Tritent Intl Corp v. Comwlth of KY , 467 F.3d 547 ( 2006 )


Menu:
  •                                   RECOMMENDED FOR FULL-TEXT PUBLICATION
    Pursuant to Sixth Circuit Rule 206
    File Name: 06a0400p.06
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE SIXTH CIRCUIT
    _________________
    X
    Plaintiffs-Appellants, -
    TRITENT INTERNATIONAL CORP. et al.,
    -
    -
    -
    No. 05-6791
    v.
    ,
    >
    COMMONWEALTH OF KENTUCKY,                            -
    Defendant-Appellee. -
    N
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Eastern District of Kentucky at Frankfort.
    No. 04-00067—Joseph M. Hood, Chief District Judge.
    Argued: September 20, 2006
    Decided and Filed: October 30, 2006
    Before: CLAY and GILMAN, Circuit Judges; STAFFORD, District Judge.*
    _________________
    COUNSEL
    ARGUED: David F. Dobbins, PATTERSON, BELKNAP, WEBB & TYLER LLP, New York, New
    York, for Appellants. Gary D. Wilson, Washington, D.C., for Appellee. ON BRIEF: David F.
    Dobbins, PATTERSON, BELKNAP, WEBB & TYLER LLP, New York, New York, Melinda G.
    Wilson, M.G. WILSON, PLLC, Lexington, Kentucky, for Appellants. James M. Herrick, Michael
    Plumley, OFFICE OF THE ATTORNEY GENERAL, Frankfort, Kentucky, for Appellee.
    _________________
    OPINION
    _________________
    RONALD LEE GILMAN, Circuit Judge. Plaintiffs Cibahia Tabacos Especias Ltda. (a
    Brazilian cigarette manufacturer), Tritent International Corp. (an importer of Cibahia’s cigarettes),
    and DWI, LLC (a Kentucky wholesaler of those cigarettes) (collectively, Tritent), filed suit against
    the Commonwealth of Kentucky, arguing that two Kentucky statutes have effectively prohibited
    Tritent from doing business in the state. The statutes were enacted to effectuate and enforce the
    provisions of the Master Settlement Agreement (MSA), a voluntary agreement that has been entered
    into by 46 states (the settling states) and most tobacco companies. Tritent alleges that because it is
    *
    The Honorable William H. Stafford, Jr., United States District Judge for the Northern District of Florida, sitting
    by designation.
    1
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                  Page 2
    not a party to the MSA, it has been adversely affected by anticompetitive behavior that has occurred
    as a result of the Kentucky legislation.
    In its lawsuit against the state, Tritent alleged that the Kentucky statutes are preempted by
    the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, both because the state statutes mandate or authorize unlawful
    anticompetitive behavior and because they constitute a hybrid restraint on trade. The district court
    granted Kentucky’s motion to dismiss pursuant to Rule 12(b)(6) of the Federal Rules of Civil
    Procedure. Tritent timely appealed. For the reasons set forth below, we AFFIRM the judgment of
    the district court.
    I. BACKGROUND
    A.     Factual background
    1.      The MSA
    In the early to mid-1990s, more than 40 states commenced litigation against the tobacco
    industry, seeking monetary, equitable, and injunctive relief under various consumer-protection and
    antitrust laws. The general theory of these lawsuits was that the cigarettes produced by the tobacco
    industry contributed to health problems among the population, which in turn resulted in significant
    costs to the states’ public health systems. In response to the various state lawsuits, the tobacco
    industry mounted a vigorous defense, denying the states’ allegations of wrongdoing. With no end
    to the litigation in sight, the states and the tobacco industry began collaborating on a settlement
    agreement.
    In 1998, the Attorneys General of 46 states, as well as of the District of Columbia, Puerto
    Rico, and the Virgin Islands, entered into the MSA with the four largest manufacturers of cigarettes
    in the United States. These four manufacturers—Philip Morris, RJ Reynolds, Brown & Williamson,
    and Lorillard—are referred to in the MSA as the Original Participating Manufacturers (OPMs). At
    the time the MSA became effective, the OPMs collectively controlled approximately 97% of the
    domestic market for cigarettes.
    The purposes of the MSA, from the viewpoint of the settling states, were to prevent youth
    smoking, to promote public health, and to secure monetary payments from the tobacco
    manufacturers. In exchange for the OPMs’ cooperation in achieving these purposes, the settling
    states agreed to drop any pending claims against the tobacco industry and to refrain from filing
    additional claims. The OPMs, as discussed in detail below, agreed in turn to implement various
    tobacco-related health measures and to make payments to the settling states in perpetuity. In the
    MSA, the OPMs agreed to pay a minimum of $206 billion over the first twenty-five years of the
    agreement.
