Kevin Marilley v. Charlton Bonham ( 2016 )


Menu:
  •                  FOR PUBLICATION
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
    KEVIN MARILLEY; SALVATORE              No. 13-17358
    PAPETTI; SAVIOR PAPETTI, on
    behalf of themselves and                   D.C. No.
    similarly situated,                  4:11-cv-02418-DMR
    Plaintiffs-Appellees,
    v.                        OPINION
    CHARLTON H. BONHAM, in his
    official capacity as Director of
    the California Department of
    Fish and Game,
    Defendant-Appellant.
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of California
    Donna M. Ryu, Magistrate Judge, Presiding
    Argued and Submitted En Banc June 21, 2016
    San Francisco, California
    Filed December 21, 2016
    2                     MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    Before: Sidney R. Thomas, Chief Judge, and Stephen
    Reinhardt, Kim McLane Wardlaw, William A. Fletcher,
    Marsha S. Berzon, Milan D. Smith, Jr., Mary H. Murguia,
    Jacqueline H. Nguyen, Andrew D. Hurwitz, John B.
    Owens, and Michelle T. Friedland, Circuit Judges.
    Opinion by Judge W. Fletcher;
    Dissent by Judge Milan D. Smith, Jr.;
    Dissent by Judge Reinhardt
    SUMMARY*
    Civil Rights
    The en banc court reversed the district court’s summary
    judgment in favor of plaintiffs and remanded for the district
    court to enter summary judgment for California in an action
    brought by a class of nonresident commercial fishers
    challenging California’s nonresident fee differential for four
    commercial fishing licenses, vessel registration and permits.
    The en banc court first held that California’s fee
    differentials for commercial fishing vessel registrations,
    fishing licenses, Dungeness crab permits, and herring gill
    net permits fell within the purview of the Privileges and
    Immunities Clause. The en banc court determined that
    whether the calculation was made at the general level of all
    nonresident commercial fishers, or at the specific level of
    nonresident commercial fishers for Dungeness crab and
    *
    This summary constitutes no part of the opinion of the court. It has
    been prepared by court staff for the convenience of the reader.
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                         3
    herring, the fee differentials charged by California were less
    than the amount by which California subsidized the
    management of the nonresidents’ portions of its commercial
    fishery. The en banc court therefore held that the fee
    differentials survived the Privileges and Immunities Clause
    challenge because the differentials were justified by a
    substantial reason that was closely related to the differential
    fees.
    The en banc court held that the fees survived an Equal
    Protection Clause challenge because California’s interest in
    receiving compensation for its commercial fishery
    management provided a “rational basis” for its fee
    differentials.
    Dissenting, Judge M. Smith, joined in full by Hurwitz and
    Owens and by Reinhardt and Berzon as to Part III, stated the
    majority assumed away the major defect in its analysis: the
    fact that nonresident fishermen pay multiple California taxes
    too, yet nonetheless commence each fishing season thousands
    of dollars in the hole by virtue of California’s discriminatory
    differentials. In Judge M. Smith’s view, the fee differentials
    are illegal under the Privileges and Immunities Clause.
    Dissenting, Judge Reinhardt, joined by Judge Berzon,
    concurred in Part III of Judge M. Smith’s dissent and agreed
    that California failed to carry its burden of demonstrating that
    the differential fees it charges to nonresidents were closely
    drawn to the achievement of a substantial state objective.
    4                 MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    COUNSEL
    M. Elaine Meckenstock (argued) and Gary Alexander,
    Deputy Attorneys General; Annadel A. Almendras,
    Supervising Deputy Attorney General; Robert W. Byrne,
    Senior Assistant Attorney General; Kamala D. Harris,
    Attorney General; Office of the Attorney General, Oakland,
    California; for Defendant-Appellant.
    Stuart G. Gross (argued) and Jared M. Galanis, Gross Law,
    San Francisco, California; Todd R. Gregorian and Tyler A.
    Baker, Fenwick & West LLP, Mountain View, California; for
    Plaintiffs-Appellees.
    OPINION
    W. FLETCHER, Circuit Judge:
    California charges nonresident commercial fishers higher
    fees for vessel registrations, licenses, and permits than it
    charges resident commercial fishers. A certified class of
    nonresident commercial fishers challenges the fee
    differentials under the Privileges and Immunities Clause and
    the Equal Protection Clause. We hold that California’s fee
    differentials do not violate either clause.
    I. Background
    California requires both resident and nonresident
    commercial fishers to register their vessels and to purchase
    licenses and permits in order to engage in commercial fishing
    in the waters of the state. See Cal. Fish & Game Code
    §§ 7852, 7881 (2013). For many years, California has
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                       5
    managed its commercial fishery at a substantial loss. See Cal.
    Fish & Game Code §§ 710.5(a), 710.7(a)(1) (2007). In Fiscal
    Year (FY) 2010–11, the year for which we have the most
    extensive documentation in the record, California’s
    Department of Fish and Game spent approximately $20
    million managing its commercial fishery. In the same year,
    California received approximately $5.8 million in
    fees—including registration, license, and permit fees paid by
    residents and nonresidents—from participants in its
    commercial fishing industry. The approximately $14 million
    shortfall was covered by California’s general tax revenues.
    California has statutorily mandated fees for commercial
    fishing vessel registrations, licenses, and permits. See Cal.
    Fish & Game Code §§ 713, 7852, 7881, 8280.6, 8550.5. Fees
    are adjusted annually based on inflation. Beginning in 1986,
    California charged nonresidents more than residents for
    certain commercial fishing registrations, licenses, and
    permits. In 1986, California for the first time charged
    nonresidents more than residents for herring gill net permits.
    In 1993, California for the first time charged nonresidents
    more for commercial fishing vessel registrations and
    commercial fishing licenses. In 1995, California for the first
    time charged nonresidents more for Dungeness crab permits.
    In license year 2010, the fees for resident and nonresident
    commercial fishers were as follows:
    Commercial fishing vessel registration:
    Resident: $317.00
    Nonresident: $951.50
    6                  MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    Commercial fishing license:
    Resident: $120.75
    Nonresident: $361.75
    Dungeness crab vessel permits:
    Resident: $254.00
    Nonresident: $507.50
    Herring gill net permits:
    Resident: $336.00
    Nonresident: $1,269.00
    Cal. Dep’t Fish & Game, Digest of California Commercial
    Fishing Laws and Licensing Requirements (2010).
    Dungeness crab and herring were (and are) limited entry
    fisheries for which a limited number of permits was (and is)
    available.
    Depending on the activity in question, a commercial
    fisher in California could be required to pay several fees. For
    example, a fishing vessel owner who personally engaged in
    fishing for herring was required to pay a vessel registration
    fee, a commercial fishing license fee, and a herring gill net
    permit fee. For a California resident holding a single permit,
    the total cost in 2010 would have been $773.75. For a
    nonresident, the total cost would have been $2,582.25, or 3.3
    times as much as for a resident. A vessel owner who
    personally engaged in fishing for Dungeness crab was
    required to pay a vessel registration fee, a commercial fishing
    license fee, and a Dungeness crab permit fee. For a
    California resident, the total cost in 2010 would have been
    $691.75; for a nonresident, the total cost would have been
    $1,820.75, or 2.6 times as much as for a resident. Of the
    approximately $5.8 million in fees paid to California in FY
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                       7
    2010–11 by the commercial fishing industry, approximately
    $435,000 came from fee differentials paid by nonresidents.
    Plaintiffs, a class of nonresident commercial fishers,
    challenge the four nonresident fee differentials—for
    commercial fishing vessel registrations, commercial fishing
    licenses, Dungeness crab permits, and herring gill net
    permits. Plaintiffs brought a class action in district court
    against California’s Director of the Department of Fish and
    Game (for convenience, “California”), challenging the fee
    differentials as violating the dormant Commerce Clause, the
    Privileges and Immunities Clause, and the Equal Protection
    Clause. Plaintiffs voluntarily dismissed their dormant
    commerce clause claim. The parties filed cross-motions for
    summary judgment on the remaining two claims. The district
    court ruled for the plaintiff class on its privileges and
    immunities claim, did not reach its equal protection claim,
    and entered judgment under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure
    54(b). California appealed the grant of Plaintiffs’ motion for
    summary judgment and the denial of its own motion for
    summary judgment. A divided three-judge panel of this court
    affirmed. Marilley v. Bonham, 
    802 F.3d 958
    (9th Cir. 2015).
    We granted rehearing en banc. Marilley v. Bonham, 
    815 F.3d 1178
    (9th Cir. 2016).
    For the reasons that follow, we reverse the grant of
    summary judgment to Plaintiffs. We remand with directions
    to grant summary judgment to California.
    II. Standard of Review
    We review de novo a district court’s decision granting or
    denying a motion for summary judgment. Rocky Mountain
    8                  MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    Farmers Union v. Corey, 
    730 F.3d 1070
    , 1086 (9th Cir.
    2013).
    III. Discussion
    A. Privileges and Immunities
    Article IV, Section 2, clause 1, of the Constitution
    provides that “[t]he Citizens of each State shall be entitled to
    all Privileges and Immunities of Citizens in the several
    States.” The Clause’s “primary purpose . . . was to help fuse
    into one Nation a collection of independent, sovereign
    States.” Toomer v. Witsell, 
    334 U.S. 385
    , 395 (1948). The
    Clause “establishes a norm of comity” between citizens of
    separate states. Austin v. New Hampshire, 
    420 U.S. 656
    , 660
    (1975).
    A challenge under the Privileges and Immunities Clause
    entails “a two-step inquiry.” Sup. Ct. of Va. v. Friedman,
    
