Kleen Products LLC v. RockTenn CP, LLC , 831 F.3d 919 ( 2016 )


Menu:
  •                                In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    ____________________
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    KLEEN PRODUCTS LLC, et al.,
    Plaintiffs-Appellees,
    v.
    INTERNATIONAL PAPER COMPANY, et al.,
    Defendants-Appellants.
    ____________________
    Appeals from the United States District Court for the
    Northern District of Illinois, Eastern Division.
    No. 10 C 5711 — Harry D. Leinenweber, Judge.
    ____________________
    ARGUED DECEMBER 8, 2015 — DECIDED AUGUST 4, 2016
    ____________________
    Before WOOD, Chief Judge, and BAUER and WILLIAMS, Cir-
    cuit Judges.
    WOOD, Chief Judge. The antitrust laws prohibit competing
    economic actors from colluding to agree on prices, either di-
    rectly or through such mechanisms as output restrictions. See
    United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 
    310 U.S. 150
    (1940);
    Palmer v. BRG of Georgia, Inc., 
    498 U.S. 46
    (1990). That is just
    what the plaintiffs in the case before us allege the producers
    and sellers of containerboard did. The plaintiff-purchasers
    2                                       Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    filed this suit under Sherman Act § 1, 15 U.S.C. § 1, seeking to
    recover treble damages for the overcharges they allegedly
    paid. See Clayton Act § 4, 15 U.S.C. § 15. What brings the case
    before us at this time—well before the merits have been re-
    solved—is the district court’s decision to certify a nationwide
    class of purchasers under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 23.
    The defendants, International Paper Company, Georgia-Pa-
    cific LLC, Temple-Inland Inc., RockTenn CP, LLC, and Weyer-
    hauser Company (to whom we will refer collectively as De-
    fendants unless the context requires otherwise), asked us to
    accept this interlocutory appeal from the certification decision
    pursuant to Rule 23(f). We agreed to do so. Finding no abuse
    of discretion in the district court’s decision, however, we af-
    firm.
    I
    The Purchasers allege in their complaint that the defend-
    ant companies agreed “to restrict the supply of container-
    board by cutting capacity, slowing back production, taking
    downtime, idling plants, and tightly restricting inventory.”
    These actions predictably led to an increase in the price of con-
    tainerboard—a price increase that caused Purchasers to pay
    more for containerboard products than they would have paid
    in the absence of the illegal agreement. The named plaintiff
    on the complaint is Kleen Products LLC. It asked the district
    court to certify the following class:
    All persons that purchased Containerboard Products
    directly from any of the Defendants or their subsidiar-
    ies or affiliates for use or delivery in the United States
    from at least as early as February 15, 2004 through No-
    vember 8, 2010.
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                          3
    The proposed definition carved out the defendants them-
    selves, entities or personnel related to them, and governmen-
    tal entities. The Defendants opposed class certification on a
    number of grounds: whether common questions predomi-
    nate; whether antitrust injury can be proved using a common
    method; whether the amount of damages can be proved using
    a common method; and whether a class action is superior.
    As the Supreme Court emphasized in Wal-Mart Stores, Inc.
    v. Dukes, 
    564 U.S. 338
    (2011), “Rule 23 does not set forth a mere
    pleading standard. A party seeking class certification must af-
    firmatively demonstrate his compliance with the Rule … .” 
    Id. at 350.
    We must therefore take a careful look at the evidence
    that the Purchasers presented in support of class certification
    as we assess the district court’s ruling. Some of that evidence
    was provided by experts, but at this stage we need say little
    about them, because no defendant challenged the Purchasers’
    experts under Federal Rule of Evidence 702 or the Supreme
    Court’s decision in Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharm., Inc., 
    509 U.S. 579
    (1993). See Tyson Foods, Inc. v. Bouaphakeo, 
    136 S. Ct. 1036
    ,
    1049 (2016) (where there is no Daubert challenge, district court
    may rely on expert evidence for class certification). The dis-
    trict court also pointed out that “[f]or the most part, the par-
    ties agree on the basic facts, and both parties’ experts rely
    upon the same data, so there are little if any factual disputes
    that the Court must resolve to decide class certification.” For
    that reason, the court concluded that there was no need for a
    comprehensive evidentiary hearing. This, in our view, was a
    case-management decision that we have no reason to second-
    guess, despite Defendants’ complaints. See American Honda
    Motor Co. v. Allen, 
