Global TelLink v. FCC ( 2017 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued February 6, 2017            Decided June 13, 2017
    Amended August 4, 2017
    No. 15-1461
    GLOBAL TEL*LINK,
    PETITIONER
    v.
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION AND UNITED
    STATES OF AMERICA,
    RESPONDENTS
    CENTURYLINK PUBLIC COMMUNICATIONS, INC., ET AL.,
    INTERVENORS
    Consolidated with 15-1498, 16-1012, 16-1029, 16-1038,
    16-1046, 16-1057
    On Petitions for Review of an Order of
    the Federal Communications Commission
    2
    Mithun Mansinghani, Deputy Solicitor General, Office of
    the Attorney General for the State of Oklahoma, argued the
    cause for State and Local Government Petitioners. With him
    on the briefs were E. Scott Pruitt, Attorney General, Patrick R.
    Wyrick, Solicitor General, Nathan B. Hall, Assistant Solicitor
    General, James Bradford Ramsay, Jennifer Murphy,
    Christopher J. Collins, Mark Brnovich, Attorney General,
    Office of the Attorney General for the State of Arizona,
    Dominic E. Draye, Deputy Solicitor General, Leslie Rutledge,
    Attorney General, Office of the Attorney General for the State
    of Arkansas, Lee Rudofsky, Solicitor General, Nicholas Bronni,
    Deputy Solicitor General, Danny Honeycutt, Karla L. Palmer,
    Tonya J. Bond, Joanne T. Rouse, Derek Schmidt, Attorney
    General, Office of the Attorney General for the State of Kansas,
    Jeffrey A. Chanay, Chief Deputy Attorney General, Chris
    Koster, Attorney General, Office of the Attorney General for
    the State of Missouri, J. Andrew Hirth, Deputy General
    Counsel, Brad D. Schimel, Attorney General, Office of the
    Attorney General for the State of Wisconsin, Misha Tseytlin,
    Solicitor General, Daniel P. Lennington, Deputy Solicitor
    General, Gregory F. Zoeller, Attorney General, Office of the
    Attorney General for the State of Indiana, Thomas M. Fisher,
    Solicitor General, Jeff Landry, Attorney General, Office of the
    Attorney General for the State of Louisiana, Patricia H. Wilton,
    Assistant Attorney General, Adam Paul Laxalt, Attorney
    General, Office of the Attorney General for the State of
    Nevada, and Lawrence VanDyke, Solicitor General. Jared
    Haines, Assistant Solicitor General, Office of the Attorney
    General for the State of Oklahoma, David G. Sanders,
    Assistant Attorney General, Office of the Attorney General for
    the State of Louisiana, and Dean J. Sauer, Attorney, Office of
    the Attorney General for the State of Missouri, entered
    appearances.
    3
    Michael K. Kellogg argued the cause for ICS Carrier
    Petitioners. With him on the briefs were Aaron M. Panner,
    Benjamin S. Softness, Stephanie A. Joyce, Andrew D. Lipman,
    Brita D. Strandberg, Jared P. Marx, John R. Grimm, Robert A.
    Long, Jr., Kevin F. King, Marcus W. Trathen, Julia C.
    Ambrose, and Timothy G. Nelson.
    Andrew D. Lipman and Stephanie A. Joyce were on the
    brief for petitioner Securus Technologies, Inc.
    David M. Gossett, Attorney, Federal Communications
    Commission, argued the cause for respondent. On the brief
    were Howard J. Symons at the time the brief was filed, General
    Counsel, Jacob M. Lewis, Associate General Counsel, Sarah
    E. Citrin, Counsel, and Robert B. Nicholson and Daniel E.
    Haar, Attorneys, U.S. Department of Justice. Mary H.
    Wimberly, Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice, Brendan T.
    Carr, Acting General Counsel, Federal Communications
    Commission, and Richard K. Welch, Deputy Associate General
    Counsel, entered appearances.
    Lori Swanson, Attorney General, Office of the Attorney
    General for the State of Minnesota, Kathryn Fodness and
    Andrew Tweeten, Assistant Attorneys General, Eric T.
    Schneiderman, Attorney General, Office of the Attorney
    General for the State of New York, Robert W. Ferguson,
    Attorney General, Office of the Attorney General for the State
    of Washington, Karl A. Racine, Attorney General, Office of the
    Attorney General for the District of Columbia, Lisa Madigan,
    Attorney General, Office of the Attorney General for the State
    of Illinois, Maura Healey, Attorney General, Office of the
    Attorney General for the Commonwealth of Massachusetts,
    and Hector Balderas, Attorney General, Office of the Attorney
    General for the State of New Mexico were on the brief for
    4
    amici curiae State of Minnesota, et al. in support of
    respondents.
    Glenn S. Richards was on the brief for intervenors
    Network Communications International Corp. in support of
    respondents.
    Andrew Jay Schwartzman argued the cause for intervenors
    The Wright Petitioners. With him on the brief was Drew T.
    Simshaw.
    Danny Y. Chou was on the brief for amicus curiae The
    County of Santa Clara and the County of San Francisco in
    support of respondent.
    Opinion for the court filed by Senior Circuit Judge
    EDWARDS.
    Concurring opinion filed by Senior Circuit Judge
    SILBERMAN.
    Opinion filed by Circuit Judge PILLARD, dissenting as to
    Sections II.B through II.F and concurring in part.
    Before: PILLARD, Circuit Judge, and EDWARDS and
    SILBERMAN, Senior Circuit Judges.
    EDWARDS, Senior Circuit Judge: The Communications
    Act of 1934 (“1934 Act”) authorized the Federal
    Communications Commission (“Commission” or “FCC”) to
    ensure that interstate telephone rates are “just and reasonable,”
    
    47 U.S.C. § 201
    (b), but left regulation of intrastate rates
    primarily to the states. In the Telecommunications Act of 1996
    (“1996 Act”), Congress amended the 1934 Act to change the
    Commission’s limited regulatory authority over intrastate
    5
    telecommunication so as to promote competition in the
    payphone industry.
    Before the passage of the 1996 Act, Bell Operating
    Companies (“BOCs”) had dominated the payphone industry to
    the detriment of other providers. Congress sought to remedy
    this situation by authorizing the Commission to adopt
    regulations ensuring that all payphone providers are “fairly
    compensated for each and every” interstate and intrastate call.
    
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)(A). “[P]ayphone service” expressly
    includes “the provision of inmate telephone service in
    correctional institutions, and any ancillary services.” 
    Id.
    § 276(d). The issues in this case focus on inmate calling
    services (“ICS”) and the rates and fees charged for these calls.
    Following the passage of the 1996 Act, the Commission
    avoided intrusive regulatory measures for ICS. And prior to the
    Order under review in this case, the Commission had never
    sought to impose rate caps on intrastate calls. Rather, the FCC
    consistently construed its authority over intrastate payphone
    rates as limited to addressing the problem of under-
    compensation for ICS providers.
    Due to a variety of market failures in the prison and jail
    payphone industry, however, inmates in correctional facilities,
    or those to whom they placed calls, incurred prohibitive per-
    minute charges and ancillary fees for payphone calls. In the
    face of this problem, the Commission decided to change its
    approach to the regulation of ICS providers. In 2015, in the
    Order under review, the Commission set permanent rate caps
    and ancillary fee caps for interstate ICS calls and, for the first
    time, imposed those caps on intrastate ICS calls. Rates for
    Interstate Inmate Calling Services (“Order”), 30 FCC Rcd.
    12763, 12775–76, 12838–62 (Nov. 5, 2015), 
    80 Fed. Reg. 79136
    -01 (Dec. 18, 2015). The Commission also proposed to
    6
    expand the reach of its ICS regulations by banning or limiting
    fees for billing and collection services – so-called “ancillary
    fees” – and by regulating video services and other advanced
    services in addition to traditional calling services.
    Five inmate payphone providers, joined by state and local
    authorities, now challenge the Order’s design to expand the
    FCC’s regulatory authority. In particular, the Petitioners
    challenge the Order’s proposed caps on intrastate rates, the
    exclusion of “site commissions” as costs in the agency’s
    ratemaking methodology, the use of industry-averaged cost
    data in the FCC’s calculation of rate caps, the imposition of
    ancillary fee caps, and reporting requirements. And one ICS
    provider separately challenges the Commission’s failure to
    preempt inconsistent state rates and raises a due process
    challenge.
    Following the presidential inauguration in January 2017,
    counsel for the FCC advised the court that, due to a change in
    the composition of the Commission, “a majority of the current
    Commission does not believe that the agency has the authority
    to cap intrastate rates under section 276 of the Act.” Counsel
    thus informed the court that the agency was “abandoning . . .
    the contention . . . that the Commission has the authority to cap
    intrastate rates” for ICS providers. Counsel also informed the
    court that the FCC was abandoning its contention “that the
    Commission lawfully considered industry-wide averages in
    setting the rate caps.” However, the Commission has not
    revoked, withdrawn, or suspended the Order. And one of the
    Intervenors on behalf of the Commission, the “Wright
    Petitioners,” continues to press the points that have been
    abandoned by the Commission.
    For the reasons set forth below, we grant in part and deny
    in part the petitions for review, and remand for further
    7
    proceedings with respect to certain matters. We also dismiss
    two claims as moot.
       We hold that the Order’s proposed caps on intrastate rates
    exceed the FCC’s statutory authority under the 1996 Act.
    We therefore vacate this provision.
       We further hold that the use of industry-averaged cost data
    as proposed in the Order is arbitrary and capricious because
    it lacks justification in the record and is not supported by
    reasoned decisionmaking. We therefore vacate this
    provision.
       We additionally hold that the Order’s imposition of video
    visitation reporting requirements is beyond the statutory
    authority of the Commission. We therefore vacate this
    provision.
       We find that the Order’s proposed wholesale exclusion of
    site commission payments from the FCC’s cost calculus is
    devoid of reasoned decisionmaking and thus arbitrary and
    capricious. This provision cannot stand as presently
    proposed in the Order under review; we therefore vacate
    this provision and remand for further proceedings on the
    matter.
       We deny the petitions for review of the Order’s site
    commission reporting requirements.
       We remand the challenge to the Order’s imposition of
    ancillary fee caps to allow the Commission to determine
    whether it can segregate proposed caps on interstate calls
    (which are permissible) and the proposed caps on intrastate
    calls (which are impermissible).
    8
       Finally, we dismiss the preemption and due process claims
    as moot.
    I.   BACKGROUND
    A. Statutory Background
    The 1934 Act, 
    47 U.S.C. § 151
    , et seq., established a system
    of regulatory authority that divides power between individual
    states and the FCC over inter- and intrastate telephone
    communication services. New England Pub. Commc’ns
    Council, Inc. v. FCC, 
    334 F.3d 69
    , 75 (D.C. Cir. 2003). Under
    this statutory scheme, the Commission regulates interstate
    telephone communication. See id.; 
    47 U.S.C. § 151
    . This
    regulatory authority includes ensuring that all charges “in
    connection with” interstate calls are “just and reasonable.” 
