Pacific Choice Seafood Company v. Wilbur Ross ( 2020 )


Menu:
  •                 FOR PUBLICATION
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD COMPANY;           No. 18-15455
    SEA PRINCESS, LLC; PACIFIC
    FISHING, LLC,                                D.C. No.
    Plaintiffs-Appellants,     4:15-cv-05572-
    HSG
    v.
    WILBUR ROSS, U.S. Secretary of              OPINION
    Commerce; NATIONAL MARINE
    FISHERIES SERVICE,
    Defendants-Appellees.
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the Northern District of California
    Haywood S. Gilliam, Jr., District Judge, Presiding
    Argued and Submitted December 4, 2019
    San Francisco, California
    Filed September 25, 2020
    Before: Sidney R. Thomas, Chief Judge, and William A.
    Fletcher and Eric D. Miller, Circuit Judges.
    Opinion by Judge Miller
    2             PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    SUMMARY *
    Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and
    Management Act
    The panel affirmed the district court’s summary
    judgment entered in favor of the National Marine Fisheries
    Service in an action brought by Pacific Choice Seafood
    Company challenging the Service’s rule imposing a quota
    system for the Pacific non-whiting groundwater fishery,
    limiting the total allowable catch and prohibiting any one
    entity from controlling more than 2.7 percent of the
    outstanding quota share.
    In 2015, the Service determined that Pacific Choice and
    related entities together owned or controlled at least 3.8
    percent of the quota share. Acting under the Magnuson-
    Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act of 1976
    (the “Act”), the Service ordered Pacific Choice to divest its
    excess share.
    The panel held that Pacific Choice’s suit was timely
    because it was brought within 30 days of the Service’s
    publication of the 2015 rule requiring divestiture. 
    16 U.S.C. § 1855
    (f)(1).
    In challenging the 2.7 percent quota share limit, first,
    Pacific Choice argued that the Service misinterpreted the
    term “excessive share” in 18 U.S.C. § 1853a(c)(5)(D) by
    sidelining considerations of market power in favor of per-
    *
    This summary constitutes no part of the opinion of the court. It
    has been prepared by court staff for the convenience of the reader.
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                   3
    vessel profitability. Because the Act was ambiguous as to
    what factors the Service must consider in setting a maximum
    share, the panel turned to step two of the framework set forth
    in Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. NRDC, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
     (1984),
    and considered whether the Service adopted a “reasonable
    interpretation” of the statute. The panel held that it was
    reasonable for the Service to conclude that other factors can
    dictate a lower maximum share than might be required by a
    singular focus on preventing excessive market power.
    Second, Pacific Choice argued that the Service acted
    arbitrarily and capriciously by failing to consider all relevant
    factors and relying on insufficient analysis in choosing the
    2.7 percent limit. The panel held that the record showed that
    the Service considered market power. The panel further held
    that the Service engaged in a reasoned process from which
    its path to the 2.7 percent limit may reasonably be discerned.
    The panel held that Pacific Choice’s interpretation of the
    administrative record was not persuasive. The panel
    concluded that the Service did not act arbitrarily or
    capriciously in setting the 2.7 percent maximum share.
    The panel rejected Pacific Choice’s statutory and
    Administrative Procedure Act challenges to the Service’s
    control rule. The Act requires that the Service “establish []
    a maximum share . . . that a [share] holder is permitted to
    hold, acquire, or use.” 16 U.S.C. § 1853a(c)(5)(D)(i). The
    Service interpreted “hold, acquire, or use” to include
    “control” and defined “control” to include, among other
    things, “the ability through any means whatsoever to control
    or have a controlling influence over the entity to which
    [quota      share]       is    registered.”    
    50 C.F.R. § 660.140
    (d)(4)(iii)(H). The panel held that its review of the
    Service’s interpretation of the rule was governed by Chevron
    analysis, and the panel saw nothing in the statute that
    4            PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    unambiguously foreclosed the Service’s approach. The
    panel further held that the rule was not arbitrary or
    capricious.
    COUNSEL
    Ryan P. Steen (argued) and Jason T. Morgan, Stoel Rives
    LLP, Seattle, Washington, for Plaintiffs-Appellants.
    David Gunter (argued) and Bridget Kennedy McNeil,
    Attorneys; Eric Grant, Deputy Assistant Attorney General;
    Jeffrey Bossert Clark, Assistant Attorney General;
    Environment and Natural Resources Division, United States
    Department of Justice; Maggie B. Smith, Office of the
    General Counsel, National Oceanic and Atmospheric
    Administration, Washington, D.C.; for Defendants-
    Appellees.
    OPINION
    MILLER, Circuit Judge:
    In 2010, the National Marine Fisheries Service
    implemented a quota system for the Pacific non-whiting
    groundfish fishery, one of several stocks of fish that the
    Service administers in the Pacific Ocean. Acting under the
    Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management
    Act of 1976, 
    16 U.S.C. §§ 1801
    –1891d (the Magnuson-
    Stevens Act or the Act), the Service imposed a quota limiting
    the total allowable catch, divided it among the participants
    in the fishery, and prohibited any one entity from “own[ing]
    or control[ling]” more than 2.7 percent of the outstanding
    quota share. 
    50 C.F.R. § 660.140
    (d)(4)(i). The Service
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                5
    defined “control” to include “the ability through any means
    whatsoever to control or have a controlling influence over”
    an entity with quota share. 
    Id.
     § 660.140(d)(4)(iii)(H).
    In 2015, the Service determined that Pacific Choice
    Seafood Company and related entities (collectively, Pacific
    Choice) together owned or controlled at least 3.8 percent of
    the quota share. After the Service ordered Pacific Choice to
    divest its excess share, Pacific Choice brought this action,
    alleging that the Service’s 2.7 percent maximum share and
    its “control” rule exceeded its authority under the
    Magnuson-Stevens Act and violated the Administrative
    Procedure Act. The district court granted summary judgment
    to the Service. We affirm.
    I
    Congress enacted the Magnuson-Stevens Act to prevent
    overfishing and to ensure that “fisheries [are] conserved and
    maintained so as to provide optimum yields on a continuing
    basis.” 
    16 U.S.C. § 1801
    (a)(5). The Act establishes eight
    regional fishery management councils, each of which is
    charged with developing a “fishery management plan” for
    the fisheries in its region. 
    Id.
     § 1852(a)(1), (h)(1). A
    management plan must prescribe measures “necessary and
    appropriate for the conservation and management of the
    fishery.” Id. § 1853(a)(1), (b)(3). Once a council develops a
    plan, the Secretary of Commerce must evaluate it and either
    approve or reject it. Id. § 1854(b)(1). The Secretary has
    delegated that responsibility to the Service. See Pacific
    Dawn LLC v. Pritzker, 
    831 F.3d 1166
    , 1170 (9th Cir. 2016).
    In 1990, the regional fishery councils began to regulate
    some fisheries by adopting quota programs under which the
    councils divided up the total allowable catch and gave
    participants in the fishery the right to harvest a specified
    6            PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    quantity of fish. See Pacific Coast Fed’n of Fishermen’s
    Ass’ns v. Blank, 
    693 F.3d 1084
    , 1087 (9th Cir. 2012). Such
    programs proved controversial, and in 1996, Congress
    imposed a temporary moratorium on new quota programs.
    Sustainable Fisheries Act, Pub. L. No. 104-297, § 108(e),
    
