Hahnaman Albrecht v. Potash Corporation ( 1999 )


Menu:
  •                   United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE EIGHTH CIRCUIT
    ___________
    No. 97-1330
    ___________
    Blomkest Fertilizer, Inc.; Cobden Grain *
    & Feed, on behalf of themselves and all *
    others similarly situated;                   *
    *
    Plaintiffs                     *
    *
    Hahnaman Albrecht, Inc.; John Peterson, *
    doing business as Almelund Feed &            *
    Grain; Laing-Gro Fertilizers, Inc.;          *
    *
    Plaintiffs - Appellants        *
    *
    Clearbrook AG Service, Inc., on behalf * Appeal from the United States
    of itself and all others similarly situated; * District Court for the
    Reamford Liquid Fertilizer, Inc., on         * District of Minnesota.
    behalf of itself and all others similarly *
    situated; Tolley's, Inc., on behalf of itself*
    and all others similarly situated;           *
    *
    Plaintiffs                     *
    *
    James River Farm Service, Inc., on           *
    behalf of itself and all other similarly *
    situated;                                    *
    *
    Plaintiffs - Appellants        *
    *
    Angela Coleman, on behalf of herself *
    and all others similarly situated;           *
    *
    Plaintiffs                     *
    *
    AG Network, Inc.;                            *
    *
    Plaintiffs - Appellants        *
    *
    Marcelline Farm Supply, Inc., on behalf *
    of itself and all others similarly situated, *
    *
    Plaintiffs                     *
    *
    v.                                    *
    *
    Potash Corporation of Saskatchewan, *
    Inc.; Potash Corporation of                  *
    Saskatchewan Sales, Inc.; Potash             *
    Company of America, Inc.; IMC                *
    Fertilizer Group, Inc.; Kalium               *
    Chemicals, Ltd.; Kalium Canada, Ltd.; *
    Noranda Minerals, Inc.; Central Canada *
    Potash Co.; Noranda Sales Corporation, *
    Ltd.; Cominco, Ltd.; Cominco                 *
    American, Inc.; Eddy Potash, Inc.; New *
    Mexico Potash Corporation;                   *
    *
    Defendants - Appellees         *
    *
    Rio Algom, Ltd.;                             *
    *
    Defendant                      *
    *
    PPG Canada, Limited; PPG Industries, *
    Inc.; IMC Global,                            *
    *
    Defendants - Appellees.        *
    -2-
    ___________
    Submitted: November 17, 1997
    Filed: May 7, 1999
    ___________
    Before BEAM, HEANEY, and JOHN R. GIBSON, Circuit Judges.
    ___________
    JOHN R. GIBSON, Circuit Judge.
    A certified class of potash buyers appeals the district court's entry of judgment
    in favor of the defendant potash producers in this antitrust case. The class claims that
    the producers conspired to fix potash prices in violation of section one of the
    Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1 (1994). The district court adopted a recommendation
    of the Magistrate Judge concluding that the class had not produced any evidence
    supporting an inference of conspiracy. Although much of the class's evidence of
    behavior in the potash industry was consistent with a price-fixing conspiracy, the
    court held that the facts were equally consistent with legal oligopolistic behavior.
    Relying on Monsanto Company v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 
    465 U.S. 752
    (1984),
    and Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    (1986),
    the court entered summary judgment against the class. In re Potash Antitrust
    Litigation, 
    954 F. Supp. 1334
    (D. Minn. 1997). The class appeals, arguing that the
    district court misapplied the standards of Monsanto and Matsushita to change the
    standard for summary judgment in antitrust cases. We reverse in part and affirm in
    part.
    The potash industry is an oligopoly1 in which the producers ended a price war
    and raised prices dramatically. The question is whether the class has shown that the
    1
    An oligopoly is a market in which there are few sellers.
    -3-
    new prices resulted from an agreement among the producers to raise and stabilize
    prices, rather than from innocent reactions to market conditions, combined with
    actions of the United States and Canadian governments.
    Potash is a mineral which is an essential ingredient in fertilizer. Because
    potash is an essential ingredient, the demand for potash is "inelastic," meaning that
    people will continue to buy it even if the price goes up, and they will not buy much
    more, even if the price goes down. The effect of this inelastic demand is that low
    prices are bad for the producers because the low price does not result in greater sales,
    except insofar as one producer can take sales away from other producers.
    Conversely, producers benefit from high prices, because they can sell about as much
    potash and keep the extra money.
    The market for potash in the United States is dominated by Canadian firms.
    Their share of sales in the United States rose in the early and mid 1980's. Canadian
    potash constituted 76.7% of the United States' domestic consumption in 1984, 82.6%
    in 1985, and 84.3% in 1986. David G. Haglund and Alex von Bredow, U.S. Trade
    Barriers and Canadian Minerals: Copper, Potash and Uranium 68. Not only did the
    Canadians have a tremendous share of world potash reserves (the province of
    Saskatchewan alone had nearly fifty percent of world reserves), but the Canadians
    also enjoyed the advantage of being closer to prime United States agricultural areas
    than were the U.S. domestic producers, who were concentrated in the Southwest.
    The principal Canadian potash producers are defendants in this case: Potash
    Corporation of Saskatchewan Incorporated (PCS);2 Potash Corporation of America
    2
    Including Potash Corporation of Saskatchewan Sales Limited, a subsidiary of
    PCS.
    -4-
    (PCA); IMC Fertilizer Group, Inc.; Kalium3; Noranda Minerals, Inc.4; and Cominco.5
    These Canadian firms are allied in Canpotex, a cartel that exists to sell potash outside
    the United States. (In addition to these Canadian firms, two affiliated American
    companies, New Mexico Potash Corporation and Eddy Potash, are also named as
    defendants.)
    The biggest of these Canadian firms, PCS, was originally owned by the
    province of Saskatchewan and was run as a governmental company for the avowed
    purposes of providing jobs and promoting the local Saskatchewan economy.
    Unfortunately for the potash industry, due to a slump in agriculture, potash demand
    fell tremendously in the 1980's, resulting in oversupply. The effect of the oversupply
    was a potash price war, with prices bottoming in 1986 when PCS charged C$45.36
    per ton FOB mine.6 The industry was in crisis. PCS alone lost $103 million in 1986.
    The president of PCS Sales wrote in an internal memorandum that the industry would
    not be able to end the price war without "joint action":
    3
    Including PPG Canada Limited, which operated Kalium as a division; PPG
    Industries, Inc., parent corporation of PPG Canada; and Kalium Chemicals, Ltd. and
    Kalium Canada, Ltd.
    4
    Including Noranda Minerals, Inc., Noranda Sales Corporation, Ltd., and
    Central Canada Potash Company Limited, which amalgamated with Noranda Metals
    Industries Limited under Canadian law.
    5
    Including Cominco, Ltd. and its subsidiary Cominco American Incorporated.
    6
    Quoting actual prices in this case is quite treacherous because prices are
    variously given in Canadian and United States dollars, for metric tons and short tons,
    for different grades of potash, and for potash delivered to different places, often
    without specifying all these variables. Therefore, we give particular numbers only
    for purposes of illustration and do not base our legal reasoning or holding on any
    particular figures.
    -5-
    It is not possible for a single producer to affect [sic] a turn-around;
    however, joint action by a group of producers or governments could
    achieve this.
    Given the competitive nature of the business, joint action in North
    America is not possible except through a vehicle such as Canpotex.
    Canpotex by itself cannot achieve the objectives unless there is tacit
    approval and support on the part of other potash exporters. The danger
    inherent in multilateral decisions by Canpotex (or PCS Sales) is that the
    world will again see us as a residual supplier. . . . PCS Sales' past
    support of price with a view to achieve stability is proof of the fallacy
    of such attempts.
    In fact, Noranda, Kalium, PCA, and PCS had each tried to increase prices unilaterally
    during 1986, and were forced to rescind the increases when the other producers
    undercut them.
    In 1986, the province of Saskatchewan elected a government which promised
    to privatize PCS. In preparation for privatizing the company, PCS replaced its
    management with Charles Childers, CEO, and William Doyle, sales chief, who came
    to PCS from rival company IMC. Childers was quoted in a trade publication as
    saying that it was incumbent on PCS "to lead" in order to "straighten out our own
    company and hopefully give some strength to the potash industry as a whole."
    Also in 1986, two American producers7 filed a complaint with the United
    States Department of Commerce alleging that the Canadian companies were dumping
    potash in the United States at less than fair value (which can mean below prices
    charged for exports to a third country, below domestic prices in the country where the
    product is produced, or below a reconstructed cost of production, Haglund and von
    