    47 U.S.C. § 201
    (b). “The Commission may prescribe such rules
    and regulations as may be necessary in the public interest to
    carry out” these provisions. 
    Id.
    The FCC, however, “is generally forbidden from entering
    the field of intrastate communication service, which remains
    the province of the states.” New England Pub., 
    334 F.3d at
    75
    (citing 
    47 U.S.C. § 152
    (b)). Section 152(b) of the 1934 Act
    erects a presumption against the Commission’s assertion of
    regulatory authority over intrastate communications. This is
    “not only a substantive jurisdictional limitation on the FCC’s
    power, but also a rule of statutory construction” in interpreting
    the Act’s provisions. La. Pub. Serv. Comm’n v. FCC, 
    476 U.S. 355
    , 373 (1986).
    The 1996 Act “fundamentally restructured the local
    telephone industry,” New England Pub., 
    334 F.3d at 71
    , by
    changing the FCC’s authority with respect to some intrastate
    activities and “remov[ing] a significant area from the States’
    9
    exclusive control,” AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 
    525 U.S. 366
    , 382 n.8 (1999). Nevertheless, the states still primarily
    “reign supreme over intrastate rates.” New England Pub., 
    334 F.3d at 75
     (quoting City of Brookings Mun. Tel. Co. v. FCC,
    
    822 F.2d 1153
    , 1155 (D.C. Cir. 1987)). “Insofar as Congress
    has remained silent . . . § 152(b) continues to function. The
    Commission could not, for example, regulate any aspect of
    intrastate communication not governed by the 1996 Act on the
    theory that it had an ancillary effect on matters within the
    Commission’s primary jurisdiction.” AT&T Corp., 
    525 U.S. at
    382 n.8.
    Although the strictures of § 152 remain in force, the
    changes imposed by the 1996 Act were significant. Evidence
    of this is seen in the “Special Provisions Concerning Bell
    Operating Companies.” 
    47 U.S.C. §§ 271
    –76. Section 276 was
    “specifically aimed at promoting competition in the payphone
    service industry.” New England Pub., 
    334 F.3d at 71
    . While
    local phone services were once thought to be natural
    monopolies, “[t]echnological advances . . . made competition
    among multiple providers of local service seem possible, and
    Congress [in the 1996 Act] ended the longstanding regime of
    state-sanctioned monopolies.” AT&T Corp., 
    525 U.S. at 371
    ;
    see also Glob. Crossing Telecomms., Inc. v. Metrophones
    Telecomms., Inc., 
    550 U.S. 45
    , 50 (2007).
    The market history is illuminating. After AT&T had
    divested its local exchange carriers into individual BOCs in
    1982, BOCs continued to discriminate against non-BOC
    payphone providers and effectively foreclosed competition.
    The BOCs accomplished this by generally making sure that
    other providers were not compensated for calls using BOC-
    owned payphone lines. See New England Pub., 
    334 F.3d at 71
    .
    Thus, because technology constraints forced many non-BOC
    providers to use BOC-owned payphone lines, those providers
    10
    were often left uncompensated for payphone calls. The 1996
    Act changed these market practices.
    In § 276, Congress clearly aimed to “promote competition
    among payphone service providers and promote the
    widespread deployment of payphone services to the benefit of
    the general public.” 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1). Covered payphone
    services include “inmate telephone service in correctional
    institutions, and any ancillary services.” 
    Id.
     § 276(d). Section
    276 of the 1996 Act authorizes the Commission “to prescribe
    regulations consistent with the goal of promoting competition,
    requiring that the Commission take five specific steps toward
    that goal.” New England Pub., 
    334 F.3d at 71
    . One such step is
    to “establish a per call compensation plan to ensure that all
    payphone service providers are fairly compensated for each
    and every completed intrastate and interstate call using their
    payphone,” and to prescribe regulations to establish this
    compensation plan by November 1996. 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1),
    (b)(1)(A). The remaining four steps further encourage or force
    competition between BOC and non-BOC providers. 
    Id.
    § 276(b)(1)(B)–(E). Any state requirements that are
    inconsistent with FCC’s regulations adopted pursuant to § 276
    are preempted. Id. § 276(c).
    B. Factual and Procedural Background
    Over the years, payphone providers have sought to provide
    inmate calling services to inmates in prisons and jails
    nationwide. ICS providers now compete with one another to
    win bids for long-term ICS contracts with correctional
    facilities. In awarding contracts to providers, correctional
    facilities usually give considerable weight to which provider
    offers the highest site commission, which is typically a portion
    of the provider’s revenue or profits. See Implementation of Pay
    Tel. Reclassification & Comp. Provisions of Telecomms. Act of
    11
    1996, 17 FCC Rcd. 3248, 3252–53 (2002). Site commissions
    apparently range between 20% and 63% of the providers’
    profits, but can exceed that amount. Id. at 3253 n.34. And ICS
    providers pay over $460 million in site commissions annually.
    Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at 12821.
    Once a long-term, exclusive contract bid is awarded to an
    ICS provider, competition ceases for the duration of the
    contract and subsequent contract renewals. Winning ICS
    providers thus operate locational monopolies with a captive
    consumer base of inmates and the need to pay high site
    commissions. See 17 FCC Rcd. at 3253. After a decade of
    industry consolidation, three specialized ICS firms now control
    85% of the market. Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at 12801. And ICS
    per-minute rates and ancillary fees together are extraordinarily
    high, with some rates as high as $56.00 for a four-minute call.
    Id. at 12765 n.4.
    In reviewing this market situation, the FCC found that
    inmate calling services are “a prime example of market
    failure.” Id. at 12765. In its brief to this court, FCC counsel
    aptly explains the seriousness of the situation:
    Inmates and their families cannot choose for
    themselves the inmate calling provider on whose
    services they rely to communicate. Instead,
    correctional facilities each have a single provider of
    inmate calling services. And very often, correctional
    authorities award that monopoly franchise based
    principally on what portion of inmate calling revenues
    a provider will share with the facility—i.e., on the
    payment of “site commissions.” Accordingly, inmate
    calling providers compete to offer the highest site
    commission payments, which they recover through
    correspondingly higher end-user rates. See [Order, 30
    12
    FCC Rcd. at 12818–21]. If inmates and their families
    wish to speak by telephone, they have no choice but to
    pay the resulting rates.
    Br. for FCC at 4.
    In February 2000, Intervenor Martha Wright filed a
    putative class action against ICS providers on behalf of her
    grandson, other inmates, and their loved ones to challenge ICS
    rates and fees. Complaint, Wright, et al. v. Corr. Corp. of Am.,
    No. 1:00-CV-00293 (D.D.C. Feb. 16, 2000). In 2001, the
    District Court stayed the case to afford the FCC the opportunity
    to consider the reasonableness of ICS rates in the first instance
    through rulemaking. Thereafter, in 2003 and in 2007, Martha
    Wright and others petitioned the Commission for rulemaking
    to regulate ICS rates and fees. Petition for Rulemaking, FCC
    No. 96-128 (Nov. 3, 2003); Petitioners’ Alternative
    Rulemaking Proposal, FCC No. 96-128 (Mar. 1, 2007).
    The record compiled by the Commission fairly clearly
    supports its determination that ICS charges raise serious
    concerns. As noted in the FCC’s brief to the court:
    Excessive rates for inmate calling deter
    communication between inmates and their families,
    with substantial and damaging social consequences.
    Inmates’ families may be forced to choose between
    putting food on the table or paying hundreds of dollars
    each month to keep in touch. See [Order, 30 FCC Rcd.
    at 12766–67]. When incarcerated parents lack regular
    contact with their children, those children—2.7 million
    of them nationwide—have higher rates of truancy,
    depression, and poor school performance. See [id. at
    12766–67 & 12767 n.18]. Barriers to communication
    from high inmate calling rates interfere with inmates’
    13
    ability to consult their attorneys, see [id. at 12765],
    impede family contact that can “make[] prisons and
    jails safer spaces,” [id. at 12767], and foster
    recidivism, see [id. at 12766–67].
    Br. for FCC at 4–5. Petitioners do not seriously contest these
    facts. See Joint Br. for Pet’rs at 7 (acknowledging that “calling
    rates often exceed, sometimes substantially, rates for ordinary
    toll calls”).
    In 2013, the Commission issued an interim order imposing
    a per-minute rate cap for interstate ICS calls, citing its plenary
    authority over interstate calls under § 201(b) and its mandate
    to ensure that providers are “fairly compensated” under § 276.
    Rates for Interstate Inmate Calling Services (“Interim Order”),
    28 FCC Rcd. 14107, 14114–15 (2013). ICS providers
    petitioned for this court’s review of the Interim Order. The
    court stayed application of certain portions of the Interim
    Order but allowed its interstate rate caps to remain in effect.
    Order, Securus Techs. v. FCC, No. 13-1280 (“Securus I”) (D.C.
    Cir. Jan. 13, 2014), ECF No. 1474764 (staying only 
    47 C.F.R. §§ 64.6010
    , 64.6020, and 64.6060). In December 2014, the
    court held the petitions in abeyance while the Commission
    proceeded to set permanent rates. Order, Securus I (D.C. Cir.
    Dec. 16, 2014), ECF No. 1527663.
    In 2015, the Commission set permanent rate caps and
    ancillary fee caps for interstate ICS calls, and for the first time
    the agency imposed caps on intrastate ICS calls. Order, 30 FCC
    Rcd. at 12775–76, 12838–62. The rate caps were set for four
    categories – “all prisons” and three tiers of jails based on size
    – and the rate caps varied by category. 
    Id. at 12770
    . The rate
    caps, which were made effective immediately, ranged from
    $.14 to $.49 per minute, but were to decrease as of July 1, 2018,
    to $.11 to $.22 per minute. 
    Id.
     In setting the rate caps, the
    14
    Commission used a ratemaking methodology based on
    industry-average cost data that excluded site commissions as a
    cost. 
    Id. at 12790
    , 12818–38. The Order also imposed
    reporting requirements on ICS providers, including for video
    visitation services and site commissions. 
    Id.
     at 12890–93.
    ICS providers Global Tel*Link; Securus Technologies,
    Inc.; CenturyLink Public Communications, Inc.; Telmate,
    LLC; and Pay Tel Communications (“Pay Tel”) (collectively
    “Petitioners”) separately petitioned for review. Various state
    and local correctional authorities, governments, and
    correctional facility organizations petitioned and/or intervened
    on behalf of Petitioners. Martha Wright’s putative class and
    various inmate-related legal organizations (“Intervenors”)
    intervened on behalf of the Commission.
    In early 2016, the court consolidated the petitions for
    review. On March 7, 2016, the court stayed the application of
    the Order’s rate caps and ancillary fee caps as to single-call
    services while this case was pending. Order, Global Tel*Link,
    et al. v. FCC, No. 15-1461 (“Global Tel*Link”) (D.C. Cir. Mar.
    7, 2016), ECF No. 1602581. Subsequently, on March 23, 2016,
    the court stayed the application of the Interim Order to
    intrastate rates. Order, Global Tel*Link (D.C. Cir. Mar. 23,
    2016), ECF No. 1605455.