    110 Stat. 3559
    , 3576–77 (1996). In 2007, after the National
    Academy of Sciences concluded that quota programs “can
    be effective solutions to a host of fishery-related problems,
    including economic inefficiency, overcapitalization . . . and
    overfishing,” Congress reauthorized new quota programs,
    which it called “limited access privilege programs.” Pacific
    Coast, 693 F.3d at 1087–88; see Magnuson-Stevens Fishery
    Conservation and Management Reauthorization Act of
    2006, Pub. L. No. 109-479, § 106, 
    120 Stat. 3575
    , 3586
    (2007).
    Congress set out several requirements for limited access
    privilege programs. Most relevant here, a council must
    ensure that no one entity acquires “an excessive share” of the
    total privileges. 16 U.S.C. § 1853a(c)(5)(D). To that end, a
    council must establish “a maximum share, expressed as a
    percentage of the total limited access privileges, that a
    limited access privilege holder is permitted to hold, acquire,
    or use,” along with “any other limitations or measures
    necessary to prevent an inequitable concentration of limited
    access privileges.” Id.
    This case involves the limited access privilege program
    for the Pacific non-whiting groundfish fishery. As their
    name suggests, groundfish live near the bottom of the ocean.
    See West Coast Groundfish, National Oceanic and
    Atmospheric Administration, https://www.fisheries.noaa.gov/
    species/west-coast-groundfish. The fishery consists of more
    than 90 species of groundfish in the Pacific Ocean off the
    coast of California, Oregon, and Washington, including
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                   7
    lingcod, sablefish, sole, and rockfish, but not including the
    Pacific whiting, or hake, which is regulated separately. See
    
