Horne v. United States Department of Agriculture , 750 F.3d 1128 ( 2014 )


Menu:
  •                  FOR PUBLICATION
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
    MARVIN D. HORNE and LAURA R.              No. 10-15270
    HORNE, DBA RAISIN VALLEY
    FARMS, a partnership, and DBA                D.C. No.
    RAISIN VALLEY FARMS MARKETING             1:08-cv-01549-
    ASSOCIATION, AKA RAISIN VALLEY               LJO-SMS
    MARKETING, an unincorporated
    association; MARVIN D. HORNE;
    LAURA R. HORNE; DON DURBAHN,                OPINION
    and the ESTATE OF RENA DURBAHN,
    DBA LASSEN VINEYARDS, a
    partnership,
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,
    v.
    UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF
    AGRICULTURE,
    Defendant-Appellee.
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Eastern District of California
    Lawrence J. O’Neill, District Judge, Presiding
    Argued and Submitted
    February 14, 2014—San Francisco, California
    Filed May 9, 2014
    2                        HORNE V. USDA
    Before: Stephen Reinhardt, Michael Daly Hawkins,
    and Ronald M. Gould, Circuit Judges.
    Opinion by Judge Hawkins
    SUMMARY*
    Taking
    Following a reversal and remand from the United States
    Supreme Court, the panel affirmed the district court’s
    summary judgment in favor of the United States Secretary of
    Agriculture in an action alleging that the Secretary’s
    regulatory program for California’s raisin producers violated
    the Takings Clause of the Fifth Amendment.
    Pursuant to the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of
    1937, the Department of Agriculture implemented a
    “Marketing Order” to ensure orderly market conditions by
    regulating raisin supply. The Secretary required California
    producers of certain raisins to divert a percentage of their
    annual crop to a reserve, and the Secretary could impose a
    penalty on producers who failed to comply with the diversion
    program. Plaintiffs, California raisin producers, alleged that
    the Secretary worked a constitutional taking by depriving
    raisin producers of their personal property, the diverted
    raisins, without just compensation.
    *
    This summary constitutes no part of the opinion of the court. It has
    been prepared by court staff for the convenience of the reader.
    HORNE V. USDA                           3
    As a threshold issue, the panel held that the plaintiffs had
    standing to bring this constitutional challenge. Turning to the
    merits, the panel held that the Marketing Order and its
    penalties did not work a physical per se taking. The panel
    concluded that the Marketing Order’s reserve requirements -
    and the provisions permitting the Secretary to penalize the
    plaintiffs for failing to comply with those requirements - did
    not constitute a taking under the Fifth Amendment.
    COUNSEL
    Michael W. McConnell (argued), John C. O’Quinn and
    Joseph F. Cascio, Kirkland & Ellis LLP, Washington, D.C.,
    and Brian C. Leighton, Clovis, California, for Plaintiffs-
    Appellants.
    Stuart F. Delery, Acting Assistant Attorney General, Joshua
    Waldman (argued) and Michael S. Raab, Attorneys,
    Appellate Staff, Civil Division, United States Department of
    Justice, Washington, D.C.; Benjamin B. Wagner, United
    States Attorney, and Benjamin E. Hall, Assistant United
    States Attorney, Fresno, California, for Defendant-Appellee.
    OPINION
    HAWKINS, Senior Circuit Judge:
    To ensure stable market conditions, the Secretary of
    Agriculture, administering a complex regulatory program,
    requires California producers of certain raisins to divert a
    percentage of their annual crop to a reserve. The percentage
    of raisins diverted to the reserve varies annually according to
    4                         HORNE V. USDA
    that year’s crop output. Subject to administrative and judicial
    review, the Secretary can impose a penalty on producers who
    fail to comply with the diversion program. The program’s
    goal is to keep raisin supply relatively constant from year to
    year, smoothing the raisin supply curve and thus bringing
    predictability to the market for producers and consumers
    alike.    The diverted raisins are sold, oftentimes in
    noncompetitive markets, and raisin producers are entitled to
    a pro rata share of the sales proceeds less administrative
    costs. In some years, this “equitable distribution” is
    significant; in other years it is zero.
    Eschewing any Commerce Clause or regulatory takings
    theory, Plaintiffs-Appellants Marvin and Laura Horne (“the
    Hornes”) challenge this regulatory program and, in particular,
    the Secretary’s ability to impose a penalty for non-
    compliance, as running afoul of the Takings Clause of the
    Fifth Amendment.1         Specifically, the Hornes argue
    Defendant-Appellee the Department of Agriculture (“the
    Secretary”), charged with overseeing the diversion program,
    works a constitutional taking by depriving raisin producers of
    their personal property, the diverted raisins, without just
    compensation. The Secretary defends the constitutionality of
    the reserve requirement. Concluding the diversion program
    1
    Collectively referred to as “the Hornes,” the Plaintiffs-Appellants are
    Marvin and Laura Horne, d/b/a Raisin Valley Farms (a California general
    partnership), and d/b/a Raisin Valley Farms Marketing Association (a
    California unincorporated association), together with their business
    partners Don Durbahn and the Estate of Rena Durbahn, collectively d/b/a
    Lassen Vineyards (a California general partnership).
    HORNE V. USDA                                5
    does not work a constitutional taking on the theory advanced
    by the Hornes, we affirm the judgment of the district court.2
    FACTUAL AND PROCEDURAL BACKGROUND
    A
    Raisin prices rose rapidly between 1914 and 1920,
    peaking in 1921 at $235 per ton. This surge in prices spurred
    increased production, which in turn caused prices to plummet
    back down to between $40 and $60 per ton, even while
    production continued to expand. As a result of this growing
    disparity between increasing production and decreasing
    prices, the industry became “compelled to sell at less than
    parity prices and in some years at prices regarded by students
    of the industry as less than the cost of production.” Parker v.
    Brown, 
    317 U.S. 341
    , 364 (1943); see 
    id. at 363–64
    &
    nn.9–10; see also Zuber v. Allen, 
    396 U.S. 168
    , 174–76
    (1969) (describing market conditions). See generally Daniel
    Bensing, The Promulgation of Implementation of Federal
    Marketing Orders Regulating Fruit and Vegetable Crops
    Under the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937,
    5 San Joaquin Agric. L. Rev. 3 (1995) (describing the history
    of the AMAA and the structure of the regulatory program it
    authorizes).
    This market upheaval pervaded the entire agriculture
    industry, prompting Congress to enact the Agricultural
    Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, as amended, 7 U.S.C.
    2
    In doing so, we note the Court of Federal Claims has also upheld the
    constitutionality of this regulatory program. See Evans v. United States,
    
