OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States ( 2005 )


Menu:
  •                                 RECOMMENDED FOR FULL-TEXT PUBLICATION
    Pursuant to Sixth Circuit Rule 206
    File Name: 05a0435p.06
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE SIXTH CIRCUIT
    _________________
    X
    Plaintiff-Appellee, -
    OFFICEMAX, INC.,
    -
    -
    -
    No. 04-4009
    v.
    ,
    >
    UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,                            -
    Defendant-Appellant. -
    N
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of Ohio at Cleveland.
    No. 03-00961—Patricia A. Gaughan, District Judge.
    Argued: July 29, 2005
    Decided and Filed: November 2, 2005
    Before: ROGERS and SUTTON, Circuit Judges; ROSEN, District Judge.*
    _________________
    COUNSEL
    ARGUED: Teresa E. McLaughlin, UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE, Washington,
    D.C., for Appellant. Henry D. Levine, LEVINE, BLASZAK, BLOCK & BOOTHBY, LLP,
    Washington, D.C., for Appellee. ON BRIEF: Teresa E. McLaughlin, Robert W. Metzler, UNITED
    STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE, Washington, D.C., for Appellant. Henry D. Levine,
    Stephen J. Rosen, LEVINE, BLASZAK, BLOCK & BOOTHBY, LLP, Washington, D.C., Stephan
    J. Schlegelmilch, BAKER & HOSTETLER, Cleveland, Ohio, for Appellee. David Isaacson, New
    York, New York, for Amicus Curiae.
    SUTTON, J., delivered the opinion of the court, in which ROSEN, D. J., joined. ROGERS,
    J. (pp. 16-20), delivered a separate dissenting opinion.
    _________________
    OPINION
    _________________
    SUTTON, Circuit Judge. When a party presents the question whether “and” means “or,” it
    is tempting to be dismissive of the claim or, worse, to make a crack about the demise of the rule of
    law. But in this instance the disputed “and” appears in the context of several uses of the term that
    are alternately conjunctive and disjunctive and as much as nine billion dollars in potential tax refund
    *
    The Honorable Gerald E. Rosen, United States District Judge for the Eastern District of Michigan, sitting by
    designation.
    1
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                          Page 2
    claims (according to the government) rest on the resolution of the issue in this case and others, both
    of which prompt us to be anything but dismissive of the question.
    At issue is the meaning of “toll telephone service,” which Congress has subjected to a three-
    percent federal excise tax. The relevant legislation defines the phrase as “a telephonic quality
    communication for which [ ] there is a toll charge which varies in amount with the distance and
    elapsed transmission time of each individual communication.” 26 U.S.C. § 4252(b)(1) (emphasis
    added). According to the IRS, the definition means that the tax applies when the telephone company
    assesses a toll charge that varies in amount by either the distance or elapsed transmission time of
    each individual communication, or both. According to OfficeMax, the definition means that the tax
    applies when the telephone company assesses a toll charge that varies in amount by both the distance
    and elapsed transmission time of each individual communication. Given the traditional presumption
    that Congress uses “and” conjunctively, given other contextual clues supporting a conjunctive
    reading, given the awkwardness of construing the provision as the government does and given the
    historical fact that the one provider of long-distance telephone service in 1965, when the definition
    was adopted, charged for phone calls both by distance and time, we conclude that a toll charge must
    vary by both distance and elapsed transmission time in order to be taxed. We thus hold for the
    taxpayer and affirm.
    I.
    A.
    In 1898, 22 years after Alexander Graham Bell’s work led to the invention of the telephone,
    Congress imposed the first tax on telephone service. Designed to curb the federal deficit caused by
    the Spanish-American War, the temporary tax applied to “every person, firm or corporation owning
    or operating any telephone line or lines” and charged one cent for “messages or conversations
    transmitted over their respective lines . . . for which a charge of fifteen cents or more was imposed.”
    30 Stat. at 460, Pub. L. No. 55-133 (1898). Congress repealed the tax as scheduled in 1902. See
    Louis Alan Talley, The Federal Excise Tax on Telephone Service: A History 1 (Congressional
    Research Service 2001), available at http://www.law.umaryland.edu/marshall/crsreports/
    crsdocuments/RL30553_01042001.pdf (hereinafter “Talley”). Beginning in 1914 and continuing
    through 1916, in response to falling revenues caused by the start of World War I, Congress
    reenacted the tax—this time applying it to owners or operators of “any telegraph or telephone line
    or lines” and charging the same one cent for “dispatches, messages, or conversations originated at
    each of their respective exchanges, toll stations, or offices, and transmitted thence over their lines
    . . . for which a charge of 15 cents or more was imposed.” 30 Stat. at 761, Pub. L. No. 217; see
    Talley at 1–2. Between 1917 and 1924, in response to the United States’ entry into the war,
    Congress imposed a higher tax—“5 cents upon each telegraph, telephone, or radio, dispatch,
    message, or conversation, which originates within the United States, and for the transmission of
    which a charge of 15 cents or more is imposed.” 40 Stat. 300, Pub. L. No. 50. Congress increased
    the tax to 10 cents for calls costing more than 50 cents in 1919. See Talley at 3.
    The Great Depression prompted the next iteration of the tax, and it has existed in one form
    or another ever since. 
    Id. In 1932,
    Congress enacted a tax on “each telegraph, telephone, cable, or
    radio dispatch, message, or conversation, which originates . . . within the United States,” applying
    different rates to each service. 47 Stat. at 270, Pub. L. No. 154. In 1958, Congress changed the
    organization and labeling of the “communication services” tax, 72 Stat. at 1289, Pub. L. No. 85-859,
    dividing it into six categories, two of which concern us here: (1) “general telephone service,” i.e.,
    local telephone services; and (2) “toll telephone service,” i.e., long-distance service involving a toll
    charge. 72 Stat. at 1290, Pub. L. No. 85-859. The local (“general”) and long-distance (“toll”)
    telephone service taxes continued at varying rates through 1959, when Congress passed legislation
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                        Page 3
    repealing the tax on July 1, 1960. But by that date new legislation had enacted a one-year extension,
    and subsequent one-year extensions maintained the tax through 1965. Talley at 4–5.
    In 1965, Congress enacted the Excise Tax Reduction Act, which called for the repeal of most
    excise taxes, including an immediate reduction of the telephone tax from ten percent to three percent
    followed by an annual one-percent reduction thereafter until the tax was completely repealed on
    January 1, 1969. 79 Stat. at 145, Pub. L. No. 89-44. The 1965 legislation retained three categories
    of taxable services: “local telephone service,” “toll telephone service” and “teletypewriter exchange
    service.” As to toll telephone service, originally defined in the 1958 legislation as “a telephone or
    radio telephone message or conversation for which (1) there is a toll charge, and (2) the charge is
    paid within the United States,” Congress enacted the following definition, unchanged to this day:
    (1) a telephonic quality communication for which (A) there is a toll charge which
    varies in amount with the distance and elapsed transmission time of each individual
    communication and (B) the charge is paid within the United States, and
    (2) a service which entitles the subscriber, upon payment of a periodic charge
    (determined as a flat amount or upon the basis of total elapsed transmission time),
    to the privilege of an unlimited number of telephonic communications to or from all
    or a substantial portion of the persons having telephone or radio telephone stations
    in a specified area which is outside the local telephone system area in which the
    station provided with this service is located.
    79 Stat. at 146, Pub. L. No. 89-44; 26 U.S.C. § 4252(b). When Congress enacted this legislation
    (and for many years before and after its passage), the country had just one provider of long-distance
    service—AT&T. See, e.g., Am. Bankers Ins. Group v. United States, 
    408 F.3d 1328
    , 1333 (11th Cir.
    2005). And when Congress passed this version of the tax, AT&T already imposed a toll charge
    based on variations in both the time and distance of each call. 
    Id. In 1966,
    in response to spending pressures brought on by the Vietnam War, Congress began
    another series of extensions of the tax. The extensions continued through the 1970s and 1980s, with
    legislation maintaining the tax at varying rates through 1991. During these years, long-distance
    telecommunications transformed from a service offered by only one commercial provider to a
    service offered by several companies in a competitive market. The Federal Communications
    Commission issued a 1971 Specialized Common Carrier decision opening the long distance market
    to competition. See Michael R. Ward, Bureau of Economics Staff Report: Measurements of Market
    Power in Long Distance Telecommunications (Federal Trade Commission 1995), available at
    http://www.ftc.gov/reports/telecomm.pdf. An antitrust suit filed by the Department of Justice and
    the eventual settlement of that litigation in 1982 spurred further competition in the long-distance
    market. “While AT&T’s share of the long distance market’s revenues in 1982 was 95%, by 1987
    its market share had fallen to 80%, and [in 1993 was] about 60%. By 1991, MCI’s and Sprint’s
    revenue market shares had climbed to 17% and 10% respectively.” 
    Id. at 4
    (citation omitted).
    In 1990, Congress made the excise tax permanent at a three-percent rate, and, aside from a
    1997 amendment clarifying that calling cards were taxable, it did not revisit the issue again during
    that decade. The 1990s, however, did see a change in the way companies billed for long-distance
    telephone services, with long-distance companies beginning to offer for the first time nationwide
    long-distance plans for flat per-minute rates. AT&T abandoned its distance-and-time formula in
    favor of a time-only formula in 1997.
    Congress most recently considered the tax in 2000, when it enacted a package of spending
    and tax bills that proposed repealing the tax. A presidential veto, however, prevented the bill from
    becoming a law.
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                          Page 4
    B.
    From the first quarter of 1999 through the last quarter of 2002, OfficeMax purchased long
    distance telephone service from MCI. During this time, MCI charged OfficeMax one flat per-minute
    rate for every long distance call it made between States, another flat per-minute rate for long
    distance calls within each State (the rate of which varied by State) and another flat per-minute rate
    for long distance calls to international destinations (the rate of which varied by the destination
    country). At the end of each call, MCI rounded up to the nearest minute, multiplied the number of
    minutes by the flat per-minute rate, and assessed a total charge for the call. At the end of the billing
    cycle, MCI added up the total charges for all of the calls and billed OfficeMax for the amount. In
    addition, MCI collected from OfficeMax, and remitted to the federal government, the three-percent
    excise tax ostensibly imposed on these calls. On April 6, 2002, and February 13, 2003, OfficeMax
    filed claims with the federal government for a full refund of the $380,296.72 in excise taxes it had
    paid through MCI. In seeking a refund, OfficeMax argued that MCI was not providing a taxable
    service—neither a “toll telephone service, a “local telephone service” nor a “teletypewriter exchange
    service,” as Congress has defined those phrases. Most pertinently, the company argued, it had not
    provided a “toll telephone service” because it did not provide “a telephonic quality communication
    for which [ ] there is a toll charge which varies in amount with the distance and elapsed transmission
    time of each individual communication,” 26 U.S.C. § 4252(b)(1) (emphasis added).
    The district court granted OfficeMax’s motion for summary judgment, reasoning that the
    statutory language requires a telephone service plan’s charges to vary both with the distance and
    elapsed time of each call. It also rejected the IRS’s alternative arguments that OfficeMax’s long-
    distance plan met (1) an alternative definition for “toll telephone service” provided in § 4252(b)(2)
    or (2) the definition of “local telephone service,” § 4252(a), both of which must pay the same tax.
    II.
    Section 4251 of Title 26 imposes a tax on “amounts paid for communications services.” It
    defines “communications services” as “(A) local telephone service; (B) toll telephone service; and
    (C) teletypewriter exchange service.” 
    Id. Section 4252
    defines “toll telephone service” as:
    (1) a telephonic quality communication for which (A) there is a toll charge which
    varies in amount with the distance and elapsed transmission time of each individual
    communication and (B) the charge is paid within the United States, and
    (2) a service which entitles the subscriber, upon payment of a periodic charge
    (determined as a flat amount or upon the basis of total elapsed transmission time),
    to the privilege of an unlimited number of telephonic communications to or from all
    or a substantial portion of the persons having telephone or radio telephone stations
    in a specified area which is outside the local telephone system area in which the
    station provided with this service is located.
    26 U.S.C. § 4252(b) (emphasis added). The section defines “local telephone service” as:
    (1) the access to a local telephone system, and the privilege of telephonic quality
    communication with substantially all persons having telephone or radio telephone
    stations constituting a part of such local telephone system, and
    (2) any facility or service provided in connection with a service described in
    paragraph (1).
    No. 04-4009            OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                            Page 5
    26 U.S.C. § 4252(a). The section defines “teletypewriter exchange service” as:
    the access from a teletypewriter or other data station to the teletypewriter exchange
    system of which such station is a part, and the privilege of intercommunication by
    such station with substantially all persons having teletypewriter or other data stations
    constituting a part of the same teletypewriter exchange system, to which the
    subscriber is entitled upon payment of a charge or charges (whether such charge or
    charges are determined as a flat periodic amount, on the basis of distance and elapsed
    transmission time, or in some other manner).
    26 U.S.C. § 4252(c).
    As these sections of the tax code reveal, Congress used “and” in more than one sense when
    it enacted these provisions in 1965—giving it a conjunctive meaning (requiring all items) in some
    places and giving it a disjunctive or cumulative meaning (allowing any of the items) in other places.
    Section 4252(b)(1), for example, requires that the toll charge vary in amount with the distance and
    elapsed time of each individual communication “and” that the charge be paid within the United
    States. Both sides of this “and,” the parties agree, must be satisfied for the telephone service to be
    taxable. The same is true of other uses of the term in these provisions. See 26 U.S.C. § 4252(a)(1)
    (defining one alternative meaning of “local telephone service” as “access to a local telephone
    system, and the privilege of telephonic quality communication with . . . such local telephone
    system”) (emphasis added); § 4252(c) (defining “teletypewriter exchange service” as “access . . .
    to the teletypewriter exchange system . . . and the privilege of intercommunication . . . with
    substantially all persons . . . [in] the same teletypewriter exchange system”) (emphasis added).
    At times, however, Congress used the term differently. Take § 4251: it defines
    “communications services” as “local telephone service, toll telephone service, and teletypewriter
    exchange service.” 26 U.S.C. §4251 (emphasis added). No one doubts the disjunctive (or
    cumulative) nature of this usage because the definitions of the services in § 4252 are generally
    mutually exclusive and because no service exists that can satisfy all three definitions at once.
    Section 4252 likewise uses “and” to connect a list of alternative definitions of toll telephone service
    found in §§ 4252(b)(1) and (b)(2). Here, too, no one contests that a “toll charge which varies in
    amount with the distance and elapsed transmission time of each individual communication,”
    § 4252(b)(1), cannot simultaneously be a “periodic charge (determined as a flat amount or upon the
    basis of total elapsed transmission time) [for] the privilege of an unlimited number of telephonic
    communications,” § 4252(b)(2).
    As these different usages reveal, there is more to “and” than meets the eye. The case, then,
    does not simply turn on the intuition that “and” means “and,” “or” means “or,” and never the twain
    shall meet. For several reasons, however, the “and” at issue in this dispute requires a telephone
    company’s toll charge to vary both by distance and time to be taxable.
    First, dictionary definitions, legal usage guides and case law compel us to start from the
    premise that “and” usually does not mean “or.” Dictionaries consistently feature a conjunctive
    definition of “and” as the primary meaning of the word, see, e.g., Webster’s Third New