    In August 2016, on reconsideration of the FCC’s Order, the
    Commission raised the rate caps to account for a small portion
    of site commissions. Rates for Interstate Inmate Calling
    Services (“Reconsideration Order”), 31 FCC Rcd. 9300
    (2016). ICS providers petitioned for review of the
    Reconsideration Order, but the court held those petitions in
    abeyance and stayed the Reconsideration Order pending the
    outcome of this case. See Order, Securus Techs. v. FCC, No.
    15
    16-1321 (“Securus II”) (D.C. Cir. Nov. 2, 2016), ECF No.
    1644302.
    On January 31, 2017, counsel for the FCC filed a letter
    advising this court that the Commission had experienced
    “significant changes in [its] composition.” Letter at 1, Global
    Tel*Link (D.C. Cir. Jan. 31, 2017), ECF No. 1658521. Of the
    five Commissioners who had voted on the Order, two of the
    three Commissioners in the majority had left the FCC. 
    Id.
    Because the dissent’s position now commanded a majority,
    counsel for the FCC informed the court that “a majority of the
    current Commission does not believe that the agency has the
    authority to cap intrastate rates under section 276 of the Act.”
    
    Id.
     Counsel thus advised the court that the FCC was
    “abandoning . . . the contention . . . that the Commission has
    the authority to cap intrastate rates” for ICS. 
    Id.
     Counsel
    additionally informed the court that the FCC was abandoning
    its contention “that the Commission lawfully considered
    industry-wide averages in setting the rate caps.” 
    Id. at 2
    . At oral
    argument, counsel for the Commission confirmed the agency’s
    abandonment of these aspects of the Order. Tr. of Oral
    Argument at 43–45, Global Tel*Link (D.C. Cir. Feb. 6, 2017),
    ECF No. 1666379.
    II. ANALYSIS
    A. The Posture of this Case
    The current posture of this case is unusual because counsel
    for the FCC has advised the court that the agency will not
    oppose two of the principal challenges raised by Petitioners
    regarding: (1) the authority of the FCC to set permanent rate
    caps and ancillary fee caps for intrastate ICS calls; and (2) the
    legality of the Commission’s consideration of industry-wide
    averages in setting rate caps. In light of the FCC’s change of
    16
    position, a question arises as to whether these challenges are
    moot.
    It is well established that “voluntary cessation of allegedly
    illegal conduct does not deprive [a judicial] tribunal of power
    to hear and determine the case, i.e., does not make the case
    moot.” United States v. W.T. Grant Co., 
    345 U.S. 629
    , 632
    (1953). As the Court explained:
    A controversy may remain to be settled in such
    circumstances, e.g., a dispute over the legality of the
    challenged practices. The defendant is free to return to
    his old ways. This, together with a public interest in
    having the legality of the practices settled, militates
    against a mootness conclusion. For to say that the case
    has become moot means that the defendant is entitled
    to a dismissal as a matter of right. The courts have
    rightly refused to grant defendants such a powerful
    weapon against public law enforcement.
    
    Id. at 632
     (citations omitted).
    “Voluntary cessation” justifies the dismissal of a case on
    grounds of mootness only when “the defendant can
    demonstrate that there is no reasonable expectation that the
    wrong will be repeated. The burden is a heavy one.” 
    Id. at 633
    (citation and internal quotation marks omitted); see also
    Friends of the Earth, Inc. v. Laidlaw Envtl. Servs. (TOC), Inc.,
    
    528 U.S. 167
    , 189 (2000) (“[T]he standard we have announced
    for determining whether a case has been mooted by the
    defendant’s voluntary conduct is stringent: ‘A case might
    become moot if subsequent events made it absolutely clear that
    the allegedly wrongful behavior could not reasonably be
    expected to recur.’ The ‘heavy burden of persua[ding]’ the
    court that the challenged conduct cannot reasonably be
    17
    expected to start up again lies with the party asserting
    mootness.” (quoting United States v. Concentrated Phosphate
    Export Ass’n, 
    393 U.S. 199
    , 203 (1968))); Payne Enters., Inc.
    v. United States, 
    837 F.2d 486
    , 491–92 (D.C. Cir. 1988)
    (same).
    There is absolutely no basis for dismissing as moot the
    claims relating to the issues that the FCC has “abandoned.”
    Indeed, neither the FCC, the Petitioners, nor the Intervenors
    have urged this. The reason is fairly simple: the Order that gave
    rise to the petitions for review is still in force. Although counsel
    for the FCC has made it clear that the agency will not defend
    portions of the Order, the Commission has never acted to
    revoke, withdraw, or suspend the Order. Given this posture of
    the case, it is plain that there has been no “voluntary cessation”
    by the FCC that would warrant dismissal of Petitioners’
    challenges to the Order.
    B. Standard of Review
    Although Petitioners’ challenges to the provisions of the
    Order purporting to cap intrastate rates and to apply industry-
    wide averages in setting rate caps are not moot, a question
    remains as to what standard governs our review of these
    provisions. Normally, we would follow the familiar two-step
    Chevron framework as the appropriate standard of review. See
    Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
     (1984). Under the Chevron framework,
    an agency’s power to regulate “is limited to the scope
    of the authority Congress has delegated to it.” Am.
    Library Ass’n v. FCC, 
    406 F.3d 689
    , 698 (D.C. Cir.
    2005). Pursuant to Chevron Step One, if the intent of
    Congress is clear, the reviewing court must give effect
    to that unambiguously expressed intent. If Congress
    18
    has not directly addressed the precise question at issue,
    the reviewing court proceeds to Chevron Step Two.
    Under Step Two, “[i]f Congress has explicitly left a
    gap for the agency to fill, there is an express delegation
    of authority to the agency to elucidate a specific
    provision of the statute by regulation. Such legislative
    regulations are given controlling weight unless they are
    . . . manifestly contrary to the statute.” Chevron, 
    467 U.S. at
    843–44. Where a “legislative delegation to an
    agency on a particular question is implicit rather than
    explicit,” the reviewing court must uphold any
    “reasonable interpretation made by the administrator
    of [that] agency.” 
    Id. at 844
    . But deference to an
    agency’s interpretation of its enabling statute “is due
    only when the agency acts pursuant to delegated
    authority.” Am. Library Ass’n, 406 F.3d at 699.
    EDWARDS, ELLIOTT, AND LEVY, FEDERAL STANDARDS                   OF
    REVIEW 166–67 (2d ed. 2013).
    The disputed Order in this case was promulgated by the
    FCC “carrying the force of law.” United States v. Mead Corp.,
    
    533 U.S. 218
    , 226–27 (2001). Therefore, it was presumptively
    subject to review pursuant to Chevron. 
    Id.
     The oddity here,
    however, is that the agency no longer seeks deference for the
    parts of the Order purporting to cap intrastate rates for ICS
    providers and to apply industry-wide averages in setting the
    rate caps. In these circumstances, it would make no sense for
    this court to determine whether the disputed agency positions
    advanced in the Order warrant Chevron deference when the
    agency has abandoned those positions.
    Although the Chevron framework is of no significance with
    respect to the cap on intrastate rates and the application of
    industry-wide averages issues, this does not affect the court’s
    19
    jurisdiction to address these issues. See, e.g., New Process
    Steel, L.P. v. NLRB, 
    560 U.S. 674
    , 679–83 (2010) (deciding the
    statutory issue without reference to the Chevron framework).
    Therefore, “[w]ith Chevron inapplicable, . . . ‘we must decide
    for ourselves the best reading’” of the statutory provisions at
    issue in this case. Miller v. Clinton, 
    687 F.3d 1332
    , 1342 (D.C.
    Cir. 2012) (quoting Landmark Legal Found. v. IRS, 
    267 F.3d 1132
    , 1136 (D.C. Cir. 2001)).
    It is well recognized that when a disputed agency
    interpretation does not carry the force of law, it still may be
    “entitled to respect,” at least to the extent that the interpretation
    has the “power to persuade.” Skidmore v. Swift & Co., 
    323 U.S. 134
    , 140 (1944); see also Mead, 
    533 U.S. at
    227–31;
    Christensen v. Harris Cty., 
    529 U.S. 576
    , 587 (2000).
    However, in this case, because the FCC now offers no
    interpretations in support the provisions of the Order
    purporting to cap intrastate rates for ICS providers and apply
    industry-wide averages in setting the rate caps, the court must
    resolve these issues applying the usual rules of statutory
    construction. See, e.g., MCI Telecomms. Corp. v. Am. Tel. &
    Tel. Co., 
    512 U.S. 218
     (1994); see generally ROBERT A.
    KATZMANN, JUDGING STATUTES (2014); WILLIAM N.
    ESKRIDGE, JR., ABBE R. GLUCK & VICTORIA F. NOURSE,
    STATUTES, REGULATION, AND INTERPRETATION 409–29
    (2014).
    With respect to the remaining issues before the court, we
    will apply the Chevron framework, as applicable. As to all
    other issues, we will apply § 706(2)(A) of the Administrative
    Procedure Act (“APA”), which provides that a reviewing court
    shall “hold unlawful and set aside agency action, findings, and
    conclusions found to be . . . arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of
    discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with law.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(A). Under this standard of review, we search for
    20
    “reasoned decisionmaking.” Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n of U.S.,
    Inc. v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co. (“State Farm”), 
    463 U.S. 29
    , 52 (1983). This means that we must determine whether the
    FCC “examine[d] the relevant data and articulate[d] a
    satisfactory explanation for its action including a rational
    connection between the facts found and the choice made.” 
    Id. at 43
     (internal quotation marks omitted).
    C. The Authority of the FCC to Set Permanent Rate Caps
    and Ancillary Fee Caps for Intrastate ICS Calls
    In the disputed Order, the Commission asserted authority
    to impose rate caps on intrastate ICS calls for the first time. It
    did so under the guise of § 276 of the 1996 Act, which requires
    the Commission to “establish a per call compensation plan to
    ensure that all payphone service providers are fairly
    compensated for each and every completed intrastate and
    interstate call using their payphone,” and to prescribe
    regulations to establish this compensation plan. 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1), (b)(1)(A). Petitioners assert that the provision in
    § 276, requiring the Commission to ensure that ICS providers
    are “fairly compensated,” does not override the command of
    § 152(b), which forbids the FCC from asserting jurisdiction
    over “charges, classifications, practices, services, facilities, or
    regulations for or in connection with intrastate communication
    service.” 
    47 U.S.C. § 152
    (b) (emphasis added). Petitioners also
    contend that § 276 does not give the Commission ratemaking
    authority comparable to the authority that it has under § 201 to
    regulate and cap interstate rates. Finally, Petitioners point out
    that the intrastate rate caps prescribed in the Order make little
    sense in light of the undisputed record evidence showing that
    many ICS providers have costs that are higher than the disputed
    rate caps. We agree with Petitioners that, on the record in this
    case, § 276 did not authorize the Commission to impose
    21
    intrastate rate caps as prescribed in the Order. Several
    considerations have influenced our judgment on this matter.
    First, as noted above, § 152(b) of the 1934 Act erects a
    presumption against the Commission’s assertion of regulatory
    authority over intrastate communications. La. Pub. Serv.
