Iowa Utilities Board v. FCC ( 2000 )


Menu:
  •                       United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE EIGHTH CIRCUIT
    ________________
    No. 96-3321 (and consolidated cases)
    ________________
    Iowa Utilities Board, et al.,             *
    *
    Petitioners,                        *
    *      On Petitions for Review of an Order
    v.                                  *      of the Federal Communications
    *      Commission.
    Federal Communications                    *
    Commission and United States of           *
    America,                                  *
    Respondents.
    ________________
    Submitted: September 17, 1999
    Filed: July 18, 2000
    ________________
    Before WOLLMAN, Chief Judge, BOWMAN and HANSEN, Circuit Judges.
    ________________
    HANSEN, Circuit Judge.
    These cases are before us on remand from the Supreme Court. See AT & T
    Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 
    525 U.S. 366
     (1999). Local telephone service providers
    (known as "incumbent local exchange carriers" or "ILECs") and their industry
    associations petition for review of the First Report and Order1 issued by the Federal
    1
    In re Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, 
    11 FCC Rcd 15499
     (1996) (First Report and Order).
    Communications Commission (FCC) which contains the FCC's findings and rules2
    pertaining to the local competition provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 19963
    (the Act). The Act requires an ILEC to (1) permit requesting new entrants
    (competitors) in the ILEC's local market to interconnect with the ILEC's existing local
    network and, thereby, use that network to compete in providing local telephone service
    (interconnection); (2) provide its competitors with access to elements of the ILEC's
    own network on an unbundled basis (unbundled access); and (3) sell to its competitors,
    at wholesale rates, any telecommunications service that the ILEC provides to its
    customers at retail rates in order to allow the competing carriers to resell those services
    (resale). See 
    47 U.S.C. § 251
    (c)(2)-(4) (1994 ed., Supp. III).4 Through this Act,
    Congress sought "to promote competition and reduce regulation in order to secure
    lower prices and higher quality services for American telecommunications consumers
    and encourage the rapid deployment of new telecommunications technologies."
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, purpose statement, 
    110 Stat. 56
    , 56 (1996). Challenges to the First Report and Order were consolidated in this
    court.
    2
    The FCC's rules are codified in scattered sections of Title 47, Code of Federal
    Regulations. All references in this opinion to the Code of Federal Regulations are to
    the 1997 version.
    3
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, 
    110 Stat. 56
     (codified
    as amended in scattered sections of Title 47, United States Code).
    4
    All references in this opinion to sections and subsections of the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996 in the United States Code are to the 1997 supplement
    unless otherwise indicated.
    2
    I. Background
    We present a brief summary of the background of this case based upon the belief
    that all parties are familiar with the opinion of the Supreme Court as well as our prior
    opinion. In our prior opinion, Iowa Utils. Bd. v. F.C.C., 
    120 F.3d 753
     (8th Cir. 1997),
    we concluded, in relevant part, that (1) the FCC exceeded its jurisdiction in
    promulgating various pricing rules; (2) the FCC exceeded its jurisdiction in
    promulgating 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.405
    , regarding rural exemptions; (3) the FCC exceeded
    its jurisdiction in promulgating 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.303
    , regarding preexisting agreements;
    and (4) various unbundling rules, including the superior quality rules and the
    combination of network elements rule, were contrary to the Act.
    The Supreme Court affirmed in part, reversed in part, and remanded. See AT
    & T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 
    525 U.S. 366
     (1999). The Supreme Court reversed that
    part of our opinion pertaining to jurisdiction and held that the FCC had jurisdiction to
    (1) design a pricing methodology; (2) promulgate rules pertaining to rural exemptions;
    and (3) promulgate rules regarding preexisting agreements. The Supreme Court also
    reversed our decision to vacate 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.315
    (b). The Supreme Court did not
    address the part of our opinion vacating the superior quality rules, 47 C.F.R. § §
    51.305(a)(4) and 51.311(c), and the additional combination of network elements rule,
    
    47 C.F.R. § 51.315
    (c)-(f).
    On remand we must now review on the merits the FCC's forward-looking pricing
    methodology, proxy prices, and wholesale pricing provisions. The petitioners also
    request that the court vacate 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.317
    , regarding the identification of
    additional unbundled network elements, and that the court reaffirm its previous decision
    vacating the superior-quality rules and the additional combination of network elements
    3
    rule. We also must review on the merits 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.405
    , regarding rural
    exemptions, and 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.303
    , pertaining to preexisting agreements.
    II. Analysis
    The United States Courts of Appeals have exclusive jurisdiction to review final
    orders of the FCC pursuant to 
    28 U.S.C. § 2342
    (1) and 
    47 U.S.C. § 402
    (a) (1994). In
    reviewing an agency's interpretation of a statute, we must defer to the agency only if
    its interpretation is consistent with the plain meaning of the statute or is a reasonable
    construction of an ambiguous statute. See Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Resources
    Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 842-43 (1984). We will overturn an agency
    interpretation that conflicts with the plain meaning of the statute, see 
    id.,
     is an
    unreasonable construction of an ambiguous statute, see 
    id. at 844-45
    , or is arbitrary and
    capricious. See 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
     (1994); Chevron, 
    467 U.S. at 844
    . In making our
    decision regarding reasonableness, the issue "is not whether the Commission made the
    best choice, or even the choice that this Court would have made, but rather 'whether the
    FCC made a reasonable selection from among the available alternatives.'"
    Southwestern Bell Tel. Co. v. F.C.C., 
    153 F.3d 523
    , 559-60 (8th Cir. 1998) (quoting
    MCI Telecomms. Corp. v. FCC, 
    675 F.2d 408
    , 413 (D.C. Cir. 1982).
    A. Pricing Methodology
    Congress established pricing standards for the rates that may be charged by
    ILECs to their new local service competitors for interconnection and for the furnishing
    of network elements on an unbundled basis. The statute, in relevant part, states:
    (d) Pricing standards
    (1) Interconnection and network element charges
    Determinations by a State commission of the just and
    reasonable rate for the interconnection of facilities and
    equipment for purposes of subsection (c)(2) of section 251
    4
    of this title, and the just and reasonable rate for network
    elements for purposes of subsection (c)(3) of such section–
    (A) shall be–
    (i) based on the cost
    (determined without reference to
    a rate-of-return or other
    ratebased proceeding) of
    providing the interconnection or
    network element (whichever is
    applicable), and
    (ii) nondiscriminatory, and
    (B) may include a reasonable profit.
    