    74 Fed. Cl. 554
    , 558 (2006), aff’d, 250 F. App’x. 321 (Fed. Cir. 2007)
    (unpub.).
    6                         HORNE V. USDA
    § 601 et seq. (“AMAA”), to bring consistency and
    predictability to the Nation’s agricultural markets. Pursuant
    to the AMAA, the Department of Agriculture implemented
    the Marketing Order Regulating the Handling of Raisins
    Produced from Grapes Grown in California, 7 C.F.R. Part 989
    (“Marketing Order”), in 1949 in direct response to the market
    conditions described in Parker.
    The Marketing Order ensures “orderly” market conditions
    by regulating raisin supply. 7 U.S.C. § 602(1). The Secretary
    has delegated to the Raisin Administrative Committee
    (“RAC”) the authority to set an annual “reserve tonnage”
    requirement, which is expressed as a percentage of the overall
    crop.3 See 7 C.F.R. §§ 989.65–66. The remaining raisins are
    “free tonnage” and can be sold on the open market. The
    reserved raisins are diverted from the market to smooth the
    peaks of the raisin supply curve. 
    Id. at §
    989.67(a). To
    smooth the supply curve’s valleys, reserved raisins are
    released when supply is low. By varying the reserve
    requirement annually, the RAC can adapt the program to
    address changing growing and market conditions. For
    example, in the 2002–03 and 2003–04 crop years at issue
    here, the reserve percentages were set at forty-seven percent
    and thirty percent of the annual crop, respectively.
    The operation of the Marketing Order turns on a
    distinction between “producers” and “handlers.”           A
    “producer” is a “person engaged in a proprietary capacity in
    3
    The RAC is currently comprised of forty-seven industry-nominated
    representatives appointed by the Secretary, of whom thirty-five represent
    producers, ten represent handlers, one represents the cooperative
    bargaining association, and one represents the public. See 7 C.F.R.
    §§ 989.26, 989.29, and 989.30.
    HORNE V. USDA                                  7
    the production of grapes which are sun-dried or dehydrated
    by artificial means until they become raisins . . . .” 7 C.F.R.
    § 989.11. By contrast, included in the definition of a
    “handler,” 
    id. at 989.15,
    is any person who “stems, sorts,
    cleans, or seeds raisins, grades stemmed raisins, or packages
    raisins for market as raisins,” 
    id. at 989.14.4
    Raisin producers
    convey their entire crop to a handler, receiving a pre-
    negotiated field price for the free tonnage. 
    Id. at §
    989.65.
    Handlers, who sell free tonnage raisins on the open market,
    bear the obligation of complying with the Marketing Order by
    diverting the required percentage of each producer’s raisins
    to “the account of the [RAC].” 
    Id. § 989.66(a).
    Handlers
    must also prepare the reserved raisins for market, and the
    RAC compensates them for providing this service. 
    Id. at §
    989.66(f).
    The RAC tracks how many raisins each producer
    contributes to the reserve pool. When selling the raisins, the
    RAC has a regulatory duty to sell them in a way that
    “maxim[izes] producer returns.” 
    Id. at §
    989.67(d)(1). The
    RAC, which receives no federal funding, finances its
    operations and the disposition of reserve raisins from the
    proceeds of the reserve raisin sales. Whatever net income
    remains is disbursed to producers, who retain a limited equity
    4
    Specifically, any person who “stems, sorts, cleans, or seeds raisins,
    grades stemmed raisins, or packages raisins for market as raisins” is a
    “packer” of raisins, and all packers are handlers. 7 C.F.R. §§ 989.14 &
    989.15. These definitions apply only to activities taking place within “the
    area,” which simply refers to the State of California. 
    Id. at §
    989.4.
    Additionally, any producer who sorts and cleans his own raisins in
    their unstemmed form is not a packer with respect to those raisins. 7
    C.F.R. § 989.14.
    8                         HORNE V. USDA
    interest in the RAC’s net income derived from reserved
    raisins. See 7 U.S.C. § 608c(6)(E); 7 C.F.R. § 989.66(h).
    B
    Dissatisfied with what they view as an out-dated
    regulatory regime, the Hornes set out to restructure their
    raisin operation such that the Marketing Order would not
    operate against them. Put another way, the Hornes came up
    with a non-traditional packing program which, in their view,
    the Secretary had no authority to regulate. Instead of sending
    their raisins to a traditional packer, against whom the reserve
    requirement of the Marketing Order would clearly operate,
    the Hornes purchased their own handling equipment to clean,
    stem, sort, and package raisins. The Hornes then performed
    the traditional functions of a handler with respect to the
    raisins they produced. The Hornes believed that, by cleaning,
    stemming, sorting, and packaging their own raisins, they
    would not be “handlers” with respect to the raisins they
    produced. In addition, the Hornes performed the same
    functions for a number of other producers for a per-pound
    fee. Similarly, by not acquiring title to the raisins of other
    producers but rather charging those producers a per-pound
    fee, the Hornes believed they did not fall within the
    regulatory definition of “handler” with respect to the third-
    party producers’ raisins. With this set-up, the Hornes
    believed the requirements of the Marketing Order would not
    apply to them, relieving them of the obligation to reserve any
    raisins.5
    5
    The government contends the Hornes lack standing to assert a takings
    defense with respect to raisins they never owned, i.e., raisins produced by
    third parties. The government concedes the Hornes have standing to
    assert a takings defense with respect to raisins they produced themselves.
    HORNE V. USDA                                    9
    C
    The Secretary disagreed with the Hornes and applied the
    Marketing Order to their operation with respect to the raisins
    grown both by the Hornes and by third-party producers. At
    the end of protracted administrative proceedings, a U.S.D.A.
    Judicial Officer found the Hornes liable for numerous
    regulatory violations and imposed a monetary penalty of
    $695,226.92.6 The Hornes then sought review of that final
    agency action in federal district court pursuant to 7 U.S.C.
    § 608c(14)(B). In district court, the Hornes alleged they were
    not “handlers” within the meaning of the regulation and
    further alleged the agency’s order violated the Takings Clause
    and the Eighth Amendment’s prohibition against excessive
    fines. The district court granted summary judgment in favor
    We decline to decide what rights under California law a non-title
    holder has to challenge the “taking” of property in his possession. See
    Vandevere v. Lloyd, 
    644 F.3d 957
    , 963 (9th Cir. 2011) (holding that for
    the takings claim “whether a property right exists . . . is a question of state
    law”) (emphasis omitted). Here, it is enough to note the Hornes clearly
    have standing to assert a taking defense with respect to the raisins they
    produced themselves, entitling them to a decision on the merits for at least
    that property. Because we rule against the Hornes on the merits, we need
    not further address the standing issue.
    6
    The Judicial Officer ordered the Hornes to pay (1) $8,783.39 in
    overdue assessments for the 2002–03 and 2003–04 crop years,
    (2) $483,843.53 as the dollar equivalent for the raisins not held in reserve,
    and (3) $202,600 as a civil penalty for failure to comply with the
    Marketing Order. The overdue assessments in their entirety and $25,000
    of the civil penalty were imposed for violations of the Marketing Order