    Bredow, supra, at 65
    ). The Department investigated the claim and in August 1987
    7
    One of the American companies was New Mexico Potash Corporation, a
    defendant in this 
    case. 954 F. Supp. at 1343
    .
    -6-
    issued a preliminary determination that the Canadian producers were dumping potash.
    The Department ordered the Canadian companies to post bonds on all exports to the
    United States, which would be payable to the United States as a duty if there were a
    final determination of dumping and injury to American producers. The amount of the
    bond varied for each firm according to the firm's "dumping margin," that is, the
    average amount by which the firm's United States sale price fell below the foreign
    market value in the cases examined by the Department. The dumping margins varied
    wildly, from 9.14 percent for IMC up to a crippling 85.2 percent for Noranda.
    The Saskatchewan government responded to the United States's action by
    adopting legislation which would give the province the power to limit and prorate
    production among Saskatchewan producers. Haglund and von 
    Bredow, supra, at 76
    .
    Within days of the introduction of the Saskatchewan legislation, on September 4,
    1987, PCS announced that it would increase its prices by $35 per ton (from $58 to
    $93 per short ton for coarse grade f.o.b. mine), or sixty percent, to account for the
    bond expense. PCS's dumping margin was set at 51.9 per cent. PCS chose to raise
    its price only by $35, the amount necessary to pay duties on the industry average
    dumping margin of 36.62 per cent, rather than by the amount necessary to pay its
    own duty of 51.9 percent. PCS's choice of the industry average figure was, at the
    least, an attempt to pick a figure that other producers would follow. On September
    11, 1987, the other Canadian producer defendants all8 announced either a $35 price
    increase or a new price of $93, rather than increasing the price by the amount
    necessary to cover their individual duty costs.
    On January 8, 1988, the Canadian producers reached an agreement with the
    Department of Commerce, suspending the earlier order. The suspension agreement
    8
    The PCA price list is dated September 16, 1987, but a September 11 memo to
    the file by Vice President John Ripperger refers to the price increase as having
    already taken place.
    -7-
    imposed a minimum price on Canadian producers selling in the United States market,
    but oddly, the minimum price chosen was still less than the "foreign market value":
    the Canadians were only forbidden from undercutting "foreign market value" by more
    than fifteen percent of the producer's dumping margin. Haglund and von 
    Bredow, supra, at 88
    . The literal terms of the suspension agreement made each producer's
    minimum price vary with its own foreign market value (which was arrived at by
    different methodologies for different firms) and with its own dumping margin; as the
    defendants' expert William Barringer opined, the "uncertainties" in such a calculation
    make it impossible to predict with accuracy what price for any particular transaction
    would be in compliance with the agreement. However, correspondence from the
    Department of Commerce, which had responsibility for monitoring compliance with
    the suspension agreement, indicates that the Department used an industry average
    figure in assessing compliance.
    As soon as the suspension agreement was in place, PCS again led the way in
    determining industry pricing, announcing it would rebate the earlier $35 surcharge,
    and on January 11, 1988, publishing its new price list at $86 per ton for granular
    grade, an $18 increase. The other Canadian producers matched PCS's increase within
    11 days, and Kalium raised its price to 
    $87. 954 F. Supp. at 1366
    . The Department
    of Commerce, in monitoring compliance with the agreement, noted that the agreement
    imposed an average floor price of $60.67, and that in the five months following the
    agreement the average price charged was $79.28.
    The class's expert, Prof. Gordon Rausser, opined and presented data purporting
    to show that the industry average prices for potash were higher than would be
    expected based on market factors during the 1988-1993 period (i.e., prices were
    "supra- competitive"). Perhaps more to the point, prices remained significantly
    higher than the minimum prices imposed by the suspension agreement from 1988 to
    -8-
    1993,9 with the exception of a short period in 1990 when PCS cut its prices drastically
    for the avowed purpose of stabilizing prices within the industry. Only in the wake of
    this January 1990 “market correction,” did prices briefly dip below the suspension
    agreement price floor.
    The plaintiffs filed suit against the Canadian producers and two affiliated
    American producers, New Mexico Potash Corp. and Eddy Potash, alleging a
    conspiracy to raise and stabilize prices. Their proof of the conspiracy was
    circumstantial, consisting of the economic evidence of supracompetitive pricing and
    evidence of price discussions among competitors.
    The defendants moved for summary judgment on the ground that the class had
    not produced any evidence that showed that the defendants had conspired, rather than
    setting their prices individually taking into account their competitors' probable
    responses. The motion was referred to a magistrate judge. The class's strongest
    evidence that the supracompetitive prices resulted from conspiracy was the evidence
    of price-verification communications among competitors and complaints and threats
    among competitors about discounting. The magistrate judge rejected each of these
    types of evidence on the ground that they did not exclude the possibility of
    independent action. In re Potash Antitrust Litigation, 
    954 F. Supp. 1334
    (D. Minn.
    1997). The magistrate judge concluded that the price-verification practices were
    9
    The dissent argues that Rausser does not take into account the effect of the
    antidumping proceedings, and his testimony is thus irrelevant. Infra at 43. The only
    aspect of Rausser's evidence on which we have relied is his evidence about forecasted
    and actual price levels. His price level evidence specifically includes the prices that
    he contends would be required under the antidumping suspension agreement;
    therefore, he obviously does take into account the effect of the antidumping
    proceedings. The dissent's attack on Rausser's conclusion that a conspiracy existed
    is irrelevant to our decision; we do not rely on Rausser's opinion on this ultimate
    question, but have necessarily undertaken our own analysis of whether the evidence
    sufficed to make a prima facie case of conspiracy.
    -9-
    irrelevant because they were sporadic and concerned completed sales. 
    Id. at 1378.
    The magistrate judge similarly disregarded the evidence of competitors complaining
    and threatening each other, because the evidence did not exclude the possibility that
    the competitors on the receiving end of these communications could have ignored the
    threats and complaints and acted independently. E.g., 
    id. at 1375,
    1384. The district
    court adopted the magistrate judge's recommendations and entered summary
    judgment for the defendants. 
    Id. at 1339.
    On appeal, the class argues that the district court misapprehended the summary
    judgment standard, requiring the plaintiffs to establish their case beyond a reasonable
    doubt to avoid summary judgment.
    I.
    The standard for summary judgment in antitrust cases is, of course, the same
    as for summary judgment generally: "[T]he evidence of [the nonmovant] is to be
    believed, and all justifiable inferences are to be drawn in [its] favor." Eastman Kodak
    Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 456 (1992) (emphasis added)
    (quotation omitted); Bathke v. Casey's General Stores, Inc., 
    64 F.3d 340
    , 342-43 (8th
    Cir. 1995) ("We must review the record in the light most favorable to the non-moving
    party. . . ."). However, substantive requirements of the antitrust laws "limit the range
    of permissible inferences from ambiguous evidence in a [Sherman Act] § 1 case."
    Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    , 588 (1986).
    Specifically, "conduct as consistent with permissible competition as with illegal
    conspiracy does not, standing alone, support an inference of antitrust conspiracy."
    
    Id. Often in
    conspiracy cases, the only difference between legal and illegal conduct
    is the existence of an agreement to do the same thing the parties could have done
    legally without an agreement. Naturally, the parties cannot be relied on to confess
    -10-
    that they have entered the forbidden agreement, so conspiracy cases usually must be
    proved by circumstantial evidence. ES Development, Inc. v. RWM Enterprises, Inc.,
    
    939 F.2d 547
    , 553-54 (8th Cir. 1991) (“[I]t is axiomatic that the typical conspiracy
    is rarely evidence by explicit agreements, but must almost always be proved by
    inferences that may be drawn from the behavior of the alleged conspirators.”)
    (quotations omitted), cert. denied, 
    502 U.S. 1097
    (1992). As Justice Powell observed
    in Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 
    465 U.S. 752
    (1984), a case involving
    vertical10 conspiracy to set prices, "[T]he economic effect of . . . unilateral and
    concerted vertical price setting . . . is in many, but not all, cases similar or identical.
    And judged from a distance, the conduct of the parties in the various situations can
    be indistinguishable." 
    Id. at 762
    (citations omitted). Because it is important to
    punish only the forbidden conduct and to avoid deterring legal economic activity,
    
    Matushita, 475 U.S. at 594
    , a submissible antitrust conspiracy case must include some
    evidence that "tends to exclude the possibility of independent action by the [alleged
    conspirators]." 
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 768
    ; 
    Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 574
    .
    In determining whether the evidence tends to exclude independent action, we
    must take into account the defendants' “legitimate business reasons” for their conduct,
    The Corner Pocket v. Video Lottery Technologies, Inc.,
    123 F.3d 1107
    , 1112 (8th Cir.
    1997), cert. denied, ___ U.S. ___, 
    118 S. Ct. 1054
    (1998). If the plaintiffs' evidence
    supports the defendant's theory of the case as easily as the plaintiffs', summary
    judgment for the defendant is proper. See 
    id. at 1109;
    City of Tuscaloosa v. Harcos
    Chemicals, Inc., 
    158 F.3d 548
    , 569 (11th Cir. 1998). Although we must weigh the
    defendants' evidence in the balance in evaluating the sufficiency of the plaintiffs' case,
    Corner 
    Pocket, 123 F.3d at 1112
    , the plaintiffs' evidence only has to "tend to exclude"
    innocent explanation--it does not have to exclude it absolutely. See In re Prescription
    10
    A vertical conspiracy involves people operating at different levels of the
    production and distribution chain, e.g., manufacturers and the wholesalers to whom
    they sell. A horizontal conspiracy involves competitors operating at the same level
    of the production and distribution chain, e.g., rival grocery stores.
    -11-
    Brand Name Drug Antitrust Lit., 
    123 F.3d 599
    , 613 (7th Cir. 1998) (Summary
    judgment in antitrust case not warranted even if key evidence “susceptible of an
    innocent interpretation” because record must be viewed in light most favorable to
    nonmovant), cert. denied, ___ U.S. ___, 
    118 S. Ct. 1178
    (1998); Apex Oil Co. v.
    DiMauro, 
    822 F.2d 246
    , 253, 257 (2d Cir.) (choice between reasonable inferences left
    to the fact-finder at trial), cert. denied, 
    484 U.S. 997
    (1987). Monsanto itself held that
    evidence of a newsletter article should be submitted to a jury where an inference of
    conspiracy from the article was reasonable, but not inevitable. The Court stated: "The
    interpretation of these documents and the testimony surrounding them properly was
    left to the jury." 
    465 U.S. 766
    at n.11. Admittedly, there was other "substantial direct
    evidence" of conspiracy in Monsanto, 
    id. at 765,
    but the newsletter issue points out
    that there is still a role for the jury in choosing among inferences in section one cases.
    The plaintiffs' evidence must amount to more than a scintilla, but the plaintiff does not
    have to outweigh the defendant's evidence item by item. Rossi v. Standard Roofing,
    Inc., 
    156 F.3d 452
    , 466 (3d Cir. 1998). In Monsanto the Court recognized that the
    defendant's evidence had "force," but concluded that the case was properly submitted
    to a jury. 
    465 U.S. 768
    at n.14. "Matsushita demands only that the nonmoving party's
    inferences be reasonable in order to reach the jury, a requirement that was not
    invented, but merely articulated, in that decision." Eastman 
    Kodak, 504 U.S. at 468
    (emphasis added).
    In applying the Monsanto standard, we must view the evidence as a whole,
    rather than asking whether each item of evidence viewed in isolation meets the
    standard. In re Workers' Compensation Ins. Antitrust Lit., 
    867 F.2d 1552
    , 1563 (8th
    Cir.), cert. denied, 
    492 U.S. 920
    (1989); City of Tuscaloosa v. Harcros Chemicals,
    