    50 C.F.R. § 660.140
    , table 1 to paragraph (d)(1)(ii)(D). The
    relevant regional council for the fishery is the Pacific Fishery
    Management Council, which has representatives from
    California, Oregon, Washington, and Idaho, as well as from
    Indian tribes with federally recognized fishing rights in those
    States. 
    16 U.S.C. § 1852
    (a)(1)(F).
    Even before Congress reauthorized limited access
    privilege programs in 2007, the Council had started to
    implement a rationalization program for the Pacific fisheries
    it manages. In this context, “rationalization” means avoiding
    overcapacity—the presence of more fishing vessels than
    necessary to catch a sustainable number of fish—by, among
    other things, reducing the number of vessels operating in the
    Council’s fisheries. In addition to reducing overfishing, the
    Council aimed to “increase net economic benefits” from its
    fisheries and to create “individual economic stability” for
    vessels that operated within them. Pacific Coast, 693 F.3d
    at 1089.
    The Council’s years-long deliberative process began
    with the Trawl Individual Quota Committee, a committee of
    industry representatives formed to analyze possible quota
    limits on both an aggregate and per-species level. In 2003,
    relying on data from aggregate average catches from 1994 to
    2003, the Quota Committee proposed several possible limits
    on the aggregate quota share that could be held by any one
    entity, ranging from 1.5 to 5 percent of the total allowable
    catch.
    After the Quota Committee completed its analysis, the
    Groundfish Allocation Committee reviewed the
    recommendations and “added three options for the Council’s
    consideration,” ranging from the average maximum share
    8            PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    for the 1994–2003 period to 1.5 times those limits. The
    Allocation Committee’s report paid particular attention to
    the “maximum fleet consolidation level” that each option
    would create—in other words, how much market
    concentration would result. Part of the Allocation
    Committee’s analysis involved calculating a Herfindahl-
    Hirschman index, or “HHI,” a measure of market
    concentration commonly employed in the antitrust context.
    See Saint Alphonsus Med. Ctr.-Nampa Inc. v. St. Luke’s
    Health Sys., Ltd., 
    778 F.3d 775
    , 786 (9th Cir. 2015). That
    analysis suggested that the Council could set aggregate catch
    limits up to about 18 percent without creating
    anticompetitive effects in the fishery.
    But after significant deliberation among the Quota
    Committee, the Allocation Committee, and the Council, the
    Allocation Committee failed to agree on a single
    recommendation. After proposing two new options, the
    Allocation Committee asked yet another committee—the
    Groundfish Management Team—to evaluate all of the
    options that had been proposed.
    The Management Team began by noting that while
    “[a]ntitrust concerns define the upper extreme of where
    limits can be set,” fishing quotas are also “a tool for
    balancing the Council’s social objectives against the
    undesired effects of the . . . drive toward increased economic
    efficiency.” In contrast to the Quota Committee and the
    Allocation Committee, which had focused on aggregate
    revenues, the Management Team focused on per-vessel
    profitability. It analyzed historical data on a per-vessel basis
    to determine the current profitability of the fishery. It then
    projected profitability based on varying fleet sizes, and it
    cautioned that “concerns about control” resulting from
    higher quota share maximums “go beyond revenues” and
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                   9
    involve “other issues such as bargaining, market power, and
    types of relationships that may influence the operation of the
    fishery.” In light of its conclusion that a fleet size of 40 to
    50 vessels would provide optimal profitability while
    minimizing “control and consolidation of quota ownership,”
    the Management Team presented possible maximum quota
    shares ranging from approximately 1.3 to 3.8 percent but
    ultimately recommended a limit of 2.3 to 2.7 percent
    depending on the desired amount of consolidation.
    The Management Team’s per-vessel approach mostly
    won out. In March 2009, the Groundfish Advisory Subpanel
    evaluated proposals from the Management Team and the
    Allocation Committee and issued a brief report. The
    Advisory Subpanel acknowledged the “trade-off”
    recognized by the Management Team “between preventing
    excessive market control . . . and the lower revenues and
    efficiency associated with control limits that are set too low.”
    It recommended a 2.7 percent maximum aggregate quota
    share, which it noted was the “mid range of the data” in the
    Management Team’s report. The Advisory Subpanel did not
    completely      adopt      the      Management           Team’s
    recommendations; some of its proposed limits for individual
    species instead matched the Allocation Committee’s
    recommendations, or proposed a limit not recommended by
    either committee.
    After further deliberation on several matters not at issue
    here, the Council proposed Amendment 20 to the overall
    fishery plan implementing the limited access privilege
    program, including the 2.7 percent aggregate catch limit.
    
    75 Fed. Reg. 53,380
     (Aug. 31, 2010); 
    75 Fed. Reg. 32,994
    (June 10, 2010). The Service approved the plan in August
    2010 with some technical changes, and it finalized the
    relevant rules in October and December of that year. See
    10           PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    
    75 Fed. Reg. 78,344
     (Dec. 15, 2010); 
    75 Fed. Reg. 60,868
    (Oct. 1, 2013). The Service and the Council also jointly
    published a final environmental impact statement containing
    an extensive discussion of the agency’s development of the
    limited access privilege program.
    At the same time, the Service adopted a “control” rule to
    enforce the provision of section 1853a that prohibits anyone
    with limited access privileges from “hold[ing], acquir[ing],
    or us[ing]” any quota share exceeding the regulatory
    maximum. 16 U.S.C. § 1853a(c)(5)(D)(i); see 75 Fed. Reg.
    at 60,954–55. In the final rule, the Service interpreted section
    1853a as authorizing it to prohibit permit holders from
    “own[ing] or control[ling]” quota share above the maximum.
    
    50 C.F.R. § 660.140
    (d)(4)(i)(A). It then defined “control”
    as, among other things, the “ability through any means
    whatsoever to control or have a controlling influence” over
    an     entity   holding       quota     share.     
    50 C.F.R. § 660.140
    (d)(4)(iii)(H).
    Not everyone welcomed the new rule. Pacific Choice
    operates a seafood-processing facility in Eureka, California,
    and indirectly controls several vessels that participate in the
    fishery. After significant delay while the Service worked out
    divestiture procedures for entities holding excess share, the
    Service eventually implemented the 2010 rule and notified
    Pacific Choice that it held at least 3.8 percent of the fishery’s
    quota share. That share exceeded the 2.7 percent maximum
    and triggered the divestiture provisions. See 
    50 C.F.R. § 660.140
    (d)(4)(v). The Service issued various moratoria on
    the requirement to transfer excess quota share after an initial
    allocation, but in November 2015, it issued a final rule
    requiring divestiture. See 
    80 Fed. Reg. 69,138
     (Nov. 9,
    2015).
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                  11
    Pacific Choice complied with the divestiture
    requirement and brought this action against the Service soon
    thereafter. On cross-motions for summary judgment, the
    district court granted summary judgment for the Service,
    concluding that Pacific Choice had not established that either
    the 2.7 percent maximum share or the Service’s control rule
    violated the Act or the APA.
    II
    We begin by considering whether we have jurisdiction
    to hear this case. Neither party has raised the issue, but we
    have a duty to determine whether we have jurisdiction, “even
    though the parties are prepared to concede it.” Spencer
    Enters., Inc. v. United States, 
    345 F.3d 683
    , 687 (9th Cir.
    2003) (quoting Bender v. Williamsport Area Sch. Dist.,
    
