Gerald Carlin v. Dairyamerica, Inc. , 688 F.3d 1117 ( 2012 )


Menu:
  •                    FOR PUBLICATION
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
    GERALD CARLIN, JOHN RAHM, PAUL           
    ROZWADOWSKI, And BRYAN WOLFE,                   No. 10-16448
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,               USDC No.
    v.                             1:09-CV-00430-
    DAIRYAMERICA, INC. and                            AWI-DLB
    CALIFORNIA DAIRIES, INC.,                         OPINION
    Defendants-Appellees.
    
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Eastern District of California
    Anthony W. Ishii, United States District Judge, Presiding
    Argued and Submitted
    August 31, 2011—San Francisco, California
    Filed August 7, 2012
    Before: Raymond C. Fisher and Johnnie B. Rawlinson,
    Circuit Judges, and George H. Wu, District Judge.*
    Opinion by Judge Wu
    * The Honorable George H. Wu, United States District Judge for the
    Central District of California, sitting by designation.
    8727
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.          8729
    COUNSEL
    Benjamin D. Brown (argued), Daniel A. Small, Victoria S.
    Nugent, George F. Farah and Brent W. Johnson, Cohen Mil-
    stein Sellers & Toll PLLC, Washington, D.C.; Joseph J.
    Tabacco, Jr., Christopher T. Heffelfinger and Anthony D.
    Phillips, Berman DeValerio, San Francisco, California; Ron
    Kilgard, Keller Rohrback P.L.C., Phoenix, Arizona; Jon A.
    Tostrud, Case Lombardi and Pettit, Honolulu, Hawaii; Lynn
    L. Sarko, Mark A. Griffin, Juli E. Farris, Keller Rohrback
    8730                CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    P.L.C., Seattle, Washington; J. Barton Goplerud, Hudson,
    Mallaney, Shindler and Anderson, PC, West Des Moines,
    Iowa, for the plaintiffs-appellants.
    Allison A. Davis, Davis Wright Tremaine LLP, San Fran-
    cisco, California; Charles M. English (argued), Wendy M.
    Yoviene and E. John Steren, Ober, Kaler, Grimes & Shriver,
    Washington, D.C., for defendant-appellee DairyAmerica, Inc.
    John J. Vlahos (argued), Lawrence M. Cirelli and S. Anne
    Johnson, Hanson Bridgett LLP, San Francisco, California, for
    defendant-appellee California Dairies, Inc.
    OPINION
    WU, District Judge:
    This appeal raises two issues: (1) whether the judicially
    created “filed rate doctrine,”1 which typically has been uti-
    lized in common carrier and public utility litigation, is appli-
    cable in a class action lawsuit seeking monetary and
    injunctive relief under state law arising from the misreporting
    of pricing data to the United States Department of Agriculture
    (“USDA”), where the data in turn were used to set a minimum
    price structure for raw milk sales; and (2) if the doctrine is
    applicable in that situation, whether the district court erred
    when it dismissed the plaintiffs’ state causes of action on the
    ground that the filed rate doctrine barred such claims, even
    1
    The precept is most often cited as the “filed rate doctrine,” although it
    is sometimes referenced as the “filed tariff doctrine” (see, e.g., Davel
    Commc’ns, Inc. v. Qwest Corp., 
    460 F.3d 1075
    , 1084 (9th Cir. 2006)),
    and, on rarer occasions, as the “Keogh doctrine” (see, e.g., Cost Mgmt.
    Servs., Inc. v. Wash. Natural Gas Co., 
    99 F.3d 937
    , 943 & n.7 (9th Cir.
    1996)), after the case where it was purportedly first established (i.e.,
    Keogh v. Chi. & Nw. Ry. Co., 
    260 U.S. 156
     (1922)). As used herein
    (except where a different term is utilized within a quoted source), the ref-
    erence will be to the “filed rate doctrine.”
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                  8731
    though the court found that “[i]t is not disputed that [the]
    USDA determined that the rates calculated . . . were errone-
    ous and that other rates should have applied based on cor-
    rected pricing inputs.”2
    BACKGROUND
    I.       Statutory and Regulatory Framework as to Milk
    Pricing
    As observed in Zuber v. Allen, 
    396 U.S. 168
    , 172-73
    (1969):
    The two distinctive and essential phenomena of
    the milk industry are a basic two-price structure that
    permits a higher return for the same product,
    depending on its ultimate use, and the cyclical char-
    acteristic of production.
    Milk has essentially two end uses: as a fluid staple
    of daily consumer diet, and as an ingredient in manu-
    factured dairy products such as butter and cheese.
    Milk used in the consumer market has traditionally
    commanded a premium price, even though it is of no
    higher quality than milk used for manufacture. While
    cost differences account for part of the discrepancy
    in price, they do not explain the entire gap. At the
    same time the milk industry is characterized by peri-
    ods of seasonal overproduction. The winter months
    are low in yield and conversely the summer months
    are fertile. In order to meet fluid demand which is
    relatively constant, sufficiently large herds must be
    maintained to supply winter needs. The result is
    oversupply in the more fruitful months. The histori-
    cal tendency prior to regulation was for milk distrib-
    2
    The district court’s dismissal decision is reported at Carlin v.
    DairyAmerica, Inc., 
    690 F. Supp. 2d 1128
     (E.D. Cal. 2010).
    8732               CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    utors, “handlers,” to take advantage of this surplus to
    obtain bargains during glut periods. Milk can be
    obtained from distant sources and handlers can
    afford to absorb transportation costs and still pay
    more to outlying farmers whose traditional outlet is
    the manufacturing market. [Footnote omitted.] To
    maintain income[,] farmers increase production and
    the disequilibrium snowballs.
    Congress passed the Agricultural Marketing Agreement
    Act of 1937 (
    7 U.S.C. § 601
     et seq.) (“AMAA”) “in order to
    establish and maintain orderly marketing conditions and fair
    prices for agricultural commodities.” Glickman v. Wileman
    Bros. & Elliott, Inc., 
    521 U.S. 457
    , 461 (1997). Section 8c of
    the AMAA (7 U.S.C. § 608c) authorizes the Secretary of
    Agriculture to issue “orders” applicable to “handlers” who
    receive, process, package, or redistribute milk or milk products.3
    “Marketing orders promulgated pursuant to the AMAA are a
    species of economic regulation that has displaced competition
    in a number of discrete markets . . . .” Glickman, 
    521 U.S. at 461
    . As stated in Block v. Cmty. Nutrition Inst., 
    467 U.S. 340
    (1984), “[t]he ‘essential purpose [of this milk market order
    scheme is] to raise producer prices,’ S. Rep. No. 1011, 74th
    Cong., 1st Sess., 3 (1935), and thereby to ensure that the ben-
    efits and burdens of the milk market are fairly and proportion-
    ally shared by all dairy farmers.” 
    Id. at 342
     (second alteration
    in original); see also Ark. Dairy Coop. Ass’n, v. U.S. Dep’t of
    Agric., 
    573 F.3d 815
    , 818 (D.C. Cir. 2009).
    Milk, milk products, and prices paid by handlers to produc-
    ers of raw milk (i.e., dairy farmers) are regulated by what are
    commonly referred to as Federal Milk Marketing Orders
    (“FMMOs”) issued by the USDA pursuant to section 8c(5) of
    the AMAA. 7 U.S.C. § 608c(5). The promulgation process is
    described in Block as follows:
    3
    In the context of milk and milk products, “handler” is defined in 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.9
     (2012).
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                8733
    Under the scheme established by Congress, the
    Secretary must conduct an appropriate rulemaking
    proceeding before issuing a milk market order. The
    public must be notified of these proceedings and pro-
    vided an opportunity for public hearing and com-
    ment. See 7 U. S. C. § 608c(3). An order may be
    issued only if the evidence adduced at the hearing
    shows “that [it] will tend to effectuate the declared
    policy of this chapter with respect to such commodi-
    ty.” 7 U. S. C. § 608c(4). Moreover, before any mar-
    ket order may become effective, it must be approved
    by the handlers of at least 50% of the volume of milk
    covered by the proposed order and at least two-thirds
    of the affected dairy producers in the region. 7 U. S.
    C. §§ 608c(8), 608c(5)(B)(i). If the handlers with-
    hold their consent, the Secretary may nevertheless
    impose the order. But the Secretary’s power to do so
    is conditioned upon at least two-thirds of the produc-
    ers consenting to its promulgation and upon his mak-
    ing an administrative determination that the order is
    “the only practical means of advancing the interests
    of the producers.” 7 U. S. C. § 608c(9)(B).
    
    467 U.S. at 342
     (alteration in original).
    Section 8c(5) of the AMAA requires that the FMMOs con-
    tain provisions which, inter alia: (1) classify milk in accor-
    dance with the purpose for which it is used, (2) set minimum
    prices for each such use that handlers must pay, (3) require
    that said prices be uniform except that adjustments can be
    made for production differentials, grade or quality of the milk,
    and locations of delivery, and (4) provide for the use of
    “blended” prices such that all producers of milk subject to a
    particular FMMO receive a uniform price for the milk deliv-
    ered to handlers regardless of the ultimate use of the milk. 7
    U.S.C. § 608c(5). The AMAA (and hence each FMMO) only
    requires a minimum price. As observed in Farmer Union Milk
    Mktg. Coop. v. Yeutter, 
    930 F.2d 466
    , 468-69 (6th Cir. 1991):
    8734               CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    Although the AMAA mandates a minimum price, it
    does not mandate a maximum price. Handlers cannot
    pay less than the blend price, but they are allowed to
    pay as much as they want. In times of relative scar-
    city, handlers can and do negotiate premiums,
    known as “over-order” prices, for the sale of the
    milk. These premiums are most typically paid for
    milk that is intended for Class I use, but they can
    apply to any of the three classes. Thus, market forces
    are allowed to intrude on this regime on occasion,
    though only in one direction.
    FMMOs have been issued which cover some, but not all,
    regions of the United States.4 See 7 C.F.R. pts. 1001, 1005-07,
    1030, 1032-33, 1124, 1126, 1131, 1135 (2012) (setting price
    regulations for each designated region).
    The Secretary of Agriculture has delegated his authority
    under the AMAA to the Under Secretary for Marketing and
    Regulatory Programs, see 
    7 C.F.R. § 2.22
    (a)(1)(viii)(G)
    (2011), and, in turn, the Under Secretary has delegated it to
    the Administrator for the Agricultural Marketing Service
    (“AMS”). 
    7 C.F.R. § 2.79
    (a)(8)(viii) (2011); see also White
    Eagle Coop. Ass’n v. Connor, 
    553 F.3d 467
    , 482 (7th Cir.
    2009). As to each operative FMMO, there is a “market admin-
    istrator” selected by the Secretary who is empowered, inter
    alia, to: (1) “[a]dminister the order in accordance with its
    terms and provisions”; (2) “[m]ake rules and regulations to
    effectuate the terms and provisions of the order”; (3)
    “[r]eceive, investigate, and report complaints of violations to
    the Secretary”; and (4) announce FMMO prices on designated
    days of each month. 
    7 C.F.R. §§ 1000.25
    (b), 1000.53 (2012).
    The district court correctly observed that “[t]he method by
    which [the USDA has] accomplished [the framework for a
    4
    For example, there is no FMMO covering the state of California. See
    Hillside Dairy Inc. v. Lyons, 
    539 U.S. 59
    , 61 (2003).
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.             8735
    minimum price structure for milk and milk products] is admit-
    tedly complex.” 
    690 F. Supp. 2d at 1130
    . A description of
    part of that methodology is provided in Ark. Dairy Coop.
    Ass’n, 
    573 F.3d at 818-19
    , as follows:
    The AMAA and its implementing regulations use
    two regulatory mechanisms: price fixing and pay-
    ment pooling. The minimum prices that handlers
    must pay vary according to the end use of the milk,
    as categorized in four classes. See 7 U.S.C.
    § 608c(5)(A); 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.40
     (Class I milk is
    sold in fluid form, Class II milk is used to make ice
    cream, soft cheeses, and related products, Class III
    milk is used to produce harder cheeses, and Class IV
    milk is used to make butter and related products
    [including nonfat dry milk products].). Instead of
    setting specific prices to be paid for each Class, the
    Secretary has established a formula by which the
    price for each Class is determined monthly based on
    the average nationwide wholesale prices from the
    previous month. See 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.50
    ; Milk in the
    Northeast and Other Marketing Areas; Notice of
    Proposed Rulemaking and Tentative Partial Final
    Decision, 
    73 Fed. Reg. 35,306
    , 35,308 (June 20,
    2008) (“Tentative Decision”). The formulas for
    Class III and IV milk are based on the nationwide
    average prices for butter, nonfat dry milk, cheese,
    and dry whey, minus a set dollar amount for each of
    those products, multiplied by a “yield factor.” 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.50
    (l)-(o). Class I and II prices are
    derived from the Class III and IV prices but Class I
    prices are adjusted for the location of the handler so
    that handlers pay different prices in different geo-
    graphic areas. See 
    7 C.F.R. §§ 1000.50
    , 1000.52.
    The amounts subtracted from the average sale prices
    of Class III and IV products, known in the milk
    industry as “make allowances” or “manufacturing
    allowances,” are intended to represent the costs to
    8736            CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    the handlers of making the end dairy products from
    raw milk. Tentative Decision, 73 Fed. Reg. at
    35,308. In essence, handlers retain from the average
    wholesale price the amount set by the make allow-
    ance and transfer the balance to producers.
    The second major component of dairy market reg-
    ulation is payment pooling. Under this system, han-
    dlers pay prices according to the end use of milk, but
    all the producers in a geographic area receive the
    same monthly average or “blended” price per unit of
    milk sold, regardless of the use to which their milk
    is put. See 7 U.S.C. § 608c(5)(B); 
    7 C.F.R. §§ 1000.70
    , 1000.76. This payment equalization is
    accomplished through the “producer settlement
    fund” into which handlers pay, or from which han-
    dlers withdraw, according to whether their blend-
    price payments to producers are less or greater than
    the end-use-value of the milk they have purchased.
    