    Comm’n, 
    476 U.S. at 373
     (making it clear that this is “not only
    a substantive jurisdictional limitation on the FCC’s power, but
    also a rule of statutory construction” in interpreting the Act’s
    provisions). As we explain below, the Order in this case does
    not come close to overcoming this presumption in proposing to
    cap intrastate rates.
    Second, the Order erroneously treats the Commission’s
    authority under § 201 and § 276 as coterminous. Section 201
    imbues the Commission with traditional ratemaking powers
    over interstate calls, including the imposition of rate caps. The
    statute explicitly directs the FCC to ensure that interstate rates
    are “just and reasonable,” and to “prescribe such rules and
    regulations as may be necessary in the public interest” to carry
    out these provisions. 
    47 U.S.C. § 201
    (b). Section 276, however,
    does not give the Commission authority to determine “just and
    reasonable” rates. Rather, § 276 merely directs the Commission
    to “ensure that all [ICS] providers are fairly compensated” for
    their inter- and intrastate calls. 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)(A).
    The language and purpose of § 201 in the 1934 Act are
    fundamentally different from the language and purpose of
    § 276 in the 1996 Act. The Order glosses over these differences
    in declaring that the Commission has authority to ensure that
    rates are “just, reasonable and fair.” See, e.g., Order, 30 FCC
    Rcd. at 12766, 12817. This is not what § 201(b) and § 276 say.
    And once the Order misquotes the language of § 201(b) and
    § 276, it goes on to conclude that these provisions in their
    combined effect authorize the FCC to set rate caps to ensure
    22
    that both inter- and intrastate rates are “‘just and reasonable’
    and do not take unfair advantage of inmates, their families, or
    providers consistent with the ‘fair compensation’ mandate of
    section 276.” Id. at 12817. In other words, in ignoring the terms
    of § 276, the Order conflates two distinct statutory grants of
    authority into a synthetic “just, reasonable and fair” standard.
    This is impermissible.
    Third, the Order asserts that the Commission “has
    previously found that the term ‘fairly compensated’ [in § 276]
    permits a range of compensation rates . . ., but that the interests
    of both the payphone service providers and the parties paying
    the compensation must be taken into account,” implying
    considerations of fairness to the consumer. Id. at 12814 n.335.
    This assertion is unfounded. The truth is that the Commission’s
    prior orders align with a narrow reading of the statute that does
    not purport to treat the Commission’s authority under § 201
    and § 276 as coterminous. The FCC’s prior orders to which the
    Order here refers construed the “fairly compensated” mandate
    of § 276 as irrelevant to ICS rates reached through contractual
    bargaining. This was because the FCC had determined that
    “whenever a [payphone provider] is able to negotiate for itself
    the terms of compensation for the calls its payphones originate,
    then [the Commission’s] statutory obligation to provide fair
    compensation is satisfied.” Implementation of the Pay Tel.
    Reclassification & Comp. Provisions of the Telecomms. Act of
    1996, 11 FCC Rcd. 21233, 21269 (1996). This is hardly
    evidence of “just, reasonable and fair” ratemaking under § 276.
    Furthermore, it is noteworthy that the Commission’s prior
    orders repeatedly acknowledge that § 276 focuses on the
    problem of uncompensated calls in situations in which BOC
    providers engaged in anti-competitive behavior. In other
    words, the FCC recognized that a principal reason for the
    enactment of § 276 was to address “the limitation on the ability
    23
    of [payphone providers] and carriers to negotiate a mutually
    agreeable amount” because of technological and regulatory
    constraints. Implementation of the Pay Tel. Reclassification &
    Comp. Provisions of the Telecomms. Act of 1996, 14 FCC Rcd.
    2545, 2551, 2569 (1999). Therefore, the prior orders to which
    the Order at issue here refers focused on payphone providers
    and carriers to determine whether the providers were fairly
    compensated. See, e.g., id. at 2570; Implementation of Pay Tel.
    Reclassification & Comp. Provisions of Telecomms. Act of
    1996, 17 FCC Rcd. 21274, 21302 (2002) (referring to providers
    and the carriers compensating the providers in stating that
    § 276 “implies fairness to both sides”). The prior orders did not
    reflect anything approaching “just, reasonable and fair”
    ratemaking for intrastate rates as authorized by § 201 for
    interstate rates.
    In the agency brief that was filed with the court before the
    FCC abandoned its support of the intrastate rate caps, counsel
    argued that fairness to the consumer is implied in § 276 because
    the reference to “fair” (in “fairly compensated”) is “capacious.”
    Br. for FCC at 31. This argument finds no support in the Order.
    As noted above, the Order simply asserts that intrastate rate
    caps are consistent with the Commission’s past orders. And, as
    noted above, the Commission’s past orders do not support a
    “capacious” interpretation of “fairly compensated” in § 276 to
    suggest that it is comparable to “just, reasonable and fair”
    ratemaking in § 201. The prior orders merely relied on the
    “fairly compensated” language to set a default rate from which
    the payphone providers and carriers could negotiate a
    departure, not to reduce bargained-for compensation. See, e.g.,
    11 FCC Rcd. at 21267–69; 14 FCC Rcd. at 2569–71. The
    Commission made it clear that it meant to “g[i]ve primary
    importance to Congress’s objective of establishing a market-
    based, deregulatory mechanism for payphone compensation, as
    24
    required both in section 276 and the generally pro-competitive
    goals of the 1996 Act.” 14 FCC Rcd. at 2548.
    Finally, the Order cites two decisions of this court to justify
    an interpretation of the “fair compensation” mandate in § 276
    that includes “just and reasonable” ratemaking in § 201. Order,
    30 FCC Rcd. at 12815–16 (citing Ill. Pub. Telecomms. Ass’n v.
    FCC, 
    117 F.3d 555
    , 562 (D.C. Cir. 1997); New England Pub.,
    
    334 F.3d at 75
    ). The Order’s construction of these decisions is
    misguided because neither decision compels the conclusion
    that § 276 authorizes the Commission to cap intrastate rates
    pursuant to “just, reasonable and fair” ratemaking.
    The Order first extracts language from the decision in
    Illinois saying that § 276 provides the Commission with
    “authority to set local coin call rates.” 
    117 F.3d at 562
    . But in
    the order under review in Illinois, the FCC did not “set” local
    coin call rates by imposing caps on intrastate rates. Rather, the
    agency merely interpreted the mandate of § 276(b)(1)(A) to
    “require[] the Commission to act only with respect to those
    types of calls for which a [payphone provider] does not already
    receive fair compensation.” Id. at 559 (emphasis added). And
    even for those calls, the FCC ultimately determined a default
    floor based on the deregulated market rate and allowed the
    payphone providers to negotiate a departure from that rate. Id.
    at 560.
    In reviewing the FCC’s order that was contested in Illinois,
    we held that § 276 unambiguously overrode § 152(b)’s
    presumption against intrastate jurisdiction insofar as it granted
    the Commission authority to “set” reimbursement rates for
    local coin calls in order to ensure that payphone operators who
    were previously uncompensated were “fairly compensated.”
    Id. at 561–63. The court did not say that § 276 overrode the
    presumption against intrastate jurisdiction to allow the
    25
    Commission to reduce already compensatory rates, which is
    what the Order at issue in this case suggests. Rather, the Illinois
    court said:
    If locational monopolies turn out to be a problem,
    however, the Commission suggested some ways in
    which it might deal with them: a State might be
    permitted to require competitive bidding for locational
    contracts, or to mandate that additional [payphone
    providers] be allowed to provide payphones at the
    location; and if these remedies fail, the Commission
    may consider the matter further.
    Id. at 562–63. None of these options contemplated caps on
    intrastate rates.
    It is true that the decision in Illinois does not explicitly
    preclude the Commission from imposing intrastate rate caps.
    That was not the question before the court. But the Order at
    issue in this case is wrong in suggesting that the decision in
    Illinois reflects “significant judicial precedent [that] supports
    the Commission’s authority” to reduce already compensatory
    rates. Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at 12815. Indeed, in Illinois the court
    reversed the Commission’s decision to exclude certain
    uncompensated calls from its mandatory compensation plan
    because the failure to provide compensation for this type of
    payphone call was “patently inconsistent with § 276’s
    command that fair compensation be provided for ‘each and
    every completed . . . call.’” 
    117 F.3d at 566
    .
    The Order at issue in this case also purports to rely on a
    statement in the New England decision that § 276
    “unambiguously and straightforwardly authorizes the
    Commission to regulate . . . intrastate payphone line rates.”
    Order at 12815 (quoting New England Pub., 
    334 F.3d at 75
    ).
    26
    But here again the cited decision merely confirmed that the
    1996 Act expanded the Commission’s intrastate regulatory
    authority within the limited parameters of § 276. The New
    England court held that Congress had authorized the
    Commission to carry out the anti-subsidy and anti-
    discrimination mandates of § 276(b)(1)(D)–(E) as to both inter-
    and intrastate payphone providers because Congress intended
    § 276 as a whole to “authorize the Commission to eliminate
    barriers to competition.” 
    334 F.3d at 77
    . But when pressed to
    extend § 276’s anti-subsidy and anti-discrimination mandates
    to non-BOC carriers, the court said, “the fact remains that
    sections 276(a) and 276(b)(1)(C), the sources of the
    Commission’s authority to regulate intrastate payphone rates,
    expressly apply only to the BOCs.” Id. at 78. The court was
    also clear in saying that outside the specific directives of § 276,
    general provisions “cannot . . . trump section 152(b)’s specific
    command that no Commission regulations shall preempt state
    regulations unless Congress expressly so indicates. Absent
    authorization to apply its section 276 regulations to non-BOC
    [carriers], the Commission may not regulate their intrastate
    payphone line rates.” Id. (citation omitted).
    Thus, neither Illinois nor New England stands for the
    proposition that the Commission has broad plenary authority to
    regulate and cap intrastate rates. Rather these decisions confirm
    the limited scope of § 276 which must be applied within the
    express bounds of its specific directives.
    The Order’s misconstruction of our case law stems from its
    fundamental misreading of § 276. The Order acknowledges
    that the Commission’s authority over intrastate calls is, “except
    as otherwise provided by Congress, generally limited by
    section [152(b)] of the Act.” Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at 12814. The
    Commission thus recognized that to assert jurisdiction over
    intrastate rates, the 1996 Act must “unambiguously appl[y] to
    27
    intrastate services.” Id. The Order errs, however, in concluding
    that § 276 required it “to broadly craft regulations to ‘promote
    the widespread development of payphone services for the
    benefit of the general public,’” and that this constituted a
    “general grant of jurisdiction.” Id. (quoting 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)). This misreads the language of § 276. The statute
    merely commands the Commission, “[i]n order to promote
    competition among payphone service providers and promote
    the widespread deployment of payphone services to the benefit
    of the general public,” 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1), to prescribe
    regulations to accomplish “five specific steps toward that
    goal,” New England Pub., 
    334 F.3d at 71
    . This is not a “general
    grant of jurisdiction” over intrastate ratemaking.