    475 U.S. 534
    , 541 (1986)).
    The question is whether Pacific Choice’s suit was timely.
    The Act requires any challenge to agency actions or
    “[r]egulations promulgated by the Secretary” to be filed
    within 30 days of “the date on which the regulations are
    promulgated or the action is published in the Federal
    Register.” 
    16 U.S.C. § 1855
    (f)(1). We have held that the
    Act’s time limits are jurisdictional. See Sea Hawk Seafoods,
    Inc. v. Locke, 
    568 F.3d 757
    , 765 (9th Cir. 2009). There is
    reason to doubt whether that characterization is consistent
    with more recent Supreme Court decisions, which have
    clarified that filing deadlines are generally non-jurisdictional
    claim-processing rules. See, e.g., Henderson ex rel.
    Henderson v. Shinseki, 
    562 U.S. 428
    , 434–36 (2011). But
    even under the Court’s newer, more restrictive approach, at
    least some time limits for claims against the government
    remain jurisdictional. See John R. Sand & Gravel Co. v.
    United States, 
    552 U.S. 130
    , 139 (2008). Our prior cases are
    not “clearly irreconcilable” with any intervening Supreme
    12           PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    Court decision, and we remain bound by them. Miller v.
    Gammie, 
    335 F.3d 889
    , 893 (9th Cir. 2003) (en banc).
    Pacific Choice filed suit on December 4, 2015, which
    obviously was more than 30 days after the Service’s 2010
    rule. The lawsuit also came more than 30 days after the
    Service enforced the 2010 rule against Pacific Choice
    through its July 28, 2015 letter.
    We nevertheless conclude that Pacific Choice’s suit was
    timely because it was brought within 30 days of the Service’s
    publication of the 2015 rule requiring divestiture. A timely
    challenge to an agency’s action “may challenge both the
    action and the regulation under which the action is taken.”
    Oregon Troller’s Ass’n v. Gutierrez, 
    452 F.3d 1104
    , 1113
    (9th Cir. 2006). The 2015 rule constituted an “action,” which
    the Act defines to include any “actions . . . taken by the
    Secretary under regulations which implement a fishery
    management plan.” 
    16 U.S.C. § 1855
    (f)(2); see also Oregon
    Troller’s Ass’n, 
    452 F.3d at
    1115–16. And although Pacific
    Choice does not reassert on appeal the challenges it raised
    below to the 2015 rule, if it prevailed in this case, it could
    regain the share it was required to divest. We therefore
    conclude that Pacific Choice’s suit was timely under section
    1855(f)(1). See Oregon Troller’s Ass’n, 
    452 F.3d at
    1113–
    14; see also California Sea Urchin Comm’n v. Bean,
    
    828 F.3d 1046
    , 1049 (9th Cir. 2016).
    III
    Pacific Choice raises two challenges to the 2.7 percent
    quota share limit. First, it argues that the Service
    misinterpreted the term “excessive share” in section
    1853a(c)(5)(D) by sidelining considerations of market
    power in favor of per-vessel profitability. Second, it argues
    that the Service acted arbitrarily and capriciously by failing
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                   13
    to consider all relevant factors and relying on insufficient
    analysis in choosing the 2.7 percent limit. We review the
    district court’s decision de novo, see Pacific Dawn, 831 F.3d
    at 1173, and we reject both challenges.
    A
    We begin with Pacific Choice’s argument that the
    2.7 percent maximum share contravenes the Magnuson-
    Stevens Act. At the outset, we acknowledge some
    uncertainty as to exactly what Pacific Choice believes the
    Service’s interpretive error to be. In its opening brief, Pacific
    Choice asserted that “‘[e]xcessive share,’ as used in
    16 U.S.C. § 1853a(c)(5)(D) . . . means ‘conditions of
    monopoly or oligopoly,’” and that the Service violated the
    Act because it “relied on . . . factors outside the scope of
    [section 1853a(c)(5)(D)] by setting a maximum share that
    reflected ‘a chance of generating a reasonable profit.’” That
    language suggests that it is improper for the Service to
    consider any factors other than market power, or at least that
    it is improper for the Service to consider whether a
    maximum share will allow reasonable profits. But in its reply
    brief, Pacific Choice rejected that suggestion as “a straw
    man,” disclaiming the argument that the Service “may only
    consider market power” and arguing instead that “market
    power is an essential and indispensable factor” for
    determining a maximum share, which the Service ignored by
    “bas[ing] the limit solely on other factors.”
    To the extent Pacific Choice means that market power is
    one of many factors that the Service must consider, we do
    not think the Service disagrees. To the contrary, when asked
    at oral argument if the Service is required to consider market
    power, counsel for the Service said yes. And in promulgating
    the 2010 rule, the Service explained that the Council had
    “considered a wide range of factors such as social benefits,
    14           PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    impact on labor, impacts on processors, impacts on
    harvesters, impacts on the public, the number and sizes of
    firms, within-sector competition, market power, efficiency,
    geographic distribution, communities, and fairness and
    equity.” 75 Fed. Reg. at 33,004 (emphasis added). The
    Service advanced a similar interpretation in a 2007 guidance
    document instructing fishery councils to consider “market
    power including monopoly . . . or monopsony” in designing
    limited access privilege programs.
    Pacific Choice appears to believe, however, that
    considering market power as one of several factors is not
    enough. Instead, we understand Pacific Choice’s statutory
    argument to be that whatever limit the Service sets, it must
    in some sense be “based on” market-power considerations.
    In other words, Pacific Choice’s argument implies that it
    would be improper for the Service to determine that a
    particular limit would prevent any market participant from
    exercising market power but then to set a lower limit that
    reflects other considerations. We note that where, as here,
    market power could be avoided with a higher limit than is
    needed to achieve other objectives, Pacific Choice’s position
    is not so different, in practice, from a rule that the Service
    may consider only market power.
    In assessing Pacific Choice’s statutory argument, we
    apply the framework of Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. NRDC, Inc.,
    