    International Dictionary 80 (2002) (“along with or together with . . . added to or linked to . . . as well
    as”), or the first usage of the word historically, see Oxford English Dictionary (2d ed, 1989)
    (“[i]ntroducing a word, clause, or sentence, which is to be taken side by side with, along with, or in
    addition to, that which precedes it”); Caleb Nelson, Originalism and Interpretive Conventions, 70
    U. Chi. L. Rev. 519, 519 (2003) (“In all living languages, the conventional usages of individual
    words change over time. For illustrations, one need only consult the Oxford English Dictionary,
    which arranges its definitions of each word so that they proceed from the earliest usages to those that
    were introduced more recently.”). Cf. Webster’s Third New International Dictionary 80 (2002)
    No. 04-4009            OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                           Page 6
    (alternative six of the second definition of “and”: “reference to either or both of two alternatives . . .
    esp[ecially] in legal language when also plainly intended to mean or”).
    Legal usage guides are to the same effect. See 1A Norman J. Singer, Statutes and Statutory
    Construction § 21.14 at 179–80 (6th ed. 2002) (“Statutory phrases separated by the word ‘and’ are
    usually to be interpreted in the conjunctive.” ); 
    id. at 183–84
    (“While there may be circumstances
    which call for an interpretation of the words ‘and’ and ‘or,’ ordinarily these words are not
    interchangeable. The terms ‘and’ and ‘or’ are often misused in drafting statutes. . . . The literal
    meaning of these terms should be followed unless it renders the statute inoperable or the meaning
    becomes questionable.”); 1 Bouvier’s Law Dictionary and Concise Encyclopedia 194–95 (3d
    Revision 1914) (“A conjunction connecting words or phrases expressing the idea that the latter is
    to be added to or taken along with the first. It is said to be equivalent to ‘as well as.’”); 
    id. at 195
    (“It is sometimes construed as meaning ‘or.’”); Bryan A. Garner, A Dictionary of Modern Legal
    Usage 55 (2d ed. 1995) (“Oddly, and is frequently misused for or where a single noun, or one of
    two nouns, is called for. . . . Sloppy drafting sometimes leads courts to recognize that and in a given
    context means or, much to the chagrin of some judges.” (quoting MacDonald v. Pan Am. World
    Airways, Inc., 
    859 F.2d 742
    , 746 (9th Cir. 1988) (Kozinski, J., dissenting) (“We give our language,
    and our language-dependent legal system, a body blow when we hold that it is reasonable to read
    ‘or’ for ‘and.’”))).
    Reflecting these traditional assumptions about the meaning of the term, the Supreme Court
    has said that “and” presumptively should be read in its “ordinary” conjunctive sense unless the
    “context” in which the term is used or “other provisions of the statute” dictate a contrary
    interpretation. See Crooks v. Harrelson, 
    282 U.S. 55
    , 58 (1930) (“We find nothing in the context
    or in other provisions of the statute which warrants the conclusion that the word ‘and’ was used
    otherwise than in its ordinary sense.”); United States v. Field, 
    255 U.S. 257
    , 262 (1921) (“These
    conditions are expressed conjunctively; and it would be inadmissible, in construing a taxing act, to
    read them as if prescribed disjunctively.”); City of Rome v. United States, 
    446 U.S. 156
    , 172 (1980)
    (“By describing the elements of discriminatory purpose and effect in the conjunctive, Congress
    plainly intended that a voting practice not be precleared unless both discriminatory purpose and
    effect are absent.”). The federal courts of appeals have done likewise. See, e.g., Bruce v. First Fed.
    Sav. & Loan Ass’n of Conroe Inc., 
    837 F.2d 712
    , 715 (5th Cir. 1988) (“The word ‘and’ is therefore
    to be accepted for its conjunctive connotation rather than as a word interchangeable with ‘or’ except
    where strict grammatical construction will frustrate clear legislative intent.”).
    When courts have interpreted “and” disjunctively, they have done so only to avoid an
    incoherent reading of a statute. See Slodov v. United States, 
    436 U.S. 238
    , 246–47 (1978)
    (interpreting a statute disjunctively that limited personal liability to “any person required to collect,
    truthfully account for and pay over any tax imposed by this title” because a conjunctive reading
    would lead to an absurd result: “Because the duty to pay over the tax arises only at the quarter’s end,
    a ‘responsible person’ who willfully failed to collect taxes would escape personal liability for that
    failure simply by resigning his position.”) (quotations and brackets omitted); Sosa v. Chase
    Manhattan Mortgage Corp., 
    348 F.3d 979
    , 981, 983 (11th Cir. 2003) (interpreting as disjunctive the
    phrase “[n]o person shall give and no person shall accept any portion” because “[e]xtending liability
    only if there were both a culpable giver and acceptor of an unearned fee would lead to irrational
    results”); United States v. Bonilla-Montenegro, 
    331 F.3d 1047
    , 1050–51 (9th Cir. 2003) (interpreting
    as disjunctive a definition of “crime of violence”—“an offense . . . that has as an element the use . . .
    of physical force . . . and [ ] includes murder, manslaughter, kidnapping, [etc.]”—because it would
    “def[y] common sense” to require an enumerated crime of violence also to have a use-of-force
    element) (quotation omitted); Peacock v. Lubbock Compress Co., 
    252 F.2d 892
    , 893 (5th Cir. 1958)
    (interpreting as disjunctive “an employer engaged in . . . the ginning and compressing of cotton”
    because “compressing is an operation entirely removed from ginning and [ ] the two are never
    carried on together”).
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                        Page 7
    Second, consistent with the inquiry proposed by these definitions and cases, there is nothing
    unusual (or for that matter absurd) about requiring a telephone toll charge to vary both with distance
    and time before subjecting it to tax. That is exactly the way long-distance calls were charged for
    a considerable period of time. In 1965, when Congress enacted this definition, the country had just
    one long-distance telephone provider, and AT&T billed for long-distance calls based both on the
    distance and time of the call or on a WATS-line basis (i.e., a flat rate for unlimited calling). Not
    surprisingly, when the drafters of § 4252 defined taxable long-distance service, they adopted a
    definition that turns on the distance-and-time measure of charging for the call, see § 4252(1), and
    a definition that turns on the WATS-line method of billing, see § 4252(2).
    There is something odd, by contrast, about giving the distance-and-time requirement a
    disjunctive interpretation. Why would Congress write a statute that says toll charges may vary by
    time or distance? In the last decade, it is true, time-varied toll charges have proved to be a viable
    stand-alone option. How strange, however, to impose a toll charge that varies solely by distance,
    with all calls from, say, Columbus, Ohio to Bozeman, Montana costing the same amount regardless
    of whether they last 60 seconds, 60 minutes or 60 days. At no point in this litigation has the
    government given us any indication that there is now, or ever has been, such a curious billing
    practice.
    The government, we suppose, might respond that the drafters had a different disjunctive
    interpretation of “and” in mind. Instead of taxing calls charged on one basis (distance) or the other
    (time), what Congress really meant to do was to tax calls charged on the basis of time and distance
    together or on the basis of time alone. Given the presumption that “and” has a conjunctive meaning
    and given the understandable reason why Congress would have embraced that meaning here, it is
    hard to see why we should adopt not just a disjunctive reading of the term but such a nuanced and
    changeable one.
    Third, context bolsters this conclusion. In writing the 1965 legislation, Congress defined
    three types of taxable communication services: “toll telephone service,” “local telephone service”
    and “teletypewriter exchange service.” It chose to define local telephone service simply by
    reference to “access” to “a” local telephone system; it chose to define the other two services by
    reference to the method of charging for those services. As to toll telephone service, we have seen,
    Congress taxed long-distance phone calls charged on the basis of time and distance. In defining
    teletypewriter exchange, it chose not to use a time-and-distance methodology alone and chose not
    to deploy the all-purpose, protean “and” that the government claims was used in defining toll
    telephone service. Rather than limit the taxable communication services to one billing method, it
    imposed the tax on charged teletypewriter services “whether such charge or charges are determined
    as a flat periodic amount, on the basis of distance and elapsed transmission time, or in some other
    manner.” 26 U.S.C. § 4252(c).
    This phrase, enacted at the same time as § 4252(1)(A), shows that Congress used a distance-
    and-time formulation elsewhere in the same bill and plainly meant it to have a traditionally
    conjunctive connotation there. See Gustafson v. Alloyd Co., Inc., 
    513 U.S. 561
    , 570 (1995)
    (recognizing “that identical words used in different parts of the same act are intended to have the
    same meaning”) (quotation omitted). And it shows the ease with which Congress could have
    demonstrated the taxability of different methods of toll charges or all charges (“or in some other
    manner”) had it wished to do so when defining toll telephone service.
    Fourth, in reaching this conclusion, we are not alone. Every court to reach this issue—save
    one district court subsequently reversed—has concluded that the statute unambiguously requires
    variance by both distance and elapsed transmission time. See Am. Bankers Ins. Group v. United
    States, 
    408 F.3d 1328
    (11th Cir. 2005) (reversing Am. Bankers Ins. Group, Inc. v. United States, 
    308 F. Supp. 2d 1360
    (S.D. Fla. 2004)); Am. Online, Inc. v. United States, 
    64 Fed. Cl. 571
    (Ct. Cl. 2005);
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                        Page 8
    Honeywell Int’l, Inc. v. United States, 
    64 Fed. Cl. 188
    (Ct. Cl. 2005); AMTRAK v. United States, 
    338 F. Supp. 2d 22
    (D.D.C. 2004); Hewlett-Packard Co. v. United States, No. 04-03832, 2005 U.S. Dist.
    LEXIS 199972 (N.D. Cal. Aug. 5, 2005); Reese Bros. v. United States, No. 03-745, 2004 U.S. Dist.
    LEXIS 27507 (W.D. Pa. Oct. 20, 2004); Fortis, Inc. v. United States, No. 03 Civ. 5137, 2004 U.S.
    Dist. LEXIS 18686 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 16, 2004). We are comfortable in charting a similar course here.
    Attempting to counter this conclusion, the government first argues that we must account for
    the other uses of “and” in this legislation that have a disjunctive or cumulative meaning. But the
    case law referenced above adequately accounts for this argument. As those cases provide, “and”
    presumptively has a conjunctive meaning save when that interpretation makes little or no sense in
    context. Sections 4251 and 4252, it is true, contain three instances where “and” is not used in its
    customary conjunctive sense. But in each case, context requires the term to be construed
    disjunctively because it conjoins a list of mutually exclusive alternatives. See § 4251(b)(1) (taxing
    “(A) local telephone service; (B) toll telephone service; and (C) teletypewriter exchange service”)
    (emphasis added); § 4252(b) (defining “toll telephone service” as the definition at issue in this case
    “and” an alternative definition that could not be satisfied simultaneously) (emphasis added);
    § 4252(a) (defining “local telephone service” as “(1) [a substantive definition] and (2) any facility
    or service provided in connection with a service described in paragraph (1)”) (emphasis added). In
    marked contrast, a toll charge simultaneously may be based on variations in distance and time.
    The government next argues that these other uses of “and” at a minimum establish
    ambiguity about the meaning of the term in § 4252(b)(1)(A). “[A]mbiguity,” however, “is a creature
    not of definitional possibilities but of statutory context.” Brown v. Gardner, 
    513 U.S. 115
    , 118
    (1994). And the question whether a statute is ambiguous arises after, not before, a court applies
    traditional canons of interpretation—the most important here being the context in which the word
    appears and the presumption that “and” carries a conjunctive connotation. See Chevron, U.S.A., Inc.
    v. Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 843 n.9 (1984) (“If a court, employing traditional
    tools of statutory construction, ascertains that Congress had an intention on the precise question at
    issue, that intention is the law and must be given effect.”); Robinson v. Shell Oil Co., 
    519 U.S. 337
    ,
    341 (1997) (“The plainness or ambiguity of statutory language is determined by reference to the
    language itself, the specific context in which that language is used, and the broader context of the
    statute as a whole.”).
    Nor does the government’s invocation of legislative history advance its cause. For one, the
    government has not presented the necessary warrant—a case of statutory ambiguity—for
    commencing a search of the statute’s legislative history. See Ex parte Collett, 
    337 U.S. 55
    , 61
    (1949); Chapman v. The Higbee Co., 
    319 F.3d 825
    , 829 (6th Cir. 2003); see also United States v.
    R.L.C., 
    503 U.S. 291
    , 307–11 (1992) (Scalia, J., concurring).
    For another, even the most far-reaching search of the legislative history behind the 1965 Act
    uncovers little. The committee report describing this provision elucidates nothing; it merely parrots
    the language that Congress ultimately enacted into law. Cf. Pub. L. No. 89-44, 79 Stat. 136, 146,
    with H.R. Rep. No. 433 (1965), reprinted in 1965 U.S.C.C.A.N. 1645, 1677 (“Toll telephone service
    is defined as being a telephonic quality communication for which a toll charge is made which varies
    in amount with the distance and the lapsed transmission time of individual communications, but only
    if the charge is paid within the United States.”).
    And the explanations for passing the 1965 Act do as much to undermine the government’s
    position as to support it. When Congress enacted the present definition of toll telephone service in
    1965—changing it from a broad definition of a service for which a toll was charged and paid within
    the United States, Pub. L. No. 85-859, 72 Stat. 1275, 1290 (1958)—it defined the phrase in a way
    that accounted for two distinct billing methods employed in 1965 by AT&T, the sole long-distance
    provider at that time. As we have noted, the first method calculated a charge for each call based on
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                         Page 9
    elapsed time and distance. The distance between the originator and receiver of the call would fall
    within one of several concentric mileage bands measured from the call’s origin. The per-minute rate
    of the call varied depending on which mileage band applied. This system was codified in
    § 4252(b)(1). The second method, known as “Wide Area Telephone Service” or “WATS,”
    calculated one charge per billing period, based on either a flat rate or the total elapsed time of all
    calls made during the period. This charge entitled the customer to an unlimited number of calls
    regardless of distance, and it was codified in § 4252(b)(2). See 1965 USCCAN 1676–77.
    All of this supports our interpretation. It shows why Congress would define toll telephone
    service as requiring a charge that varied both by time and distance. And it shows why Congress
    would define taxable telephone calls based on how a private company billed the calls: There was
    just one company; AT&T’s job was to collect the tax, not to pay it; and its monopoly status
    eliminated any commercial pressure to accommodate tax-sensitive clients.
    Persisting, the government points out that (1) Congress crafted the new definitions “to make
    it clear that it is the service as such which is being taxed and not merely the equipment being
    supplied,” 1965 USCCAN 1676, not to exempt certain long-distance phone calls from taxation, and
    (2) Congress added an important exemption for “private communication services” (e.g., intercoms)
    but again did not aim to eliminate from taxation certain long-distance calls because of the way they
    were billed. Even if we were to infer from these shards of legislative evidence that Congress meant
    to tax all long-distance service as it existed in 1965—through the creation of a definition based on
    extant billing methods—that does not mean we should interpret the same language to include all
    long distance service as it exists today. A statute enacted in 1890 that imposed an excise tax on
    sales, say, of “any vehicle of transportation” would cover airplanes, even though they were not
    invented until several years after 1890. Yet a statute enacted in 1890 that taxed sales of “any vehicle
    of transportation designed to convey passengers by land or sea” would not cover sales of traditional
    airplanes, even though the legislator’s purpose in 1890 could fairly be characterized as taxing all
    modes of transportation. Why should it be any different for this tax when time brings to an end an
    uncompetitive communications market and leads to wireless telephone communication (for which
    distance-based billing may make less sense)? As these examples suggest and as the terms of the
    1965 legislation require, “[i]t is ultimately the provisions of our laws rather than the principal
    concerns of our legislators by which we are governed.” Oncale v. Sundowner Offshore Serv., Inc.,
    