    7 C.F.R. §§ 1000.70
    , 1000.76. Again, the effect of
    this regime is that handlers make payments which
    vary according to the market value of the milk they
    use (as reflected in minimum prices), while all pro-
    ducers in an area receive the same average, or
    blended, price per unit of milk.
    Different geographic areas of the United States are
    regulated under slightly different conditions,
    although the formulas used to set prices of Class III
    and IV milk are the same in all areas. See 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.50
    . Each of eleven areas, generally known as
    a “marketing area” or “milk marketing area,” is gov-
    erned by a different “Order” of the Secretary. See,
    e.g., 7 U.S.C. § 608c(5)(A); 
    7 C.F.R. § 1001.2
    .
    The process utilized by the AMS during the relevant period
    here to establish the formulas through which minimum prices
    were set pursuant to an FMMO is also complicated, but is
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                  8737
    adequately summarized in Ark. Dairy Coop., Inc. v. U.S.
    Dep’t of Agric., 
    576 F. Supp. 2d 147
    , 152 (D.D.C. 2008),
    aff’d, 
    573 F.3d 815
     (D.C. Cir. 2009), as follows:
    Under the FMMOs, a dairy plant pays, and a dairy
    producer receives, minimum prices in the form of
    federally established “component prices” for butter-
    fat, protein, solids not fat, and other solids, or skim-
    fat prices that are derived from those component
    prices. See 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.50
    . There are three fac-
    tors that are used in the pricing formulas: (1) prices
    of certain dairy products surveyed by the National
    Agricultural Statistics Service (“NASS”); (2) a make
    allowance; and (3) a yield. See 
    id.
     The levels of each
    of these factors affect the price that plants pay for
    raw milk and, ultimately, how much producers
    received for their milk. Adjustments in any of these
    factors will impact pricing.
    The make allowance and the yield are fixed by
    rule; the product prices are determined weekly by
    NASS. See 
    id.
     Every Friday morning, NASS reports
    the prices of certain cheeses, butter, non-fat dry
    milk, and dry whey. USDA then announces the
    advanced prices based on the weighted average of
    two weeks of NASS prices. 
    Id.
     The make allowances
    represent the allowance for manufacturing raw milk
    into a finished product. Changes to the make allow-
    ance have an inverse relationship to the resulting
    changes in the minimum prices. Producers benefit
    from lower make allowances, and manufacturers
    benefit from higher make allowances. The yield fac-
    tor represents the amount of a manufactured dairy
    product that can be produced per hundredweight
    (100 pounds) of milk. USDA accounts for the por-
    tion of the price of milk that is attributable to the
    costs of the manufacturing process through the make
    allowance. When the price of manufactured goods is
    8738               CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    raised, however, USDA recaptures the cost by
    reporting a higher price for the wholesale product
    prices to NASS. As a result, any increase in the sell-
    ing price of manufactured goods used to produce
    milk will increase the price manufacturers must pay
    producers for raw milk. 
    Id.
    The pricing formulas are changed through formal
    rule-making hearings. See 
    7 C.F.R. §§ 900.3-900.18
    .
    After the close of the evidentiary portion of the hear-
    ing, exceptions and comments are filed by interested
    parties and an administrative law judge certifies the
    transcript to USDA. See 
    id.
     §§ 900.9-900.10. Dairy
    Programs, a division of USDA, then prepares and
    submits a recommendation to USDA. The recom-
    mendation details the findings of fact, rationale, and
    the legal authority for its decision. See id. § 900.12.
    After Dairy Programs has issued its recommenda-
    tion, another round of comments follow, and a refer-
    endum on the order, as amended, is held. Producers
    facing a referendum must choose between voting out
    the entire marketing order or approving the amended
    order. There is no vote on the amendment itself. If
    the referendum passes, the order is adopted and
    becomes a final rule. See id. §§ 900.300-311.
    To actually set the minimum prices, FMMOs require the
    collection and input of certain economic information regard-
    ing commercial transactions involving milk and milk prod-
    ucts. See, e.g., 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.50
     (2012). Prior to 2000, the
    USDA’s National Agricultural Statistics Service (“NASS”)
    relied on the prices of dairy commodities on established and
    specified public exchanges, including the Chicago and New
    York Mercantile Exchanges, in the calculation of FMMO
    minimum milk prices. See, e.g., 
    63 Fed. Reg. 35,564
     (June 30,
    1998).5 The Dairy Market Enhancement Act of 2000, 7 U.S.C.
    5
    See also Kenneth Bailey & Peter Tozer, An Evaluation of Federal
    Order Reform, 84 J. Dairy Sci. 974, 977 (2001) (indicating that NASS had
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                    8739
    § 1637 et seq. (“DMEA”), was enacted in part to give the
    USDA the authority to make the reporting of dairy product
    information mandatory. See 
    72 Fed. Reg. 36,341
     (July 3,
    2007). However, the regulations implementing the DMEA
    (now codified at 7 C.F.R. Part 1170 (2012)) were not promul-
    gated until 2008.
    The district court summarized NASS’s methods for collect-
    ing pricing information during the period of time relevant to
    this action (and the parties have not disputed that summary)
    as follows:
    Pursuant to the DMEA, weekly surveys are con-
    ducted by the National Agricultural Statistics Service
    (“NASS”) to collect wholesale prices for representa-
    tive products within each category. The survey infor-
    mation is gathered from product manufacturers
    (sometimes referred to in pleadings as milk “han-
    dlers”) who produce a million pounds or more of
    manufactured product per year. The FMMO mini-
    mum prices for milk for class III (hard cheese) and
    IV (dry milk and butter) products are determined by
    applying the wholesale prices reported in the weekly
    surveys to formulae specified by the FMMO. The
    FMMO minimum prices for products in Classes I
    and II are derived by mathematic formulae from the
    prices determined in Classes III and IV.
    Of significance to this action, one of the major
    wholesale pricing inputs collected by NASS for
    computation of the FMMO minimum price for milk
    for Class IV products is the wholesale price for
    been using such exchanges for pricing information but that they were con-
    sidered to be “thin markets” because only a small percent of the commodi-
    ties were actually traded on them and, hence, they were subject to
    potential price manipulation).
    8740             CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    NFDM [nonfat dry milk]. The DMEA requires han-
    dlers to submit NASS survey information according
    to instructions that, among other things, direct the
    handler to exclude from the survey wholesale prices
    for NFDM for forward sales contracts. Forward sales
    contracts are defined as contracts in which the sell-
    ing price is set more than 30 days before the comple-
    tion of the transaction. It appears undisputed that
    forward sales contracts generally reflected lower
    prices for NFDM than were reflected in contracts
    that were completed at or near the time of the trans-
    action during the time period in question.
    