    467 U.S. 837
     (1984). “[W]hen an agency is authorized by
    Congress to issue regulations and promulgates a regulation
    interpreting a statute it enforces, the interpretation receives
    deference if the statute is ambiguous and if the agency’s
    interpretation is reasonable.” Encino Motorcars, LLC v.
    Navarro, 
    136 S. Ct. 2117
    , 2124 (2016).
    Our first step is to determine whether Congress has
    “directly addressed the precise question at issue.” Chevron,
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                 15
    
    467 U.S. at 843
    . We conclude that it has not. The relevant
    statutory text directs the Service to
    (D) ensure that limited access privilege
    holders do not acquire an excessive share
    of the total limited access privileges in the
    program by—
    (i) establishing a maximum share,
    expressed as a percentage of the total
    limited access privileges, that a
    limited access privilege holder is
    permitted to hold, acquire, or use; and
    (ii) establishing any other limitations or
    measures necessary to prevent an
    inequitable concentration of limited
    access privileges.
    16 U.S.C. § 1853a(c)(5)(D). That provision defines neither
    “excessive share” nor “maximum share,” and it contains no
    reference to market power. Other provisions of the same
    section make clear that limited access privilege programs are
    to serve a variety of objectives. Specifically, such programs
    “shall . . . promote—(i) fishing safety; (ii) fishery
    conservation and management; and (iii) social and economic
    benefits.” Id. § 1853a(c)(1)(C).
    Pacific Choice points to a separate section of the Act that
    outlines standards for fishery management and instructs the
    Service to ensure that allocations of quota share are “(A) fair
    and equitable to all such fishermen; (B) reasonably
    calculated to promote conservation; and (C) carried out in
    such manner that no particular individual, corporation, or
    other entity acquires an excessive share of such privileges.”
    
    16 U.S.C. § 1851
    (a)(4). Like section 1853a(c)(5)(D),
    16           PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    however, that provision does not say what Congress meant
    by “excessive share.” And the next paragraph makes clear
    that although the Service must “consider efficiency” in
    developing fishery management measures, economic
    efficiency is not the only goal: “no such measure shall have
    economic allocation as its sole purpose.” 
    Id.
     § 1851(a)(5).
    Pacific Choice emphasizes that the Service previously
    interpreted section 1851(a)(4)’s “excessive share” clause to
    “imply conditions of monopoly or oligopoly.” 
    60 Fed. Reg. 61,200
    , 61,202 (Nov. 29, 1995). The Service’s prior
    interpretations cannot transform otherwise ambiguous
    statutory text into an unambiguous command because “the
    whole point of Chevron is to leave the discretion provided
    by the ambiguities of a statute with the implementing
    agency.” Smiley v. Citibank (S.D.), N.A., 
    517 U.S. 735
    , 742
    (1996). In any event, the Service’s belief that the term
    “excessive share” “impl[ies]” market power is itself far from
    an unambiguous statement that market power must have
    singular importance—almost by definition, one cannot
    “directly address[]” an issue by implication. Chevron,
    
    467 U.S. at 843
    .
    Pacific Choice also relies on the Act’s legislative history,
    but legislative history cannot “supply mandatory
    requirements not found within the [Magnuson-Stevenson
    Act] itself.” Pacific Coast, 693 F.3d at 1093. Even if it could,
    the legislative history here does not do so. Pacific Choice
    points to two floor statements from individual
    Representatives indicating that Congress was concerned
    about preventing “excessive and inequitable consolidation at
    the expense of small-scale fishermen,” 152 Cong. Rec.
    23,359 (Dec. 8, 2006) (statement of Rep. Allen), and wanted
    to “protect[] small fishermen from those who would like to
    consolidate fisheries,” id. at 23,360 (statement of Rep.
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                17
    Rahall). Those statements reflect a desire to protect small
    fishing operations, but, like the statutory text, they do not
    suggest that the maximum share must be no more restrictive
    than necessary to avoid excessive concentration.
    Because the Act is ambiguous as to what factors the
    Service must consider in setting a maximum share, we turn
    to step two of the Chevron framework: whether the Service
    has adopted a “reasonable interpretation” of the statute.
    
    467 U.S. at 844
    . We have previously held that the Act gives
    the Service “broad discretion” to carry out its provisions.
    Northwest Envtl. Def. Ctr. v. Brennan, 
    958 F.2d 930
    , 935 n.3
    (9th Cir. 1992). Congress directed the Service to consider a
    wide range of factors in establishing limited access privilege
    programs, including “the basic cultural and social
    framework of the fishery” and “the sustained participation of
    small owner-operated fishing vessels and fishing
    communities that depend on the fisheries.” 16 U.S.C.
    § 1853a(c)(5)(B). In light of those objectives, it was
    reasonable for the Service to conclude that other factors can
    dictate a lower maximum share than might be required by a
    singular focus on preventing excessive market power—or,
    in other words, that the Service may attempt to do something
    more than act simply as a fishery-specific version of the
    Federal Trade Commission or the Justice Department’s
    Antitrust Division.
    Pacific Choice suggests that the Service erred in
    interpreting the Act to permit consideration of whether
    vessels would have a “chance at generating a reasonable
    profit.” We disagree. The Act requires the Service to
    “include measures to assist, when necessary and appropriate,
    entry-level and small vessel owner-operators, captains,
    crew,     and    fishing     communities.”    16     U.S.C.
    § 1853a(c)(5)(C). While Congress noted that those measures
    18           PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    might “includ[e] . . . set-asides of harvesting allocations” or
    “economic assistance,” it did not say that those actions were
    the only such measures the Service could adopt. Id. Instead,
    Congress left it to the Service to determine when and how
    assisting small vessel owner-operators might be “necessary
    and appropriate.” Id. Giving weight to the chance of
    generating a profit was a reasonable way to implement
    Congress’s directive.
    B
    Although the Service permissibly interpreted the Act, we
    still must ensure that the 2.7 percent maximum share is not
    “arbitrary, capricious, [or] an abuse of discretion.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(A). That standard is deferential: as long as an
    agency has “examine[d] the relevant data and articulate[d] a
    satisfactory explanation for its action including a ‘rational
    connection between the facts found and the choice made,’”
    the Supreme Court has made clear that “a court is not to
    substitute its judgment for that of the agency.” Motor Vehicle
    Mfrs. Ass’n of U.S., Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co.,
    