    600 F.3d 813
    , 815 (7th Cir. 2010) (evidentiary
    hearing should be held “if necessary”); West v. Prudential Sec.,
    Inc., 
    282 F.3d 935
    , 938 (7th Cir. 2002) (same).
    4                                        Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    Two final points are worth making before we turn to the
    evidence. First, nothing in Wal-Mart changed the applicable
    standard of review, which is deferential (as the cases say, only
    for “abuse of discretion”). Messner v. Northshore Univ.
    HealthSystem, 
    669 F.3d 802
    , 811 (7th Cir. 2012). Second, it re-
    mains true that Rule 23 does not demand that every issue be
    common; classes are routinely certified under Rule 23(b)(3)
    where common questions exist and predominate, even
    though other individual issues will remain after the class
    phase. See, e.g., McMahon v. LVNV Funding, 
    807 F.3d 872
    , 875–
    76 (7th Cir. 2015); Pella Corp. v. Saltzman, 
    606 F.3d 391
    , 393 (7th
    Cir. 2010).
    II
    Although the requirements for class certification under
    Rule 23 are familiar, we set out the critical sections of the rule
    here for ease of reference:
    (a) Prerequisites. One or more members of a class
    may sue or be sued as representative parties on behalf
    of all members only if:
    (1) the class is so numerous that joinder of all
    members is impracticable;
    (2) there are questions of law or fact common to
    the class;
    (3) the claims or defenses of the representative
    parties are typical of the claims or defenses of
    the class; and
    (4) the representative parties will fairly and ad-
    equately protect the interests of the class.
    ***
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                         5
    (b) Types of Class Actions. A class action may be
    maintained if Rule 23(a) is satisfied and if:
    ***
    (3) the court finds that the questions of law or
    fact common to class members predominate
    over any questions affecting only individual
    members, and that a class action is superior to
    other available methods for fairly and efficiently
    adjudicating the controversy. The matters perti-
    nent to these findings include:
    (A) the class members’ interests in indi-
    vidually controlling the prosecution or
    defense of separate actions;
    (B) the extent and nature of any litigation
    concerning the controversy already be-
    gun by or against class members;
    (C) the desirability or undesirability of
    concentrating the litigation of the claims
    in the particular forum; and
    (D) the likely difficulties in managing a
    class action.
    Our focus is on the predominance requirement of subpart
    (b)(3), since, as the district court noted, “Defendants have con-
    ceded that typicality, commonality, and adequacy have been
    satisfied so long as [Purchasers] have adequately proven pre-
    dominance,” and no one is arguing about numbers either.
    A
    We begin with some background facts about the contain-
    erboard industry. “Containerboard” is the term for a sheet of
    6                                          Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    heavy paper with a smooth top and bottom (the linerboard)
    and a fluted layer between the two (the corrugated medium).
    It is made in large, expensive mills; as of 2008, no new mills
    had been built in the United States for more than 12 years. The
    containerboard sheets are cut and folded into products such
    as boxes of varying sizes. The industry is dominated by verti-
    cally integrated producers, which means simply that the fab-
    rication of the containerboard and then its processing into fi-
    nal products are handled internally by a firm. This means, im-
    portantly for antitrust purposes, that the Purchasers bought
    directly from the alleged conspirators, not through interme-
    diaries. See Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 
    431 U.S. 720
    (1977) (dis-
    tinguishing between direct-purchaser suits, which are permit-
    ted under Clayton Act § 4, and indirect-purchaser suits, which
    are not).
    Containerboard is a commodity, sold in standardized
    compositions and weights. The final products are also stand-
    ardized; one trade association commented that “boxes are es-
    sentially commodity items used in well established markets.”
    The most common containerboard product sold in the United
    States in 2010 was unbleached kraft linerboard weighing 42
    pounds per thousand square feet. Pulp & Paper Week (PPW),
    an industry periodical, publishes weekly price indices that in-
    clude the price for the 42-pound linerboard for delivery east
    of the Rocky Mountains. The PPW index, as it is called, is
    widely used within the industry as a benchmark.
    A small and shrinking number of firms produce most of
    the containerboard in North America. As of 1997, the five
    largest firms (i.e. the current defendants or their predecessors)
    were responsible for 41% of North American production. By