    487 U.S. 59
    , 64 (1988); United Bldg. and Constr. Trades
    Council v. Camden, 
    465 U.S. 208
    , 218 (1984); see also
    Council of Ins. Agents & Brokers v. Molasky-Arman,
    
    522 F.3d 925
    , 934 (9th Cir. 2008). At step one, the plaintiff
    bears the burden of showing that the challenged law “fall[s]
    within the purview of the Privileges and Immunities Clause.”
    
    Friedman, 487 U.S. at 64
    (quoting 
    Camden, 465 U.S. at 221
    –22); see also Schoenefeld v. Schneiderman, 
    821 F.3d 273
    , 279 (2d Cir. 2016) (quoting 
    Friedman, 487 U.S. at 64
    ).
    If the plaintiff makes the required step-one showing, at step
    two the burden shifts to the state to show that the challenged
    law is “closely related to the advancement of a substantial
    state interest.” 
    Friedman, 487 U.S. at 65
    (citing Sup. Ct. of
    N.H. v. Piper, 
    470 U.S. 274
    , 284 (1985)); see also
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                       9
    
    Schoenefeld, 821 F.3d at 279
    (quoting 
    Friedman, 487 U.S. at 67
    ).
    We address these two steps in turn.
    1. Purview of the Clause
    The “threshold matter” in any Privileges and Immunities
    Clause case is whether a challenged law “fall[s] within the
    purview” of the Clause. 
    Camden, 465 U.S. at 218
    (quoting
    Baldwin v. Mont. Fish & Game Comm’n, 
    436 U.S. 371
    , 388
    (1978)). A plaintiff must show that the challenged law treats
    nonresidents differently from residents and impinges upon a
    “fundamental” privilege or immunity protected by the Clause.
    
    Camden, 465 U.S. at 218
    . Because California charges higher
    fees to nonresident commercial fishers, see Cal. Fish & Game
    Code §§ 7852, 7881, 8280.6, 8550.5, we easily conclude that
    Plaintiffs’ interests are “facially burdened.” McBurney v.
    Young, 
    133 S. Ct. 1709
    , 1715 (2013); see also Hillside Dairy
    Inc. v. Lyons, 
    539 U.S. 59
    , 66–67 (2003); Carlson v. State,
    
    798 P.2d 1269
    , 1274 (Alaska 1990) (“[L]icense fees which
    discriminate against nonresidents are prima facie a violation
    of [the Privileges and Immunities Clause].”). Further, an
    unbroken line of authority characterizes commercial fishing
    as a “common calling” that is protected by the Privileges and
    Immunities Clause. See Mullaney v. Anderson, 
    342 U.S. 415
    ,
    417–19 (1952) (striking down Alaska’s differentials for
    commercial fishing licenses as violating the Privileges and
    Immunities Clause); 
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 403
    (“[C]ommercial
    shrimping in the marginal sea, like other common callings, is
    within the purview of the privileges and immunities clause.”);
    Connecticut ex rel. Blumenthal v. Crotty, 
    346 F.3d 84
    , 96 (2d
    Cir. 2003) (holding that “commercial lobstering” falls within
    the purview of the Privileges and Immunities Clause);
    10                 MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    Tangier Sound Waterman’s Ass’n v. Pruitt, 
    4 F.3d 264
    , 266
    (4th Cir. 1993) (explaining that commercial fishing is a
    “protected privilege” because it implicates “‘the right to earn
    a living’” (quoting 
    Toomer, 344 U.S. at 403
    )); 
    Carlson, 798 P.2d at 1274
    (“Commercial fishing is a sufficiently
    important activity to come within the purview of the
    Privileges and Immunities Clause.”).
    We therefore conclude that California’s challenged fee
    differentials fall within the purview of the Privileges and
    Immunities Clause.
    2. Closely Related to the Advancement of a Substantial
    State Interest
    a. Commercial Fishing Fees and State Subsidy
    California’s differential fees for nonresident fishers have
    not reduced the percentage of nonresidents obtaining permits.
    In license year 1986, the year differential fees were
    introduced for herring gill net permits, nonresidents held
    17.5% of these permits in California. In license year 2012,
    the most recent year for which we have information in the
    record, nonresidents held 19% of these permits. In license
    year 1993, the year differential fees were introduced for
    commercial fishing vessel registrations and commercial
    fishing licenses, nonresident commercial fishers held 7.2% of
    all commercial fishing vessel registrations and 6.6% of all
    commercial fishing licenses in California. In license year
    2012, nonresident commercial fishers registered 9.4% of all
    commercial fishing vessel registrations and 12.9% of all
    commercial fishing licenses in California. In license year
    1995, the year differential fees were charged for Dungeness
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                     11
    crab permits, nonresidents held 9.8% of these permits. In
    license year 2012, nonresidents held 13.9% of these permits.
    According to a declaration of Tony Warrington, Assistant
    Chief of the Law Enforcement Division of California’s
    Department of Fish and Game (“DFG”) (now the Department
    of Fish and Wildlife), a “reasonable and conservative
    estimate” of commercial fishing enforcement expenditures by
    the Law Enforcement Division in FY 2010–11 is
    $10,320,963. According to a declaration of Helen Carriker,
    Deputy Director of Administration of DFG, additional FY
    2010–11 expenditures by the License and Revenue Branch of
    DFG and by the Marine Region of DFG were $9,499,000.
    Carriker states, however, that these numbers do “not capture
    all of DFG’s commercial fishing costs,” and that “all DFG
    programs benefit commercial fishermen in some way.”
    These numbers also do not include fishing-related
    conservation expenditures by other California agencies, such
    as the California Coastal Commission. Based on the numbers
    provided by Warrington and Carriker, a conservative estimate
    is that California spent approximately $20,000,000 in FY
    2010–11 on enforcement, management, and conservation
    activities benefitting commercial fishers.
    Warrington estimated the FY 2010–11 expenditures by
    the Law Enforcement Division of DFG attributable to the
    Dungeness crab fishery as $921,394, and attributable to the
    herring gill net fishery as $75,094. He noted, however, that
    these numbers “likely underestimate the enforcement costs
    for these two fisheries” because not all personnel costs (in
    terms of both numbers of people and numbers of overtime
    hours) were included, and because some equipment expenses
    were not included. Carriker estimated the FY 2010–11
    expenditures by the License and Revenue Branch of DFG
    12                 MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    attributable to the Dungeness crab fishery as $83,921, and
    attributable to the herring gill net fishery as $97,431.
    According to a declaration by Marci Yaremko,
    Environmental Program Manager for DFG, FY 2010–11
    expenditures by the Marine Region of DFG attributable to the
    Dungeness crab fishery were “at least” $109,797, and
    attributable to the herring gill net fishery were “at least”
    $285,981.      Combining the expenditures by the Law
    Enforcement Division, the License and Revenue Branch, and
    the Marine Region, in FY 2010–11 California’s DFG spent at
    least $1,115,112 attributable to the Dungeness crab fishery
    and at least $458,506 attributable to the herring gill net
    fishery.
    During FY 2010–11, California residents registered 2,812
    commercial fishing vessels; nonresidents registered 304
    vessels.     Nonresidents’ vessels thus accounted for
    approximately 10% of the total registrations in that year.
    California residents purchased 5,618 commercial fishing
    licenses; nonresidents purchased 775 licenses. Nonresidents
    accounted for approximately 12% of the total licenses.
    California residents paid the yearly fee for 500 Dungeness
    crab permits; nonresidents paid the fee for 76 permits.
    Nonresidents accounted for approximately 13% of the total
    Dungeness crab permits. California residents paid the yearly
    fee for 180 herring gill net permits; nonresidents paid the fee
    for 39 permits. Nonresidents accounted for approximately
    18% of the total herring gill net permits.
    During FY 2010–11, California received, from residents
    and nonresidents, a total of approximately $2,415,000 for
    commercial vessel registrations, commercial fishing licenses,
    Dungeness crab permits, and herring gill net permits. Of that
    amount, approximately $435,000 was due to fee differentials
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                       13
    paid by nonresident fishers. Broken down by category, the
    fee differentials were approximately $193,000 for
    commercial fishing boat registrations; approximately
    $187,000 for commercial fishing licenses; approximately
    $19,000 for Dungeness crab permits; and approximately
    $36,000 for herring gill net permits.
    Overall, during FY 2010–11 California received
    approximately $5,800,000 in commercial fishing revenues,
    including revenues from resident and nonresident fishing
    vessel registrations, fishing licenses, Dungeness crab permits,
    and herring gill net permits. Using $20,000,000 as the
    conservative estimate of California’s overall commercial
    fishery expenditures, the FY 2010–11 shortfall was slightly
    over $14,000,000. If we exclude from the calculation fee
    differentials paid by nonresidents, the shortfall in FY
    2010–11 was approximately $14,435,000. The shortfall was
    covered by California’s general tax revenues. This shortfall
    was a subsidy, or benefit, provided by California taxpayers to
    the commercial fishing industry in California. The question
    before us is whether, or to what degree, nonresident
    commercial fishers may be required to pay differential fees to
    account for their proportionate share of that subsidy, or
    benefit.
    b. Advancement of a Substantive State Interest
    i. State Expenditures and Compensation by Nonresidents
    (a) State Expenditures
    The Supreme Court has decided two cases in which
    differential fees were charged to nonresident commercial
    fishers. First, in Toomer v. Witsell, 
    334 U.S. 385
    (1948),
    14                 MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    South Carolina charged a license fee of $25 for commercial
    shrimp boats owned by state residents. It charged a license
    fee of $2,500—one hundred times greater—to commercial
    shrimp boats owned by nonresidents. 
    Id. at 389.
    The Court
    wrote that “South Carolina plainly and frankly discriminates
    against non-residents, and the record leaves little doubt but
    what the discrimination is so great that its practical effect is
    virtually exclusionary.” 
    Id. at 396–97;
    see also 
    id. at 398
    (noting “a near equivalent of total exclusion”). The Court
    struck down the fee differential as a violation of the
    Privileges and Immunities Clause. 
    Id. at 403.
    The Court was
    careful, however, to endorse differential fees that were
    compensation or reimbursement for state-provided benefits as
    to which nonresidents would otherwise be free riders. The
    Court wrote that the Clause allows a state “to charge non-
    residents a differential which would merely compensate the
    State for any added enforcement burden they may impose or
    for any conservation expenditures from taxes which only
    residents pay.” 
    Id. at 399.
    Second, in Mullaney v. Anderson, 
    342 U.S. 415
    (1952),
    the Tax Commissioner of Alaska charged a commercial
    fishing license fee of $5 to residents and a $50 fee—a ten
    times greater fee—to nonresidents. Alaska sought to justify
    the fee differential based on enforcement costs attributable to
    nonresident commercial fishers, but the record did not
    support its attempted justification. Indeed, wrote the Court,
    the Tax Commissioner and his Deputy “specifically
    disclaimed any knowledge of the dollar cost of enforcement.”
    