    The Order at issue in this case is legally infirm because it
    purports to cap intrastate rates based on a “just, reasonable and
    fair” test that is not enunciated in the statute, conflates distinct
    grants of authority under § 201 and § 276, and misreads our
    judicial precedent and the FCC’s own prior orders to support
    capping already compensatory rates under the guise of ensuring
    providers are “fairly compensated.” The point here is
    straightforward:
    The FCC’s belief that lower ICS calling rates reflect
    desirable social policy cannot justify regulations that
    exceed its statutory mandate. Section 276 of the
    Communications Act authorizes the FCC to ensure that
    ICS providers are not deprived of fair compensation
    for the use of their payphones; § 201 authorizes it to
    ensure that rates for and in connection with interstate
    telecommunications services are just and reasonable.
    The FCC may not ignore these statutory limits to
    advance its preferred correctional policy.
    Joint Br. for Pet’rs at 4.
    28
    We therefore reverse and vacate the provision in the Order
    that purports to cap intrastate rates as beyond the statutory
    authority of the Commission. We need not decide the precise
    parameters of the Commission’s authority under § 276. We
    simply hold here that the agency’s attempted exercise of
    authority in the disputed Order cannot stand.
    D. The Categorical Exclusion of Site Commission Costs
    The Petitioners contend that:
    The FCC’s exclusion of site commission payments
    from the costs used to set ICS rate caps was unlawful.
    ICS providers are required by state and local
    governments and correctional institutions to pay site
    commissions; those commissions are accordingly a
    cost of providing service like other state taxes and fees
    that the FCC recognizes as recoverable costs. The FCC
    acknowledged that, taking site commissions into
    consideration, the rate caps were below providers’
    costs. This violates the FCC’s obligation to “ensure
    that all payphone service providers are fairly
    compensated,” 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)(A), § 201’s “just
    and reasonable” requirement, and the Constitution’s
    Takings Clause.
    Joint Br. for Pet’rs at 16. The concerns raised by Petitioners
    are compelling.
    The Commission’s categorical exclusion of site
    commissions from the calculus used to set ICS rate caps defies
    reasoned decisionmaking because site commissions obviously
    are costs of doing business incurred by ICS providers. Yet, the
    Order categorically excluded site commissions and then “set
    the rate caps below cost.” Id. at 20. This is hard to fathom. “An
    29
    agency acts arbitrarily or capriciously if it has . . . offered an
    explanation either contrary to the evidence before the agency
    or so implausible as not to reflect either a difference in view or
    agency expertise.” Defs. of Wildlife & Ctr. for Biological
    Diversity v. Jewell, 
    815 F.3d 1
    , 9 (D.C. Cir. 2016) (citing State
    Farm, 
    463 U.S. at 43
    ). Ignoring costs that the Commission
    acknowledges to be legitimate is implausible.
    The FCC’s suggestion that site commissions “have nothing
    to do with the provision of ICS,” Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at 12822
    (internal quotation marks omitted), makes no sense in light of
    the undisputed record in this case. In some instances,
    commissions are mandated by state statute, Rates for Interstate
    Inmate Calling Services, 27 FCC Rcd. 16629, 16643 (2012),
    and in other instances commissions are required by state
    correctional institutions as a condition of doing business with
    ICS providers, 17 FCC Rcd. at 3252–53. “If agreeing to pay
    site commissions is a condition precedent to ICS providers
    offering their services, those commissions are ‘related to the
    provision of ICS.’” Joint Br. for Pet’rs at 21. And it does not
    matter that the states may use the commissions for purposes
    unrelated to the activities of correctional facilities. The ICS
    providers who are required to pay the site commissions as a
    condition of doing business have no control over the funds once
    they are paid. None of the other reasons offered by the
    Commission to justify the categorical exclusion of site
    commissions passes muster.
    On the record before us, we simply cannot comprehend the
    agency’s reasoning. Where, as here, an agency’s “explanation
    for its determination . . . lacks any coherence,” we owe “no
    deference to [the agency’s] purported expertise.” Tripoli
    Rocketry Ass’n v. Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco, Firearms, and
    Explosives, 
    437 F.3d 75
    , 77 (D.C. Cir. 2006); see also Coburn
    v. McHugh, 
    679 F.3d 924
     (D.C. Cir. 2012). Not only does the
    30
    FCC’s reasoning defy comprehension, the categorical
    exclusion of site commissions cannot be easily squared with
    the requirements of § 276 and § 201. We therefore vacate this
    portion of the Order.
    In its 2016 Reconsideration Order, the Commission raised
    the rate caps specifically to account for a portion of site
    commissions, effectively acknowledging that a categorical
    exclusion of site commissions from the ratemaking calculus is
    implausible. The Commission said:
    [W]e have decided, out of an abundance of caution, to
    take a more conservative approach and expressly
    account for facilities’ ICS-related costs when
    calculating our rate caps. Accordingly, we grant the
    Hamden Petition in part . . . and increase our interstate
    and intrastate rate caps to expressly account for
    reasonable facility costs related to ICS.
    Reconsideration Order, 31 FCC Rcd. at 9302. Although the
    FCC purported to change its position in the Reconsideration
    Order, that order does not moot Petitioner’s challenge here.
    See, e.g., N.E. Fla. Contractors v. Jacksonville, 
    508 U.S. 663
    ,
    662 (1993) (replacing the challenged law “with one that differs
    only in some insignificant respect” and “disadvantages
    [petitioners] in the same fundamental way” does not moot the
    underlying challenge).
    The Reconsideration Order is not before us, so we cannot
    say whether it provides a satisfactory response to Petitioners’
    challenge. We will leave this for the Commission’s
    consideration on remand. We also leave it to the Commission
    to assess on remand which portions of site commissions might
    be directly related to the provision of ICS and therefore
    legitimate, and which are not. In addition, although we
    31
    conclude that the Order at issue here is arbitrary and capricious
    insofar as it categorically excludes site commissions from the
    ratemaking calculus, we do not reach Petitioners’ remaining
    arguments that the exclusion of site commissions denies ICS
    providers fair compensation under § 276 and violates the
    Takings Clause of the Constitution because it forces providers
    to provide services below cost. These matters should be
    addressed by the Commission on remand once it revisits the
    exclusion of site commissions from the ratemaking calculus.
    E. The Legality of the FCC’s Use of Industry-Wide
    Averages in Setting Rate Caps
    Petitioners contend that:
    Even if site commissions are disregarded, the rate
    caps were set too low to ensure compensation “for each
    and every completed . . . call.” [
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)(A)]. The FCC’s caps are below average
    costs documented by numerous ICS providers and
    would deny cost recovery for a substantial percentage
    of all inmate calls. The FCC’s assertion that ICS
    providers with costs above the caps operate
    inefficiently is contrary to the record. The FCC relied
    on two outlier ICS providers that — combined —
    represent 0.1 percent of the ICS market. And it ignored
    evidence showing that the cost to provide ICS varies
    widely on the basis of regional differences, such as the
    age and condition of a given facility or the specific
    security features that correctional authorities demand.
    ****
    The record includes two economic analyses, both
    concluding that the Order’s rate caps are below cost
    32
    for a substantial number of ICS calls even after
    excluding site commissions. . . .
    The Order does not challenge these studies or their
    conclusions. On the contrary, it acknowledges that
    seven of 14 ICS providers that submitted cost data
    reported per-minute costs of “$0.25 or higher,” above
    the highest prepaid rate cap of $0.22 per minute.
    Joint Br. for Pet’rs at 16–17, 30–31 (quoting Order, 30 FCC
    Rcd. at 12669–70, 12795). Petitioners’ claims are well taken
    and largely undisputed. And, as noted above, the FCC has
    abandoned its contention that the agency lawfully considered
    industry-wide averages in setting the rate caps, and for good
    reasons.
    First, to the extent that the Order purports to set caps for
    intrastate rates, it is infirm for the reasons stated above. Second,
    the averaging calculus is patently unreasonable. The FCC
    calculated its rate caps “using a weighted average per minute
    cost,” Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at 12790, allowing providers to
    “recover average costs at each and every tier,” 
    id. n.170
    . This
    makes calls with above-average costs in each tier unprofitable,
    however, and thus does not fulfill the mandate of § 276 that
    “each and every” inter- and intrastate call be fairly
    compensated. See Am. Pub. Commc’ns Council v. FCC, 
    215 F.3d 51
    , 54, 57–58 (D.C. Cir. 2000).
    Moreover, the Order advances an efficiency argument –
    that the larger providers can become profitable under the rate
    caps if they operate more efficiently – based on data from the
    two smallest firms. See Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at 12790–95. Not
    only do those firms represent less than one percent of the
    industry, but the record shows that regional variation, not
    efficiency, accounts for cost discrepancies among providers.
    33
    See 
    id.
     at 12965 n.61 (dissenting statement of Commissioner
    Pai). The Order does not account for these conflicting record
    data.
    In sum, the Order’s analysis of the record data in setting
    rate caps was not the product of reasoned decisionmaking. We
    will therefore vacate that portion of the Order and remand for
    further proceedings.
    F.   The Imposition of Ancillary Fee Caps
    Contrary to Petitioners’ contentions, the Order’s
    imposition of ancillary fee caps in connection with interstate
    calls is justified. The Commission has plenary authority to
    regulate interstate rates under § 201(b), including “practices
    . . . for and in connection with” interstate calls. The Order
    explains that ICS providers use ancillary fees as a loophole in
    avoiding per-minute rate caps. Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at 12842.
    Furthermore, ancillary fees for interstate calls satisfy the test
    of the Commission’s authority under § 201(b) as they are “in
    connection with” interstate calls. However, these
    considerations do not fully answer the question whether the
    disputed imposition of ancillary fee caps is permissible.
    As noted above, we have found that, on the record in this
    case, the Order’s imposition of intrastate rate caps fails review
    under § 276. Therefore, we likewise hold that the FCC had no
    authority to impose ancillary fee caps with respect to intrastate
    calls. However, we cannot discern from the record whether
    ancillary fees can be segregated between interstate and
    intrastate calls. We are therefore obliged to remand the matter
    to the FCC for further consideration.
    34
    G. The Imposition of Reporting Requirements
    The Commission initially contended that the Order’s
    requirements with respect to reporting requirements for video
    visitation services and site commissions were unripe for review
    because they were pending budgetary approval by the Office
    of Management and Budget (“OMB”). After briefing, however,
    OMB approval was published. See 
    82 Fed. Reg. 12182
    -01
    (Mar. 1, 2017). Accordingly, the Commission withdrew its
    ripeness challenge. Letter, Global Tel*Link (D.C. Cir. Mar. 1,
    2017), ECF No. 1663705. Therefore, the parties agree that we
    may review the Commission’s imposition of the disputed
    reporting requirements.
    We hold that the video visitation services reporting
    requirement, 
    47 C.F.R. § 64.6060
    (a)(4), is too attenuated to the
    Commission’s statutory authority to justify this requirement.
