NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company ( 2007 )


Menu:
  •                              RECOMMENDED FOR FULL-TEXT PUBLICATION
    Pursuant to Sixth Circuit Rule 206
    File Name: 07a0424p.06
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE SIXTH CIRCUIT
    _________________
    X
    Plaintiff-Appellant, -
    NICSAND, INC.,
    -
    -
    -
    No. 05-3431
    v.
    ,
    >
    3M COMPANY,                                                -
    Defendant-Appellee. -
    N
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of Ohio at Cleveland.
    No. 03-02619—Ann Aldrich, District Judge.
    Argued: March 7, 2007
    Decided and Filed: October 17, 2007
    Before: BOGGS, Chief Judge; MARTIN, SILER, BATCHELDER, DAUGHTREY, COLE,
    CLAY, GILMAN, GIBBONS, ROGERS, SUTTON,* COOK, McKEAGUE, and GRIFFIN,
    Circuit Judges.
    _________________
    COUNSEL
    ARGUED: Dennis E. Murray, Jr., MURRAY & MURRAY CO., L.P.A., Sandusky, Ohio, for
    Appellant. Dean Ringel, CAHILL, GORDON & REINDEL, New York, New York, for Appellee.
    ON BRIEF: Dennis E. Murray, Jr., MURRAY & MURRAY CO., L.P.A., Sandusky, Ohio, for
    Appellant. Dean Ringel, CAHILL, GORDON & REINDEL, New York, New York, James P.
    Murphy, SQUIRE, SANDERS & DEMPSEY, Washington, D.C., J. Philip Calabrese, SQUIRE,
    SANDERS & DEMPSEY, Cleveland, Ohio, for Appellee.
    SUTTON, J., delivered the opinion of the court, in which BOGGS, C. J., SILER,
    BATCHELDER, GILMAN, GIBBONS, ROGERS, COOK, McKEAGUE, and GRIFFIN, JJ.,
    joined. MARTIN, J. (pp. 13-22), delivered a separate dissenting opinion, in which DAUGHTREY,
    COLE, and CLAY, JJ., joined.
    *
    The Honorable Karen Nelson Moore, Circuit Judge, took no part in the consideration or decision of the case.
    1
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                              Page 2
    _________________
    OPINION
    _________________
    SUTTON, Circuit Judge. Between 1987 and 2001, NicSand and 3M were the only
    nationwide suppliers in the market for do-it-yourself automotive sandpaper, and they competed for
    the business of six large retailers, which controlled 80% of the market and which (with one
    exception) offered their shelf space on an exclusive basis for a year at a time. NicSand developed
    this niche market and eventually gained a 67% share of it. Between 1997 and 2001, however, it lost
    most of the market when 3M offered the large retailers greater up-front discounts and longer
    exclusive agreements than NicSand had offered in the past or apparently was willing to offer in the
    future.
    When NicSand filed an antitrust lawsuit to complain about 3M’s conduct, the district court
    dismissed the complaint for lack of antitrust standing and, more particularly, for lack of a cognizable
    antitrust injury. Because 3M did not engage in below-cost—or predatory—pricing, because five of
    the six large retailers demanded exclusivity as a precondition for doing business, because the
    allegations show no more than that 3M competed with its rival on the same essential terms that
    NicSand and the large retailers had already established for this market and because the antitrust laws
    in the end protect competition, not competitors, we affirm.
    I.
    This case comes to us as an appeal from a Rule 12(b)(6) dismissal. We thus look to
    NicSand’s allegations in the complaint (in truth, the first amended complaint) to determine the
    details of the dispute—who the parties are, how the market for do-it-yourself automotive sandpaper
    works and how the parties competed with each other.
    The parties. NicSand is an Ohio corporation based in Berea, Ohio, and has been in business
    since 1982. It makes a variety of products for automotive body repair, including automotive
    sandpaper (technically speaking, coated abrasives), which consumers use before, during or after
    painting a car or truck. Sales of automotive sandpaper accounted for one-half of NicSand’s revenue
    in 1996. 3M is a Delaware corporation based in Maplewood, Minnesota. In addition to making a
    variety of other products, 3M produces automotive sandpaper.
    The market for do-it-yourself automotive sandpaper. NicSand “largely developed” the
    market for do-it-yourself automotive sandpaper, increasing the number of products offered in the
    market from 20 in 1987 to 80 in 2000. Am. Compl. ¶ 10. The development of the market, NicSand
    claims, was “fueled primarily by [its] superior marketing, superior packaging, innovation, and
    superior value.” 
    Id. ¶ 11.
           Between 1987 and 2000, just two companies supplied automotive sandpaper (and related
    products) in the national market: NicSand and 3M. As of 1995, NicSand was the dominant player,
    holding a 67% share of the market.
    NicSand and 3M did not sell their automotive sandpaper products directly to consumers; they
    instead relied on retailers to distribute the products through a “highly concentrated” retail market.
    
    Id. ¶ 14.
    In 1997, just six large retailers—Advance Auto Parts, AutoZone, CSK Auto, Kmart, Pep
    Boys, Wal-Mart—controlled 80% of the retail market, while smaller retailers divided up the
    remaining 20% of the market.
    Perhaps due to the relatively “small value” of the market, five of the six large retailers sold
    just one brand of the product at a time, meaning they permitted NicSand or 3M, but not both, to sell
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                             Page 3
    its products at the stores. 
    Id. ¶ 62.
    “In order to simplify planning and reduce costs,” the large
    retailers also re-negotiated these single-brand agreements just once a year, giving the supplier a
    year-long “de facto exclusive agreement” with each retailer. 
    Id. ¶ 25.
    In order to replace an existing
    supplier of automotive sandpaper, a new supplier not only had to offer favorable prices but also had
    to (1) produce a full line of do-it-yourself automotive sandpaper, (2) provide racks and other display
    equipment for the retailer, (3) provide a discount on the retailer’s first order and (4) purchase the
    retailer’s existing supply of the sandpaper. Because the large retailers typically restocked the full
    line of sandpaper products five to seven times a year, buying out a retailer’s existing supply of the
    sandpaper could cost a supplier up to 14% to 20% of its annual revenues from that retailer.
    NicSand complied with these requirements in seeking to obtain the large retailers’ business,
    and by every measure it succeeded. By 1996, it was the exclusive supplier for four of the large
    retailers: Kmart, Advance Auto, CSK Auto and AutoZone. And along with 3M it supplied Pep
    Boys, the one large retailer that did not insist on an exclusive agreement.
    3M was the sole supplier of the sixth large retailer—Wal-Mart. NicSand did not—and could
    not—compete for this business, because Wal-Mart sought a single supplier that could meet all of
    its sandpaper needs, which included providing two products that NicSand did not make: sandpaper
    for Wal-Mart’s power tool and paint departments.
    NicSand made substantial profits on its exclusive-sales agreements with four of the six large
    retailers. In 1996, NicSand’s annual sales to Kmart totaled $475,000 with profit margins of 38%.
    In 1997, its sales to Advance Auto totaled $550,000 with margins of 49%, and its sales to CSK Auto
    totaled $369,000 with margins of 44%. In 1999, its sales to AutoZone totaled $2,200,000 with
    margins of 39%.
    Competition between the two companies from 1997 through 2001. According to NicSand,
    3M sought to monopolize the market for do-it-yourself automotive sandpaper beginning in 1997.
    To that end, 3M offered Kmart $300,000 in 1997 as an incentive to switch suppliers and to enter into
    an “explicit or sub rosa” exclusive-dealing agreement for “several years.” 
    Id. ¶ 23.
    Kmart accepted
    3M’s offer and told NicSand that it would not review price quotes from NicSand for a “few years.”
    