    Id. at 418.
    Applying the Privileges and Immunities Clause to
    a Territory (as Alaska then was), the Court struck down the
    fee differential. The Court quoted the language from Toomer
    endorsing differential fees that prevent nonresidents from free
    riding on state-provided enforcement and conservation
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                       15
    efforts, 
    id. at 417,
    and the Court was careful to say that
    precise cost and reimbursement figures were not required in
    order to justify differential fees, 
    id. at 418
    (“Constitutional
    issues affecting taxation do not turn on even approximate
    mathematical determinations.”).
    To justify the fee differentials challenged in this case,
    California points to the approximately $14 million yearly
    shortfall in its expenditures in managing its commercial
    fishery. As noted above, without the revenue produced by the
    fee differentials, the yearly shortfall would be an additional
    $435,000. California contends that the fee differentials
    charged to nonresident commercial fishers appropriately
    compensate it for costs incurred in enforcement and
    conservation efforts attributable to nonresidents as their
    proportionate share, and that the fee differentials reduce
    (though do not entirely eliminate) the free-rider problem that
    would otherwise exist.
    On several occasions, the Supreme Court has stated that
    a state’s expenditures may justify discrimination against
    nonresidents that would otherwise be impermissible under the
    Privileges and Immunities Clause. As just noted, the Court
    stated in Toomer and Mullaney that a state may charge
    differential fees to nonresident commercial fishers in order to
    recover the state’s expenditures in enforcement and
    conservation measures that are attributable to the
    nonresidents. In Camden, a municipal ordinance required
    that at least forty percent of workers employed on city
    construction projects be residents of Camden, New Jersey.
    The Court wrote, “The fact that Camden is expending its own
    funds or funds it administers in . . . terms of a grant is
    certainly a factor—perhaps the crucial factor—to be
    considered in evaluating whether the statute’s discrimination
    16                MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    violates the Privileges and Immunities Clause.” 
    Camden, 465 U.S. at 221
    .
    The Court’s decisions under the Commerce Clause make
    much the same point about state expenditures. Commerce
    Clause decisions are relevant to the Privileges and
    Immunities Clause because the two clauses share the same
    underlying concerns. See, e.g., Hicklin v. Orbeck, 
    437 U.S. 518
    , 531–32 (1978) (“[T]he mutually reinforcing relationship
    between the Privileges and Immunities Clause . . . and the
    Commerce Clause—a relationship that stems from their
    common origin in the Fourth Article of the Articles of
    Confederation and their shared vision of federalism . . .
    —renders several Commerce Clause decisions appropriate
    support for our conclusion [under the Privileges and
    Immunities Clause].” (internal citation omitted)). In Reeves,
    Inc. v. Stake, 
    447 U.S. 429
    (1980), South Dakota built and
    owned its own cement plant. When demand for cement
    exceeded supply, South Dakota instituted a policy of
    satisfying all orders from South Dakota customers first,
    relegating out-of-state customers to the end of the line. The
    Court sustained the policy against a dormant Commerce
    Clause challenge, writing:
    The State’s refusal to sell to buyers other than
    South Dakotans is “protectionist” only in the
    sense that it limits benefits generated by a
    state program to those who fund the state
    treasury and whom the State was created to
    serve . . . . Such policies, while perhaps
    “protectionist” in a loose sense, reflect the
    essential and patently unobjectionable purpose
    of state government—to serve the citizens of
    the State.
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        17
    