    463 U.S. 29
    , 43 (1983) (quoting Burlington Truck Lines v.
    United States, 
    371 U.S. 156
    , 168 (1962)); accord FCC v.
    Fox Television Stations, Inc., 
    556 U.S. 502
    , 513–14 (2009).
    As an initial matter, the Service asks us to disregard
    Pacific Choice’s objections because Pacific Choice did not
    raise them before the agency. Generally, a “party forfeits
    arguments that are not raised during the administrative
    process.” Lands Council v. McNair, 
    629 F.3d 1070
    , 1076
    (9th Cir. 2010). But we will consider any issue that was
    “raised with sufficient clarity to allow the decision maker to
    understand and rule on the issue raised, whether the issue
    was considered sua sponte by the agency or was raised by
    someone other than the petitioning party.” Glacier Fish Co.,
    LLC v. Pritzer, 
    832 F.3d 1113
    , 1120 n.6 (9th Cir. 2016)
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                19
    (internal quotation marks and citation omitted). Because the
    Service in fact examined the issues that Pacific Choice now
    raises, including in response to other commenters during the
    notice-and-comment period, we consider them on the merits.
    In assessing the Service’s decision, we “review the
    whole record,” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    , which includes “everything
    that was before the agency pertaining to the merits of its
    decision.” Portland Audubon Soc. v. Endangered Species
    Comm., 
    984 F.2d 1534
    , 1548 (9th Cir. 1993). Pacific Choice
    urges us to examine only the Service’s decision memoranda
    while ignoring the Council’s materials, including analyses
    by the Quota Committee, the Allocation Committee, the
    Management Team, and the Advisory Subpanel. Although
    the Act requires the Service to “evaluat[e]” the Council’s
    proposed regulations to “determine whether they are
    consistent with the fishery management plan” and with the
    Act, it does not require the Service to engage in a lengthy
    discussion of every aspect of the plan or to repeat points
    already made by the Council and its committees. 
    16 U.S.C. § 1854
    (b)(1). Instead, when the Service finds that an
    amendment is consistent with a fishery plan, the Act requires
    it to do no more than “publish such regulations in the Federal
    Register,” along with any “technical changes as may be
    necessary for clarity and an explanation of those changes.”
    
    Id.
     § 1854(b)(1)(A). Pacific Choice offers no authority
    supporting its assertion that we should focus exclusively on
    the Service’s memoranda from the very end of the
    administrative process. To the contrary, we have previously
    upheld the Service’s regulations on the basis of findings by
    the Council and its committees. See Fisherman’s Finest, Inc.
    v. Locke, 
    593 F.3d 886
    , 896 (9th Cir. 2010).
    Pacific Choice contends that the Service’s decision-
    making process was flawed in two ways: the Service “failed
    20           PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    to consider an important aspect of the problem” by ignoring
    market power altogether, State Farm, 
    463 U.S. at 43
    , and it
    also failed to articulate “the methods by which, and the
    purposes for which” it set the maximum share at 2.7 percent
    rather than at some other percentage, San Antonio, Tex. ex
    rel. City Pub. Serv. Bd. v. United States, 
    631 F.2d 831
    , 852
    (D.C. Cir. 1980). We reject both of those arguments.
    First, the record shows that the Service did consider
    market power. After the Quota Committee completed its
    initial analysis based on historical aggregate revenue, the
    Allocation Committee examined the degree of concentration
    within the fishery, calculating an HHI. Relying on
    Department of Justice antitrust guidelines defining a
    concentrated market based on HHI, the Allocation
    Committee concluded that all of the options then under
    consideration—ranging from 1.5 to 5 percent—were
    “unlikely” to “affect market power.” With the conclusion in
    hand that market-power considerations were unlikely to be
    significant factors in establishing a maximum share, the
    Service might have understandably decided to ignore market
    power.
    But contrary to Pacific Choice’s representations, market-
    power considerations and economic analyses continued to
    play a prominent role in the agency’s consideration of the
    maximum share. Building on the Allocation Committee’s
    analysis, the Management Team acknowledged the dual
    purposes of setting maximum shares: the limits not only
    serve as “preventative measures against anticompetitive
    market conditions” but also “ensure that the benefits . . .
    arising from the public fishery resource accrue to a minimum
    number of [quota-share] owners.” The Management Team
    then conducted an in-depth analysis of the degree of
    concentration in the fishery, projecting vessel profitability
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                  21
    based on varying levels of market concentration. After
    cautioning against the effect that higher quota-share
    maximums might have on “bargaining, market power, and
    . . . . undue influence over other aspects of the fishery,” the
    Management Team presented a range of options from 1.3 to
    3.8 percent depending on the Service’s desired degree of
    “consolidation” within the fishery. While Pacific Choice
    might prefer the higher limits suggested by the Allocation
    Committee’s HHI analysis rather than the lower ones
    suggested by the Management Team’s economist, we see no
    reason to second-guess the Management Team’s economic
    analysis.
    Nor did the Management Team offer the final word on
    market power—the Council itself detailed its reasoning in an
    exhaustive overview in the 2010 environmental impact
    statement, which it issued jointly with the Service. While it
    is true that the Council stated that its quota-share limits were
    “aimed at more than just preventing market power or other
    anticompetitive situations,” that is not the same as ignoring
    market power.
    Second, we conclude that the agency engaged in a
    reasoned process from which its path to the 2.7 percent limit
    “may reasonably be discerned.” Alaska Dep’t of Envtl.
    Conservation v. EPA, 
    540 U.S. 461
    , 497 (2004) (quoting
    Bowman Transp., Inc. v. Arkansas-Best Freight Sys., Inc.,
    