    Since 1998, approximately 41 additional tobacco companies have joined the MSA. These
    companies, referred to as the Subsequent Participating Manufacturers (SPMs), are bound by the
    MSA’s restrictions and must make payments to the settling states as set forth in the MSA.
    Collectively, the OPMs and the SPMs are referred to as the Participating Manufacturers (PMs). Any
    tobacco company choosing not to participate in the MSA is referred to as a Nonparticipating
    Manufacturer (NPM).
    The amount of money that the PMs are required to annually contribute to the states varies
    according to several factors. All payments are based primarily on the number of cigarettes sold.
    For the OPMs, the payments are determined in accordance with their relative market share as of
    1997. The payment amount of a particular OPM is also dictated by the “Volume Adjustment,”
    which compares the number of cigarettes sold in each payment year to the number of cigarettes sold
    in 1997. If the number of cigarettes sold by an OPM in a given year is less than the number it sold
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                  Page 3
    in 1997, the Volume Adjustment allows that OPM to reduce its payment to the settling states. In
    other words, a reduction in the amount of cigarettes sold by the OPMs results in the settling states
    receiving less money.
    The annual payments of the SPMs are determined by their relative market share as compared
    to other SPMs. For the SPMs that joined the MSA within 90 days of its execution, the annual
    payments are determined by the number of cigarettes an SPM sells beyond the “grandfathered”
    volume—calculated as the higher of either the individual SPM’s market share in 1998 (the year the
    MSA was executed) or 125% of the SPM’s market share in 1997. If an SPM’s sales volume or
    market share declines below the grandfathered amount, then it is not required to make any payments
    to the settling states. SPMs that failed to join the MSA within 90 days of its execution do not
    receive the benefit of any grandfathered amount.
    The payments from the PMs are deposited into an escrow account until disbursement to the
    settling states. Each state receives a payment equal to its “Allocable Share,” a percentage of the
    funds held in escrow that has been agreed upon by the settling states and memorialized in the MSA.
    This “Allocable Share” (as measured by a percentage of the total funds in escrow) does not vary
    according to how many cigarettes are sold in a particular state in a given year.
    During the drafting of the MSA, the OPMs and the settling states contemplated that many
    of the smaller tobacco companies would choose not to join the MSA. This failure to join posed a
    potential problem for both the OPMs and the settling states. The OPMs worried that the NPMs, both
    because they would not be bound by the advertising and other restrictions in the MSA and because
    they would not be required to make payments to the settling states, would be able to charge lower
    prices for their cigarettes and thus increase their market share.
    Although the settling states’ motivation was different from that of the OPMs, these states
    also were concerned about the effect of the tobacco companies that refused to join the MSA. The
    settling states worried that the NPMs would be able to regulate their sales so as to stay afloat
    financially while at the same time being effectively judgment-proof. As a result of these twin
    concerns, the OPMs and the settling states sought to have the MSA provide these other tobacco
    companies with incentives to join the agreement.
    One such incentive, called the NPM Adjustment, provides that the payments by the PMs to
    the settling states may be adjusted according to the “NPM Adjustment Percentage.” According to
    this provision, if a nationally recognized firm of economic consultants determines that the PMs have
    lost market share as a result of compliance with the MSA, the PMs’ required payments to the settling
    states will be reduced to account for the loss. The NPM Adjustment therefore gives the settling
    states an incentive to protect the market dominance of the PMs, because otherwise the settling states
    themselves will receive less funds.
    In addition to the NPM Adjustment, the MSA contains other provisions to protect the PMs.
    Primary among these provisions is a requirement that the settling states adopt “complementary”
    legislation to effectuate the MSA, with a failure to do so resulting in substantial reductions in the
    yearly payments. This complementary legislation, enacted by Kentucky and the other settling states,
    is the subject of the present case.
    2.      Kentucky’s Escrow Statute
    As discussed above, Kentucky and the other settling states wanted NPMs to participate in
    the MSA’s public health provisions or to be otherwise accountable for the harms caused by their
    products. Section 131.602 of the Kentucky Code, commonly referred to as the Escrow Statute, was
    part of the complementary legislation designed to address this concern. The Escrow Statute requires
    “[a]ny tobacco product manufacturer selling cigarettes to consumers within [Kentucky], whether
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                     Page 4
    directly or through a distributor, retailer, or similar intermediary or intermediaries,” to do one of the
    following: (1) join the MSA as an SPM, or (2) deposit into escrow an amount determined by the
    statute, currently 1.67539 cents per cigarette sold in Kentucky (or approximately 33.5 cents per
    pack). While the funds are held in escrow, the NPM receives any interest earned on the funds it
    deposits.