    unrelated to the reserve requirement. See, e.g., 7 C.F.R. § 989.73
    (requiring handlers to file certain reports); 
    id. at §
    989.77 (requiring
    handlers to allow the Agricultural Marketing Service access to records).
    The balance of the penalty and assessments pertain directly to the Hornes’
    failure to reserve raisins.
    10                         HORNE V. USDA
    of the Secretary on all counts. See Horne v. U.S. Dep’t of
    Agric., No. CV-F-08-1549 LJO SMS, 
    2009 WL 4895362
    (E.D. Cal. filed Dec. 11, 2009).
    The Hornes appealed to this court. We affirmed the
    district court with respect to the Hornes’ statutory claims,
    holding that even if the AMAA’s definitions of “handler” and
    “producer” are ambiguous, the Secretary’s application of the
    Marketing Order to the Hornes was neither arbitrary nor
    capricious, and it was supported by substantial evidence.
    Horne v. U.S. Dep’t of Agric., 
    673 F.3d 1071
    , 1078 (9th Cir.
    2011) (“Horne I”). We also affirmed the district court’s grant
    of summary judgment in favor of the Secretary on the Eighth
    Amendment claim. 
    Id. at 1080–82.
    And we held we lacked
    jurisdiction over the Fifth Amendment claim. Specifically,
    we held the Hornes brought their takings claim as producers
    rather than handlers. Because the AMAA did not in our view
    displace the Tucker Act with respect to a producer’s claim,
    we held that jurisdiction over the takings claim fell with the
    Court of Federal Claims rather than the district court. 
    Id. at 1078–80.
    The Hornes sought and the Supreme Court granted
    certiorari with respect to the jurisdictional issue.7 Reversing
    our judgment on that issue alone, the Supreme Court held (1)
    7
    Because the Hornes’ certiorari petition only challenged our disposition
    of the Hornes’ Fifth Amendment claim, Horne I is the final judgment of
    the Hornes’ Eighth Amendment and statutory claims. Accordingly,
    because the statutory claims are no longer at bar, the Hornes concede they
    no longer challenge the Judicial Officer’s imposition of $8,783.39 in
    overdue assessments or the related $25,000 in civil penalties. The Hornes’
    challenge is confined to the remaining dollar value equivalent and its
    attendant civil penalty (hereinafter, “the penalty”), because these are
    directly traceable to the Hornes’ failure to reserve raisins. 
    See supra
    n.5.
    HORNE V. USDA                            11
    the Hornes brought their takings claim as handlers, and
    (2) the Hornes, as handlers, may assert a constitutional
    defense to the underlying agency action in district court.
    Horne v. Dep’t of Agric., 
    133 S. Ct. 2053
    , 2061, 2062 (2013).
    (The Supreme Court reserved the question of whether the
    Hornes could have sought relief in the Court of Federal
    Claims, instead holding only that handlers could obtain
    judicial review in district court. 
    Id. at 1062
    n.7.) The
    Supreme Court remanded for a determination of the merits of
    the Hornes’ takings claim, which, having received
    supplementary briefing and additional oral argument, we now
    decide.
    STANDARD OF REVIEW
    We review de novo a district court’s grant of summary
    judgment in a case involving a constitutional challenge to a
    federal regulation. Ariz. Life Coal., Inc. v. Stanton, 
    515 F.3d 956
    , 962 (9th Cir. 2008); Doe v. Rumsfeld, 
    435 F.3d 980
    , 984
    (9th Cir. 2006).
    STANDING
    The Secretary contends the Hornes lack standing to
    challenge the portion of the penalty attributable to the sale of
    any raisins produced by third-party firms, then handled by the
    Hornes (the “third-party raisins”). The Secretary argues the
    Hornes never owned these raisins and so cannot challenge
    their seizure.8 We find this argument unpersuasive.
    8
    The Secretary concedes the Hornes have standing to challenge the
    remainder of the penalty.
    12                         HORNE V. USDA
    As the Supreme Court made clear, the injury suffered by
    the Hornes is not the obligation to reserve raisins for the RAC
    (which, of course, the Hornes did not do), but rather to pay
    the penalty imposed for the Hornes’ failure to comply with
    the Marketing Order. 
    Horne, 133 S. Ct. at 2061
    n.4. Thus,
    the government’s contention that the Hornes would not have
    standing to challenge a government seizure of the third-party
    raisins (a seizure which, of course, never happened) is
    irrelevant to the standing inquiry here.9
    Instead, we analyze whether the Hornes have standing to
    challenge the penalty. A monetary penalty is an actual,
    concrete and particularized injury-in-fact. Sacks v. Office of
    Foreign Assets Control, 
    466 F.3d 764
    , 771 (9th Cir. 2006)
    (citing Cent. Ariz. Water Conserv. Dist. v. EPA, 
    990 F.2d 1531
    , 1537 (9th Cir. 2006)); see Lujan v. Defenders of
    Wildlife, 
    504 U.S. 555
    , 560 (1992). The need to pay a
    penalty is obviously traceable to its imposition, and a
    favorable merits determination in this litigation would redress
    the Hornes’ alleged injury, thereby satisfying the Lujan
    requirements. See 
    Lujan, 504 U.S. at 560
    –61. We thus hold
    9
    Additionally, we doubt the government’s contention that the Hornes
    would lack standing to challenge a seizure of property they held in
    bailment. In an analogous situation, we have held that individuals lacking
    an ownership interest in a given piece of property have standing to
    challenge the seizure of that property. See United States v. $191,910 in
    U.S. Currency, 
    16 F.3d 1051
    , 1057 (9th Cir. 1994) (“In order to contest
    a forfeiture, a claimant need only have some type of property interest in
    the forfeited items. This interest need not be an ownership interest; it can
    be any type of interest, including a possessory interest.”), superseded on
    other grounds by statute as stated in United States v. $80,180.00, 
    303 F.3d 1182
    , 1184 (9th Cir. 2002). In any event, because we hold the Hornes
    have established standing as the subjects of the penalty, we need not
    confront this question.
    HORNE V. USDA                        13
    the Hornes have standing to bring this constitutional
    challenge.
    CONSTITUTIONAL CLAIM
    The Takings Clause does not prohibit the government
    from taking property for public use; rather, it requires the
    government to pay “just compensation” for any property it
    takes. U.S. Const. amend. V. Thus, a takings challenge
    follows a two-step inquiry. First, we must determine whether
    a “taking” has occurred; that is, whether the complained-of
    government action constitutes a “taking,” thus triggering the
    requirements of the Fifth Amendment. If so, we move to the
    second step and ask if the government provided just
    compensation to the former property owner. Brown v. Legal
    Found. of Wash., 
    538 U.S. 216
    , 231–32, 235–36 (2003); First
    English Evangelical Lutheran Church of Glendale v. Cnty. of
    L.A., 
    482 U.S. 304
    , 314 (1987).
    However, before turning to the first step of this formula,
    we must address a threshold issue and identify precisely
    which property was allegedly taken from the Hornes.
    A
    The Hornes declined to comply with the reserve
    requirement of the Marketing Order; at no time did the
    Hornes, either as producers or as handlers, ever physically
    convey raisins to the RAC. Instead, the Secretary imposed
    the penalty on the Hornes for their failure to comply with the
    Marketing Order. In general, the imposition and collection of
    penalties and fines does not run afoul of the Takings Clause.
    See Koontz v. St. Johns River Water Management District,
    