    Id. at 442.
    Similarly, in McBurney v. Young, 
    133 S. Ct. 1709
    (2013), the Supreme Court rejected a dormant Commerce
    Clause challenge to a Virginia Freedom of Information Act
    provision under which only Virginia residents were allowed
    to compel production of state government documents. Citing
    Reeves, the Court wrote, “Insofar as there is a ‘market’ for
    public documents in Virginia, it is a market for a product that
    the Commonwealth has created and of which the
    Commonwealth is the sole manufacturer.” 
    Id. at 1720.
    The
    Court therefore held that Virginia could reserve for its
    citizens the benefits of the product it had created through the
    expenditure of state funds.
    (b) Compensation by Nonresidents for State-provided
    Benefits
    The core principle of the foregoing cases is that when a
    state makes an expenditure from a fund to which nonresidents
    do not contribute, and when the state provides a benefit
    through that expenditure to both residents and nonresidents,
    the state may exclude nonresidents from the benefit either in
    whole or in part, or it may seek compensation from
    nonresidents for the benefit conferred. When the benefit at
    issue is access to a natural resource, the state may not exclude
    nonresidents, but it may seek reimbursement for money spent
    to manage and preserve the resource. In such cases, as the
    Court wrote in Toomer, the Privileges and Immunities Clause
    allows a state “to charge non-residents a differential which
    would merely compensate the State for any added
    enforcement burden they may impose or for any conservation
    expenditures from taxes which only residents pay.” 
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 399
    .
    18                 MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    Several related principles come from these same cases.
    First, the benefit provided to a nonresident, and the
    appropriate amount of compensation from the nonresident,
    need not be determined with mathematical precision. The
    constitutional question “do[es] not turn on even approximate
    mathematical determinations.” 
    Mullaney, 342 U.S. at 418
    .
    Second, we accord states deference in determining the benefit
    provided and the appropriate amount of compensation. A
    privileges and immunities inquiry “must . . . be conducted
    with due regard for the princip[le] that the States should have
    considerable leeway in analyzing local evils and in
    prescribing appropriate cures.” 
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 396
    .
    Third, in seeking compensation from nonresidents, a state
    must treat nonresidents and residents with “substantial
    equality.” 
    Id. at 396
    (“[I]t was long ago decided that one of
    the privileges which the [Privileges and Immunities Clause]
    guarantees to citizens of State A is that of doing business in
    State B on terms of substantial equality with the citizens of
    that State.”).
    Consistent with these principles, we may calculate at a
    general level the benefit provided by California and the
    appropriate compensation from nonresident fishers.
    California spent approximately $20,000,000 managing its
    commercial fishing industry in FY 2010–11. Not including
    the fee differentials paid by nonresident fishers, California
    received a total amount of approximately $5,365,000 in fees
    from the commercial fishing industry. This amount includes
    all fees, not limited to commercial fishing license fees,
    commercial fishing vessel registration fees, Dungeness crab
    permits, and herring gill net permits. Of that total amount
    (again excluding the amount paid in fee differentials),
    approximately $1,980,000 came from registration, license,
    and permit fees paid by commercial fishers. The remaining
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                       19
    approximately $3,385,000 came from fish landing taxes and
    from licensing fees paid by fish buyers, sellers, and
    importers. The shortfall in revenues (excluding nonresident
    differentials) in FY 2010–11 was approximately $14,635,000,
    or approximately 73% of the entire amount spent by
    California in managing its commercial fishery. The shortfall
    was a subsidy, or benefit, provided by California to its
    commercial fishing industry, paid by California taxpayers.
    All commercial fishers in California—residents and
    nonresidents alike—benefited from this subsidy.
    We will assume, as a rough estimate, that commercial
    fishers as a whole benefited from the states’ subsidy in
    proportion to the amount they paid in fees. Excluding fee
    differentials, the amount paid to California by commercial
    fishers ($1,980,000) was 37% of the total amount paid to
    California by the entire commercial fishing industry
    ($5,365,000). Thirty-seven percent of the state’s $14,635,000
    subsidy is approximately $5,341,000. That amount went to
    commercial fishers as their proportionate share of the subsidy
    in FY 2010–11. Nonresident commercial fishers in
    California were 12% of all commercial fishers in FY
    2010–11. Twelve percent of the $5,341,000 subsidy that
    went to all commercial fishers is approximately $641,000.
    California could have charged up to that amount to
    nonresident fishers in FY 2010–11, as their proportionate
    share of the subsidy, or benefit, provided to them by
    California out of its general fund. In actual fact, nonresident
    fishers paid a total of $435,000 in fee differentials in FY
    2010–11, substantially less than the amount of their
    proportionate share of the subsidy, or benefit, provided to
    them by California.
    20                 MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    We may also calculate the subsidies provided to the two
    specific fisheries for which California charges fee
    differentials—Dungeness crab and herring. As described
    above, in FY 2010–11 California’s DFG spent approximately
    $1,115,000 attributable to the Dungeness crab fishery and
    approximately $460,000 attributable to the herring fishery.
    As noted above, the overall subsidy provided by California to
    its commercial fishery is 73% of California’s total
    expenditures for managing its commercial fishery. We will
    assume, as a rough estimate, that 73% of the amount spent on
    the Dungeness crab and herring fisheries is the amount by
    which those specific fisheries were subsidized in FY
    2010–11.
    Seventy-three percent of the subsidy provided to the
    Dungeness crab fishery is approximately $814,000.
    Nonresidents were 13% of the Dungeness crab permit holders
    in FY 2010–11.          Thirteen percent of $814,000 is
    approximately $106,000, which is the proportionate share of
    the subsidy provided to nonresident Dungeness crab fishers
    in FY 2010–11. The differential fee charged to nonresident
    Dungeness crab fishers in FY 2010–11 was approximately
    $19,000, substantially less than the $106,000 subsidy, or
    benefit, provided to them.
    Seventy-three percent of the subsidy provided to the
    herring fishery is approximately $335,000. Nonresidents
    were 18% of the herring gill net permit holders in FY
    2010–11. Eighteen percent of $335,000 is approximately
    $60,000. The differential fee charged to nonresident herring
    gill net fishers in FY 2010–11 was $36,000, substantially less
    than the $60,000 subsidy, or benefit, provided to them.
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        21
    Thus, whether the calculation is made at the general level
    of all nonresident commercial fishers, or at the specific level
    of nonresident commercial fishers for Dungeness crab and
    herring, the fee differentials charged by California are less
    than the amount by which California subsidizes the
    management of the nonresidents’ portions of its commercial
    fishery.
    In contrast to the fee differential charged in Toomer,
    California commercial fishing differentials are not “virtually
    exclusionary.” 
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 397
    . Indeed, quite the
    contrary. As the numbers given above demonstrate, the
    percentages of nonresident fishing vessel registrations,
    nonresident commercial fishing licenses, nonresident
    Dungeness crab permits, and nonresident herring gill net
    permits have all increased since the institution of differential
    fees for nonresidents. Further, in contrast to the fee
    differentials in Toomer and Mullaney, the multiples of the
    fees charged to residents are relatively modest. In Toomer,
    South Carolina charged nonresident shrimpers one hundred
    times what it charged residents. In Mullaney, Alaska charged
    nonresident fishers ten times what it charged residents. In
    California, the multiples ranged from about two to slightly
    less than four.
    We therefore conclude that the fee differentials charged
    by California are permitted under the Privileges and
    Immunities Clause.
    ii. California Taxes Paid by Nonresident Fishers
    The above analysis is premised on the nonresident fishers
    in this case not having paid “taxes which only [California]
    residents pay.” 
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 399
    . Plaintiffs did not
    22                  MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    argue in the district court or in their briefs to us that they have
    paid California income tax on their earnings from commercial
    fishing in California, and that they are therefore protected by
    the Privileges and Immunities Clause from having to pay fee
    differentials. Plaintiffs made this argument for the first time
    during oral argument before our en banc panel. Our
    dissenting colleagues use Plaintiffs’ late-raised argument as
    the central rationale of their dissent. We could hold
    Plaintiffs’ argument waived for failure to raise it in the
    district court and for failure to raise it in their briefs to us.
    However, we address it on the merits, for there is enough
    uncontested information in the record to allow us to consider
    and reject it. Because we reject the argument, there is no
    unfairness to California resulting from Plaintiffs’ failure to
    raise it until oral argument before our en banc panel.
    If Plaintiffs paid more than de minimus income tax to
    California, such that they should be assimilated, either
    entirely or in part, to California resident taxpayers for
    purposes of the Privileges and Immunities Clause, we would
    have to modify our analysis. However, we do not need to do
    so because the three named plaintiffs have paid either no or
    minimal California income tax. One of the named plaintiffs
    has fished commercially in California for many years and has
    never paid California income tax. The other two named
    plaintiffs have fished commercially in California for many
    years; each has paid income taxes in California for only three
    of those years.
    Named plaintiff Savior Papetti lives in McKinney, Texas.
    He owns two commercial fishing boats. He uses one of them
    to fish in Alaska. He has kept the other boat in San Francisco
    since 2000. He does not own any herring gill net permits, but
    has fished regularly for herring in California, missing only a
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        23
    few years, by leasing permits from others. He has fished for
    Dungeness crab regularly since 2006 except for a “couple [of]
    years.” He stated in his deposition that he has filed California
    tax returns “every year.” He specifically stated that he has
    not paid California income tax since 1992. There is nothing
    in the record to indicate that he paid California income taxes
    before 1992.
    Named plaintiff Salvatore Papetti, Savior’s father, lives
    in Bellingham, Washington. He states in his deposition that
    he has worked as a commercial fisherman since 1963. He
    owns two commercial fishing boats. He keeps one of them in
    Alaska. He now uses it to fish for salmon, but in the past has
    used it to fish for Dungeness crab and herring in California.
    At the time of his deposition, his other boat was in
    Washington for repairs. He uses that boat to fish for herring
    in Alaska and in California, and for salmon in Washington.
    He fished for Dungeness crab in California as late as 2007.
    About five or six years ago, he sold his crab permit to his son
    Savior. He has never missed a herring season in California
    except the year the season was closed due to an oil spill in
    San Francisco Bay. He has filed California income tax
    returns “every year,” but has paid income taxes to California
    in only three of those years. He paid $331 in 2004, $652 in
    2009, and $2,273 in 2010.
    Finally, named plaintiff Kevin Marilley lives in Lynden,
    Washington. He has worked as a commercial fisherman since
    1974. He owns three commercial fishing boats. He keeps
    two in Alaska and uses them to fish there. He keeps the third
    boat in Bellingham, Washington, and uses it to fish for
    salmon in Alaska and herring in California. He fished for
    squid and herring in California between 1989 and 2005, and
    fished for squid in California in 2009. He regularly fished for
    24                  MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    herring in California through 2007. He stated in his
    deposition that he intended to fish for herring in California in
    2013. He stated in his deposition that he “believe[d]” he filed
    a California tax return for every year he fished in California
    up through 2003. The last time he filed a tax return in
    California was 2003. He paid income tax in California in
    only three years. He paid $153 in 1994, $3,161 in 1995, and