    Inc., 158 F.3d at 565
    (plaintiffs' expert data and testimony "need not prove the
    plaintiff's case by themselves; they must merely constitute one piece of the puzzle");
    Apex Oil 
    Co., 822 F.2d at 254-55
    .
    We review the district court's determination de novo. 
    Bathke, 64 F.3d at 343
    .
    -12-
    II.
    The type of case alleged here is a good illustration of the abstract principles
    stated in Monsanto and Matsushita. In this case, it is undisputed that PCS, the largest
    firm in a concentrated market (the oligopoly), decided to stop the carnage of price
    wars by raising and stabilizing prices. The other sellers in the industry followed PCS's
    lead and all received higher prices for their potash. This, of course, is what any
    rational oligopolist, not just antitrust villains, would want to do. According to
    accepted economic theory, one would expect a rational oligopolist to raise his price
    hoping the others would follow his lead. The other oligopolists know that if they keep
    their prices low, the brave price leader will simply cut his prices and the battle will
    resume. On the other hand, if they raise their prices in turn, they can content
    themselves with selling less product at a higher price and end up with more money in
    their pockets. See Clamp-All Corp. v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Institute, 
    851 F.2d 478
    , 484-
    85 (1st Cir. 1988) (Breyer, J.), cert. denied, 
    488 U.S. 1007
    (1989). The loser will be
    the consumer, who benefits from competition, not peaceful coexistence between
    suppliers. Even though this phenomenon of "interdependence" or "oligopoly pricing"
    is in a sense anticompetitive, it is legal, so long as it occurs without an agreement
    among the oligopolists. 
    Id. As then-Judge
    Breyer explained:
    Courts have noted that the Sherman Act prohibits agreements, and they
    have almost uniformly held, at least in the pricing area, that such
    individual pricing decisions (even when each firm rests its own decision
    upon its belief that competitors will do the same) do not constitute an
    unlawful agreement under section 1 of the Sherman Act. That is not
    because such pricing is desirable (it is not), but because it is close to
    impossible to devise a judicially enforceable remedy for "interdependent"
    pricing. How does one order a firm to set its prices without regard to the
    likely reactions of its 
    competitors? 851 F.2d at 484
    (emphases in original).
    -13-
    On the other hand, the law can and does prohibit oligopolists from agreeing to
    match prices. If the oligopolists agree to coordinate price increases, their actions may
    look the same as innocent oligopoly pricing from the outside, but they have committed
    a per se violation of section one of the Sherman Act. United States v. Socony-Vacuum
    Oil Co., 
    310 U.S. 150
    , 212-18 (1940). The law forbids nonverbal agreements in
    restraint of trade, as well as express ones; otherwise, the law would be emasculated as
    competitors accomplished the forbidden goal with a wink and a nod. The Supreme
    Court's classic formulation of the conspiracy requirement comes from American
    Tobacco Co. v. United States, 
    328 U.S. 781
    , 809-10 (1946):
    No formal agreement is necessary to constitute an unlawful conspiracy.
    Often crimes are a matter of inference deduced from the acts of the
    person accused and done in pursuance of a criminal purpose. . . . The
    essential combination or conspiracy in violation of the Sherman Act may
    be found in a course of dealings or other circumstances as well as in any
    exchange of words. Where the circumstances are such as to warrant a
    jury in finding that the conspirators had a unity of purpose or a common
    design and understanding, or a meeting of minds in an unlawful
    arrangement, the conclusion that a conspiracy is established is justified.
    (emphasis added) (citations omitted). Accord 
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 768
    (Test is
    whether the evidence "reasonably tends to prove that the manufacturer and others had
    a conscious commitment to a common scheme designed to achieve an unlawful
    objective.").
    Therefore, parallel pricing can result either from legal, almost inevitable
    behavior in a concentrated market, or from an unlawful agreement in restraint of trade.
    Although parallel pricing evidence is consistent with illegal conduct, it is equally
    consistent with lawful conduct, and thus does not tend to exclude the possibility of
    independent action. Parallel pricing in a concentrated market cannot make a
    submissible section one case, although it may set the groundwork for such a case. See
    State of Arizona v. Standard Oil Co. (In re Coordinated Pretrial Proceedings), 906
    -14-
    F.2d 432, 444 (9th Cir. 1990) ("We recognize that such interdependent pricing may
    often produce economic consequences that are comparable to those of classic cartels.
    Nonetheless, proof of such pricing, standing alone, is generally considered insufficient
    to establish a violation of the Sherman Act."), cert. denied, 
    500 U.S. 959
    (1991).
    Numerous courts have stated that plaintiffs can establish a prima facie case of
    conspiracy by showing parallel prices together with "plus factors." E.g., Wallace v.
    Bank of Bartlett, 
    55 F.3d 1166
    , 1168 (6th Cir. 1995), cert. denied, 
    516 U.S. 1047
    (1996); Petruzzi's IGA Supermarkets, Inc. v. Darling-Delaware Co., 
    998 F.2d 1224
    ,
    1232-33 (3d Cir.), cert. denied, 
    510 U.S. 994
    (1993); Apex Oil 
    Co., 822 F.2d at 253
    -
    54; Todorov v. DCH Healthcare Auth., 
    921 F.2d 1438
    , 1456 n.30 (11th Cir. 1991).
    Some factors mentioned as "plus factors" are actually background facts, which though
    they may make the existence of a conspiracy more likely, do not suffice to prove a
    conspiracy. For instance, "motive to conspire","opportunity to conspire" or "high
    level of interfirm communications," all make conspiracy possible, but do not tend to
    exclude the possibility of independent action. Apex 
    Oil, 822 F.2d at 254
    . On the
    other hand, acts that would be irrational or contrary to the defendant's economic
    interest if no conspiracy existed, but which would be rational if the alleged agreement
    existed, do tend to exclude the possibility of independent action. Re/Max Internat'l,
    Inc. v. Realty One, Inc., Nos. 96-3362, 96-3469 and 96-3470, 
    1999 WL 184350
    at *
    11 (6th Cir. April 6, 1999); Harcros 
    Chemical, 158 F.3d at 572
    .
    III.
    In this case, the class pursues a number of plus factor theories, which the district
    court concluded were inadequate to make a prima facie case. Of the “plus factors” that
    merely make conspiracy possible, such as motive and opportunity to conspire, the
    plaintiffs have adduced abundant evidence.
    -15-
    Moreover, the plaintiffs have introduced a significant amount of evidence of
    conduct that we can only characterize as solicitations to enter a price fixing agreement.
    Most, but not all, of the solicitations were by PCS. For instance, PCS freely
    complained to Kalium about Kalium's failure to adhere to pricing cut-offs. It was the
    custom in the industry to give lower prices at times of year when there was no
    immediate need for fertilizer, but to raise prices during high use periods. Kalium
    published price lists announcing the pricing cut-off pattern, but in fact often shipped
    at the lower price after the cut-off date when it did not get orders filled before the cut-
    off date. PCS sales chief Bill Doyle repeatedly upbraided Kalium's Vice President
    Robert Turner for shipping at the lower price after the cut-off date. Turner responded
    "something to the effect" that he would run his own business. Another time, Doyle
    called Turner and advised him that neither PCS, IMC nor Cominco planned to accede
    to a certain customer's request to delay filling an order–that is, to ship at the old price
    after the cut-off. Turner answered that Kalium would try to ship by a certain date,
    which intent it had already published in a letter to its customers. In the same vein,
    Doyle approached Turner about a certain bid and told Turner that Kalium's action was
    “wrong.” John Ripperger, Vice President of PCA, also testified that Doyle asked him
    if PCA was going to institute a price increase and not carry over product at the old
    price; Ripperger interpreted this question to mean that Doyle "would prefer that we
    don't make sales at the old price." Also, Doyle complained to Ripperger that PCA's
    pricing was undermining prices in Florida. Ripperger reported a conversation in
    which Gary Snyder of PCS asked a PCA salesman if he had sold at a certain price, and
    then said, “We [PCS] will take it [price] down and bury you [PCA] if that's what you
    want.” In 1988, after the sale of Kalium, Charles Childers, the CEO of PCS, called on
    Jay Proops, one of Kalium's new owners, armed with a chart showing that PCS was
    losing market share and that Kalium and other producers were gaining. Childers said
    Kalium was undercutting the price. Proops did some research and concluded that
    Childers' chart had incorrect information and that Kalium was not undercutting.
    Therefore, Proops took no action in response to Childers's visit. In August 1990,
    Childers telephoned Joseph Sullivan, the other owner of Kalium. Childers told
    -16-
    Sullivan that PCS's “price leadership was not working, despite major efforts” and that
    Childers “wanted to discuss this issue” with Sullivan. Sullivan declined to discuss
    prices. Another time a PCS employee took advantage of a trade meeting to apologize
    to Kalium's Turner about a low bid PCS had made by mistake. The PCS employee
    testified that he explained the mistake to Turner because he had "some concern that
    it [the low price] may spread in the marketplace," and that he "was hopeful that it
    wouldn't go any darn further." Turner testified that Kalium matched the bid, but the
    reaction was "pretty much confined to that account. It did not go beyond that."
    Though most of these overtures were initiated by PCS, on isolated occasions
    others did the same. Robert Turner of Kalium called John Ripperger of PCA to
    complain about a salesman who was cutting prices in Wisconsin. Similarly, Kip
    Williams of IMC complained to John Ripperger of PCA about price-cutting in Florida.
    The magistrate judge held this solicitation evidence was inadequate to show
    conspiracy for two reasons. First, the magistrate judge stated that the complaints and
    inquiries about pricing cut-offs were only complaints and inquiries, not “requests” to
    stop post-cutoff 
    shipments. 954 F. Supp. at 1376
    . We reject this reasoning because
    it is unlikely that these businessmen would waste their time making telephone calls to
    competitors without any expectation that their calls might have business results. It is
    reasonable to infer that they hoped for a favorable response from these contacts.
    The magistrate judge's second reason for holding that the solicitations did not
    prove conspiracy is that there was no evidence that the people on the receiving end of
    those solicitations accepted them and formed a deal. 
    Id. This is
    an important point.
    The evidence of solicitation is relevant, because it shows conspiratorial state of mind
    on the part of the solicitor and may also indicate that the solicitor was acting upon an
    earlier agreement. 6 Phillip E. Areeda, Antitrust Law § 1419c (1986) (“Besides
    serving as direct evidence of a particular agreement, a solicitation might be
    circumstantial evidence of an ongoing conspiracy. Although no favorable response
    -17-
    to the solicitation is shown, the solicitation itself might be the product of a prior
    agreement.”) (footnote omitted). But though this evidence sets the scene for
    conspiracy, it does not tend to exclude the possibility of innocence, since it only
    definitively shows a guilty intent on the part of the solicitor, rather than a mutual
    meeting of the minds.11 Of course, it is possible to accept a solicitation by acting in
    accord with it, rather than by expressing assent, see Interstate Circuit v. United States,
    