    Id. ¶ 26
    (emphasis omitted).
    One year later, 3M did the same thing with Advance Auto and CSK Auto, offering the one
    $285,000 and the other $200,000 to switch suppliers and to enter into “multi-year” exclusive-dealing
    agreements. 
    Id. ¶¶ 30,
    32. Advance Auto and CSK Auto accepted 3M’s offers and refused to
    discuss switching suppliers with NicSand “for at least a few years.” 
    Id. ¶ 37.
           Two years later, in 2000, 3M offered a similar deal to AutoZone, which long had been
    NicSand’s largest customer. 3M offered AutoZone $1,000,000 to switch suppliers and to enter a
    “multi-year” exclusive-dealing agreement. 
    Id. AutoZone accepted
    the offer. When contacted by
    NicSand, AutoZone refused to discuss switching back to NicSand as a supplier “for at least a few
    years.” 
    Id. By 2001,
    NicSand’s only remaining customers were Pep Boys (which sold NicSand and 3M
    products) and several smaller retailers. With a significant drop in its sales volume, NicSand lost its
    economies of scale; its “raw material costs increased dramatically,” 
    id. ¶ 41;
    and it could no longer
    “fill existing orders at an appropriate cost,” 
    id. ¶ 60.
    Because NicSand could “no
    longer . . . compete,” it left the market for do-it-yourself automotive sandpaper in 2001 and sought
    to reorganize under Chapter 11 of the Bankruptcy Code. 
    Id. ¶ 41.
    Since leaving the market,
    NicSand alleges that retailers (though it makes no allegations about suppliers like 3M) have raised
    consumer prices for do-it-yourself automotive sandpaper by as much as 70%.
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                               Page 4
    The complaint. On December 30, 2003, NicSand filed this lawsuit under § 4 of the Clayton
    Act, claiming that 3M had monopolized, or attempted to monopolize, the market for automotive
    sandpaper in violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act. See 15 U.S.C. §§ 2, 15. The complaint sought
    (1) to recover NicSand’s “lost profits” or the “value” of NicSand’s business and (2) to treble those
    damages as permitted under the antitrust laws. Compl. at 9. The district court dismissed the
    complaint under Rule 12(b)(6) for lack of antitrust standing because NicSand “failed to . . . plead
    an injury to competition resulting from 3M’s conduct.” D. Ct. Op. at 5.
    II.
    A.
    At first glance, one might fairly wonder whether a complaint like this one should be
    dismissed for lack of antitrust standing. Standing, in a conventional Article III sense, requires just
    proof of actual injury, causation and redressability. See Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife, 
    504 U.S. 555
    , 560–61 (1992). And NicSand readily satisfies these requirements: It was injured (when it lost
    these accounts); 3M caused the injury (when it offered better terms to the retailers than NicSand had
    offered in the past); and NicSand’s request for damages will redress its injury (by permitting it to
    recover the profits—indeed, three times the profits—it made before 3M entered the picture).
    Seemingly making matters easier for NicSand, we look at its complaint through the prism of Rule
    12(b)(6), requiring us to accept all of its allegations and all reasonable inferences from them as true.
    Mich. Paytel Joint Venture v. City of Detroit, 
    287 F.3d 527
    , 533 (6th Cir. 2002).
    Yet antitrust standing and Article III standing are not one and the same, and we not only
    may—but we must—reject claims under Rule 12(b)(6) when antitrust standing is missing. In the
    first place, an antitrust claimant must do more than make “allegations of consequential harm
    resulting from a violation of the antitrust laws,” and that is true even when the complaint is
    “buttressed by an allegation of intent to harm the [claimant].” Associated Gen. Contractors of Cal.,
    Inc. v. Cal. State Council of Carpenters, 
    459 U.S. 519
    , 545 (1983). Even when a complaint makes
    these allegations, it may not proceed when “[o]ther relevant factors—the nature of the [claimant’s]
    injury, the tenuous and speculative character of the relationship between the alleged antitrust
    violation and the [claimant’s] alleged injury, the potential for duplicative recovery or complex
    apportionment of damages, and the existence of more direct victims of the alleged
    conspiracy—weigh heavily against judicial enforcement.” 
    Id. Most pertinently
    for our purposes,
    antitrust standing “ensures that a plaintiff can recover only if the loss stems from a
    competition-reducing aspect or effect of the defendant’s behavior.” Atl. Richfield Co. v. USA
    Petroleum Co., 
    495 U.S. 328
    , 344 (1990). Far from being “a mere technicality,” antitrust standing
    “is the glue that cements each suit with the purposes of the antitrust laws, and prevents abuses of
    those laws” by claimants seeking to halt the strategic behavior of rivals that increases, rather than
    reduces, competition. HyPoint Tech., Inc. v. Hewlett-Packard Co., 
    949 F.2d 874
    , 877 (6th Cir.
    1991).
    In the second place, antitrust standing is a threshold, pleading-stage inquiry and when a
    complaint by its terms fails to establish this requirement we must dismiss it as a matter of law—lest
    the antitrust laws become a treble-damages sword rather than the shield against
    competition-destroying conduct that Congress meant them to be. “It is one thing to be cautious
    before dismissing an antitrust complaint in advance of discovery, but quite another to forget that
    proceeding to antitrust discovery can be expensive.” Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 
    127 S. Ct. 1955
    ,
    1966–67 (2007). Given the limited “success of judicial supervision in checking discovery abuse”
    and “the threat [that] discovery expense will push cost-conscious defendants to settle even anemic
    cases before reaching those proceedings,” 
    id. at 1967,
    the federal courts have been “reasonably
    aggressive” in weeding out meritless antitrust claims at the pleading stage, Valley Prods. Co. v.
    Landmark, 
    128 F.3d 398
    , 403 (6th Cir. 1997); see Bell 
    Atl., 127 S. Ct. at 1966
    (“[S]omething beyond
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                               Page 5
    the mere possibility of [relief] must be alleged, lest a plaintiff with a largely groundless claim be
    allowed to take up the time of a number of other people, with the right to do so representing an in
    terrorem increment of the settlement value.”) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    For these reasons, it should come as no surprise that, in the seminal antitrust standing case,
    the Supreme Court dismissed the claim under Rule 12(b)(6). See Associated Gen. 
    Contractors, 459 U.S. at 545
    –46. And our court has dismissed numerous lawsuits for lack of antitrust standing under
    Rule 12(b)(6). See Indeck Energy Servs. v. Consumers Energy Co., 
    250 F.3d 972
    , 977 (6th Cir.
    2000); Valley 
    Prods., 128 F.3d at 407
    ; Hodges v. WSM, Inc., 
    26 F.3d 36
    , 39 (6th Cir. 1994); Peck
    v. Gen. Motors Corp., 
    894 F.2d 844
    , 848 (6th Cir. 1990); Apperson v. Fleet Carrier Corp., 
    879 F.2d 1344
    , 1351–52 (6th Cir. 1989); Tennessean Truckstop, Inc. v. NTS, Inc., 
    875 F.2d 86
    , 90 (6th Cir.
    1989); Axis, S.p.A. v. Micafil, Inc., 
    870 F.2d 1105
    , 1111 (6th Cir. 1989); Southaven Land Co. v.
    Malone & Hyde, Inc., 
    715 F.2d 1079
    , 1088 (6th Cir. 1983); see also N.W.S. Mich., Inc. v. Gen. Wine
    & Liquor Co., 58 F. App’x 127, 129–30 (6th Cir. Feb. 6, 2003); Park Ave. Radiology Assocs., P.C.
    v. Methodist Health Sys., No. 98-5668, 
    1999 WL 1045098
    , at *7 (6th Cir. Nov. 10, 1999); Dry v.
    Methodist Med. Ctr. of Oak Ridge, Inc., No. 89-5470, 
    1990 WL 3489
    , at *5 (6th Cir. Jan. 19, 1990).
    B.
    Of the various requirements for establishing antitrust standing, the one that concerns us here
    is antitrust injury, which is a “necessary, but not always sufficient,” condition of antitrust standing.
    Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colo., Inc., 
    479 U.S. 104
    , 110 n.5 (1986). An antitrust claimant must
    show more than merely an “injury causally linked” to a competitive practice; it “must prove antitrust
    injury, which is to say injury of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows
    from that which makes the defendants’ acts unlawful.” Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat,
    Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 489 (1977) (emphasis added). At a minimum, this requirement means that one
    competitor may not use the antitrust laws to sue a rival merely for vigorous or intensified
    competition. “‘[I]t is inimical to [the antitrust] laws to award damages’ for losses stemming from
    continued competition,” 
    Cargill, 479 U.S. at 109
    –10 (quoting 
    Brunswick, 429 U.S. at 488
    ) (second
    alteration in original), because “[t]he antitrust laws . . . were enacted for ‘the protection of
    competition not competitors,’” 
    Brunswick, 429 U.S. at 488
    (quoting Brown Shoe Co. v. United
    States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 320 (1962)); see 
    id. (prohibiting competitor
    claim where the claimant sought
    in damages “the profits they would have realized had competition been reduced”). Accordingly,
    even though a claimant alleges that an injury is “causally related to an antitrust violation,” it “will
    not qualify as ‘antitrust injury’ unless it is attributable to an anticompetitive aspect of the practice
    under scrutiny.” Atl. 
    Richfield, 495 U.S. at 334
    .
    Moreover, a “naked assertion” of antitrust injury, the Supreme Court has made clear, is not
    enough; an antitrust claimant must put forth factual “allegations plausibly suggesting (not merely
    consistent with)” antitrust injury. Bell 
    Atl., 127 S. Ct. at 1966
    ; see 
    id. at 1964–65
    (“[A] plaintiff’s
    obligation to provide the grounds of his entitlement to relief requires more than labels and
    conclusions, and a formulaic recitation of the elements of a cause of action will not do . . . . [A]
    complaint [must have] enough factual matter (taken as true) to suggest [that an antitrust injury
    occurred].”) (internal quotation marks omitted); 
    id. at 1966
    (“[T]he threshold requirement of Rule
    8(a)(2) [is] that the plain statement [in the complaint] possess enough heft to show that the pleader
    is entitled to relief.”) (internal quotation marks omitted); 
    id. (“[A] naked
    assertion . . . gets the
    complaint close to stating a claim, but without some further factual enhancement it stops short of
    the line between possibility and plausibility . . . .”).
    All of this is not to say that one competitor may never sue another under the antitrust laws.
    But courts typically have permitted such claims to proceed only when one of the rivals has engaged
    in some form of predatory pricing or illegal tying—when the rival has engaged in something more
    than vigorous price, product or service competition. See, e.g., Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                              Page 6
    Technical Servs., Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 461–79 (1992) (illegal tying); Utah Pie Co. v. Cont’l Baking
    Co., 
    386 U.S. 685
    , 696–98 (1967) (predatory pricing); Spirit Airlines, Inc. v. Nw. Airlines, Inc., 
    431 F.3d 917
    , 921 (6th Cir. 2005) (predatory pricing); LePage’s Inc. v. 3M, 
    324 F.3d 141
    , 155–57 (3d
    Cir. 2003) (illegal tying); Bell v. Cherokee Aviation Corp., 
    660 F.2d 1123
    , 1127–32 (6th Cir. 1981)
    (illegal tying).
    C.
    In attempting to satisfy this requirement, NicSand targets three of 3M’s competitive tactics:
    (1) the up-front payments that 3M offered to the four retailers; (2) the multi-year terms of the
    agreements between 3M and the retailers; and (3) the exclusive nature of these agreements. Because
    “the injury and damages” suffered by NicSand from these competitive practices, however, do not
    “match the rationale for finding [an antitrust] violation,” HyPoint 
    Tech., 949 F.2d at 879
    —but
    indeed flow from the kind of competition that the antitrust laws were designed to foster—NicSand
    has not established a cognizable antitrust injury.
    The up-front discounts. NicSand first complains about the “cash payment[s]” that 3M
    offered four of the large retailers to obtain their business—$300,000 to Kmart in 1997, $285,000 to
    Advance Auto in 1998, $200,000 to CSK Auto in 1998 and $1 million to AutoZone in 2000. Br.
    at 21; see Am. Compl. ¶¶ 21, 30, 32, 35. Even after accounting for these payments, however,
    NicSand concedes that 3M did not engage in any form of predatory pricing—it concedes in other
    words that 3M did not sell automotive sandpaper below cost with the goal of recouping its losses
    by charging monopolistic prices later. See NicSand’s Mem. in Opp. to 3M’s Mot. to Dismiss, JA
    132 (“NicSand’s Amended Complaint Is Not Premised On Predatory Pricing.”); Reply Br. at 6.
    Given this concession and given the realities of this market, 3M’s payments do not show
    antitrust injury. If the up-front payments, when combined with the price terms that 3M offered each
    of these large retailers, “are not predatory, any losses flowing from them cannot be said to stem from
    an anticompetitive aspect of defendant’s conduct. It is in the interest of competition to
    permit . . . firms to engage in vigorous competition, including price competition.” Atl. 
    Richfield, 495 U.S. at 340
    –41 (internal quotation marks and footnote omitted). The market conditions at the time
    3M made these offers, according to NicSand’s own allegations, buttress the point. In 1997, this
    market consisted primarily of six large retailers, and NicSand was the sole supplier of four of them.
    NicSand controlled 67% of the market and earned 38–49% profit margins on its sales to these four
    retailers. Am. Compl. ¶¶ 22, 31, 33, 36. NicSand gives no explanation why it has a right to preserve
    38–49% margins—under the antitrust laws no less—on a product, sandpaper, that (so far as the
    complaint is concerned) does not take any ingenuity to make.
    Rather than upsetting the competition-enhancing goals of the antitrust laws, the payments
    furthered them. The “payments” are nothing more than “price reductions offered to the buyers for
    the exclusive right to supply a set of stores under multi-year contracts.” Augusta News Co. v.
    Hudson News Co., 
    269 F.3d 41
    , 45 (1st Cir. 2001). “[C]utting prices in order to increase business
    often is the very essence of competition”; and “mistaken inferences in cases such as this one are
    especially costly, because they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect. We
    must be concerned lest a rule or precedent that authorizes a search for a particular type of
    undesirable pricing behavior end up by discouraging legitimate price competition.” Matsushita
    Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    , 594 (1986) (internal quotation marks and
    citation omitted); accord Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 
    540 U.S. 398
    , 414 (2004). “It would be ironic indeed if the standards” for establishing antitrust injury “were
    so low that antitrust suits themselves became a tool for keeping prices high.” Brooke Group Ltd.
    v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 226–27 (1993).
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                                Page 7
    One of the existing barriers to entry in this market, moreover, required would-be suppliers
    to offer up-front payments. Before they would consider switching suppliers, the large retailers
    required new suppliers to offer to (1) purchase the retailer’s existing supply of automotive sandpaper
    and (2) provide a discount on the retailer’s first order. Together these demands could cost a new
    supplier up to 23% of its first year’s revenues. See Am. Compl. ¶¶ 48, 49, 51. All of this goes to
    show that, by offering up-front discounts to the retailers, 3M was merely offering them something
    that, generically speaking, they already insisted on receiving. That 3M offered greater discounts,
    though still non-predatory discounts, to win the retailers’ business does not offend the antitrust laws,
    much less undermine the competitive environment those laws were designed to foster.
    The multi-year terms. Just as 3M’s advances amounted to legitimate competition, so did its
    decision to enter into multi-year agreements. Once again, 3M did nothing more than compete on
    terms that the market already required. A would-be supplier does not violate the antitrust laws by
    offering a multi-year agreement in a market in which the retailers already require one-year “de
    facto” agreements. See 
    id. ¶ 25.
    If the buyers in a market demand one thing, the antitrust laws do
    not prohibit an entrant from offering that same thing on slightly different terms. Cf. Verizon
    