    2007, the Defendants furnished 74% of that production. Add
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                         7
    in the next two firms, and the number swelled to 84%. (This
    evidence is ambiguous: a cartel’s market share will shrink
    over time, to the extent that the high prices attract new entry
    from fringe competitors or imports, but its market share will
    grow to the extent that the cartel successfully uses exclusion-
    ary devices. The existing record does not resolve that ambigu-
    ity, but it does not matter for purposes of class certification.)
    There was a great deal of evidence designed to show that
    the hypothesis that Defendants had organized a cartel was
    one that a jury could accept. We do not need to review all of
    it, but we offer some key points. During the class period,
    which ran from February 15, 2004, through November 8, 2010,
    Defendants attempted 15 price increases, and with one excep-
    tion, all Defendants joined each one, at roughly the same time
    (11 out of 15 times within the same month). Twelve times out
    of 15 they increased prices by identical amounts; the remain-
    ing times the increases of different firms varied by less than
    2% of the average price.
    Capacity in the industry over this period was declining in
    North America, though increasing elsewhere; meanwhile, de-
    mand was constant or increasing. Defendants increased
    prices at least once during the recession of 2008 and 2009, and
    they raised prices again twice in 2010. Inventory levels were
    decreasing, because of several steps they took: they closed
    many mills; they indefinitely idled some; they temporarily
    idled others; and they slowed down production. In 2005, they
    announced mill closures representing 931,000 tons of capac-
    ity, and shortly thereafter they raised prices $30/ton. They did
    much the same thing in 2009. Communication among the De-
    fendants was easy, thanks to trade associations.
    8                                      Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    These and other facts spurred the Purchasers to bring this
    suit and to structure it as a class action. They filed their mo-
    tion for class certification only after extensive discovery. In
    that motion, they relied on the type of industry facts we have
    just mentioned, as well as on reports from two experts, Mi-
    chael J. Harris and Mark Joseph Dwyer. Defendants coun-
    tered with reports from two other experts, Dennis Carlton and
    Janusz Ordover. Harris concluded that the structure of the
    containerboard industry made it likely that a conspiracy
    among the Defendants could succeed in increasing prices for
    all or nearly all purchasers; he also opined that Defendants’
    strategy would not have made sense if it had been undertaken
    unilaterally by each company. Carlton and Ordover disa-
    greed, contending that Defendants’ pricing behavior could be
    explained by oligopolistic interdependence (that is, by paral-
    lel but independent behavior undertaken by firms in a con-
    centrated market). They suggested ways in which the supply
    restrictions might have been rational under the circum-
    stances. Tellingly, however, they never said that there might
    have been a cartel with respect to some purchasers and not
    with respect to others.
    On the subject of damages, Purchasers’ expert Dwyer ex-
    amined price movements. For example, he compared the ac-
    tual prices paid by a sample of class members before and after
    the Defendants’ price increases and found that in 92% of cases
    those prices increased. He also constructed a regression
    model to estimate the overcharges made possible by the con-
    spiracy. That model indicated that the class paid overcharges
    of approximately 3.08%, or in dollar terms, approximately
    $3.8 billion too much. Defendants’ experts criticized the sam-
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                         9
    ple size that Harris had used, and they asserted that Purchas-
    ers’ experts had failed adequately to account for external fac-
    tors influencing price and capacity.
    B
    The district court began its analysis of predominance—the
    central disputed issue in the case—by recalling the Supreme
    Court’s statement in Amchem Products, Inc. v. Windsor, 
    521 U.S. 591
    (1997), that “[t]he Rule 23(b)(3) predominance inquiry
    tests whether proposed classes are sufficiently cohesive to
    warrant adjudication by representation.” 
    Id. at 623.
    It also
    acknowledged that, as the Supreme Court puts it, “Rule
    23(b)(3)’s predominance criterion is even more demanding
    than Rule 23(a).” Comcast Corp. v. Behrend, 
    133 S. Ct. 1426
    , 1432
    (2013). Predominance is satisfied when “common questions
    represent a significant aspect of a case and … can be resolved
    for all members of a class in a single adjudication.” 
    Messner, 669 F.3d at 815
    (internal quotation marks omitted); see also
    