    $845 in 1996. He last paid California income tax twenty
    years ago.
    Our dissenting colleagues do not ask to alter our analysis
    based on the non-existent or minimal California income taxes
    paid by the three named plaintiffs. Rather, they ask us to do
    so based on an unsupported assumption that unnamed class
    members paid substantially more in California income taxes
    than did the named plaintiffs.
    The record contains no evidence of California income
    taxes paid by any of the unnamed class members. Attorneys
    for the plaintiff class had an opportunity in the district court
    to present evidence of California income taxes paid by
    unnamed class members, but they failed to present any such
    evidence. Nor did they make any argument in the district
    court based on payment of California income taxes by any
    class member, named or unnamed. An assumption that
    unnamed class members paid substantially more than the
    named plaintiffs is inconsistent with the basic premises of
    class certification. Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 23(a)(3)
    requires that the “claims . . . of the representative parties [be]
    typical of the claims . . . of the class.” That is, a claim by an
    unnamed member of the class must match a “typical” claim
    by a named plaintiff. In this case, there is no such “typical”
    claim in the complaint because the named plaintiffs made no
    claim whatsoever based on their payment of California
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        25
    income taxes. Rule 23(a)(2) also requires that there be
    “questions of law or fact common to the class.” If a claim
    based on the payment of California income taxes had been
    made in the district court (which it was not), that claim was
    required to have been based on law or fact “common to the
    class.” To the extent there were facts common to such a
    claim, if it had been made, the only facts in evidence were
    those recounted above.
    In short, our dissenting colleagues ask us to make an
    assumption, based on sheer speculation, that unnamed class
    members paid substantially more in California income taxes
    than did the named plaintiffs. We respectfully decline to
    make that assumption.
    B. Equal Protection
    Plaintiffs also challenged California’s commercial fishing
    fee differentials under the Equal Protection Clause. The
    district court struck down the fee differentials as a violation
    of the Privileges and Immunities Clause and did not reach the
    equal protection question. We could remand to the district
    court to address that question in the first instance, but in the
    interest of judicial efficiency we decide the question
    ourselves.
    Because California’s commercial fishing fee differentials
    do not “classify persons based on protected characteristics,
    such as race, alienage, national origin, or sex” or “affect the
    exercise of fundamental rights,” rational basis review applies.
    Fields v. Legacy Health Sys., 
    413 F.3d 943
    , 955 (9th Cir.
    2005); see also Country Classic Dairies, Inc. v. State of
    Mont., Dep’t of Commerce Milk Control Bureau, 
    847 F.2d 593
    , 596 (9th Cir. 1988) (“[T]he right to pursue a calling is
    26                 MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    not a fundamental right for purposes of the Equal Protection
    Clause.” (citing New Orleans v. Dukes, 
    427 U.S. 297
    , 303–05
    (1976) (per curiam))); see also Medeiros v. Vincent, 
    431 F.3d 25
    , 32 (1st Cir. 2005) (“The right to ‘make a living’ is not a
    ‘fundamental right,’ for either equal protection or substantive
    due process purposes.”). Therefore, in order to succeed
    Plaintiffs must “negat[e] every conceivable basis which might
    support the legislative classification” between residents and
    nonresidents. 
    Fields, 413 F.3d at 955
    . As explained above,
    California has a “substantial reason” for charging nonresident
    differentials. It has an obvious interest in recovering from
    nonresident commercial fishers their share of the benefit
    provided to them by its management of its commercial
    fishery. Congress has recognized this interest as legitimate.
    See Pub. L. No. 109-13, § 6036(b)(1), 119 Stat. 231. But
    even absent such congressional endorsement, California’s
    interest in receiving compensation for the benefit its
    management confers provides a “rational basis” for its fee
    differentials.
    Conclusion
    We reverse the district court’s grant of summary
    judgment to Plaintiffs. California’s fee differentials for
    commercial fishing vessel registrations, fishing licenses,
    Dungeness crab permits, and herring gill net permits survive
    the Privileges and Immunities Clause challenge because the
    differentials are justified by a substantial reason that is
    closely related to the differential fees. The fees survive the
    Equal Protection Clause challenge because California has a
    rational basis for charging the differential fees. California is
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        27
    therefore entitled to summary judgment on both of Plaintiffs’
    claims. We remand with directions to the district court to
    enter summary judgment for California.
    REVERSED and REMANDED.
    M. SMITH, Circuit Judge, with whom HURWITZ and
    OWENS, Circuit Judges, join in full, and REINHARDT and
    BERZON, Circuit Judges, join as to Part III, dissenting:
    The majority assumes away the major defect in its
    analysis: the fact that nonresident fishermen pay multiple
    California taxes too, yet nonetheless commence each fishing
    season thousands of dollars in the hole by virtue of
    California’s discriminatory differentials. To avoid dealing
    with this problem, the majority employs the analytical head
    fake of fixating on the named plaintiffs and ignoring the rest
    of the class. It then opines that the named plaintiffs’ tax
    liability is de minimus, assumes that finding is representative,
    and concludes that its analysis need go no further.
    That approach is deeply flawed. Our analysis cannot
    properly ignore the bevy of taxes nonresident fishermen pay
    collectively to the State. Moreover, the majority improperly
    transposes the evidentiary burden: it is California that must
    demonstrate that the differentials recoup a subsidy funded
    only by its residents. Hence, any purported lack of evidence
    on the tax liability of nonresident fishermen counts against
    the State, not the other way around. The majority shrugs this
    off, and thereby fails to require California to bear the burden
    the Privileges and Immunities Clause demands.
    28                 MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    California, like the majority, overlooks how nonresident
    taxes defray the costs of any subsidy for conservation, and
    thereby fails to meet its burden to show its discrimination is
    “closely drawn” to the achievement of a substantial state
    objective. Sup. Ct. of Va. v. Friedman, 
    487 U.S. 59
    , 68
    (1988). For that reason, I would affirm the district court’s
    judgment in favor of the plaintiffs, and I respectfully dissent.
    I.
    Salvatore Papetti and his wife Nancy fish for herring
    together in a two person team. They make the trip to San
    Francisco from Bellingham, Washington, to fish on their
    boat, the “Pacman.” It is tough work—“being on the ocean
    day and night, your body wears out” because “when there’s
    fish, you just got to go go go go . . . they’re here today and
    they’re gone tomorrow. . . . You got to catch as much as you
    can when you can.” They fish “five days a week, 24 hours a
    day, Sunday sundown till Friday noon.” They land their
    catch every day while the fish are still fresh to ensure the
    bounty does not spoil.
    They hold two commercial fishing licenses, three herring
    gill net permits, and one commercial fishing vessel
    registration. This would cost them $1566.50 in license fees
    if they were California residents, using the majority’s
    numbers from 2010. California, however, extracts $5482.00
    from the Papettis, based simply on their status as
    nonresidents. So, Salvatore and Nancy start the season with
    a $3915.50 deficit, relative to their in-state competitors.
    Adding insult to injury, every year it gets worse because
    commercial fishing fees are automatically indexed for
    inflation. Cal. Fish & Game Code § 713 (2013). The effect
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        29
    of the indexing is to widen the gap between resident and
    nonresident fishing license fees each season.
    Savior Papetti—Nancy and Salvatore’s son—must endure
    the same built-in headwinds. He registers a boat in
    California, obtains a fishing license, and secures permits to
    fish for herring and crab. But since he hails from McKinney,
    Texas, he starts each season $2062.00 behind his California
    resident competitors. Kevin Marilley is no different. He sets
    sail on the “Sundance Kid” near San Francisco to fish for
    herring. He registers his boat, obtains a fishing license, and
    has three herring gill net permits, so he starts $3674.50 in the
    red, unlike his California resident competitors. Frustrated by
    the disadvantage, Marilley and the Papettis challenge four of
    California’s differential fees under the Privileges and
    Immunities Clause of the U.S. Constitution.
    A.
    The Privileges and Immunities Clause is one of the
    cornerstones upon which our nation was built. Its origins add
    an important perspective on the State’s burden in this dispute.
    After the revolution, “[t]he strong sympathies . . . which
    bound the States together during a common war, dissolved on
    the return of peace.” Gibbons v. Ogden, 
    22 U.S. 1
    , 223
    (1824) (Johnson, J. concurring). For the first time, the states
    found themselves “in the unlimited possession of those
    powers over their own commerce, which they had so long
    been deprived of, and so earnestly coveted.” 
    Id. at 224.
    State
    parochialism “began to show itself in iniquitous laws and
    impolitic measures, from which grew up a conflict of
    commercial regulations, destructive to the harmony of the
    States.” 
    Id. 30 MARILLEY
    V. BONHAM
    New York, for instance, obtained firewood from
    Connecticut and goods from the farms of New Jersey, but
    because such trade harmed domestic industry, the State
    required “every Yankee sloop” and “Jersey market boat” to
    pay an entrance fee and a duty. JOHN FISKE, THE CRITICAL
    PERIOD OF AMERICAN HISTORY, 1783–1789 150S52 (1897).
    New Jersey retaliated by laying a tax on property New York
    had acquired in Sandy Hook. 
    Id. at 152.
    Connecticut’s
    merchants refused “to send any goods whatever into the hated
    state for a period of twelve months.” 
    Id. Yet, as
    three other
    New England states “closed their ports to British shipping,”
    Connecticut saw fit to “thr[ow] hers wide open, an act which
    she followed up by laying duties upon imports from
    Massachusetts.” 
    Id. at 148S49.
    Connecticut’s practice of
    “denying to outlanders the treatment that its citizens
    demanded for themselves was widespread.” Austin v. New
    Hampshire, 
    420 U.S. 656
    , 660 (1975). “This came to
    threaten at once the peace and safety of the union.” H. P.
    Hood & Sons, Inc. v. Du Mond, 
    336 U.S. 525
    , 533 (1949)
    (internal quotation marks omitted).
    The new country initially tried to solve the problem with
    the toothless Articles of Confederation, which provided:
    The better to secure and perpetuate mutual
    friendship and intercourse among the people
    of the different States in this Union, the free
    inhabitants of each of these States . . . shall be
    entitled to all privileges and immunities of
    free citizens in the several States; and the
    people of each State shall have free ingress
    and regress to and from any other State, and
    shall enjoy therein all the privileges of trade
    and commerce, subject to the same duties,
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        31
    impositions, and restrictions as the inhabitants
    thereof . . . .
    Art. IV. Since no state could unilaterally enforce this
    provision, the economic interaction of the several states
    became more and more fraught. Ultimately, this internecine,
    economic fratricide became “the immediate cause[] that led
    to the forming of a [constitutional] convention.” 
    Gibbons, 22 U.S. at 224
    ; see also KATHLEEN M. SULLIVAN & GERALD
    GUNTHER, CONSTITUTIONAL LAW 82 (17th ed. 2010) (“The
    poor condition of American commerce and the proliferating
    trade rivalries among the states were the immediate
    provocations for the calling of the Constitutional
    Convention.”)
    The Privileges and Immunities Clause was primarily
    aimed at “creat[ing] a national economic union,” Sup. Ct. of
    N.H. v. Piper, 
    470 U.S. 274
    , 279S80 (1985), and was taken
    from the Articles of Confederation “with no change of
    substance or intent, unless it was to strengthen the force of the
    clause in fashioning a single nation,” 
    Austin, 420 U.S. at 661
    .
    It affirms “[t]he Citizens of each State shall be entitled to all
    Privileges and Immunities of Citizens in the several States.”
    U.S. Const. art. IV, § 2, cl. 1. Alexander Hamilton referred
    to the Clause quite simply as “the basis of the Union.” The
    Federalist No. 80, at 502 (B. Wright ed., 1961). It “place[d]
    the citizens of each State upon the same footing with citizens
    of other States, so far as the advantages resulting from
    citizenship in those States are concerned.” Paul v. Virginia,
    