    As originally enacted, the Escrow Statute provided for the release of the funds under any of
    the following three circumstances:
    (a) To pay a judgment or settlement on any released claim brought against such
    tobacco product manufacturer by Kentucky or any releasing party located or residing
    in Kentucky. . . .
    (b) To the extent that [an NPM] establishes that the amount it was required to place
    into escrow in a particular year was greater than the state’s allocable share of the
    total payments that such manufacturer would have been required to make in that year
    under the [MSA] . . . had it been a participating manufacturer, the excess shall be
    released from escrow and revert back to such [NPM].
    (c) To the extent not released from escrow under paragraphs (a) and (b) of this
    subsection, funds shall be released from escrow and revert back to such [NPM]
    twenty-five (25) years after the date on which they were placed into escrow.
    Ky. Rev. Stat. § 131.602 (2)(a-c) (2000).
    Subsection (2) of the Escrow Statute, as originally drafted, is referred to as the “Allocable
    Share Release” (ASR) provision. This provision allowed an NPM to receive a refund of all
    payments in excess of the amount that it would have had to pay to Kentucky had the NPM been a
    PM.
    The ASR provision was intended to equalize the payments made under Kentucky’s Escrow
    Statute and the hypothetical payment that the NPM would have been required to make had it been
    a PM. For tobacco companies that sold cigarettes on a nationwide scale, the ASR provision served
    its desired purpose; the escrow obligations and the hypothetical MSA obligations were substantially
    the same. Not all companies, however, followed this nationwide business model. Some companies
    followed a regional business model, selling their products only in Kentucky and a few other states.
    As a result, those companies were able to obtain refunds of most of the money they placed in
    escrow. A brief hypothetical scenario will help to illuminate the disparity between the two business
    models.
    Assume that an NPM operating on a nationwide scale would have been required to pay
    $100,000 total to the settling states if it had joined the MSA. Because Kentucky’s Allocable Share
    is approximately 1.68%, Kentucky would have received no more than $1,680 from the NPM in the
    hypothetical event that the NPM became an SPM. The NPM, pursuant to the ASR provision, would
    have been entitled to a release of any escrowed funds in excess of the $1,680—meaning that the
    monetary obligation to Kentucky of an NPM was similar to that of an SPM. Under this business
    model, of course, the NPM would have had similar escrow obligations in the other settling states.
    Assume now that the NPM operated only in Kentucky. Regardless of the number of
    cigarettes sold in Kentucky, the NPM would pay the flat-rate-per-cigarette intended to be equivalent
    to that paid by an SPM selling the same number of cigarettes nationwide. The difference, though,
    is that the NPM would still be entitled to a release of all escrowed funds above the 1.68% that it
    would have had to pay Kentucky under the MSA—even though all of its sales were targeted in
    Kentucky (meaning that it had no escrow obligations in the other settling states). As a result of this
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                     Page 5
    disparity, NPMs operating on a regional level were able to reclaim most of the funds they placed in
    escrow. This in turn allowed the NPMs to artificially lower their prices, which, according to
    Kentucky, made the NPMs’ cigarettes more attractive to “price-sensitive youth.” Kentucky also
    believed that this practice resulted in disproportionate harm because, although the NPMs
    significantly contributed to cigarette sales in Kentucky, they did not contribute in a proportional
    manner to the funds held in escrow.
    As a result of the business practices of various NPMs, Kentucky repealed the ASR provision
    in 2004. The amended version of the statute now reads as follows:
    (b) To the extent that [an NPM] establishes that the amount it was required to place
    into escrow on account of units sold in the state in a particular year was greater than
    the [MSA] settlement payments, as determined pursuant to section IX(i) of that
    agreement, including after final determination of all adjustments, that such
    manufacturer would have been required to make on account of such units sold had
    it been a participating manufacturer, the excess shall be released from escrow and
    revert back to such [NPM] . . . .
    Ky. Rev. Stat. § 131.602(2)(b)(2004).