    47 U.S.C. § 252
    (d)(1).
    The FCC promulgated various pricing rules to implement the Act. The FCC's
    pricing provisions that pertain to the pricing of interconnection and network elements
    utilize a forward-looking economic cost methodology that is based on the total element
    long-run incremental cost (TELRIC) of the element. These costs are to be based on an
    ILEC's existing wire center locations using the most efficient technology available in
    the industry regardless of the technology actually used by the ILEC and furnished to
    the competitor. See First Report and Order ¶ 685. State commissions are to employ
    TELRIC to determine the price an ILEC may charge its competitors for the right to
    interconnect with the ILEC and/or to use the ILEC's network elements to compete with
    the ILEC in providing telephone services.
    The petitioners contend the TELRIC method violates the plain language and
    purpose of the Act and represents arbitrary and capricious decision-making. The
    petitioners challenge TELRIC on four grounds.
    5
    1. Hypothetical Network Standard
    In its First Report and Order, the FCC explained that forward-looking
    methodologies, like TELRIC, consider the costs that a carrier would incur in the future
    for providing the interconnection or unbundled access to its network elements. See
    First Report and Order ¶ 683. These costs either can be based on the most efficient
    network configuration and technology currently available, or on the ILEC's existing
    network infrastructures. See 
    id.
     The FCC chose an approach which it says combined
    the two possibilities. See id. ¶ 685. Pursuant to § 252(d)(1), the FCC promulgated 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.505
     entitled "Forward-looking economic cost." It states in part that "[t]he
    total element long-run incremental cost of an element should be measured based on the
    use of the most efficient telecommunications technology currently available and the
    lowest cost network configuration, given the existing location of the incumbent LEC's
    wire centers." 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.505
    (b)(1). The only nonhypothetical factor in the
    calculation is the use of the actual location of the ILEC's existing wire centers.
    The petitioners assert that the hypothetical network standard upon which
    TELRIC's costs are based is contrary to the Act's plain language. Section
    252(d)(1)(A)(i) requires the just and reasonable rates for network elements to be "based
    on the cost (determined without reference to a rate-of-return or other rate-based
    proceeding) of providing the interconnection or network element." 
    Id.
     (emphasis
    added). The petitioners contend the language points inescapably to the actual costs the
    ILEC incurs for furnishing its existing network to the competitor either through
    interconnection or on an unbundled network element basis. However, the petitioners
    explain that the costs under the FCC's pricing methodology are those costs that would
    be incurred by a hypothetical carrier deploying a hypothetical network that is optimally
    efficient in technology and configuration. The petitioners argue that the FCC's
    6
    hypothetical network standard does not reflect what they are statutorily required to
    furnish to their competitors and is, therefore, flatly contrary to the statute.
    The respondents counter the petitioners' assertion that TELRIC costs are based
    on a hypothetical network. The respondents contend TELRIC does reflect the ILECs'
    costs but on a predictive forward-looking basis that assumes a reasonable level of
    efficiency. According to the respondents, setting rates based on the use of the most
    efficient technology available and on the lowest cost network configuration using
    existing wire center locations is consistent with the statute, promotes competition, and
    is a reasonable application of forward-looking costs.
    The intervenors in support of the FCC (the intervenors) explain that costs should
    be based on what any firm, including the specific ILEC whose rates are to be set,
    would incur in providing the network elements today. They suggest these costs should
    be the replacement cost of the network using the technology available today and that
    no firm in a competitive market would charge rates based on the cost of reproducing
    obsolete technology. The intervenors contend that calculating the cost of old
    technology with current prices defeats the purpose of using a forward-looking
    methodology.
    We agree with the petitioners that basing the allowable charges for the use of an
    ILEC's existing facilities and equipment (either through interconnection or the leasing
    of unbundled network elements) on what the costs would be if the ILEC provided the
    most efficient technology and in the most efficient configuration available today
    utilizing its existing wire center locations violates the plain meaning of the Act. It is
    clear from the language of the statute that Congress intended the rates to be "based on
    the cost . . . of providing the interconnection or network element," 
    id.
     (emphasis
    added), not on the cost some imaginary carrier would incur by providing the newest,
    most efficient, and least cost substitute for the actual item or element which will be
    furnished by the existing ILEC pursuant to Congress's mandate for sharing. Congress
    7
    was dealing with reality, not fantasizing about what might be. The reality is that
    Congress knew it was requiring the existing ILECs to share their existing facilities and
    equipment with new competitors as one of its chosen methods to bring competition to
    local telephone service, and it expressly said that the ILECs' costs of providing those
    facilities and that equipment were to be recoverable by just and reasonable rates.
    Congress did not expect a new competitor to pay rates for a "reconstructed local
    network," First Report and Order ¶ 685, but for the existing local network it would be
    using in an attempt to compete.
    It is the cost to the ILEC of providing its existing facilities and equipment either
    through interconnection or by providing the specifically requested existing network
    elements that the competitor will in fact be obtaining for use that must be the basis for
    the charges. The new entrant competitor, in effect, piggybacks on the ILEC's existing
    facilities and equipment. It is the cost to the ILEC of providing that ride on those
    facilities that the statute permits the ILEC to recoup. This does not defeat the purpose
    of using a forward-looking methodology as the intervenors assert. Costs can be
    forward-looking in that they can be calculated to reflect what it will cost the ILEC in
    the future to furnish to the competitor those portions or capacities of the ILEC's
    facilities and equipment that the competitor will use including any system or component
    upgrading that the ILEC chooses to put in place for its own more efficient use. In our
    view it is the cost to the ILEC of carrying the extra burden of the competitor's traffic
    that Congress entitled the ILEC to recover, and to that extent, the FCC's use of an
    incremental cost approach does no violence to the statute. At bottom, however,
    Congress has made it clear that it is the cost of providing the actual facilities and
    equipment that will be used by the competitor (and not some state of the art presently
    available technology ideally configured but neither deployed by the ILEC nor to be
    used by the competitor) which must be ascertained and determined.
    Consequently, we vacate and remand to the FCC rule 51.505(b)(1).
    8
    2. Use of a Forward-looking Methodology
    The petitioners contend that the FCC's use of its forward-looking TELRIC
    methodology, which denies the ILECs recovery of their historical costs, is contrary to
    the express terms of the Act and is unreasonable. The petitioners state that the term
    "cost" plainly refers to historical cost and that the juxtaposition of "cost" in §
    252(d)(1)(A)(i) with "profit" in § 252(d)(1)(B) confirms this. They refer to the
    discussion of profit in paragraph 699 of the First Report and Order as support for their
    proposition that if profit must be read in an accounting sense, then so too must cost.
    In addition, they assert the FCC failed to provide an adequate explanation for its
    rejection of historical costs and that an agency is not allowed to change ratemaking
    methodologies without cogently explaining why the change is being made.
    The respondents argue the term "cost" is an elastic term that can be construed
    to mean either historical or forward-looking costs and that the FCC's interpretation of
    cost as forward-looking is reasonable. They clarify the discussion in the First Report
    and Order regarding profit. They explain that the FCC found that a normal profit,
    which TELRIC is designed to yield, represents a "reasonable profit" within the meaning
    of the statute and that the FCC has not construed profit to mean accounting profit. The
    respondents also argue the FCC explained in detail its decision to use forward-looking
    costs and that the decision was reasonable based on the new competitive objectives of
    the 1996 Act. The intervenors agree with the respondents that the term "cost" imposes
    no clear limits on the FCC's authority to establish a ratemaking methodology, and
    according to their argument, it is in these circumstances that an agency is entitled to
    deference.
    We respectfully disagree with the petitioners' contention that cost, as it is used
    in the statute, means historical cost. The statute simply states that rates "shall be based
    on the cost . . . of providing the interconnection or network element." 
    47 U.S.C. § 252
    (d)(1)(A). We conclude the term "cost," as it is used in the statute, is ambiguous,
    9
    and Congress has not spoken directly on the meaning of the word in this context. We
    agree with the assessment that "the word 'cost' is a chameleon, capable of taking on
    different meanings, and shades of meaning, depending on the subject matter and the
    circumstances of each particular usage." Strickland v. Commissioner, Maine Dept. of
    Human Servs., 
    48 F.3d 12
    , 19 (1st Cir. 1995), cert. denied, 
    516 U.S. 850
     (1995).
    The FCC has the authority to make rules to fill any gap in the Act left by
    Congress, provided the agency's construction of the statute is reasonable. See Chevron,
    