    306 U.S. 208
    , 226-27 (1939), but the defendants can plausibly contend that their
    actions would have been the same regardless of the solicitation. Compare 
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 763
    (complaints together with action consistent with complaint on vertical
    conspiracy case not sufficient evidence of conspiracy) with Brown v. Pro Football
    League, 
    518 U.S. 231
    , 241 (1996) ("Antitrust law also sometimes permits judges or
    juries to premise antitrust liability upon little more than uniform behavior among
    competitors, preceded by conversations implying that later uniformity might prove
    desirable."). The class has not shown actions taken in response to the solicitations that
    are inconsistent with independent action.
    Therefore, the crucial question remains whether the plaintiffs have shown any
    plus factors that do tend to exclude the possibility of independent action. We, like the
    district court, conclude that many of the class’s theories are inadequate to carry the
    plaintiff’s burden under Monsanto,12 but we believe the evidence of price verification
    11
    Commentators observe that even an unaccepted solicitation facilitates
    coordination of prices in an oligopoly, see Areeda, supra, § 1419d, but this is not the
    class's theory in this case.
    12
    In particular, we conclude that the magistrate judge was correct in holding
    that many of the alleged actions against self-interest by the defendants were simply
    one of a number of reasonable actions those defendants could have taken. 
    E.g., 954 F. Supp. at 1363-65
    , 1368. The law does not permit us to second-guess the
    defendants' plausible business decisions. Corner 
    Pocket, 123 F.3d at 1112
    ; see Apex
    
    Oil, 822 F.2d at 254
    . The defendants' decisions to enter the suspension agreement
    instead of trying their luck in a full blown contested proceeding with the Department
    -18-
    communications among competitors does establish a prima facie case, when combined
    with the structure of this industry and supracompetitive pricing.
    The class has produced evidence that the defendant producers cooperated in
    disclosing prices they had charged on particular sales. The industry practice was that
    each producer published a price list stating its price, the dates for which that price
    would be available, and any discounts that the producer would extend. The price lists
    were widely distributed to customers and certainly were no secret. However, actual
    prices sometimes deviated from the lists. For instance, Steve Hoffman of IMC
    testified that the percentage of the time that IMC received list price was small. When
    Childers and Doyle came to PCS, a key aspect of their program to raise industry prices
    was to insist on the list price. Doyle stated in an industry publication: “When I first
    came on board in the spring of 1987, the first word I put out to our sales force was
    that the price list was our price, stick to that price and no bending. Anybody who
    bends was out of here.” Despite published price lists with the high follow-the-leader
    price, the producers continued to undercut each other in privately negotiated deals.
    When word of the discounting got around to PCS, PCS executives, particularly sales
    chief William Doyle, were quite active in contacting the discounter and asking for
    verification of the rumored price. Significantly, Doyle testified that he never made
    any such price verification calls before 1987.13 The number of these verification
    of Commerce, and the decision of PCS to sell potash to PCA are two examples of
    decisions that certainly have a rational basis. Even if later armchair quarterbacks
    disagree with whether they were the most profitable courses of action, reasonable
    people might make these decisions in the absence of an illegal agreement. Therefore,
    such actions do not tend to exclude the possibility of innocence. See Willman v.
    Heartland Hosp. East, 
    34 F.3d 605
    , 611 (8th Cir. 1994), cert. denied, 
    514 U.S. 1018
    (1995).
    13
    There was, however, very sketchy evidence that occasional price verification
    contacts occurred before the alleged conspiracy dates. Gene Jones, a sales manager
    at PCS, testified that employees might ask their competitors about a price if they saw
    -19-
    communications was difficult to pin down, but Bill Doyle estimated he initiated or
    received three to four calls per year with PCA, five to six per year with IMC, three to
    four per year with Cominco, five to six total with Kalium , "a few" with NMPC, and
    one to two total with Noranda. Doyle was by no means the only person making such
    calls on behalf of PCS, and there is evidence that the other defendants called each
    other as well (except that there is no evidence of others calling Noranda).
    These exchanges were often between high level executives who were
    responsible for pricing decisions for their companies or who conveyed the price
    information to those who did set prices. For instance, Dale Massie, Vice-president of
    marketing of Cominco, testified that he had price verification communications with
    Bill Doyle, head of sales at PCS. Massie testified that he made up the Cominco price
    lists, and the evidence shows that Doyle had a key role in determining PCS pricing
    policy. Charles Hoffman at IMC reported price information from Doyle to his
    superiors to inform them that "we would have to meet" PCS's price. Similarly, John
    Ripperger, Vice President of PCA, had price verification discussions with Doyle, and
    Doyle said he had obtained price information from John Huber, Kalium's Vice
    President of Sales. The exchange of information between high level executives, who
    were in a position to respond to what they learned, distinguishes this case from Jacob
    Blinder & Sons v. Gerber Prods. Co. (In re Baby Food Antitrust Litigation), 
    166 F.3d 112
    , 125-26, 135 (3d Cir. 1999), in which the court held that price discussions among
    low level employees did not show a conspiracy. In Baby Food, the court stated: "No
    evidence . . . shows that any executive of any defendant exchanged price or market
    information with any other executive." 
    Id. at 135.14
    each other, but that they were not permitted to telephone each other. He said this
    could have happened a total of three to five times in 1986 and 1987. This evidence
    is too skeletal to seriously undermine the class’s case.
    14
    The dissent argues at pages 41-42, infra, that the facts of Baby Food show
    high-level executives collected information gathered by low-level employees. See
    -20-
    Price verification communications can violate section one in two ways.15 First,
    an agreement to exchange such communications can constitute an unreasonable
    restraint of trade under the rule of reason if the anticompetitive effect of the agreement
    outweighs its beneficial effects. Penne v. Greater Minneapolis Area Board of
    Realtors, 
    604 F.2d 1143
    , 1148 (8th Cir. 1979); In re Coordinated Pretrial
    
    Proceedings, 906 F.2d at 447
    n.13. Second, the exchange of such information can be
    evidence of the existence of an agreement to fix or stabilize prices. See 
    Penne, 604 F.2d at 1149
    ; In re Coordinated Pretrial 
    Proceedings, 906 F.2d at 447
    n.13; In re
    Plywood Antitrust Litigation, 
    655 F.2d 627
    , 633-34 (5th Cir. Unit A 1981); Morton
    Salt Co v. United States, 
    235 F.2d 573
    , 577 (10th Cir. 1956) (competitors' exchange
    of price information “is a factor appropriately considered in determining the existence
    of a conspiracy”). It is this second theory that the class pursues in this case.
    As we have said, acts that would be contrary to the actor's self interest in the
    absence of a conspiracy but which can be explained as part of a conspiracy, provide
    the crucial type of plus factor evidence necessary to exclude the possibility of
    independent action. The class contends that “the price verification calls were
    inconsistent with the 'pricing secrecy' sought by participants in oligopolistic industries
    because in such industries 'each producer would like to secretly “shade” 
    price[s], 166 F.3d at 118-19
    . There is a crucial difference between gathering information to
    use to one's own advantage and giving out information for one's competitors to use
    to their advantage (and one's own detriment). In this case, it is the potash producers'
    pattern of giving their competitors valuable information which we identify as an act
    ostensibly contrary to the producers' self-interest. See page 24, infra.
    15
    The dissent quotes United States v. United States Gypsum Co., 
    438 U.S. 422
    ,
    441 n.16 (1978), in effect for the proposition that exchange of price information
    among competitors is not per se illegal. Infra at page 41 n.25. This proposition is of
    course true, and that is why we state above that such communications violate section
    one only if they fail under the rule of reason or if they are evidence of an agreement
    to fix or stabilize prices. That said, the fact that such exchanges are not per se illegal
    clearly dose not mean that they are always permissible.
    -21-
    thereby gaining sales and avoiding retaliation.'” The class's argument finds support
    in the reasoning of United States v. United States Gypsum Co., 
    438 U.S. 422
    (1978),
    which stated:
    Price concessions by oligopolists generally yield competitive advantages
    only if secrecy can be maintained; when the terms of the concession are
    made publicly known, other competitors are likely to follow and any
    advantage to the initiator is lost in the process. Thus, if one seller offers
    a price concession for the purpose of winning over one of his
    competitor's customers, it is unlikely that the same seller will freely
    inform its competitor of the details of the concession so that it can be
    promptly matched and 
    diffused. 438 U.S. at 456
    (citations omitted). Gypsum's observation about the expected result
    of sharing information with competitors about price concessions is borne out by the
    record in this case. For instance, Steve Hoffman of IMC testified about several cases
    in which he called competitors (PCS and PCA) to ask whether they had really made
    the concessions reported by customers. When PCS and PCA confirmed the price cuts,
    IMC lowered its price to meet them. Similarly, Dean McWilliams of NMPC/Eddy
    recalled a time when Bill Doyle called him and asked about a particular price.
    McWilliams said he “probably confirmed the price,” and that his company then lost
    the order, so he believes that Doyle responded to the information by meeting his price.
    The magistrate judge cited several reasons in holding that the price confirmation
    discussions were immaterial. First, the information concerned completed sales, rather
    than future 
    prices. 954 F. Supp. at 1379
    . This distinction does not appear
    determinative in this case because the defendants said they were interested in the
    completed sales prices because they wanted to know what to charge. For instance,
    David Benusa of Cominco made verification calls so he could "[m]eet a competitive
    price if that opportunity was available."
    -22-
    Second, the magistrate judge discounted the price verifications as “sporadic”
    because they were not coordinated or 
    systematic. 954 F. Supp. at 1379
    . The evidence
    indicates that the defendants called each other when they had reason to think their
    competitors were cutting prices, and that they responded to each other's inquiries. The
    total number of such inquiries is difficult to set, but the defendants characterize it as
    “no more than several dozen”--surely more than a scintilla. Cf. United States v.
    Container Corp., 
    393 U.S. 333
    , 335 (1969) (price-fixing agreement where "all that was
    present was a request by each defendant of its competitors for information as to the
    most recent price charged or quoted, whenever it needed such information" . . .;
    "[t]here was to be sure an infrequency and irregularity of price exchanges.")
    Moreover, Gypsum specifically observed that sporadic exchanges, as opposed to
    coordinated exchanges, were inimical to the self-interest of the party giving the
    