    75 U.S. 168
    , 180 (1868). The Court found it gave outsiders
    “an exemption from higher taxes or impositions than are paid
    by the other citizens of the state.” Corfield v. Coryell,
    
    6 F. Cas. 546
    , 552 (No. 3,230) (Cir. Ct. E.D. Pa. 1823). “It
    has been justly said that no [other] provision in the
    32                     MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    Constitution has tended so strongly to constitute the citizens
    of the United States one people . . . .” 
    Paul, 75 U.S. at 180
    .
    B.
    In light of this background, when states erect barriers that
    impair our national economic unity, they bear a significant
    burden of justification: laws implicating the Clause must
    serve a “substantial state interest” and be “closely related” to
    the advancement of that interest to be valid. 
    Friedman, 487 U.S. at 65
    . A substantial interest does not exist “unless
    there is something to indicate that non-citizens constitute a
    peculiar source of the evil at which the [discriminatory]
    statute is aimed.” Hicklin v. Orbeck, 
    437 U.S. 518
    , 525S26
    (1978) (quotation marks omitted, brackets in original). States
    of course do have some flexibility in prescribing appropriate
    cures for local ills and, when levying fees, need not
    demonstrate mathematical precision. See Toomer v. Witsell,
    
    334 U.S. 385
    , 396 (1948). But citizens of State A must be
    allowed to do business in State B “on terms of substantial
    equality with the citizens of that State.” 
    Id. (emphasis added).
    C.
    The “evil” the fee differentials target in this case is the
    potential for nonresidents to “free ride” on California’s
    investment in its fisheries.1 The State’s valid interest thus lies
    1
    The California legislature never articulated this aim, but the State
    insists the fee differentials were passed to close a budget gap. It is
    undisputed that nonresident fishermen were never actually identified as a
    unique source of any problem that would justify charging them a
    differential. Additionally, as “the Clause forbids a State from intentionally
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                                 33
    in seeking reimbursement for a benefit funded exclusively by
    California residents. In this situation, California may exact
    only “a differential which would merely compensate the State
    for [1] any added enforcement burden [nonresidents] may
    impose or [2] for any conservation expenditures from taxes
    which only residents pay.” 
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 399
    (emphasis added).2
    giving its own citizens a competitive advantage in business or
    employment,” it is appropriate to examine whether the differentials were
    enacted for a protectionist purpose. McBurney v. Young, 
    133 S. Ct. 1709
    ,
    1716 (2013). Here, California’s enactment of the Dungeness crab fee
    differential bears the hallmarks of economic protectionism. As the district
    court observed, the California Assembly Committee on Water, Parks, and
    Wildlife opposed an early version of the bill, noting it “provided[d] an
    unfair advantage to the sponsors of the bill – the Pacific Coast Federation
    of Fisherman [sic] [a resident fishermen advocacy group] – by making it
    very difficult for any new crab fishers to obtain permits and enter the
    market.” The Department of Fish and Game (“DFG”) later commented
    “[t]his bill is an attempt to . . . control competition to California fishermen
    and processors from out of state.” DFG’s enrolled bill report described
    the legislation as “an industry sponsored bill to prevent out-of-state
    commercial fishermen from moving into California and getting an undue
    share of the California Dungeness crab resource.” When the fee was
    renewed in 2006, Senate Republican analysis of the bill observed “where
    resource management crosses the line into economic protectionism it
    should be opposed . . . DFG should explore other management options that
    focus on maintaining the crab population instead of the industry
    population.”
    2
    The majority suggests that “a state’s expenditures may justify
    discrimination against nonresidents.” Maj. Op. at 15. But the cases it
    cites involve the Commerce Clause, not the Privileges and Immunities
    Clause, and assume that nonresidents do not “fund the state treasury.”
    Reeves, Inc. v. Stake, 
    447 U.S. 429
    , 224 (1980); McBurney v. Young,
    
    133 S. Ct. 1709
    , 1712S13 (2013) (quoting 
    Reeves, 447 U.S. at 224
    ).
    34                       MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    California elected to put all of its eggs in the second
    basket, as it never asserted, much less provided any evidence,
    that nonresident commercial fishermen impose any added
    enforcement or management burden on the State.3 In
    conducting our analysis, we thus look to the aggregate
    benefits nonresident fishermen receive at the expense of
    California’s taxpayers. To calculate that benefit, I will
    leverage, but do not endorse, the majority’s handiwork.
    The majority assumes the $20 million spent on licensing
    and enforcement is akin to conservation. Maj. Op. at 18–19.
    It then finds a $14,635,000 shortfall, after accounting for
    $5,365,000 received in fees, not including differentials. 
    Id. Next, the
    majority assumes commercial fishermen benefitted
    from the subsidy in proportion to the amount they paid in fees
    ($1,980,000 / $5,365,000).4 
    Id. That equals
    thirty-seven (37)
    percent of the $14,635,000 shortfall, meaning fishermen were
    subsidized to the tune of $5,341,000. 
    Id. at 19.
    Since
    nonresidents account for twelve percent of commercial
    fishermen, the majority tags them with twelve percent of that
    amount. 
    Id. at 19.
    In other words, according to the majority,
    nonresident fishermen received a $641,000 “subsidy.” 
    Id. This analysis
    fails because it assumes that the State’s
    subsidy derives from “taxes which only residents pay,”
    