    467 U.S. at 843
    . Likewise, "Congress is well aware that the ambiguities it chooses to
    produce in a statute will be resolved by the implementing agency." AT & T Corp., 
    525 U.S. at 397
     (citation to Chevron omitted). Forward-looking costs have been recognized
    as promoting a competitive environment which is one of the stated purposes of the Act.
    The Seventh Circuit, for example, explained, "[I]t is current and anticipated cost, rather
    than historical cost that is relevant to business decisions to enter markets . . . historical
    costs associated with the plant already in place are essentially irrelevant to this decision
    since those costs are 'sunk' and unavoidable and are unaffected by the new production
    decision." MCI Communications v. American Tel. & Tel. Co., 
    708 F.2d 1081
    , 1116-
    17 (7th Cir. 1983), cert. denied, 
    464 U.S. 891
     (1983). Here, the FCC's use of a
    forward-looking cost methodology was reasonable. The FCC sought comment on the
    use of forward-looking costs and concluded that forward-looking costs would best
    ensure efficient investment decisions and competitive entry. See First Report and
    Order ¶ 705. It is apparent that the FCC explained in detail its reason for selecting a
    forward-looking cost methodology to implement the new competitive goals of the Act,
    and any past rejection of forward-looking methodologies was made in a monopoly,
    rather than a competitive, environment. See First Report and Order ¶¶ 618-711.
    10
    Additionally, we are unpersuaded by the petitioners' discussion of the
    juxtaposition of the word "profit" with "cost" in the statute. The FCC did not interpret
    profit as accounting5 profit as the petitioners contend. The First Report and Order
    discusses only two types of profit: economic6 and normal7. See First Report and Order
    5
    Accounting profit equals the difference between total revenue and explicit costs.
    Explicit costs are those costs incurred when a monetary payment is made. Accounting
    profit is typically higher than economic profit because accounting profit only subtracts
    explicit costs rather than the total opportunity costs. See ROGER A. ARNOLD,
    ECONOMICS 484-85 (2d ed. 1992).
    6
    Economic profit equals the difference between total revenue and total
    opportunity cost, including both explicit and implicit costs. Implicit costs represent the
    value of resources used for which no monetary payment is made. See 
    id.
     Economic
    profit is also referred to as supranormal profit. See First Report and Order ¶ 699.
    7
    Normal profit is achieved when a company earns revenue that is equal to its
    total opportunity costs. This is the level of profit needed for a company to cover all of
    its opportunity costs. Normal profit is the same as zero economic profit. See ARNOLD,
    supra note 5, at 485.
    11
    ¶ 699. The FCC interpreted the word "profit" in the statute to mean "normal profit."
    The FCC found that TELRIC provides for a "normal" profit and that level of profit is
    reasonable within the meaning of the statute. Section 252(d)(1)(B) states only that the
    rates paid for either interconnection or furnishing unbundled access "may include a
    reasonable profit." The use of the word "may" indicates that the inclusion of a
    reasonable profit is not mandatory but permitted. Additionally, nothing in the phrase
    "may include a reasonable profit" suggests "cost" must mean historical costs. A
    "profit" can be made whether a historical cost or forward-looking cost methodology is
    used. We reiterate that a forward-looking cost calculation methodology that is based
    on the incremental costs that an ILEC actually incurs or will incur in providing the
    interconnection to its network or the unbundled access to its specific network elements
    requested by a competitor will produce rates that comply with the statutory requirement
    of § 252(d)(1) that an ILEC recover its "cost" of providing the shared items.
    3. Effect of Universal Service Subsidies
    The petitioners submit that the failure to include the costs imposed by the
    government mandated subsidies in network element prices would frustrate the Act's
    objectives by forcing the ILECs to bear a disproportionate share of the universal
    service burdens. They explain that when an incumbent carrier provides to a competitor
    the network elements needed to serve a business customer, the costs to the incumbent
    not only include the costs of operating the particular network elements furnished but
    also the loss of that customer's contribution to support lower rates for others. The loss
    of that contribution, the petitioners argue, must be included in the determination of the
    rates charged the competitor for unbundled access to the ILEC's network elements.
    The respondents and intervenors assert that allowing the ILECs to include the
    costs of universal service subsidies in its rates would violate the Act. They argue §
    12
    252(d)(1) requires rates to reflect the costs of providing the network elements, not the
    costs of universal service subsidies. Including those costs, according to the
    respondents, would violate that section of the Act. The respondents cite two decisions
    in which we concluded that the costs of universal services subsidies should not be
    included in the costs of providing the network elements. See Competitive Telecomms.
    Ass'n v. F.C.C., 
    117 F.3d 1068
    , 1074-75 (8th Cir. 1997); Southwestern Bell Tel. Co.,
    
    153 F.3d at 540
    .
    In accordance with our previous opinions, we maintain our view that the costs
    of universal service subsidies should not be included in the costs of providing the
    network elements. Section 252(d)(1)(A)(1) requires rates to be cost-based. Universal
    service charges are not based on the actual costs of providing interconnection or the
    requested network element. See Competitive Telecomms., 
    117 F.3d at 1073
    .
    "[P]ayment of cost-based rates represents full compensation to the incumbent LEC for
    use of the network elements that carriers purchase." Southwestern Bell, 
    153 F.3d at 540
     (quoting In re Access Charge Reform; Price Cap Performance Review for Local
    Exchange Carriers; Transport Rate Structure and Pricing; End User Common Line
    Charges, 
    12 FCC Rcd 15982
     (1997) ¶ 337). Including the costs of universal service
    subsidies would allow for double recovery. See id.
    4. Takings Argument
    The petitioners contend the use of the TELRIC method to set rates raises a
    serious Fifth Amendment takings issue that the statute should be construed to avoid.
    The petitioners challenge the pricing rules as mandating invalid confiscatory rates. The
    petitioners insist the statute must be read so that an ILEC receives just and reasonable
    compensation in the constitutional sense for the services it provides to its competitors.
    13
    The respondents argue that the claim that the use of TELRIC will constitute a
    taking is not ripe for judicial consideration because, at this point, it is unknown whether
    the rates established under TELRIC will constitute just and reasonable compensation.
    In addition, the intervenors point out that TELRIC compensates the ILECs for the
    present market value of the property taken which is all that is constitutionally required
    for just and reasonable compensation.
    Because we have vacated 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.505
    (b)(1), we have some doubt that
    we need to address the argument that TELRIC also violates the Constitution. Our
    remand to the FCC of the TELRIC rule should result in a new rule for determining the
    compensation that the ILECs will receive for the new competitor's use of the ILEC's
    property--a rule that should accurately determine the actual costs to the ILEC of
    furnishing its network (either by interconnection or on an unbundled element basis) to
    its competitors together with a permitted reasonable profit. Whether the new rule will
    result in rates that do not provide just and reasonable compensation cannot be foretold.
    However, in the event our view of TELRIC's statutory invalidity turns out to be
    incorrect, and to avoid as best we can another remand, we proceed further with the
    petitioners' constitutional assertions.
    In our earlier opinion we determined that the ILECs' claims that the FCC's
    unbundling rules constituted an unconstitutional taking were not ripe for adjudication.
    See Iowa Utils. Bd., 
    120 F.3d at 818
    . We did so principally on the basis that the rates
    for the unbundled access were to be set by the state commissions, that the actual rates
    were largely yet unknown, and that the Act provided for a mechanism (arbitration
    before the state commissions and review in federal district court) to determine what the
    just and reasonable rates would be in individual cases. That ripeness conclusion was
    not attacked in the Supreme Court. While we recognize that the argument made here
    (that TELRIC itself, because it is based on a hypothetical network using the most
    efficient technology available which bears little or no resemblance to the ILEC's
    property which will be actually made available to competitors, must result in rates that
    14
    are neither just nor reasonable, and confiscatory in the constitutional sense) is not the
    same one we addressed in our earlier opinion, we conclude for many of the same
    reasons we expressed before, see 
    id.,
     that the present takings claim is not ripe for
    review.8
    The Constitution protects public utilities from rates which are "so unjust as to be
    confiscatory." Duquesne Light Co. v. Barasch, 
    488 U.S. 299
    , 307 (1989). However,
    a takings claim cannot be based on the ratemaking methodology, but rather it must be
    based on the rate itself. "It is not theory but the impact of the rate order which counts."
    Federal Power Comm'n v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 
    320 U.S. 591
    , 602 (1944). Until the
    actual rates are established, we cannot conclude whether the impact of TELRIC driven
    rates will constitute a taking. "It is not enough that a party merely speculates that a
    government action will cause harm." Alenco Communications, Inc. v. F.C.C., 
    201 F.3d 608
    , 624 (5th Cir. 2000). We do not need to disregard Chevron deference and interpret
    the statute in accordance with the petitioners' views in order to avoid an
    unconstitutional taking in this instance. The possibility that a regulatory program may
    result in a taking does not justify the use of a narrowing construction. See United
    States v. Riverside Bayview Homes, Inc., 
    474 U.S. 121
    , 128-29 (1985). In such
    circumstances, the adoption of a narrowing construction might frustrate a potentially
    permissible application of a statute. See 
    id. at 128
    . Because the consequences of the
    FCC's choice to use TELRIC methodology cannot be known until the resulting rates
    have been determined and applied, the constitutional claim is not ripe. See Duquesne,
    
