a joint and several obligation
    against Mannesmann since Mannesmann was not involved in
    several projects for which restitution was awarded.
    1
    MIA raises an assertion before this court that it did not
    raise below--that, because the statute of limitations for
    antitrust violations is five years, MIA cannot be made to pay
    restitution for losses occurring more than five years before the
    return of the indictment.   Because this contention was not raised
    below, we review it only for plain error--that is, we look to see
    whether "our failure to consider the question results in
    `manifest injustice.'"   United States v. Gerald Vonsteen, 
    950 F.2d 1086
    , 1092 (5th 1992) (citation omitted); see United States
    v. Sherbak, 
    950 F.2d 1095
    , 1101 (5th Cir. 1992) ("[I]ssues raised
    for the first time on appeal `are not reviewable by this [c]ourt
    unless they involve purely legal questions and failure to
    consider them would result in manifest injustice.") (citations
    omitted).23
    23
    See also United States v. Campbell, 
    942 F.2d 890
    , 894
    n.2 (5th Cir. 1991) ("Because Campbell raises this claim for the
    first time on appeal, the issue is deemed waived."); United
    States v. Jackson, 
    700 F.2d 181
    , 190 (5th Cir.), cert. denied,
    
    464 U.S. 842
    , 
    104 S. Ct. 139
     (1983) ("We have long held that,
    absent a showing of manifest injustice, a litigant may not raise
    a theory on appeal that was not presented to the district
    court.").
    -24-
    24
    A Sherman Act conspiracy is a partnership in crime that
    continues until all its objectives have been accomplished or
    abandoned.   See United States v. Kissel, 
    218 U.S. 601
    , 607-08, 31
    S. Ct 124, 126 (1910) ("A conspiracy to restrain or monopolize
    trade by improperly excluding a competitor from business
    contemplates that the conspirators will remain in business, and
    will continue their combined efforts to drive the competitor out
    until they succeed.") ("A conspiracy is a partnership in criminal
    purposes . . . . [and] an overt act of one partner may be the act
    of all without any new agreement specifically directed to that
    act.").   MIA was convicted of participating in a single
    continuing conspiracy that began more than five years before the
    indictment was returned, but which did not end until 1984--a time
    within the five-year period of limitations.   Under the Probation
    Act,24 the only limits on restitution are that repayment must
    relate (i) to the particular offense of which the defendant was
    convicted and (ii) to the actual losses suffered by the victim.
    See United States v. Boswell, 
    565 F.2d 1338
    , 1343 (5th Cir.) ("As
    a condition of probation a district court undoubtedly has the
    authority to require that a defendant make restitution to injured
    parties for the actual loss or damage caused by the offense for
    which he stands convicted . . . .") (citations omitted) (emphasis
    in original), cert. denied, 
    439 U.S. 819
    , 
    99 S. Ct. 81
     (1978);
    see also United States v. Stuver, 
    845 F.2d 73
    , 76 (4th Cir. 1988)
    (holding that precise amount of loss for restitution purposes
    24
    See supra note 22.
    -25-
    25
    must be legally determined in the underlying criminal
    proceeding); United States v. Johnson, 
    700 F.2d 699
    , 701 (11th
    Cir. 1983) ("The amount of restitution cannot exceed the actual
    losses flowing from the offense for which the defendant had been
    convicted.").   The restitution order in this case did not exceed
    those bounds and, therefore, does not constitute "manifest
    injustice."
    2
    MIA also claims that the restitution order should be reduced
    by the amount of money MIA paid to settle a civil class action
    suit alleging "the same form of conspiracy for which Mannesmann
    was convicted in this case."25   We disagree.
    While a court may offset restitution in a criminal case by
    the amount of a civil settlement to avoid double recovery by
    victims, the availability of such an offset
    depends upon what payment was made in the settlement,
    whether the claims settled involved the same acts of
    the defendants as those that are predicates of their
    criminal convictions, and whether the payment satisfies
    the penal purposes the district court sought to impose.
    United States v. Rico Industries, Inc., 
    854 F.2d 710
    , 715 (5th
    Cir. 1988), cert. denied, 
    489 U.S. 1078
    , 
    109 S. Ct. 1529
     (1989).
    In the civil case, plaintiffs alleged a 20-year price fixing
    conspiracy beginning in 1966, that affected hundreds of projects,
    fabricators, engineering companies, and end users.26    The
    criminal case at issue concerns a four-year bid rigging
    25
    MIA Brief at 28.
    26
    Record Excerpts at tab 33.
    -26-
    26
    conspiracy involving sales made through a single fabricator, TPB.
    Only two of the 28 defendants named in the civil suit--MIA and
    Guyon--were involved in the criminal conspiracy.   Most
    importantly, in settling its civil case, MIA paid a total of
    $814,000 to a significantly broader class of victims for a
    significantly broader number of projects, and MIA has offered no
    accounting to show how the victims of its criminal conspiracy
    received restitution through that civil conspiracy settlement.27
    Accordingly, we find no reason to diminish the amount of the
    district court's restitution order.
    3
    Finally, MIA asserts that, since its involvement in the
    conspiracy was limited, the district court's award of joint
    restitution is patently unfair to MIA.   Specifically, MIA argues
    that:
    [i]f MIA were a major player in the conspiracy, it
    would have been involved in a larger share of the
    number of allegedly rigged inquiries. The government
    introduced evidence of bids on 72 different projects.
    MIA submitted a total of eleven (11) bids on all of the
    projects. The 72 projects ultimately became jobs. The
    evidence at trial indicated that MIA participated in
    only eight total jobs. . . . In short, the government
    attempts to place responsibility on MIA's shoulder's
    for a volume of commerce that exceeded $5,000,000. The
    projects for which MIA allegedly sold pipe had a total
    27
    MIA's civil settlement does not limit MIA's payments to
    victims injured by bid rigging in this criminal case; rather,
    that settlement extends to all purchasers of specialty steel
    piping material in the United States who purchased under cost-
    plus contracts between 1966 and 1985 from numerous fabricators in
    addition to TPB. Record Excerpts at tab 34, pp. 3-4; MIA Brief at
    28.
    -27-
    27
    of just $1,842,693 in volume of commerce allegedly
    affected by the conspiracy.28
    MIA's assertion is based on the claim that, while it is
    financially able to pay and the other defendants are not, the
    other defendants' culpability is demonstratably greater.
    The government charged, and the jury found, that defendants
    engaged in a single, continuing conspiracy to rig bids on certain
    cost-plus contracts between 1981 and 1984.   It is well-
    established that, as a participant in this conspiracy, MIA is
    legally liable for all the acts of its coconspirators in
    furtherance of this crime.   See United States v. Kissel, 
    218 U.S. 601
    , 608, 
    31 S. Ct. 124
    , 126 (1910) ("[T]he conspiracy continues
    up to the time of abandonment or success.") ("A conspiracy is a
    partnership in criminal purposes . . . [and] an overt act of one
    partner may be the act of all without any new agreement
    specifically directed to that act."); see also Hyde v. United
    States, 
    225 U.S. 347
    , 369, 
    32 S. Ct. 793
    , 803 (1912) (the
    liability of an individual conspirator continues until the
    conspiracy accomplishes its goals or that conspirator withdraws,
    the latter of which requires an affirmative action).
    Accordingly, the district court did not abuse its discretion in
    holding MIA jointly and severally liable for all losses to the
    victims of the four-year conspiracy proved at trial.   See United
    States v. Haile, 
    795 F.2d 489
    , 491 (5th Cir. 1986) (Section 3651
    28
    MIA Reply Brief of Defendants-Appellants Mannesman
    International Alloys, Inc. and Richard A. Brazzale at 10, United
    States v. All Star Industries, Inc., No. 91-2439 (5th Cir. filed
    Dec. 13, 1991) (citations and footnotes omitted).
    -28-
    28
    of the Probation Act "gives broad authority to district courts to
    impose conditions of probation that in the judgment of the
    sentencing judge serve to rehabilitate the criminal or secure
    compliance with court orders, and otherwise are in the public
    interest.") (holding, however, that Probation Act precludes
    monetary penalties other than those enumerated in the statute);
    United States v. Van Cauwenberghe, 
    827 F.2d 424
    , 435 (9th Cir.
    1987) (holding that joint and several liability for entire actual
    loss could have been imposed on each fraud defendant as condition
    of probation), cert. denied, 
    484 U.S. 1042
    , 
    108 S. Ct. 773
    (1988); United States v. Tzakis, 
    736 F.2d 867
    , 871 (2d Cir. 1984)
    (holding that district court did not abuse its discretion by
    imposing on defendant, as condition of probation, joint and
    several liability with codefendant for restitution of full amount
    of losses caused by their crime); see also United States v. Hand,
    