    The Commission asserts that whether or not video visitation
    services are a form of ICS, they are still subject to the agency’s
    jurisdiction. See, e.g., Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at 12891–92; Br. for
    FCC at 56–57. We disagree. Before it may assert its jurisdiction
    to impose such a reporting requirement, the Commission must
    first explain how its statutory authority extends to video
    visitation services as a “communication[] by wire or radio”
    under § 201(b) for interstate calls or as an “inmate telephone
    service” under § 276(d) for interstate or intrastate calls. The
    Order under review offers no such explanations. We therefore
    vacate the reporting requirement for video visitation services.
    In contrast, we find no merit in Petitioners’ challenge to
    the site commission payment reporting requirement under 
    47 C.F.R. § 64.6060
    (a)(3). The quibble between the parties is
    largely over semantics. The Commission agrees that the
    definition of site commission payment should be read largely
    as Petitioners argue: namely, site commissions are “incentive
    35
    payments designed to influence a correctional authority’s
    selection of its monopoly service provider, not a form of
    ordinary tax.” Br. for FCC at 59 (citing Order, 30 FCC Rcd. at
    12818–22). So defined, the reporting requirement is lawful on
    its face and Petitioners do not disagree. We therefore deny the
    petition for review.
    H. The Preemption and Due Process Claims
    Petitioner Pay Tel separately challenges the Commission’s
    refusal to preempt certain state ICS rate caps that are lower than
    those the Commission set in the Order. Because we are
    vacating the portion of the Order imposing intrastate rate caps
    under § 276(b), the preemption provision under § 276(c) is no
    longer at issue. There are no relevant regulations under § 276
    remaining in the Order with respect to which the lower state
    rate caps might be preempted. This issue is therefore moot.
    Pay Tel’s claim that its due process rights were infringed
    when it was not given timely access to key cost data that the
    FCC relied on in setting the rate caps is also moot. We are
    vacating the portion of the Order setting rate caps for intrastate
    rates; the Commission has acknowledged that its use of
    industry-average data to set rates was error; and Pay Tel
    obtained access to the disputed data prior to the Commission’s
    issuance of the Reconsideration Order setting rate caps that
    supersede those in the Order at issue. The concerns raised by
    Pay Tel are thus moot.
    III. CONCLUSION
    In accordance with the foregoing opinion, we grant in part
    and deny in part the petitions for review, vacate certain
    provisions in the disputed Order, and remand for further
    36
    proceedings with respect to certain matters. We also dismiss
    two claims as moot.
    So ordered.
    CLARIFICATION AND AMENDMENT
    OF THE MAJORITY OPINION
    After the opinions in this case were issued, the Wright
    Petitioners filed a petition for rehearing en banc, challenging
    the panel majority’s decision on three points relating to the
    FCC’s Order on interstate and intrastate prison phone rates. On
    the three points in issue, the majority opinion reaches the
    following judgments:
    •   We hold that the Order’s proposed caps on
    intrastate rates exceed the FCC’s statutory
    authority under the 1996 Act. We therefore
    vacate this provision.
    •   We further hold that the use of industry-averaged
    cost data as proposed in the Order is arbitrary and
    capricious because it lacks justification in the
    record and is not supported by reasoned
    decisionmaking. We therefore vacate this
    provision.
    •   We find that the Order’s proposed wholesale
    exclusion of site commission payments from the
    FCC’s cost calculus is devoid of reasoned
    decisionmaking and thus arbitrary and capricious.
    This provision cannot stand as presently proposed
    in the Order under review; we therefore vacate
    this provision and remand for further proceedings
    on the matter.
    Global Tel*Link v. FCC, 
    859 F.3d 39
    , 45 (D.C. Cir. 2017).
    In its petition for rehearing en banc, the Wright Petitioners
    complain that, “[a]lthough this case involves an ambiguous
    statute administered by the FCC, the panel did precisely what
    2
    Chevron disclaimed: it ‘impose[d] its own construction on the
    statute’ rather than defer to the FCC’s detailed analysis of an
    ambiguous statute. . . . The panel opinion creates a dangerous
    loophole to evade judicial review when agencies are unable or
    unwilling to justify changed positions.” Br. for Wright
    Petitioners at 6, 8 (quoting Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural
    Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 843 (1984)).
    These claims are meritless.
    Lest there be any confusion over the majority’s opinion
    going forward, there are two points that warrant clarification.
    First, the majority opinion carefully analyzes the terms of the
    FCC’s Order and the agency’s justifications in support of the
    Order. The majority does not second-guess the agency. Rather,
    the majority found the FCC’s justifications for the proposed
    caps on intrastate rates “manifestly contrary to the statute,”
    Chevron, 
    467 U.S. at 844
    , and clearly unworthy of deference.
    Second, as noted above, after reviewing the entire
    record in this case, the majority opinion concludes that “the
    Order’s proposed caps on intrastate rates exceed the FCC’s
    statutory authority under the 1996 Act.” It goes without saying
    that if an agency action exceeds its statutory authority, the
    agency is entitled to no deference under Chevron. See, e.g.,
    Sullivan v. Zebley, 
    493 U.S. 521
    , 541 (1990); Goldstein v. SEC,
    
    451 F.3d 873
    , 880–81 (D.C. Cir. 2006). As the concurring
    opinion notes, “the statute’s structure and context demonstrates
    that the agency’s interpretation would fail at Chevron’s second
    step; it is an unreasonable (impermissible) interpretation of
    section 276.” If this point was lost in the original opinion issued
    by the majority, we make it clear now. We need not and do not
    decide whether we were required to follow Chevron Step Two
    even though the agency declined to defend its position before
    the court. The important point here is that we have carefully
    3
    analyzed the contested provisions of the FCC’s Order and
    found that they cannot survive review under either the “best
    reading” of the statute standard, Miller v. Clinton, 
    687 F.3d 1332
    , 1342 (D.C. Cir. 2012) (quoting Landmark Legal Found.
    v. IRS, 
    267 F.3d 1132
    , 1136 (D.C. Cir. 2001)), or pursuant to
    Chevron Step Two.
    There is no Chevron question with respect to the
    majority’s decision on the use of industry-averaged cost data
    as proposed in the Order. The majority found that provision
    arbitrary and capricious because it lacks justification in the
    record and is not supported by reasoned decisionmaking. The
    same is true with respect to the majority decision on the
    Order’s proposed wholesale exclusion of site commission
    payments from the FCC’s cost calculus. We found that
    provision devoid of reasoned decisionmaking and thus
    arbitrary and capricious. It is clear that no Chevron deference
    is due to agency decisions that are unsupported by reasoned
    decisionmaking.
    SILBERMAN, Senior Circuit Judge, concurring: I concur
    with Judge Edwards’ opinion in all respects. I especially agree
    that Chevron deference would be inappropriate in these unusual
    circumstances. I write separately to point out, as to the FCC’s
    claimed jurisdiction to set intrastate rate caps, that I think our
    result would be the same if the Chevron framework was in play,
    i.e., if the FCC had elected to defend this part of its regulation.
    There is no question that the relevant statutory language,
    “fairly compensated,” is ambiguous. 47 U.S.C. 276(b)(1)(A).
    Even the FCC agrees. But Judge Edwards’ careful explanation
    of the statute’s structure and context demonstrates that the
    agency’s interpretation would fail at Chevron’s second step; it
    is an unreasonable (impermissible) interpretation of section 276.
    Much of the recent expressed concern about Chevron
    ignores that Chevron’s second step can and should be a
    meaningful limitation on the ability of administrative agencies
    to exploit statutory ambiguities, assert farfetched interpretations,
    and usurp undelegated policymaking discretion.1 This case
    presents just one example of those kinds of agency tactics.
    There are others. Accord Michigan v. EPA, — U.S. —, 
    135 S. Ct. 2699
    , 2713 (2015) (Thomas, J., concurring) (“Although we
    hold today that [the agency] exceeded even the extremely
    permissive limits on agency power set by our precedents, we
    1
    See, e.g., City of Arlington v. FCC, — U.S. —, 
    133 S. Ct. 1863
    (2013) (Roberts, C.J., dissenting). Of course, some also question “step
    two” itself. For example, an essay in the Virginia Law Review
    contended that “Chevron Has Only One Step.” Matthew C.
    Stephenson & Adrian Vermeule, 
    95 Va. L. Rev. 597
     (2009). But that
    position ignores the practical effect on future agency discretion of a
    court opinion either affirming or reversing an agency interpretation at
    step one versus step two. Cf. Nat’l Cable & Telecomms. Ass’n v.
    Brand X Internet Servs., 
    545 U.S. 967
     (2005).
    2
    should be alarmed that it felt sufficiently emboldened by those
    precedents to make the bid for deference that it did here.”)
    To be sure, some have lamented that as a practical matter,
    under Chevron, either the case is decided at the first step or the
    agency prevails once it receives deference under step two. But
    that is not what the Chevron case called for.
    Chevron itself involved a phrase “stationary source” that
    was not at all defined and clearly could equally refer to (a) a
    factory complex, or (b) a specific emitter of pollution. 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 860-64 (1984). But it would have been unreasonable to
    refer to (c) a whole city. Yet too many times agencies have
    taken advantage of an ambiguity to pursue a (c), (d), or (f)
    interpretation that accorded with policy objectives. See, e.g.,
    Verizon v. FCC, 
    740 F.3d 623
    , 660 (D.C. Cir. 2014) (Silberman,
    J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
    Unfortunately, the Supreme Court for some time after
    Chevron contributed to the step one winner-take-all narrative by
    neglecting to rely on step two even when it was really called for.
    Take for example MCI Telecommunications Corp. v. AT&T Co.,
    
    512 U.S. 218
     (1994), in which Justice Scalia—perhaps the
    foremost expositor of Chevron—used statutory structure and
    context, much like Judge Edwards does in our case, to
    demonstrate that the FCC’s reliance on the word “modify” was
    unacceptable, see, e.g., 
    id. at 228-29
    . But he never conceded
    that the word “modify” was ambiguous, which it was. 
    Id. at 228
    (“We have not the slightest doubt that [single definition] is the
    meaning the statute intended.”).
    Subsequently, however, in AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities
    Board, 
    525 U.S. 366
     (1999), Justice Scalia implicitly relied on
    step two. He concluded that because the agency failed to
    interpret the terms of the statute “in a reasonable fashion,” the
    3
    rule must be vacated. 
    Id. at 392
    . Then, in City of Arlington v.
    FCC, — U.S. —, 
    133 S. Ct. 1863
     (2013), he admonished that
    “where Congress has established an ambiguous line, the agency
    can go no further than the ambiguity will fairly allow,” 
    id. at 1874
    . And most recently in Michigan v. EPA, — U.S. —, 
    135 S. Ct. 2699
     (2015), when invalidating agency action under step
    two, he was more explicit still: “Chevron allows agencies to
    choose among competing reasonable interpretations of a statute;
    it does not license interpretive gerrymanders under which an
    agency keeps parts of statutory context it likes while throwing
    away parts it does not,” 
    id. at 2708
    .
    We have at times been careful to apply step two review
    vigorously. See, e.g., Goldstein v. SEC, 
    451 F.3d 873
     (D.C. Cir.