    Wal-Mart, 564 U.S. at 350
    (a common contention for Rule
    23(a)(2) purposes “must be of such a nature that it is capable
    of classwide resolution—which means that determination of
    its truth or falsity will resolve an issue that is central to the
    validity of each one of the claims in one stroke”). With those
    principles in mind, the court evaluated the two central ele-
    ments of the Purchasers’ case: the alleged violation of the an-
    titrust laws, and the causal link between that violation and
    their alleged injury. It set the question of damages to one side,
    noting that “it is well established that the presence of individ-
    ualized questions regarding damages does not prevent certi-
    fication under Rule 23(b)(3).” 
    Messner, 669 F.3d at 815
    (citing
    
    Wal-Mart, 564 U.S. at 362
    (“individualized monetary claims
    belong in Rule 23(b)(3)”)).
    10                                        Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    With respect to proof of liability, the court had this to say:
    To prove each element of a conspiracy, virtually all
    class members would be relying on the same evidence
    that Plaintiffs have submitted in support of class certi-
    fication—namely, the documents, emails, phone rec-
    ords, and other indirect evidence necessary to prove
    that Defendants conspired in violation of antitrust
    laws. … [I]t is much more efficient to have a single trial
    on the alleged conspiracy rather than thousands of
    identical trials all alleging identical conspiracies based
    on identical evidence.
    While acknowledging that Defendants hotly contested the
    conspiracy allegation, the court found that their arguments
    went to the merits, not to the suitability of the case for class
    treatment.
    Turning to causation, to which it also referred as “antitrust
    impact,” the court rejected the Defendants’ effort to equate
    this case to Comcast, where the Supreme Court found a mis-
    match between the plaintiffs’ damages theory and the evi-
    dence they presented to show predominance. First, on the
    question of impact, defined as whether Purchasers were
    harmed, the court found that at the class-certification stage
    the plaintiffs needed to demonstrate that the element of im-
    pact is capable of class-wide proof at trial, through evidence
    common to all class members. Looking at all the evidence, the
    court found this element satisfied. For example, the Defend-
    ants’ price increases were not tailored to each individual pur-
    chaser; this was a commodity market with a structure condu-
    cive to collusion; communications took place at a high level;
    the common use of the PPW index affected all market partic-
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                        11
    ipants; and the Defendants lacked any other reasonable expla-
    nation for the tight correlation between the index and their
    announcements of price increases.
    With respect to damages, the court found that the Purchas-
    ers had the burden of producing a reliable method of measur-
    ing classwide damages based on common proof. It rejected
    the Defendants’ argument that the eventual need to examine
    each individual purchaser’s damages was enough to defeat a
    finding of predominance. Nothing in Comcast, the court said,
    requires a different outcome. As this court noted in In re IKO
    Roofing Shingle Products Liability Litigation, 
    757 F.3d 599
    (7th
    Cir. 2014), the plaintiffs’ damages expert in Comcast had esti-
    mated harm based on the assumption that all four theories of
    liability that plaintiffs offered had been established. The class
    certified by the court, however, was limited to only one of
    those theories. This, we explained, is what the Supreme Court
    said, “made class treatment inappropriate: without a theory
    of loss that matched the theory of liability, the class could not
    get anywhere.” 
    Id. at 602.
    With that point established, the
    court assessed Dwyer’s report, concluded that both the meth-
    odology and the data were reliable, and concluded that it
    could be used to demonstrate class-wide damages.
    Finally, the court held that Purchasers had shown the su-
    periority of proceeding under Rule 23(b)(3). The fact that
    some class members had signed releases as a part of a settle-
    ment of an earlier class action (dealing with an alleged liner-
    board conspiracy that took place between 1993 and 1995) did
    not require a contrary finding. As the court said,
    [t]he conduct at issue in the prior litigation was De-
    fendants’ allegedly collusive behavior in the mid-nine-
    ties. The actions at issue here are coordinated market
    12                                      Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    manipulation and price-increase announcements that
    occurred nearly a decade later. … Under Defendants’
    argument, they are free to keep colluding in violation
    of antitrust laws so long as they conspire in the same
    way as they were alleged to have behaved in a prior
    settled case. The Court is unaware of any case support-
    ing this argument; indeed, several cases are to the con-
    trary.
    The court also rejected similar arguments based on particular
    contractual provisions, and it decided that retaining defend-
    ant Rock-Tenn in the case would not violate its bankruptcy
    discharge.
    C
    1
    We follow the same general outline that the district court
    used, looking first at predominance and then at superiority.
    Within predominance, we consider two points: whether com-
    mon methods of proof can be used to demonstrate the exist-
    ence of the alleged collusion and its effect on prices in the con-
    tainerboard market; and whether the existence and impact of
    any such collusion predominate over other factors that may
    affect an individual plaintiff’s damages. These inquiries apply
    to all defendants. Defendant RockTenn raises some additional
    arguments related to its bankruptcy; we address these at the
    close of the opinion.
    In order to secure class certification, the Purchasers had to
    demonstrate (not merely allege) that there is proof common
    to all class members, and that this proof would show that they
    suffered “injuries that reflect the anticompetitive effect of ei-
    ther the violation or the anticompetitive acts made possible by
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                         13
    the violation.” James Cape & Sons Co. v. PCC Const. Co., 
    453 F.3d 396
    , 399 (7th Cir. 2006); see Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-
    Mat, Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    (1977).
    Purchasers tendered extensive evidence that, if believed,
    would be enough to prove the existence of the alleged con-
    spiracy. Not surprisingly, it is largely circumstantial. But they
    offered voluminous written materials of various types, which
    in the aggregate pointed to the existence of both agreement
    and actions to violate the antitrust laws. Indeed, Defendants
    do not contest that the existence of the conspiracy could be
    (perhaps had to be) proven by evidence common to the class.
    The more difficult question (though not too difficult in the
    end) is whether the common evidence could show the fact of
    injury on a classwide basis. See 
    Messner, 669 F.3d at 819
    (“The
    ability to use such common evidence and common methodol-
    ogy to prove a class’s claims is sufficient to support a finding
    of predominance on the issue of antitrust impact for certifica-
    tion under Rule 23(b)(3).”). At base, Defendants argue that it
    is not enough for Purchasers to prove aggregate injury and
    one aggregate overcharge, without allocating how much of
    that overcharge was paid by each individual class member.
    They urge that Purchasers have the burden of showing that
    every class member must prove at least some impact from the
    alleged violation. For that proposition, they rely on In re Hy-
    drogen Peroxide Antitrust Litigation, 
    552 F.3d 305
    , 311 (3d Cir.
    2008), and In re Rail Freight Fuel Surcharge Antitrust Litigation,
    