    690 F. Supp. 2d at 1130-31
    . NASS required the han-
    dlers/reporting firms to fill out “Annual Validation Works-
    heets” which included the question “[w]hen reporting nonfat
    dry milk sales data to NASS, did you or can you: exclude for-
    ward pricing sales (sales in which the selling price is estab-
    lished, and not adjusted, 30 or more days before the
    transaction is completed)?”
    For enforcement purposes, the DMEA provides that “[e]ach
    [reporting firm] . . . shall maintain, and make available to the
    Secretary, on request, original contracts, agreements, receipts,
    and other records associated with the sale or storage of any
    dairy products during the 2-year period beginning on the date
    of the creation of the records.” 7 U.S.C. § 1637b(c)(6). The
    2000 version of the DMEA also provided that “[t]he Secretary
    shall take such actions as the Secretary considers necessary to
    verify the accuracy of the information submitted or reported
    under this subtitle.” Pub. L. No. 106-532, § 273(c)(3), 
    114 Stat. 2541
    . In 2008, the DMEA was amended and bolstered
    with the following provision:
    QUARTERLY AUDITS. — The Secretary shall
    quarterly conduct an audit of information submitted
    or reported under this subtitle and compare such
    information with other related dairy market statistics.
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                      8741
    Food, Conservation, and Energy Act of 2008, Pub. L. No.
    110-234, § 1510(b), 
    122 Stat. 9237
     (codified at 7 U.S.C.
    § 1637b(c)(3)(B)).
    Once NASS collects price and volume data, the AMS uses
    them to calculate the FMMO minimum raw milk prices. Non-
    fat dry milk (“NFDM”) prices are one factor used by AMS to
    determine FMMO minimum prices. The DMEA contains no
    enforcement mechanism or mechanism for compensating pro-
    ducers who receive prices for their milk that are lower than
    they should be due to inaccurate reporting.6
    II.   Factual and Procedural Background
    Plaintiffs are “dairy farmers located in states other than
    California who sold raw milk that was priced according to
    [FMMOs] during the time between January 1, 2002 and April
    30, 2007.” 
    690 F. Supp. 2d at 1129-30
    . Defendants are: (1)
    DairyAmerica, Inc. (“DairyAmerica”), a non-profit entity “es-
    tablished by a group of nine dairy cooperatives for the pur-
    pose of marketing dairy products manufactured by the
    6
    The AMAA contains no provision under which milk producers can
    challenge a marketing order through administrative review. See United
    Dairymen of Ariz. v. Veneman, 
    279 F.3d 1160
    , 1164 (9th Cir. 2002). The
    Supreme Court in Stark v. Wickard, 
    321 U.S. 288
     (1944), held that pro-
    ducers could obtain judicial review of the Secretary of Agriculture’s prac-
    tice of deducting certain administrative expenses from the settlement fund
    before calculating the blended price which resulted in a reduced price for
    the producers. The Court found a basis for judicial review because the
    AMAA had given producers “definite personal rights” and “the silence of
    Congress as to judicial review is, at any rate in the absence of an adminis-
    trative remedy, not to be construed as a denial of authority to the
    aggrieved person to seek appropriate relief in the federal courts in the
    exercise of their general jurisdiction.” 
    Id. at 309
    . In our consideration of
    the holdings in Stark, we concluded that “judicial review of the producers’
    complaint was necessary to ‘ensure achievement of the Act’s most funda-
    mental objectives — to wit, the protection of the producers of milk and
    milk products.’ ” United Dairymen, 
    279 F.3d at 1165
     (quoting Block, 
    467 U.S. at 352
    ).
    8742             CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    cooperatives” and (2) California Dairies, Inc., one of the nine
    cooperatives. Id. at 1130. It is alleged that DairyAmerica sells
    approximately 75 percent of the NFDM produced in the
    United States.
    As stated by the district court:
    It is not disputed that, during the time in question,
    Dairy America submitted pricing information to the
    NASS survey that improperly included wholesale
    prices for forward contracts for NFDM. Plaintiffs
    allege, and Defendants do not appear to dispute, that
    approximately ninety percent of the contracts exe-
    cuted by Dairy America and reported in the weekly
    NASS surveys were forward contracts that should
    not have been reported in the NASS surveys accord-
    ing to DMEA procedures. Plaintiffs contends [sic]
    that, because forward contract prices were signifi-
    cantly below spot prices during the time period in
    question, the minimum prices set by the FMMO’s
    for raw milk were significantly lower than would
    have been the case if the information provided by
    Dairy America to NASS had been provided accord-
    ing to instructions.
    Id. at 1131. On account of DairyAmerica’s market domi-
    nance, its erroneous reports had the effect of pushing FMMO
    minimum prices paid to milk producers noticeably lower than
    they would have been otherwise. Thus, because of its own
    transgressions, DairyAmerica obtained significant financial
    benefits from the lowered prices, to the detriment of plaintiff
    dairy farmers.
    In March 2007, DairyAmerica’s misreporting was revealed
    by The Milkweed, a dairy industry publication. In April 2007,
    DairyAmerica’s CEO confirmed that misreporting to the
    NASS.
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                8743
    On or about April 20, 2007, NASS requested that all 39
    firms that had reported NFDM data review their weekly price
    and sales volume submissions for the period of April 29, 2006
    through April 14, 2007, and submit revisions. On June 28,
    2007, NASS published “revised prices and sales volume” for
    NFDM, and the “AMS calculated that the errors in the report-
    ing of nonfat dry milk prices for the period April 29, 2006
    through April 14, 2007 had increased the average 2-week
    price of NFDM by $0.0218 per pound and the average 4-5
    week price of NFDM by $0.0193 per pound during a period
    of 14 months.”
    In February 2008, the USDA Office of the Inspector Gen-
    eral (“OIG”) issued a report regarding “the April 2007 discov-
    ery of the error in the reporting of nonfat dry milk prices.”
    Office of Inspector Gen., U.S. Dep’t of Agric., No. 26901-01-
    IR, Inspection Report: Survey and Estimation Internal Con-
    trols for Nonfat Dry Milk and the Dairy Products Prices
    Report i (2008), available at http:// www.usda.gov/oig/
    webdocs/26901-01-IR.pdf (last visited June 19, 2012).
    Among its findings were:
    A large dairy firm inappropriately included long-
    term forward contracted nonfat dry milk volume and
    price information in their weekly submissions to
    NASS. We found that this dairy firm has been
    including data for sales of this type since 2002.
    NASS then aggregated the misreported data from
    this large dairy firm with the weekly data submitted
    by other dairy firms for the same reporting period.
    This caused inaccurate nonfat dry milk aggregated
    volume and price statistics to be published weekly.
    The internal controls for the survey and estimation
    process used by NASS for the Dairy Products Prices
    report were inadequate, as this error went undetected
    from 2002 until April 2007.
    8744                CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    NASS’ published nonfat dry milk price statistics are
    utilized by AMS as a component of its formula for
    establishing federal milk marketing order (FMMO)
    prices. Given that incorrect nonfat dry milk prices
    were factored into the FMMO formula, the published
    FMMO prices were also incorrect. AMS issued a
    report on June 28, 2007 stating: “The total classified
    value of milk regulated under the FMMO program
    for the period covered by the NASS revision was
    understated by $50 million . . . “ covering the period
    between April 29, 2006, and April 14, 2007.
    ....
    AMS did not have the authority to audit a reporting
    firm’s books when the misreporting occurred. The
    authority was included in the Dairy Marketing Act of
    2000, but the rulemaking necessary to implement a
    program of audits was not completed until July
    2007. AMS began performing audits on August 6,
    2007. Between August 6, 2007, and September 30,
    2007, AMS visited seven plants reporting nonfat dry
    milk volume and price statistics. Based on these vis-
    its, AMS notified NASS of reporting discrepancies
    at six of the plants. NASS contacted these plants and
    explained the proper reporting criteria.
    Id. at i-ii.
    Following the release of the Inspection Report, NASS sent
    letters to “dairy firms” (i.e., handlers) that reported NFDM
    information asking whether they had correctly related the
    NFDM data between January 4, 2002 and April 22, 2006, and,
    if they had not, to provide corrected data. None of the dairy
    firms provided corrected information, and, hence, the NASS
    (and consequently the USDA) was unable to publish revised
    NFDM data or FMMO prices for that period.7 In August
    7
    As noted by the NASS:
    In cases where there had been reporting problems, NASS pro-
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                     8745
    2007, AMS instituted a new auditing process which included
    in-person inspections of large dairy firms and their sales
    records.
    Beginning in March 2009, each plaintiff filed a class action
    on behalf of a nationwide class of raw milk producers in fed-
    eral court based on diversity jurisdiction. See 
    690 F. Supp. 2d at 1131
    . The cases were eventually consolidated. 
    Id.
     The
    Amended Class Action Complaint contains four causes of
    action: the first and second claims for relief charged negligent
    misrepresentation and negligent interference with prospective
    economic advantage, respectively, both under California com-
    mon law; the third claim asserted violation of California’s
    Unfair Business Practices Law, California Business and Pro-
    fessions Code § 17200 et seq.; and the fourth claim alleged
    unjust enrichment under California common law.
    Defendants filed separate motions seeking dismissal of the
    entire lawsuit on five grounds: (1) the filed rate doctrine
    barred plaintiffs’ claims, (2) the DMEA confers no right of
    private enforcement, (3) the USDA is an indispensable party
    but immune from suit herein, (4) the price reporting program
    creates no legal obligation on defendants’ part, and (5) plain-
    tiffs’ state law claims are preempted by the DMEA. The dis-
    trict court dismissed the monetary portions of all four claims
    solely on the grounds that they were not justiciable pursuant
    vided the firms with their previously reported data and asked
    them to review and submit appropriate corrections.
    NASS agreed to summarize results of this process in a special
    report to be released on June 19, 2008. However, no firms pro-
    vided corrected data, and therefore NASS will not issue a special
    report.
    News Release, Nat’l Agric. Statistics Serv., U.S. Dep’t of Agric., NASS
    Will Not Issue Special Report on Nonfat Dry Milk Prices (June 19, 2008),
    available        at        http://www.nass.usda.gov/Newsroom/Notices/
    06_19_2008.asp (last visited June 19, 2012).
    8746              CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    to the filed rate doctrine. 
    690 F. Supp. 2d at 1140-41
    . The dis-
    trict court also held that, while the filed rate doctrine purport-
    edly does not bar injunctive relief, the third cause of action —
    wherein such relief was requested — was inadequately pled.
    
    Id. at 1140
    . In so ruling, the district court noted that:
    Because the filed rate doctrine applies narrowly to
    bar only claims that are based on minimum prices
    paid for raw milk, the court is not willing at this
    point to make the determination that there are no
    other facts that Plaintiffs could possibly plead that
    would cure the deficiency. Further, as noted, the
    court cannot determine at this point that there is no
    non-money equitable remedy available to Plaintiffs.
    For that reason the [amended complaint] will be dis-
    missed with leave to amend.
    The court is also mindful that the filed rate doc-
    trine consists of a body of law that has been the sub-
    ject of conflicting interpretations. The court will
    therefore give favorable consideration to the motion
    of either party for interlocutory appeal on the issue
    of whether the filed rate doctrine bars Plaintiffs’
    claims in this case.
    
    Id. at 1141
    .
    Plaintiffs filed an initial appeal, but their appeal was dis-
    missed because the district court’s ruling was not a final
    order. See WMX Techs., Inc. v. Miller, 
    104 F.3d 1133
    , 1136
    (9th Cir. 1997) (en banc). Plaintiffs then moved in the district
    court to dismiss their complaint with prejudice so that this
    court could exercise jurisdiction. The district court granted
    that motion. Plaintiffs then filed a timely notice of appeal.
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.               8747
    DISCUSSION
    I.   Standard of Review and Applicable Procedural Law
    We review de novo challenges to a dismissal for failure to
    state a claim under Federal Civil Rule 12(b)(6). N.M. State
    Inv. Council v. Ernst & Young LLP, 
    641 F.3d 1089
    , 1094 (9th
    Cir. 2011). That standard is applied to a district court’s dis-
    missal based on the filed rate doctrine. California ex rel.
    Lockyer v. Dynegy, Inc., 
    375 F.3d 831
    , 849 n.16 (9th Cir.
    2004), amended, 
    387 F.3d 966
     (9th Cir. 2004); Brown v. MCI
    Worldcom Network Servs., Inc., 
    277 F.3d 1166
    , 1169 (9th Cir.
    2002). “Such review is generally limited to the face of the
    complaint, materials incorporated into the complaint by refer-
    ence, and matters of judicial notice.” N.M. State Inv. Council,
    