    488 U.S. at 317
     (Scalia, White, and O'Connor, JJ., concurring) (noting that the
    8
    We note, with no small amount of interest, that the Supreme Court has granted
    certiorari to review the Fifth Circuit's decision in Texas Office of Pub. Util. Counsel v.
    FCC, 
    183 F.3d 393
     (5th Cir. 1999), where the Fifth Circuit noted that the use of a
    forward-looking cost model to determine universal service subsidies did not result in
    an unconstitutional taking. GTE Service Corp. v. FCC, 
    68 U.S.L.W. 3496
     (U.S. June
    5, 2000) (No. 99-1244).
    15
    Constitution looks to the consequences produced rather than the technique employed).
    B. Wholesale Rates
    Section 252(d)(3) of the Act provides that state commissions "shall determine
    wholesale rates on the basis of retail rates charged to subscribers for the
    telecommunications service requested, excluding the portion thereof attributable to any
    marketing, billing, collection, and other costs that will be avoided by the local exchange
    carrier." Pursuant to this section, the FCC promulgated 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.607
     which
    excludes "avoided retail costs" from wholesale rates. "Avoided retail costs" are defined
    by the FCC as "those costs that reasonably can be avoided when an incumbent LEC
    provides a telecommunications service for resale at wholesale rates to a requesting
    carrier." 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.609
    (b).
    The petitioners challenge the FCC's interpretation of the term "avoided retail
    costs." The petitioners contend § 252(d)(3) plainly requires wholesale rates to reflect
    the ILECs' retail rates less those costs that an ILEC actually avoids when it loses its
    retail customers to a reselling competitor. However, under the FCC's definition of
    "avoided retail costs," the petitioners argue the FCC requires them to exclude all
    retailing costs rather than only those costs that an ILEC actually avoids. The
    petitioners state that many costs associated with retailing are fixed and will not begin
    to decline initially nor will the costs decline proportionately to the number of customers
    lost to the reseller. The petitioners explain the phrase "will be avoided" in § 252(d)(3)
    means "actually avoided" because otherwise the wholesale discount given the reseller
    would be inflated.
    The respondents counter that the phrase "will be avoided" is ambiguous and that
    the FCC reasonably interpreted the language of the statute. The intervenors explain
    that the ILECs avoid incurring any retailing costs when engaging in wholesale
    16
    transactions, and even if certain retailing costs are fixed, the ILECs would still incur
    only those costs that arose in connection with the ILECs' retailing activities. The
    respondents state that making competitors pay for a portion of the ILECs' retailing
    costs, even though the new entrant is not the cause of those retail costs, would result
    in the new entrants subsidizing the ILECs' retail offerings while still having to pay the
    new entrants' own retailing costs.
    We agree with the petitioners that the phrase "will be avoided" refers to those
    costs that the ILEC will actually avoid incurring in the future, because of its wholesale
    efforts, not costs that "can be avoided." The verb "will" is defined, in part, as "a word
    of certainty." BLACK'S LAW DICTIONARY 1598 (6th ed. 1990). Whereas, the verb
    "can" is "[o]ften used interchangeably with 'may,'" id. at 206, and may is a word "of
    speculation and uncertainty." Id. at 1598. The language of the statute is clear.
    Wholesale rates shall exclude "costs that will be avoided by the local exchange carrier."
    
    47 U.S.C. § 252
    (d)(3). The plain meaning of the statute is that costs that are actually
    avoided, not those that could be or might be avoided, should be excluded from the
    wholesale rates.
    If the Congress had meant the standard to be one of reasonable avoidability, it
    could have easily said so. We note that Congress's starting point in § 252(d)(3) is the
    retail rates the ILEC charges its subscribers for the same service the new competitor
    (who wants to enter the market by reselling) has requested be furnished to it. From
    those retail rates, the ILEC's costs that "will be avoided" by furnishing those services
    to the competitor are to be excluded. The statute recognizes that the ILEC will itself
    remain a retailer of telephone service with its own continuing costs of providing that
    retail telephone service. The FCC's rule treats the ILEC as if it were strictly a
    wholesaler whose sole business is to supply local telephone service in bulk to new
    purveyors of retail telephone service. Under the statute as it is written, it is only those
    continuing costs of providing retail telephone service which will be avoided by selling
    17
    to the competitor the services it requests which are to be excluded. The FCC's rule is
    contrary to the statute.
    Consequently, we vacate and remand rule 51.609.
    C. Proxy Prices
    The FCC established proxy prices to be used for interconnection and network
    element charges, wholesale rates, and the rates for termination and transport. The state
    commissions are to use these proxy prices if they do not use the provided ratemaking
    method to establish rates. The proxy prices consist of upper limits higher than which
    the rates set by the state commissions shall not go.
    The petitioners argue the proxy prices should be vacated for three reasons. First,
    the petitioners state that the respondents expressly disavowed the proxy prices before
    the Supreme Court in order to support the FCC's position that it was not trying to set
    specific prices, but rather it was merely designing a pricing methodology. Therefore,
    the FCC, according to the petitioners, is judicially estopped from trying to revive the
    proxy prices now. Second, the petitioners contend the proxy prices should be vacated
    because they are based on the unlawful TELRIC method and employ the impermissible
    definition of "avoided retail costs." Third, the petitioners argue the proxy prices were
    developed using unreliable cost models and, as a result, are arbitrary and capricious.
    The respondents counter that the petitioners' challenge to the proxy prices is not
    subject to review because the proxy prices are not binding on the states. The
    respondents contend that states may elect to use the proxy prices, but the states are not
    required to use them. The respondents insist that this court has jurisdiction to review
    only final orders of the FCC, and the proxy prices are not final orders because they do
    not impose an obligation on the states. The intervenors add that substantial deference
    18
    should be accorded to the FCC because the issue concerns interim relief, citing
    Competitive Telecommunications Association v. F.C.C., 
    117 F.3d 1068
    , 1073-75 (8th
    Cir. 1997).
    We agree with the petitioners that the respondents are estopped from trying to
    now revive the proxy prices. "The doctrine of judicial estoppel prohibits a party from
    taking inconsistent positions in the same or related litigation." Hossaini v. Western
    Missouri Med. Ctr., 
    140 F.3d 1140
    , 1142 (8th Cir. 1998). Judicial estoppel is invoked
    "to protect the integrity of the judicial process." Id. at 1143. The FCC represented to
    the Supreme Court that it was not establishing rates and depriving the state
    commissions of their role in implementing the Act. See Reply Br. for Federal Pet'rs at
    7, AT & T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 
    525 U.S. 366
     (1999) 
    1998 WL 396961
     (Nos. 97-
    826, 97-829, 97-830, 97-831, 97-1075, 97-1087, 97-1099, and 97-1141). The FCC
    emphasized that it was merely providing a methodology for state commissions to use
    in completing the "critical and complex task of determining the economic costs of an
    efficient telephone network." 
    Id.
     The FCC dismissed the proxy prices as "designed
    for a past period in which no cost studies could have been made available to the state
    commissions. They have no relevance to this case." 
    Id.
     at 7 n.5.
    We are not persuaded by the FCC's explanation to this court of its position
    before the Supreme Court. The respondents explain that the proxy prices were not
    relevant to the ILECs' claim before the Supreme Court that the pricing rules intruded
    on the states' role in establishing rates because the proxy prices were optional. The
    First Report and Order very clearly commands the use of the proxy prices by directing
    that "a state commission shall use [default proxies] . . . in the period before it applies
    the pricing methodology." First Report and Order ¶ 619 (emphasis added).
    Additionally, rule 51.503(b) states that the ILECs' rates for its elements "shall be
    established" using either TELRIC or the proxy prices. See 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.503
    (b)
    (emphasis added). The word "shall" is language of a mandatory nature. Clark v.
    Brewer, 
    776 F.2d 226
    , 230 (8th Cir. 1985). It is clear from the language of the First
    19
    Report and Order, as well as the rules, that the state commissions are to use the proxy
    prices until the state commissions have established their own rates using the TELRIC
    method. The use of the proxy prices until such time is not optional.
    The Supreme Court held that the FCC "has jurisdiction to design a pricing
    methodology." AT & T Corp., 
    525 U.S. at 385
    . However, the FCC does not have
    jurisdiction to set the actual prices for the state commissions to use. Setting specific
    prices goes beyond the FCC's authority to design a pricing methodology and intrudes
    on the states' right to set the actual rates pursuant to § 252(c)(2). Following the
    Supreme Court's opinion, we now agree with the FCC that its role is to resolve "general
    methodological issues," and it is the state commission's role to exercise its discretion
    in establishing rates. Br. for Federal Pet'rs at 26-27, AT & T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd.,
    