    523 U.S. 75
    , 79–80 (1998).
    A legislature that chooses to define eligibility for taxation based on how a private entity
    chooses to charge for the service, moreover, can hardly be treated as a body that means to impose
    a tax for all time. Just the opposite seems true, as the approach ultimately cedes the taxing authority
    to private entities, which is presumably why this method of taxation infrequently appears in Title
    26.
    A party willing to invoke broad generalizations of legislative purpose, at any rate, must
    account for equally plausible—yet vastly different—characterizations of that intent. When Congress
    wrote the present definition of toll telephone service in 1965, it planned to eliminate the tax in its
    entirety over the following three years. Entitled the “Excise Tax Reduction Act,” the 1965
    legislation imposed an immediate reduction of the telephone tax (from 10 percent to 3 percent),
    established an annual one-percent reduction of the tax, then called for the elimination of the tax on
    January 1, 1969. See 1965 USCCAN 1676; 
    id. at 1645,
    1649 (noting that the legislation “either in
    the current fiscal year, or over the next 3 subsequent years, removes entirely [the] miscellany of
    selective excise taxes [including the communications services excise tax] except those designed to
    serve certain specific purposes”); 
    id. at 1655
    (House committee report noted that “[i]n large part,
    these taxes were imposed as emergency wartime measures (either in World War II or the Korean
    War) or as an emergency method of raising revenues at the time of the depression of the 1930’s”).
    The Congress that enacted this legislation thus did not contemplate the continued application of the
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                          Page 10
    language past January 1, 1969, let alone to 1999. No matter how clear its design to include the
    lion’s share of long-distance service in existence between 1965 and 1969, that does not lead to the
    inference that the 1965 Congress meant to tax the lion’s share of long distance service in existence
    between 1999 and 2002. In the end, “application of ‘broad purposes’ of legislation at the expense
    of specific provisions ignores the complexity of the problems Congress is called upon to address and
    the dynamics of legislative action.” Board of Governors of Federal Reserve System v. Dimension
    Financial Corp., 
    474 U.S. 361
    , 373–74 (1986); Rodriguez v. United States, 
    480 U.S. 522
    , 526
    (1987) (per curiam) (“[I]t frustrates rather than effectuates legislative intent simplistically to assume
    that whatever furthers the statute’s primary objective must be the law.”).
    The government also fails to gain ground by emphasizing that “the statute does not state that
    the charge must vary with ‘both distance and elapsed time.’” U.S. Br. at 27. The presumption that
    “and” has a conjunctive meaning, however, spares legislative drafters from having to use a belt-and-
    suspenders approach (or, shall we say, both belt-and-suspenders approach) every time they deploy
    the term. The argument also comes perilously close to suggesting an interpretive presumption in
    favor of the government and against the taxpayer. Regardless of the current status of the “traditional
    canon that construes revenue-raising laws against their drafter,” United Dominion Indus. v. United
    States, 
    532 U.S. 822
    , 839 (2001) (Thomas, J., concurring), the government has not identified any
    case establishing an opposite presumption. See Bowers v. New York & Albany Literage Co., 
    273 U.S. 346
    , 350 (1927) (“The provision is part of a taxing statute; and such laws are to be interpreted
    liberally in favor of the taxpayers.”); United States v. Merriam, 
    263 U.S. 179
    , 188 (1923) (“If the
    words are doubtful, the doubt must be resolved against the government and in favor of the
    taxpayer.”); Benziger v. United States, 
    192 U.S. 38
    , 55 (1904); American Net & Twine Co. v.
    Worthington, 
    141 U.S. 468
    , 474 (1891); Leavell v. Blades, 
    141 S.W. 893
    , 894 (Mo. 1911) (“When
    the tax gatherer puts his finger on the citizen, he must also put his finger on the law permitting it.”).
    The government next urges us to defer to a 1979 IRS revenue ruling holding that a ship-to-
    shore satellite service that charged users without reference to distance satisfied the definition of
    “toll telephone service.” Rev. Rule 79-404, 1979-2 C.B. 382. But the one-page analysis in this
    revenue ruling does not contain the traditional hallmarks for receiving deference, whether under
    Chevron, or under Skidmore v. Swift & Co., 
    323 U.S. 134
    (1944). The revenue ruling acknowledges
    that “[l]iterally, the service provided in this case does not come within the definition of . . . ‘toll
    telephone service’ . . . because the charge for such service does not vary with distance and therefore
    does not meet the requirement of section 4252(b)(1).” Rev. Rule 79-404, 1979-2 C.B. 382, *3. It
    then echoes the point, explaining that “[t]he toll charges described in section 4252(b)(1) . . . vary
    in amount with both distance and elapsed transmission time of the individual communication.” 
    Id. at *6
    (emphasis added). Despite this “literal[]” meaning of the statute, the IRS determined that the
    communications service was “essentially” a toll telephone service “in order to comport with the
    legislative intent” of the statute, which it discerned as seeking to encompass all long-distance service
    in existence in 1965 and therefore all long-distance service in the future (including what was being
    provided in 1979). In the IRS’s words:
    The service in this case is essentially “toll telephone service” as described in section
    4252(b)(1) of the Code, even though the charge for calls between remote maritime
    stations and stations in the United States vary with elapsed transmission time only.
    The toll charges described in section 4252(b)(1), that vary in amount with both
    distance and elapsed transmission time of the individual communication, reflect
    Congress’ understanding of how the charges for long distance calls were computed
    at the time the section was enacted. The intent of the statute would be frustrated if
    a new type of service otherwise within such intent were held to be nontaxable merely
    because charges for it are determined in a manner which is not within the literal
    language of the statute.
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                         Page 11
    
