Duffy Tool v. NLRB , 233 F.3d 995 ( 2000 )


Menu:
  • In the
    United States Court of Appeals
    For the Seventh Circuit
    Nos. 00-1626, 00-2032
    Duffy Tool & Stamping, L.L.C.,
    Petitioner/Cross-Respondent,
    v.
    National Labor Relations Board,
    Respondent/Cross-Petitioner,
    and
    International Union, United Automobile,
    Aerospace, and Agricultural Implement
    Workers of America, AFL-CIO,
    Intervenor.
    Petition to Review and Cross-Petition
    to Enforce Order of the
    National Labor Relations Board.
    Argued October 23, 2000--Decided December 1, 2000
    Before Posner, Diane P. Wood, and Williams, Circuit
    Judges.
    Posner, Circuit Judge. When a union wins an
    election to be the exclusive bargaining
    representative of a group of workers, the
    employer becomes duty-bound to bargain in good
    faith with the union. 29 U.S.C. sec. 158(a)(5).
    The aim of the bargaining process is to negotiate
    a collective bargaining agreement that will
    define the terms and conditions of employment of
    the represented workers during the term of the
    agreement. There is no duty to agree, however,
    and if the parties deadlock (reach "impasse," in
    the jargon of labor law), the employer is free to
    operate his business as he did before bargaining
    began, and therefore he may alter the terms and
    conditions of the workers’ employment. E.g.,
    Litton Financial Printing Div. v. NLRB, 
    501 U.S. 190
    , 198 (1991); Lapham-Hickey Steel Corp., 
    904 F.2d 1180
    , 1185 (7th Cir. 1990). He can also do
    this if the union takes steps to delay or avoid
    bargaining or if the alteration is necessary to
    avoid serious hardship to the employer. E.g.,
    Vincent Industrial Plastics, Inc. v. NLRB, 
    209 F.3d 727
    , 734 (D.C. Cir. 2000); Visiting Nurse
    Services of Western Mass., Inc. v. NLRB, 
    177 F.3d 52
    , 57-58 (1st Cir. 1999). But if there is no
    deadlock, no foot-dragging by the union, and no
    exigency requiring an immediate change in the
    terms or conditions of employment to stave off
    disaster, the employer may not make such a change
    unilaterally. Litton Financial Printing Div. v.
    NLRB, supra, 
    501 U.S. at 198
    . This is an
    important rule. The overriding goal of federal
    labor law is labor peace, and is promoted when
    the parties to a labor dispute avoid a test of
    strength involving a strike or a lockout by
    negotiating a collective bargaining agreement,
    which will standardly include a no-strike clause,
    thus assuring labor peace during the term of the
    agreement (usually three years) and setting the
    stage for future renewals of the agreement.
    Anything that interferes with the negotiation
    process and makes reaching agreement less likely
    interferes with this goal.
    It is against this policy background that we
    consider the employer’s argument in this case,
    which is that it is free to make unilateral
    changes in the terms and conditions of its
    workers’ employment as soon as the parties reach
    deadlock on any issue in the negotiation. The
    union won an election back in October of 1996.
    During the course of the ensuing negotiations,
    the company put forward a proposal to institute a
    "no fault" attendance policy under which a tardy
    worker would get a certain number of points for
    every incident of tardiness, regardless of
    whether he was at fault, and if he accumulated a
    specified number of points could be fired. The
    company’s existing attendance policy was more
    lenient. The union opposed the proposal. The
    employer declared an impasse and on January 1,
    1998, put the new policy into effect and later
    fired some workers who might not have been fired
    under the old policy. The Board found that while
    the parties may have been deadlocked over the "no
    fault" policy by the beginning of 1998, they were
    not yet deadlocked on all the mandatory issues
    for collective bargaining; they had not reached
    an "overall impasse." The employer disagrees that
    it had not yet reached an overall impasse with
    the union, but there is enough evidence to
    support the Board’s conclusion, leaving the
    employer to argue that piecemeal impasse, the
    deadlock over the proposed new attendance policy,
    was enough to free Duffy to implement the
    proposal.
    Decisions of the Fifth Circuit support this
    position. NLRB v. Pinkston-Hollar Construction
    Services, Inc., 
    954 F.3d 306
    , 311-12 (5th Cir.
    1992); Nabors Trailers Inc. v. NLRB, 
    910 F.2d 268
    , 273 (5th Cir. 1990); Winn-Dixie Stores, Inc.
    v. NLRB, 
    567 F.2d 1343
    , 1349-50 (5th Cir. 1978);
    NLRB v. J.P. Stevens & Co., 
    538 F.2d 1152
    , 1162
    (5th Cir. 1976); A.H. Belo Corp. v. NLRB, 
    411 F.2d 959
    , 971 (5th Cir. 1969); NLRB v. Tex-Tan,
    Inc., 
    318 F.2d 472
    , 480-81 (5th Cir. 1963).
    Though only Winn-Dixie and Belo involved neither
    foot-dragging by the union nor financial
    exigencies compelling the employer to make the
    change immediately, cf. Visiting Nurse Services
    of Western Mass., Inc. v. NLRB, supra, 
    177 F.3d at 59
    ; NLRB v. Triple A Fire Protection, Inc.,
    