    525 U.S. 366
     (1999), 
    1998 WL 396945
     (No. 97-831).
    The proxy prices are also infirm because they rely on the hypothetical most
    efficient carrier rationale which we have found to be violative of the Act, ante at 5-8,
    and because they rely on the erroneous definition of "avoided retail costs."
    We conclude the proxy prices cannot stand and, for the foregoing reasons, vacate
    rules 51.513, 51.611, and 51.707.
    D. Unbundling Rules
    The FCC issued numerous rules to implement the ILECs' duties to provide
    unbundled access to their network elements under subsection 251(c)(3). Many of these
    rules were previously challenged. In light of the Supreme Court's opinion, we revisit
    three of the unbundling rules.
    20
    1. Identification of Additional Unbundled Network Elements
    The Supreme Court vacated 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.319
     which required the ILECs to
    provide requesting carriers with unbundled access to a minimum of seven network
    elements so long as access was "necessary" and failure to provide the access would
    "impair" the competitors' ability to provide services. The Supreme Court vacated 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.319
     because the FCC's interpretation of the "necessary" and "impair"
    standard was too broad and unreasonable. See AT & T Corp., 
    525 U.S. at 388-92
    .
    The ILECs request that we now vacate rule 51.317 because it utilizes the same
    "necessary" and "impair" standard of rule 51.319. The Supreme Court did not
    specifically address the validity of rule 51.317. This court previously upheld the
    "necessary" and "impair" standard, but we vacated the portion of rule 51.317 that
    created the presumption that a network element must be unbundled if it is technically
    feasible to do so.
    The respondents concede that rule 51.317 must be remanded to the FCC as a
    result of the Supreme Court's opinion. See Resp'ts' Br. at 87 n.42. Therefore, we
    vacate rule 51.317 without any further discussion.
    2. Superior Quality Rules
    In our previous opinion, we vacated 
    47 C.F.R. §§ 51.305
    (a)(4) and 51.311(c),
    collectively known as the superior quality rules. These rules require an ILEC to
    provide, upon request, interconnection and unbundled network elements that are
    superior in quality to that which the ILEC provides to itself. The Supreme Court did
    not address these rules.
    21
    The petitioners ask us to reaffirm our previous decision vacating the superior
    quality rules. They contend the Supreme Court's decision did not affect our conclusion
    that the superior quality rules violated the Act because the FCC did not seek a review
    of our prior decision vacating these rules.
    The respondents argue that the Supreme Court affirmed the FCC's general
    authority to adopt rules implementing the Act and that under this general authority the
    superior quality rules are valid. The intervenors agree and explain that because nothing
    in the Act forecloses the superior quality rules, the rules should be reinstated.
    We again conclude the superior quality rules violate the plain language of the
    Act. We further conclude that nothing in 
    47 U.S.C. §§ 154
    (i), 201(b), or 303(r) gives
    the FCC the power to issue regulations contrary to the plain language of the Act. As
    we were correctly reminded at oral argument that this court is not a "super FCC,"
    neither is the FCC an alter ego Congress free to change the words of a statute from "at
    least equal in quality" to "superior in quality" when it exercises its rule-making power.
    Subsection 251(c)(2)(C) requires the ILECs to provide interconnection "that is at least
    equal in quality to that provided by the local exchange carrier to itself . . . ." Nothing
    in the statute requires the ILECs to provide superior quality interconnection to its
    competitors. The phrase "at least equal in quality" establishes a minimum level for the
    quality of interconnection; it does not require anything more. We maintain our view
    that the superior quality rules cannot stand in light of the plain language of the Act for
    all the reasons we previously expressed. See Iowa Utils. Bd., 
    120 F.3d at 812-13
    . We
    also note that it is self-evident that the Act prevents an ILEC from discriminating
    between itself and a requesting competitor with respect to the quality of the
    interconnection provided.
    3. Additional Combinations Rule
    In our previous opinion, we also vacated 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.315
    (c)-(f), the
    additional combinations rule. This rule requires an ILEC to perform the functions
    22
    necessary to combine unbundled network elements in any technically feasible manner.
    Although the Supreme Court reversed our decision to vacate 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.315
    (b),
    prohibiting the ILECs from separating requested network elements that are already
    combined, the Supreme Court did not address subsections (c)-(f).
    The petitioners request that we reaffirm our prior decision vacating the additional
    combinations rule. The petitioners state that the Supreme Court's decision to reinstate
    51.315(b) does not call into question this court's decision to vacate 51.315(c)-(f). The
    petitioners explain 51.315(b) is different because it prohibited ILECs from separating
    previously combined network elements over the objection of the requesting carrier.
    The additional combinations rule contained in subsections (c)-(f), on the other hand,
    requires the ILECs to combine their own network elements in new ways or with
    elements provided by the requesting carriers. They argue the additional combinations
    rule violates the Act.
    In addition to the respondents' argument regarding the general rulemaking
    authority of the FCC, they assert this court's decision to vacate rules 51.315(c)-(f) was
    predicated on language rejected by the Supreme Court when it reinstated rule
    51.315(b). In reinstating subsection (b), the Supreme Court emphasized the ambiguous
    nature of § 251(c)(3) regarding the separation of leased network elements. See AT &
    T Corp., 
    525 U.S. at 395
    . Because of this ambiguity, the Supreme Court concluded,
    subsection (b) is rationally based on the nondiscrimination language in § 251(c)(3). See
    id. The respondents rely on the same nondiscrimination language to support
    subsections (c)-(f) because without these subsections, they argue, new entrants would
    incur higher costs for unbundled network elements than the ILECs incur. The
    intervenors agree that the policy concerns of ensuring against an anticompetitive
    practice not only support 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.315
    (b) but also subsections (c)-(f).
    We are not persuaded by the respondents' contention that the Supreme Court's
    reinstatement of rule 51.315(b) affects our decision to vacate subsections (c)-(f). Nor
    23
    do we agree with the Ninth Circuit that the Supreme Court's opinion undermined our
    rationale for invalidating the additional combinations rule. See U.S. West
    Communications v. MFS Intelenet, Inc., 
    193 F.3d 1112
    , 1121 (9th Cir. 1999), cert.
    denied, 
    68 U.S.L.W. 3669
     (U.S. June 29, 2000) (No. 99-1641). The Ninth Circuit
    misinterpreted our decision to vacate subsections (c)-(f). We did not, as the Ninth
    Circuit suggests, employ the same rationale for invalidating subsections (c)-(f) as we
    did in invalidating subsection (b). See MCI Telecomms. v. U.S. West, 
    204 F.3d 1262
    ,
    1268 (9th Cir. 2000) ("The Eighth Circuit invalidated Rules 315(c)-(f) using the same
    rationale it employed to invalidate Rule 315(b). That is, the Eighth Circuit concluded
    that requiring combination was inconsistent with the meaning of the Act because the
    Act calls for 'unbundled' access.") Rather, the issue we addressed in subsections (c)-(f)
    was who shall be required to do the combining, not whether the Act prohibited the
    combination of network elements. See Iowa Utils. Bd., 
    120 F.3d at 813
    .
    Rule 51.315(b) prohibits the ILECs from separating previously combined
    network elements before leasing the elements to competitors. The Supreme Court held
    that 51.315(b) is rational because "[section] 251(c)(3) of the Act is ambiguous on
    whether leased network elements may or must be separated." AT & T Corp., 
    525 U.S. at 395
    . Therefore, under the second prong of Chevron, the Supreme Court concluded
    51.315(b) was a reasonable interpretation of an ambiguous statute.
    Unlike 51.315(b), subsections (c)-(f) pertain to the combination of network
    elements. Section 251(c)(3) specifically addresses the combination of network
    elements. It states, in part, "An incumbent local exchange carrier shall provide such
    unbundled network elements in a manner that allows requesting carriers to combine
    such elements in order to provide such telecommunication service." Here, Congress
    has directly spoken on the issue of who shall combine previously uncombined network
    elements. It is the requesting carriers who shall "combine such elements." It is not the
    duty of the ILECs to "perform the functions necessary to combine unbundled network
    elements in any manner" as required by the FCC's rule. See 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.315
    (c).
    24
    We reiterate what we said in our prior opinion: "[T]he Act does not require the
    incumbent LECs to do all the work." Iowa Utils. Bd., 
    120 F.3d at 813
    . Under the first
    prong of Chevron, subsections (c)-(f) violate the plain language of the statute. We are
    convinced that rules 51.315(c)-(f) must remain vacated.
    E. Rural Exemptions
    Congress enacted § 251(f) to relieve the small and rural ILECs from some of the
    obligations imposed by other subsections of § 251. The FCC promulgated 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.405
     to establish standards that the state commissions must follow in determining
    whether the small and rural ILECs are entitled to the exemption, suspensions, or
    modifications set forth in § 251(f).
    The petitioners contend rule 51.405 cannot be reconciled with the language of
    the statute. They challenge the rule on three grounds. First, they argue the rule
    eliminates two of the three prerequisites that must be satisfied before a state
    commission may terminate an exemption. Second, they disagree with the limitation the
    rule places on the statutory phrase "unduly economically burdensome." Third, they
    suggest that the rule impermissibly shifts the burden of proof in exemption proceedings.
    1. Prerequisites for Terminating an Exemption
    Section 251(f)(1)(A) explains that a state commission may terminate an
    exemption for a rural telephone company if a request for interconnection, services, or
    network elements "is not unduly economically burdensome, is technically feasible, and
    is consistent with section 254 of this title (other than subsections (b)(7) and (c)(1)(D)
    thereof)." The FCC promulgated 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.405
     pursuant to § 251(f). The rule
    requires the ILECs to offer evidence that the application of the requirements under §
    251(c) "would be likely to cause undue economic burden beyond the economic burden
    25