    Id. at *6
    –7.
    When the Court decided Chevron, five years after this revenue ruling, we do not think it had
    in mind deferring to tax administrators who wished to impose taxes on services that were
    “essentially,” but not “literally,” within the contours of a taxing statute. Even if this circuit gave
    Chevron deference to revenue rulings, which it does not, see Aeroquip-Vickers, Inc. v. Comm’r, 
    347 F.3d 173
    , 181 (6th Cir. 2003) (declining to give Chevron deference to revenue rulings because they
    lack the “force of law”); Ammex, Inc. v. United States, 
    367 F.3d 530
    , 535 n.2 (6th Cir. 2004) (same),
    this revenue ruling would not clear step one of the Chevron test.
    Likewise, even assuming revenue rulings were entitled to Skidmore respect, cf. United States
    v. Cleveland Indians Baseball Co., 
    532 U.S. 200
    , 220 (2001) (declining to decide whether revenue
    rulings are entitled to deference at all), that deference would apply to a revenue ruling “only to the
    extent that [it has] the ‘power to persuade.’” Christensen v. Harris County, 
    529 U.S. 576
    , 587
    (2000) (quoting 
    Skidmore, 323 U.S. at 140
    ). Under Skidmore, courts should consider “‘the
    thoroughness evident in [the ruling’s] consideration, the validity of its reasoning, its consistency
    with earlier and later pronouncements, and all those factors which give it power to persuade, if
    lacking power to control.’” United States v. Mead Corp., 
    533 U.S. 218
    , 228 (2001) (quoting
    