    Rather than being based on Kentucky’s Allocable Share (the 1.68% that Kentucky is entitled
    to under the MSA), the escrow obligation under the amended version (also known as the ASR
    Repealer) corresponds to the total MSA payment the NPM would have been required to pay had it
    been an SPM. As a result of the ASR Repealer, every manufacturer whose cigarettes are sold in
    Kentucky, regardless of where else the cigarettes are sold, is required to assume the same monetary
    obligation per cigarette that it would have incurred under the MSA, whether or not it actually joined
    the agreement.
    3.      Kentucky’s Contraband Statute
    The other key piece of complementary legislation is § 131.610 of the Kentucky Code,
    commonly referred to as the Contraband Statute. This statute requires the Kentucky Department of
    Revenue to maintain a list of all tobacco companies currently in compliance with either the MSA
    or the Escrow Statute. The list, known as the “directory,” must be available for public inspection
    and must contain the names of the complying tobacco manufacturers as well as all of the
    manufacturers’ “brand families.” 
    Id. Pursuant to
    § 131.612 of the Kentucky Code, no distributor
    may affix a Kentucky tax stamp, which is required for lawful cigarette sales, to any cigarette
    package if the manufacturer of that brand of cigarette is not listed in the directory. Tobacco
    companies that do not abide by either the MSA or the Escrow Statute are therefore effectively
    prohibited from selling their cigarettes in Kentucky.
    4.      The alleged effect of the MSA and complementary legislation
    Shortly before the MSA was executed, the OPMs controlled approximately 97% of the
    cigarette market in the United States. By 2000, however, this percentage had decreased to 94.5%.
    One reason for this change, according to Tritent, is that the OPMs have increased the price per pack
    of cigarettes in response to the payments required by the MSA. Because many cigarette smokers
    make their purchasing decisions based on cost, the higher cost of the OPMs’ cigarettes have resulted
    in a decrease in the OPMs’ market share. The OPMs are now selling less cigarettes, which in turn
    lessens their payment obligations under the MSA (because the payments are subject to the Volume
    Adjustment). Because the MSA provides a disincentive for raising market share (in the form of
    higher payments to the settling states), the NPMs argue that the PMs are not willing to engage in
    price competition.
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                     Page 6
    The NPMs, however, who are not obligated to make MSA payments or to follow the MSA’s
    advertising restrictions, should hypothetically be able to increase their market share. Such an
    increase actually occurred prior to the enactment of the ASR Repealer. A report by the National
    Association of Attorneys General confirmed that the NPMs’ market share greatly increased in the
    four years subsequent to the execution of the MSA. But the NPM Volume Adjustment reduces the
    PMs’ payment obligations in the face of such competition by the NPMs. This means that any price
    competition mounted against the PMs by the NPMs is undermined because the NPMs’ payments
    are based on the Escrow Statute rather than on the MSA, so that the NPMs do not enjoy a similar
    reduction. Therefore, any increase in the price per pack of cigarettes manufactured by the PMs is
    generally realized as additional profit rather than resulting in increased payments to the settling
    states.
    The Escrow Statute, according to the NPMs, further reduces the potential for price
    competition because it requires all tobacco companies selling cigarettes in Kentucky—whether or
    not they have joined the MSA—to make similar payments to Kentucky. Finally, the Contraband
    Statute effectively prohibits NPMs from doing business in Kentucky if they do not abide by their
    obligations under either the MSA or the Escrow Statute. Tritent argues that these two Kentucky
    statutes collectively result in an anticompetitive scheme.
    II. ANALYSIS
    A.      Standard of review
    We review de novo the district court's dismissal of a complaint pursuant to Rule 12(b)(6) of
    the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure. Harvey v. Great Seneca Financial Corp., 
    453 F.3d 324
    , 327
    (6th Cir. 2006). “A dismissal of a complaint may be affirmed if it appears that the non-movant can
    prove no set of facts in support of its claim that would entitle [it] to relief.” 
    Id. (citation and
    quotation marks omitted). Although reviewing courts must construe the complaint in the light most
    favorable to the plaintiff, accepting all factual allegations as true, a court is not required to “accept
    as true legal conclusions or unwarranted factual inferences.” Morgan v. Church’s Fried Chicken,
    
    829 F.2d 10
    , 12 (6th Cir. 1987).