    641 F.3d at 1094
    ; see also Metzler Inv. GMBH v. Corinthian
    Colls., Inc., 
    540 F.3d 1049
    , 1061 (9th Cir. 2008) (citing Tel-
    labs, Inc. v. Makor Issues & Rights, Ltd., 
    551 U.S. 308
    , 322
    (2007)). In undertaking this review, we will “accept the plain-
    tiffs’ allegations as true and construe them in the light most
    favorable to plaintiffs,” Gompper v. VISX, Inc., 
    298 F.3d 893
    ,
    895 (9th Cir. 2002), and will hold a dismissal inappropriate
    unless the complaint fails to “state a claim to relief that is
    plausible on its face,” Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 
    550 U.S. 544
    , 570 (2007).
    Because the only issues on appeal raised by plaintiffs con-
    cern the application of the filed rate doctrine and its preclu-
    sive effect in the present case and because the district court
    did not rule on defendants’ other defenses (such as the pur-
    ported lack of a private right of enforcement under the
    DMEA, the status of the USDA as an indispensable party,
    etc.), our decision is limited to the filed rate doctrine issues.
    See Singleton v. Wulff, 
    428 U.S. 106
    , 120 (1976) (“[A] federal
    appellate court does not consider an issue not passed upon
    below.”); U.S. ex rel. Lee v. SmithKline Beecham, Inc., 
    245 F.3d 1048
    , 1050 n.1 (9th Cir. 2001) (“[W]e limit our review
    to issues argued in a party’s opening brief.”).
    8748               CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    II.    The District Court Did Not Err in Concluding that
    the Agency-set Minimum Prices for Raw Milk Are
    Generally Subject to the Filed Rate Doctrine.
    A.    The Filed Rate Doctrine
    [1] As we observed in E. & J. Gallo Winery v. Encana
    Corp., 
    503 F.3d 1027
    , 1033 (9th Cir. 2007): “The [filed rate]
    doctrine is a judicial creation that arises from decisions inter-
    preting federal statutes that give federal agencies exclusive
    jurisdiction to set rates for specified utilities, originally
    through rate-setting procedures involving the filing of rates
    with the agencies.” “At its most basic, the filed rate doctrine
    provides that state law, and some federal law (e.g. antitrust
    law), may not be used to invalidate a filed rate nor to assume
    a rate would be charged other than the rate adopted by the
    federal agency in question.” Wah Chang v. Duke Energy
    Trading & Mktg., LLC, 
    507 F.3d 1222
    , 1225 (9th Cir. 2007)
    (quoting Transmission Agency v. Sierra Pac. Power Co., 
    295 F.3d 918
    , 929-30 (9th Cir. 2002)). It has generally been rec-
    ognized that there are three “purposes” or “governmental
    interests” which justify or support the filed rate doctrine.
    The origin and justifications for the doctrine can be traced
    to the Supreme Court’s early cases involving the Interstate
    Commerce Act (“ICA”). Ark. La. Gas Co. v. Hall, 
    453 U.S. 571
    , 577 (1981); see Jim Rossi, Lowering the Filed Tariff
    Shield: Judicial Enforcement for a Deregulatory Era, 
    56 Vand. L. Rev. 1591
    , 1598-99 (2003) (henceforth Lowering
    the Filed Tariff Shield). In New York, New Haven & Hartford
    R.R. Co. v. ICC, 
    200 U.S. 361
    , 391 (1906), the Court, in inter-
    preting the ICA, stated:
    [T]he great purpose of the act to regulate commerce,
    whilst seeking to prevent unjust and unreasonable
    rates, was to secure equality of rates as to all, and to
    destroy favoritism, these last being accomplished by
    requiring the publication of tariffs, and by prohibit-
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                     8749
    ing secret departures from such tariffs, and forbid-
    ding rebates, preferences and all other forms of
    undue discrimination.
    Thus, the initial raison d’être for the doctrine concerned sta-
    bilizing rates and preventing pricing discrimination amongst
    ratepayers.8 See Maislin Indus., U.S., Inc. v. Primary Steel,
    Inc., 
    497 U.S. 116
    , 126 (1990) (“The duty to file rates with
    the Commission and the obligation to charge only those rates
    have always been considered essential to preventing price dis-
    crimination and stabilizing rates.” (citations omitted)).
    Once it was determined that federal law required the pri-
    macy of filed rates and tariffs, there developed two additional
    and related justifications for the doctrine, i.e., federal preemp-
    tion (or the supremacy of federal law) and deference to fed-
    eral agency expertise (or primary jurisdiction). As observed in
    Nantahala Power & Light Co. v. Thornburg, 
    476 U.S. 953
    ,
    964 (1986):
    In Chicago & North Western Transp. Co. v. Kalo
    Brick & Tile Co., 
    450 U.S. 311
     (1981), the Court
    similarly noted that the filed rate doctrine as applied
    to the actions of the Interstate Commerce Commis-
    sion assisted in the enforcement of the supremacy of
    federal law:
    “The common rationale of these cases is
    easily stated: ‘[There] can be no divided
    8
    As noted in Lowering the Filed Tariff Shield, 56 Vand. L. Rev. at
    1599:
    In original design, the [filed rate] doctrine was intended to serve
    as a sword to protect consumers from monopolistic price discrim-
    ination, such as a railroad charging different rates to customers
    of different states, or charging the shipping companies with
    whom it competes exorbitant prices, without justifications based
    on the cost of providing service to the customer.
    8750                 CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    authority over interstate commerce, and . . .
    the acts of Congress on that subject are
    supreme and exclusive.’ Missouri Pacific
    R. Co. v. Stroud, 
    267 U.S. 404
    , 408 (1925).
    Consequently, state efforts to regulate com-
    merce must fall when they conflict with or
    interfere with federal authority over the
    same activity.” Id. at 318-319.
    (Alterations in original and parallel citations omitted). Allow-
    ing filed rates to be subject to litigation in state courts (or in
    federal courts applying state law) could result in service rates
    and conditions varying across jurisdictions, which would con-
    flict with the federal interest in uniformity. See Ark. La. Gas
    Co., 
    453 U.S. at 578-79
     (permitting individual ratepayers or
    others to attack a filed rate “would undermine the congressio-
    nal scheme of uniform rate regulation”). That conflict would
    be prevented by treating the filed rates as having what
    amounts to a preclusive effect on state law rate-based claims.
    The third justification concerns the unnecessary interjection
    of the courts into the rate-making process where they have no
    expertise or valid reason to interfere. See, e.g., Montana-
    Dakota Utils. Co. v. Nw. Pub. Serv. Co., 
    341 U.S. 246
    , 251-
    52 (1951) (“We hold that the right to a reasonable rate is the
    right to the rate which the Commission files or fixes, and that,
    except for review of the Commission’s orders, the courts can
    assume no right to a different one on the ground that, in its
    opinion, it is the only or the more reasonable one.”).
    The filed rate doctrine has been given an expansive reading
    and application in this Circuit, even in the face of “debate in
    other forums about [its] wisdom.”9 MCI Telecomms. Corp. v.
    9
    For example, California has declined to create a state filed rate doctrine
    even where the tariffs are filed with the state regulatory agency having
    authority over the subject area and even if the rates have been approved
    as reasonable by that agency. See Knevelbaard Dairies v. Kraft Foods,
    Inc., 
    232 F.3d 979
    , 992-93 (9th Cir. 2000).
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.               8751
    AT&T Co., 
    512 U.S. 218
    , 234 (1994) (quoting Sec. Servs.,
    Inc. v. Kmart Corp., 
    511 U.S. 431
    , 440 (1994)) (internal quo-
    tation marks omitted); see also Square D Co. v. Niagara
    Frontier Tariff Bureau, Inc., 
    476 U.S. 409
    , 417-24 (1986); but
    see Verizon Del., Inc. v. Covad Commc’ns Co., 
    377 F.3d 1081
    , 1089 (9th Cir. 2004) (“[T]he filed rate doctrine now
    functions in the telecommunications field as an anomaly. It is
    a relic, open to repudiation by the FCC.”). In E. & J. Gallo
    Winery, 
    503 F.3d at 1035
    , after reviewing the doctrine and
    “associated principles” of federal preemption, we concluded
    that: “to the extent Congress has given [a federal agency]
    authority to set rates under [a federal statute] and [the agency]
    has exercised that authority, such rates are just and reasonable
    as a matter of law and cannot be collaterally challenged under
    federal antitrust law or state law.” See also Wah Chang, 
    507 F.3d at 1225-26
     (“The filed rate doctrine’s fortification
    against direct attack is impenetrable. It turns away both fed-
    eral and state antitrust actions; it turns away Racketeer Influ-
    enced and Corrupt Organization Act actions; it turns away
    state tort actions; and it even turns away state attempts to
    assert sovereign power to commandeer power contracts.”
    (footnotes omitted)).
    B.   The Filed Rate Doctrine Applies to the Minimum Rates
    for Raw Milk Set under FMMOs pursuant to the
    AMAA.
    [2] No Supreme Court or federal appellate court case has
    considered whether the filed rate doctrine applies to market-
    ing orders setting the prices for raw milk under the AMAA.
    However, a number of trial courts (in addition to the district
    court here) have held it does. See, e.g., In re Se. Milk Antitrust
    Litig., 
    801 F. Supp. 2d 705
    , 732-34 (E.D. Tenn. 2011); In re
    Dairy Farmers of Am., Inc. Cheese Antitrust Litig., 
    767 F. Supp. 2d 880
    , 894-95 (N.D. Ill. 2011); Servais v. Kraft Foods,
    Inc., 
    631 N.W.2d 629
    , 633-35 (Wis. Ct. App. 2001); but see
    Ice Cream Liquidation, Inc. v. Land O’Lakes, Inc., 
    253 F. Supp. 2d 262
    , 276 (D. Conn. 2003) (holding that, while filed
    8752              CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    rate doctrine does apply to challenges to milk pricing set
    under an FMMO, it does not apply to a challenge to a defen-
    dant’s artificially inflated wholesale milk prices, which are
    permitted to be in excess of the minimum rates set under the
    FMMOs).
    Originally, the filed rate doctrine arose in the context of the
    following paradigm. A rate or tariff within an industry regu-
    lated by federal statute is filed by a carrier or other ser-
    vice/product provider with a federal agency, which in turn
    accepts and publishes it. See, e.g., Sec. Servs., Inc., 
    511 U.S. at 435
    . Thereafter, the carrier (and its customer) is not
    allowed to charge (or pay) a different rate for that ser-
    vice/product other than the filed one. 
    Id.
     (“We have held these
    provisions ‘to create strict filed rate requirements and to for-
    bid equitable defenses to collection of the filed tariff.’ ” (quot-
    ing Maislin Indus., 
    497 U.S. at 127
    )). In turn, the rate is held
    not to be subject to challenge on antitrust, state law or most
    other grounds. See, e.g., Keogh v. Chi. & Nw. Ry. Co., 
    260 U.S. 156
    , 161-65 (1922); Wegoland Ltd. v. NYNEX Corp., 
    27 F.3d 17
    , 18 (2d Cir. 1994) (“Simply stated, the doctrine holds
    that any ‘filed rate’ — that is, one approved by the governing
    regulatory agency — is per se reasonable and unassailable in
    judicial proceedings brought by ratepayers.”). As noted in Ice
    Cream Liquidation, 
    253 F. Supp. 2d at
    275:
    Application of the filed rate doctrine in any particu-
    lar case is not determined by the culpability of the
    defendant’s conduct or the possibility of inequitable
    results. Nor does the doctrine’s application depend
    on the nature of the cause of action the plaintiff
    seeks to bring. Rather, the courts have held that the
    doctrine is to be applied strictly to prevent a plaintiff
    from bringing a cause of action whenever [the] pur-
    pose[s] underlying the filed rate doctrine [are] impli-
    cated.
    (Citations omitted).
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.              8753
    [3] Here, admittedly, the statutory scheme created by
    AMAA does not present the typical filed rate scenario. For
    example, the handlers do not submit rates or prices to the
    AMS in order to create an unwavering price. Rather, various
    pricing data are provided to the NASS (some of which are
    supplied by handlers such as the defendants) and that data are
    utilized along with “make allowances” and “yields” (which
    are fixed by the agency’s rules) in pricing formulas which, in
    turn, delineate the raw milk rates. See 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.50
    (2012). Also, the rates consist of only minimum prices from
    which the handlers and producers can deviate, albeit only in
    an upward direction (which favors the dairy producers). Fur-
    ther, the set rates are not uniform across the nation. They can
    vary amongst the eleven established milk marketing areas,
    and there are also locations without any applicable FMMOs
    (and hence no controlling filed rates). See 7 C.F.R. subtit. B,
    ch. X (2012); Hillside Dairy Inc., 
    539 U.S. at 61
    . Addition-
    ally, the individual handlers make payments which vary
    according to the market value of the milk they use as reflected
    in the minimum payments, but all the milk producers in the
    area covered by the FMMO receive the same average, or
    blended, price per unit of milk. Finally, the FMMOs (which
    contain the pricing formulas), while promulgated by the
    USDA and subject to appropriate rulemaking proceedings
    including public hearing and comment, must be approved by
    the handlers of at least 50 percent of the volume of milk
    within the geographic area covered by the proposed order and
    at least two-thirds of the affected dairy producers in the
    region. See 7 U.S.C. § 608c(8). Nevertheless, despite those
    elements, there are sufficient attributes which justify the
    application of the doctrine to the AMAA milk pricing situa-
    tion generally.
    [4] First, milk pricing is the subject of extensive federal
    statutory and regulatory control. See, e.g., 7 U.S.C. § 608c(5).
    Additionally, under the AMAA, the USDA (via the AMS and
    through the FMMOs) sets minimum prices for raw milk pur-
    chased from producers by handlers where there can be no
    8754              CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    downward deviation in the rate. Therefore, to paraphrase
    Gallo, the filed rate doctrine is applicable because Congress
    has given the USDA authority to set rates under 7 U.S.C.
    § 608c(5) and the USDA has exercised that authority to create
    the FMMOs which, in turn, are utilized to establish minimum
    prices for raw milk purchases; and thus “such rates are just
    and reasonable as a matter of law.” 
    503 F.3d at 1035
    .
    Further, the three underlying justifications for the filed rate
    doctrine apply to FMMO prices set under the AMAA. The
    setting of minimum rates prevents discriminatory pricing
    (albeit to a more limited extent than other situations where the
    doctrine has been applied) and stabilizes prices by assuring
    dairy producers of reasonable payments for raw milk as fixed
    by the AMS. Additionally, the setting of minimum rates by
    means of formulas established in the FMMOs is a matter
    which clearly falls within an area of USDA expertise, which
    most courts would not possess. Finally, the AMAA and its
    concomitant regulations establish a federal scheme as to uni-
    form minimum pricing which should not generally be the sub-
    ject of attack by ratepayers or others. As stated in 
    7 U.S.C. § 602
    :
    It is declared to be the policy of Congress —
    (1) Through the exercise of the powers conferred
    upon the Secretary of Agriculture under this chapter,
    to establish and maintain such orderly marketing
    conditions for agricultural commodities in interstate
    commerce as will establish, as the prices to farmers,
    parity prices as defined by section 1301(a)(1) of this
    title [
    7 U.S.C. § 1301
    (a)].
    (2) To protect the interest of the consumer by (a)
    approaching the level of prices which it is declared
    to be the policy of Congress to establish in subsec-
    tion (1) of this section . . . and (b) authorizing no
    action under this chapter which has for its purpose
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                      8755
    the maintenance of prices to farmers above the level
    which it is declared to be the policy of Congress to
    establish in subsection (1) of this section.
    C.     Meaningful Review by the Federal Agency Is Not a
    Prerequisite to the Application of the Filed Rate Doc-
    trine.
    Plaintiffs challenge application of the filed rate doctrine
    here based on the contention that the USDA lacks “any actual
    legal authority to meaningfully review the substance of the
    pricing.” They rely on Brown v. Ticor Title Ins. Co., 
    982 F.2d 386
     (9th Cir. 1992), where we held that the filed rate doctrine
    did not apply to title insurance rates filed with state insurance
    agencies because, although the rates were filed with the state
    agencies, they “were not subjected to meaningful review by
    the state.” 
    Id.
     at 394 (citing Wileman Bros. & Elliott, Inc. v.
    Giannini, 
    909 F.2d 332
    , 337-38 (9th Cir. 1990)).10
    We are not persuaded that Brown requires meaningful
    review for the filed rate doctrine to apply in all cases, how-
    ever. In Square D Co. v. Niagara Frontier Tariff Bureau, Inc.,
    