    Skidmore, 323 U.S. at 140
    ). Generated by an agency that frequently insists that its citizens “turn
    square corners,” Rock Island, Ark. & La. R.R. Co. v. United States, 
    254 U.S. 141
    , 143 (1920), this
    revenue ruling no more supports an “essential” method of tax imposition than it does an “essential”
    method of tax payment. As other parts of our opinion explain, neither the legislative history nor
    one-sided generalizations about the purpose of the law make the case for straying from the ordinary
    meaning of the language in the statute. Agencies in the end receive Skidmore respect because of the
    persuasiveness of their reasoning, not in spite of it.
    No more availing is the government’s argument that, no matter how unpersuasive the
    revenue ruling is, we must defer to it because Congress repeatedly has reenacted the excise tax since
    1979. The Supreme Court has not spoken with one mind on this issue. On the one hand, the Court
    has said that “[w]here an agency’s statutory construction has been fully brought to the attention of
    the public and the Congress, and the latter has not sought to alter that interpretation although it has
    amended the statute in other respects, then presumably the legislative intent has been correctly
    discerned.” North Haven Bd. of Educ. v. Bell, 
    456 U.S. 512
    , 535 (1982). On the other hand, the
    Court has said: “We walk on quicksand when we try to find in the absence of corrective legislation
    a controlling legal principle.” Helvering v. Hallock, 
    309 U.S. 106
    , 121 (1940); see also Central
    Bank, N.A. v. First Interstate Bank, N.A., 
    511 U.S. 164
    , 186 (1994). Never mind: even the cases
    applying the reenactment doctrine impose limitations on it that are applicable here—“where the law
    is plain, subsequent reenactment does not constitute an adoption of a previous administrative
    construction.” 
    Brown, 513 U.S. at 121
    . And the doctrine does not apply when “the record of
    congressional discussion preceding reenactment makes no reference to the [interpretation], and there
    is no other evidence to suggest that Congress was even aware of the [agency’s] interpretive
    position.” 
    Id. Here, the
    government fails to identify any evidence in the telephone-excise-tax
    legislation from 1979 to the present that discusses or acknowledges the existence of the 1979
    revenue ruling.
    The government alternatively urges us to accept another interpretation of the provision, one
    not yet embraced by any administrative ruling. It claims that “‘distance’ clearly is shorthand for toll
    rate,” so that even if the statute requires that the toll charge vary by both distance and elapsed time,
    a service would qualify if the toll charge varied by both toll rate (even a constant toll rate) and
    elapsed time. U.S. Br. at 35. Under AT&T’s billing method in 1965, the government explains, all
    calls within a certain mileage band were charged at the same per-minute rate regardless of any
    difference in actual distance spanned by a given call. Because this system could produce equal
    billing for calls of modestly different distances (but the same time), all that the statute must require
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                         Page 12
    is some per-minute rate, however constant, by which to multiply the elapsed time. But, in making
    this argument, the government cannot escape the reality that the distance of each individual call
    under the AT&T system, measured by miles spanned and nothing more, did play a crucial role in
    the calculation of that call’s charge. Without knowing the call’s distance in miles—hence the reason
    they were called “mileage bands”—no one could ascertain the appropriate charge for the call. That
    AT&T bundled concentric mileage ranges into a series of rate quanta does not change this fact. In
    juxtaposition to the 1965 billing method used by AT&T, MCI’s model for billing OfficeMax during
    the tax years at issue does not take into account the distance of the call.
    Nor may the government prevail by comparing AT&T’s mileage bands with certain political
    zones—namely different States for intrastate calling and different countries for international
    calling—that yield different per-minute rates under the MCI plan for OfficeMax. The crucial
    variable under OfficeMax’s plan is the location of the call’s destination (for international calls) or
    the location of the call’s origin and destination (for intrastate calls) within the legal/political
    boundaries that serve as the dividing line between federal and state regulation of telephone service.
    That is, the differences in rates do not serve as a proxy for call distance, but instead accommodate
    the FCC’s regulatory jurisdiction over interstate and international calls and the states’ regulatory
    jurisdiction over intrastate calls. See La. Pub. Serv. Comm’n v. FCC, 
    476 U.S. 355
    , 360 (1986);
    AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 
    525 U.S. 366
    , 381 n.8 (1999). Moreover, any possible correlation
    between political boundaries and a call’s total distance is imperfect at best and does not convert any
    of the political zones into a measure of call distance. In many instances, for example, intrastate calls
    (which on average would seem to span a shorter distance than the longest of interstate calls)
    command higher per-minute rates than interstate calls.
    Judge Rogers’ dissent prompts a few responses. We agree with him that “and” may have a
    cumulative meaning or what comes to the same thing—a non-exclusive disjunctive meaning. And
    we agree that his examples—“I like bourbon and water” and “I like beer and wine”—begin to
    illustrate the difference. While context and common sense suggest that the former means both
    together, they suggest that the latter means either or both independently. But from the vantage point
    of the regulator or the regulated in 1965, the better analogy for “time and distance” was “bourbon
    and water,” not “beer and wine.” In 1965, “time and distance” were used in combination to measure
    telephone fees by the only telephone company on the market. Just as “bourbon and water” in
    context unambiguously requires both items, so does “time and distance.”
    But whether one prefers “bourbon and water” or “beer and wine,” each analogy is missing
    an ingredient featured here. Bourbon, water, beer and wine are all stand-alone items. Not so of
    “time and distance.” Distance, as we have shown, was not then, is not now and never has been used
    as a stand-alone measure for billing a phone call. Because one half of the pair in this case cannot
    operate independently, the better analogy is to “bread and butter,” “pancakes and syrup,” “chips and
    dip,” or less abstemiously, to “Corona and lime,” or least appetizingly, to “tequila and worm.” As
    in these examples, context and common sense indicate that the inability of one item in a conjoined
    pair to function independently means that they must be combined, that they must come two by two,
    not one by one. The same is true of “time and distance”: While time can function alone, distance
    cannot. The same problem undermines the dissent’s Venn-diagram argument, which mistakenly
    suggests that distance can exist as a stand-alone item.
    Lastly, for the dissent, it suffices to say three things in resolving this case: (1) “and” may
    have an in-combination meaning or a cumulative meaning; (2) the statute thus is ambiguous; and
    (3) the government thus should prevail under Skidmore deference. Leaving to the side the question
    of how many statutory “ands” in the United States Code would be eligible for ambiguity status under
    this interpretation, let us start by reiterating that context, common sense, history and the conjunctive
    time-and-distance formulation deployed in the tax for teletypewriter service in 1965 (“whether such
    charge or charges are determined as a flat periodic amount, on the basis of distance and elapsed
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                          Page 13
    transmission time, or in some other manner,” 26 U.S.C. § 4252(c)) all show that this “and”
    unambiguously has a conjunctive, in-combination meaning.
    But even were that not the case, it would not alter our conclusion. Skidmore breathes
    deference into an agency’s interpretation based “upon the thoroughness evident in its consideration,
    the validity of its reasoning, its consistency with earlier and later pronouncements”—based upon,
    in short, its “power to 
    persuade.” 323 U.S. at 140
    . But the revenue ruling at issue here takes an
    approach that the dissent castigates. The ruling acknowledges that “and” “literally” requires both
    time and distance: “The toll charges described in section 4252(b)(1), that vary in amount with both
    distance and elapsed transmission time of the individual communication, reflect Congress’
    understanding of how the charges for long distance calls were computed at the time the section was
    enacted.” Rev. Rule 79-404, 1979-2 C.B. 382. In abandoning this natural interpretation, the
    revenue ruling says that “a new type of service” cannot avoid taxation “merely because charges for
    it are determined in a manner which is not within the literal language of the statute.” 
    Id. The dissent
    does not defend that reasoning, and it does not defend the government’s litigating position in this
    case. Cf. Bowen v. Georgetown Univ. Hosp., 
    488 U.S. 204
    , 213 (1988) (“Deference to what appears
    to be nothing more than an agency’s convenient litigating position would be entirely
    inappropriate.”). Skidmore deference does not apply to a line of reasoning that an agency could
    have, but has not yet, adopted.
    That leaves only the possibility of deferring to the agency’s interpretation, not because it
    makes sense on its own terms, but because of its longevity. While the 1979 revenue ruling
    concerned the same definition of “toll telephone service” at issue in this case, it arose long before
    accessible cellular service (and other developments) led telephone companies to begin charging on
    the basis of time alone and it arose in the context of ship-to-shore satellites, a service that (contrary
    to the dissent’s suggestion) would not necessarily grab the attention of members of Congress and
    their staff. The real test for the agency came in the last decade when taxpayers began filing refund
    claims based on the decisions of long-distance carriers to begin charging on the basis of time alone.
    What the agency did at that point remains unclear. The taxpayer in this case argues that the IRS has
    settled many of these claims for well less than 100 cents on the dollar but claims it has been stymied
    in its attempts to obtain access to IRS records to establish whether that is true. At oral argument,
    we did not receive a clear answer one way or another. Under these circumstances and with respect
    to this anomalously reasoned revenue ruling, we are not prepared to defer to a ruling that only
    became relevant to today’s debate in the last decade and that may or may not have been followed
    consistently by the agency. Accordingly, whether the “and” in § 4252(b)(1) is ambiguous or not,
    the government has not identified any tenable bases for deferring to its position—save for the facts
    that it is the government and we depend on its fiscal health, which are not enough.
    III.
    The government argues that if it may not tax OfficeMax’s service under § 4252(b)(1), it may
    tax the company under the so-called WATS-line definition of “toll telephone service,” § 4252(b)(2),
    or under the definition of “local telephone service,” § 4252(a). We disagree.
    The alternative definition of “toll telephone service,” recall, covers:
    a service which entitles the subscriber, upon payment of a periodic charge
    (determined as a flat amount or upon the basis of total elapsed transmission time),
    to the privilege of an unlimited number of telephonic communications to or from all
    or a substantial portion of the persons having telephone or radio telephone stations
    in a specified area which is outside the local telephone system area in which the
    station provided with this service is located.
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                        Page 14
    26 U.S.C. § 4252(b)(2) (emphasis added). The government does not contend that OfficeMax paid
    a flat amount for unlimited service. It instead contends that because the toll charge for each
    individual communication varied by elapsed transmission time alone, the service amounted to a
    periodic-charge service determined on the basis of total elapsed transmission time. Not so.
    OfficeMax’s monthly bill was a total of toll charges calculated for each individual call. And for
    each of these calls, MCI rounded up to the next billing increment and multiplied by a variable rate
    to determine the individual call’s charge. The rate was subject to variation depending on other
    individual characteristics of the call as well, including “the time of day in which the call was made,”
    OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States, 
    309 F. Supp. 2d 984
    , 987 (N.D. Ohio 2004). The end result is not
    a “periodic charge” based on total elapsed time (or even total elapsed time itself rounded up to the
    next billing increment) but rather a monthly bill based on a summation of toll charges for individual
    communications. Due to the rounding, the total actual elapsed time of a bill could vary significantly
    without a change in the total amount due. The government’s argument also eschews the dichotomy
    that the legislation sets in place between services billed by call and services billed by period
    regardless of the number of calls. OfficeMax’s phone services fall on the by-call side of this line.
    Finally, the government’s argument departs from the requirements that the service must be both
    “unlimited” and to “a specified area.” See 26 U.S.C. § 4252(b)(2). The statutory language mirrors
    the concept of AT&T’s traditional WATS service, which for a flat rate allowed customers to make
    as many calls as they wanted to one of AT&T’s six U.S. service areas. OfficeMax’s phone service,
    as noted, levels charges for each call made, eschewing any reasonable definition of “unlimited” and
    allows calls to any non-local portion of the country, stretching the limits of “specified area.” All
    other courts reaching this issue have concluded similarly. Am. Bankers Ins. Group v. United States,
    