    that is typically associated with efficient competitive entry" in order to justify
    exemption. 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.405
    (c).
    The petitioners contend the rule is invalid because it alters the statutorily-
    mandated criteria that must be met in order for a state commission to terminate a rural
    ILEC's exemption. The petitioners point out that rule 51.405 refers only to the "unduly
    economically burdensome" prerequisite for termination rather than the above-mentioned
    three criteria.
    The respondents argue that the rule does not eliminate any statutory criteria
    regarding rural exemptions. The respondents explain it was not the FCC's intent, nor
    was it within the FCC's power, to eliminate any statutory requirements. The
    respondents suggest that state commissions will look to the statute itself, in addition to
    the FCC's rule, when implementing § 251(f). They further claim that the FCC has
    stated in a later order that rule 51.405(c) "does not in any way affect a state's
    responsibility to consider all three of the factors set forth in section 251(f)(1)(A)," citing
    to an order entered when the Rural Telephone Coalition sought a stay of rule 51.405(c).
    See In re Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, 
    11 FCC Rcd 20166
     (1996) ¶ 15.
    We agree with the petitioners that the rule impermissibly disregards two of the
    three statutory requirements that must be met before a state commission can terminate
    an exemption. A state commission looking at rule 51.405(c) would conclude that if a
    rural ILEC had failed to show an undue economic burden, the exemption must be
    terminated, regardless of the existence of the ILEC's companion defenses of technical
    26
    infeasibility and/or inconsistency with § 254 of the Act. A rule that permits such a
    result represents an arbitrary and unreasonable interpretation of the governing statute.
    2. Undue Economic Burden
    Rule 51.405 also refers to the statutory requirement that a request for
    interconnection, unbundled elements, or retail services for resale must not cause an
    undue economic burden in order to justify termination of an exemption under §
    251(f)(1) or to justify the denial of a petition for suspension or modification under §
    251(f)(2). The rule interprets the statutory phrase "unduly economically burdensome"
    as "undue economic burden beyond the economic burden that is typically associated
    with efficient competitive entry." 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.405
    (c),(d).
    The petitioners argue that the rule's interpretation of the statutory language is
    unreasonable because it does not allow state commissions to consider the total actual
    economic burden that competitive entry could impose on a small or rural ILEC. The
    petitioners explain that the phrase "unduly economically burdensome" indicates
    Congress intended state commissions to consider any type of economic burden that
    might be imposed by such a request, including those burdens associated with efficient
    entry.
    The respondents assert that the FCC interpreted "unduly economically
    burdensome" to refer to something more than the economic burden that commonly or
    ordinarily occurs upon efficient competitive entry because otherwise exemption,
    suspension, or modification would be virtually automatic. The respondents submit that
    Congress did not intend to preclude competitive entry into small or rural markets; rather
    Congress intended to protect the small or rural ILECs from only those § 251(b) or §
    251(c) requirements that might be unfair or inappropriate.
    27
    We agree with the petitioners that the FCC has unreasonably interpreted the
    phrase "unduly economically burdensome." We owe no deference to an agency's
    interpretation that would "frustrate the congressional policy underlying a statute."
    Bureau of ATF v. Fed. Labor Relations Auth., 
    464 U.S. 89
    , 97 (1983) (quoting NLRB
    v. Brown, 
    380 U.S. 278
    , 291-92 (1965)). In the Act, Congress sought both to promote
    competition and to protect rural telephone companies as evidenced by the congressional
    debates. See 142 CONG. REC. S687-01 (Feb. 1, 1996) (statements by Sen. Hollings and
    Sen. Burns); 142 CONG. REC. H1145-06 (Feb. 1, 1996) (statement by Rep. Orton). It
    is clear that Congress intended that all Americans, including those in sparsely settled
    areas served by small telephone companies, should share the benefit of the lower cost
    of competitive telephone service and the benefits of new telephone technologies, which
    the Act was designed to provide. It is also clear that Congress exempted the rural
    ILECs from the interconnection, unbundled access to network elements, and resale
    obligations imposed by § 251(c), unless and until a state commission found that a
    request by a new entrant that the ILEC furnish it any of § 251(c)'s methods to compete
    in the rural ILEC's market is (1) not unduly economically burdensome, (2) technically
    feasible, and (3) consistent with § 254. See 
    47 U.S.C. § 251
    (f)(1). Likewise, Congress
    provided for the granting of a petition for suspension or modification of the application
    of the requirements of § 251(b) or (c) if a state commission determined that such
    suspension or modification is necessary to avoid (1) a significant adverse economic
    impact, (2) imposing a requirement that is unduly economically burdensome, and (3)
    imposing a requirement that is technically infeasible; and is consistent with the public
    interest, convenience, and necessity. See 
    47 U.S.C. § 251
    (f)(2).
    There can be no doubt that it is an economic burden on an ILEC to provide what
    Congress has directed it to provide to new competitors in § 251(b) or § 251(c).
    Because the small and rural ILECs, while they may be entrenched in their markets,
    have less of a financial capacity than larger and more urban ILECs to meet such a
    request, the Congress declared that their statutorily-granted exemption from doing so
    should continue unless the state commission found all three prerequisites for
    28
    terminating the exemption, or determined that all prerequisites for suspension or
    modification were met in order to grant an ILEC affirmative relief. It is the full
    economic burden on the ILEC of meeting the request that must be assessed by the state
    commission. The FCC's elimination from that assessment of the "economic burden that
    is typically associated with efficient competitive entry" substantially alters the
    requirement Congress established. By limiting the phrase "unduly economically
    burdensome" to exclude economic burdens ordinarily associated with competitive
    entry, the FCC has impermissibly weakened the broad protection Congress granted to
    small and rural telephone companies. We have found no indication that Congress
    intended such a cramped reading of the phrase. If Congress had wanted the state
    commissions to consider only that economic burden which is in excess of the burden
    ordinarily imposed on a small or rural ILEC by a competitor's requested efficient entry,
    it could easily have said so. Instead, its chosen language looks to the whole of the
    economic burden the request imposes, not just a discrete part.
    Nor do we think the consideration of the whole economic burden occasioned by
    the request will result in state commissions "automatically" continuing the exemption,
    or "automatically" granting a petition for suspension or modification. In making their
    determination of "unduly economically burdensome," the state commissions will
    undoubtedly take into their judgment the fact that the ILEC will be paid for the cost of
    meeting the request and may also receive a reasonable profit pursuant to § 252(d).
    Subsections (c) and (d) of rule 51.405 are an unreasonable interpretation of the statute's
    requirement that a § 251(b) or § 251(c) request made by a competitor must not be
    "unduly economically burdensome" to the small or rural ILEC.
    3. Burden of Proof
    Rule 51.405 also requires the rural ILEC to offer evidence to the state
    commission to prove that it is entitled to a continuing exemption. The rule states,
    "Upon receipt of a bona fide request for interconnection, services, or access to
    29
    unbundled network elements, a rural telephone company must prove to the state
    commission that the rural telephone company should be entitled, pursuant to section
    251(f)(1) of the Act, to continued exemption from the requirements of section 251(c)
    of the Act." 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.405
    (a).
    The petitioners contend the FCC has improperly placed the burden of justifying
    a continued exemption on the ILECs. The petitioners discuss the language in 
    47 U.S.C. § 251
    (f)(1)(A), which states "[s]ubsection (c) of this section shall not apply to a rural
    telephone company until (i) such company has received a bona fide request for
    interconnection, services, or network elements . . . ." This language, they explain,
    indicates that the ILECs are automatically exempt from subsection (c) until a request
    has been made, and once a request is made, the burden is on the party making the
    request to prove that the request is not unduly economically burdensome, is technically
    feasible, and is consistent with § 254. They also assert the burden of proof lies with
    the proponent of the order according to the Administrative Procedure Act. See 
    5 U.S.C. § 556
    (d) (1994).
    The respondents argue it was reasonable to place the burden on the rural ILECs
    because the default rule is for the state commission to deny the exemption unless the
    state commission affirmatively finds a reason to continue the exemption. The
    respondents rely on the Senate conference report on the Act which explains that a state
    commission must rule on the continuation of an exemption within 120 days, "and, if no
    exemption is granted," then the state commission must establish a schedule for
    compliance. S. CONF. REP. NO. 104-230, at 122 (1996). The respondents emphasize
    the word "granted" implies that a state commission will only grant an exemption if there
    is a specific reason to do so.
    We agree with the petitioners that the rule impermissibly places the burden of
    proof on the ILECs. The statute states that the requirements of § 251(c) "shall not
    apply to a rural telephone company until" a request has been made. 
    47 U.S.C. § 30
    251(f)(1)(A) (emphasis added). The use of the word "until" suggests that the rural
    telephone companies have a continuing exemption that is only terminated once a bona
    fide request is made, provided the request is not unduly economically burdensome, is
    technically feasible, and is consistent with § 254. Although the conference report refers
    to state commissions granting an exemption, the language of a conference report does
    not trump the language of a statute. See Sierra Club v. Clark, 
    755 F.2d 608
    , 615 (8th
    Cir. 1985). The language of the statute uses the word "terminate" not "grant." See 
    47 U.S.C. § 251
    (f)(1)(B). The plain meaning of the statute requires the party making the
    request to prove that the request meets the three prerequisites to justify the termination
    of the otherwise continuing rural exemption.