    725 F.3d 244
    , 252 (D.C. Cir. 2013).
    While we have no quarrel with the proposition that each
    and every class member would need to make such a showing
    in order ultimately to recover, we have not insisted on this
    level of proof at the class certification stage. To the contrary,
    14                                       Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    we said in Suchanek v. Sturm Foods, Inc., 
    764 F.3d 750
    (7th Cir.
    2014), that “[i]f the [district] court thought that no class can be
    certified until proof exists that every member has been
    harmed, it was wrong.” 
    Id. at 757;
    see also Parko v. Shell Oil
    Co., 
    739 F.3d 1083
    , 1084–85 (7th Cir. 2014); McReynolds v. Mer-
    rill Lynch, Pierce, Fenner & Smith, Inc., 
    672 F.3d 482
    , 491 (7th
    Cir. 2012). There is no evidence to make us think that the class
    defined by the district court either excludes too many pur-
    chasers or contains troublesome internal conflicts, either of
    which would indicate it should be rejected. We therefore
    move on to the adequacy of the Purchasers’ showing that the
    conspiracy had an effect on the prices they paid.
    The parties have jousted over the need for some kind of
    “but-for” analysis, by which Defendants mean an expert con-
    struction of a hypothetical market free of any anticompetitive
    restraint, to which the actual market can be compared. See
    Blades v. Monsanto Co., 
    400 F.3d 562
    , 569 (8th Cir. 2005). That
    might be one way in which a plaintiff could satisfy its burden,
    but we think that the formulation is too narrow. What is es-
    sential is whether the class can point to common proof that
    will establish antitrust injury (in the form of cartel pricing
    here) on a classwide basis. Like the district court, we are sat-
    isfied that Purchasers have done so.
    The Purchasers built up their case with several types of
    evidence. First, expert Harris’s report showed that the struc-
    ture of the containerboard market was conducive to success-
    ful collusion. He pointed to the concentration of manufactur-
    ers; the vertical integration of the market; the capital-intensive
    manufacturing process (which affected the pace and likeli-
    hood of new entry); weak competition from imported con-
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                          15
    tainerboard; no good substitutes for the product; a low elas-
    ticity of demand; and a standardized, commodity product.
    These are all well accepted characteristics of a market that is
    subject to cartelization. See, e.g., In re Text Messaging Antitrust
    Litig., 
    782 F.3d 867
    , 872 (7th Cir. 2015); Minn-Chem, Inc. v.
    Agrium, Inc., 
    683 F.3d 845
    , 859–60 (7th Cir. 2012) (en banc); In
    re High Fructose Corn Syrup Litig., 
    295 F.3d 651
    , 657 (7th Cir.
    2002); Jack Walters & Sons Corp. v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 
    737 F.2d 698
    , 710–11 (7th Cir. 1984).
    Defendants pooh-pooh these cases as examples of the dis-
    credited structure-conduct-performance (SCP) paradigm that
    ruled antitrust from the 1950s until the mid-1970s. See, e.g.,
    United States v. Von’s Grocery Co., 
    384 U.S. 270
    (1966) (striking
    down a merger between a firm with 4.7% of the market and a
    firm with 4.2%). We put to one side the fact that the SCP par-
    adigm was used during that era primarily in merger cases and
    this is a cartel case alleging hard-core price-fixing—the kind
    of case in which lack of market power or reasonableness of
    price is no defense. The evidence here goes well beyond the
    structural. The flaw in the old SCP notion was the thought
    that it was enough to know the structure of a market in order
    to predict what kind of conduct would ensue, and how com-
    petitively that market would perform. No such chain of as-
    sumptions taints the Purchasers’ proof. They have shown ac-
    tual price increases, a mechanism for those increases, the com-
    munication channels the conspirators used, and factors sug-
    gesting that cartel discipline can be maintained. We are not
    saying that any of these points have been proven, of course,
    but we are saying that this evidence is enough to support class
    treatment of the merits.
    16                                      Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    Defendants also object to the Purchasers’ definition of the
    market. The Purchasers, they say, have conflated the market
    for containerboard (the material) with the market for finished
    corrugated products. The district court responded that the
    uniform vertical integration found in this industry makes it
    appropriate to look to the finished products. That is correct:
    Purchasers (and we) have no reason to dig inside the defend-
    ant companies to evaluate their internal pricing of the raw
    materials they use in producing the boxes and other products
    they sell.
    Next, Defendants criticize Dwyer’s examination of the 15
    price increases they announced and his use of the PPW index
    in that connection. He analyzed “industry-wide reflections of
    price and actual prices paid by class members before and af-
    ter” the price-increase announcements, and he found that
    nine of the 15 efforts succeeded (i.e. resulted in a durable price
    increase). He also performed a regression analysis comparing
    classwide aggregate prices to the PPW index and found that
    “more than 97% of variation in aggregate prices is explained
    by changes in the index.” He reviewed 738 contracts (those
    the Defendants had produced) and found that 96% of them
    “contained provisions that tied pricing to the PPW index.”
    The Defendants protest that the Purchasers have shown only
    correlation, not causation, but we think, taking into account
    the rest of the evidence, Purchasers have not fallen into that
    trap.
    Defendants also argue that Dwyer’s approach is the same
    kind of “trial-by-formula” that the Supreme Court rejected in
    Wal-Mart. But in that case the Court disapproved the plain-
    tiff’s attempt to take a sample of the class members, who al-
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                          17
    leged employment discrimination, to determine what per-
    centage of that sample had actually experienced discrimina-
    tion, and then to extrapolate that percentage for the whole
    class. The Purchasers here are doing nothing of the sort: they
    assert that every person or entity in North America paid the
    overcharges that resulted from Defendants’ collusive prac-
    tices. Even for transactions where prices were negotiated in-
    dividually or a longer term contract existed, the district court
    found, reasonably, that the “starting point for those negotia-
    tions would be higher if the market price for the product was
    artificially inflated.”
    We have already discussed the Purchasers’ common proof
    of damages, but we add a few more words here to respond to
    the Defendants’ Comcast arguments. Defendants understand
    Comcast to hold that “individualized damages do foreclose
    predominance if plaintiffs present no classwide method to ad-
    judicate damages tethered to their theory of antitrust viola-
    tions and if resolving those individualized damages issues
    would ‘overwhelm questions common to the class.’” Brief for
    Appellants at 36 
    (quoting 133 S. Ct. at 1433
    ). We agree with
    Defendants that Comcast insists that the damages theory must
    correspond to the theory of liability, but that is all Comcast said
    that is pertinent to our case. We must see if there is a classwide
    method for proving damages, and if not, whether individual
    damage determinations will overwhelm the common ques-
    tions on liability and impact.
    Dwyer conducted a preliminary analysis to demonstrate
    the feasibility of estimating damages on a classwide basis. He
    created two categories of products, intermediate and final,
    and he used two benchmark periods (before and after the
    class period) to compare prices. He also accounted for many
    18                                       Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    other variables, such as downstream demand, production and
    delivery, inflation, and seasonal factors, in order to control for
    other influences on price and to isolate the impact of the con-
    spiracy. Using a “dummy variable,” he calculated an average
    overcharge of 2.92% for the final products category and 3.81%
    for the intermediate products category. He then multiplied
    the average overcharges by the dollar amount of purchases by
    class members, subtracting purchases that had taken place
    under previously contracted prices. He found that the class
    members paid $801.27 million more for intermediate prod-
    ucts and $2.991 billion more for final products than they
    would have absent the conspiracy.
    Defendants complain that it is wrong to calculate aggre-
    gate rather than individual damages for the class. The district
    court rejected that position as a matter of law, as do we. We
    held in Loeb Indus., Inc. v. Sumitomo Corp., 
    306 F.3d 469
    (7th Cir.
    2002), that plaintiffs are permitted to use estimates and anal-
    ysis to calculate a reasonable approximation of their damages.
    