    408 F.3d 1328
    (11th Cir. 2005) (reversing Am. Bankers Ins. Group, Inc. v. United States, 308 F.
    Supp. 2d 1360 (S.D. Fla. 2004)); Am. Online, Inc. v. United States, 
    64 Fed. Cl. 571
    (Ct. Cl. 2005);
    Honeywell Int’l, Inc. v. United States, 
    64 Fed. Cl. 188
    (Ct. Cl. 2005); Hewlett-Packard Co. v. United
    States, No. 04-03832, 
    2005 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 19972
    (N.D. Cal. Aug. 5, 2005); Reese Bros. v. United
    States, No. 03–745, 
    2004 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 27507
    (W.D. Pa. Oct. 20, 2004); Fortis, Inc. v. United
    States, No. 03 Civ. 5137, 
    2004 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 18686
    (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 16, 2004). Indeed, even
    the government has elsewhere argued that § 4252(b)(2) applies exclusively to the traditional AT&T
    WATS service. See AMTRAK v. United States, 
    338 F. Supp. 2d 22
    , 28 (D.D.C. 2004) (“The IRS
    argues that ‘Congress drafted §4252(b)(2) purely to cover WATS service.’”(emphasis added)).
    Next, the provision defines “local telephone service” as “(1) the access to a local telephone
    system, and the privilege of telephonic quality communication with substantially all persons having
    telephone or radio telephone stations constituting a part of such local telephone system, and (2) any
    facility or service provided in connection with a service described in paragraph (1).” 26 U.S.C.
    § 4252(a). “The term ‘local telephone service,’” the statute adds, “does not include any service
    which is a ‘toll telephone service.’” 
    Id. The government
    argues that OfficeMax’s plan must be a
    service provided in connection with a local telephone service because all long-distance services
    eventually require access to local telephone systems. The only obstacle to a long distance service
    qualifying as a local telephone service, it adds, is the language excluding toll telephone service from
    the definition of local telephone service. Once it is determined that the OfficeMax plan does not
    qualify as a toll telephone service, the government concludes, it is eligible to be taxed as a local
    telephone service.
    Yet the definition of local-telephone service requires “access to a” local telephone system,
    not “access to every” local telephone system included within the boundaries of a long-distance plan.
    Not surprisingly, given its application to “local” telephone service, the definition contemplates a
    service with limited geographic reach, not a plan that makes use of an untold number of local
    services. Applying the local-telephone definition to the long-distance telephone definition,
    moreover, not only blurs the line between two statutorily defined services but also is puzzling. It
    makes one wonder why Congress would not eliminate the definition of toll telephone service
    altogether and apply the tax to all telephone services of any kind.
    No. 04-4009        OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States   Page 15
    IV.
    For these reasons, we affirm.
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                       Page 16
    _________________
    DISSENT
    _________________
    ROGERS, Circuit Judge, dissenting. A host separately asked two prospective guests what
    they liked to drink. One said, “I like bourbon and water.” The other said, “I like beer and wine.”
    When the second guest arrived at the event, the host served the guest a glass of beer mixed with
    wine. “What’s that awful drink?” said the guest, to which the host answered, “You said you liked
    beer and wine.” Replied the guest: “Pfui! You know what I meant. Quit playing word games and
    get me something I can drink.”
    Of course the host was “playing word games,” because the meanings of both “I like bourbon
    and water” and of “I like beer and wine” are clear. In the first sentence “I like” applies to “bourbon
    and water” together, whereas in the second sentence “I like” applies to each of “beer” and “wine”
    separately. Stated differently, the preceding words are distributed over the conjoined elements in
    the second sentence, so that the meaning is “I like beer and [I like] wine.” But the preceding words
    are not distributed over the conjoined elements in the first sentence, so that the meaning is “I like
    (bourbon and water).” In each sentence the word “and” has the same conjunctive meaning—the
    difference lies in whether the preceding words are distributed over the conjoined elements or not.
    Whether to interpret the preceding words as distributed over the conjoined elements or not depends
    on the context of the sentence, and what we externally know about the conjoined elements. Given
    what we know about the social context, and what we know about bourbon, water, beer and wine, the
    meanings of the two sentences are not at all ambiguous.
    I respectfully dissent in this case because it is similarly clear—from the regulatory context
    and what we know about telephone toll charges—that the words preceding the conjoined elements
    of “distance and elapsed transmission time” in the definition of “toll telephone service” are to be
    distributed over the two conjoined elements. That is, “a telephonic quality communication for which
    there is a toll charge which varies in amount with the distance and elapsed transmission time of each
    individual communication” means “a telephonic quality communication for which there is a toll
    charge which varies in amount with the distance and (a telephonic quality communication for which
    there is a toll charge which varies in amount with the) elapsed transmission time of each individual
    communication.” This natural language interpretation of the statutory language entirely disposes
    of OfficeMax’s contention that it does not owe a 3% excise tax on telephone toll charges that vary
    based on elapsed time, but do not vary based on distance. The tax is obviously owed.
    What we know about the context and about the nature of the conjoined elements strongly
    supports this interpretation. It is undisputed that, at the time of enactment of the language in
    question, the excise tax covered all home and business telephone charges, with the exception of an
    itemized list of special categories, such as services to certain news services and to state and local
    governments. It strains credulity that Congress intended that the phone company could unilaterally
    repeal a substantial tax on its customers by the simple expedient of combining its 6 or 7 long
    distance bands into one single band. It also strains credulity that Congress repeatedly refrained from
    repealing the excise tax on telephone charges, presumably because it counted on the revenue, while
    simultaneously intending to effect a repeal of the tax on the simple condition that phone companies
    find it practical to combine their long distance charging bands into one band.
    Of course without context or external knowledge, it is just as possible that all taxable toll
    charges have to vary both by distance and elapsed time. Maybe the second guest really wanted beer
    and wine in the same glass. Such a possibility at most creates an ambiguity. In the presence of an
    ambiguity, however, we are instructed by cases such as Skidmore v. Swift & Co. generally to defer
    to a long-standing agency interpretation. See Skidmore, 
    323 U.S. 134
    , 139-40 (1944). This is not
    No. 04-4009               OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                                      Page 17
    Chevron  deference, which if applicable would unquestionably require a ruling in the government’s
    favor.1 Instead, it is deference based on two powerful underlying considerations: (1) the agency is
    better positioned than the court to interpret specialized language, given its greater familiarity with
    the context in which the words are to be effectuated, and (2) congressional acquiescence in the
    agency interpretation may be inferred from Congress’s inaction in the face of agency application of
    the challenged interpretation. These two considerations, to the extent that2 they are warranted,
    support the idea that the agency properly interpreted what Congress wanted.
    While the first of these considerations is reasonably strong in this case, the second is
    exceptionally powerful. Skidmore states that the weight of an agency interpretive opinion depends
    in part on “its consistency with earlier and later 
    pronouncements.” 323 U.S. at 140
    . The logical
    basis for taking consistency into account is perforce that Congress must have acquiesced in the
    agency’s interpretation where it has been consistently applied. In contrast, where the agency has
    gone back and forth on an interpretation, there is much less reason to expect Congress to step in and
    fix the interpretation. See Gen. Elec. Co. v. Gilbert, 
    429 U.S. 125
    , 142-43 (1976). In the mine run
    of administrative interpretations, of course, this analysis has a fictional air to it. It is hard to say with
    confidence that members of Congress are really tracking the interpretive determinations of agencies,
    even when such determinations are consistent. Instead, the most we can say is that a consistent
    interpretation that adversely affects certain interests would be drawn to congressional attention in
    a way that might provoke a congressional response. In the absence of such a response, Congress
    can be assumed to be satisfied with the consistent interpretation, in the sense that Congress is
    politically comfortable with the results of the interpretation.
    This case is far from the mine run of administrative cases in this respect, however. This is
    not a case where the agency interpretation has been consistently applied to a series of five or ten
    administrative litigants around the country. And it is not a case where the politically relevant
    repercussions have not been felt. Instead, based squarely on the interpretation at issue in this case,
    millions of phone bills have charged the excise tax, and billions of dollars have been paid. Virtually
    every congressperson, every congressional staff member, every tax lobbyist, every accountant, and
    every person familiar with the terms of the statute received phone bills for years reflecting an excise
    tax on phone charges that varied only by elapsed time. Even more compelling is the political reality
    that the Government took and spent the money, and Congress, in making revenue determinations,
    took into account the money so taken in. When Congress debated whether to repeal the excise tax
    on telephone calls  in 2000, at least one member of the House expressed concern over the impending
    loss of revenue.3 The inference that Congress acquiesced in the agency’s interpretation is thus not
    1
    Chevron held that agency interpretations of ambiguous statutory terms are analogous to agency exercises of
    statutorily-granted legislative rulemaking power. Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    ,
    843-44 (1984). In United States v. Mead Corp., however, Chevron was held not to apply when the agency determination
    was sufficiently ad hoc that Congress cannot have considered the determination to be the exercise of delegated power
    to make binding interpretations. 
    533 U.S. 218
    , 231-32 (2001). While an argument could be made that Chevron
    deference applies here, by virtue of the innumerable adjudications in which the agency consistently applied its
    interpretation that the excise tax covered toll charges varying only by elapsed time, it is unnecessary to rely on Chevron
    deference in this case. The weaker but nonetheless substantial Skidmore form of deference, clearly applicable here, more
    than adequately requires that any ambiguity in this case be resolved in favor of the agency.
    2
    This contrasts with Chevron deference, where the deference is based on the idea that Congress delegated to
    the agency the power to make decisions by interpreting ambiguous provisions. See 
    Chevron, 467 U.S. at 843-44
    .
    3
    See, e.g., 146 Cong. Rec. E884 (2000) (statement of Rep. Stark) (“This bill recklessly cuts $20 billion in taxes
    that could be used for meaningful legislation . . . .”). The House Committee on Ways and Means in 2000 considered,
    and reported favorably upon, a bill to eliminate the excise tax on telephone services. H.R. Rep. No. 106-631 (2000).
    The bill, H.R. 3916, would have phased out the excise tax. From this bill, another argument can be made that Congress,
    as recently as May 2000, understood that the excise tax covered most long distance charges as they existed at the time.
    No. 04-4009               OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                                    Page 18
    fictional, but compelling. Congress not only acquiesced in the interpretation, it relied upon it in a
    very concrete and substantial way. Skidmore accordingly strongly supports the conclusion that an
    ambiguity should be construed in favor of the agency in this case.
    The Government’s position in this litigation has doubtless been weakened by the remarkably
    counterintuitive nature of some its arguments. The Government argues among other things that
    “and” means “or,” that “local” means nationwide, and that “distance” means “toll rate.” None of
    these anomalous contentions, however, is necessary to conclude that “toll telephone service”
    includes a toll charge varying solely by elapsed time.
    In particular, it is absolutely not necessary for the Government to argue that “and” means
    “or” in this case, or that “and” has a disjunctive meaning. Two meanings may be possible when
    elements are conjoined by “and” because of ambiguity as to whether the surrounding words apply
    to the conjoined elements separately or only together. But under both possibilities the elements are
    conjoined, added, cumulative. There is nothing disjunctive about it. Thus any discussion of whether
    “and” should be interpreted conjunctively or disjunctively is beside the point.
    An argument could be made that Congress, if it desired to tax telephone charges based only
    on elapsed time, could have used the disjunctive. That is, Congress could have said, “varies in
    amount with the distance or elapsed transmission time of each individual communication.” While
    Congress could have used such language, that language has the potential for a different set of
    possible interpretations. Some would argue that such language excludes charges that vary on both
    bases.
    The argument, moreover, is the equivalent of the social host giving the following retort to
    the second guest: “If you wanted beer or wine, you should have said ‘or.’” In another case involving
    a long-standing agency interpretation asserted to be contrary to plain statutory meaning, the Supreme
    Court rejected a comparable argument. In Young v. Community Nutrition Institute, the Court was
    asked to determine whether, under 21 U.S.C. § 346, the Food and Drug Administration (“FDA”) had
    a mandatory or discretionary duty to promulgate regulations determining the tolerance levels for
    harmful, but unavoidable, substances in food. 
    476 U.S. 974
    , 978 (1986). Section 346 provided that
    “the Secretary shall promulgate regulations limiting the quantity therein or thereon to such extent
    as he finds necessary for the protection of the public health.” 
    Id. at 977.
    The FDA had long
    interpreted the phrase “to such extent as he finds necessary” as modifying the word “shall.” 
    Id. at 979.
    A consumer and two public interest groups argued that “to such extent” modifies only “the
    quantity therein or thereon,” thereby requiring the FDA to promulgate tolerance levels. 
    Id. at 980.
    The Court reasoned as follows:
    While we agree with the Court of Appeals that Congress in § 346 was
    speaking directly to the precise question at issue in this case, we cannot agree with
    the Court of Appeals that Congress unambiguously expressed its intent through its
    choice of statutory language. The Court of Appeals’ reading of the statute may seem
    to some to be the more natural interpretation, but the phrasing of § 346 admits of
    either respondents’ or petitioner's reading of the statute. As enemies of the dangling
    participle well know, the English language does not always force a writer to specify
    which of two possible objects is the one to which a modifying phrase relates. A
    Congress more precise or more prescient than the one that enacted § 346 might, if
    it wished petitioner’s position to prevail, have placed “to such extent as he finds
    necessary for the protection of public health” as an appositive phrase immediately
    If the Committee thought that the excise tax did not cover modern long-distance charges, there would be no need to enact
    a phase-out. Accordingly, it can be assumed that the Committee believed that without intervention, the excise tax would
    continue to apply to modern long distance service.
    No. 04-4009               OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                                      Page 19
    after “shall” rather than as a free-floating phrase after “the quantity therein or
    thereon.” A Congress equally fastidious and foresighted, but intending respondents’
    position to prevail, might have substituted the phrase “to the quantity” for the phrase
    “to such extent as.” But the Congress that actually enacted § 346 took neither tack.
    In the absence of such improvements, the wording of § 346 must remain ambiguous.
    The FDA has therefore advanced an interpretation of an ambiguous statutory
    provision.
    “This view of the agency charged with administering the statute is
    entitled to considerable deference; and to sustain it, we need not find
    that it is the only permissible construction that [the agency] might
    have adopted but only that [the agency’s] understanding of this very
    ‘complex statute’ is a sufficiently rational one to preclude a court
    from substituting its judgment for that of [the agency].”
    