    For the foregoing reasons, we vacate rule 51.405(a), (c), and (d).
    F. Preexisting Agreements
    Congress enacted § 252 of the Act to establish procedures for state commissions
    to approve agreements between ILECs and competing telecommunication carriers
    arrived at through negotiation or arbitration. Section 252(a) requires agreements
    entered into pursuant to § 251(c)(1)'s duty to negotiate to be submitted to the state
    commissions for approval. Section 252(a)(1) states:
    Upon receiving a request for interconnection, services, or network
    elements pursuant to section 251 of this title, an incumbent local exchange
    carrier may negotiate and enter into a binding agreement with the
    requesting telecommunications carrier or carriers without regard to the
    standards set forth in subsections (b) and (c) of section 251 of this title.
    The agreement shall include a detailed schedule of itemized charges for
    interconnection and each service or network element included in the
    agreement. The agreement, including any interconnection agreement
    negotiated before February 8, 1996, shall be submitted to the State
    commission under subsection (e) of this section.
    31
    The FCC promulgated 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.303
     which requires all interconnection9
    agreements, even those that predate the 1996 Act, to be submitted to the state
    commissions for approval. The rule states, "All interconnection agreements between
    an incumbent LEC and a telecommunications carrier, including those negotiated before
    February 8, 1996, shall be submitted by the parties to the appropriate state commission
    for approval . . . ." 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.303
    (a).
    The petitioners argue that the rule violates the explicit language of the Act
    because, while the Act references agreements entered into pursuant to § 251, the rule
    applies to all agreements, even those entered into years before the Act was passed. The
    petitioners explain that agreements negotiated and entered into pre-1996 could not have
    been entered into "pursuant to section 251" because § 251 did not exist at that time, and
    therefore, only agreements that were either negotiated before the Act and formally
    entered into after the Act, or agreements that were both negotiated and formally entered
    into after the Act, must be submitted for approval.
    The respondents contend that the agreement referred to in the third sentence of
    § 252(a)(1) is not limited to the agreement mentioned in the first and second sentences.
    The first and second sentences, they argue, refer to agreements reached pursuant to §
    251, while the agreement mentioned in the third sentence refers to all, including pre-
    Act, agreements. The respondents explain that the term "negotiated" in the phrase set
    off by commas in the third sentence means a completed negotiation or, in other words,
    a negotiation that has resulted in a completed interconnection agreement.
    We agree with the petitioners that the rule is contrary to the language of the Act.
    The respondents attempt to isolate the third sentence of §252(a)(1) from the prior two
    9
    We note that the term "interconnection" has been defined by the FCC as "the
    physical linking of two networks for the mutual exchange of traffic." First Report and
    Order ¶ 26.
    32
    sentences. The FCC concluded "that the final sentence of section 252(a)(1), which
    requires that any interconnection agreement must be submitted to the state
    commissions, can and should be read to be independent of the prior sentences in
    section 252(a)(1)." First Report and Order ¶ 166. This is not a proper construction
    because "we must not be guided by a single sentence or member of a sentence, but look
    to the provisions of the whole law, and to its object and policy." United States Nat'l
    Bank of Oregon v. Independent Ins. Agents, 
    508 U.S. 439
    , 455 (1993).
    The subsection in question begins by making reference to a competitor's "request
    . . . pursuant to section 251." Upon receiving such a request, the competitor and the
    ILEC "may negotiate and enter into a binding agreement" without regard for the
    interconnection and unbundled network element access standards of § 251(b) and (c).
    The second sentence requires that the agreement so negotiated and entered into contain
    a detailed schedule of itemized charges for the items covered by the "agreement." The
    third sentence begins with the words, "[t]he agreement" (which can only mean the same
    agreement authorized by the first sentence and referred to in the second sentence) and
    requires that it be submitted to the state commission for approval pursuant to subsection
    (e).
    The phrase in the third sentence set off by commas, which reads, "including any
    interconnection agreement negotiated before February 8, 1996," serves as the co-
    subject of the verb form "shall be submitted" and explains and defines what else
    besides the "agreement" mentioned in the first two sentences of the section must be
    submitted to the state commission. The "what else" that must be submitted to the state
    commission for approval is any interconnection agreement "negotiated" before
    February 8, 1996.
    Congress was aware that many states were already exploring and experimenting
    with ways to open up local telephone markets to competition, and that telephone
    carriers were involved with each other in negotiations for those purposes prior to and
    33
    at the time of the Act's passage. See, e.g., S. REP. NO. 104-23, at 5 (1995). By using
    the phrase "including any interconnection agreement negotiated before February 8,
    1996," Congress brought within the sphere of required state commission approval all
    interconnection agreements entered into after February 8, 1996, including specifically
    those whose terms were arrived at by negotiation prior to that date but which had not
    yet been formally entered into by the parties. Because that unique group of
    interconnection agreements (those that were negotiated before but not yet entered into
    by February 8, 1996) could not have been agreements prompted or originated by either
    a request made under the Act or by the duty to negotiate contained in the Act (as the
    Act was not yet in existence at the time they were being negotiated), they could not be
    an "agreement" covered by the first two sentences and the first two words of the third
    sentence of § 252(a)(1). Nevertheless, because their subject matter, interconnection,
    was one which the Act was intended to compel, and because they would be entered
    into after the effective date of the Act, it was logical for Congress to want them subject
    to the Act's provisions. The use of the statutory language "including any
    interconnection agreement negotiated before February 8, 1996" also eliminated any
    argument that the agreeing carriers could have made in order to avoid state commission
    approval that their agreement had been negotiated before the Act's date and, therefore,
    was not subject to it.
    We also think it of some significance that Congress intentionally used both the
    terms "negotiate" and "enter into" in the first sentence of § 252(a)(1) but only used the
    verb "negotiated" in the third sentence. Had Congress wanted to include all
    interconnection agreements that had been both negotiated and entered into before the
    Act's effective date within the scope of the third sentence, all it had to do was use the
    same words it had used in the first sentence. See Kifer v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 
    777 F.2d 1325
    , 1333 n.9 (8th Cir. 1985) ("'When the same word or phrase is used in the
    same section of an act more than once, and the meaning is clear as used in one place,
    it will be construed to have the same meaning in the next place.'") (quoting United
    States v. Nunez, 
    573 F.2d 769
    , 771 (2d Cir.), cert. denied, 
    436 U.S. 930
     (1978)). It
    34
    did not, and its choice not to do so reinforces our conclusion that Congress did not
    intend to do so. See, e.g., Johnson v. United States, 
    120 S. Ct. 1795
    , 1803 (2000)
    (When Congress means the same consequences, it is "natural for Congress to write in
    like terms.").
    Across the country there were thousands of interconnection agreements existing
    between and among ILECs before the Act was passed. In Wisconsin alone the state
    commission estimated that there were over 3,000 pre-Act agreements which, under the
    FCC's construction of § 252, would now have to be submitted for approval. See
    Addendum to Br. of Pet'rs United States Telephone Ass'n et al. at 9. Many of those
    agreements were between neighboring noncompeting ILECs for the exchange of
    features and functions. There is no indication that Congress intended the state
    commissions to go back through years of agreements and approve or disapprove them.
    We conclude that Congress knew it was already giving the state commissions a huge
    amount of new work to do in arbitrating and approving the new agreements that would
    quickly be coming into being by virtue of the substantive provisions of the Act, and that
    it did not intend to add an even heavier burden by forcing the state commissions to
    replow old ground. The FCC's construction of the statute is unreasonable.
    We further find it difficult to square the FCC's interpretation with the recognized
    presumption against retroactive legislation. By construing the word "negotiated" in the
    third sentence to mean "negotiated and entered into," the FCC's rule reaches back and
    requires something that the parties to the preexisting agreement had no reason to
    expect--required state commission approval under new and different standards which
    affect the rights the parties had at the time they entered into their agreement. See
    Landgraf v. USI Film Prods., 
    511 U.S. 244
    , 280 (1994). Here again Congress's choice
    not to use the words "entered into" in the third sentence tells us that Congress did not
    intend the retroactive effect the FCC has given to the Act. Absent clear Congressional
    intent for retroactive effect, there should be none. See 
    id.
     By making the Act
    applicable to interconnection agreements that were only negotiated before the Act's
    35
    effective date (but not yet entered into), Congress gave the parties the option of either
    proceeding to enter into the negotiated agreement with the knowledge it would have to
    be submitted to the state commission for approval, or not. In so doing, an unwanted
    retroactive effect can be avoided, the parties can proceed knowing what the law will
    be, and the effect of the Act is entirely prospective.
    We hold that § 252(a)(1) applies to any agreement which was either (1) both
    negotiated and entered into pursuant to § 251 after the Act went into effect or (2) is an
    interconnection agreement that was negotiated before, but not yet entered into when,
    the Act went into effect.
    Consequently, we vacate rule 51.303.
    III. Conclusion
    We grant the pending petitions for review in part. For the reasons stated, we
    vacate, in total, 
    47 C.F.R. §§ 51.505
    (b)(1), 51.609, 51.513, 51.611, 51.707, 51.317,
    51.405(a),(c), and (d), and 51.303. We remain firm in our previous decision to vacate
    