    Commc’ns, 540 U.S. at 411
    (“Antitrust analysis must always be attuned to the particular structure
    and circumstances of the industry at issue.”); Eastman 
    Kodak, 504 U.S. at 466
    –67 (noting the
    importance of considering “actual market realities” when reviewing an antitrust claim).
    From the perspective of a retailer, multi-year agreements permit the retailer to insist that the
    supplier charge lower prices. Committing to a multi-year agreement, indeed, is no different from
    buying in bulk. From the perspective of a supplier, multi-year agreements ease an aspiring entrant’s
    ability to clear existing market barriers. Here, the large retailers demanded that a new supplier buy
    out the former supplier’s products and offer a discount on the first sale, all at a cost of up to 23% of
    the new supplier’s first year sales. It is far easier for a market entrant to clear these barriers when
    it is given several years, rather than just one, to recoup this investment. See 2 Areeda &
    Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Application ¶ 348c (“[A]
    temporary purchase commitment that overcomes an entry barrier increases rather than reduces
    competition.”).
    Had 3M used illegal tying to obtain a multi-year agreement, that might be another matter.
    But NicSand makes no such allegation. Reply Br. at 11–12 (disclaiming any such contention).
    What NicSand complains about instead is a quid pro quo—a multi-year (rather than a single-year)
    agreement for 3M in return for a substantial price discount (rather than a smaller discount) for the
    retailers. Having previously paid NicSand prices generating 38–49% profit margins, the large
    retailers cannot be blamed for accepting better prices with 3M for several years, not just one.
    Contrary to NicSand’s suggestion, the multi-year nature of the agreements makes the
    accompanying advances less troublesome, not more so. It is true, as NicSand repeatedly asserts, that
    the advances made by 3M to the retailers outpaced NicSand’s yearly profits from sales to each of
    those retailers. See Reply Br. at 3; Supp. Br. at 9. But given a reasonable estimate of the length of
    these “several year[]” agreements, say three to five years, NicSand’s complaint itself demonstrates
    that it could have competed for the exact same multi-year agreements with its customers. Am.
    Compl. ¶ 23. Had NicSand approached its customers with similar deals, it could have expected
    profit margins of 17–39% on its sales to Kmart, Advance Auto, CSK Auto and AutoZone. 
    Id. ¶¶ 21,
    30, 32, 35. While these margins would have been lower than the 38–49% margins NicSand realized
    before 3M’s entrance into the market, NicSand offers no explanation why this modest reduction in
    profit margins on a product of this sort is a concern of the antitrust laws.
    The exclusivity of the agreements. Unable to show that it suffered an antitrust injury from
    3M’s vigorous price competition and unable to show that it suffered an antitrust injury from 3M’s
    offer to extend the agreements to cover “at least a few years,” 
    id. ¶ 37,
    NicSand argues that the
    No. 05-3431            NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                                 Page 8
    exclusivity of the agreements establishes the requisite injury. While exclusive agreements in some
    instances may create impermissible barriers for new entrants to a market and may permit a supplier
    to charge monopoly prices, see Tampa Elec. Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 
    365 U.S. 320
    , 327 (1961),
    NicSand has not claimed—and cannot tenably claim—that it suffered these anticompetitive effects.
    As with NicSand’s other complaints, so here: we cannot ignore the demands of the
    marketplace in which these agreements arose. “Antitrust analysis must always be attuned to the
    particular structure and circumstances of the industry at issue.” Verizon 
    Commc’ns, 540 U.S. at 411
    ;
    see Bell 
    Atl., 127 S. Ct. at 1972
    (noting that industry history may provide “a natural explanation”
    for conduct). According to NicSand’s own complaint, all but one of the large retailers made
    exclusivity a condition for doing business with a new supplier. NicSand of course complied with
    this requirement (and several others) in obtaining the business it held in 1997, and 3M complied
    with this requirement (and several others) in winning some of that business away. If retailers have
    made supplier exclusivity a barrier to entry, one cannot bring an antitrust claim against a supplier
    for acquiescing to that requirement. Put another way, NicSand has not sued 3M because it wants
    to share shelf space with its competitor; it sued 3M because it wants that shelf space all to
    itself—just as it had it in 1997. This is just the kind of all-for-one-and-all-for-one competitor claim
    that the antitrust laws do not protect.
    Nor can NicSand plausibly argue that the exclusivity requirement created entry barriers for
    it in this market. Before 1997, NicSand controlled 67% of the market and used the existing barriers
    to entry—annual product reviews and exclusive shelf space—to preserve its lock on the market.
    From 1997 to 2000, 3M competed for and won the business of four retailers that NicSand formerly
    supplied. Through it all, however, NicSand was not a potential market entrant; it was the market
    leader. Yet NicSand offers no explanation why it could not compete for these multi-year agreements
    nor why (in view of its high margins) it could not match 3M’s discounts. As the market leader,
    NicSand was on the inside looking out, and for whatever reason the company chose not to compete.
    See 2 Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 348d3 (“Of course, a foreclosure alleged to be illegal because
    it deters entry does not injure a plaintiff already in the market. Impeding the entry of others grants
    a benefit to those already in the market.”) (footnote omitted).
    To the extent exclusivity created a market barrier, it was 3M that faced the problem, and it
    was 3M that overcame it. In 1997, according to the complaint, 3M won the business of Kmart with
    its “several years” offer; as the incumbent, NicSand had every opportunity to compete and yet it
    failed to do so. In 1998, 3M overcame a similar hurdle in obtaining the business of Advance Auto
    and CSK Auto; again, NicSand faced no such barrier and yet still failed to compete. In 2000, when
    NicSand was the exclusive supplier of only one big-box retailer, it still controlled a substantial
    portion of the market due to the volume of its business with AutoZone. Compare Am. Compl. ¶ 36
    ($2,200,000 in sales to AutoZone), with 
    id. ¶ 22
    ($475,000 in sales to Kmart), 
    id. ¶ 31
    ($550,000 in
    sales to Advance Auto), and 
    id. ¶ 33
    ($369,000 in sales to CSK Auto). Yet 3M successfully
    competed for AutoZone’s business. Though NicSand declared bankruptcy in 2001, it says nothing
    in the complaint about efforts before then to recoup the business from Kmart (which entered the 3M
    agreement in 1997) or from Advance Auto or CSK Auto (which entered the agreements in 1998).
    Nor does 3M’s size make a difference to the disposition of these allegations. See 
    Brunswick, 429 U.S. at 487
    –88 (“Yet respondents’ injury . . . bears no relationship to the size of . . . its competitor[].
    Respondents would have suffered the identical loss but no compensable injury had the acquired
    centers instead . . . been purchased by shallow pocket parents . . . . Thus, respondents’ injury was
    not of the type that the statute was intended to forestall.”) (internal quotation marks omitted). In the
    end, NicSand simply has not alleged facts establishing that the agreements in and of themselves
    created market-entry barriers that caused it a cognizable antitrust injury. See Bell 
    Atl., 127 S. Ct. at 1974
    (holding that plaintiffs must allege “enough facts” to “nudge[] their claims across the line
    from conceivable to plausible”).
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                               Page 9
    NicSand’s injury also does not stem from 3M’s alleged monopolization of the market. For
    most of the time NicSand was losing business, it retained control of a significant share of the market.
    While NicSand complains about the up-front discounts 3M offered, it does not allege that 3M was
    selling below cost, and the numbers NicSand itself offers demonstrate that 3M’s advances were
    comfortably within NicSand’s multi-year profit margins. While NicSand’s loss of business may
    have propelled 3M into a dominant market position, its injury does not correspond to any allegedly
    anticompetitive effect on the market but rather a truly competitive one.
    Any doubt about the appropriate resolution of this case can be laid to rest by Indeck Energy
    Services v. Consumers Energy Co., 
    250 F.3d 972
    (6th Cir. 2000). There an energy supplier (Indeck)
    alleged that a competitor (Consumers Energy) violated the antitrust laws by signing an exclusive
    supply contract with General Motors for a period of five to ten years. 
    Id. at 975.
    The contract came
    on the heels of similar contracts with “17 other large industrial/commercial customers,” through all
    of which Consumers Energy “succeeded in excluding competition from over 80 percent of the
    Relevant At Risk Market.” 
    Id. (internal quotation
    marks omitted). Central to the resolution of that
    case, as to this one, was that “the only harm allegedly suffered by Indeck was in the company’s
    capacity as a competitor in the marketplace, not as a defender of marketplace competition.” 
    Id. at 977.
            Indeck was the harder case. Consumers Energy controlled 80% of the market when its
    contracts preserved its hold on the market, while NicSand controlled 67% of the market when it
    began losing its hold on the market. Consumers Energy entered into longer exclusive contracts
    (5–10 years) than 3M did (“several years,” “few years” or “multi-year”). And Consumers Energy
    did not unseat the dominant market leader (as 3M did) but instead hindered a potential market
    entrant. Indeck was hardly a dominant supplier of energy, as it provided cogeneration services
    (recycling factory waste to create energy), which diminish a customer’s need for traditional energy
    rather than supply such energy. Indeck, in short, was more akin (far more akin) to a market entrant
    than NicSand.
    In its en banc papers, NicSand does not claim that Indeck (or for that matter any of our
    antitrust-injury precedents) should be overruled but insists that it can be distinguished—first on the
    ground that today’s case involves a series of contracts with several retailers as opposed to several
    contracts with one retailer. As a result, it submits, while Indeck’s harm resulted only from
    competition, NicSand suffered not simply as a single competitor in the market, but as a proxy for
    all competitors and thus for all competition. But this seems to invert the relative vices and virtues
    of the two fact patterns. While NicSand originally held all of the contracts with the retailers in
    question and lost them to competition, Indeck lost out on a single contract and alleged that it found
    itself in a market where a single dominant firm controlled 80% of the market with exclusive
    contracts of 5–10 years with all of the major industrial and commercial customers. If the harm to
    the market is the entry barriers established by “exclusive contracts,” it is Indeck, not NicSand, that
    makes the better proxy for injury to competition in the market rather than harm to a competitor.
    NicSand had the opportunity to compete for each of the contracts, while Indeck never had that
    opportunity because of the existing exclusive contracts. Nonetheless, we concluded in Indeck that
    there was no harm to competition because Indeck “failed to allege how [the exclusive contracts]
    have injured competition, especially in light of the discounted rates offered to the customers, in light
    of the fact that the exclusive contracts were of limited duration, and in light of the fact that the
    customers were free to seek other [providers] at the conclusion of the 
    contracts.” 250 F.3d at 977
    –78. We rested our decision on these grounds, and these grounds control us here—with
    NicSand, if anything, having the less compelling complaint. When one exclusive dealer is replaced
    by another exclusive dealer, the victim of the competition does not state an antitrust injury. See 11
    Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1823b (“Clearly not a victim of antitrust injury is the exclusive
    dealing partner whose business relationship was terminated in favor of a different exclusive dealing
    partner.”).
    No. 05-3431            NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                               Page 10
    NicSand next maintains that Indeck can be distinguished on the ground that 3M’s exclusive
    dealing arrangements have eliminated a superior product, noting that NicSand allegedly provides
    a better variety of products and better service than 3M. Indeck, it is true, noted that antitrust actions
    by marketplace competitors “must at least allege that exclusion of the competitor from the
    marketplace results in the elimination of a superior product or a lower-cost alternative” because
    these developments might show “that competition itself was harmed by an[] act of the 
    defendant[].” 250 F.3d at 977
    . But the court still rejected Indeck’s claim even though the company had alleged
    that its competitor’s conduct caused the market to become less diversified because Indeck provided
    “alternative sources of electrical power,” namely thermal power, while its competitor supplied only
    traditional electrical power. 
    Id. at 975
    (internal quotation marks omitted). As Indeck suggests, then,
    such an allegation may be necessary to establish antitrust standing for a competitor, but it is not
    sufficient. Under NicSand’s reading, every competitor could proceed to discovery (and avoid
    showing a true antitrust injury) by asserting an unelaborated claim that it provides better service than
    its competitors. Indeck did not permit such a pleading and neither will we.
    Even aside from Indeck, NicSand suggests in its en banc papers, and the dissent echos the
    point, that it is an efficient defender of the marketplace because the retailers face a “collective action
    problem.” Dissent at 22. In its view, this collective action problem—that no retailer will accept the
    higher prices of one supplier in order to keep competition in the supply market when all the other
    retailers are accepting lower prices from a potentially emergent monopolist supplier—justifies
    competitor standing in exclusive dealing cases. NicSand, however, did not raise this argument in
    the district court, and accordingly it is waived.
    The alleged problem, at any rate, is a mirage. If all that one can say about a supplier is that
    it has offered lower prices (though not predatory prices) to a series of retailers and that the existing
    monopolist refuses to match those prices, a retailer would have far more questions to answer for
    refusing, than for accepting, the better deal. The entities with power in this market by the terms of
    NicSand’s complaint were not the suppliers but the national retailers. It was these retailers after all
    who initially demanded exclusivity in the market for automotive sandpaper, only reviewing their
    choice of a single supplier once a year. That they have now signed longer exclusive agreements for
    much better prices not only does not establish a market failure but also shows the retailers’
    bargaining authority at work, to say nothing of adherence to their duties to consumers and
    shareholders. Why not enter a multi-year contract for a steep discount on the prices NicSand was
    charging? That helps the retailers and bodes well for consumers to boot. See 
    Indeck, 250 F.3d at 977
    (“No allegation in the complaint indicates in any manner whatsoever how [the customer] itself
    was harmed or how other customers . . . suffered by agreeing to [an exclusive] agreement with a
    lower bidder for such [product].”); see also Smith Wholesale Co. v. R.J. Reynolds Tobacco Co., 
    477 F.3d 854
    , 872 (6th Cir. 2007) (“[I]f a higher discount is realistically and practically available, why
    would a reasonable purchaser not take advantage of the best possible price?”); cf. Adam Smith, An
    Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations 201 (1838) (“[I]t always is, and must
    be, the interest of the great body of the people, to buy whatever they want of those who sell it
    cheapest.”).
    What we have said here does not mean that a potential competitor may never bring an
    antitrust claim for exclusive dealing. Had the large retailers and 3M conspired to eliminate NicSand
    from the market, that would be another matter. And should 3M use these contracts and its current
    market dominance to establish unreasonable barriers to entry in the future, a potential competitor
    might have a legitimate antitrust claim. Nor is this to say that the future competitiveness of the
    market lacks protection if 3M chooses to impose monopolist prices down the road. Aggrieved
    retailers would have standing to sue for treble damages if that occurred. See 
    Indeck, 250 F.3d at 977
    (“[A]s the direct victim of the alleged antitrust violation in this regard, [the customer] could
    prosecute its own cause of action should it deem the actions of [the supplier] inappropriate.”). “The
    existence of an identifiable class of persons whose self-interest would normally motivate them to
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                               Page 11
    vindicate the public interest in antitrust enforcement diminishes the justification for allowing a more
    remote party such as the [plaintiff] to perform the office of a private attorney general. Denying the
    [plaintiff] a remedy on the basis of its allegations in this case is not likely to leave a significant
    antitrust violation undetected or unremedied.” Associated Gen. 
    Contractors, 459 U.S. at 542
    (footnote omitted).
    But to allow this litigation to continue on these allegations is to allow one monopolist to sue
    a competitor for seizing its market position by charging less for its goods. NicSand took advantage
    of the very same exclusivity it now attacks to charge prices that made it vulnerable to 3M’s offers
    in the first place. If 3M does the same by charging excessive prices itself, it will expose itself either
    to competition or to a legitimate antitrust complaint from retailers or excluded competitors. But
    until then, as the district court rightly concluded, NicSand has suffered no antitrust injury, and until
    then NicSand has no antitrust standing to bring this case.
    The dissent worries that our decision will drive out all but the “omniscient [antitrust]
    plaintiffs that happen to know every relevant factual detail before the inception of litigation.”
    Dissent at 15. That is not true, and there is no reason this decision should have any such effect. The
    key failing in NicSand’s complaint is not that it has too few details but that it has too many. While
    we must accept all of a claimant’s allegations as true at this stage of a case, that does not mean we
    must ignore those allegations when they defeat the claim and when they show the claimant is doing
    nothing more than invoking the antitrust laws to protect a competitor, not competition. See
    