    Id. at 493.
    And we already have confirmed that at the class
    certification stage, plaintiffs are not obliged to drill down and
    estimate each individual class member’s damages. The deter-
    mination of the aggregate classwide damages is something
    that can be handled most efficiently as a class action, and the
    allocation of that total sum among the class members can be
    managed individually, should the case ever reach that point.
    If in the end the Defendants win on the merits, this entire mat-
    ter will be over in “one fell swoop.” (See WILLIAM
    SHAKESPEARE, MACBETH, act 4, sc. 3, l. 220 (David Bevington
    ed., Pearson Longman 6th ed. 2009.) If Purchasers prevail on
    the common issues, both liability and aggregate damages will
    be resolved. The district court did not commit reversible error
    when it concluded that the class issues predominated.
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                           19
    2
    Everything we have said thus far also points to the supe-
    riority of the class device for this case. We need to address
    only two potential flies in the ointment that Defendants see:
    first, the significance (if any) of certain releases that some class
    members signed; and second, the relevance of contract de-
    fenses that might apply.
    Some class members settled claims in an earlier lawsuit
    against the same companies, dealing with the same industry.
    Defendants represent that there are 39 relevant settlement
    agreements implicating almost 10,000 of the individual claims
    at issue. The Purchasers respond that these numbers are
    wrong, because they involve double-counting and give an ex-
    aggerated impression of the real number of affected class
    members, since most people who signed releases did so with
    multiple defendants. More importantly, Purchasers also note
    that the Defendants’ numbers imply that most people who
    signed releases did so after the events giving rise to the pre-
    sent case, whereas in reality the releases are heavily distrib-
    uted toward the beginning of the class period or earlier. Pur-
    chasers suggest the simple expedient of limiting the recovery
    period for any class member who signed a release to pur-
    chases made after that release was signed. That strikes us as
    an easy and effective way to handle this problem. Moreover,
    as the district court observed, the fact that some plaintiffs re-
    leased the defendants from further liability for their actions in
    the mid-1990s is not a life-time inoculation against antitrust
    liability in the same industry.
    The other contract defenses to which Defendants point in-
    volve such provisions as mandatory arbitration and media-
    tion clauses, forum-selection clauses, jury waivers, provisions
    20                                     Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386
    shortening the statute of limitations, and clauses eliminating
    remedies such as treble damages. Taking these limitations
    into account, they say, will destroy the cohesion of the class.
    The problem is that Defendants are relying on a case that in-
    volved a class-action waiver: Lozano v. AT&T Wireless Services,
    Inc., 
    504 F.3d 718
    , 728 (7th Cir. 2007), and there is no such
    waiver here. The Purchasers point out that Defendants have
    identified only 190 class members affected by this group of
    limitations, out of over 100,000 notices that were sent out pur-
    suant to Rule 23(c)(2)(B). As the record stands, this smattering
    of individual contract defenses does not undermine the supe-
    riority of the (b)(3) class action.
    III
    We noted earlier that defendant RockTenn is in a different
    position from the other defendants, because it filed for bank-
    ruptcy and received a discharge on June 30, 2010, approxi-
    mately four months before the end of the class period. The
    district court refused to dismiss RockTenn on that basis be-
    cause it found evidence that RockTenn re-joined the conspir-
    acy after the discharge. (For example, on the very evening of
    the day when the discharge order was entered, RockTenn’s
    president sent an email stating “I assume we are announcing
    tomorrow,” after three other defendants announced a simul-
    taneous price increase.) The court also found that RockTenn
    might be jointly and severally liable for actions undertaken by
    its co-conspirators before the discharge, based on its post-dis-
    charge participation. See Havoco of Am., Ltd. v. Shell Oil Co.,
    