    information. 438 U.S. at 456
    .
    Third, the magistrate judge said that the evidence indicated the defendants were
    not always candid with each other, relying on a statement by one deponent that he was
    “probably” not truthful, and by another that his counterpart at another company had
    refused to discuss prices with 
    him. 954 F. Supp. at 1379
    . These two statements
    cannot cancel out other testimony in which the producers' executives stated that they
    did furnish the requested information and that they based their prices on information
    supplied by competitors. Moreover, the two statements are hardly sufficient to support
    a summary judgment for the defendants. Jerry Jackson of PCS testified that Robert
    Turner of Kalium refused to discuss prices with him, but Turner himself testified that
    this took place after this suit was filed in 1993. Testimony about post-lawsuit
    behavior does not establish conclusively what the defendants' conduct was before the
    lawsuit. Nor should the case hinge on the testimony of Gary Snyder of PCS, who said
    that he "probably" was not truthful in responding to price verification inquiries. This
    statement is uncertain on its face and is not the kind of testimony on which we should
    resolve a case as a matter of law.
    -23-
    Fourth, the magistrate judge held that there was a legitimate business reason for
    the price verification inquiries, because the defendant inquiring wanted to know the
    competitor's selling 
    price. 954 F. Supp. at 1380
    . This is certainly a business reason
    for asking for prices, but the question is whether the competitor supplying the
    information acted contrary to his interest by telling. The Supreme Court in Gypsum
    refused to carve out a safe harbor for verifying customers' reports of prices. The
    defendants argued that the need to verify customer reports about prices to claim a
    “meeting competition” defense under the Robinson-Patman Act should justify
    oligopolistic competitors' practice of asking each other about price concessions. The
    Court concluded that the need to verify customer reports should establish no defense
    under the Sherman Act. The Court reasoned that if there were no agreement to
    provide the information reciprocally, the competitor providing information would be
    acting contrary to his own interest in responding to the 
    request. 438 U.S. at 456
    . If
    there were “an agreement, either tacit or express, providing for reciprocity among
    competitors in the exchange of information” it would likely have the effect of harming
    competition. 
    Id. at 457.
    The Court stated:
    Such an agreement would make little economic sense, in our view, if its
    sole purpose were to guarantee all participants the opportunity to match
    the secret price concessions of other participants . . . . For in such
    circumstances, each seller would know that his price concession could
    not be kept from his competitors and no seller participating in the
    information-exchange arrangement would, therefore, have any incentive
    for deviating from the prevailing price level in the industry. Regardless
    of its putative purpose, the most likely consequence of any such
    agreement to exchange price information would be the stabilization of
    industry prices. . . . [S]uch an agreement would have the effect of
    eliminating the very price concessions which provide the main element
    of competition in oligopolistic industries. . . .
    Especially in oligopolistic industries such as the gypsum board
    industry, the exchange of price information among competitors carries
    with it the added potential for the development of concerted price-fixing
    arrangements which lie at the core of the Sherman Act's prohibitions.
    -24-
    
    Id. at 457
    (citations omitted).
    Thus, in this case, if the price inquiries were unilateral, there would be no good
    reason to respond, as the competitors did. If the exchanges were pursuant to a
    reciprocity agreement, in this oligopoly setting, in which prices rose dramatically, the
    agreement would appear to have been anticompetitive. See Container 
    Corp., 393 U.S. at 340
    (Fortas, J. concurring). Action pursuant to such an agreement is not a
    "legitimate business reason."
    Moreover, these private communications between competitors have no purpose
    of informing customers of prices, such as the advance announcements of price
    increases in Reserve Supply Corp. v. Owens-Corning Fiberglas Corp., 
    971 F.2d 37
    ,
    54 (7th Cir. 1992), or the advertisement of fees in Wallace v. Bank of Bartlett, 
    55 F.3d 1166
    , 1169 and n.5 (6th Cir.1995), cert. denied, 
    516 U.S. 1047
    (1996). Cf.
    Market Force, Inc. v. Wauwatosa Realty Co., 
    906 F.2d 1167
    , 1173 (7th Cir. 1990)
    (defendant broker announced intent to pay reduced commission to buyer's brokers;
    legitimate business reason was that other brokers needed to know in advance what
    commissions defendant was willing to pay). See also United States v. Citizens &
    Southern Nat. Bank, 
    422 U.S. 86
    , 113-14 (1975) (correspondent bank program
    legitimate reason for “intimate and continuous cooperation and consultation on
    interest rates"). To the contrary, the prices stated here were discounts from the
    published price lists that reflected the prices the producers wanted to charge. Nor is
    there any evidence of special necessity for horizontal price communications, such as
    the customer fraud which justified the producers' practices in Cement Manufacturers
    Protective Association v. United States, 
    268 U.S. 588
    , 595-96 (1925). The price
    communications in this case are more like those in In re Coordinated Pretrial
    