    476 U.S. 409
    , 417 n.19 (1986), the Supreme Court held that
    the filed rate doctrine applied to rates merely filed with the
    Interstate Commerce Commission (“ICC”), even when those
    rates had not been “investigated and approved by the ICC.”
    10
    Plaintiffs also relied on our decision in Wileman Bros., which is read-
    ily distinguishable from the present case. In Wileman Bros., the defendants
    were nectarine and plum growers who served as members of committees
    appointed by the Secretary of Agriculture and who (without the Secre-
    tary’s authorization) issued and enforced a “well-matured” standard gov-
    erning when those varieties of fruits could be picked. Wileman Bros. did
    not involve a tariff or rate submitted to or issued by a federal agency.
    Thus, the filed rate doctrine was not applicable to that situation. Further,
    the holding of that case was that the defendants could not establish immu-
    nity from antitrust claims on the simple basis that the Secretary had “tacit-
    ly” approved the higher maturity standards they issued by his failing to
    explicitly disapprove them, as he could have done under applicable regula-
    tions. See 
    909 F.2d at 337-38
    .
    8756                CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    Similarly, in Gallo, we held that the filed rate doctrine applied
    to market rates for natural gas authorized by the Federal
    Energy Regulatory Commission (“FERC”). The plaintiff
    argued that the filed rate doctrine applied only to “only rates
    that have been literally filed with and approved by FERC.”
    
    503 F.3d at 1039
    . We disagreed, emphasizing that the essen-
    tial question was whether the market rates were authorized by
    the FERC. See 
    id.
     We explained that the FERC was not
    required to use “any particular form of regulation in its quest
    to ensure reasonable rates.” 
    Id.
     It mattered only that the rates
    were authorized by the FERC in the exercise of its statutory
    authority. See 
    id. at 1040-43
    .11 Thus, like the district courts
    that have addressed the issue, we do not read Brown as mak-
    ing meaningful agency review a sine qua non for the applica-
    bility of the filed rate doctrine. See In re Hawaiian &
    Guamanian Cabotage Antitrust Litig., 
    754 F. Supp. 2d 1239
    ,
    1245-46 (W.D. Wash. 2010) (collecting cases that character-
    ize Brown as an “outlier” decision on the issue).
    [5] The proper inquiry, therefore, is whether the FMMO
    11
    Gallo relied on an earlier case involving market rates for electricity,
    where it was held that the filed rate doctrine applied because the FERC
    was “doing enough regulation to justify federal preemption of state laws.”
    Gallo, 
    503 F.3d at 1041
     (quoting Pub. Util. Dist. No. 1 of Snohomish
    Cnty. v. Dynegy Power Mktg., Inc., 
    384 F.3d 756
    , 760 (9th Cir. 2004)). In
    Gallo too, we concluded that the FERC was doing enough regulation for
    the filed rate doctrine to apply. First, the FERC determined that the best
    way to ensure just and reasonable rates in the evolving natural gas market
    was to allow natural gas sales to proceed at market prices. See 
    id.
     at 1041-
    42. Second, the FERC reviewed the natural gas market and determined it
    was competitive. See id. at 1042. Third, although the FERC did not
    impose individualized reporting requirements on sellers of natural gas, it
    maintained ongoing oversight of the market and took corrective responses
    to evidence of market manipulation. See id. We thus concluded that,
    “[b]ecause FERC has not abdicated its responsibilities but has acted, albeit
    with a light hand, to authorize just and reasonable rates in the natural gas
    arena, the Filed Rate Doctrine continues to preempt any rate-setting activi-
    ties by the courts and bar federal antitrust claims under the Filed Rate
    Doctrine.” Id.
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                       8757
    minimum prices were authorized by the USDA pursuant to its
    statutory authority, or, to paraphrase Gallo, whether the
    USDA was doing enough regulation to justify federal preemp-
    tion of state laws. See Gallo, 
    503 F.3d at 1041
    . We conclude
    that it did.
    The applicable statute required the Secretary to issue orders
    which provided for a particular, but partial, methodology for
    establishing minimum uniform prices for raw milk. 7 U.S.C.
    § 608c(5). It is not disputed that the Secretary exercised his
    discretion and promulgated regulations governing that rate
    setting process and issued orders in the form of the FMMOs
    to effectuate those requirements of the statutory scheme. Part
    of the methodology includes formulas which are dependent
    upon the input of sales prices and volumes supplied by desig-
    nated handlers.
    Plaintiffs argue that the prices DairyAmerica reported to
    NASS are comparable to market-based rates like those in
    Brown because AMS only had the power to take NASS data,
    plug them into a predetermined formula, and then publish the
    resulting FMMO prices. Once the prices were reported to
    NASS, in other words, the rest of the pricing was mechanical
    and amounted to silence by AMS. Moreover, as plaintiffs
    argue, AMS did not have (at that time) the power to review
    the accuracy of data collected by the NASS. However, plain-
    tiffs do not contend that the Secretary did not have the statu-
    tory authority to review the accuracy of NASS data.12 Instead
    they argue that the USDA’s implementing regulations did not,
    during the applicable time frame, contain any explicit provi-
    sion for such a review. In opposition, defendants point out
    that the USDA has, in at least 18 instances, used its discretion
    to change the price data it used to calculate milk prices.13
    12
    The USDA clearly had statutory authority. Plaintiffs’ Complaint
    alleges that the Secretary issued a rule that allowed for such review in
    2007. Thus, even if the Secretary did not choose to review the accuracy
    of data reported to NASS, he had the power to do so.
    13
    Defendants’ citations are to the federal register and, hence, judicially
    noticeable. See 
    44 U.S.C. § 1507
    .
    8758             CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    Plaintiffs counter that, under the relevant implementing regu-
    lations, AMS only has the power to do so “[i]f for any reason
    a price or pricing constituent required for computing the
    prices described in § 1000.50 is not available.” 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.54
     (2012). Section 1000.50 calculates rates based on
    NASS pricing data.
    Plaintiffs clearly underestimate the extent of the agency’s
    authority (and its execution of those powers) in setting the
    minimum prices under the FMMOs. Indeed, the USDA here
    did far more than the FERC in the Gallo case in this regard.
    First, the agency promulgated regulations which created an
    intricate system for the setting of the prices. Unlike the FERC
    in Gallo which merely “reviewed the natural gas market and
    determined it was competitive,” 
    503 F.3d at 1042
    , the USDA
    not only examined the dairy products market, but also took
    into account volume, location, grade/quality of the milk, pro-
    duction differentials, and other factors in creating the formu-
    las in the FMMOs. Also, the formulas do not consider only
    one or two data points but a large number of them to arrive
    at the ultimate price determination. Additionally, the formulas
    which generate the rates also include the consideration of
    “make allowances” and “yields” which are fixed by the agen-
    cy’s rules. Further, the FMMOs are not effective until the
    Secretary obtains the approval of handlers of at least 50 per-
    cent of the milk processed and two-thirds of the affected dairy
    producers within the geographic territory subject to the order.
    7 U.S.C. § 608c(8). Thus, the Secretary exercises extensive
    authority vis-a-vis milk pricing in establishing the formulas in
    the FMMOs which in turn set the parameters for the issued
    minimum prices.
    Additionally, as in Gallo, the USDA here maintained ongo-
    ing oversight of the market and initiated remedial actions in
    response to evidence of market manipulation. Indeed, upon
    being informed of the misreporting by DairyAmerica, the
    agency took steps to determine the effect of the misinforma-
    tion, calculated corrective prices for the periods when the
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                      8759
    original data were available, and enacted regulations and
    amendments to the FMMOs for improved oversight of the
    reporting process. Furthermore, plaintiffs’ contention (that
    AMS did not and could not do anything but accept the NASS
    data even if it knew they were unreliable) is incorrect. Plain-
    tiffs’ argument is essentially that, had DairyAmerica provided
    false pricing information to NASS and then sent a letter to
    AMS saying “we made this data up,” AMS would have been
    obligated to use that data to set prices. That is, to say the least,
    a curious interpretation of the pertinent regulations, i.e., 
    7 C.F.R. §§ 1000.50
     and 1000.54. Indeed, during the relevant
    period, the market administrators (who were empowered to
    administer the FMMOs) had the authority to (1) make rules
    and regulations to effectuate the terms and provisions of the
    FMMOs, (2) receive, investigate, and report violations to the
    Secretary, and (3) recommend amendments to the Secretary.
    See 
    7 C.F.R. § 1000.25
    (b) (2004).
    [6] In sum, the USDA did possess the authority and did
    exercise it to address problems as to the agency-set minimum
    prices for raw milk under the FMMOs, such that the filed rate
    doctrine is applicable in the present AMAA situation.14
    14
    Plaintiffs also cite three cases from the same district court which
    declined to apply the filed rate doctrine to Medicaid reimbursement rates
    for prescription drugs. Each case, however, rejected the application of the
    doctrine at least in part because there were no filed rates. Massachusetts
    v. Mylan Labs., 
    357 F. Supp. 2d 314
    , 329 (D. Mass. 2005) (holding that
    the filed rate doctrine was inapplicable because “[t]he reported data do not
    control the rates which Defendants can charge customers, as a tariff
    would”); In re Lupron Mktg. and Sales Prac. Litig., 
    295 F. Supp. 2d 148
    ,
    163 n.16 (D. Mass. 2003); In re Pharm. Indus. Average Wholesale Price
    Litig., 
    263 F. Supp. 2d 172
    , 192 (D. Mass. 2003) (holding that filed rate
    doctrine did not apply because pharmaceutical companies do not file rates
    with any agency). Furthermore, none of these cases address the doctrine
    at significant length and they would not therefore be particularly persua-
    sive even if they were on point.
    8760               CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    III.    Precedent Does Not Require and Policy Consider-
    ations Do Not Support Applying the Filed Rate Doc-
    trine as a Bar under the Facts of This Case.
    Plaintiffs argue that even if the filed rate doctrine applies
    to agency-set milk prices in general, it should not serve as a
    bar in this case, since the USDA has indicated that it would
    have set different prices had DairyAmerica reported its data
    correctly. We know that prices would have been different but
    for the misreporting, because (1) the NASS issued retroactive
    revised prices for part of the relevant period after
    DairyAmerica acknowledged its erroneous reporting, and (2)
    AMS calculated the increase in the prices of NFDM for the
    period between April 29, 2006 and April 14, 2007. We agree
    that the filed rate doctrine does not preempt or otherwise pose
    a preclusive bar to plaintiffs’ lawsuit, because: (1) the federal
    agency itself determined that the FMMO prices were incorrect
    and (2) the policy considerations behind the doctrine do not
    justify applying the doctrine as a bar in this case.
    Plaintiffs initially attempt to avoid the strictures of the filed
    rate doctrine by arguing that they are not actually seeking to
    challenge a fixed rate at all. However, we have made it clear
    that the doctrine precludes remedies which rely on a court’s
    recalculation of rates which would have been charged, even
    if the plaintiff is not directly challenging the filed rate:
    Wah Chang cannot avoid the fact that it seeks what
    amounts to having the courts determine what rates
    the Energy Companies should have charged instead
    of the rates they did charge. Wah Chang would inev-
    itably drag the courts into a determination of what
    rate would be fair and proper. That is precisely what
    Wah Chang cannot do.
    Wah Chang, 
    507 F.3d at 1226
    . Establishing damage amounts
    for plaintiffs’ claims, similarly, would require calculating
    what rates would have been set but for the defendants’ misre-
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                        8761
    porting. For this reason, it would be unavailing for plaintiffs
    to rely on Gallo’s dictum that “[w]e are aware of no basis for
    holding that the Filed Rate Doctrine bars claims based on a
    reference point for pricing transactions (be it a trade index,
    the Consumer Price Index, or the New York Stock Exchange)
    that is not itself a FERC-approved rate.” Gallo, 
    503 F.3d at
    1048 n.15. Still, as discussed below, it is a different situation
    where the agency itself in the context of the AMAA/DMEA
    recognizes that its issued rates are in error due to the miscon-
    duct of the enriched party.
    A.       The Filed Rate Doctrine Does Not Bar Plaintiffs’
    Claims Given the USDA’s Recognition That Its Pub-
    lished FMMO Rates Were Incorrect Due to Defen-
    dants’ Misreporting.
    [7] The Supreme Court has said that the filed rate doctrine
    does not apply to bar a private litigant’s rate-related claims if
    the rate has been “suspended” or “set aside” by the relevant
    agency. Keogh, 
    260 U.S. at 163
    .15 Whether an agency has suf-
    ficiently rejected a rate for purposes of the filed rate doctrine
    analysis, whether that rejection should eliminate the doc-
    trine’s preemptive bar, and, even if the bar is so removed,
    whether thereafter a plaintiff should be allowed to recover
    damages arising from the incorrect prior rates are admittedly
    difficult issues. They can only be correctly answered after
    15
    Accord City of Groton v. Conn. Light & Power Co., 
    662 F.2d 921
    , 929
    (2d Cir. 1981):
    Under the Keogh or “filed rate” doctrine, . . . a public utility sub-
    ject to regulation is not subject to antitrust liability to its custom-
    ers for rates or services provided under tariffs approved by the
    appropriate regulatory agency. The rationale is that the regulatory
    agency determines the legal rate and the utility must collect it
    while it is in effect. The doctrine applies to rates that have been
    published but not acted upon by the regulatory agency, because
    they are the legal rates until suspended or set aside.
    (Citation omitted).
    8762               CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    consideration of the underlying statutory scheme in which the
    doctrine is being applied and the justifications for the doc-
    trine.
    Initially, the defendants contend that the issues disputed
    herein were settled by Ark. La. Gas Co., where the Supreme
    Court held that the filed rate doctrine prohibited a federally
    regulated seller of natural gas from charging higher rates than
    those filed with the FERC despite the contention that, had the
    seller applied for a higher rate, the FERC would have
    approved it. 
    453 U.S. at 573-76, 584-85
    . In that case, the
    Court did not find compelling the argument that the defen-
    dant’s misconduct (a breach of contract) had prevented the
    plaintiff seller from filing for a higher rate.16 
    Id. at 583
    . How-
    ever, the Court specifically focused on the controlling statute
    (i.e., the Natural Gas Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 717
     et seq.). It
    observed that:
    Not only do the courts lack authority to impose a dif-
    ferent rate than the one approved by the Commis-
    sion, but the Commission itself has no power to alter
    a rate retroactively. When the Commission finds a
    rate unreasonable, it “shall determine the just and
    reasonable rate . . . to be thereafter observed and in
    force.” § 5 (a), 
    52 Stat. 823
    , 15 U. S. C. § 717d (a)
    (emphasis added).
    Id. at 578. Based upon the plain text of the statute specifically
    precluding the FERC from altering a published rate retroac-
    tively as well as ordering any reparations based on the unlaw-
    fulness of past rates, the Court concluded that a state court
    could not be allowed “to award what amounts to a retroactive
    right to collect a rate in excess of the filed rate [because it
    16
    The Court in Ark. La. Gas Co. also noted that “[w]e save for another
    day the question whether the filed rate doctrine applies in the face of
    fraudulent conduct.” Id. at 583 n.13.
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                     8763
    would] ‘only accentuate[ ] the danger of conflict.’ . . . [and
    constitute a] usurpation of federal authority.” Id. at 584.17
    Obviously, where the controlling statute prohibits the fed-
    eral agency from altering a filed rate retroactively or limits
    any application of reconsidered rates to prospective situations,
    then the agency cannot effectively suspend or set aside the
    published rates for purposes of a lawsuit seeking recovery
    based on injuries arising from the imposition of those rates.
    However, unlike the Natural Gas Act, there is nothing in the
    AMAA or the DMEA which specifically bars the USDA from
    revising rates where handlers have supplied incorrect data to
    the agency.
    Turning to the issue of the extent to which the federal
    agency must indicate that it is suspending, setting aside or
    otherwise rejecting the filed rate, it is noted that a large seg-
    ment of the cases dealing with the filed rate doctrine arise in
    the context of statutes such as the ICA, the Communications
    Act, and legislation involving the FERC, where an anti-
    discriminatory policy as to filed rates or tariffs lies at the very
    heart of the statutory scheme. See, e.g., New York, New Haven
    & Hartford R.R. Co., 
    200 U.S. at 391
    ; AT&T Co. v. Central
    Office Tel., Inc., 
    524 U.S. 214
    , 223 (1998). In such situations,
    a federal agency’s ability to set aside a published rate retroac-
    tively would be extremely limited and, hence, any attempt to
    do so would have to be explicitly executed and thoroughly
    explained. For example, in Keogh, it was held that a rate that
    is filed with the ICC (and, after hearings, is approved by the
    Commission) is deemed reasonable and non-discriminatory as
    17
    Defendants also cite Montana-Dakota Utilities Co. where the Court
    declined to order the lower court to direct an agency to make a retroactive
    determination where Congress had not granted such authority to the
    agency. 
    341 U.S. at 254
    . It was noted that the agency’s decision was
    required because the reasonableness of the rate charged, which could only
    be assessed by the agency, was determinative as to whether the plaintiff
    had a viable cause of action and a basis for the federal courts to exercise
    jurisdiction. 
    Id. at 253-54
    .
    8764             CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    a matter of law, “[u]nless and until suspended or set aside.”
    