    B.      Preemption under § 1 of the Sherman Act
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides in relevant part: “Every contract, combination in the
    form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several states,
    or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to be illegal.” 15 U.S.C. § 1. Tritent argues that the
    district court erred in refusing to hold that the Sherman Act preempts Kentucky’s complementary
    legislation. As support for this proposition, Tritent claims that the Escrow and Contraband Statutes
    result in output restrictions that are classified by the Sherman Act as per se illegal and hard-core
    cartel agreements because they are designed to and, if enforced, do result in “supracompetitive
    prices.” The district court assumed, for purposes of the motion to dismiss, that the activity about
    which Tritent complained—the “illegal output cartel”—did in fact exist. See Great 
    Seneca, 453 F.3d at 327
    (requiring a court, when considering a motion to dismiss under Rule 12(b)(6), to
    construe the complaint in the light most favorable to the plaintiff and to take all factual allegations
    as true). Tritent’s contention regarding the legal effect of the complementary legislation, however,
    was not presumed by the district court. See 
    id. (allowing the
    court to arrive at its own legal
    conclusions when reviewing a motion to dismiss). The legal effect of the complementary legislation
    guides our analysis of the Sherman Act preemption argument.
    As in the typical preemption case, determining whether the Sherman Act preempts the
    Kentucky complementary legislation involves the inquiry of “whether there exists an irreconcilable
    conflict between the federal and state regulatory schemes.” Rice v. Norman Williams Co., 458 U.S.
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                     Page 7
    654, 659 (1982). The existence of such a conflict must be more than hypothetical or potential. 
    Id. (“A state
    statute is not preempted by the federal antitrust laws simply because the state scheme
    might have an anticompetitive effect.”).
    Whether a state statute that restrains competition is preempted by the Sherman Act requires
    a two-step analysis. First, Tritent must demonstrate that the complementary legislation “mandates
    or authorizes conduct that necessarily constitutes a violation of the antitrust laws in all cases,
    or . . . places irresistible pressure on a private party to violate the antitrust laws in order to comply
    with the statute.” 
    Id. at 661;
    see also 324 Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 
    479 U.S. 335
    , 345 n.8 (1987) (“Our
    decisions reflect the principle that the federal antitrust laws pre-empt state laws authorizing or
    compelling private parties to engage in anticompetitive behavior.”).
    If we conclude that Tritent has satisfied the first step of the preemption analysis, we must
    then consider whether the state statute is saved from preemption by the state-action immunity
    doctrine as set forth in Parker v. Brown, 
    317 U.S. 341
    (1943) (holding that the state “as sovereign,
    imposed the restraint as an act of government which the Sherman Act did not undertake to
    prohibit”). The rationale behind Parker immunity is that Congress, in enacting the Sherman Act,
    evidenced no intent to restrain state behavior. 
    Id. at 351.
    In California Retail Liquor Dealers Ass’n
    v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 
    445 U.S. 97
    , 105 (1980), the Supreme Court discussed Parker immunity
    in detail and established a two-part test for determining whether it saves a state statute from
    preemption by the Sherman Act: “First, the challenged restraint must be one clearly articulated and
    affirmatively expressed as state policy; second, the policy must be actively supervised by the State
    itself.” 
    Id. (citation and
    quotation marks omitted).
    We begin by addressing the first part of the Sherman Act preemption analysis—whether
    Kentucky’s complementary legislation meets the Rice standard of mandating or authorizing
    anticompetitive behavior in all cases. Tritent argues that the Escrow Statute and Contraband Statute
    collectively authorize anticompetitive behavior. According to Tritent, the complementary legislation
    enacted by Kentucky to effectuate the provisions of the MSA punishes NPMs and rewards SPMs—a
    practice that constitutes an “illegal per se output cartel.”
    Tritent asserts that the two statutes operate as follows:
    (1) When the OPMs and the settling states entered into the MSA, the price of cigarettes soon
    increased. This allowed the NPMs to become financially competitive with the OPMs (and later, the
    SPMs). Without the hindrance of the MSA payment obligations and marketing restrictions, the
    NPMs should have been able, at least in theory, to capture a larger market share.
    (2) The Escrow Statute, as originally drafted with the ASR provision, allowed the NPMs to
    offer competitive prices so long as they targeted their sales on a regional basis. Once the Escrow
    Statute was amended by the ASR Repealer, however, the NPMs were no longer able to offer
    competitive prices. The ASR Repealer effectively eliminated price competition among cigarette
    manufacturers. Under the current scheme as it operates in Kentucky, because all cigarette
    manufacturers are required to make similar payments regardless of their participation in the MSA,
    the price per pack of cigarettes is essentially equal. Moreover, because the NPMs operate on a lower
    profit margin than do the larger PMs, the escrow payments—which are based on volume—amount
    to a penalty.