    Proceedings, 906 F.2d at 448
    , which served "little purpose" other than facilitating
    price coordination.
    The defendants argue that the evidence shows no anticompetitive effect from
    the defendants' price verification practices, because the depositions showed that when
    -25-
    the producers learned of their competitors' discounts, they matched them, thus
    lowering their prices, not raising them. Though the short term effect of price
    exchanges may have been to lower the price for a particular sale, it is an economic
    truism recognized in Gypsum that, where discounts will be promptly discovered and
    matched, they are less likely to 
    happen. 438 U.S. at 457
    . Thus, the long-term effect
    (and intent) of the pattern of price exchanges could be to stabilize prices, regardless
    of its short-term effect on one sale. See Container 
    Corp., 393 U.S. at 340
    (Fortas, J.,
    concurring) (effect of price exchange was to "'stabilize' prices by joint arrangement--at
    least to limit price cuts to the minimum necessary to meet competition"). More to the
    point, the communications in this case occurred in the context of an industry with
    excess capacity; a sudden end to a price war; the industry giant's publicly avowed
    ambition to lead the industry to higher prices; large price rises above the floor set by
    the suspension agreement; and a pattern of competitors threatening and rebuking each
    other's pricing conduct. To this scene, we add private price verification
    communications among competitors having no legitimate business purpose. This
    evidence of conspiracy to fix and stabilize prices, though by no means unassailable,
    is sufficient to survive summary judgment.
    In addition to the price verification practices, some evidence concerning PCS's
    “market correction program” in December 1989 also tends to exclude the hypothesis
    of independent action. On December 18, 1989, PCS cut its prices by $18 a ton for five
    days. A PCS witness stated that the purpose (and effect) of the program was to
    stabilize prices in the industry.16 While this program was clearly meant to discipline
    price cutters, such price leadership in itself is not illegal. However, a memo written
    by a high level Kalium executive, John Huber, gives rise to an inference that the
    16
    PCS's Carlos Smith testified:
    Q. [W]as it an attempt to stabilize prices?
    A. Yes
    ...
    Q. And did it work?
    A. It leveled them.
    -26-
    program was in response to an earlier agreement. Huber wrote: “Program was a
    market correction. Weren't trying to teach other people. Only got tired of people who
    kept chipping away. Program was reasonable one--checked with people. . . . People
    started cheating . . . . We wanted to get their attention. Program to be short, very
    specific.” (emphasis added) Huber said he did not recall who he had been talking to
    when he made these notes, but the use of the phrase “We wanted to get their attention”
    suggests he was taking dictation from PCS.17 The magistrate judge dismissed this
    memorandum because “it is equally reasonable to read the terms ["cheating"] as
    referring to a general price deterioration, or to prices that were lower than those
    allowed under the Suspension 
    Agreement.” 954 F. Supp. at 1370
    . By this reasoning,
    defendants would be entitled to summary judgment if they could come up with any
    innocent explanation whatsoever for the evidence, no matter how unikely. Under
    Eastman-Kodak it is enough if the plaintiff's inference is reasonable--it does not have
    to be 
    inevitable. 504 U.S. at 468
    . In plain English, the use of the word “cheating”
    implies an agreement or convention, not independent action. Without an agreement,
    price cutting would be called “competing” not “cheating.” The magistrate judge's
    alternative suggestion that PCS was concerned about others cheating under the
    suspension agreement is far-fetched, since, according to Prof. Rausser's chart, the only
    time the prices dipped below the suspension agreement floor levels was in the
    aftermath of PCS's market correction program in January and February 1990. Dipping
    prices below the suspension agreement floor is not a convincing sign of PCS's
    devotion to the agreement. Under the Eastman Kodak standard, the inference of
    conspiracy is reasonable and the class is entitled to the benefit of it.
    17
    Another memorandum in the same time frame prepared by a Noranda
    employee states: “Casual conversation at the SMA meeting with a fairly senior PCS
    guy got quite pointed about 'market correction plan' and he was happy to indicate that
    they could do it again . . . . I don't think the conversation was idle.” The similarity of
    the messages lends additional weight to the inference that PCS was the source of
    information for the Kalium memo.
    -27-
    The class also points to another piece of evidence that, though its probative
    power is not great, does tend to exclude the hypothesis of independent action. This is
    the Canpotex memorandum of Friday, January 8, 1988, which states:
    FYI Canadian potash producers have reached agreement with the United
    States Department of Commerce and all dumping action has been
    suspended for a minimum of 5 years. It is rumored that the USD per
    metric ton increase posted by Canadian producers in 1987 to cover
    possible tariff payments to the U.S. Govt will be refunded in full or part.
    In the meantime new price lists are being issued on Monday Jan. 11 at:
    Standard Grade USD 80.00; Coarse Grade USD 84.00; Granular Grade
    USD 
    86.00. 954 F. Supp. at 1366
    (emphasis added). Canpotex was the Canadian producers' cartel
    organized for sales outside the United States. The prophecy by Canpotex that its
    owners would issue new “price lists” as of Monday, January 11, does indeed tend to
    show the price increase was coordinated, because otherwise it would have been
    impossible to know in advance what the individual producers would do. The
    magistrate judge dismissed this memorandum because of evidence that PCS had
    telexed two customers with its price list during the day of January 8. The court
    inferred that Canpotex could have been referring to the PCS “list,” which could have
    been disclosed by the 
    customers. 954 F. Supp. at 1366
    . However, the class contends
    that the record shows those telexes were transmitted after the close of business on
    Friday, January 8, and therefore are unlikely to have wound their way back to
    Canpotex in time to form the basis for the Canpotex memorandum. Defendants do not
    dispute that the telexes were transmitted late on January 8, but they suggest that the
    Canpotex memorandum can be explained by the hypothesis that someone from PCS
    could have told a customer of the price increase earlier in the day. They cite no
    evidence to support this theory. Defendants also argue the plural word “lists” actually
    meant "PCS's list" and therefore only showed knowledge about one defendants' action.
    Again, the mere possibility of an innocent explanation for evidence that tends to show
    conspiracy does not entitle defendants to summary judgment.
    -28-
    IV.
    As we understand our previous cases, it is still necessary to take into account
    the defendants' explanation of their conduct in order to ascertain whether their theory
    deprives the plaintiffs' case of its probative value. See Corner 
    Pocket, 123 F.3d at 1112
    ; Lovett v. General Motors Corp., 
    998 F.2d 575
    , 580-81 (8th Cir. 1993), cert.
    denied, 
    510 U.S. 1113
    (1994). In this case, the defendants' theory is that the price
    rises are explained entirely by the suspension agreement and the spectre of
    Saskatchewan prorationing legislation. In light of the evidence adduced by Prof.
    Rausser and the Commerce Department correspondence indicating that the industry
    price far exceeded the price floors set by the suspension agreement, we cannot see that
    this explanation deflates the class's price fixing theory. We fully understand that the
    defendants dispute Rausser's understanding of the suspension agreement price levels.
    However, defendants make no attempt to identify a price floor required by the
    suspension agreement or to show that the defendants actually set their price, for
    instance the January 11 price of $86.00 for granular grade, by reference to the
    suspension agreement floor. Indeed, their expert William Barringer argues that it was
    actually impossible to ascertain what price would satisfy the agreement. Instead, the
    defendants' expert Andrew Rosenfield opined that the defendants needed only to set
    their prices "well above" suspension agreement floor prices. Under this theory, the
    suspension agreement did not dictate the actual prices charged; therefore, the existence
    of the suspension agreement does not preclude the class's theory that the actual price
    was set by illegal collusion.
    We therefore reverse the district court's entry of summary judgment, except as
    against Noranda, NMPC/Eddy, and PPG, each of which raises convincing individual
    arguments, which we discuss in section V, infra.
    -29-
    V.
    Among the defendants, Noranda presents a special case, since there is no
    evidence that Noranda participated in supplying price information to other defendants.
    There is slight evidence linking Noranda generally to the exchange of price
    information, since PCS's Bill Doyle testified that Noranda personnel called him once
    or twice to ask about prices. Doyle recalled only one conversation, in which he told
    the Noranda employee that the price that had been reported to Noranda was inaccurate.
    However, there is no evidence that Noranda acted against its ostensible interest by
    giving price information to competitors, as opposed to asking the competitors for
    information; in the absence of such evidence there is simply not a submissible case
    against Noranda. We therefore affirm the district court's entry of summary judgment
    for Noranda.
    Plaintiffs' evidence against NMPC/Eddy also lacks a key ingredient--a showing
    of parallel pricing. Not being subject to the Department of Commerce dumping
    action, these two affiliated American defendants did not announce the $35 increase in
    September 1987. Instead, on September 15, 1987, NMPC announced a two-step
    increase: a $13.50 immediate increase, which would be followed by a $10 additional
    increase effective January 1, 1988. According to the class, this put NMPC at the same
    prices in January that the Canadians posted in January after entering the suspension
    agreement.
    The whole premise of the class's case is parallel pricing. Without parallel
    pricing, their case collapses. See In re Baby Food Antitrust 
    Litigation, 166 F.3d at 128-32
    ; Krehl v. Baskin Robbins Ice Cream Co., 
    664 F.2d 1348
    , 1357 (9th Cir. 1982);
    Meat Price Investigators Ass'n v. Iowa Beef Processors, Inc. (In re Beef Industry
    Antitrust Litigation), 
    907 F.2d 510
    , 514 (5th Cir. 1990) ("When an antitrust plaintiff
    relies on circumstantial evidence of conscious parallelism to prove a § 1 claim, he
    must first demonstrate that the defendant's actions were parallel").
    -30-
    The time gap and the number of important events (such as settlement of the
    Department of Commerce proceedings) between the Americans' action in September
    1987 and the Canadians' post-suspension agreement action in January 1988 defeats
    any inference that those actions were parallel. The class further argues that after
    January 1988 the American defendants refrained from competing on price. However,
    the class's proffered evidentiary support for this argument is quite inadequate. In fact,
    NMPC increased its market share dramatically during this 
    period. 954 F. Supp. at 1365
    . The evidence against NMPC/Eddy cannot survive summary judgment.
    PPG Industries, Inc. and PPG Canada, Ltd., whom we will refer to jointly as
    "PPG," argue that the district court entered judgment for it on the alternative ground
    that its suit was barred by the statute of limitations. PPG points out that the class
    failed to appeal this ruling, since it did not raise the limitations issue in its opening
    brief. PPG filed a motion to dismiss this appeal on this same theory, which motion
    was denied without opinion by another panel. The plaintiffs contend that the
    magistrate judge did not dispose of the statute of limitations question. However, we
    conclude that he did reach that issue as to PPG, 
    see 954 F. Supp. at 1390-91
    , and that
    the district court's order accepted his recommendation that the suit against PPG was