    Brunswick, 429 U.S. at 488
    . In considerable detail, NicSand’s amended complaint explained the
    market for do-it-yourself automotive sandpaper, see Am. Compl. ¶¶ 25, 46, 47, 48, 51, explained
    that the relevant retailers demanded exclusivity by refusing to stock more than one brand of the
    sandpaper at a time, see 
    id. ¶ 47,
    explained that the relevant retailers had “de facto” one-year
    exclusive agreements with their suppliers, see 
    id. ¶ 25,
    explained how all of the relevant retailers
    demanded up-front payments before they would switch suppliers, see 
    id. ¶¶ 21,
    30, 32, 35,
    highlighted NicSand’s domination of that market under these precise conditions, see 
    id. ¶ 15,
    detailed the 38–49% profit margins NicSand earned before 3M entered the picture (presumably to
    enhance NicSand’s request for treble damages), see 
    id. ¶¶ 22,
    31, 33, 36, and spelled out the amounts
    of the up-front discounts that 3M offered four of the retailers, see 
    id. ¶¶ 21,
    30, 32, 35.
    Confirming what the details in its amended complaint showed, NicSand disclaimed in its
    response to the Rule 12(b)(6) motion that 3M had engaged in predatory pricing or illegal tying.
    When “the complaint itself gives reasons” to doubt plaintiff’s theory, Bell 
    Atl., 127 S. Ct. at 1972
    ,
    and when later pleadings confirm those doubts, it is not our task to resuscitate the claim but to put
    it to rest. Nothing prevents a plaintiff from pleading itself out of court, which is all that happened
    here.
    The dissent suggests that we can resuscitate this claim by returning to NicSand what it has
    given away—a predatory-pricing claim. When a party concedes that it is not bringing a claim,
    however, no purpose of Rule 12(b)(6) is served by overlooking the concession, and there is nothing
    “misleading,” Dissent at 16, about reading and accepting the concession. Plainly and simply, the
    company acknowledged that “NicSand’s Amended Complaint Is Not Premised On Predatory
    Pricing.” JA 132; Reply Br. at 6. The plaintiff remains the master of its complaint, and when it says
    that it is not bringing a predatory-pricing claim, we should take it at its word.
    Nor, to be fair to NicSand’s counsel, was this an unusual concession to make. “[P]redatory
    pricing schemes are rarely tried, and even more rarely successful.” Matsushita Elec. 
    Indus., 475 U.S. at 589
    . Success requires not just below-cost pricing but a product market that will allow the
    would-be monopolist to raise prices later without the threat of new market entrants. 
    Id. at 591
    n.15.
    NicSand, in short, had ample reasons for conceding that 3M did not engage in a predatory-pricing
    scheme, and we should accept the concession.
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                              Page 12
    The claim also cannot be revived based on the allegation that retail prices have risen a total
    of 70% since NicSand left the market. Dissent at 21. An allegation about retail prices in the
    context of a case against a supplier does not by itself show that the supplier engaged in
    anticompetitive conduct and does not show that NicSand’s injury “flows from that which makes
    [3M’s] acts unlawful.” 
    Brunswick, 429 U.S. at 489
    . Res ipsa loquitur is not a theory of antitrust
    injury, and it surely is not one after the Supreme Court’s decision in Bell Atlantic, which set out to
    eliminate this kind of loose antitrust pleading. Just as in Bell Atlantic, where the Court held that,
    “[w]ithout more, parallel conduct does not suggest 
    conspiracy,” 127 S. Ct. at 1966
    , so here: a price
    increase by retailers, without more, does not suggest anticompetitive behavior by suppliers.
    NicSand’s speculations show at most the “possibility” of an entitlement to relief, 
    id., which is
    just
    what Bell Atlantic said would not suffice at the pleading stage, 
    id. (requiring “allegations
    plausibly
    suggesting (not merely consistent with)” an entitlement to relief). While it is assuredly true that Bell
    Atlantic “in fact makes simpler the task before us in this case” than it was before the Supreme
    Court’s decision, Dissent at 15, it is hard to see how that decision makes it “simpler” to rule in the
    plaintiff’s favor, as the dissent contends, 
    id. The dissent
    adds that “[i]t is not the appropriate response under the law to answer
    anticompetitive conduct with more anticompetitive conduct,” suggesting that the only way NicSand
    could have responded to 3M’s courtship of NicSand’s customers over a four-year period would be
    to compete illegally. 
    Id. at 18.
    But why compete illegally if, as NicSand’s amended complaint says,
    it had 38–49% margins before 3M entered the competitive picture? Such profits surely left NicSand
    negotiating options over a four-year period between competing illegally and invoking the antitrust
    laws to preserve these margins.
    The dissent expresses skepticism about our decision in Indeck, relying on a commentator
    who has questioned the decision. See 
    id. at 18
    n.8. But no party to this case, as we have noted, has
    asked us to reconsider Indeck. And, what is more, the central criticism leveled by the commentator
    concerns the statement in Indeck upon which the dissent principally relies, 
    id. at 12—Indeck’s
    requirement that the antitrust plaintiff must show the “elimination of a superior product or a lower-
    cost alternative,” 
    Indeck, 250 F.3d at 977
    ; see Ronald W. Davis, Standing on Shaky Ground: The
    Strangely Elusive Doctrine of Antitrust Injury, 70 Antitrust L.J. 697, 747–48 (2003). As we have
    explained, Maj. Op. at 10, Indeck’s injury-to-the-market language need not detain us here because
    it is at most a necessary, but not a sufficient, condition for proving antitrust standing. See 
    Indeck, 250 F.3d at 977
    (A competitor plaintiff “must at least allege” injury to the market.) (emphasis
    added). And NicSand cannot meet another necessary requirement—that it suffered an antitrust
    injury, as opposed to the ill effects of price competition, which understandably “hurts,” Dissent at
    16, but which does not by itself state a cognizable antitrust claim. See Maj. Op. at 10. Otherwise,
    every time an allegedly “superior product or a lower-cost alternative” was eliminated from the
    market by competition, the producer of that product would have antitrust standing. That is not what
    Indeck said or did.
    III.
    For these reasons, we affirm.
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                               Page 13
    _________________
    DISSENT
    _________________
    BOYCE F. MARTIN, JR., Circuit Judge, dissenting, joined by Judges Daughtrey, Cole, and
    Clay. In a recent dissent, Justice Stevens wrote nostalgically about times gone by, when most “high-
    speed driving took place on two-lane roads rather than on superhighways” and “when split-second
    judgments about the risk of passing a slow-poke in the face of oncoming traffic were routine.” Scott
    v. Harris, 
    127 S. Ct. 1769
    , 1782 n.1 (2007). There is a time I reflect upon nostalgically as well —
    a time when monopoly was an evil targeted by Congress and guarded against by the antitrust laws
    of the United States. See United States v. Von’s Grocery Co., 
    384 U.S. 270
    , 274 (1966). Since their
    enactment, it has been the purpose of the federal antitrust laws to prevent the emergence of
    entrenched monopoly power and “to perpetuate and preserve, for its own sake and in spite of
    possible cost,” the existence of competition in industry. 
    Id. at 275
    n.7 (quoting United States v.
    Aluminum Co. of America, 
    148 F.2d 415
    , 429 (2d Cir. 1945) (Hand, J.)). Today, however, the
    majority treats monopoly more as a board game than as an economic harm to the public. Because
    I cannot read the antitrust laws so narrowly, I respectfully dissent.
    I.
    As noted by the majority, our main concern in this case is whether NicSand has sufficiently
    alleged not only standing under Article III of the Constitution, but also standing under the antitrust
    laws. To be sure, this is a more onerous task than that faced by most civil plaintiffs. Yet this task,
    though challenging, should not be insurmountable. NicSand must allege more than mere economic
    injury, for the antitrust laws were enacted for “the protection of competition, not competitors.”
    Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 488 (1977) (quoting Brown Shoe Co.
    v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 320 (1962)). As the majority correctly notes, NicSand must show
    that the injury it suffered is “of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and [] flows from
    that which makes defendants’ acts unlawful.” 
    Id. at 489.
    That is, the injury “should reflect the
    anticompetitive effect either of the violation or of anticompetitive acts made possible by the
    violation.” 
    Id. Despite what
    the majority holds today, NicSand has alleged that type of injury in
    this case.
    “The Supreme Court has articulated certain factors to be analyzed in determining whether
    a plaintiff has established antitrust standing.” Indeck Energy Servs. v. Consumers Energy Co., 
    250 F.3d 972
    ,976 (6th Cir. 2000) (citing Associated Gen. Contractors of Cal., Inc. v. California State
    Council of Carpenters, 
    459 U.S. 519
    , 537-45 (1983)). Those factors include:
    (1) the causal connection between the antitrust violation and harm to the plaintiff and
    whether that harm was intended to be caused; (2) the nature of the plaintiff’s alleged
    injury including the status of the plaintiff as consumer or competitor in the relevant
    market; (3) the directness or indirectness of the injury, and the related inquiry of
    whether the damages are speculative; (4) the potential for duplicative recovery or
    complex apportionment of damages; and (5) the existence of more direct victims of
    the alleged antitrust violation.
    