    (3) The Contraband Statute provides the enforcement mechanism for Kentucky’s statutory
    scheme. While the Escrow Statute requires NPMs like Tritent to make the yearly payments, the
    Contraband Statute prohibits the NPMs who have not met their monetary obligations under the
    Escrow Statute from selling their cigarettes in Kentucky (because the NPMs cannot obtain the
    necessary tax stamps). The complementary legislation, then, requires the NPMs to either raise their
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                    Page 8
    prices to cover their payment obligations—which has the effect of prohibiting the NPMs from
    undercutting the PMs’ prices—or to abandon the Kentucky market. This anticompetitive end result
    is allegedly mandated by the complementary legislation itself.
    The accuracy of Tritent’s characterization regarding the operation of the Kentucky statutes
    is the first issue that we must address on appeal. As discussed above, the Supreme Court in Rice
    made clear that in order to be preempted by the Sherman Act, the state statute in question must
    mandate illegal conduct in all 
    cases. 458 U.S. at 661
    . This court had occasion to consider the Rice
    requirement in McNeilus Truck and Manufacturing Co. v. Ohio, 
    226 F.3d 429
    (6th Cir. 2000). In
    McNeilus, the Ohio statute in question required dealers of remanufactured vehicles to either perform
    their own repairs or to enter into a binding contract with a dealer of new vehicles located within 20
    miles of the selling dealer so that customers could obtain service on their vehicles without voiding
    the manufacturer’s warranty. 
    Id. at 434.
    If the dealer of remanufactured vehicles failed to comply
    with the statute, the statute gave the state the authority to revoke the dealer’s license. 
    Id. McNeilus, a
    dealer of remanufactured vehicles, alleged that the Ohio law authorized
    anticompetitive behavior and was thus preempted by the Sherman Act. 
    Id. at 435.
    Because it could
    not perform repairs in-house, McNeilus attempted to secure a binding contract with several different
    dealers of new vehicles. 
    Id. at 436.
    All of the dealers within 20 miles of McNeilus’s location
    refused. 
    Id. According to
    McNeilus, these dealers participated in a “group boycott” because
    McNeilus imported its vehicles from out of state, a practice that angered the other Ohio dealers. 
    Id. Because the
    group boycott was facilitated by the statute, McNeilus alleged that the statute was
    preempted by the Sherman Act. 
    Id. This court
    rejected McNeilus’s claim. After recognizing that a group boycott was illegal
    per se under the Sherman Act, the McNeilus court acknowledged that the Ohio law “facilitate[d]”
    the alleged illegal behavior. 
    Id. at 441.
    Such facilitation, however, was not enough to support a
    holding of preemption. Even though the law had anticompetitive effects, the McNeilus court held
    that preemption was not called for because “the statute neither authorizes nor requires that dealers
    engage in behavior proscribed by the federal antitrust laws.” 
    Id. In other
    words, even though the
    statute encouraged, and even induced, the illegal behavior, McNeilus had no claim against the state.
    The court instead reasoned that McNeilus would have been better served bringing a claim against
    the dealers, because they were the actual perpetrators of the alleged anticompetitive behavior.
    Despite the pronouncement in McNeilus that the encouragement of anticompetitive behavior
    does not result in Sherman Act preemption, Tritent argues that “it is difficult to conjure up a more
    obvious case of preemption than that presented by these implementing statutes.” Tritent contends
    that the McNeilus court made clear that the lack of an explicit authorization in a State statute to
    promote or create an illegal per se activity is not dispositive of the preemption issue and is not the
    end of the inquiry.
    We find Tritent’s effort to distinguish McNeilus unpersuasive. This court in McNeilus
    essentially held that neither Ohio’s enactment of a statutory scheme under which new vehicle dealers
    were able to boycott McNeilus’s business, nor its enforcement of that scheme, were sufficient to
    require preemption under the Sherman Act. The anticompetitive behavior about which Tritent
    complains, and the relationship of that behavior to Kentucky’s complementary legislation, is
    remarkably similar to the scenario considered in McNeilus. In both cases, the states (Ohio in
    McNeilus and Kentucky here) enacted statutes that facilitated anticompetitive behavior, behavior
    that we must presume (for the purposes of Rule 12(b)(6)) to be illegal per se under the Sherman Act.
    And, in both cases, the offending parties (the dealers of new vehicles in McNeilus and the PMs in
    the present case) would have been unable to effectuate the anticompetitive behavior without the
    benefit of the respective statutes. Tritent and the other NPMs in the present case, for example, might
    have been able to offer their cigarettes at lower prices per pack, and thus increase their market share,
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                  Page 9
    had they been free of the monetary obligations resulting from the MSA and the complementary
    legislation.