    260 U.S. at 160-63
    . However, the Court observed that in the
    context of the ICA, setting aside or suspending the published
    tariff for purposes of a legal action for damages would be
    extremely difficult because (1) any such case which led to a
    damages award to the plaintiff shipper would operate as “a
    preference over his trade competitors” and vitiate the para-
    mount purpose of the ICA (i.e., preventing pricing discrimina-
    tion), and (2) in any such proceeding, “the Commission
    [would have to] determine whether a rate is discriminatory
    . . . . But by no conceivable proceeding could the question
    whether a hypothetical lower rate would under conceivable
    conditions have been discriminatory, be submitted to the
    Commission for determination.” 
    Id. at 163-64
    .
    Plaintiffs cite to the Supreme Court’s decision in Maislin
    for the proposition that the doctrine does not bar claims chal-
    lenging prices that were rejected by the relevant agency. That
    reading of the case is overbroad. In Maislin, the Court noted
    the ICA prohibited both carriers and shippers from deviating
    from published tariffs filed with the ICC, but also required
    that the carrier’s rates be nondiscriminatory and reasonable,
    and charged the ICC, upon determining that a rate or practice
    violates the statute, with prescribing the subsequent rate or
    practice to be followed. 
    497 U.S. at 119-20
    . In 1986, in
    response to a growing trend wherein carriers and shippers pri-
    vately negotiated rates lower than those filed with the agency,
    the ICC concluded that changes in the motor carrier industry
    “clearly warrant[ed] a tempering of the former harsh rule of
    adhering to the tariff rate in virtually all cases,” and so it
    established a new policy whereby in referenced cases it would
    “decid[e] if the collection of undercharges would be an unrea-
    sonable practice.” 
    Id. at 121
    . A carrier that had entered into
    such a private contract went bankrupt, and its bankruptcy
    estate brought an action against the shipper to collect the dif-
    ference between the contract rate and the higher filed tariff.
    The Court initially held that “The filed rate doctrine . . . con-
    tains an important caveat: The filed rate is not enforceable if
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                        8765
    the ICC finds the rate to be unreasonable.” 
    Id. at 128
    . The
    Court went on to quote from Arizona Grocery Co. v. Atchi-
    son, Topeka & Santa Fe Ry. Co., 
    284 U.S. 370
    , 384 (1932),
    that “Under [the Act] the shipper was bound to pay the legal
    rate; but if he could show that it was unreasonable he might
    recover reparation.” Id. at 129 (alteration in original).18 Thus,
    Maislin stands, in part, for the limited proposition that, where
    the statute allows the agency to decide that a published tariff
    is unreasonable under controlling law, the filed rate doctrine
    18
    However, the Court found that the ICC had not found the rates were
    unreasonable but rather that the carrier had engaged in an unreasonable
    practice. It then held that:
    The Commission argues that under the filed rate doctrine, a find-
    ing that the carrier engaged in an unreasonable practice should,
    like a finding that the filed rate is unreasonable, disentitle the car-
    rier to collection of the filed rate. We have never held that a carri-
    er’s unreasonable practice justifies departure from the filed tariff
    schedule. But we need not resolve this issue today because we
    conclude that the justification for departure from the filed tariff
    schedule that the ICC set forth in its Negotiated Rates policy rests
    on an interpretation of the Act that is contrary to the language and
    structure of the statute as a whole and the requirements that make
    up the filed rate doctrine in particular.
    Under the Negotiated Rates policy, the ICC has determined
    that a carrier engages in an unreasonable practice when it
    attempts to collect the filed rate after the parties have negotiated
    a lower rate. The ICC argues that its conclusion is entitled to def-
    erence because § 10701 does not specifically address the types of
    practices that are to be considered unreasonable and because its
    construction is rational and consistent with the statute. See Chev-
    ron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 843 (1984).
    We disagree. For a century, this Court has held that the Act,
    as it incorporates the filed rate doctrine, forbids as discriminatory
    the secret negotiation and collection of rates lower than the filed
    rate. See supra, at 126-128. By refusing to order collection of the
    filed rate solely because the parties had agreed to a lower rate, the
    ICC has permitted the very price discrimination that the Act by
    its terms seeks to prevent.
    