    Id. (citations omitted).
    Moreover, “[a]ll five factors must be balanced, . . . with no one factor being
    determinative.” 
    Id. (citing Peck
    v. General Motors Corp., 
    894 F.2d 844
    , 846 (6th Cir. 1990)).
    This case comes before us on appeal from the district court’s grant of 3M’s motion to
    dismiss. The Supreme Court recently clarified the standard an antitrust plaintiff must satisfy at this
    stage, holding that an antitrust plaintiff need only provide “a short and plain statement of the claim
    showing that [he] is entitled to relief,” so that the defendant has “fair notice of what the . . . claim
    No. 05-3431               NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                                          Page 14
    is and the grounds upon which it rests.” Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 
    127 S. Ct. 1955
    , 1964 (2007)
    (citations omitted).1 Although many commentators have intimated that Bell Atlantic represents a
    significant departure from prior law, the decision in fact makes simpler the task before us in this
    case.
    In Bell Atlantic, the Court explained that “a plaintiff’s obligation to provide the grounds of
    his ‘entitlement to relief’ requires more than labels and conclusions, and a formulaic recitation of
    the elements of a cause of action will not do.” 
    Id. at 1964-65
    (internal quotation marks and citations
    omitted). Thus, the key distinction is between a bare-bones complaint asserting only the elements
    of a claim and a complaint asserting not only legal elements, but also facts to support those elements.
    Courts are well-suited to distinguish between the two. Indeed, we do so all the time when reviewing
    questions of fact, mixed questions of law and fact, and questions of law. It is not a controversial
    assertion that, while a plaintiff need not assert detailed facts, a plaintiff must assert some facts.
    “Without some factual allegation in the complaint, it is hard to see how a claimant could satisfy the
    requirement of providing not only ‘fair notice’ of the nature of the claim, but also ‘grounds’ on
    which the claim rests.” 
    Id. at 1965
    n.3 (citing 5 Wright & Miller § 1202, at 94, 95 (Rule 8(a)
    “contemplates the statement of circumstances, occurrences, and events in support of the claim
    presented” and does not authorize a pleader’s “bare averment that he wants relief and is entitled to
    it”)). Thus, at the 12(b)(6) stage, “[f]actual allegations must be enough to raise a right to relief
    above the speculative level, . . . on the assumption that all the allegations in the complaint are true
    (even if doubtful in fact).” 
    Id. at 1965
    (citations omitted).
    NicSand’s complaint establishes a right to relief above the speculative level. Notably,
    NicSand has provided detailed factual allegations regarding the payments made by 3M to retailers,
    the years in which exclusive contracts were entered, and the approximate duration of the contracts.
    In particular, with regard to the duration of the exclusive contracts, NicSand has alleged a reasonable
    basis for inferring that they will last a few years — to wit, that the retailers told NicSand that they
    could not even discuss the possibility of doing business with NicSand for at least a few years. These
    factual allegations must be taken as true. Potentially relevant information may be missing from the
    complaint, but it is exactly this additional information that, with the benefit of discovery, may entitle
    NicSand to relief. Yet following today’s decision, it is difficult to see how any antitrust
    plaintiff—short of those few omniscient plaintiffs that happen to know every relevant factual detail
    before the inception of litigation and without the benefit of discovery—will be able to overcome a
    motion to dismiss. See Freightliner of Knoxville, Inc. v. DaimlerChrysler Vans, LLC, 
    484 F.3d 865
    ,
    874 (6th Cir. 2007) (“[Plaintiff]’s claims under the [Robinson-Patman Act] may well be highly
    speculative, and discovery may well reveal that they are futile, but we cannot—nor can the district
    court—make such a determination based on the pleadings alone.”).
    II.
    For a number of years, NicSand had a significant share of the market for do-it-yourself retail
    automotive coated abrasives.    NicSand sold its products through a handful of retailers and 3M was
    its only competitor.2 Agreements between suppliers and retailers for these products lasted one year
    in the de facto sense because retailers did not want to change their inventories mid-year. According
    to NicSand’s complaint, 3M pushed retailers into a series of multi-year exclusive dealing
    1
    The Court made clear that Rule 8(a)’s liberal notice pleading standard applied to antitrust actions, Bell 
    Atl., 127 S. Ct. at 1964
    , and not Rule 9’s “‘heightened’ pleading standard,” 
    id. at 1973
    n.14.
    2
    The majority characterizes 3M as a “market entrant.” Maj. Op. at 14. Given that 3M, as NicSand’s only
    competitor, had approximately 33% of the market in 1995, 3M is hardly a “market entrant.” See Complaint ¶ 8 (“In
    1995, NicSand had approximately 67% of the DIY [do-it-yourself] retail automotive coated abrasives market.”).
    No. 05-3431              NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                                       Page 15
    arrangements, excluding NicSand from the market. The terms of these exclusive agreements, and
    their harm to consumers by the creation of a monopoly, form the crux of this case.
    The new agreements drastically changed the market and were more than simply a
    regurgitation of the old agreements with “slightly different terms.” Maj. Op. at 14. For one thing,
    3M offered unprecedented substantial, up-front cash payments to retailers. For another, 3M
    contractually guaranteed multi-year exclusivity with retailers, cutting NicSand out of the market for
    an extended period of time. 3M pushed retailers, including NicSand’s clients, into the exclusive
    agreements.
    First, let us focus on 3M’s up-front cash payments. Using figures provided in the complaint,
    we are presented with the following picture for each of the four relevant big retailers:
    1.      Kmart: In 1996, NicSand’s sales to Kmart were $475,000 per year and its profits were
    $180,000 per year. In 1997, 3M executed a contract with Kmart which provided for a
    payment “in excess of $300,000.” This payment is equal to approximately 63% of
    NicSand’s3sales to Kmart and 167% of NicSand’s annual profits on sales to Kmart from the
    prior year.
    2.      Advance Auto: In 1997, NicSand’s sales to Advance Auto were $550,000 and its profits
    were $272,000. In 1998, 3M executed a contract with Advance Auto which provided for a
    payment of “over $285,000.” This payment is equal to approximately 52% of NicSand’s
    sales to Advance Auto and 105% of NicSand’s annual profits on sales to Advance Auto from
    the prior year.
    3.      CSK: In 1997, NicSand’s sales to CSK were $369,000 and its profits were $164,000. In
    1998, 3M executed a contract with CSK which provided for a payment of “over $200,000.”
    This payment is equal to approximately 54% of NicSand’s sales to Kmart and 122% of
    NicSand’s annual profits on sales to CSK from the prior year.
    4.      AutoZone: In 1999, NicSand’s sales to AutoZone were $2,200,000 and its profits were
    $865,000. In 2000 and 2001, 3M executed a contract with AutoZone which provided for a
    payments totaling “over $1,000,000.” The annual value of these payments ($500,000) is
    equal to approximately 23% of NicSand’s sales to AutoZone and 58% of NicSand’s annual
    profits on sales to AutoZone from the prior year.
    Complaint ¶¶ 21, 30, 32, 35.
    As these numbers demonstrate, 3M’s cash payments exceeded NicSand’s profits from the
    prior year for three of the retailers. In other words, from 1997 through 2000, 3M signed agreements
    with three retailers, the terms of which NicSand could not possibly match on an individual basis
    without selling below cost — an action that may have given 3M a cause of action under the Sherman
    Act. See Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 
    127 S. Ct. 1069
    , 1074 (2007).
    If sales coupled with substantial up-front cash payments to those retailers would have
    resulted in a loss for NicSand, then it is a reasonable inference that they may have been below cost
    for 3M as well. However, it is obvious that without discovery NicSand would have had no way of
    3
    According to NicSand’s complaint, in addition to providing this up-front payment, 3M also agreed to pay the
    cost of buying out Kmart’s stock of NicSand do-it-yourself retail automotive coated abrasives, thus increasing the
    amount that 3M paid to secure Kmart’s exclusive business. Complaint ¶ 27. Although buying out a competitor’s stock
    was the traditional practice during annual line reviews, it is unclear from the complaint whether 3M also bought out
    NicSand’s remaining stock from the other three big-box retailers when it obtained its multi-year exclusive dealing
    agreements with them.
    No. 05-3431               NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                                          Page 16
    knowing with certainty 3M’s production or other overhead costs. It is telling that, in its
    memorandum in support of its motion to dismiss, 3M noted that NicSand had made “no allegation
    regarding how [NicSand] purports to measure 3M’s costs.” JA 83. This is the very purpose of
    discovery in a civil case. It simply cannot be that a business must know everything about its
    competitors before bringing suit in an antitrust case. After all, a business that knows everything
    about its competitors is likely to dominate them, rather than fall prey to them, as NicSand did here.
    The majority is quick to point out that “NicSand concedes that 3M did not engage in any
    form of predatory pricing.” Maj. Op. at 12 (citing JA 132 and Reply Br. 6). This assertion is
    misleading. In saying that its complaint is not based on “predatory pricing,” NicSand is simply
    stating that 3M’s conduct is not premised on the type of conduct typically referred to as “predatory
    pricing,” that is, the pricing of an individual item below the cost of its production. Cf. Black’s Law
    Dictionary 1215 8th ed. 2004 (defining “predatory pricing” as “[u]nlawful below-cost pricing
    intended to eliminate specific competitors and reduce overall competition.”). In other words,
    NicSand’s allegations do not pertain to the price terms offered by 3M but rather to the
    unprecedented and unusually large up-front cash payments used by 3M to secure exclusive-dealing
    agreements. JA 132-134 & n.10. While NicSand did not use the magic words “predatory pricing”
    in its complaint, the allegations that 3M charged competitive prices and offered substantial, up-front
    payments, negating any possible profits, amounts to the same thing. Thus, the conduct alleged by
    NicSand, a form of predatory pricing, is still predatory conduct that hurts, and in this case
    eliminated, competition. See 
    id. at 133
    n.10. As NicSand aptly notes in its response to 3M’s motion
    to dismiss, “[t]he point is not that 3M’s supracompetitive payments crossed the predatory pricing
    line, but that they were part and parcel of a different, but equally insidious, form of predatory,
    anticompetitive, conduct.” 
    Id. In fact,
    the majority, when defending the multi-year terms of 3M’s agreements, seems to
    acknowledge that 3M effectively sold below cost. The majority explains that it would be easier for
    a supplier such as 3M to gain a foothold in the market “when it is given several years, rather than
    just one, to recoup this investment.” Maj. Op. at 14. The “investment” that 3M would “recoup” is
    the loss it took by offering substantial, up-front payments. Those payments, upon further discovery,
    might be revealed to have effectively amounted to below-cost pricing. Cf. Matsushita Elec. Indus.
    Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    , 589 (1986) (“The success of any predatory scheme
    depends on maintaining monopoly power for long enough both to recoup the predator’s losses and
    to harvest some additional gain.”).
    Perhaps recognizing that NicSand would have lost money had it offered matching lump-sum
    payments to three out of the four retailers, 3M asks this court to compare NicSand’s aggregate
    profits from four individual retailers in four individual years (Kmart in 1996, Advance Auto in 1997,
    CSK in 1997, and AutoZone in 1999) to the aggregate of 3M’s payments over a later four-year
    period (1997-2000). By aggregating in this manner, 3M attempts to gloss over the fact that NicSand
    would have had to have sold below cost to three out of the four retailers. This approach asks us to
    read NicSand’s complaint in the light most favorable to 3M. Nevertheless, even under that improper
    approach, there is a small margin for error. According to 3M, the aggregate    data for NicSand would
    yield a profit margin of merely five percent — a meager profit indeed.4
    The poor quality of the data at issue makes this potential five percent profit margin hinge on
    several levels of assumptions, which could be—or could not be—confirmed through discovery. To
    4
    3M arrives at this profit margin by first adding NicSand’s annual sales and profits from each of the four
    retailers in the four individual years, which amounts to $3,594,000 in sales and $1,481,000 in profits. 3M then takes the
    total annual value of its four lump-sum payments made in the individual years to be $1,285,000 (3M divides its payment
    to AutoZone in half). 3M then subtracts $1,285,000 from $1,481,000 to arrive at a total profit of $196,000, which, when
    divided by sales of $3,594,000, yields a profit margin of approximately 5%. Appellee Supp. Br. at 8-9 n.4.
    No. 05-3431               NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                                         Page 17
    be sure, on this record, we have little choice but to compare profit data for NicSand’s last year with
    a particular retailer to the amount of 3M’s up-front payment to that retailer in the subsequent year.
    That is the best we can do because NicSand was eliminated from the market, and therefore was not
    around long enough to develop its own profit data in the later years. But when we aggregate this
    data, we are forced to use 3M’s assumptions about how well NicSand might have performed in the
    market with respect to individual retailers in years after 3M secured contracts with them, and to
    compare those assumptions with the actual payments made by 3M. Moreover, the data fails to
    account either for inflation or for any line of credit NicSand may have had, such that the estimated
    profit margin may contain significant inaccuracy. And, the data also fails to account for the fact that
    these agreements were made in secret, thereby depriving NicSand of an opportunity to compete by
    offering comparable deals. In order to avoid elimination from the market, NicSand not only would
    have had to match 3M’s payments, but also presumably would have had to pay the cost of inducing
    a retailer to breach its exclusive contract with 3M. In contrast, 3M did not have to bear that cost
    because the exclusivity of the prior agreements was merely de facto — retailers could switch at any
    time without penalty.
    Given the multiple levels of uncertainty incorporated into 3M’s analysis, it is impossible to
    tell how accurate or solid that predicted profit margin is, or whether, indeed, NicSand would have
    lost money in the aggregate. That realization is more troubling in light of the obviously sequential
    conduct that took place in this case. 3M acquired three retailers over a series of years, each time
    employing allegedly anticompetitive agreements. Only in the final year, when NicSand was already
    on its last legs, was 3M able to recoup its losses on its deals with the other three retailers by securing
    a more favorable agreement with AutoZone. Given our duty to read the facts in the light most
    favorable to NicSand   in this case, it is simply impossible to conclude that these agreements were not
    anticompetitive.5
    In addition to downplaying the importance of 3M’s substantial up-front payments, the
    majority is also untroubled by the exclusivity of the agreements or the agreements’ multi-year terms.
    The majority claims that the type of exclusivity demanded by 3M is the same type of exclusivity that
    retailers demanded prior to 3M’s market dominance. But according to NicSand’s complaint, under
    the retailers’ pre-1997 rules, exclusivity lasted no longer than the completion of one purchase order.
    Retailers were free to switch suppliers from one purchase order to the next. See Complaint ¶ 25
    (“[R]etailers would typically not change suppliers other than at the time of their annual line review.”
    (Emphasis added)). A retailer carrying 3M’s products was free to suddenly solicit NicSand’s line
    of products. Or alternatively, a retailer was free to do what Pep Boys did — carry both suppliers’
    lines simultaneously. Although it appears that in reality, retailers opted to stick with one supplier
    for a full year, these agreements were, at most, “de facto” exclusive in the sense that once a retailer
    decided to receive its inventory from one supplier, it was unlikely to switch suppliers for one year.
    Thus, while an individual retailer perhaps wisely chose to keep one supplier’s product on its shelves
    for a period of one year, that retailer was simply not contractually bound to do so. There were no
    actual “exclusive dealing agreements” prior to 1997. Rather, there were four retailers choosing an
    economically reasonable course of business, and two suppliers competing fairly for that business.6
    And even so, agreements with suppliers were reconsidered every year during annual line reviews.
    5
    3M also asks us to make another profits calculation by spreading each of the four payments and profits over
    two years, which would yield a higher profit margin of 16%. Appellee Supp. Br. at 8-9 n.4. The majority goes even
    farther, claiming that under another unspecified methodology, NicSand still could have had profit margins of 17%-39%.
    Maj. Op. at 15. For the reasons already stated above, I believe that in light of the flaws already inherent in the
    methodology discussed above, any such calculations would be excessively speculative at best and would require us to
    misconstrue NicSand’s complaint in 3M’s favor.
    6
    Nor does the complaint state that the retailers were contemplating multi-year contracts or enacting any change
    in the market. All changes in the market were a direct result of 3M’s conduct.
    No. 05-3431                NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                                           Page 18
    Under this system, although NicSand may have been the more successful competitor in the market
    for a time, it alleges its success was owed to its “superior marketing, superior packing, innovation,
    and superior value,” 
    id. ¶ 11,
    not to anticompetitive practices.
    Contrary to the majority’s averments, NicSand should not have sought multi-year
    arrangements with retailers like 3M did. It is not the appropriate response under the law to answer
    anticompetitive conduct with more anticompetitive conduct. Moreover, in a battle for a monopoly
    between NicSand and 3M, it is hard to imagine how NicSand could have prevailed. Given the
    choice between a certain amount of money in one up-front payment or in installments over several
    years, any reasonable retailer would have chosen the former. That is simply time-value-of-money
    economics. 3M is a manufacturing powerhouse that obviously had the ability to subsidize its
    operations in the do-it-yourself-retail-automotive-coated-abrasives market with revenues from other
    sectors.7 NicSand, in contrast, may not have had the capital to match 3M’s substantial up-front
    payments and may not have been able to do so without selling below cost. The majority opinion
    lacks a certain real-world understanding of the relative positions of the two companies at issue in
    this case.
    In sum, under a plausible reading of NicSand’s complaint, 3M did the following. First, it
    offered retailers unprecedented and substantial up-front payments — payments that may have, in
    effect, been a form of below-cost pricing. 3M executed contracts with retailers that gave 3M
    exclusivity for several years in order to guarantee 3M time to recoup any losses. This multi-year
    exclusivity, when paired with its agreements with other retailers, also gave 3M a large enough share
    of the market such that its sole competitor, NicSand, would no longer be able to stay afloat. These
    agreements guaranteed 3M a monopoly in the do-it-yourself-retail-automotive-coated-abrasives
    market. NicSand’s allegations of 3M’s anticompetitive conduct are further bolstered by the fact that
    NicSand was forced into bankruptcy, 
    id. ¶ 43,
    3M now controls almost 100% of the market share,
    