    Id. at 980-81
    (citing Chem. Mfrs. Assn. v. Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 
    470 U.S. 116
    , 125
    (1985)).
    Finally, the fact that most telephone charges in 1965 varied both by distance and elapsed
    time does not4say anything about what Congress intended when charges were later based solely on
    elapsed time. The majority suggests that if Congress contemplated charges based solely on time
    elapsed, Congress must also have had the “strange” intent of imposing a tax on the “curious”
    practice of billing solely by distance, regardless of elapsed time. For the following reasons, the
    conclusion simply does not follow.
    4
    The legislative history of § 4251 supports the position that Congress would have intended the 1965 definition
    to cover long distance service today and that modern sessions of Congress also thought that current long distance was
    subject to the tax.
    Contrary to the district court’s characterization, the definition of toll telephone service was not “narrowed” in
    1965 in an attempt to reduce the coverage of the excise tax. The 1965 Excise Tax Reduction Act had multiple goals.
    The House and Senate Committees did view the excise tax on communication services to be undesirable, because the
    tax “fell with greater severity on those with low incomes” and harmed businesses. H.R. Rep. No. 89-433 (1965), as
    reprinted in 1965 U.S.C.C.A.N. 1645, 1676. In order to achieve the goal of first reducing the tax, then eliminating the
    tax altogether, the Act reduced the rate of the tax from its original 10% to 3% in the first year, 2% in the second year,
    1% in the third year, with the tax to be eliminated in 1969. Id.; see also S. Rep. No. 89-324 (1965), as reprinted in 1965
    U.S.C.C.A.N. 1690, 1725. (As explained by the majority, the phase-out was later repealed for revenue-related reasons.)
    The definition of toll telephone service was not changed to help in the reduction or elimination of the tax. The
    definition was “updated and modified to make it clear that it is the service as such which is being taxed and not merely
    the equipment being supplied.” 1965 U.S.C.C.A.N. at 1676, 1725. This update was unrelated to the reduction goal,
    which was addressed in its entirety by the phase-out provisions described above.
    No. 04-4009           OfficeMax, Inc. v. United States                                      Page 20
    We can think of charging by elapsed time and charging by distance as overlapping circles,
    where area A is charging by elapsed time, area C is charging by distance,
    and area B is charging by both distance and elapsed time. The issue in
    this case is whether Congress meant to include all charges in areas A, B,
    and C, or only charges in area B. The majority’s argument is based on
    the idea that, for practical purposes, Congress assumed that areas A and
    C did not exist; there was only B at the time of enactment. (i.e., the
    circles happened to be congruent and cover identical areas at the time.)
    But what do we draw from this? One conclusion is that Congress never
    intended to create the possibility of a gap in the form of areas A and C.
    This is the more likely answer, for the reasons given above. Another
    conclusion is that Congress expressly limited itself to area B, and
    inadvertently created the gap of A and C, when those possibilities arose. This is less likely given
    Congress’ intention to tax substantially all long distance service. See supra note 4.
    The majority’s point—that area C was a null set in 1965 and continues to be a null set
    now—really does not affect the analysis one way or another. The issue is whether Congress meant
    to draw a line around all of A, B, and C, or whether it meant to draw a line around only B. That
    Congress apparently did not anticipate a gap leads to the conclusion that it did not intend to create
    one.
    In my view, we should not encourage lawyers to play word games at the expense of the
    public fisc. I respectfully dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 04-4009