    626 F.2d 549
    , 554 (7th Cir. 1980) (“[A] co-conspirator who joins
    a conspiracy with knowledge of what has gone on before and
    Nos. 15-2385 & 15-2386                                         21
    with an intent to pursue the same objectives may, in the anti-
    trust context, be charged with the preceding acts of its co-con-
    spirators.”).
    The district court’s reasoning was sound. RockTenn is free
    to argue at trial that it did not re-join the conspiracy. There is
    no conflict with bankruptcy law, however, if it did so, because
    in that case its liability would be predicated on post-discharge
    conduct. To the extent that these nuances need to be brought
    to the jury’s attention, we are confident that the district court
    can do so through proper instructions.
    IV
    We conclude by noting again the basis of our ruling. First,
    with respect to the central issue of class certification under
    Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 23(a) and (b)(3), the only con-
    tested points relate to predominance and superiority. Defend-
    ants did not challenge Purchasers’ experts under Daubert and
    Federal Rule of Evidence 702, and so we accept their reports
    for what they are worth at this stage. We did not discuss the
    opposing views expressed by Defendants’ experts because
    they did not undermine the class certification decision. De-
    fendants’ experts’ reports will be important, we assume, at the
    merits stage, but the fact that class certification decisions must
    be supported by evidence does not mean that certification is
    possible only for a party who can demonstrate that it will win
    on the merits.
    We AFFIRM the class-certification order of the district
    court.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 15-2386