    As McNeilus makes clear, however, the facilitation, or even encouragement, of
    anticompetitive behavior is not sufficient to warrant federal preemption. Kentucky’s complementary
    legislation, in order to be preempted, must “mandate or authorize” illegal behavior “in all cases.”
    
    Id. at 440;
    see also 
    Rice, 458 U.S. at 661
    . The statutes in question do nothing of the sort. They
    simply require that all tobacco companies—whether or not they choose to join the MSA—make
    payments to the state or face “blacklisting” from the Kentucky market.
    The PMs’ practice of increasing cigarette prices, thus keeping sales volume down, has
    allowed them to maintain a stable market share. This has resulted in lower payments to the settling
    states. If Tritent and the other NPMs had chosen not to raise their prices in response to the PMs’
    price increase, the NPMs’ market share would have presumably increased, but this would have
    subjected them to higher payments under the Escrow Statute. Kentucky’s current statutory scheme
    (in light of the ASR Repealer) thus provides a disincentive for the NPMs to engage in price
    competition with the PMs. The genesis of this anticompetitive behavior, however, stemmed neither
    from the MSA nor the complementary legislation that Kentucky enacted to give effect to the MSA’s
    provisions. Instead, the behavior with which Tritent really takes issue is the behavior of the PMs
    following the MSA’s enactment. Because such behavior was neither mandated nor explicitly
    authorized by the state of Kentucky, McNeilus forecloses Tritent’s argument on this issue.
    Tritent, however, relies on a case from the Second Circuit that reached a contrary result. In
    Freedom Holdings, Inc. v. Spitzer, 
    357 F.3d 205
    (2d Cir. 2004), the Second Circuit held that an
    NPM plaintiff had stated a cause of action under the Sherman Act because “the scheme as alleged
    threatens to become a permanent, nationwide cartel.” 
    Id. at 226.
    The Freedom Holdings court
    focused on the relationship between the MSA and New York’s complementary legislation. It
    correctly noted that although the settling states were parties to the MSA, the agreement itself was
    also the product of joint negotiations among the OPMs. 
    Id. at 224.
    Classifying the MSA as an
    “express market-sharing agreement among private tobacco manufacturers,” the Freedom Holdings
    court went on to hold that the NPM plaintiff in that case had satisfied the first prong of Sherman Act
    preemption analysis because New York’s complementary legislation allowed the PMs to effectuate
    the anticompetitive behavior contemplated by the MSA. 
    Id. at 226.
            Once the Freedom Holdings court accepted as true the NPM plaintiff’s allegations of
    anticompetitive behavior following the enactment of New York’s complementary legislation, its
    analysis regarding the first preemption prong ended. The Freedom Holdings court repeatedly
    characterized the complementary legislation as “allow[ing], “permit[ing],” and “empower[ing]”
    anticompetitive behavior, but the court never considered whether the statutes themselves mandated
    or authorized illegal conduct in all cases. Instead, the Freedom Holdings court essentially presumed
    that the NPM plaintiff had satisfied the first preemption prong simply by alleging a scheme under
    which anticompetitive behavior was prevalent. See also Grand River Enters. Six Nations, Ltd. v.
    Pryor, 
    425 F.3d 158
    , 173 (2d Cir. 2005) (relying on Freedom Holdings to affirm the district court’s
    denial of a motion to dismiss).
    Such an approach is contrary to this court’s decision in McNeilus. Under McNeilus, Tritent
    must make a showing that Kentucky’s complementary legislation does more than simply “facilitate”
    anticompetitive 
    behavior. 226 F.3d at 441
    . In other words, the fact that the volume-based payment
    scale in the MSA and in the Escrow Statute influenced the PMs to raise their prices and lower their
    output is not enough to satisfy the first prong of the Rice preemption analysis.
    The scenario considered by the McNeilus court represented a similar indirect effect. In both
    cases, the competitors’ behavior (other dealers in McNeilus and PMs in the present case) followed
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                   Page 10
    the enactment of state laws that facilitated the anticompetitive scheme. This scenario, however, has
    been held by other courts to be insufficient in and of itself to warrant preemption of the
    complementary legislation. See Xcaliber Int’l Ltd., LLC v. Kline, No. 05-2261, 
    2006 WL 288705
    ,
    *4 (D. Kan. Feb. 7, 2006) (“Stretching the Court’s per se analysis to include the “effect” of
    [Kansas’s complementary legislation], however, directly subverts the holding in Rice that “a state
    statute is not preempted by the federal antitrust laws simply because the state scheme might have
    an anticompetitive effect.”) (quotation marks omitted); S & M Brands, Inc. v. Summers, 
    393 F. Supp. 2d
    604, 629 (M.D. Tenn. 2005) (citing McNeilus to hold that Tennessee’s complementary legislation
    is not preempted by the Sherman Act because it neither mandates nor authorizes a violation of the
    antitrust laws); Sanders v. Lockyer, 
    365 F. Supp. 2d 1093
    , 1101 (N.D. Cal. 2005) (“The California
    statutes do not mandate, permit, or place irresistible pressure on manufacturers to take concerted
    action; rather they require unilateral action by each to make settlement or escrow payments.”).
