Joseph Baldi v. Samuel Son & Company Limited ( 2008 )


Menu:
  •                                In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    Nos. 08-1022, 08-1136
    JOSEPH A. B ALDI, et al.,
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    v.
    S AMUEL S ON & C OMPANY, L TD., et al.,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    Appeals from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of Illinois, Eastern Division.
    No. 05 C 2990—Rebecca R. Pallmeyer, Judge.
    A RGUED S EPTEMBER 24, 2008—D ECIDED N OVEMBER 24, 2008
    Before P OSNER, W OOD , and T INDER, Circuit Judges.
    P OSNER, Circuit Judge. The trustee in bankruptcy (we
    simplify—actually there are two trustees) of a defunct
    firm named Longview Aluminum LLC filed adversary
    actions in bankruptcy court to recover for the debtor’s
    estate several payments that Longview had made
    within four years before it declared bankruptcy. The
    principal basis for the claims and the only one we need
    2                                     Nos. 08-1022, 08-1136
    discuss is 11 U.S.C. § 544(b), which allows a trustee
    in bankruptcy to avoid transfers made by the bankrupt
    that would be voidable under state law if made by an
    unsecured creditor. The Uniform Fraudulent Transfer
    Act, in force in Illinois, allows such avoidance if the
    debtor was insolvent on the date of the transfer and
    received less than a reasonably equivalent value in ex-
    change. UFTA § 5(a); 740 ILCS 160/6(a). Only the first
    requirement is at issue. The corresponding provision of
    the Bankruptcy Code, 11 U.S.C. § 548(a)(1), is materially
    identical except that the federal provision allowed the
    trustee to reach back only one year (since raised to two
    years) before the declaration of bankruptcy, and that
    was too short a period to do anything for the trustee in
    this case.
    Insolvency is defined by both statutes as having a
    balance sheet on which liabilities exceed assets. 11 U.S.C.
    § 101(32)(A); 740 ILCS 160/3(a). The bankruptcy judge
    found that Longview had not been insolvent during the
    period, running from February 26, 2001, to April 1, 2001,
    in which the transfers were made; and the district
    judge affirmed. The trustee had tried only to show that
    Longview was insolvent on both the beginning and
    ending dates, on the assumption that if it was insolvent
    on both dates then probably it was insolvent on the
    dates of the actual transfers, which fell between those
    end points; there is nothing to counter this assumption,
    see Haynes & Hubbard, Inc. v. Stewart, 
    387 F.2d 906
    ,
    908 (5th Cir. 1967), so we accept it. This approach is
    called the “rule of retrojection.” In re Mama D’Angelo, Inc.,
    
    55 F.3d 552
    , 554 (10th Cir. 1995); Briden v. Foley, 776
    Nos. 08-1022, 08-1136                                     
    3 F.2d 379
    , 382-83 (1st Cir. 1985). The question is whether
    Longview was insolvent at the beginning of the transfer
    period.
    A company named Michigan Avenue Partners, LLC
    (we’ll call it “MAP”) decided to enter the aluminum
    industry, and did so by acquiring among other properties
    the Longview aluminum manufacturing plant, jointly
    owned by Alcoa and Reynolds Metals, in Washington
    state. A subsidiary of MAP had brought an antitrust suit
    against Alcoa and Reynolds that had eventuated in an
    order forcing the divestiture of the plant—a Pyrrhic
    victory for antitrust, for the result of the divestiture, as
    we are about to see, was a reduction in the output of
    aluminum.
    MAP paid $140 million for Longview. But it did not
    have to dig into its own pockets for the money. The
    manufacture of aluminum requires large amounts of
    electricity; and Longview’s electricity supplier, the
    Bonneville Power Administration (an agency within the
    Department of the Interior), desperate to be able to con-
    tinue serving its most necessitous customers in a period
    of electricity shortage, paid Longview Aluminum LLC
    $226 million to cease buying electricity for the next
    16 months. Longview planned to use the $226 million
    not only to pay the purchase price of the plant but also
    to enable it to resume manufacturing aluminum at the
    end of this “curtailment” period, as the parties call it.