    133 S. Ct. 2586
    , 2601 (2013) (listing cases). Here, however,
    14                        HORNE V. USDA
    the Hornes link the Secretary’s imposition of a penalty to a
    specific governmental action they allege to be a taking. In
    effect, the Hornes argue the constitutionality of the penalty
    rises or falls with the constitutionality of the Marketing
    Order’s reserve requirement.
    We agree that the penalty cannot be analyzed without
    reference to the reserve requirement, and we find Koontz
    instructive on this point. In Koontz, a permitting agency
    refused to grant a developer a building permit until the
    developer funded offsite environmental impact mitigation
    
    works. 133 S. Ct. at 2593
    . The developer sued, arguing the
    permitting agency’s conditions for obtaining a permit violated
    the “nexus and rough proportionality” rule of Nollan v.
    California Coastal Commission, 
    483 U.S. 825
    (1987), and
    Dolan v. City of Tigard, 
    512 U.S. 374
    (1994).10 The Supreme
    Court of Florida declined to apply Nollan and Dolan, because
    in those cases the permitting agencies granted the relevant
    permit subject to a condition subsequent. The Florida court
    did not believe Nollan and Dolan would apply to situations in
    which the permitting agency refused to issue a permit until
    the permittee met a condition precedent. The Supreme Court
    reversed, holding the distinction between conditions
    precedent and subsequent constitutionally irrelevant in this
    context. See 
    id. at 2596.
    Relevant to this case, Koontz confronts the issue of how
    to analyze a takings claim when a “monetary exaction,” rather
    than a specific piece of property, is the subject of that claim.
    Koontz distinguished Eastern Enterprises v. Apfel, 
    524 U.S. 498
    (1988), by noting that in Koontz, “unlike Eastern
    Enterprises, the monetary obligation burdened petitioner's
    10
    We discuss Nollan and Dolan in more detail in Section D.
    HORNE V. USDA                              15
    ownership of a specific parcel of land.” 
    Koontz, 133 S. Ct. at 2599
    ; accord 
    id. at 2600
    (“The fulcrum this case turns on is
    the direct link between the government’s demand and a
    specific parcel of real property.”). This direct linkage
    between the monetary exaction and the piece of land guided
    the Court to invoke the substantive takings jurisprudence
    relevant to the land for the purpose of determining whether
    the related monetary exaction constituted a taking. 
    Id. Here, the
    Secretary specifically linked a monetary
    exaction (the penalty imposed for failure to comply with the
    Marketing Order) to specific property (the reserved raisins).
    The Hornes faced a choice: relinquish the raisins to the RAC
    or face the imposition of a penalty. There is no question the
    monetary exaction is linked to specific property because the
    Judicial Officer’s order requires the Hornes to repay the
    market value of the unreserved raisins (plus an additional
    penalty for non-compliance). Because the Marketing Order
    is structured in this way, we follow Koontz to analyze the
    constitutionality of the penalty imposed on the Hornes against
    the backdrop of the reserve requirement. If the Secretary
    works a constitutional taking by accepting (through the RAC)
    reserved raisins, then, under the unconstitutional conditions
    doctrine, the Secretary cannot lawfully impose a penalty for
    non-compliance. But if the receipt of reserved raisins does
    not violate the Constitution, neither does imposition of the
    penalty. See 
    id. at 2596
    (discussing the unconstitutional
    conditions doctrine).11
    11
    Contrary to the Hornes’ suggestion, however, we read Koontz only to
    say this much. The Hornes argue Koontz somehow substantively altered
    the doctrinal landscape against which we evaluate takings claims. We
    disagree. Koontz simply clarifies the range of takings cases in which
    Nollan and Dolan provide the rule of decision. 
    See 133 S. Ct. at 2598
    16                        HORNE V. USDA
    B
    We return to the task of determining whether the
    imposition of the penalty for failure to comply with the
    reserve requirement constitutes a taking. A “paradigmatic
    taking” occurs when the government appropriates or occupies
    private property. Lingle v. Chevron U.S.A., Inc., 
    544 U.S. 528
    , 537 (2005). Lingle gives as an example of this sort of
    taking the government’s wartime seizure of a coal mine. Id.;
    see United States v. Pewee Coal Co., 
    341 U.S. 114
    , 115–16
    (1951). Because the government neither seized any raisins
    from the Hornes’ land nor removed any money from the
    Hornes’ bank account, the Hornes cannot—and do
    not—argue they suffered this sort of “paradigmatic taking.”
    Instead, we must enter the doctrinal thicket of the
    Supreme Court’s regulatory takings jurisprudence. Since
    Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 
    260 U.S. 393
    (1945), the
    Court has recognized that “government regulation of private
    property may, in some instances, be so onerous that its effect
    is tantamount to a direct appropriation or ouster—and that
    such ‘regulatory takings’ may be compensable . . . .” 
    Lingle, 544 U.S. at 538
    . In general, regulatory takings are analyzed
    under the ad hoc framework announced in Penn Central
    Transportation Co. v. City of New York, 
    438 U.S. 104
    , 124
    (1978). The Hornes, however, have intentionally declined to
    pursue a Penn Central claim. Instead, they argue the
    (declining to address merits of petitioner’s claim under Nollan and Dolan);
    