Citation Numbers: 831 F.3d 919

Judges: Wood

Filed Date: 8/4/2016

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/13/2023

Authorities (19)

Jack Walters & Sons Corp. v. Morton Building, Inc. , 737 F.2d 698 ( 1984 )

Havoco of America, Ltd. v. Shell Oil Company , 626 F.2d 549 ( 1980 )

james-cape-sons-company-v-pcc-construction-company-fka-streu , 453 F.3d 396 ( 2006 )

In Re High Fructose Corn Syrup Antitrust Litigation. Appeal ... , 295 F.3d 651 ( 2002 )

Pella Corp. v. Saltzman , 606 F.3d 391 ( 2010 )

American Honda Motor Co., Inc. v. Allen , 600 F.3d 813 ( 2010 )

randy-blades-collin-cain-fredrick-l-samples-mark-a-jent-roger-rivest , 400 F.3d 562 ( 2005 )

loeb-industries-incorporated-los-angeles-scrap-iron-metal-corporation , 306 F.3d 469 ( 2002 )

dean-west-and-lyndell-eickholz-individually-and-on-behalf-of-a-class-of , 282 F.3d 935 ( 2002 )

United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co. , 60 S. Ct. 811 ( 1940 )

United States v. Von's Grocery Co. , 86 S. Ct. 1478 ( 1966 )

Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc. , 97 S. Ct. 690 ( 1977 )

Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois , 97 S. Ct. 2061 ( 1977 )

Palmer v. BRG of Georgia, Inc. , 111 S. Ct. 401 ( 1990 )

Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc. , 113 S. Ct. 2786 ( 1993 )

Amchem Products, Inc. v. Windsor , 117 S. Ct. 2231 ( 1997 )

Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. Dukes , 131 S. Ct. 2541 ( 2011 )

Comcast Corp. v. Behrend , 133 S. Ct. 1426 ( 2013 )

Tyson Foods, Inc. v. Bouaphakeo , 136 S. Ct. 1036 ( 2016 )

View All Authorities »