    Among the costs it would incur to resume would be
    some $33 million in union wage payments, and this
    was recorded as a liability on Longview’s balance sheet
    4                                     Nos. 08-1022, 08-1136
    when the company was formed on February 26, 2001.
    The balance sheet showed assets of $248 million and
    liabilities of $206 million.
    Longview never did resume operations. By the end of
    the 16-month curtailment period, falling prices for alumi-
    num and rising prices for electricity had made the pro-
    duction of aluminum from the plant uneconomical. The
    firm declared bankruptcy. (Its plant was ultimately dis-
    mantled.) But although it is a fair guess that Longview
    was insolvent before the curtailment period ended, the
    trustee’s expert—and essentially his only source of evi-
    dence—Brooks D. Myhran (a business consultant who
    specializes in the valuation of companies), did not
    attempt to determine at what point during that period
    Longview became insolvent. The trustee pitched his
    entire case on showing that Longview had been insolvent
    from the beginning, that is, from February 26, 2001.
    Now it is very strange to suppose a start-up company
    bankrupt from the day of its formation. Especially this
    start-up. Why would experienced businessmen, which
    the principals of MAP were, pay $140 million for a firm
    that had negative value? There is no suggestion that
    Longview had significant liquidation value, should it
    never resume operations. So MAP must have thought
    that Longview would resume operations, or at least had
    a good enough chance of doing so to make the company
    worth at least $140 million. Of course many start-ups fail,
    but if a significant probability of failure sufficed to pro-
    nounce a start-up insolvent, how would any start-up
    finance its operations? Its trade creditors would fear
    Nos. 08-1022, 08-1136                                        5
    being trapped by sections 544 or 548 of the Bankruptcy
    Code when they were paid by the start-up for supplies
    that they had furnished it. The trustee thinks it a killer
    point that Longview did not have any operating income
    when it started up. Well, of course not; no start-up starts
    with an income flow.
    The pitfalls of hindsight are especially acute in dealing
    with a start-up. As we said, start-ups often fail. When one
    fails, it is easy enough to find an expert who will opine
    that it was certain to fail from the very start. Such facile
    proof should rarely be accepted, and it was rightly
    rejected in this case.
    To establish Longview’s insolvency at its starting date,
    Myhran jacked up its liabilities from the $206 million
    shown on the company’s balance sheet to $367 million. He
    did this by adding contingent liabilities, including a
    contingent pension liability, contingent post-retirement
    benefit obligations, contingent severance payments, and
    the penalty provision in a take-or-pay contract with
    Bonneville. Contingent liabilities are—contingent. “By
    definition, a contingent liability is not certain—and often
    is highly unlikely—ever to become an actual liability. To
    value the contingent liability it is necessary to discount
    it by the probability that the contingency will occur and
    the liability become real.” In re Xonics Photochemicals,
    Inc., 
    841 F.2d 198
    , 199 (7th Cir. 1988); see, e.g., Freeland v.
    Enodis Corp., 
    540 F.3d 721
    , 730 (7th Cir. 2008); In re Chase &
    Sanborn Corp., 
    904 F.2d 588
    , 594 (11th Cir. 1990). Myhran
    treated Longview’s contingent liabilities as certainties.
    That invalidated his expert opinion. In re Wallace’s Book-
    6                                       Nos. 08-1022, 08-1136
    stores, Inc., 
    316 B.R. 254
    , 260-62 (Bkrtcy. E.D. Ky. 2004); see
    FDIC v. Bell, 
    106 F.3d 258
    , 264-65 (8th Cir. 1997).
    The pension liability was not Longview’s liability; it
    was the liability of companies affiliated with Longview.
    It would become Longview’s liability only if the
    affiliates defaulted on their pension obligations, and
    Myhran offered no estimate of the probability of such
    an event. The take-or-pay provision required Longview
    to pay some $20 million to Bonneville in the event that
    Longview did not reopen and therefore did not buy
    electricity from Bonneville after the curtailment period.