    id. at 2602–03
    (declining to alter or overrule the holdings of Nollan and
    Dolan).
    HORNE V. USDA                                17
    Marketing Order, though a regulation, works a categorical
    taking.12
    Since Mahon, the Supreme Court has identified three
    “relatively narrow categories” of regulations which work a
    categorical, or per se, taking. Each category has a
    paradigmatic or representative case. 
    Lingle, 544 U.S. at 538
    .13 The representative case of the first category, Loretto
    v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp., 
    458 U.S. 419
    ,
    427–38 (1982), holds that permanent physical invasions of
    real property work a per se taking. The second, represented
    by Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 
    505 U.S. 1003
    ,
    1015 (1992), teaches that regulations depriving owners of all
    economically beneficial use of their real property also work
    a per se taking. The third line of cases, represented by Nollan
    and Dolan, articulate a more nuanced rule. Together, Nollan
    and Dolan hold that a condition on the grant of a land use
    permit requiring the forfeiture of a property right constitutes
    a taking unless the condition (1) bears a sufficient nexus with
    and (2) is roughly proportional to the specific interest the
    government seeks to protect through the permitting process.
    12
    Similarly, the Hornes concede the AMAA and Marketing Order fall
    within Congress’s Commerce Clause authority. However, that a
    governmental action is authorized by the Commerce Clause does not
    immunize it from the requirements of the Takings Clause. 
    Lingle, 544 U.S. at 543
    ; Kaiser Aetna v. United States, 
    444 U.S. 164
    , 172 (1979).
    13
    We read Lingle to elevate the land use exaction cases to a third
    category on par with permanent physical invasions and complete
    economic deprivation 
    regulations. 544 U.S. at 538
    (“Outside these two
    categories (and the special context of land-use exactions discussed below),
    regulatory takings challenges are governed by Penn Central Transp. Co.
    v. New York City.”) (citation omitted and emphasis added).
    18                    HORNE V. USDA
    If those two conditions are met, then the imposition of the
    conditional exaction is not a taking.
    We must determine which analytical framework provides
    the proper point of departure for our inquiry into whether a
    taking has occurred here. The Hornes see a direct analogy
    between Loretto’s occupation of land for the purpose of
    installing an antenna and the Marketing Order’s reserve
    requirement. The Secretary argues Nollan and Dolan provide
    better guidance to evaluate the constitutionality of what the
    Secretary characterizes as a use restriction on raisins. We
    must first identify which of the categorical takings case lines,
    if any, the Marketing Order implicates. Second, we must
    apply that case line’s substantive law to determine whether a
    taking has occurred.
    C
    Loretto applies only to a total, permanent physical
    invasion of real property. Two independent reasons assure us
    that the Marketing Order does not fall within the “very
    narrow” scope of the Loretto 
    rule, 458 U.S. at 441
    : First, the
    Marketing Order operates on personal, rather than real
    property, and second, the Marketing Order is carefully crafted
    to ensure the Hornes are not completely divested of their
    property rights, even with respect to the reserved raisins.
    1
    The Marketing Order operates against personal, rather
    than real, property. Because the Takings Clause undoubtedly
    protects personal property, see Phillips v. Wash. Legal
    Found., 
    524 U.S. 156
    , 172 (1998) (interest earned on
    lawyers’ trust account is a protected private property); Brown,
    HORNE V. USDA                        
    19 538 U.S. at 235
    (same); Ruckelshaus v. Monsanto Co.,
    
    467 U.S. 986
    , 1001–04 (1984) (same for trade secrets), this
    distinction does not mean the Takings Clause is inapplicable.
    But, as the Supreme Court stated in Lucas, the Takings
    Clause affords less protection to personal than to real
    property:
    [O]ur “takings” jurisprudence . . . has
    traditionally been guided by the
    understandings of our citizens regarding the
    content of, and the State’s power over, the
    “bundle of rights” that they acquire when they
    obtain title to property. It seems to us that the
    property owner necessarily expects the uses of
    his property to be restricted, from time to
    time, by various measures newly enacted by
    the State in legitimate exercise of its police
    powers; as long recognized, some values are
    enjoyed under an implied limitation and must
    yield to the police power. And in the case of
    personal property, by reason of the State’s
    traditionally high degree of control over
    commercial dealings, he ought to be aware of
    the possibility that new regulation might even
    render his property economically worthless (at
    least if the property’s only economically
    productive use is sale or manufacture for
    sale). In the case of land, however, we think
    the notion pressed by the Council that title is
    somehow held subject to the “implied
    limitation” that the State may subsequently
    eliminate all economically valuable use is
    inconsistent with the historical compact
    20                     HORNE V. USDA
    recorded in the Takings Clause that has
    become part of our constitutional culture.
    