    2006). This is just such a case where the agency’s original
    claim for Chevron deference—before the agency’s control
    switched—would have been rejected at Chevron step two; a
    muscular use of that analysis is a barrier to inappropriate
    administrative adventure.
    PILLARD, Circuit Judge, dissenting as to Sections II.B
    through II.F and concurring in part:
    The administrative record is full of compelling evidence
    of dysfunction in the inmate-calling marketplace, with harsh
    consequences for inmates and their families. The rule under
    review began with a 2000 lawsuit filed by inmates, family
    members, loved ones, and counsel (referred to in these
    proceedings as the Wright Petitioners). Finally acting on the
    Wright Petitioners’ concerns, the FCC in 2015 modestly
    curtailed exorbitant per-minute calling rates and limited
    providers’ ability to extract confusing and unrelated ancillary
    fees—amounting to as much as 38 percent of total inmate-
    calling revenue—for such things as setting up an account,
    funding an account, issuing a refund, and closing an account.
    See 30 FCC Rcd. 12763, 12838-42 (2015). The record shows
    that these high prices impair the ability of inmates, by
    definition isolated physically from the outside world, to sustain
    fragile filaments of connection to families and communities
    that they might hope to rejoin. The majority’s decision scuttles
    a long-term effort to rein in calling costs that are not
    meaningfully subject to competition and that profit off of
    inmates’ desperation for connection.
    The majority’s path to that result is flawed. I cannot agree
    that a company is “fairly compensated” under 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)(A) when it charges inmates exorbitant prices to use
    payphones inside prisons and jails, shielded from competition
    by a contract granting it a facility-wide payphone monopoly.
    The majority does not question that Congress enacted the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996 to combat phone
    monopolies, facilitate competition, and thereby ensure better
    service at lower prices to consumers. Consistent with the 1996
    Act’s general approach of “replac[ing] a state-regulated
    monopoly system with a federally facilitated, competitive
    market,” section 276 of the Act specifically addressed defects
    in the intrastate and interstate payphone market (now largely
    obsolete except in cellphone-free environments such as
    2
    prisons). New England Pub. Commc’ns Council, Inc. v. FCC,
    
    334 F.3d 69
    , 77 (D.C. Cir. 2003).
    The majority holds it beyond debate that “fairly
    compensated” is not about fairness to the consumer. It sees no
    statutory support for the FCC’s effort to require fairer intrastate
    rates for inmates because it reads section 276’s fair-
    compensation mandate as unambiguously one-sided, only
    empowering the FCC to enhance unfairly low, not to reduce
    unfairly high, compensation for calls. It accepts Global
    Tel*Link’s characterization of section 276 as nothing but a “no
    free calls” provision, Oral Arg. Tr. 40:55, confined to the
    enacting Congress’s acknowledged concern about independent
    payphone providers going uncompensated for certain calls.
    But that reading is truncated. As it typically does, Congress
    responded to a particular problem by enacting a law that speaks
    in more general terms: here, by requiring that payphone calls
    in prisons and elsewhere be “fairly compensated.” It did so for
    the stated purpose—fully relevant here—of promoting
    competition among payphone providers to expand the
    availability of payphone services to consumers. 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1).
    The majority offers one plausible reading of section 276,
    but it is assuredly not the only one. Congress has not “directly
    spoken to the precise question at issue” in this case, so the
    question for us is whether the FCC’s view when it promulgated
    the challenged rule—that section 276 grants authority not only
    to raise inadequate rates but also to reduce excessive,
    monopoly-driven rates—was a “permissible construction of
    the statute.” Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council,
    Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 842-43 (1984). I think it was. If the FCC
    under new management wishes by notice and comment to
    change its rule, the statute gives it latitude to do so. We should
    uphold the rule that is on the books and leave to the agency to
    decide whether and how to change it.
    3
    I.
    The FCC reasonably interpreted section 276 to “authorize
    the Commission to impose intrastate rate caps as prescribed in
    the Order.” Op. at 20-21. Congress instructed the FCC to
    “establish a per call compensation plan to ensure that all
    payphone service providers are fairly compensated for each
    and every completed intrastate and interstate call using their
    payphone[s].” 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)(A). To begin with,
    nobody contests that authority to establish “a per call
    compensation plan” includes some authority over end-user
    calling rates. Indeed, this court already so held. See Illinois
    Public Telecommunications Ass’n v. FCC, 
    117 F.3d 555
    , 562
    (D.C. Cir. 1997) (“Because … there is no indication that the
    Congress intended to exclude local coin rates from the term
    ‘compensation’ in § 276, we hold that the statute
    unambiguously grants the Commission authority to regulate
    the rates for local coin calls.”). And the plain text of the statute
    grants that authority over both intrastate and interstate
    payphone services, including “inmate telephone service in
    correctional institutions.” 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (d). Thus, the only
    dispute is whether the word “fairly” implies an ability to reduce
    excesses, as well as bolster deficiencies, in the compensation
    that payphone providers would otherwise receive.
    Importantly, Congress chose “fairly” rather than, say,
    “adequately,” “sufficiently,” or “amply.” Those words have
    different meanings. Had it used any of the latter three terms, I
    would agree that Congress only authorized regulation to
    prevent under-compensation, but its choice of the word “fairly”
    denotes no such limitation. Compare WEBSTER’S NEW
    COLLEGIATE DICTIONARY 407 (1980) (defining “fair” as, inter
    alia, “marked by impartiality and honesty: free from self-
    interest, prejudice, or favoritism”), with 
    id. at 14
     (defining
    “adequate” as, inter alia, “sufficient for a specific
    requirement”), and 
    id. at 1156
     (defining “sufficient” as, inter
    4
    alia, “enough to meet the needs of a situation or a proposed
    end”). Those words are also used differently in everyday
    language. See Schindler Elevator Corp. v. U.S. ex rel. Kirk,
    
    563 U.S. 401
    , 407 (2011) (court looks to “ordinary meaning”
    in absence of statutory definition). If a grocer demanded $20
    for a banana, we might call that price adequate, sufficient, or
    ample—but nobody would call it fair.
    The statutory context shows that Congress’ choice of the
    word “fairly” reasonably connotes its concern for unfairly
    excessive as well as deficient compensation. Elsewhere in the
    Communications Act, Congress used the term “fair” in
    conjunction with “just” and “reasonable”—familiar terms of
    art used in connection with rate-setting authority. See 
    47 U.S.C. § 204
    (b) (providing for partial authorization of new
    charges, which would otherwise be stayed, if the FCC
    determines “that such partial authorization is just, fair, and
    reasonable”); 
    id.
     § 205(a) (authorizing the FCC to prescribe
    “what classification, regulation, or practice is or will be just,
    fair, and reasonable”). And the fact that section 276 is one of
    several “Special Provisions Concerning Bell Operating
    Companies,” see Op. at 9, does not suggest that Congress
    exclusively intended to regulate the relationship between
    BOCs and non-BOCs to boost the latter’s compensation and
    was wholly unconcerned about the risk that callers would be
    charged excessive rates.
    The purpose and history behind the congressional action
    here comport with this reading of the statutory text and context.
    In passing the 1996 Telecommunications Act, Congress aimed
    to “promot[e] competition in the payphone service industry.”
    New England, 
    334 F.3d at 71
    ; see also 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)
    (stating congressional purpose “to promote competition among
    payphone service providers and promote the widespread
    deployment of payphone services to the benefit of the general
    public”).    To be sure, the immediate anti-competitive
    5
    malfunction confronting Congress at the time was that certain
    payphone providers were, under certain circumstances, under-
    compensated. See Illinois Pub. Telecomms. Ass’n v. FCC, 
    752 F.3d 1018
    , 1026 (D.C. Cir. 2014). But the central aim was to
    advance competition to the benefit of the end users of payphone
    services. Senator Kerry, for instance, explained that his goal in
    introducing section 276 was “to establish a level playing field
    for independent payphone providers,” and thereby to enable
    competition “on the basis of price, quality and service, rather
    than on marketshare and subsidies.” 3 Reams & Manz, Federal
    Telecommunications Law: A Legislative History of the
    Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, 
    110 Stat. 56
     (1996), at S710.
    Consistent with that pro-competitive agenda, the FCC and
    this court have long assumed that section 276 provides tools for
    addressing monopoly power and market failure in the
    payphone market. For instance, in Illinois, the state petitioners
    argued that the FCC had unlawfully ignored the problem of
    “locational monopolies,” that is, situations in which a
    payphone provider “obtains an exclusive contract for the
    provision of all payphones at an isolated location, such as an
    airport, stadium, or mall, and is thereby able to charge an
    inflated rate for local calls made from that location.” 
    117 F.3d at 562
    . We recognized that the FCC had not ignored the
    problem of locational monopolies; it had simply “concluded
    that it would deal with them if and when specific [providers]
    are shown to have substantial market power.” 
    Id.
     Now, twenty
    years later, the FCC has identified a discrete area where
    payphone providers do have substantial market power: prisons
    and jails. The inmate-calling market is, the FCC found, “a
    prime example of market failure” because, instead of
    competing to reduce rates and improve services for callers,
    providers compete to offer ever-higher site commissions to
    correctional facilities so as to gain monopoly access to a
    literally captive consumer base. 30 FCC Rcd. at 12765 & n.9.
    6
    Nevertheless, the majority cites four considerations that
    influenced its rejection of the FCC’s claimed authority over
    intrastate inmate calling services. Op. at 21-24. None is
    compelling.
    First, the majority notes that section 152(b) “erects a
    presumption against the Commission’s assertion of regulatory
    authority over intrastate communications.” Op. at 21 (citing
    Louisiana Pub. Serv. Comm’n v. FCC, 
    476 U.S. 355
    , 373
    (1986)). That is true, but section 276, by its plain terms,
    “overcom[es] this presumption.” Op. at 21. Congress
    instructed the FCC to ensure fair compensation for all
    payphone calls—interstate and intrastate. 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)(A). To that end, Congress expressly provided for
    preemption of inconsistent state regulation. 
    Id.
     § 276(c). This
    case is thus unlike Louisiana, which held that federal power
    over depreciation charges pursuant to section 220 was limited
    to the interstate ratemaking context; it is simply not “possible”
    here that section 276 “do[es] no more than spell out the
    authority of the FCC . . . in the context of interstate regulation.”
    Louisiana, 
    476 U.S. at 377
    . Whatever section 276 means, it
    applies in both the interstate and intrastate contexts. Cf. N.Y.
    & Pub. Serv. Comm’n of N.Y. v. FCC, 
    267 F.3d 91
    , 102-03 (2d
    Cir. 2001) (concluding that section 251(e) clearly “grants the
    FCC authority to act with respect to those areas of intrastate
    service encompassed by the terms ‘North American
    Numbering Plan’ and ‘numbering administration,’” and
    applying Chevron deference to agency’s interpretation of
    “what either term encompasses”).