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 399
    , notwithstanding the fact that the
    3
    The State concedes it did not analyze the impact of nonresident
    commercial fishermen on its fisheries generally, nor identify any savings
    it would realize if nonresidents were excluded from participating in its
    fisheries. As such, there is no evidence in the record that the differentials
    compensate for any added burden or expense nonresidents impose on
    commercial fisheries.
    4
    The State never advanced, let alone justified, this assumption.
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                              35
    record shows that nonresident commercial fisherman pay
    California taxes as well. Nonresident fishermen, in other
    words, must “be assimilated, either entirely or in part, to
    California resident taxpayers for purposes of the Privileges
    and Immunities Clause,” Maj. Op. at 22, because—like
    Golden State residents—they too pay taxes to fund the State’s
    conservation expenditures.
    II.
    A.
    The State’s expert, Dr. Carriker, says commercial
    fishermen in California earned $150 million in 2009, $179
    million in 2010, and $204 million in 2011. The State also
    consistently represented it could charge fees to nonresident
    fishermen in relation to their percentage of overall fishermen.
    Thus, taking the majority’s number, we can attribute twelve
    percent of those earnings to the efforts of out-of-state
    fishermen. By that account, nonresident fishermen paid
    personal income taxes to the State on earnings approximating
    $18–$24 million.5
    We can also consider it in another way. Using the
    landings data submitted both for residents and nonresidents,
    Dr. Carriker submits that the “average per-fisherman income”
    5
    To be clear, California taxes the income of nonresidents “derived
    from sources within this state,” Cal. Rev. & Tax. Code § 17041(i)(1)(B),
    “including income from a business, trade, or profession carried on within
    this State.” Cal. Code Regs. tit. 18, § 17951-2. California also imposes a
    property tax on boats, including those registered in California but located
    outside of it. See California State Board of Equalization, Frequently
    Asked Questions – Personal Property, https://www.boe.ca.gov/
    proptaxes/faqs/personal.htm.
    36                   MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    in California was $91,293.03 in 2009, $105,858.00 in 2010,
    and $105,070.28 in 2011. If we assume nonresident
    fishermen are comparable to their in-state counterparts,
    nonresidents would be liable for at least 9.3 percent in
    personal income taxes on roughly those amounts. See
    Franchise Tax Board, 2014 ANNUAL REPORT tbl.A1-B
    (2014), available at https://www.ftb.ca.gov/Archive/
    AboutFTB/Tax_Statistics/Reports/2014/Annual_Report.sht
    ml#Tax_Rates (showing personal income tax rates for each
    income level from 1935 to 2014) [hereinafter 2014 FTB
    Report].
    Alternatively, if we divide the aggregate earnings
    (approximately $24 million) by the number of nonresident
    fishermen (775), nonresidents would be paying California
    taxes on $31,000 per year on average. This estimate,
    however, assumes income is distributed evenly,
    notwithstanding the fish will bite for some fishermen more
    than others. Accordingly, $31,000 might be construed as the
    median income, meaning half of nonresident fishermen would
    make more each year, and the other half less. In that
    scenario, it would not be surprising for the named plaintiffs
    to have made modest in-state tax payments, even where
    nonresident fisherman collectively contribute substantially.
    California never contemplated, much less accounted for,
    the contributions nonresident fishermen make in personal
    income taxes.6 Based on the evidence in the record, however,
    we can reasonably infer nonresident fishermen’s incomes
    6
    Regardless of when the issue was raised, the above evidence has
    always been in the record, and we review a district court’s decision
    granting a motion for summary judgment de novo. Rocky Mountain
    Farmers Union v. Corey, 
    730 F.3d 1070
    , 1086 (9th Cir. 2013).
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        37
    contribute meaningfully in the aggregate to the State’s
    conservation expenditures. See, e.g., SER 20 (“[A]
    substantial portion of General Fund revenue comes from
    nonresident sources, including personal income tax paid by
    nonresidents, including nonresident commercial fishermen.”).
    Consider also the fact that California derives close to
    thirty percent of the General Fund from sales and use tax
    revenue. Nonresident fishermen like the Papettis pay those
    taxes just as California residents do—to purchase food, fuel,
    and other necessary materials in California. I assume that
    nonresident fishermen are also a salty bunch, and likely pay
    excise taxes too, on cigarettes, beer, wine, and alcohol,
    thereby adding further to the State’s general revenue. Yet
    California makes no effort to account for any of these
    nonresident funds in justifying its fee differentials, or to
    explain how nonresidents remain on the “same footing” as
    residents in spite of them. That simply is unjustifiable; under
    the Privileges and Immunities Clause California is required
    to do more. See Mullaney v. Anderson, 
    342 U.S. 415
    , 418
    (1952) (“[S]omething more is required than bald assertion to
    establish a reasonable relation between the higher fees and
    the higher cost[s] to the [State].”); Tangier Sound
    Waterman’s Ass’n v. Pruitt, 
    4 F.3d 264
    , 267 (4th Cir. 1993)
    (finding differential not “closely related” to asserted interest
    because, among other things, State gave “no recognition” to
    sales and use taxes paid by nonresident fishermen); Carlson
    v. State, 
    798 P.2d 1269
    , 1278 (Alaska 1990) (reading Toomer
    “to mean that if nonresident fishermen paid the same taxes as
    Alaskans and these taxes were substantially the sole revenue
    source for the state out of which conservation expenditures
    were made, then differential fees would not be permissible”).
    38                 MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    The majority concedes its analysis would have to be
    “modif[ied]” if nonresident fisherman “paid more than de
    minimus” taxes to California, Maj. Op. at 22, but it shrugs off
    the few thousands of dollars the named plaintiffs paid to
    California as being insufficient to meet its novel standard. By
    itself, this is error—the State must demonstrate “a reasonable
    relationship between the danger represented by non-citizens,
    as a class, and the severe discrimination practiced upon
    them.” 
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 399
    (emphasis added). In this
    case, California has failed to make any such showing.
    Apparently unable to respond more adequately to our
    argument, the majority steps purposefully to the plate, swings
    as hard as it can, and whiffs, by fixating on Rule 23’s class
    certification standards. Emphatically, those standards do not
    require that class members be carbon copies of each other.
    They therefore cannot excuse the majority’s failure to grapple
    with the hole in its argument. For instance, the majority
    invokes “commonality,” but “[t]he existence of shared legal
    issues with divergent factual predicates is sufficient” to meet
    that “permissive” standard. Hanlon v. Chrysler Corp.,
    
    150 F.3d 1011
    , 1019 (9th Cir. 1988) (emphasis added).
    Likewise, “typicality” requires “only that [the named
    plaintiffs’] claims be ‘typical’ of the class, not that [the
    named plaintiffs] be identically positioned to each other or to
    every class member.” Parsons v. Ryan, 
    754 F.3d 657
    , 686
    (9th Cir. 2014); see also Ellis v. Costco Wholesale Corp.,
    
    657 F.3d 970
    , 985 n.9 (9th Cir. 2011) (“Differing factual
    scenarios resulting in a claim of the same nature as other class
    members does not defeat typicality.”).
    Here, the district court found both elements satisfied
    because the plaintiffs “articulated a common constitutional
    issue at the heart of each proposed class member’s claim for
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                             39
    relief,” and resolution of that issue “would inform similar
    claims by other proposed class members regardless of factual
    differences among class members.” This finding by no
    means warrants the majority’s factual assumption that every
    class member paid the same amount as the named plaintiffs
    in state taxes to California. Maj. Op. at 25. Indeed, Rule 23
    requires only that each class member here pay fees higher
    than those charged to in-state residents. And, though the
    extent of nonresident tax liability might be a common
    question, Rule 23 permits certification even where the answer
    varies based on the unique factual circumstances of each
    nonresident fisherman. In short, neither “commonality” nor
    “typicality” mean the majority must assume every
    nonresident fisherman, across all species, location, and
    circumstance, earned the same income as the named plaintiffs
    and owed the same taxes to the state of California. Maj. Op.
    at 24–25. In fact, the opposite conclusion is more reasonable
    given some nonresidents fish for herring, others for crab, and
    still others for both, to say nothing of the fishermen who add
    outings for crayfish or lobster, amongst many other
    commodities. Were it not evident enough that the majority is
    seeking to avoid the elephant in the room, it bemoans the
    absence of any information about the income taxes
    nonresident fishermen pay to California, 
    id. at 24,
    without
    even considering the aggregate statistics cited above, and the
    reasonable inferences drawn from those data.7
    7
    The majority asserts our inferences are unsupported, but that is
    incorrect. Our assessment derives from the aggregate earnings statistics
    California placed into the record, which were taken from landings data
    submitted both for resident and nonresident commercial fishermen. 
    See supra
    II.A. We do not claim, as the majority states, that every unnamed
    class member makes “substantially more” than the named plaintiffs. Maj.
    Op. at 24. Our argument is that the record reasonably reflects that
    nonresident fishermen—taken collectively, across the full range of their
    40                     MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    Even if we accept the majority’s framing, the named
    plaintiffs can still “be assimilated . . . to California resident
    taxpayers.” Maj. Op. at 22. We have no reason to believe
    that fishermen are any different from resident and nonresident
    tax-filers in the State more generally. And whereas fifty-
    eight (58) percent of resident filers owe personal income
    taxes to California, sixty (60) percent of nonresident filers
    owe them.8 Compare 2014 FTB Report tbl.B-4A (showing
    58.4 percent of residents returns were taxable in 2013), with
    