    Lucas, 505 U.S. at 1027
    –28.
    Lucas uses comparative language to make clear the
    Takings Clause affords more protection to real than to
    personal property. While the precise contours of these
    differing levels of protection are not entirely sharp, Lucas
    suggests the government’s authority to regulate such property
    without working a taking is at its apex where, as here, the
    relevant governmental program operates against personal
    property and is motivated by economic, or “commercial,”
    concerns. Indeed, it is clear the holding of Lucas is limited to
    cases involving land. The sentence which rejects the State’s
    contention that “the State may subsequently eliminate all
    economically valuable use” of the Lucas’s property begins
    with the phrase “[i]n the case of land” and is expressly
    contrasted against commercial personal property, over which
    the government exerts a “traditionally high degree of
    control.” 
    Id. at 1028.
    The real/personal property distinction also undergirds
    Loretto. Justifying its bright-line rule, Loretto states
    “whether a permanent physical occupation has occurred
    presents relatively few problems of proof. The placement of
    a fixed structure on land or real property is an obvious fact
    that will rarely be subject to 
    dispute.” 458 U.S. at 437
    (emphasis added). This example underscores the narrow
    reach of Loretto. In reaching its decision, the Court discussed
    the evolution of its takings jurisprudence, citing virtually only
    cases pertaining to real property. See 
    id. at 427–37.
    And
    because the case unquestionably (and solely) concerned real
    property, the Loretto Court did not have occasion to consider
    HORNE V. USDA                                21
    the occupation of personal property. Given the Court’s later
    discussion of personal property in Lucas, we see no reason to
    extend Loretto to govern controversies involving personal
    property. See also Wash. Legal Found. v. Legal Found. of
    Wash., 
    271 F.3d 835
    , 854 (9th Cir. 2001) (en banc), aff’d sub
    nom., Brown v. Legal Found. of Wash., 
    538 U.S. 216
    (2003)
    (“The per se analysis has not typically been employed outside
    the context of real property. It is a particularly inapt analysis
    when the property in question is money.”).
    2
    Equally importantly, the Hornes did not lose all
    economically valuable use of their personal property. Unlike
    Loretto, which applies only when each “‘strand’ from the
    ‘bundle’ of property rights” is “chop[ped] through . . . taking
    a slice of every 
    strand,” 458 U.S. at 435
    , the Hornes’ rights
    with respect to the reserved raisins are not extinguished
    because the Hornes retain the right to the proceeds from their
    sale. See 7 U.S.C. § 608c(6)(E); 7 C.F.R. § 989.66(h). The
    Hornes essentially call this right meaningless because the
    equitable distribution may be zero.14 But, the equitable
    distribution is not zero in every year, and even in years with
    a zero distribution, there are gross proceeds from the sale of
    the reserved raisins; it just so happens that in those years,
    those gross proceeds are not greater than the operating
    expenses of the RAC.
    14
    The parties dispute whether there was a distribution for the crop years
    in question and, if so, the value of that distribution. We do not consider
    this dispute material to the question of whether a taking occurred because
    the distribution reflects net revenue. For the reasons we give, we focus on
    the gross revenue generated by the reserve raisin pool.
    22                       HORNE V. USDA
    Here, we pause to focus on the RAC’s structure and
    purpose, as well as the benefits it secures for producers such
    as the Hornes. The RAC is governed by industry
    representatives including producers and handlers.15 Its
    purpose is to stabilize market conditions for raisin producers.
    Thus, the Hornes’ equitable stake in the reserved raisins, even
    in years in which they are not entitled to a cash distribution
    from the RAC, funds the administration of an industry
    committee tasked with (1) representing raisin producers, such
    as the Hornes, and (2) implementing the reserve requirement,
    the effect of which is to stabilize the field price of raisins. In
    light of this scheme, the Hornes cannot claim they lose all
    rights associated with the reserve raisins. Indeed, the
    structure of the diversion program ensures the reserved
    raisins continue to work to the Hornes’ benefit after they are
    diverted to the RAC, even in years in which producers
    receive no equitable distribution of the RAC’s net profits.16
    For these reasons, the Hornes’ reliance on Loretto is
    unavailing. Loretto specifically preserves the state’s
    “substantial authority” and “broad power to impose
    appropriate restrictions upon an owner’s use of his 
    property.” 458 U.S. at 441
    . Here, the reserved raisins are not
    permanently occupied; rather, their disposition, while tightly
    controlled, inures to the Hornes’ benefit. Coupled with
    15
    In fact, Mr. Horne has been an alternate member, though never a
    voting member, of the RAC.
    16
    We must clarify that we do not hold the RAC’s market intervention
    constitutes “just compensation” for a taking. Because we hold no taking
    occurs, we do not conduct a just compensation inquiry. We discuss the
    RAC’s purpose and organization solely to show that the Hornes’ rights to
    the reserved raisins, even if diminished by the Marketing Order, are not
    extinguished by it.
    HORNE V. USDA                                23
    Lucas’s distinction between real and personal property, this
    assures us the diversion program does not work a per se
    taking.17
    D
    Instead of looking to Loretto for the rule of decision here,
    the Secretary urges us to apply the “nexus and rough
    proportionality” rule of Nollan and Dolan to this case, asking
    us in essence to hold that the reserve requirement constitutes
    a use restriction on the Hornes’ personal property and then
    analogize that use restriction to the land use permitting
    context. We believe this approach is the most faithful way to
    apply the Supreme Court’s precedents to the Hornes’ claim.18
    In Nollan, the California Coastal Commission conditioned
    the grant of a permit to build a beachfront home on the
    landowner’s surrender of an easement along the coastal side
    of the property in order to link two public beaches by a
    publically accessible 
    path. 483 U.S. at 828
    . However, the
    Commission’s proffered reason for imposing this condition
    was to mitigate the diminished “visual access” to the ocean
    17
    Nor would the Hornes fare any better under a Lucas theory. Lucas
    plainly applies only when the owner is deprived of all economic benefit
    of the 
    property. 505 U.S. at 1019
    & n. 8. If the property retains any
    residual value after the regulation’s application, Penn Central applies. 
    Id. The equitable
    stake, even in years where there is no monetary distribution,
    is clearly not valueless, and thus Lucas does not apply.
    18
    We do not mean to suggest that all use restrictions concerning
    personal property must comport with Nollan and Dolan. Rather, we hold
    Nollan and Dolan provide an appropriate framework to decide this case
    given the significant but not total loss of the Hornes’ possessory and
    dispositional control over their reserved raisins.
    24                    HORNE V. USDA
    from the non-coastal edge of the property caused by the
    Nollan’s proposed improvement. 
    Id. at 828–29.
    The
    Supreme Court held there was no “nexus” between the
    exaction-by-condition and the Commission’s asserted state
    interest, then held that, absent such a nexus, the imposition of
    the condition was a taking. 
    Id. at 837.
    Dolan provides us the analytical framework to apply in
    cases where a legitimate nexus exists between the asserted
    state interest and the proposed exaction. In Dolan, a
    landowner sought permits to enlarge and improve her
    commercial property. As in Nollan, the permitting agency
    approved the permit subject to certain conditions. First, the
    agency required the dedication of certain creek-side land for
    the purpose of mitigating the increased water run-off that
    could potentially occur as a result of the landowner’s plan to
    pave a parking lot. Second, the agency required the
    dedication of a 15-foot strip of land to be used for a
    pedestrian and bicycle pathway, the purpose of which was to
    mitigate the increased traffic flow spawned by the proposed
    commercial 
    development. 512 U.S. at 380
    . Dolan held there
    was an appropriate nexus between the state’s legitimate
    interests and the proposed exactions. 
    Id. at 387–88.
    But Dolan also held the proposed means and the ends in
    question were not “roughly proportional[]” to each other and
    thus the permit as issued constituted a taking. 
    Id. at 391;
    see
    
