Garcia, Raul v. Moneygram Payment ( 2001 )


Menu:
  • In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    Nos. 01-1172 & 01-1176
    In the Matter of:
    Mexico Money Transfer Litigation
    Appeals from the United States District Court for the
    Northern District of Illinois, Eastern Division.
    Nos. 98 C 2407 & 98 C 2408--Rebecca R. Pallmeyer, Judge.
    Argued September 7, 2001--Decided October 4, 2001
    Before Bauer, Easterbrook, and Manion,
    Circuit Judges.
    Easterbrook, Circuit Judge. "Send $300 to
    Mexico for $15." This tag line, typical
    of promotions by the two defendants
    (MoneyGram and Western Union, plus its
    subsidiary Orlandi Valuta), is at the
    core of these consolidated class actions.
    Plaintiffs contend that "for $15" is
    fraudulent because the wire transfer
    companies collect for their services not
    only cash paid over the counter (the $15)
    but also the difference between the
    retail currency exchange rate quoted to
    customers and the wholesale (interbank)
    rate, for transactions of $5 million or
    more, at which the defendants buy pesos.
    Plaintiffs believe that the quoted price
    must include the difference in foreign
    exchange rates (the "fx spread", which
    averages about $25 per transaction) or
    that the defendants must at least reveal
    the price that they pay for pesos, so
    that the customers may work out the
    spread for themselves. The classes sought
    treble damages under the Racketeer
    Influenced and Corrupt Organizations Act
    (rico), 18 U.S.C. sec.sec. 1961-68, and
    state anti-fraud laws. Class
    representatives estimated that defendants
    make as much as $300 million per year
    from the fx spread, and they sought
    treble this sum, over many years, as
    damages. The proposed recovery thus ran
    into the billions of dollars.
    The class got much less. The defendants-
    -which contended that they have not
    committed fraud because they reveal
    exactly how many pesos will be delivered
    in Mexico for exactly how many dollars--
    were unwilling to pay very much on what
    they deemed a weak claim. Moreover, to
    curtail the risk of fraud, they were
    unwilling to pay any cash except to class
    members who established their identities.
    For many members of the class, who are
    either not lawful residents of the United
    States or otherwise unwilling to submit
    personal details, mandatory
    identification would block relief. So the
    parties settled the case on other terms.
    Defendants agreed to disclose in future
    transactions and advertisements that
    there is a fx spread and that each
    defendant sets its own retail price of
    pesos, and to provide a toll-free
    telephone number from which customers can
    learn the going retail exchange rate.
    They also agreed to provide class members
    with coupons entitling them to $6 off the
    price of one future wire transfer for
    every transfer made since November 1993.
    (To simplify the exposition we disregard
    some additional details, which may be
    found in the district court’s opinion.)
    The face value of coupons to be made
    available approaches $400 million.
    Finally, defendants agreed to pay about
    $4.6 million to organizations that assist
    the Mexican-American community; the
    parties call this "cy pres relief" in
    recognition of the fact that many class
    members will prove to be unidentifiable,
    will not claim their coupons, or will not
    use all coupons they receive. Finally,
    the defendants agreed to bear the expense
    of notifying the class (which normally
    must be borne by the representative
    plaintiffs, see Eisen v. Carlisle &
    Jacquelin, 
    417 U.S. 156
    (1974); White v.
    Sundstrand Corp., 
    256 F.3d 580
    (7th Cir.
    2001)) as well as the expense of
    administering the settlement; these
    outlays have been estimated at about $16
    million, to which about $10 million in
    attorneys’ fees will be added. After
    receiving notice under Fed. R. Civ. P.
    23(c)(2), about 2,800 class members opted
    out, retaining their right to sue
    independently. Raul Garcia and Lydia
    Bueno intervened and objected to the
    settlement. The district court held a
    hearing under Rule 23(e), took testimony
    from the objectors and several expert
    witnesses, and later approved the
    compromise and entered the proposed
    consent decree. 2000 U.S. Dist. Lexis
    18863 (N.D. Ill. Dec. 21, 2000).
    According to the objectors, the court
    should not have certified a nationwide
    class, or indeed allowed the litigation
    to proceed in Illinois (rather than
    California, where about a third of the
    class members reside). They also think
    that the class should have received more,
    and in particular should have been
    compensated in cash rather than coupons.
    Most of the objectors’ arguments occasion
    little or no discussion. For example,
    their complaint about the location of the
    court not only overlooks the fact that
    rico authorizes nationwide service of
    process, see 18 U.S.C. sec.1965; Lisak v.
    Mercantile Bancorp, Inc., 
    834 F.2d 668
    ,
    671-72 (7th Cir. 1987), but also supposes
    that this suit has proceeded "in
    Illinois," as if the district court were
    exercising the power of that state. A
    state court might well have the necessary
    authority, see Phillips Petroleum Co. v.