    419 U.S. 281
    , 286 (1974)). Pacific Choice argues that the
    Advisory Subpanel picked 2.7 percent only because it was
    the “mid range of the data presented” in the Management
    Team’s economic analysis. Even if that were an accurate
    characterization    of    the     Advisory       Subpanel’s
    recommendation, it would not necessarily establish that the
    Service’s decision was unreasoned given the extensive
    discussion of Act’s factors presented at each step of the
    22           PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    rulemaking process. We have upheld similar determinations
    in the past where the agency “had to choose some number
    from a broad range” and selected “a reasonable figure.” San
    Luis & Delta-Mendota Water Auth. v. Jewell, 
    747 F.3d 581
    ,
    616 (9th Cir. 2014); see Missouri Pub. Serv. Comm’n v.
    FERC, 
    215 F.3d 1
    , 5–6 (D.C. Cir. 2000).
    In any event, Pacific Choice’s interpretation of the
    administrative record is not persuasive. Pacific Choice
    misconstrues the Advisory Subpanel’s recommendation,
    which did not state that the panel recommended 2.7 percent
    because that figure was in the middle of the Management
    Team’s recommendations. Instead, the Advisory Subpanel
    adopted the Management Team’s recommendation because
    it concluded that the “revenue-based approach . . . [was] a
    useful conceptual approach” for setting a maximum share.
    The Advisory Subpanel’s recommendation is brief, but it
    reveals independent judgment on each aspect of the
    recommendations from the Allocation Committee and the
    Management Team, most notably on individual species
    limits.
    More generally, we see no reason to focus only on the
    Advisory Subpanel’s memo when it constituted just one step
    in the lengthy administrative process. Viewed as a whole, the
    record contains extensive justification for the 2.7 percent
    limit. As the Management Team concluded, that limit
    accommodates a variety of the Council’s objectives for
    setting a maximum share, including “cap[ping] the initial
    allocation of quota share at a level that is consistent with”
    historical quota distributions on the 2003 control date, and
    allowing more consolidation in the fishery than a lower
    limit—such as 2.3 percent—would accomplish. The
    Service’s environmental impact statement fully explains
    how the agency arrived at the 2.7 percent limit from the
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                 23
    Quota Committee’s initial recommendation of 1.5 to
    5 percent.
    Under the APA, “we will uphold a decision of less than
    ideal clarity if the agency’s path may reasonably be
    discerned.” Bowman, 419 U.S. at 286. We have no difficulty
    in following the Service’s path to the 2.7 percent maximum
    share, and we hold that the Service did not act arbitrarily or
    capriciously in setting it.
    IV
    Pacific Choice also advances statutory and APA
    challenges to the Service’s control rule. We reject both.
    The Magnuson-Stevens Act requires that the Service
    “establish[] a maximum share . . . that a [share] holder is
    permitted to hold, acquire, or use.” 16 U.S.C.
    § 1853a(c)(5)(D)(i). According to Pacific Choice, the
    Service exceeded the authority granted by that statute when
    it interpreted “hold, acquire, or use” to include “control” and
    proceeded to define “control” to include, among other
    things, “the ability through any means whatsoever to control
    or have a controlling influence over the entity to which
    [quota       share]      is     registered.”     
    50 C.F.R. §660.140
    (d)(4)(iii)(H). Pacific Choice argues that the rule
    “effectively re-writes Congress’s definition” by using the
    word “control,” which does not appear in the statute. But the
    word “acquire,” which does appear in the statute, means “to
    come into possession, control, or power of disposal of.”
    Webster’s Third New International Dictionary 18 (2002)
    (emphasis added). If that were not enough, the word “use”
    easily encompasses the concept of control. See Friends of
    Animals v. United States Fish & Wildlife Serv., 
    879 F.3d 1000
    , 1006–09 (9th Cir. 2018). Beyond that, section
    1853a(c)(5)(D)(ii) gives the Service even broader authority
    24           PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    to establish “any other limitations or measures necessary to
    prevent an inequitable concentration of limited access
    privileges.” 16 U.S.C. § 1853a(c)(5)(D)(ii).
    Pacific Choice responds that we must read the statute
    against a background of ordinary corporate-law principles,
    under which a corporation is a distinct entity from its
    owners. We agree that Congress drafts laws while “aware of
    settled principles of corporate law.” Dole Food Co. v.
    Patrickson, 
    538 U.S. 468
    , 474 (2003). It is also true that
    Congress defined the term “person” in the Act to mean “any
    individual . . . corporation, partnership, association, or other
    entity.” 
    16 U.S.C. § 1802
    (36). But the Service’s control rule
    does not purport to redefine personhood. Instead, it defines
    when a person “own[s] or control[s]” quota share nominally
    held by other people. 
    50 C.F.R. § 660.140
    (d)(4)(i)(A). That
    is in no way inconsistent with the common-law
    understanding of corporate ownership.
    Because the Service’s interpretation of “hold, acquire, or
    use” represents an exercise of delegated authority, our
    review of it is governed by Chevron, and we see nothing in
    the statute that unambiguously forecloses the Service’s
    approach. Instead, the Service’s rule represents a reasonable
    implementation of Congress’s directive that quota
    allocations be “fair and equitable” and be “carried out in
    such manner that no particular individual, corporation, or
    other entity acquires an excessive share of such privileges.”
    