    id. tbl.B-4G (showing
    60.2 percent nonresident returns were
    taxable in 2013). So, like ordinary Californians, some
    nonresident fishermen pay the State more in personal income
    income distribution—pay taxes that contribute materially to the State’s
    conservation expenditures (a fact California completely ignores). Unlike
    the majority’s hypothesis, under which unnamed class members are clones
    of the named plaintiffs, our assessment comports with common sense. We
    appreciate that 775 fisherman—some of whom fish the whole year in
    California, others of whom fish part-time—will earn incomes that fall
    along a distribution, such that some will owe California income taxes, and
    others will not. Given that point, the majority has no basis, under Rule 23
    or otherwise, to assume the California tax liability of the three named
    plaintiffs is broadly representative. More importantly, it is California’s
    burden to demonstrate our understanding is untrue in order to justify its
    discriminatory differentials. It has made no such showing in this case.
    Next, while it is true that “[i]f a claim based on the payment of
    California income taxes had been made in the district court, that claim was
    required to have been based on law or fact ‘common to the class,’” Maj.
    Op. at 25, that observation affords the majority no help. The law common
    to the class is the constitutional issue under the Privileges and Immunities
    Clause, and Rule 23(a)(2), stated in the disjunctive, requires nothing more.
    In other words, the only common “claim” that is required by Rule 23 to
    appear in the complaint is the one the plaintiffs advanced—that each class
    member pays fees higher than those charged to California residents.
    8
    The Franchise Tax Board’s 2014 Annual Report is the most recent
    available data.
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        41
    taxes than others, but like Californians generally, nonresident
    fishermen contribute meaningfully to the State’s coffers
    collectively. All told, the majority improperly focuses on a
    few fishermen whose contributions it deems insignificant on
    the overall tax liability spectrum, but the record reflects, and
    common sense dictates, nonresident fishermen’s taxes
    contribute materially to conservation expenditures.
    B.
    By chalking up to a rounding error the taxes nonresidents
    pay, the majority effectively shifts the applicable burden.
    Yet, any purported lack of evidence on the tax liability of
    nonresident fishermen is a strike against California, not
    against the plaintiffs. It is California that shoulders the
    burden to demonstrate that its discrimination “bears a close
    relation to the achievement of substantial state objectives.”
    
    Friedman, 487 U.S. at 70
    . Moreover, it is California that
    must demonstrate its differentials “merely compensate” for
    expenditures that derive from taxes “which only residents
    pay.” 
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 399
    . Finally, it is California that
    must demonstrate it permits nonresident fishermen to do
    business “on terms of substantial equality” with citizens of
    the State. 
    Id. at 396
    . Unfortunately, the majority lets
    California off the hook, for while the State is owed some
    deference, it made no effort to account for nonresident taxes
    whatsoever. California simply fails to meet its burden. The
    upshot is that nonresident fishermen stand on different
    footing than residents, whether fisherman or not. They alone
    pay differentials but must also pay the same taxes on income
    earned within the State.
    To illustrate, the 775 nonresident fishermen can be
    charged for a $641,000 “subsidy,” even though they pay state
    42                     MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    taxes to cover this conservation expenditure. In-state
    fishermen, by contrast, receive a $4,700,080 subsidy, but
    California’s 15,000,000 taxpayers collectively foot the bill.
    Accordingly, using the majority’s numbers, California
    residents, whether fisherman or not, pay about thirty cents on
    average towards the subsidy to in-state fishermen, whereas
    nonresident fishermen are charged over $800 each on average
    for the “subsidy” they receive.9
    It bears repeating: California shoulders the burden of
    showing the additional fees charged to nonresidents are
    closely related to the “taxes which only residents pay,”
    
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 399
    , and California must permit
    nonresident fishermen to do business on terms of substantial
    equality with citizens of the State. By overlooking how the
    taxes nonresident fishermen pay the State defray the costs of
    any subsidy for conservation, California fails to meet its
    burden. The fee differentials must accordingly be struck
    down.
    9
    Notably, Carlson rejected the “proposition that the state may
    subsidize its own residents in the pursuit of their business activities and
    not similarly situated nonresidents, even though this results in substantial
    inequality of 
    treatment.” 798 P.2d at 1278
    . The court found such a
    system “economically indistinguishable from imposing a facially equal tax
    on residents and nonresidents while making it effectively unequal by a
    system of credits and exemptions.” 
    Id. It declined
    to strike down the
    differential imposed by Alaska on this basis because state taxes were not
    “substantially the sole revenue source” for conservation expenditures. 
    Id. (noting 86
    percent of state revenues derived from petroleum production).
    The opposite is true here—personal income tax and sales tax made up 86
    percent of General Fund revenues for the year ending June 30, 2015. See
    California State Controller’s Office, COMPREHENSIVE ANNUAL FINANCIAL
    REPORT FOR THE FISCAL YEAR ENDED JUNE 30, 2015 42 (2016), available
    at http://www.sco.ca.gov/Files-ARD-Local/LocRep/cafr15web.pdf.
    MARILLEY V. BONHAM                        43
    C.
    If left to stand on this showing, we have no reason to
    think interstate fee differentials will not proliferate. Indeed,
    California could, for example, charge nonresident truckers
    and commercial airline pilots fees for earning a living off
    state-subsidized highways and airports. And why wouldn’t
    states seek to recoup from those professions conservation
    expenditures aimed at maintaining air quality? As in this
    case, they need only intend to close a budget gap and need
    not identify any relationship between the shortfall and
    nonresident truckers or pilots. Further, they need not
    determine what burdens nonresidents impose, if any, on the
    state’s air, roads, and other infrastructure. Nor would they
    need to identify any savings the state would realize if
    nonresident truckers and pilots were excluded. Finally, they
    could, like California, ignore nonresident taxes in setting the
    fee, so long as a few of the truckers or pilots earned incomes
    that led to modest in-state tax payments. The Privileges and
    Immunities Clause should preclude such barriers because
    they disrupt interstate economic harmony unjustifiably. The
    majority unfortunately holds otherwise, and thereby subverts
    one of the most important economic compacts that initially
    bound us together.
    III.
    This country is more than a league of confederated
    states—it is a nation. Yet the enactment of discriminatory fee
    differentials promotes our economic balkanization. We must
    be mindful of competing interests when evaluating such
    measures, but they require ample justification. California’s
    showing in this case does not come close to meeting its
    44                  MARILLEY V. BONHAM
    burden, so the fee differentials are illegal under the Privileges
    and Immunities Clause. I respectfully dissent.
    REINHARDT, Circuit Judge, dissenting, in which BERZON,
    Circuit Judge, joins.
    I concur in Part III of Judge M. Smith’s dissent and agree
    that California failed to carry its burden of demonstrating that
    the differential fees it charges to nonresidents are “closely
    drawn” to the achievement of a “substantial state objective.”
    Supreme Court of Virginia v. Friedman, 
    487 U.S. 59
    , 68
    (1988). Permissible state objectives include “compensat[ing]
    the State for any added enforcement burden they may impose
    or for any conservation expenditures from taxes which only
    residents pay.” Toomer v. Witsell, 
    334 U.S. 385
    , 399 (1948).
    Here, California does not contend that nonresident fishermen
    impose any sort of added enforcement burden. Nor does the
    state provide persuasive evidence that its fee differentials
    bear a “reasonable relationship” to its legitimate interest in
    receiving compensation from nonresidents for its
    “conservation expenditures from taxes which only residents
    pay.” 
    Toomer, 334 U.S. at 399
    (1948). Therefore, I agree with
    Judge M. Smith that the state has failed to make the requisite
    showing to justify any differential. That conclusion does not
    embrace either of the views expressed by the original panel
    as to how a differential should be calculated when it is in fact
    justified. See Marilley v. Bonham, 
    802 F.3d 958
    , 966–68 (9th
    Cir. 2015), reh’g en banc granted, 
    815 F.3d 1178
    (9th Cir.
    2016) (Graber., J., dissenting) (comparing the “per capita”
    and “fair share” approaches to calculating a justified fee
    differential).