    Shutts, 
    472 U.S. 797
    (1985), but no
    matter. This suit is in a United States
    District Court, which exercises the
    judicial power of the nation. All class
    members and defendants live within the
    territorial jurisdiction of the district
    court, given sec.1965. If both the
    representatives and the defendants are
    satisfied with venue (which they are)
    individual class members have no
    complaint. Only two of the other
    objections require treatment: the
    propriety of class certification in light
    of potential differences among state
    laws, and the adequacy of the defendants’
    payments.
    The district court found that the class
    meets all requirements of Rule 23(a)
    (numerosity, commonality, typicality, and
    adequacy of representation), plus the
    requirements of Rule 23(b)(3)
    (predominance of common over individual
    disputes and superiority of class
    disposition). It is hard to quarrel with
    these conclusions. The class is very
    large; each individual claim is small;
    the defendants handled all wire transfers
    the same way. Sometimes class treatment
    will be inappropriate even if all of
    these things are true, when recovery
    depends on law that varies materially
    from state to state. See, e.g., Isaacs v.
    Sprint Corp., 2001 U.S. App. Lexis 18324
    (7th Cir. Aug. 14, 2001); Szabo v.
    Bridgeport Machines, Inc., 
    249 F.3d 672
    (7th Cir. 2001); In re Rhone-Poulenc
    Rorer Inc., 
    51 F.3d 1293
    (7th Cir. 1995).
    The class representatives avoided this
    pitfall in two ways: first, they confined
    their theories to federal law plus
    aspects of state law that are uniform;
    second, they asked for certification of a
    class for settlement only, a step that
    the Supreme Court approved in Amchem
    Products, Inc. v. Windsor, 
    521 U.S. 591
    (1997). Given the settlement, no one need
    draw fine lines among state-law theories
    of relief. By relying principally on
    federal substantive law, the
    representative plaintiffs followed the
    pattern of antitrust and securities
    litigation, where nationwide classes are
    certified routinely even though every
    state has its own antitrust or securities
    law, and even though these state laws may
    differ in ways that could prevent class
    treatment if they supplied the principal
    theories of recovery. See, e.g., In re
    Prudential Insurance Co. Sales Practice
    Litigation, 
    148 F.3d 283
    , 314-15 (3d Cir.
    1998). Many opinions, of which Amchem is
    
    one, 521 U.S. at 625
    , give consumer fraud
    as an example of a claim for which class
    treatment is appropriate.
    Nonetheless, the objectors imply, these
    class representatives are inadequate
    because they failed to investigate and
    deploy every potential state-law theory.
    Why they should have an obligation to
    find some way to defeat class treatment
    is a mystery. It is best to bypass
    marginal theories if their presence would
    spoil the use of an aggregation device
    that on the whole is favorable to holders
    of small claims. Instead of requiring the
    plaintiffs to conduct what may be a snipe
    hunt, district judges should do what the
    court did here: Invite objectors to
    identify an available state-law theory
    that the representatives should have
    raised, and that if presented would have
    either increased the recovery or
    demonstrated the inappropriateness of
    class treatment.
    Our objectors believe that they have
    found such a theory, rooted in a
    California statute regulating the
    performance of financial intermediaries
    that offer international money transfers.
    See Cal. Fin. Code sec.sec. 1800-27. The
    objectors see a plausible claim in almost
    every subsection of this statute. The
    district court analyzed them all and
    found that none of the subsections gives
    the class any advantage over rico. We
    agree with that assessment. No purpose
    would be served by an exhaustive
    analysis, for one appears in the district
    judge’s careful opinion. An example will
    suffice. Section 1810(a) states: "Every
    licensee or its agent shall forward all
    moneys received . . . or give
    instructions committing equivalent funds
    to the person designated by the
    customer". The objectors see in this an
    obligation to transfer funds at the
    wholesale fx rate. We see no discussion
    of the difference between wholesale and
    retail prices for foreign currency; the
    section seems designed instead to require
    that the intermediary keep its promise to
    transfer the funds. Of course we may have
    missed some subtle interaction among the
    sections of the California Financial
    Code, but enforcement is not committed to
    judges in the first instance. It is
    committed to the California Department of
    Financial Institutions, see Cal. Fin.
    Code sec.sec. 1817-19, 1821, 1826, and
    the Department has never considered it
    necessary for regulated institutions to
    disclose (or hand over to the customer)
    the fx spread. We know this not only from
    the absence of regulations (and
    enforcement actions) but also from the
    testimony in the Rule 23(e) hearing of
    Stanley Cardenas, a former head of the
    Department. California gives substantial
    leeway to agencies in interpreting the
    laws they administer, see Dobbins v. San
    Diego County Civil Service Commission, 
    75 Cal. App. 4th 125
    , 131 (4th Dist. 1999),
    and since the Department’s view
    corresponds to an ordinary-language read
    ing of the statute a claim under this law
    could not do the plaintiffs much good.