    id. ¶ 67,
    and prices for these products have risen by 70% since NicSand left the market, 
    id. ¶ 63.
    As
    discussed below, with this monopoly now established, 3M no longer has to worry about keeping a
    superior and diverse product line or keeping its prices low.
    III.
    In Indeck, we explained that in a case where a competitor sues another competitor for an
    alleged antitrust violation, the plaintiff “must at least allege that [its] exclusion . . . from the
    marketplace   results in the elimination of a superior product or a lower-cost 
    alternative.” 250 F.3d at 977
    .8 Since this case comes before us at the 12(b)(6) stage, we must focus on NicSand’s
    particular allegations of harm to the market. To do so, we need look only to NicSand’s complaint,
    which alleges, in pertinent part:
    11. [The growth in NicSand’s market share] between 1987 and 2000 in DIY retail
    automotive coated abrasives was fueled primarily by NicSand’s superior marketing,
    superior packaging, innovation, and superior value. NicSand acquired and retained
    7
    Any good lawyer knows the value of Post-It Notes and Tabs. See, e.g., LePage’s, Inc. v. 3M, 
    324 F.3d 141
    ,
    157 (3d Cir. 2003)(finding ample evidence that 3M used exclusive agreements to entrench its monopoly over transparent
    tape); see also N.J. Wood Finishing Co. v. Minn. Mining & Mfg. Co., 
    332 F.2d 346
    , 348 (3d Cir. 1964) (“3M [is] a highly
    diversified company, manufacturing and selling a number of product lines and segments.”)
    8
    One commentator has noted that the continuing validity of Indeck as a correct application of the Supreme
    Court’s five-factor test has been called into question by later cases. See Ronald W. Davis, Standing on Shaky Ground:
    The Strangely Elusive Doctrine of Antitrust Injury, 70 Antitrust L. J. 697, 748 n.184 (2002-2003) (“In . . . Conwood [Co.
    v. United States Tobacco Co., 
    290 F.3d 768
    (6th Cir. 2002)], the court alluded to no requirement that the plaintiff’s snuff
    had to taste better, or cost less, than the defendant monopolist’s snuff.”); see also 
    id. at 737-43,
    747-48 (criticizing the
    Sixth Circuit’s precedent on the question of what a competitor must establish to show antitrust injury).
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                            Page 19
    its share of that market by offering better value than its competitors, providing on-
    time delivery, instituting innovative programs designed to assist DIY retailers in
    increasing their volume and profitability in the DIY retail automotive coated
    abrasives market, offering more products in less space, offering flexible payment
    terms, packaging each of its products in a manner consistent with that product’s
    market orientation, and, creating new specialty products at the request of customers.
    63. As a result of 3M’s attempted monopolization and/or monopolization of the
    market for DIY retail automotive coated abrasives, consumer prices for DIY retail
    automotive coated abrasives have risen significantly, in some cases, as much as 70%.
    64. As a result of 3M’s attempted monopolization and/or monopolization of the
    market for DIY retail automotive coated abrasives, the number of available DIY
    retail automotive coated abrasives products available for purchase by consumers has
    dropped by as much as half, from approximately eighty to approximately forty.
    69. Consumers have suffered as a result of 3M’s unlawful monopolization of the
    DIY retail automotive coated abrasives market, as prices have increased and
    selection has decreased substantially since 3M established its monopoly.
    Under a fair reading of the quoted paragraphs, NicSand has met Indeck’s requirements. First, it has
    alleged that its products were superior to 3M’s products. Given that “superior” is a comparative
    term and that 3M was NicSand’s only competitor during the relevant period, see Complaint ¶ 12
    (“NicSand’s only competitor in the DIY retail automotive coated abrasives market during the period
    1987 to 2000 was 3M.”), NicSand’s complaint could only have been alleging that its products were
    superior to 3M’s. NicSand claimed superiority in several senses: “superior marketing, superior
    packing, innovation, and superior value.” 
    Id. ¶ 11;
    see also 
    id. ¶ 58
    (“3M did not offer a superior
    product, superior pricing, or superior service.”).
    The majority complains, however, that what NicSand offers us is simply “an unelaborated
    claim that it provides better service than its competitors.” Maj. Op. at 21. Neither 12(b)(6) nor
    Indeck requires much, if any, further elaboration. Nevertheless, NicSand does in fact explain what
    it means, noting that it provided better value, on-time delivery, and “innovative programs designed
    to assist DIY retailers in increasing their volume and profitability in the DIY retail automotive
    coated abrasives market, offering more products in less space.” Complaint ¶ 11. NicSand also touts
    its flexible payment terms, packaging, and perhaps most importantly, its “creat[ion of] new specialty
    products at the request of customers.” 
    Id. In addition
    to the allegation of superior products and
    service, NicSand also alleges that since 3M established its monopoly, the selection of products has
    decreased substantially. 
    Id. ¶ 64,
    69. Thus, NicSand has alleged a decrease not only in product
    quality, but also in market diversity. While NicSand certainly could have alleged that its sandpaper
    had a better coefficient of friction than 3M’s, or something else to similar effect, NicSand does not
    need to supply such detailed factual information at the pleading stage, without the benefit of
    discovery.
    NicSand has also alleged that since its departure from the market, “consumer prices for DIY
    retail automotive coated abrasives have risen significantly, in some cases, as much as 70%.” 
    Id. ¶ 63;
    see also 
    id. ¶ 69
    (“[P]rices have increased . . . since 3M established its monopoly.”). NicSand
    has sufficiently alleged that its exclusion has “result[ed] in the elimination of . . . a lower-cost
    alternative,” which in turn “ indicat[es] that competition itself was harmed by” 3M’s conduct.
    