    497 U.S. at 129-30
     (footnote omitted).
    8766             CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    will not bar a plaintiff from seeking reparation from the impo-
    sition of the unreasonable rate.
    The Supreme Court in ICC v. American Trucking Associa-
    tions, 
    467 U.S. 354
     (1984), considered the related issue
    regarding the extent to which an agency can retroactively
    reject a previously filed rate. In the Motor Carrier Act of
    1980, 
    49 U.S.C. § 10706
    (b)(3), Congress set forth specific
    guidelines to which motor carrier rate bureaus had to comply
    in order to receive antitrust immunity. In response, the ICC
    issued an interpretive ruling wherein it proposed to adopt a
    new remedy wherein it would retroactively reject “effective”
    tariffs that had been submitted in substantial violation of the
    law. It based its authority to adopt that remedy on former 
    49 U.S.C. § 10762
    (e), which provided that the “Commission may
    reject a tariff submitted to it by a common carrier . . . if that
    tariff violates this section or regulation of the Commission
    carrying out this section.” Id. at 359-60. The Court held that
    section 10762(e) did not authorize the Commission to reject
    effective tariffs, but nevertheless found that the ICC’s author-
    ity “is not bounded by the powers expressly enumerated in the
    Act . . . . [but that] the Commission also has discretion to take
    actions that are ‘legitimate, reasonable, and direct[ly] adjunct
    to the Commission’s express statutory power.’ ” Id. at 364-65
    (third alteration in original) (quoting In re Trans Alaska Pipe-
    line Rate Cases, 
    436 U.S. 631
    , 655 (1978)). The Court found
    the ICC’s new remedy to be a “justifiable adjunct to its
    express statutory mandate.” 467 U.S. at 370.
    The district court here considered the issue of whether the
    FMMO prices were rejected by the agency such that the filed
    rate doctrine would be inapplicable. It found that the USDA
    had disapproved of the rates but then stated that “the issue
    before the court is whether the disapproval of rates by the reg-
    ulating agency can be held by the courts to operate retroac-
    tively.” 
    690 F. Supp. 2d at 1139
    . The court relied on both
    American Trucking and City of Groton to hold that “rejection”
    in the context of filed rate doctrine analysis necessarily
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                       8767
    involves (1) the agency’s (presumably formal) suspension or
    setting aside of the published rates, and (2) a finding that a
    “statutory mandate” would be furthered by the retroactive
    rejection of the minimum pricing structures set forth in
    FMMOs in question.19 
    Id. at 1139-40
    . We disagree with the
    first point and conclude that the second was satisfied.
    [8] As discussed above, the primary purposes of the
    AMAA and DMEA are: (1) “to establish and maintain such
    orderly marketing conditions for agricultural commodities in
    interstate commerce as will establish, as the prices to farmers,
    parity prices,” 
    7 U.S.C. § 602
    (1), and (2) “the protection of
    the producers of milk and milk products,” Block, 
    467 U.S. at 352
    . Additionally, the prices that are set for raw milk under
    the applicable statutes are minimum rates which can be (and
    are) subject to further negotiation between handlers and dairy
    farmers. Those rates are not initially filed and reviewed by the
    19
    The district court also held that the filed rate doctrine should preclude
    plaintiffs’ claim for damages because they had not alleged that
    DairyAmerica’s actions were willful or knowing. 
    690 F. Supp. 2d at
    1139-
    40. Plaintiffs argue that NASS’s instructions were clear and that the fact
    that DairyAmerica’s reporting errors were self-serving suggests that its
    misstatements were knowing. The Supreme Court made a similar infer-
    ence in American Trucking, holding that “[t]he guidelines for antitrust
    immunity . . . are of such a nature that carriers who submit tariffs in sub-
    stantial violation of agreements will be aware of their transgressions.” 467
    U.S. at 370-71. The regulations in this case were similarly clear (“don’t
    report long-term prices” is not a very hard instruction to understand), yet
    we need not address the issue of whether DairyAmerica’s misreporting
    was intentional because neither the district court nor the parties have iden-
    tified a precedent which holds that knowledge is determinative of plain-
    tiffs’ right to proceed. The district court quotes Cooperative Power
    Association v. FERC, which held that American Trucking “approved retro-
    active tariff rejection as a sanction for knowing violations of agreements”
    but omits its qualification that the Supreme Court’s decision was premised
    on the assumption that “any carrier in substantial violation of a rate-bureau
    agreement would be aware of the violation.” 
    739 F.2d 390
    , 391 n.3 (8th
    Cir. 1984) (per curiam). Cooperative Power contains no language requir-
    ing knowledge. And since American Trucking assumed knowledge, it did
    not reach the question of whether damages could be recovered without it.
    8768                CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    agency but rather are the product of formulas established by
    the USDA which are, in part, dependent upon the receipt of
    pricing data from certain handlers. In such a situation, there
    is nothing in the controlling statutes or concomitant regula-
    tions that would appear to require any formal process or par-
    ticular expression for the agency’s retroactively setting aside
    or rejecting milk prices that have been incorrectly set as a
    result of misreporting by certain handlers. Further, the statu-
    tory goals as to an orderly mandate of marketing conditions
    and the protection of milk producers would both be served by
    imposing consequences on handlers for misreporting data20
    that resulted in incorrect FMMO pricing and multimillion dol-
    lar losses for dairy farmers.
    [9] Neither Keogh, Maislin, nor American Trucking
    addresses the issue of what specific steps an agency need take
    before it can be deemed to have “rejected” a rate. Such a
    question cannot be considered in a vacuum; the steps required
    before an agency’s rate “rejection” should be recognized will
    necessarily vary based on both the statutory framework within
    which the agency acts and upon the purposes of the statute in
    furtherance of which the agency acts. In American Trucking,
    the Court noted that the agency itself had limited its rejection
    powers such that “effective tariffs will be nullified only upon
    findings of substantial violations of rate-bureau agreements.”
    467 U.S. at 370. Neither Keogh nor Maislin had the opportu-
    nity to address this issue of when an agency has taken suffi-
    cient steps to officially disapprove a rate. We conclude that
    the USDA’s actions here constitute a sufficient rejection such
    that the filed rate doctrine is not a bar. Further, the statutory
    mandate of the AMAA and the DMEA, as well as the policies
    of the filed rate doctrine more generally, are furthered by our
    conclusion that the filed rate doctrine does not apply to bar
    plaintiffs’ claims here.
    20
    The district court found that about 90 percent of the contracts reported
    to the NASS by DairyAmerica were forward contracts, which under
    DMEA procedures were not to be included in the data provided to the
    NASS. 
    690 F. Supp. 2d at 1131
    .
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                    8769
    [10] The USDA adequately expressed its disapproval of
    the FMMO prices.21 While the USDA’s recalculation of mini-
    mum dairy prices was not explicitly called a rejection, the
    agency recognized that earlier filed rates were incorrect at the
    time they were filed and imposed significant and improper
    costs on producers. These “revisions” were, as AMS made
    clear, not necessarily complete since “reallocation effects
    [were] not considered.” The USDA also sought to recalculate
    prices for the whole class period, but could not do so because
    dairy handlers did not supply it with accurate data on their
    sales of NFDM for the entire class period. While plaintiffs
    seek to characterize these revisions as a wholesale repudia-
    tion, and defendants as a mere speculative exercise, the reality
    is that AMS did recognize and attempt to estimate the impact
    of DairyAmerica’s misstatements. The Secretary then took
    actions to revise regulations to prevent such misreporting
    from recurring. The USDA took no further action, noting that
    “[a]ll of the funds in the FMMO pools for the 14-month
    period covered by NASS’ revision had previously been dis-
    bursed to the milk producers, and corrective disbursements to
    producers were no longer possible.” But the USDA also rec-
    ognized that the rates that were filed were incorrect at the
    time they were filed. Indeed, when members of Congress, out-
    raged by the uncompensated losses suffered by the milk pro-
    ducers, asked what plans the agency had to remedy the
    situation, the USDA responded by ensuring that, moving for-
    21
    While the defendants argue that the AMS (which defendants charac-
    terize as “the division that the Secretary charged with FMMO minimum
    price oversight and enforcement”) did not reject or change previously
    announced FMMO prices as a result of the discovery of their misreporting,
    the USDA OIG has stated: “Given that incorrect nonfat dry milk prices
    were factored into the FMMO formula, AMS has stated that its published
    FMMO prices were incorrect. According to the AMS, this caused the total
    value of milk to be understated by $50 million between April 29, 2006 and
    April 14, 2007.” Further, on June 28, 2007, AMS issued a report on “Im-
    pacts of NASS Nonfat Dry Milk Price and Sales Volume Revisions on
    Federal Order Prices” which was based on revisions due to the discovery
    of the misreporting.
    8770                 CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    ward, the agency would promulgate regulations providing for
    more oversight responsibilities and more effective enforce-
    ment mechanisms. See 7 C.F.R. pt. 1170 (2012).
    [11] Given that at the time of the misreporting the agency
    lacked the authority to sanction DairyAmerica,22 the record
    supports the conclusion that the USDA rejected the FMMO
    rates at issue. It is in precisely this scenario that Maislin and
    Keogh recognized that the filed rate doctrine should not bar
    a private litigant from pursuing claims involving those rates.
    Our holding will not permit a flood of litigation such that
    the filed rate doctrine will be circumvented every time a milk
    producer has a quibble with FMMO prices. To the contrary,
    this case presents a narrow exception to the general rule that
    the filed rate doctrine not only applies but functions so as to
    bar FMMO price-related claims. Here, we are faced with the
    unusual situation where (1) the misreporting is both signifi-
    cant in scope and undisputed between the parties, (2) the
    USDA has recognized that the FMMO rates based on
    DairyAmerica’s erroneous reports were incorrect, and (3) per-
    mitting the rate-related claims to move forward is the only
    way to remedy the injuries suffered by the milk producers, the
    very class of persons the statutory scheme was enacted to pro-
    tect.
    B.    The Purposes of the AMAA and DMEA Would Not Be
    Served by Giving the Filed Rate Doctrine Preemptive
    Effect Here.
    The district court reasoned that “while the DMEA sets forth
    procedures for the submission and collection of milk pricing
    survey data, there is nothing to indicate a ‘statutory mandate’
    22
    Because the USDA itself had no mechanism for retroactive sanctions,
    plaintiffs reason, it could only have attempted to calculate revised rates to
    facilitate private litigation (they deny, however, that such an interpretation
    of the agency’s actions is necessary for their claims to succeed).
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                      8771
    that would be furthered by the retroactive ‘rejection’ of the
    minimum pricing structures set forth in the FMMO’s in ques-
    tion.” 
    690 F. Supp. 2d at 1139
    . Yet, as cited by plaintiffs, the
    DMEA’s mandate is that the USDA “shall establish a pro-
    gram of mandatory dairy product information reporting that
    will . . . provide timely, accurate, and reliable market informa-
    tion.” 7 U.S.C. § 1637b(a). Their complaint includes numer-
    ous statements from legislators which suggest that the
    DMEA, by compelling dairy firms to provide information to
    NASS, was intended to help AMS produce more accurate
    prices. Retroactive adjustment of FMMO rates provides a
    straightforward incentive for reporting firms to obey the
    DMEA which would increase the accuracy and reliability of
    market information and ensure that AMS sets correct and
    accurate prices.
    Further, the AMAA (which is the underlying legislation)
    was created to stop the “destabilizing competition” among
    dairy farmers and the essential purpose of the FMMO scheme
    is to raise producer prices. Block, 467 U.S. at 341-42. It
    would be contrary to those statutory purposes to hold that a
    handler who misreports required data (which results in poten-
    tially millions of dollars in losses to dairy producers and
    unjustified monetary benefits to itself) should be able to avoid
    liability because of the absence of a specific provision as to
    retroactive remedies, even after the agency has found miscon-
    duct by that party.23 However, the plaintiffs here are proceed-
    ing under state law, not federal. Hence, at this point, it is only
    the filed rate doctrine that has been utilized as a barrier to
    their case.
    23
    If the acts of misreporting by the handler were considered to be viola-
    tions of the FMMO orders themselves, the AMAA provides for civil pen-
    alties of up to $1,000 for each such violation. 7 U.S.C. § 608c(14)(B).
    8772                 CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    C.        The Purposes of the Filed Rate Doctrine Do Not Sup-
    port Applying It as a Bar under the Facts of This Case.
    Since the cases cited by both plaintiffs and defendants pro-
    vide, at best, vague guidance on the applicability of the filed
    rate doctrine to the facts of this case, this court would look
    again to the purposes of the doctrine in the context of the
    present statutory scheme. Clipper Exxpress v. Rocky Moun-
    tain Motor Tariff Bureau, Inc., 
    690 F.2d 1240
    , 1266-67 (9th
    Cir. 1982) (applying Keogh’s policy considerations to deter-
    mine that the filed rate doctrine was not a bar). Courts typi-
    cally describe the filed rate doctrine as having three purposes:
    deference to agencies’ greater expertise in rate-setting, pre-
    venting discrimination by ensuring all ratepayers face the
    same price, and avoiding disruption of a Congressional
    scheme for uniform price regulation. Wegoland Ltd., 
    27 F.3d at 21
    . All of these goals would be implicated by a reversal of
    the district court’s decision.
    1.    Assessing damages would not require excessive
    speculation or hypothetical considerations of agency
    decision making.
    Defendants argue that the filed rate doctrine should be
    applied because, even with the NASS recalculation, the dis-
    trict court would have a great deal of trouble calculating dam-
    ages. Plaintiffs counter that the formula used to convert
    NFDM data to FMMO prices was at all relevant times fixed
    by statute and regulation. Defendants concede this, but argue
    that a shift in the filed rate would have had substitution effects24
    and hence a simple recalculation of the FMMO rates would
    not produce an accurate measure of damages. In other words,
    if DairyAmerica had accurately reported NFDM prices, some
    FMMO prices would have been different. That price differ-
    ence would have given market participants a different set of
    24
    MS referred to these as “reallocation” effects. Defendants call them a
    “dynamic model.” But all parties are referring to the same phenomenon.
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.                       8773
    relative prices for different classes of milk which in turn
    would have produced losses or gains that cannot be captured
    by AMS’s mere revision of FMMO prices. This is certainly
    true to some extent, but it is impossible to say how large this
    effect would have been without more facts. Given that the dif-
    ferences in prices were two cents per pound of NFDM, it
    seems likely that any substitution effects would have been rel-
    atively small.25 On the other hand, the aggregate effect of just
    14 months of misstated prices was $50 million, so substitution
    effects might still have been significant.
    Some uncertainty can arise in any calculations of damages,
    but that does not preclude recovery where it is clear that some
    damage has occurred.26 Unlike the damages contemplated in
    25
    Defendants also note that other firms’ misstatements were included in
    the revised figures issues by NASS and then argue that plaintiffs might not
    be able to get data from firms besides DairyAmerica in discovery and
    hence would not be able to calculate accurate revised prices using the
    FMMO formulas. But if plaintiffs seek to recover damages from
    DairyAmerica only, damages would be measured by the effect
    DairyAmerica’s misstatements alone had on the FMMO prices. Also, as
    noted above, DairyAmerica sells about 75 percent of the NFDM produced
    in the United States, and approximately 90 percent of its contracts reported
    in the weekly NASS surveys were forward contracts which should not
    have been included.
    26
    As stated in Clemente v. State, 
    707 P.2d 818
    , 828 (Cal. 1985):
    In general, one who has been tortiously injured is entitled to be
    compensated for the harm and the injured party must establish
    “by proof the extent of the harm and the amount of money repre-
    senting adequate compensation with as much certainty as the
    nature of the tort and the circumstances permit.” (Rest.2d Torts,
    § 912, p. 478.) However, “[t]here is no general requirement that
    the injured person should prove with like definiteness the extent
    of the harm that he has suffered as a result of the tortfeasor’s con-
    duct. It is desirable that responsibility for harm should not be
    imposed until it has been proved with reasonable certainty that
    the harm resulted from the wrongful conduct of the person
    charged. It is desirable, also, that there be definiteness of proof
    of the amount of damage as far as is reasonably possible. It is
    8774                 CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    Keogh, those in the present case are not “purely speculative”
    or “supplied by conjecture,” and “proof of such facts” is not
    “impossible.” 
    260 U.S. at 164-65
    . To prevail in Keogh, the
    plaintiffs would have had to show not only that the rate would
    have been different had the defendants’ misconduct not
    occurred, but that the ICC would have disapproved of that dif-
    ferent rate. 
    Id. at 164
    . In the present case, by contrast, the
    actions the USDA would have taken had it had correct data
    from DairyAmerica are clear: the USDA would have
    announced different FMMO prices, ones more favorable to
    the producers. It is only the specific prices that would have
    been set which remain somewhat unclear. Calculating dam-
    ages would not, therefore, involve the kind of “hypothetical”
    speculation about agency decisions that Keogh forbids.
    2.    Plaintiffs’ claims do not pose a significant risk of
    price discrimination or destabilization.
    Discrimination in the present context relates to the concern
    that “[i]f [one party] could recover . . . damages resulting
    from the exaction of a rate higher than that which would oth-
    erwise have prevailed, the amount recovered might, like a
    rebate, operate to give him a preference over his trade com-
    petitors.” 
    Id. at 163
    . Plaintiffs contend that discrimination is
    not an issue because their suit’s class-action allegations
    ensure that all affected milk producers will be treated alike.
    Defendants counter that the Supreme Court has ruled that
    class action status alone is not enough to defeat the filed rate
    doctrine. Square D, 476 U.S. at 423. We have endorsed an
    opinion of the Second Circuit which interpreted Square D to
    hold that the principle of nondiscrimination still suggests the
    even more desirable, however, that an injured person not be
    deprived of substantial compensation merely because he cannot
    prove with complete certainty the extent of harm he has suf-
    fered.” (Rest.2d Torts, § 912, com. a, at p. 479.)
    (Alteration in original).
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.              8775
    filed rate doctrine should be applied in class actions. In re
    NOS Commc’ns, 
    495 F.3d 1052
    , 1059 (9th Cir. 2007) (citing
    Marcus v. AT&T Corp., 
    138 F.3d 46
    , 61 (2d Cir. 1998)). Mar-
    cus, however, qualified this holding: “We agree that ‘the con-
    cerns for discrimination are substantially alleviated in [a]
    putative class action’ . . . . However, the Supreme Court has
    rejected the suggestion that . . . the nondiscrimination princi-
    ple [is] inapplicable to a putative class action suit.” Marcus,
    