    id. at 394–96.
    While not reducible to mathematical certainty,
    the Dolan “rough proportionality” requirement does require
    a permitting agency to “make some sort of individualized
    determination that the required dedication is related both in
    nature and extent to the impact of the proposed
    development.” 
    Id. at 391.
    Thus, the distillate of the
    Nollan/Dolan rule appears to be this: If the government seeks
    HORNE V. USDA                          25
    to obtain, through the issuance of a conditional land use
    permit, a property interest the outright seizure of which would
    constitute a taking, the government’s imposition of the
    condition also constitutes a taking unless it: (1) bears a
    sufficient nexus with and (2) is roughly proportional to the
    specific interest the government seeks to protect through the
    permitting process.
    We apply the Nollan/Dolan rule here because we believe
    it serves to govern this use restriction as well as it does the
    land use permitting process. At bottom, the reserve
    requirement is a use restriction applying to the Hornes insofar
    as they voluntarily choose to send their raisins into the stream
    of interstate commerce. The Secretary did not authorize a
    forced seizure of the Hornes’ crops, but rather imposed a
    condition on the Hornes’ use of their crops by regulating their
    sale. As we explained in a similar context over seventy years
    ago, the Marketing Order “contains no absolute requirement
    of the delivery of [reserve-tonnage raisins] to the [RAC]” but
    rather only “a conditional one.” Wallace v. Hudson-Duncan
    & Co., 
    98 F.2d 985
    , 989 (9th Cir. 1938) (rejecting a takings
    challenge to a reserve requirement under the walnut
    marketing order); see also Yee v. City of Escondido, 
    503 U.S. 519
    , 527–28 (1992) (holding municipal regulation of a
    mobile home park owners’ ability to rent did not work a
    taking where park owners voluntarily rented their land and
    thus acquiesced in the regulation); cf. Ruckelshaus, 
    467 U.S. 986
    , 1070 (1994) (“a voluntary submission of data by an
    applicant in exchange for the economic advantages of a
    registration can hardly be called a taking”).
    Moreover, there are important parallels between Nollan
    and Dolan on one hand and the raisin diversion program on
    the other. All involve a conditional exaction, whether it be
    26                     HORNE V. USDA
    the granting of an easement, as in Nollan; a transfer of title,
    as in Dolan; or the loss of possessory and dispositional
    control, as here. All conditionally grant a government benefit
    in exchange for an exaction. And, critically, all three cases
    involve choice. Just as the Nollans could have continued to
    lease their property with the existing bungalow and Ms.
    Dolan could have left her store and unpaved parking lot as
    they were, the Hornes, too, can avoid the reserve requirement
    of the Marketing Order by, as the Secretary notes, planting
    different crops, including other types of raisins, not subject to
    this Marketing Order or selling their grapes without drying
    them into raisins. Given these similarities, we are satisfied
    the rule of Nollan and Dolan governs this case.
    1. The Nexus Requirement
    We now turn to the nexus requirement and ask if the
    reserve program “further[s] the end advanced as [its]
    justification.” 
    Nollan, 483 U.S. at 837
    . Unquestionably, the
    AMAA aims to “establish and maintain . . . orderly marketing
    conditions for agricultural commodities,” 7 U.S.C. § 602(1),
    as well as to keep consumer prices stable, 
    id. at §
    602(2). By
    reserving a dynamic percentage of raisins annually such that
    the domestic raisin supply remains relatively constant, the
    Marketing Order program furthers the end advanced:
    obtaining orderly market conditions. The government
    represents (and the Hornes do not dispute) that by smoothing
    the peaks and valleys of the supply curve, the program has
    eliminated the severe price fluctuations common in the raisin
    industry prior to the implementation of the Marketing Order,
    making market conditions predictable for industry and
    consumers alike. On this basis, the Marketing Order satisfies
    the Nollan nexus requirement.
    HORNE V. USDA                              27
    2. The Rough Proportionality Requirement
    Dolan does not require a “precise mathematical
    calculation,” instead obliging the permitting agency only to
    make an “individualized determination” that the condition
    imposed is “related both in nature and extent to the impact”
    of the permittee’s activity. 
    Dolan, 512 U.S. at 391
    . The
    Marketing Order meets this requirement. The percentage of
    raisins to be reserved is revised annually to conform to
    current market conditions. While Dolan does not require a
    “mathematical calculation,” neither does it prohibit the RAC
    from imposing a condition stated mathematically, i.e., as a
    percentage. Indeed, here the RAC’s imposition of the reserve
    requirement is not just in “rough” proportion to the goal of
    the program, but in more or less actual proportion to the end
    of stabilizing the domestic raisin market.19 By annually
    modifying the “extent,” 
    id., of the
    reserve requirement to
    keep pace with changing market conditions, the RAC ensures
    its program does not overly burden the producer’s ability to
    compete while reducing to the producer’s benefit the potential
    instability of this particular market.
    Nor do we believe Dolan’s command that the condition
    imposed be “individualized” presents a problem here. As
    Dolan made clear, it was an adjudicative, not a legislative,
    decision being 
    reviewed. 512 U.S. at 835
    . Individualized
    review makes sense in the land use context because the
    development of each parcel is considered on a case-by-case
    19
    The Hornes do not challenge the adequacy or fairness of the RAC’s
    decision to set the 2002–03 and 2003–04 reserve tonnage requirements at
    forty-seven percent and thirty percent, respectively. In other words, the
    Hornes’ challenge is to the program itself, not the details of its
    implementation in the crop years at issue.
    28                       HORNE V. USDA
    basis. But here, the use restriction is imposed evenly across
    the industry; all producers must contribute an equal
    percentage of their overall crop to the reserve pool. At
    bottom, Dolan’s individualized review ensures the
    government’s implementation of the regulations is tailored to
    the interest the government seeks to protect. The Marketing
    Order accomplishes this goal by varying the reserve
    requirement annually in accordance with market and industry
    conditions. Given that raisins are fungible (as opposed to
    land, which is unique), we think this is enough to ensure the
    means of the Marketing Order’s diversion program is at least
    roughly proportional to its goals.20
    CONCLUSION
    While the Hornes’ impatience with a regulatory program
    they view to be out-dated and perhaps disadvantageous to
    smaller agricultural firms is understandable, the courts are not
    well-positioned to effect the change the Hornes seek, which
    is, at base, a restructuring of the way government regulates
    raisin production. The Constitution endows Congress, not the
    courts, with the authority to regulate the national economy.
    See United States v. Rock Royal Co-op, Inc., 
    307 U.S. 533
    ,
    572 (1939). Accordingly, it is to Congress and the
    Department of Agriculture to which the Hornes must address
    their complaints. The courts are not institutionally equipped
    20
    We reiterate that we analyze the Hornes’ challenge to the monetary
    penalty through the lens of the Marketing Order’s reserve requirement
    because the monetary penalty is pegged directly to the extent of the
    Hornes’ non-compliance with the Order, as measured by the ton and
    market value of the raisins. Accordingly, we hold the Secretary’s
    imposition of the penalty satisfies any requirement Koontz may impose
    that we independently analyze the monetary exaction under Nollan and
    Dolan.
    HORNE V. USDA                          29
    to modify wholesale complex regulatory regimes such as this
    one.
    Instead, our role is to answer the narrower question of
    whether the Marketing Order and its penalties work a
    physical per se taking. We hold they do not. There is a
    sufficient nexus between the means and ends of the
    Marketing Order. The structure of the reserve requirement is
    at least roughly proportional (and likely actually proportional)
    to Congress’s stated goal of ensuring an orderly domestic
    raisin market. We reach these conclusions informed by the
    Supreme Court’s acknowledgment that governmental
    regulation of personal property is more foreseeable, and thus
    less intrusive, than is the taking of real property. This,
    coupled with our observation that the Secretary has
    endeavored to preserve as much of the Hornes’ ownership of
    the raisins as possible, leads us to conclude the Marketing
    Order’s reserve requirements—and the provisions permitting
    the Secretary to penalize the Hornes for failing to comply
    with those requirements—do not constitute a taking under the
    Fifth Amendment.
    AFFIRMED.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 10-15270