    Because Tritent has failed to satisfy the first prong of Sherman Act preemption analysis, we
    need not consider the second prong’s Parker state-action immunity doctrine. See 
    Rice, 458 U.S. at 662
    n.9 (“Because of our resolution of the pre-emption issue, it is not necessary for us to consider
    whether the statute may be saved from invalidation under the doctrine of Parker v. Brown . . . .”);
    see also Philip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, 1 Antitrust Law § 217 (2000) (explaining that
    consideration of the Parker state-action immunity doctrine “would probably be essential” only in
    a case where a state statute mandated an activity otherwise illegal under the Sherman Act). We
    therefore conclude that Kentucky’s complementary legislation is not subject to Sherman Act
    preemption.
    C.     Tritent’s failure to show preemption precludes consideration of its hybrid-
    restraint claim
    Almost in passing, Tritent argues that Kentucky’s complementary legislation meets the
    characteristics of a hybrid restraint as described in 324 Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 
    479 U.S. 335
    (1987).
    A hybrid restraint exists where “private actors are . . . granted a degree of private regulatory power”
    by the state. 
    Id. at 345
    n.8 (quotation marks omitted). The presence of a hybrid restraint would
    obviate the requirement that Tritent demonstrate an “agreement” in order to prove unlawful behavior
    under the Sherman Act. If such a hybrid restraint conflicts with the Sherman Act, it may still be
    immune from Tritent’s challenge if it meets the two-prong Midcal test discussed in Part II.B. above.
    See 
    Midcal, 445 U.S. at 105
    (holding that a hybrid restraint will not result in preemption if the
    challenged restraint is clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed as a state policy, and the state
    actively supervises that policy).
    Tritent alleges that the present case includes a hybrid restraint because the complementary
    legislation allows PMs to “raise prices sufficiently with market share protection to pay the States
    and thereafter to retain as much as they could possibly realize from these protected price rises.” The
    district court found no need to reach this issue, however, because it held that the complementary
    legislation does not mandate or authorize unlawful anticompetitive behavior. It thus concluded that
    the Rice standard is applicable to any challenged restraint in the Sixth Circuit, hybrid or not.
    On appeal, Tritent all but abandons its hybrid-restraint argument by failing to challenge the
    district court’s unwillingness to reach the issue. Tritent also fails to articulate why Kentucky’s
    legislative scheme even constitutes a hybrid restraint. Instead, Tritent focuses its efforts on the two-
    prong Midcal state-immunity test, arguing that the complementary legislation is not immune from
    challenge because Kentucky fails to supervise the anticompetitive scheme. See 
    Midcal, 445 U.S. at 105
    (stating that the second-prong of the state-immunity analysis is whether the state actively
    supervises the anticompetitive restraint).
    No. 05-6791           Tritent Int’l Corp. et al. v. Commonwealth of Kentucky                 Page 11
    Supreme Court caselaw makes clear that the Rice preemption analysis—that is, whether the
    state statute at issue mandates or authorizes unlawful anticompetitive behavior—must precede the
    analysis under the hybrid-restraint theory. See, e.g., 324 Liquor 
    Corp., 479 U.S. at 345
    & n.8
    (striking down a hybrid restraint after determining that the legislative scheme was “inconsistent with
    § 1 of the Sherman Act”); 
    Rice, 458 U.S. at 665-69
    (Stevens, J., concurring in the judgment)
    (classifying Midcal and Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp., 
    341 U.S. 384
    (1951), as cases
    involving hybrid restraints, and determining that “in both cases the Court had the benefit of a
    conclusive presumption that [the activity at issue] was anticompetitive”). As discussed above,
    Tritent cannot make the necessary preemption showing under Rice. This failure left the district court
    with the authority to avoid reaching a decision on the hybrid-restraint issue.
    III. CONCLUSION
    For all of the reasons set forth above, we AFFIRM the judgment of the district court.