    16 U.S.C. § 1851
    (a)(4).
    Nor are we persuaded that the rule is arbitrary and
    capricious. Pacific Choice does not identify a deficiency in
    the Service’s rulemaking process but instead argues that the
    Service’s definition of “control” is so broad—and thus so
    vague—that it constitutes an abuse of discretion. In limited
    situations, we have recognized that an agency might act
    PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS                 25
    arbitrarily and capriciously by “fail[ing] to properly specify”
    its rules such that it leaves “no method by which” a regulated
    party “can gauge [its] performance.” Arizona Cattle
    Grower’s Ass’n v. United States Fish & Wildlife Serv.,
    
    273 F.3d 1229
    , 1250–51 (9th Cir. 2001). This is not such a
    situation.
    The rule is indeed broad. Its broadest provision covers
    any person who “has the ability through any means
    whatsoever to control or have a controlling influence over”
    an     entity    holding      quota    share.    
    50 C.F.R. § 660.140
    (d)(4)(iii)(H). But breadth is not the same thing as
    vagueness. See Pennsylvania Dep’t of Corrections v. Yeskey,
    
    524 U.S. 206
    , 212 (1998). The rule’s terms have clear
    meanings sufficient to inform regulated entities about what
    types of conduct the Service will prohibit: ownership or
    control that evades the Service’s maximum share limits. For
    example, clause (d)(4)(iii)(A) deems control satisfied when
    a person “has the right to direct . . . the business of [an]
    entity,” clause (d)(4)(iii)(B) when a person “has the right to
    limit the actions of or replace” corporate officers, and clause
    (d)(4)(iii)(C) when a person “has the right to direct . . . the
    transfer of” quota share. It requires no great leap to read the
    more general language of clause (d)(4)(iii)(H) as prohibiting
    the same sort of thing. See Yates v. United States, 
    574 U.S. 528
    , 545 (2015).
    Crucially, we see no ambiguity about whether Pacific
    Choice “own[ed] or control[led]” the related entities at issue
    here. Pacific Choice’s brief discloses that each of the six
    entities that held quota share are wholly owned either by
    Frank Dulcich or by a corporation that Dulcich owns. Under
    any plausible definition of “control,” Dulcich controls the
    Pacific Choice entities. Because Pacific Choice is subject to
    the control rule even under its narrowest construction, we
    26          PACIFIC CHOICE SEAFOOD V. ROSS
    need not consider the rule’s outermost limits or whether, in
    some other case, the Service might abuse its discretion by
    applying the rule in a surprising or unforeseeable way. See
    Village of Hoffman Estates v. Flipside, Hoffman Estates,
    Inc., 
    455 U.S. 489
    , 495 (1982) (“A plaintiff who engages in
    some conduct that is clearly proscribed cannot complain of
    the vagueness of the law as applied to the conduct of
    others.”).
    AFFIRMED.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 18-15455

Filed Date: 9/25/2020

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/25/2020

Authorities (23)

Lands Council v. McNair , 629 F.3d 1070 ( 2010 )

portland-audubon-society-v-the-endangered-species-committee-oregon-lands , 984 F.2d 1534 ( 1993 )

oregon-trollers-association-suislaw-fishermens-association-thomas-harris , 452 F.3d 1104 ( 2006 )

spencer-enterprises-inc-li-hui-chang-and-chung-chuan-sun-jerry-chien-hua , 345 F.3d 683 ( 2003 )

Fishermen's Finest, Inc. v. Locke , 593 F.3d 886 ( 2010 )

Sea Hawk Seafoods, Inc. v. Locke , 568 F.3d 757 ( 2009 )

MO Pub Svc Cmsn v. FERC , 215 F.3d 1 ( 2000 )

san-antonio-texas-acting-by-and-through-its-city-public-service-board-v , 631 F.2d 831 ( 1980 )

arizona-cattle-growers-association-jeff-menges , 273 F.3d 1229 ( 2001 )

christine-l-miller-guardian-ad-litem-tonnie-savage-guardian-ad-litem-v , 335 F.3d 889 ( 2003 )

northwest-environmental-defense-center-v-james-w-brennen-assistant , 958 F.2d 930 ( 1992 )

Smiley v. Citibank (South Dakota), N. A. , 116 S. Ct. 1730 ( 1996 )

Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States, Inc. v. State ... , 103 S. Ct. 2856 ( 1983 )

Hoffman Estates v. Flipside, Hoffman Estates, Inc. , 102 S. Ct. 1186 ( 1982 )

Burlington Truck Lines, Inc. v. United States , 83 S. Ct. 239 ( 1962 )

Bender v. Williamsport Area School District , 106 S. Ct. 1326 ( 1986 )

Pennsylvania Department of Corrections v. Yeskey , 118 S. Ct. 1952 ( 1998 )

Dole Food Co. v. Patrickson , 123 S. Ct. 1655 ( 2003 )

Alaska Department of Environmental Conservation v. ... , 124 S. Ct. 983 ( 2004 )

John R. Sand & Gravel Co. v. United States , 128 S. Ct. 750 ( 2008 )

View All Authorities »