    47 C.F.R. §§ 51.305
    (a)(4) and 51.311(c) (the superior quality rules) and 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.315
    (c)-(f) (the additional combinations rule). In all other respects, we deny the
    petitions for review.
    A true copy.
    Attest:
    CLERK, U.S. COURT OF APPEALS, EIGHTH CIRCUIT
    36
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 96-3321

Filed Date: 7/18/2000

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/13/2015

Authorities (21)

Nancy Strickland v. Commissioner, Maine Department of Human ... , 48 F.3d 12 ( 1995 )

Texas Office of Public Utility Counsel v. Federal ... , 183 F.3d 393 ( 1999 )

MCI Communications Corporation and MCI Telecommunications ... , 708 F.2d 1081 ( 1983 )

Iowa Utilities Board v. F.C.C. , 120 F.3d 753 ( 1997 )

Alenco Comm v. FCC , 201 F.3d 608 ( 2000 )

Sierra Club and Defenders of Wildlife v. William P. Clark, ... , 755 F.2d 608 ( 1985 )

Federal Power Commission v. Hope Natural Gas Co. , 64 S. Ct. 281 ( 1944 )

Duquesne Light Co. v. Barasch , 109 S. Ct. 609 ( 1989 )

mci-telecommunications-corporation-a-delaware-corporation-mci-metro-access , 204 F.3d 1262 ( 2000 )

1997-2-trade-cases-p-71877-8-communications-reg-pf-1068-competitive , 117 F.3d 1068 ( 1997 )

edward-clark-v-lou-v-brewer-warden-of-the-iowa-state-penitentiary-at , 776 F.2d 226 ( 1985 )

us-west-communications-v-mfs-intelenet-inc-sharon-l-nelson-chairman , 193 F.3d 1112 ( 1999 )

southwestern-bell-telephone-company-southern-new-england-telephone-company , 153 F.3d 523 ( 1998 )

National Labor Relations Board v. Brown , 85 S. Ct. 980 ( 1965 )

United States v. Riverside Bayview Homes, Inc. , 106 S. Ct. 455 ( 1985 )

United States National Bank v. Independent Insurance Agents ... , 113 S. Ct. 2173 ( 1993 )

Landgraf v. USI Film Products , 114 S. Ct. 1483 ( 1994 )

At&T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board , 119 S. Ct. 721 ( 1999 )

Johnson v. United States , 120 S. Ct. 1795 ( 2000 )

Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco & Firearms v. Federal Labor ... , 104 S. Ct. 439 ( 1983 )

View All Authorities »