Filed Date: 11/2/2005

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/22/2015

Authorities (41)

Sosa v. Chase Manhattan Mortgage Corporation , 348 F.3d 979 ( 2003 )

American Bankers Insurance Group v. United States , 408 F.3d 1328 ( 2005 )

george-a-macdonald-and-patrick-j-marckesano-allen-b-wheeler-william-j , 859 F.2d 742 ( 1988 )

R. A. Peacock, M. L. Coffer, and H. J. Wilson v. Lubbock ... , 252 F.2d 892 ( 1958 )

Lynette Chapman v. The Higbee Company, D/B/A Dillard ... , 319 F.3d 825 ( 2003 )

Ammex, Inc. v. United States of America Internal Revenue ... , 367 F.3d 530 ( 2004 )

Skidmore v. Swift & Co. , 65 S. Ct. 161 ( 1944 )

Benziger v. United States , 24 S. Ct. 189 ( 1904 )

United States v. Field , 255 U.S. 257 ( 1921 )

United States v. Merriam , 44 S. Ct. 69 ( 1923 )

United States v. Francisco Bonilla-Montenegro , 331 F.3d 1047 ( 2003 )

National Railroad Passenger Corp. v. United States , 338 F. Supp. 2d 22 ( 2004 )

American Bankers Insurance Group, Inc. v. United States , 308 F. Supp. 2d 1360 ( 2004 )

Office Max, Inc. v. United States , 309 F. Supp. 2d 984 ( 2004 )

United States v. Mead Corp. , 121 S. Ct. 2164 ( 2001 )

Helvering v. Hallock , 60 S. Ct. 444 ( 1940 )

Oncale v. Sundowner Offshore Services, Inc. , 118 S. Ct. 998 ( 1998 )

At&T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board , 119 S. Ct. 721 ( 1999 )

Christensen v. Harris County , 120 S. Ct. 1655 ( 2000 )

Chemical Manufacturers Ass'n v. Natural Resources Defense ... , 105 S. Ct. 1102 ( 1985 )

View All Authorities »