    time-barred. At any rate, the plaintiffs' contention of tolling based on fraudulent
    concealment by PPG has no adequate basis in the record, and PPG is entitled to
    summary judgment.
    We therefore affirm the summary judgment against Noranda, NMPC and Eddy,
    and PPG, and reverse the judgment of the district court and remand for further
    proceedings as to all other appellees.
    BEAM, Circuit Judge, dissenting.
    -31-
    In this Sherman Act case, the court applies its own brand of market-place justice
    through the use of a newly minted, but flawed summary judgment standard. In so
    doing, the court disregards well-established Supreme Court precedent, ignores the
    well-defined law of this circuit and wrongly applies portions of an inapposite Supreme
    Court opinion. I dissent.
    I.    BACKGROUND
    This dispute involves the production and sale of potash, a mineral essential to
    plant growth and therefore used in fertilizer. I will not attempt to restate the
    exhaustive evidence thoroughly discussed by the magistrate judge, but will merely
    summarize the relevant facts and restate specific evidence as reasonably necessary for
    a rational discussion of the issues.
    Both parties, and the court, agree that the North American potash industry is
    an oligopoly.18 Prices in an oligopolistic market tend to be higher than those in a
    purely competitive market, and will fluctuate independently of supply and demand.
    See Enrico Adriano Raffaelli, Oligopolies and Antitrust Law, 19 Fordham Int'l. L. J.
    915, 916 (1996). Furthermore, "price uniformity is normal in a market with few
    sellers and homogeneous products." E.I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co. v. Federal Trade
    Comm'n, 
    729 F.2d 128
    , 139 (2d Cir. 1984). This is because all producers in an
    oligopoly must charge roughly the same price or risk losing market share.
    The Canadian province of Saskatchewan is the source of most potash consumed
    in the United States. The Potash Corporation of Saskatchewan (PCS), founded by the
    province and a defendant in this litigation, holds thirty-eight percent of the North
    18
    An oligopoly is an "[e]conomic condition where only a few companies sell
    substantially similar or standardized products." Black's Law Dictionary 1086 (6th ed.
    1990).
    -32-
    American potash production capacity. As a governmental enterprise, PCS had no
    mandate to maximize profits and was not accountable to private owners. Instead, the
    company was primarily concerned with maintaining employment and generating
    money for the local economy. Not surprisingly, PCS endured huge losses as it mined
    potash in quantities that far outstripped global demand. These policies impacted the
    entire potash industry: during the 1980's, the price of potash fell to an historic low.
    In 1986, Saskatchewan voters elected a provincial government which had promised
    to privatize PCS. New management was appointed to PCS after the elections.
    Thereafter, PCS significantly reduced its output and raised its prices.
    Also in 1986, New Mexico Potash Corporation (NMPC) and another American
    potash producer (who is not a named defendant) filed a complaint with the United
    States Department of Commerce. Frustrated with low potash prices, the petitioners
    alleged that Canadian producers had been dumping their product in the United States
    at prices below fair market value. In 1987, the Department issued a preliminary
    determination that the Canadian producers were dumping potash and ordered the
    companies to post bonds on all exports to the United States. These bonds were set
    according to each firm's calculated "dumping margin." Eventually, the Department
    negotiated a Suspension Agreement with each of the Canadian producers. The
    agreement raised the price of Canadian potash in the United States by setting a
    minimum price at which each Canadian producer could sell in this country.19 This
    agreement remains in effect today. When the Canadian producers entered into the
    Suspension Agreement, PCS announced that it was raising its prices by eighteen
    dollars per ton. Other producers quickly approximated the higher price. The price of
    potash has remained markedly higher after the Suspension Agreement.
    19
    Under the agreement, each firm could sell potash in the United States at less
    than fair market value by an amount equal to 15% of its preliminary dumping margin.
    -33-
    The class alleges that between April 1987 and July 1994 the named defendants20
    (collectively, "the producers") colluded to increase and stabilize the price of potash
    in violation of section 1 of the Sherman Act. The class proceeds under the price fixing
    theory of conscious parallelism. The producers, in turn, maintain that prices were the
    product of the interdependent nature of the industry and its reaction to significant
    external forces. The district court granted the producers' motions for summary
    judgment and the class appeals.
    II.   DISCUSSION
    The class asserts that if we affirm the district court, we will "stand alone in
    holding that circumstantial evidence, even if overwhelming, cannot be used to defeat
    a summary judgment motion in anti-trust cases." We would make no such legal
    history here, however, because the class's proffered evidence, far from overwhelming,
    fails to establish the elements of a prima facie case. The court reverses the district
    court but in the process makes two critical errors: (1) it incorrectly states the standard
    for summary judgment and (2) it incorrectly applies the standard.
    A.     Summary Judgment Standard
    20
    The class named six Canadian potash producers: (1) Potash Corporation of
    Saskatchewan, Inc. and Potash Corporation of Saskatchewan Sales, Ltd. (collectively
    "PCS"); (2) Cominco, Ltd. and Cominco American, Inc. (collectively "Cominco");
    (3) IMC Global, Inc.; (4) Kalium Chemicals, Ltd., Kalium Canada, Ltd. and its former
    owner and operator, PPG Industries, Inc. and PPG Canada, Ltd. (collectively
    "Kalium"); (5) Noranda Mineral, Inc., Noranda Sales Corporation Ltd. and Central
    Canada Potash Co. (collectively "Noranda"); and (6) Potash Corporation of America,
    Inc. and its owner Rio Algom, Ltd. (collectively "PCA"). The American potash
    producers named as defendants are New Mexico Potash Corporation (NMPC) and its
    affiliate Eddy Potash Inc. (Eddy).
    -34-
    The Supreme Court in Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 
    465 U.S. 752
    ,
    764 & 768 (1984) and Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    , 588 (1986), provided the standard used to determine whether the plaintiffs'
    evidence of a section 1 violation survives a summary judgment motion. We are among
    the majority of circuits to apply Monsanto and Matsushita broadly in section 1 price
    fixing cases such as the one before us. See Corner Pocket of Sioux Falls, Inc. v. Video
    Lottery Tech., Inc., 
    123 F.3d 1107
    , 1109 (8th Cir. 1997), cert. denied, 
    118 S. Ct. 1054
    (1998). In order to withstand summary judgment, plaintiffs must present evidence that
    "tends to exclude the possibility of independent action" by the defendants. 
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 764
    & 768. This means that conduct that is "as consistent with permissible
    [activity] as with illegal conspiracy does not, standing alone, support an inference of
    antitrust conspiracy." 
    Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 588
    . Applied in this case, the standard
    requires that from the evidence, if it is as reasonable to infer a price-fixing conspiracy
    as it is to infer permissible activity, then the plaintiffs' claim, without more, fails on
    summary judgment.
    The court, although reciting the Monsanto and Matsushita rule, disregards this
    clear standard by repeatedly citing from Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical
    Services, Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    (1992), a wholly inapposite case. Eastman Kodak was not
    concerned with the sufficiency of evidence of conspiratorial acts, as we are here, but
    rather with whether Eastman Kodak possessed market power sufficient to be guilty of
    "tying."21 
    Id. at 455
    & 459. Eastman Kodak presented a unique factual situation
    totally distinct from the evidentiary underpinnings of this litigation.
    21
    A classic tie-in occurs when a seller conditions the sale of product A on
    purchase of product B. Tying arrangements violate section 1 of the Sherman Act if
    the seller (Eastman Kodak) has appreciable market power in the tying product and if
    the arrangement affects a substantial volume of commerce in the tied product.
    Eastman 
    Kodak, 504 U.S. at 461-62
    .
    -35-
    The misuse of Eastman Kodak, and the damaging impact such misuse had on
    the court's view of the summary judgment standard is clearly evident. The court, for
    instance, quotes Eastman Kodak as stating, "'Matsushita demands only that the
    nonmoving party's inferences be reasonable in order to reach the jury, a requirement
    that was not invented, but merely articulated, in that decision.'" Ante at 12 (quoting
    Eastman 
    Kodak, 504 U.S. at 468
    ). This quotation, of course, is misleading since any
    reasonable inference must still tend to exclude the possibility of independent action.
    Similarly, the court later states "[u]nder Eastman-Kodak it is enough if the plaintiff's
    inference is reasonable." Ante at 27 (concluding that if the inference of conspiracy is
    reasonable, the class is entitled to the benefit of it). In view of the court's mistaken
    approach, it cannot be overemphasized that the Supreme Court has rejected this
    particular summary judgment test and has clearly heightened the standard–the
    evidence must, as indicated, tend to exclude the "possibility" of independent action.
    Interestingly, the court's discussion draws near the proper standard but then,
    inexplicably, proceeds with an analysis that leads it far astray. Proper analysis
    demonstrates that the court has not adhered to the controlling precedent of Monsanto
    and Matsushita especially as this precedent has been broadly construed by this circuit
    in Corner Pocket.
    B.     Applying the Standard
    The class's price-fixing claim is based on a theory of conscious parallelism.
    Conscious parallelism is the process "not in itself unlawful, by which firms in a
    concentrated market might in effect share monopoly power, setting their prices at a
    profit-maximizing, supracompetitive level by recognizing their shared economic
    interests." Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    ,
    227 (1993). The class and the court point out that the producers' prices were roughly
    equivalent during the alleged conspiracy, despite differing production costs. They
    -36-
    further note that price changes by one producer were quickly met by the others. This
    establishes only that the producers consciously paralleled each other's prices.
    Evidence that a business consciously met the pricing of its competitors does not
    prove a violation of the antitrust laws. See Theatre Enter., Inc. v. Paramount Film
    Distrib. Corp., 
    346 U.S. 537
    , 540-41 (1954). Particularly when the product in question
    is fungible, as potash is, courts have given parallel pricing little probative weight. See
    Bendix Corp. v. Balax, Inc., 
    471 F.2d 149
    , 160 (7th Cir. 1972). Even the court
    concedes that "parallel pricing [is] almost inevitable" in a market situation such as this.
    Ante at 14. An agreement is properly inferred from conscious parallelism only when
    certain "plus factors" exist. See In re Baby Food Antitrust Litigation, 
    166 F.3d 112
    ,
    122 (3d Cir. 1999); see, e.g., Admiral Theatre Corp. v. Douglas Theatre Co., 
    585 F.2d 877
    , 884 (8th Cir. 1978) (requiring evidence that defendant acted contrary to self-
    interest in addition to evidence of conscious parallelism to establish antitrust
    violation). A plus factor refers to "'the additional facts or factors required to be
    proved as a prerequisite to finding that parallel [price] action amounts to a
    conspiracy.'" In re Baby 
    Food, 166 F.3d at 122
    (quoting 6 Phillip E. Areeda, Antitrust
    Law § 1433(e) (1986)).
    The plaintiff has the burden to present evidence of consciously paralleled
    pricing supplemented with one or more plus factors. See Todorov v. DCH Healthcare
    Auth., 
    921 F.2d 1438
    , 1456 n.30 (11th Cir. 1991). However, even after carrying the
    initial burden, a court must still conclude, based upon all the evidence before it, that
    the plaintiff's evidence tends to exclude the possibility of independent action. See
    