    Indeck, 250 F.3d at 977
    (emphasis in original). In other words, as a result of 3M eliminating its only
    competitor through a series of exclusive dealing contracts, competition was lessened, and prices
    increased as a result. And indeed, price increases of this magnitude certainly injure consumers. This
    type of problem goes to the heart of what the antitrust laws were designed to prevent. Cf. Reiter v.
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                               Page 20
    Sonotone Corp., 
    442 U.S. 330
    , 342 (1979) (“The essence of the antitrust laws is to ensure fair price
    competition in an open market.”).
    Although the majority dispenses with these factual allegations by concluding that NicSand
    has not alleged that 3M raised its prices, Maj. Op. at 6, it is a reasonable inference that at least some
    portion of the 70% price increase could be due to 3M’s monopoly. The idea that the retailers might
    be passing on some additional cost from 3M should not be controversial. Cf. Northwest Airlines v.
    County of Kent, 
    510 U.S. 355
    , 376 (1994) (Thomas, J., dissenting) (“Any cost an airline bears is in
    some sense an ‘indirect’ charge ‘on persons traveling in air commerce,’ because the airline
    ultimately will pass that cost on to consumers in the form of higher ticket prices.”); Acadia Motors
    v. Ford Motor Co., 
    44 F.3d 1050
    , 1056 (1st Cir. 1995) (“[I]t is quite commonplace for manufacturers
    and other regulated entities to pass on to retailers and consumers their costs of complying with
    regulatory statutes.”). Yet the majority believes this is not good enough, taking aim at NicSand for
    not specifying that the apparent increase in prices was due to actions by 3M and not by retailers.
    To dismiss this case on the pleadings on that basis defeats the whole point of notice pleading. When
    retailers raise prices, they do not include on their price tags a footnote outlining their reasons. At
    this point, before discovery, all NicSand can go by is what it sees in stores, and its allegations based
    on those observations raise a reasonable inference that 3M has used its monopoly power to increase
    prices. Nothing more should be required.
    The majority apparently believes that NicSand has merely alleged that 3M’s conduct caused
    the market to become less diversified, and argues that Indeck stands for the proposition that less
    diversity in the marketplace, standing alone, is insufficient to establish antitrust standing. Maj. Op.
    at 21. As discussed above, that is not all NicSand alleged in its complaint. However, assuming
    arguendo that all NicSand has alleged is that the market has become less diverse, I would part ways
    with the majority on its result because this “less diverse” market is now clearly a monopoly and the
    facts, as alleged by NicSand, show that the special dangers inherent in monopoly power may exist
    in this case. Von’s 
    Grocery, 384 U.S. at 275
    , 277 & n.7.
    Antitrust cases focus on exclusion from the relevant market, and the relevant market usually
    has characteristics that pertain to the case at hand. Diversity is valuable in any marketplace, but
    more so in some than in others. In Indeck, the relevant market was one for the commodity of electric
    power. The relevant question about the diversity of the market was whether the exclusion of thermal
    power from the market, in and of itself, was enough to establish antitrust standing. The Indeck court
    apparently believed that it was not. However, the electric power market is entirely different from
    the market at issue in this case. In most markets for electric power, it is not uncommon—given the
    substantial start-up, maintenance, and regulatory costs of operating a power plant—for there to exist
    long-term exclusive agreements with one producer. Cf. Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co.,
    