    138 F.3d at 61
     (first alteration in original) (emphasis added)
    (citations and internal quotation marks omitted). NOS Com-
    munications should, therefore, be read as rejecting any blan-
    ket rule that discrimination is not a concern in class actions,
    but still not going so far as holding that putative class action
    status is irrelevant to our inquiry into the discriminatory
    impact of not applying the filed rate doctrine.
    While putative class action status does not resolve the ques-
    tion, defendants’ arguments that judgment in favor of plain-
    tiffs would have a discriminatory effect are weak. Defendants
    contend that awarding damages against DairyAmerica would
    discriminate against them in comparison with other milk han-
    dlers. However, as observed above, the prohibition against
    discriminatory pricing under the AMAA is concerned with
    discrimination suffered by the dairy producers, not the han-
    dlers. In any case, were damages assessed against it,
    DairyAmerica would not be paying a higher (discriminatory)
    rate at all; it would be paying damages corresponding to the
    higher rate its own mistakes (or bad acts) had previously
    caused producers to pay it. It would therefore not, as defen-
    dants contend, “face higher/non-uniform prices for the rele-
    vant period.” Instead, it would face the same prices as
    everyone else and also a separate damage award. That award
    might, certainly, put it at a disadvantage relative to its com-
    petitors (though it is unclear how large that disadvantage
    would be given that it controls 75 percent of the NFDM mar-
    ket), but it has already profited from the lower prices its mis-
    reporting has allowed it to enjoy; damages would at least
    partially cancel out this undeserved benefit.
    8776              CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.
    3.   Allowing Plaintiffs’ claims to go forward would not
    unduly disrupt the Congressional pricing scheme
    embodied by the AMAA.
    Plaintiffs did not initiate this lawsuit to challenge the agen-
    cy’s authority to set minimum milk prices or to directly con-
    test rates which the USDA in its expertise has continued to
    treat as being correct and/or valid. Rather, it was only after
    the USDA concluded that DairyAmerica’s misreporting had
    contaminated the minimum price setting process that this
    action was filed. Consequently, this case does not involve a
    scenario where a litigant is seeking to have a court substitute
    its evaluation of a proper rate for the agency’s determination.
    This lawsuit does not constitute a disruption of the Congres-
    sional pricing scheme embodied in the AMAA. As we
    observed in Gallo, “[m]isreported rates and rates reported for
    fictitious transactions are not [agency]-approved rates, and
    barring claims that such fictitious transactions damaged pur-
    chasers in the natural gas market would not further the pur-
    pose of the filed rate doctrine.” 
    503 F.3d at 1045
    . Moreover,
    the rate scheme here differs from typical filed rates. While
    Congress undoubtedly intended the FMMOs’ minimum prices
    to apply in a uniform way within the monthly periods and the
    geographic areas, there is no indication of an overarching con-
    gressional or agency intent for uniformity on a nationwide
    scale, for a long period of time, or even in terms of the actual
    price paid, given that the FMMO merely sets a floor price.
    The facts of this case, therefore, do not justify applying the
    filed rate doctrine preemptively. The district court would not
    need to second-guess agency decision-making or speculate
    about what the agency would have done in order to assess lia-
    bility or calculate damages. To hold otherwise would be an
    exercise of mechanical formalism in contravention of the pur-
    poses of both the AMAA/DMEA and the filed rate doctrine
    itself.
    CARLIN v. DAIRYAMERICA, INC.              8777
    CONCLUSION
    [12] The district court properly determined that the filed
    rate doctrine applies to the AMAA minimum milk pricing
    program, but erred by concluding that the doctrine applies to
    bar the plaintiffs’ state-law claims in this case. The judgment
    of the district court dismissing the case is therefore reversed.
    REVERSED AND REMANDED.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 10-16448

Citation Numbers: 688 F.3d 1117

Judges: , Fisher, George, Johnnie, Rawlinson, Raymond

Filed Date: 8/7/2012

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 8/5/2023

Authorities (59)

city-of-groton-city-of-norwich-borough-of-jewett-city-second-taxing , 662 F.2d 921 ( 1981 )

lawrence-marcus-marc-kasky-on-behalf-of-themselves-and-all-others , 138 F.3d 46 ( 1998 )

WHITE EAGLE CO-OP. ASS'N v. Conner , 553 F.3d 467 ( 2009 )

Cooperative Power Association v. Federal Energy Regulatory ... , 739 F.2d 390 ( 1984 )

wegoland-ltd-michael-roth-of-the-estate-of-howard-weiner-donna-rutili , 27 F.3d 17 ( 1994 )

farmers-union-milk-marketing-cooperative-gerald-piche-peter-j-kleiman , 930 F.2d 466 ( 1991 )

wmx-technologies-inc-fka-waste-management-inc-a-delaware , 104 F.3d 1133 ( 1997 )

Cost Management Services, Inc. v. Washington Natural Gas ... , 99 F.3d 937 ( 1996 )

United States of America, Exrel., Insoon Lee v. Smithkline ... , 245 F.3d 1048 ( 2001 )

william-j-brown-iii-on-behalf-of-himself-and-all-others-similarly , 277 F.3d 1166 ( 2002 )

Metzler Inv. GMBH v. Corinthian Colleges, Inc. , 540 F.3d 1049 ( 2008 )

United Dairymen of Arizona Shamrock Farms Company v. Ann M. ... , 279 F.3d 1160 ( 2002 )

New Mexico State Investment Council v. Ernst & Young LLP , 641 F.3d 1089 ( 2011 )

clipper-exxpress-a-corporation-v-rocky-mountain-motor-tariff-bureau , 690 F.2d 1240 ( 1982 )

john-w-gompper-jr-and-esther-sefaradi-john-stewart-morton-richard , 298 F.3d 893 ( 2002 )

people-of-the-state-of-california-ex-rel-bill-lockyer-attorney-general , 387 F.3d 966 ( 2004 )

people-of-the-state-of-california-ex-rel-bill-lockyer-attorney-general , 375 F.3d 831 ( 2004 )

verizon-delaware-inc-verizon-new-england-inc-verizon-maryland-inc , 377 F.3d 1081 ( 2004 )

knevelbaard-dairies-a-general-partnership-consisting-of-john-knevelbaard , 232 F.3d 979 ( 2000 )

public-utility-district-no-1-of-snohomish-county-a-municipal-corporation , 384 F.3d 756 ( 2004 )

View All Authorities »