    863 F.2d 1100
    , 1106 (3d Cir. 1988) (Holding that, in ordering
    restitution under the Victim & Witness Protection Act, the fact
    that burden of restitution lay entirely on one defendant where
    two codefendants were equally culpable did not offend
    Constitution and "certainly . . . did not constitute an abuse of
    discretion.").
    III
    For the foregoing reasons, we AFFIRM.
    -29-
    29
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 91-2439

Filed Date: 5/28/1992

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 12/21/2014

Authorities (31)

United States v. Jeanne P. Johnson, Clarence A. Johnson , 700 F.2d 699 ( 1983 )

United States v. Ioannis Tzakis , 736 F.2d 867 ( 1984 )

United States v. Rico Industries, Inc., and Richard Hughes ... , 854 F.2d 710 ( 1988 )

United States v. Gary M. Stuver, A/K/A Gary M. Stuven , 845 F.2d 73 ( 1988 )

United States v. W.F. Brinkley & Son Construction Company, ... , 783 F.2d 1157 ( 1986 )

United States v. Patricia Hand , 863 F.2d 1100 ( 1988 )

United States v. Mmr Corporation (La) and James B. Rutland , 907 F.2d 489 ( 1990 )

United States v. Edward L. Flom, David L. Hoffman, Frank W. ... , 558 F.2d 1179 ( 1977 )

United States v. Herbert Q. Haile , 795 F.2d 489 ( 1986 )

United States v. Martin David Johnson , 872 F.2d 612 ( 1989 )

United States v. Darryl Wayne Campbell , 942 F.2d 890 ( 1991 )

United States v. Rodney Featherson, A/K/A River Rat, James ... , 949 F.2d 770 ( 1991 )

United States v. Gerald Vontsteen, A/K/A Skip Vontsteen , 950 F.2d 1086 ( 1992 )

United States v. Cargo Service Stations, Inc., T. D. McRae ... , 657 F.2d 676 ( 1981 )

United States v. Hal Brown, Jr., United States of America v.... , 936 F.2d 1042 ( 1991 )

United States v. Eugene Sherbak, United States of America v.... , 950 F.2d 1095 ( 1992 )

United States v. Charles Ray Daniel and Patrick Henry Daniel , 957 F.2d 162 ( 1992 )

united-states-v-franklin-d-schmick-joseph-edward-parr-william-jerry , 904 F.2d 936 ( 1990 )

United States v. Robert F. Hagmann , 950 F.2d 175 ( 1992 )

United States v. Robert D. Balboa , 893 F.2d 703 ( 1990 )

View All Authorities »