Citation Numbers: 750 F.3d 1128

Judges: Daly, Gould, Hawkins, Michael, Reinhardt, Ronald, Stephen

Filed Date: 5/9/2014

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 8/31/2023

Authorities (25)

Arizona Life Coalition Inc. v. Stanton , 515 F.3d 956 ( 2008 )

No. 01-55466 , 303 F.3d 1182 ( 2002 )

United States v. $191,910.00 in U.S. Currency, Bruce R. ... , 16 F.3d 1051 ( 1994 )

washington-legal-foundation-allen-d-brown-dennis-h-daugs-greg-hayes-l , 271 F.3d 835 ( 2001 )

john-doe-v-donald-rumsfeld-secretary-of-defense-les-brownlee-secretary , 435 F.3d 980 ( 2006 )

Wallace v. Hudson-Duncan & Co. , 98 F.2d 985 ( 1938 )

Parker v. Brown , 63 S. Ct. 307 ( 1943 )

Vandevere v. Lloyd , 644 F.3d 957 ( 2011 )

United States v. Rock Royal Co-Operative, Inc. , 59 S. Ct. 993 ( 1939 )

Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council , 112 S. Ct. 2886 ( 1992 )

Kaiser Aetna v. United States , 100 S. Ct. 383 ( 1979 )

Penn Central Transportation Co. v. New York City , 98 S. Ct. 2646 ( 1978 )

United States v. Pewee Coal Co. , 71 S. Ct. 670 ( 1951 )

Phillips v. Washington Legal Foundation , 118 S. Ct. 1925 ( 1998 )

Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp. , 102 S. Ct. 3164 ( 1982 )

Brown v. Legal Foundation of Washington , 123 S. Ct. 1406 ( 2003 )

Lingle v. Chevron U. S. A. Inc. , 125 S. Ct. 2074 ( 2005 )

Horne v. Department of Agriculture , 133 S. Ct. 2053 ( 2013 )

Koontz v. St. Johns River Water Management Dist. , 133 S. Ct. 2586 ( 2013 )

Ruckelshaus v. Monsanto Co. , 104 S. Ct. 2862 ( 1984 )

View All Authorities »