    Most of the other liabilities that Myhran treated as
    certain were similarly contingent on Longview’s never
    resuming production. That was a risk, of course, but not
    a certainty; Myhran made no effort to discount the risk
    by the probability that it would materialize.
    It is true, as explained in Covey v. Commercial National
    Bank, 
    960 F.2d 657
    , 660 (7th Cir. 1992), that discounting
    a contingent liability can result in overstating a debtor’s
    net assets. That is the case when the contingency is not
    whether there will be liability but whether the debtor
    will be able to pay it. If the debtor owed a creditor
    $1 million, but the probability of the creditor’s being able
    to collect the debt was only 10 percent, the creditor’s
    claim would be worth only $100,000 but the debtor’s
    liability, for purposes of calculating its solvency when
    it assumed the debt, would still be $1 million. But that is
    not this case. The contingency was the probability
    that there would be a liability, not that it would be
    uncollectible. See In re Advanced Telecommunication
    Nos. 08-1022, 08-1136                                        7
    Network, Inc., 
    490 F.3d 1325
    , 1334-36 (11th Cir. 2007); Office
    & Professional Employees Int’l Union v. FDIC, 
    27 F.3d 598
    ,
    601-02 (D.C. Cir. 1994). “To decide whether a firm is
    insolvent within the meaning of § 548(a)(2)(B)(i), a court
    should ask: What would a buyer be willing to pay for
    the debtor’s entire package of assets and liabilities? If
    the price is positive, the firm is solvent; if negative, insol-
    vent.” Covey v. Commercial National 
    Bank, supra
    , 960 F.2d
    at 660. Longview’s package of liabilities included some
    that might never materialize, so that to calculate the
    expected cost of the package Myhran would have had
    to estimate the probability that they would materialize.
    In order to depress the appearance of Longview’s
    solvency further, Myhran projected that electricity costs
    would increase (as in fact they did) and prevent the
    plant from resuming operations. There were of course
    pessimists who in February 2001 were predicting a con-
    tinued rise in electricity prices, and Longview was taking
    a risk in guessing otherwise. But all businesses are at
    risk of future changes in supply or demand that cannot
    be predicted with any certainty; that does not make
    them insolvent.
    We could go on whacking Myhran’s evidence, but
    there is no need. It was radically unconvincing, as the
    bankruptcy judge, seconded by the district judge,
    found. Likewise unconvincing is the trustee’s alternative
    ground for avoidance, which is that Longview was
    “undercapitalized.” Undercapitalization is not a
    synonym for insolvency. Moody v. Security Pacific Business
    Credit, Inc., 
    971 F.2d 1056
    , 1069-71 (3d. Cir. 1992). By way
    8                                     Nos. 08-1022, 08-1136
    of an up-to-date example, suppose a bank is very
    heavily leveraged—that is, it has a very high ratio of
    borrowed money to equity. It lends out the borrowed
    money, and as long as the borrowers pay on time it is
    fine. If many of them default, however, the present value
    of the bank’s revenues may dip below what it owes
    its depositors and other lenders, and if so then without
    an adequate equity cushion the bank will go broke. But
    until the defaults reach the point at which its liabil-
    ities exceed its assets, the bank will be solvent. So
    “undercapitalization,” which should rather be termed
    excessive leverage, while it increases the risk of
    insolvency, is not insolvency and does not require
    separate consideration in a bankruptcy case.
    This case is different from our bank hypothetical
    because there was not merely a risk but a certainty that
    there would be a period in which the firm’s costs would
    exceed its revenues, and it needed a capital cushion to
    survive that period. Concretely, Longview had to have
    enough capital to be able to maintain the aluminum
    plant until the end of the curtailment period and then to
    reopen it and operate it until substantial revenue
    started flowing into its coffers. Its balance sheet indicated
    that it had enough capital for these purposes.
    A FFIRMED.
    11-24-08