    (Plaintiffs responded to Cardenas’s
    testimony with affidavits of legislators
    who supported the statute, but those
    views, offered away from the legislative
    halls and long after the law’s enactment,
    are worthless. See Lindland v. United
    States Wrestling Association, Inc., 
    227 F.3d 1000
    , 1008 (7th Cir. 2000).) Any
    invocation of sec.1810(a) and the rest of
    California’s money-transfer legislation
    would encounter another hurdle: The
    statute does not appear to support a
    private action, except for enforcement of
    a single subsection. See Cal. Fin. Code
    sec.1810.5(c). California respects a
    legislative decision to commit
    enforcement to an agency rather than
    private plaintiffs, see Moradi-Shalal v.
    Fireman’s Fund Insurance Cos., 
    46 Cal. 3d 287
    , 300, 
    758 P.2d 58
    (1988), making it
    hard to see how the class could have used
    sec.1810 and its cousins to advantage.
    The class representatives cannot be
    branded as inadequate on account of their
    decision to abjure reliance on California
    law.
    Let us turn, then, to the adequacy of
    the settlement. This is one of many class
    actions in which everyone other than the
    plaintiffs has been paid in cash. The
    attorneys got cash, the charitable
    organizations got cash, and the customers
    got coupons. That’s enough to raise
    suspicions--especially because coupons
    serve as a form of advertising for the
    defendants, and their effect can be
    offset (in whole or in part) by raising
    prices during the period before the
    coupons expire. Maybe class actions would
    be prosecuted more vigorously if the
    class and class counsel had to accept the
    same coin. But the objectors do not say
    that the lawyers have been overpaid; they
    say that the customers have been
    underpaid. And that contention cannot be
    evaluated by stopping with the fact that
    compensation in kind is worth less than
    cash of the same nominal value. (Coupons
    are stand-ins for the wire transfer
    service, making them a form of in-kind
    payment.) Instead one must ask whether
    the value of relief in the aggregate is a
    reasonable approximation of the value of
    plaintiffs’ claim. Prospective relief to
    which the defendants have agreed will
    alert class members to the fx spread and
    promote competition that may drive the
    retail price of pesos closer to the
    interbank price; that is not an outcome
    to be sneered at. And the coupons, too,
    have value.
    Not the $400 million face value, surely.
    Experts estimated that about half of the
    coupons would be claimed, and 20% to 30%
    of those claimed would be used, implying
    a net value of $40 million to $60
    million. That conclusion is supported by
    the analysis of other coupon settlements
    and some survey research exploring the
    likely behavior of this class. Persons
    who transfer money to Mexico do so an
    average of 14 times annually, providing
    ample opportunities to use the coupons
    independent of their effect in
    stimulating demand. The coupons can be
    used throughout a 35-month period, and,
    because they are transferable, even class
    members who do not again use defendants’
    services may obtain some value (if not by
    selling them, then by giving them to rel
    atives).
    Were the class’s claims worth more than
    $40 million, plus the cy pres relief,
    plus the value of the injunction? Like
    the district court, we think not--indeed,
    we think that the claims had only
    nuisance value (including their value in
    generating bad public relations for the
    defendants). This settlement is more in
    the nature of a PR gesture, coupled with
    a goal of freedom from a drumbeat of
    litigation (similar suits have been filed
    in many state and federal courts across
    the nation), than an exchange of money
    (or coupons) for the release of valuable
    legal rights. No state or federal law
    requires either currency exchanges or
    wire-transfer firms to disclose the
    interbank rate at which they buy specie,
    as opposed to the retail rate at which
    they sell currency (and the retail price
    is invariably disclosed). That is why the
    plaintiffs have been driven to make
    generic fraud claims. But since when is
    failure to disclose the precise
    difference between wholesale and retail
    prices for any commodity "fraud"?
    Money is just a commodity in an
    international market. See Dunn v. CFTC,
    
    519 U.S. 465
    (1997). Pesos are for sale--
    at one price for those who buy in bulk
    (parcels of $5 million or more) and at
    another, higher price for those who buy
    at retail and must compensate the
    middlemen for the expense of holding an
    inventory, providing retail outlets,
    keeping records, ensuring that the
    recipient is the one designated by the
    sender, and so on. Neiman Marcus does not
    tell customers what it paid for the
    clothes they buy, nor need an auto dealer
    reveal rebates and incentives it receives
    to sell cars. This is true in financial
    markets no less than markets for physical
    goods. The customer of a bank’s foreign-
    exchange section (or an airport’s
    currency kiosk) is quoted a retail rate,
    not a wholesale rate, and must turn to
    the newspapers or the Internet to
    determine how much the bank has marked up
    its Swiss Francs or Indian Rupees. The
    holder of a checking account may be
    promised a small interest rate (say, 2%)
    on the balance and is not told at what
    rate the bank lends these funds to its
    own customers. Nor need the bank, or an
    intermediary such as MoneyGram, explain
    to customers how it profits from the
    float on funds it holds for a day or two
    between receipt and delivery. MoneyGram
    and Western Union revealed truthfully,
    and separately, the exchange rate they
    offered (the price per peso) and the rate
    for the wire transfer to Mexico.
    Eachcustomer was told how many dollars in
    the United States would result in how
    many pesos delivered in Mexico. Nothing
    in this transaction smacks of fraud, so
    the settlement cannot be attacked as too
    low.
    Affirmed