    365 U.S. 320
    , 334 (1961) (upholding a 20-year requirements contract between a public utility and
    a coal mining company, and noting that “at least in the case of public utilities the assurance of a
    steady and ample supply of fuel is necessary in the public interest.”). But long-term, exclusive
    contracts are obviously less essential in a retail-based market that supplies a product to consumers
    that is hardly a necessary commodity, the production of which does not require as substantial an
    investment of start-up capital as does a power plant, and that, as the majority quips, “does not take
    any ingenuity to make.” Maj. Op. at 12. And, since prices of electricity are usually regulated in
    some fashion by a governmental body, there is less risk of price gouging in those markets. Cf.
    Hallie v. Eau Claire, 
    471 U.S. 34
    , 47 (1985) (“[T]here is little or no danger that [a city] is involved
    in a private price-fixing arrangement.”). Moreover, Indeck focused on diversity in the source of
    electric power. To the end user—that is, the consumer—a difference in source is not terribly
    significant. Most consumers merely want reliable and affordable energy.
    However, in the retail market, a 50% reduction in the variety of products is undoubtedly
    meaningful. Different consumers desire different products for different needs. In a sense, diversity
    No. 05-3431                 NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                                              Page 21
    of products in the market for retail goods is a proxy for preserving the ability of consumers to choose
    products that they deem superior or that cost less. In other words, to say that a reduction in
    diversity does not reflect a reduction in the superiority of products or in the number of lower-cost
    alternatives is to ignore the impact of consumers’ preferences. Those consumers who relied on the
    forty products that have since disappeared from shelves may no longer have products that meet their
    goals for the cost they are willing to pay (especially given the 70% increase in price since NicSand
    was forced out of the market). This court, in essence, has decided on its own, without the benefit
    of discovery, that consumers should not be able to choose what may be a “superior       product.” This
    court cannot make that decision, at least not at the motion-to-dismiss stage.9
    The majority’s contention that there is no collective action problem in this case is also
    problematical. It is quite unlikely that in this market, retailers are going to sue over a line of
    sandpaper products, rather than simply pass the cost to consumers. It is a plausible inference from
    NicSand’s complaint that this is what the retailers have done in this case, since retail prices allegedly
    have risen seventy percent since NicSand’s exclusion from the market. Further, NicSand has
    suffered substantial injury in this case, whereas the retailers, given the small size of the relevant
    market, have suffered only marginal injury relative to their entire sales portfolios. Thus, they have
    less motivation to bring suit against 3M, given litigation costs and the risk of hurting their
    relationships with 3M, a company with substantial market presence across numerous product lines.
    As the panel majority aptly noted:
    the magnitude of the discounts (measured as a percentage of NicSand’s sales)
    declined as 3M locked up a progressively larger share of the distribution market.
    That is, as 3M seemed more likely to attain a monopoly position, the downstream
    distributors demanded progressively smaller discounts—perhaps because they
    expected NicSand to exit the market and hoped to assure themselves of some
    discount (and not be the only one of the distributors not to have done so) before none
    was available.
    9
    Neither the Indeck panel nor the majority in this case addressed our precedent’s “necessary predicate” test for
    antitrust standing. I therefore will not address it in detail. I pause to note only that I believe the test is satisfied in this
    case. The “necessary predicate” test was most recently examined by this court in In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litigation,
    
    332 F.3d 896
    (6th Cir. 2003). There, plaintiffs, purchasers of a particular heart medication, sued the manufacturer of
    the brand-name version of the drug and a manufacturer of a generic version of the drug, alleging that the former agreed
    to pay the latter $40 million per year to delay introduction of its generic version. Defendants made an argument similar
    to the one that 3M makes here: that plaintiffs failed to satisfy the necessary predicate test because even in the absence
    of the contract, the generic manufacturer could have legally and unilaterally delayed introduction of the drug into the
    market. 
    Id. at 912.
    The In re Cardizem court rejected this logic, explaining that in the prior cases, “complaints were
    dismissed for failure to allege antitrust injury because each of the defendants had taken an action that it was lawfully
    entitled to take, independent of the alleged antitrust violation, which was the actual, indisputable, and sole cause of the
    plaintiff’s injury.” 
    Id. at 914.
    The court stated that “[t]he fact that [defendant] could have unilaterally, and legally,
    decided not to bring its generic product to a manifestly profitable market ha[d] no relevance in assessing whether the
    plaintiffs adequately alleged that the antitrust violation was the necessary predicate for their injury.” 
    Id. at 915.
    The
    court further observed:
    [D]efendants’ position, if adopted, risks undermining a basic premise of antitrust law[:] . . . [that] in
    many instances, an otherwise legal action — e.g. setting a price — becomes illegal if it is pursuant to
    an agreement with a competitor. Under the defendants’ view, such an action would never cause
    antitrust injury because a defendant could have unilaterally and legally set the same price.
    
    Id. at 195
    n.19.
    The only issue in this case is whether the exclusive agreements at issue were anticompetitive and whether they
    injured the market under the relevant precedent. Because they were and they did, there is nothing else at issue in this
    case that suggests that 3M took any legal actions that were “the actual, indisputable, and sole cause of [NicSand]’s
    injury.” 
    Id. at 914.
    Accordingly, the “necessary predicate” test is satisfied here.
    No. 05-3431           NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Company                                            Page 22
    NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Co., 
    457 F.3d 534
    , 546 n.8 (6th Cir. 2006), vacated by 
    2006 U.S. App. LEXIS 32342
    (6th Cir. Nov. 22, 2006) (en banc). In essence, a collective action problem arose in this case
    because each retailer’s choice to get on 3M’s bandwagon was profitable to that retailer in the short-
    term and did not account for the potential long-term cost of a monopoly in the relevant market.
    IV.
    The majority seeks to characterize this case as one in which one company that had long
    prospered in a particular niche market became lazy and fell victim to a more vigorous competitor
    that simply played the game of business more effectively. While NicSand may have once been the
    dominant competitor, that former status can neither legalize 3M’s anticompetitive business practices
    nor make 3M immune from antitrust suit. Yes, NicSand was 3M’s competitor, and yes, it obviously
    fell prey to 3M’s tactics. However, 3M now holds a monopoly over the market, products have been
    eliminated and prices have correspondingly risen by seventy percent. The question here is whether
    the tactics 3M employed to attain that status were legal and whether NicSand is an adequate
    representative of the market’s interests in this suit. Contrary to the majority’s contentions, at this
    stage of the case, it is impossible to conclude that NicSand has failed to meet its burden. The
    dangers of monopoly are well-recognized in our law, see Von’s Grocery 
    Co., 384 U.S. at 274-75
    ,
    and I believe the majority has improperly turned a blind eye to them in this case.
    Accordingly, I respectfully dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 05-3431

Filed Date: 10/17/2007

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/22/2015

Authorities (37)

Augusta News Company v. Hudson News Co., Portland News Co., ... , 269 F.3d 41 ( 2001 )

Acadia Motors, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co. , 44 F.3d 1050 ( 1995 )

Valley Products Company, Inc. v. Landmark, a Division of ... , 128 F.3d 398 ( 1997 )

sharon-bell-as-trustee-in-bankruptcy-of-the-estate-of-executive-airways , 660 F.2d 1123 ( 1981 )

New Jersey Wood Finishing Company v. Minnesota Mining and ... , 332 F.2d 346 ( 1964 )

lepages-incorporated-lepages-management-company-llc , 324 F.3d 141 ( 2003 )

indeck-energy-services-inc-an-illinois-corporation-indeck-saginaw , 250 F.3d 972 ( 2000 )

Richard Hodges and Custom Tours, Inc. v. Wsm, Inc. Grand ... , 26 F.3d 36 ( 1994 )

michigan-paytel-joint-venture-michigan-paytel-inc-noah-inc-v-city-of , 287 F.3d 527 ( 2002 )

In Re: Cardizem Cd Antitrust Litigation. Louisiana ... , 332 F.3d 896 ( 2003 )

Freightliner of Knoxville, Inc. Carroll Properties, L.P. ... , 484 F.3d 865 ( 2007 )

Axis, S.P.A. v. Micafil, Inc. , 870 F.2d 1105 ( 1989 )

smith-wholesale-company-inc-rice-wholesale-co-inc-andalusia , 477 F.3d 854 ( 2007 )

Southaven Land Co., Inc. v. Malone & Hyde, Inc. , 715 F.2d 1079 ( 1983 )

Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc. , 112 S. Ct. 2072 ( 1992 )

The Tennessean Truckstop, Inc. v. Nts, Inc. , 875 F.2d 86 ( 1989 )

billy-ray-apperson-and-don-apperson-individually-and-on-behalf-of-a-class , 879 F.2d 1344 ( 1989 )

conwood-company-lp-conwood-sales-company-lp-v-united-states-tobacco , 290 F.3d 768 ( 2002 )

roger-peck-carolyn-b-peck-and-robert-w-peck-v-general-motors , 894 F.2d 844 ( 1990 )

Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis v. ... , 124 S. Ct. 872 ( 2004 )

View All Authorities »