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 764
    & 768; 
    Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 588
    ; see also In re Baby
    
    Food, 166 F.3d at 122
    . As noted, the class identified parallel pricing. The class also
    asserts several possible plus factors. The court rejects all22 but one, concluding that
    22
    The court extensively reviews the class's allegations that motive to conspire,
    opportunity to conspire, solicitation, a high level of interfirm communications, and
    -37-
    "we believe the evidence of price verification communications among competitors"
    constitutes a sufficient plus factor. Ante at 18-19.
    In my view, the class's price verification evidence is far too ambiguous to
    constitute a plus factor that supports an inference of conspiracy. Cf. Corner 
    Pocket, 123 F.3d at 1112
    (finding a letter to be too ambiguous to help the plaintiffs defeat
    summary judgment). In any event, considering the evidence as a whole, the price
    verification evidence does not tend to exclude the possibility of independent action,
    as required under Monsanto and Matsushita, since other significant events strongly
    suggest independent action. The fundamental difficulty with the class's argument
    regarding price verifications is that it assumes a conspiracy first, and then sets out to
    "prove" it. And the court has apparently adopted this approach. However, a litigant
    may not proceed by first assuming a conspiracy and then explaining the evidence
    accordingly.
    The class's evidence shows that possibly several dozen price verifications
    occurred between employees, including high-level sales employees, of different
    companies,23 over at least a seven-year period. These contacts involved the
    certain alleged actions against self-interest constitute plus factors. These are all either
    completely rejected or given insignificant weight as "background facts, which . . . do
    not suffice to prove a conspiracy." Ante at 15. For example, the class asserts
    evidence that the producers acted against their self-interests by participating in the
    Suspension Agreement. See, e.g., Petruzzi's IGA Supermarkets, Inc. v. Darling-
    Delaware Co., 
    998 F.2d 1224
    , 1243-45 (3d Cir. 1993) (denying defendants' motion
    for summary judgment where defendants refrained from bidding aggressively on
    accounts already serviced by other defendants). The court summarily rejected this
    contention. Ante at 18 n.12. Thus, the information is generally gratuitous and
    irrelevant.
    23
    It is noteworthy that the court cites price communications involving
    defendant companies that it subsequently finds not to have participated in the alleged
    conspiracy (Noranda and NMPC/Eddy). See, e.g., Ante at 20 & 29-30.
    -38-
    verification of "prices they had charged on particular sales." Ante at 19 (emphasis
    added). The downfall of this circumstantial evidence of an agreement to fix prices is
    that it bears no relationship to the price increases most in question because it lacks the
    logical link necessary to infer such a relationship.
    The class alleges that the price-fixing conspiracy began "at least as early as
    April, 1987." Complaint at 11. In 1987, the price for potash was at historically low
    levels, such that producers were losing millions of dollars. Then, a sudden and
    dramatic increase in price by PCS occurred on September 4, 1987, and approximately
    a week later the remaining producers followed suit.24 The class and the court argue
    that the large and parallel price rises which were nearly simultaneous combine with
    the price verifications to create an inference sufficient to survive summary judgment.
    The problem with this theory is that the price verification evidence only applied
    to prices already charged on particular sales, not to future broad market prices. The
    court overlooks a critical causal link in this: there is no evidence to support the
    inference that the price verifications had an impact on price increases. The only
    evidence is that prices were possibly cut as a result. "[T]o survive summary judgment,
    there must be evidence that the exchanges of information had an impact on pricing
    decisions." In re Baby 
    Food, 166 F.3d at 125
    (citing Krehl v. Baskin-Robbins Ice
    Cream Co., 
    664 F.2d 1348
    , 1357 (9th Cir. 1982)). There is no evidence here that price
    increases resulted from any price verification or any particular communication of any
    kind. How can subsequent price verification evidence on particular sales support a
    conspiracy for the setting of a broad market price on September 4, 1987? It cannot.
    24
    This price increase was rescinded in the wake of the Suspension Agreement.
    In its place came a much smaller increase on January 11, 1988 by PCS–three days
    after the Suspension Agreement created a price floor–which was followed thereafter
    by the remaining producers.
    -39-
    Even if we find the price verification evidence relevant, when considered with
    all the facts, it does not tend to exclude the possibility of independent action. To the
    contrary, there is strong evidence of independent action. Just before and concurrent
    with the suspect price increases, the following occurred: the price of potash was at
    historic lows and the producers were losing millions; potash companies in the United
    States complained to the United States Department of Commerce that the Canadian
    producers were dumping potash at well-below market value; the Department of
    Commerce made a preliminary determination that the Canadian producers were
    dumping and required expensive bonds for all imports; the industry leader, the
    government founded PCS, hired new management and began privatization with the
    goal of becoming profitable; legislation was passed in the province of
    Saskatchewan–the source of nearly all U.S. potash–that provides for the setting and
    prorating of potash production; potash producers reached a Suspension Agreement
    with the Department of Commerce that sets price floors for potash; and PCS was
    finally privatized and significantly reduced its output. In the face of these
    circumstances and with the price leadership of PCS in this oligopolistic industry, it
    would be ridiculous to think that the remaining companies would not also raise their
    prices in a parallel fashion. The class's weak circumstantial evidence that the dramatic
    increases were the result of a price-fixing agreement is not sufficient to survive
    summary judgment. This leaves only the question whether there is sufficient evidence
    to support an agreement to stabilize and maintain prices in violation of section 1 of the
    Sherman Act.
    The court's evidence of an agreement to maintain the price of potash at an
    artificially high level after the initial price increases is again the parallel pricing and
    price verifications. Parallel pricing is conceded, leaving the burden once again on the
    price verifications. It is common sense to think that a conspiracy to fix a price
    involves a company that communicates with another company before the price
    quotation to the customer. Here, in every instance, we have communications to verify
    -40-
    a price on a completed sale. To escape this logical conclusion, the court makes several
    unconvincing arguments.
    The court points to a statement by one witness, that he made verification calls
    in part to see if he could "[m]eet a competitive price if that opportunity was available."
    Ante at 22. This sounds strangely like competition since the participants are lowering
    prices to compete. In response to this argument, the court contends that although in
    the short-term the prices are lowered, the long-term effect is to maintain artificially
    high prices.25 However, the class's own evidence establishes that there was a
    continual decline in the price for potash over the years in question. Appellants'
    Appendix at 1422-29.
    Further detrimental to the court's theory are its own statements that companies
    seldom received the listed price for the product and "continued to undercut each other
    in privately negotiated deals." Ante at 19. I suppose that the court is arguing, without
    evidence one way or the other, that the slow decline in price was not a fast enough
    decline. This seems to be getting into the very ambiguous and speculative territory the
    Supreme Court has sought to avoid in section 1 claims. See 
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 762-64
    ; 
    Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 594
    . The Supreme Court has held that when
    circumstantial evidence is ambiguous, summary judgment should be granted to the
    defendants. See 
    Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 763
    -64.
    25
    The Supreme Court has also noted that:
    The exchange of price data and other information among competitors
    does not invariably have anticompetitive effects; indeed such practices
    can in certain circumstances increase economic efficiency and render
    markets more, rather than less, competitive.
    United States v. United States Gypsum Co., 
    438 U.S. 422
    , 441 n.16 (1978).
    -41-
    The price verifications relied upon were also sporadic and testimony suggests
    that price verifications were not always given. The fact that there were several dozen
    communications is not so significant considering the communications occurred over
    at least a seven-year period, a period in which there may have been tens of thousands
    of transactions. Furthermore, you would expect companies to verify prices
    considering this is an oligopoly and accounts are very large. These facts further
    undermine the already speculative assertions of the court. The evidence falls far short
    of excluding the possibility of independent action.
    A recent case that demonstrates the frailty of the court's analysis is In re Baby
    Food Antitrust Litigation, 
    166 F.3d 112
    (3d Cir. 1999). The defendants, nationally
    prominent corporations with 98% of the baby food business, were Gerber, H.J. Heinz,
    and Beech-Nut. The numerous intercompany pricing communications found by the
    Third Circuit to be insufficient to support a section 1 violation are tersely dismissed
    by the court as "price discussions among low level employees." Ante at 20. However,
    the deposition testimony revealed that district sales employees and district sales
    managers of Heinz, one of the alleged conspirators, "were required to submit
    competitive activity reports to their superiors concerning baby food sales from
    information they picked up from competitor sales representatives." In re Baby 
    Food, 166 F.3d at 118-19
    . This same line of testimony revealed that supervising managers
    for Heinz informed district managers "on a regular basis before any announcement to
    the trade as to when Heinz's competitors were going to increase [their] wholesale list
    prices." 
    Id. at 119.
    The president of Beech-Nut, another alleged conspirator, "testified
    that it was [Beech-Nut's] policy for sales representatives to gather and report pricing
    information of [Beech-Nut's] competitors." 
    Id. (emphasis added).
    Indeed, the In re
    Baby Food case is replete with evidence that pricing information was systematically
    obtained and directed to high-level executives of Gerber (including Gerber's vice
    president of sales), Beech-nut and Heinz, the principal national competitors in the
    baby food industry. So, for the court to disregard the holding in In re Baby Food
    because "'[n]o evidence . . . shows that any executive of any defendant [Gerber,
    -42-
    Beech-Nut and Heinz] exchanged price or market information with any other
    executive,'" Ante at 20 (quoting In re Baby 
    Food, 166 F.3d at 135
    ) (emphasis added),
    is to blithely ignore the fact that a carefully conceived and effective system of price
    information gathering for the benefit of corporate executives was at all relevant times
    alive and well in the baby food industry.26
    Notwithstanding communications that far surpassed any information exchanges
    established in this case, the Third Circuit correctly applied Matsushita and granted
    summary judgment to the defendants. In doing so, the Third Circuit aptly noted that
    "to survive summary judgment [on the basis of exchanged pricing information] there
    26
    In its footnote 14, the court purports to find a difference in price discussions
    where one purported conspirator gathers information and another purported
    conspirator gives the information. This difficult to understand argument makes
    nothing more than a distinction without a difference, especially here where there is
    clearly no evidence connecting any price discussions with the fixing, increasing or
    maintaining of a price level. See In re Baby 
    Food, 166 F.3d at 125
    . The only
    evidence is to the contrary and dramatizes the court's flawed reasoning. When price
    verifications were made, there was no evidence that the companies increased prices
    or even held the line on prices. Instead, the court itself depicts producers cutting
    prices in response to confirmed price cuts by another producer on a particular sale.
    In one instance, the producer who verified a price was then underbid and lost the
    order. Ante at 22-23. It is difficult to understand the reasoning that, on this evidence,
    transforms this from an obviously competitive market to a collusive agreement to fix
    prices. What the court has done, contrary to its own admonition, is view the price
    verifications in isolation without considering their actual results or attempting to
    make a connection with the fixing of prices. See Ante at 12 ("In applying the
    Monsanto standard, we must view the evidence as a whole, rather than asking
    whether each item of evidence viewed in isolation meets the standard." (citing In re
    Workers' Compensation Ins. Antitrust Lit., 
    867 F.2d 1552
    , 1563 (8th Cir. 1989); City
    of Tuscaloosa v. Harcros Chems., Inc., 
    158 F.3d 548
    , 565 (11th Cir. 1998); Apex Oil
    Co. v. DiMauro, 
    822 F.2d 246
    , 254-55 (2d Cir. 1987))).
    -43-
    must be evidence that the exchanges of information had an impact on pricing
    decisions." In re Baby 
    Food, 166 F.3d at 125
    (citing 
    Krehl, 664 F.2d at 1357
    ). As
    earlier stated, there is absolutely no such evidence in this litigation, only speculation.
    Finally, the class argues, in a last ditch effort, that its expert's econometric
    model provided crucial confirmation that the prevailing potash prices during the
    alleged conspiracy were above those expected in the absence of collusion. Cf. 
    Id. (rejecting a
    similar argument). We need not decide whether such evidence, in a proper
    case, could constitute a plus factor, because the report in this case is not probative of
    collusion.
    The class's expert evidence is lacking in two crucial respects. First, the expert
    admits that his model fails to take into account the dramatic events surrounding the
    price increases: namely the privatization of PCS and the anti-dumping proceedings.
    Second, the expert's report, as the magistrate judge noted, relies almost exclusively on
    evidence (such as the producers' common membership in trade associations and their
    publication of price lists to customers) that is not probative of collusion as a matter of
    law. The expert's model is fundamentally unreliable because of heavy (if not
    exclusive) reliance on evidence that is not probative of conspiracy, coupled with his
    failure to consider significant external forces that unquestionably served to raise the
    price of potash. See Loudermill v. Dow Chem. Co., 
    863 F.2d 566
    , 570 (8th Cir.
    1988).
    III.   CONCLUSION
    The class has failed to present evidence of collusion sufficient to preclude
    summary judgment under Monsanto and Matsushita. The producers are therefore
    entitled to summary judgment. For the foregoing reasons, the decision of the district
    court should be affirmed. I dissent from the court's holding to the contrary.
    -44-
    A true copy.
    ATTEST:
    CLERK, U.S. COURT OF APPEALS, EIGHTH CIRCUIT.
    -45-
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 97-1330

Filed Date: 5/7/1999

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 10/13/2015

Authorities (37)

Clamp-All Corporation v. Cast Iron Soil Pipe Institute , 851 F.2d 478 ( 1988 )

april-wallace-and-vickie-gwin-v-bank-of-bartlett-boatmens-bank-of , 55 F.3d 1166 ( 1995 )

alexandre-b-todorov-md-individually-and-neurology-clinic-pc-an , 921 F.2d 1438 ( 1991 )

E.I. Du Pont De Nemours & Company v. Federal Trade ... , 729 F.2d 128 ( 1984 )

apex-oil-company-v-joseph-dimauro-triad-petroleum-inc-tic-commodities , 822 F.2d 246 ( 1987 )

Morton Salt Company, Royal Crystal Salt Company, Deseret ... , 235 F.2d 573 ( 1956 )

es-development-inc-and-edwin-g-sapot-v-rwm-enterprises-inc-dba , 939 F.2d 547 ( 1991 )

Reserve Supply Corporation v. Owens-Corning Fiberglas ... , 971 F.2d 37 ( 1992 )

joseph-rossi-rossi-florence-corp-rossi-roofing-inc-v-standard-roofing , 156 F.3d 452 ( 1998 )

in-re-beef-industry-antitrust-litigation-mdl-docket-no-248-meat-price , 907 F.2d 510 ( 1990 )

1993-1-trade-cases-p-70293-39-fed-r-evid-serv-234-petruzzis-iga , 998 F.2d 1224 ( 1993 )

market-force-incorporated-v-wauwatosa-realty-company-coldwell-banker , 906 F.2d 1167 ( 1990 )

in-re-baby-food-antitrust-litigation-jacob-blinder-sons-inc-wiseway , 166 F.3d 112 ( 1999 )

in-re-plywood-antitrust-litigation-french-quarter-apartments-ltd-v , 655 F.2d 627 ( 1981 )

gilbert-bathke-valoris-bathke-ronald-condon-lanina-condon-panora-oil , 64 F.3d 340 ( 1995 )

Thomas G. Lovett, Trustee of the Bankruptcy Estate of John ... , 998 F.2d 575 ( 1993 )

Ca 79-3319 John Penne and Penne Realty, Inc., a Minnesota ... , 604 F.2d 1143 ( 1979 )

Abraham Loudermill and Joyce Loudermill v. The Dow Chemical ... , 863 F.2d 566 ( 1988 )

The Corner Pocket of Sioux Falls, Inc. v. Video Lottery ... , 123 F.3d 1107 ( 1997 )

charles-r-willman-md-v-heartland-hospital-east-heartland-hospital-west , 34 F.3d 605 ( 1994 )

View All Authorities »