    136 F.3d 727
    , 738-39 (11th Cir. 1998), all the
    cases make clear the Fifth Circuit’s belief that
    an employer is free to make a unilateral change
    upon sufficient notice to enable the union to
    discuss its objections with the employer, even if
    the parties are in the midst of bargaining. The
    Board, however, has repeatedly rejected the Fifth
    Circuit’s doctrine, RBE Electronics of S.D. Inc.,
    
    320 N.L.R.B. 80
    , 81-82 (1995); Intermountain
    Rural Electric Ass’n, 
    305 N.L.R.B. 783
    , 786
    (1991), enforced, 
    984 F.2d 1562
     (10th Cir. 1993);
    Master Window Cleaning, Inc., 
    302 N.L.R.B. 373
    ,
    379 (1991), enforced, 
    15 F.3d 1087
     (1994); Winn-
    Dixie Stores, Inc., 
    243 N.L.R.B. 972
    , 974 (1979),
    and other circuits have sided with the Board,
    Vincent Industrial Plastics, Inc. v. NLRB, supra,
    
    209 F.3d at 735
    ; Visiting Nurses Services of
    Western Mass., Inc. v. NLRB, 
    177 F.3d at 58
    ; NLRB
    v. Central Plumbing Co., 
    492 F.2d 1252
    , 1254 (6th
    Cir. 1974), rightly in our view.
    The employer’s position would empty the duty to
    bargain of meaning, and this in two respects: (1)
    by removing issues from the bargaining agenda
    early in the bargaining process, it would make it
    less likely for the parties to find common
    ground; (2) by enabling the employer to paint the
    union as impotent, it would embolden him to hold
    out for a deal so unfavorable to the union as to
    preclude agreement.
    (1) A negotiation is more likely to be
    successful when there are several issues to be
    resolved ("integrative bargaining") rather than
    just one, because it is easier in the former case
    to strike a deal that will make both parties feel
    they are getting more from peace than from war.
    Howard Raiffa, The Art and Science of Negotiation
    97-103, 131-32 (1982). If the only thing at issue
    in a labor negotiation is wages, that is, money,
    the parties are playing a zero-sum game: a dollar
    more in wages is a dollar gained by the union but
    a dollar lost by the employer. But suppose a dues
    checkoff is also at issue. Since it probably is
    worth more to the union not to have to dun the
    workers for their union dues than it costs the
    employer to deduct the dues from the worker’s
    paycheck and remit them to the union, the union
    may be willing to give a little in bargaining
    over wages in order to get the dues checkoff.
    Similarly, the employer may be willing to "pay"
    for a no-strike clause by agreeing to a grievance
    procedure jointly administered by the union and
    the employer, and that may be a concession that
    the union very much wants in order to give the
    workers a sense that the union is protecting them
    from arbitrary discipline by the employer. With
    both parties eager for this trade, it may be
    easier for them to compromise on other issues.
    The particular trade creates value that can be
    used to fund, as it were, other concessions by
    both sides, bringing the parties nearer to the
    state in which both feel better off with an
    agreement than with a strike.
    The employer points out that the implementation
    of a proposal need not remove it from the
    negotiation, since it can always be rescinded.
    The point is literally but not practically
    correct. The employer may be able to make
    implementation irrevocable as a practical matter
    by sinking heavy costs in the implementation and
    thus committing himself to stay the course, for
    example by laying off a number of workers
    pursuant to the adopted proposal and hiring
    permanent replacements under contracts providing
    for generous severance benefits. In addition, the
    employer will be reluctant to lose face with the
    workers by abandoning a measure that it put into
    effect during the negotiation to show (see next
    paragraph) that the union could do nothing for
    them, and he may also fear that if he
    renegotiates after declaring a deadlock it will
    strengthen the union’s contention in the ensuing
    proceedings before the Labor Board that the
    parties had not in fact deadlocked.
    (2) If by deadlocking on a particular issue the
    employer is free to implement his proposal with
    regard to that issue, he signals to the workers
    that the union is a paper tiger. Vincent
    Industrial Plastics, Inc. v. NLRB, supra, 
    209 F.3d at 735
    ; Visiting Nurses Services of Western
    Mass., Inc. v. NLRB, supra, 
    177 F.3d at 59
    . This
    is especially true when as in this case the
    proposal reduces the workers’ job security
    compared to what it was before the election. It
    makes it look as if the workers are actually
    worse off as the result of the election--which of
    course is what the employer, looking forward to a
    possible strike vote and to the eventual
    decertification of the union, wants them to
    think. By undermining support for the union, the
    employer positions himself to stiffen his demands
    in what remains of the bargaining process,
    knowing that if the process breaks down the union
    may be unable to muster enough votes to call a
    strike. This stiffening of terms is likely to
    cause the process to break down, since the union
    cannot afford, by moderating its own demands, to
    acknowledge that it is indeed a paper tiger.
    There is a further and we think conclusive
    objection to the employer’s position. There
    really is no such animal as a deadlock on a
    single issue in a multifaceted negotiation; or if
    there is it is vanishingly rare, a truly
    endangered species. Nothing is more common during
    a negotiation than for one or both parties to
    make nonnegotiable demands. Usually this is
    bluffing, since if the negotiation is truly
    multifaceted, there is generally a price at which
    the parties will surrender these demands. Anyone
    who has been involved in a negotiation knows
    this. Suppose you’re negotiating with a builder
    over the terms for the construction of a house.
    You are very concerned about delay and ask that
    he agree to include a liquidated-damages clause
    that will obligate him to reduce the contract
    price by $100 for every day that completion is
    delayed beyond six months from the signing of the
    contract. He refuses indignantly, saying that he
    never agrees to a damages-for-delay clause, that
    the risk is too great given the uncontrollable
    contingencies of construction, that you should
    find someone else to build your house. You would
    be foolish to take this emphatic refusal at face
    value, as creating an impasse that placed the
    issue beyond negotiation. Raiffa, supra, at 142-
    45. You would probably come back to him with an
    offer to extend the deadline for completion, or
    to accept a somewhat higher purchase price to
    compensate him for assuming the risk of delay, or
    to reduce the amount of per diem damages.
    That is doubtless the case here as well. It is
    inconceivable that the employer is so wedded to a
    "no fault" attendance policy--an idea that first
    occurred to it during the negotiation--that it
    would not abandon the policy in exchange for a
    suitable concession in some other term of the
    collective bargaining agreement. Not that an
    employer has no legitimate concern with
    absenteeism; of course it does; but until the
    union came on the scene the employer had not
    thought a "no fault" policy the right way to deal
    with the problem. Suppose the workers care above
    all about their job security and are therefore
    desperate to have any discharges for absenteeism
    governed by a "for cause" rather than a "no
    fault" standard. Then the employer might be able
    to extract generous concessions in exchange for
    backing down from his demand. An unreasonable
    refusal to even consider backing down from a
    demand plainly not central to the employer’s
    business or labor relations would itself be a
    sign of bad faith. See NLRB v. Wright Motors,
    Inc., 
    603 F.2d 604
    , 608-10 and n. 5 (7th Cir.
    1979); NLRB v. A-1 King Size Sandwiches Inc., 
    732 F.2d 872
    , 877-78 (11th Cir. 1984); NLRB v. Patent
    Trader, Inc., 
    415 F.2d 190
    , 198 (2d Cir. 1969),
    modified on other grounds, 
    426 F.2d 791
     (2d Cir.
    1970) (en banc); NLRB v. Reed & Prince Mfg. Co.,
    
    205 F.2d 131
    , 139 (1st Cir. 1953); see also
    Federal Mogul Corp., 
    212 N.L.R.B. 950
    , 951
    (1974), enforced, 
    524 F.2d 37
     (6th Cir. 1975).
    For all these reasons, we think the Board is on
    sound ground in insisting that the employer
    bargain until it is plain that the parties are
    deadlocked in the negotiation as a whole, a point
    not reached here. As for the employer’s complaint
    that the provision of the Board’s remedy that
    seeks to restore the status quo by rescinding the
    "no fault" attendance policy and reinstating the
    workers fired under it will require the
    reinstatement of the workers that the company
    would have fired even under the previous, more
    lenient policy, we do not read the order so. The
    order directs the company to reinstate with
    backpay employees "discharged, suspended, or
    otherwise denied work opportunities as a result
    of the work rules" (emphasis added). The order is
    not intended to make any worker better off than
    he would have been had the company not violated
    the law by instituting the new attendance policy
    before it had bargained to impasse.
    The petition for review is denied, and the
    cross-petition to enforce the Board’s order is
    granted.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 00-1626

Citation Numbers: 233 F.3d 995

Judges: Per Curiam

Filed Date: 12/1/2000

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/12/2023

Authorities (18)

National Labor Relations Board v. Reed & Prince Mfg. Co. , 205 F.2d 131 ( 1953 )

Visiting Nurses v. NLRB , 177 F.3d 52 ( 1999 )

National Labor Relations Board v. A-1 King Size Sandwiches, ... , 732 F.2d 872 ( 1984 )

National Labor Relations Board v. Triple a Fire Protection, ... , 136 F.3d 727 ( 1998 )

National Labor Relations Board v. Patent Trader, Inc. , 415 F.2d 190 ( 1969 )

Intermountain Rural Electric Association v. National Labor ... , 984 F.2d 1562 ( 1993 )

Nabors Trailers, Inc. (N/k/a Steego Transportation ... , 910 F.2d 268 ( 1990 )

National Labor Relations Board v. Tex-Tan, Inc. , 318 F.2d 472 ( 1963 )

National Labor Relations Board v. Central Plumbing Company , 492 F.2d 1252 ( 1974 )

National Labor Relations Board v. Patent Trader, Inc. , 426 F.2d 791 ( 1970 )

National Labor Relations Board v. J. P. Stevens & Company, ... , 538 F.2d 1152 ( 1976 )

Federal-Mogul Corporation v. National Labor Relations Board , 524 F.2d 37 ( 1975 )

winn-dixie-stores-inc-petitioner-cross-v-national-labor-relations , 567 F.2d 1343 ( 1978 )

a-h-belo-corporation-afaa-tv-v-national-labor-relations-board-local , 411 F.2d 959 ( 1969 )

National Labor Relations Board v. Wright Motors, Inc. , 603 F.2d 604 ( 1979 )

Lapham-Hickey Steel Corp., D/B/A Stephenson-Yost Steel Co. ... , 904 F.2d 1180 ( 1990 )

Vincent Industrial Plastics, Inc. v. National Labor ... , 209 F.3d 727 ( 2000 )

Litton Financial Printing Div., Litton Business Systems, ... , 111 S. Ct. 2215 ( 1991 )

View All Authorities »