    Second, the majority says that “the Order erroneously
    treats the Commission’s authority under § 201 and § 276 as
    coterminous.” Op. at 21. My colleagues appear to draw that
    conclusion from the FCC’s repeated use of the phrase “just,
    reasonable, and fair”—an amalgam of the two provisions’ key
    terms. As I read the Order, the bundling of those three words
    7
    simply reflects that the FCC’s authority over inmate calling
    derives from the sum of those authorizations. The majority’s
    inference that the Order fails to respect the difference between
    sections 201 and 276, and in particular, fails to appreciate that
    section 201 applies only to interstate rates, has no support in
    the record.
    Third, the majority concludes that the FCC erred in finding
    support for its approach in prior agency orders. Op. at 22-23.
    The majority says that “the prior orders . . . focused on
    payphone providers and carriers to determine whether the
    providers were fairly compensated.” Op. at 23. But this court
    has held that “compensation” includes end-user rates; it is not
    limited to payments between payphone providers and carriers.
    Illinois, 
    117 F.3d at 562
     (“[W]e hold that the statute
    unambiguously grants the Commission authority to regulate
    the rates for local coin calls.”).
    Fourth, the majority says the FCC mistakenly relied on this
    court’s decisions in Illinois and New England. Op. at 24-26.
    The majority acknowledges that Illinois “held that § 276
    unambiguously overrode § 152(b)’s presumption against
    intrastate jurisdiction insofar as it granted the Commission
    authority to ‘set’ reimbursement rates for local coin calls in
    order to ensure that payphone operators who were previously
    uncompensated were ‘fairly compensated.’” Op. at 24.
    According to the majority, however, setting rates to increase
    providers’ compensation is different from reducing “already
    compensatory rates.” Op. at 25. Yet Illinois ratified the FCC’s
    assertion of authority to regulate “locational monopolies.” 
    117 F.3d at 562
    . The majority responds that the FCC never said it
    would consider intrastate rate caps as the means of breaking up
    such monopolies. See Op. at 25. But the FCC, as we noted in
    Illinois, “specifically reserved the right to modify its
    deregulation scheme, for example, by limiting the number of
    compensable calls from each payphone.” 
    117 F.3d at 563
    .
    8
    Limiting the number of compensable calls per phone is, of
    course, economically similar to limiting the rate per call; either
    incentivizes broader deployment of payphones to maintain the
    same revenue levels. Thus, the FCC contemplated, and the
    Court approved, just the sort of pro-consumer regulation the
    FCC eventually undertook in the Order under review.
    Petitioners argue that in the rule at issue in Illinois, the
    FCC had merely claimed the authority “to adjust the per-call
    compensation scheme that the FCC itself put in place to ensure
    fair compensation,” not the “authority to regulate existing
    market rates.” ICS Pet’rs Br. 46 n.31. That is a false
    dichotomy. Cf. Illinois, 
    117 F.3d at 563
     (“A market-based
    approach is as much a compensation scheme as a rate-setting
    approach.”). The bottom line is that the FCC anticipated the
    problem of monopoly power in the provision of payphone
    services, and this Court ratified the agency’s authority to
    combat that problem by reducing providers’ compensation,
    including by adjusting end-user rates. There is thus no basis
    for the majority’s contention that “the FCC consistently
    construed its authority over intrastate payphone rates as limited
    to addressing the problem of under-compensation for ICS
    providers.” Op. at 5.
    The majority also takes issue with the Order’s invocation
    of New England, but the FCC correctly relied on that precedent
    for the limited point that “section 276 unambiguously and
    straightforwardly authorizes the Commission to regulate [the
    Bell Operating Companies’] intrastate payphone line rates.” 30
    FCC Rcd. at 12815 (quoting 
    334 F.3d at 75
    ). The fact that the
    FCC and this court previously articulated section 276 authority
    in terms of generic rate regulation is relevant here. And,
    contrary to the majority, New England’s holding that section
    276(b)(1)(C) does not apply to non-Bell Operating Companies
    has no resonance in this case. The provision at issue here,
    section 276(b)(1)(A), is indisputably applicable to non-BOCs:
    9
    it requires that “all payphone service providers [be] fairly
    compensated.” 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1)(A) (emphasis added).
    None of this is to suggest that the FCC has the same “broad
    plenary authority to regulate and cap intrastate rates” that it has
    over interstate rates. Op. at 26. Notably, whereas section 201
    broadly requires that “[a]ll charges, practices, classifications,
    and regulations for and in connection with [interstate]
    communication service[] shall be just and reasonable,” section
    276 is more narrowly focused on “compensation.” The FCC
    simply did not need “broad plenary authority” to conclude that
    inmate calling service providers charging as much as $56.00
    for a four-minute call, see Op. at 11, were not being “fairly
    compensated.”
    II.
    The majority also holds that the FCC’s complete exclusion
    of site commissions from its cost calculus and its use of
    industry-wide averages were arbitrary and capricious. See Op.
    at 28-33. It is unclear why the majority finds it necessary to
    address how the caps were calculated, given its rejection of the
    FCC’s power to cap at all. In any event, the majority’s analysis
    is misguided.
    Regarding site commissions, the majority says that
    “[i]gnoring costs that the Commission acknowledges to be
    legitimate is implausible.” Op. at 29. But the FCC did not
    acknowledge site commissions as legitimate costs. Quite to the
    contrary, the FCC agreed with a commenter who described site
    commissions as “legal bribes to induce correctional agencies to
    provide ICS providers with lucrative monopoly contracts.” 30
    FCC Rcd. at 12821. In other words, the FCC viewed site
    commissions not as real costs of doing business, but as “an
    apportionment of profit” between providers and correctional
    facilities. 
    Id. at 12822
    . The majority suggests that if site
    commissions are “directly related to the provision” of inmate
    10
    calling services in that they are conditions of receiving
    contracts to provide such services, they are “therefore
    legitimate.” Op. at 30. That equation makes no sense; the fact
    that a cost was charged under a prior regulatory regime cannot
    mean the agency is required to recognize that cost as
    “legitimate” and is disempowered from regulating it.
    Simply put, the fact that a state may demand them does not
    make site commissions a legitimate cost of providing calling
    services. The majority asserts that “[i]n some instances,
    commissions are mandated by state statute,” Op. at 29, but the
    record reflects that there is only one such statute, Tex. Gov’t
    Code Ann. § 495.027(a)(2). That statute categorically
    demands site commissions of at least 40 per cent of the
    provider’s gross revenue, which only illustrates the problem
    that site commissions are a form of monopoly rent not tied to
    actual costs.
    Indeed, considering site commissions as a compensable
    cost would effectively negate the FCC’s authority to mitigate
    locational monopolies. Imagine that a payphone provider (in
    the pre-cell phone era) contracted with a large stadium to
    provide just three payphones, anticipating that its monopoly
    would enable it to charge several dollars per minute while
    kicking back some percentage to the stadium. Plainly, the
    statutory goals of “competition” and “widespread deployment
    of payphone services” could be well served by a rule imposing
    reasonable, market-sensitive price caps to spur providers to
    offer more phones to maintain the same levels of revenue. 
    47 U.S.C. § 276
    (b)(1). But any such price cap would be worthless
    if it had to be calculated to ensure that the provider could
    continue its kickbacks to the stadium.            The kickback
    arrangement might, in some sense, be “related” to the provision
    of payphone services at the stadium, but it is not “reasonably”
    related because acceding to such preexisting contractual
    relationships is inconsistent with the statutory scheme.
    11
    On the averaging issue, the majority concludes that
    because the Order “makes calls with above-average costs . . .
    unprofitable,” it “does not fulfill the mandate of § 276 that
    ‘each and every’ inter- and intrastate call be fairly
    compensated.” Op. at 32. This holding seems to follow from
    the majority’s pinched interpretation of section 276 as a one-
    way ratchet whereby providers are always entitled to recoup
    “actual” costs incurred under monopoly conditions, no matter
    how extravagant. As I have explained, I believe that section
    276 conveys some authority to lower rates, which means the
    FCC need not take as given “calls with above-average costs.”
    Additionally, the majority fails to reckon with the FCC’s
    independent authority to cap rates for interstate calls under
    section 201, despite acknowledging that this power is “broad”
    and “plenary.” Op. at 26. In my view, the FCC has wide
    discretion under its section 201 “just and reasonable” interstate
    ratemaking authority to decide which costs to take into account
    and to use industry-wide averages that do not necessarily
    compensate “each and every” call, as section 276 requires. See
    Nat’l Ass’n of Regulatory Util. Comm’rs v. FERC, 
    475 F.3d 1277
    , 1280 (D.C. Cir. 2007) (agency is not “weaponless
    against conduct that might encourage or cloak the running up
    of unreasonable costs”). As the state petitioners aptly
    summarized, section 201 “gave the Commission broad
    regulatory authority over interstate communication in a
    ‘traditional form,’ mirroring regulation of railroads and public
    utilities, enabling it to set rates to allow a monopolistic utility
    to recover a reasonable profit but also protect the consumer
    from unjustly high prices.” State Pet’rs Br. at 28-29. The
    majority never explains why the FCC’s rate-setting
    methodology would be impermissible as to the interstate caps.
    III.
    Finally, I note that the majority offers no persuasive reason
    for abandoning the Chevron framework (which it admittedly
    12
    does only in dicta, as Chevron deference plays no role in an
    opinion holding section 276 unambiguous). It acknowledges
    that the Order is “presumptively subject” to deferential review,
    but then concludes that “it would make no sense for this court
    to determine whether the disputed agency positions advanced
    in the Order warrant Chevron deference when the agency has
    abandoned those positions.” Op. at 18. Absent any briefing on
    the subject or any citation to precedent, I cannot agree.
    The FCC, through notice-and-comment rulemaking, took
    certain positions—most notably that section 276 authorizes
    regulation of the fairness of intrastate inmate-calling rates—
    and defended them vigorously in briefing before this court.
    Less than a month before argument, the court on its own motion
    directed the parties to explain whether this case should be held
    in abeyance in light of recent personnel changes at the FCC.
    The FCC responded that the court should “move forward on
    the current schedule.” Doc. No. 1656116 (Jan. 17, 2017). Two
    weeks later, and just a week before argument, the FCC
    informed us that it would no longer defend certain points that
    it had briefed, but that the Wright Petitioners would “defend all
    aspects of the Order.” Doc. No. 1658521 (Jan. 31, 2017). The
    FCC has not committed to formally reviewing the Order, as
    other similarly situated agencies have recently done. See, e.g.,
    Murray Energy Corp. v. EPA, No. 15-1385, Doc. No. 1670218
    (April 7, 2017) (requesting postponement of oral argument so
    that agency could “fully review” the relevant rule). By
    suggesting that agencies can relinquish judicial deference
    through such limited and belated maneuvers as refusing to
    defend portions of their briefs during oral argument, the
    majority risks enabling agencies to end-run the principle that
    they must “use the same procedures when they amend or repeal
    a rule as they used to issue the rule in the first instance.” Perez
    v. Mortgage Bankers Ass’n, 
    135 S. Ct. 1199
    , 1206 (2015).
    ***
    13
    The majority appears to leave an opening for the FCC—
    on some other record and by some other reasoning—to rein in
    excessive inmate-calling rates, both interstate and intrastate.
    See Op. at 20, 29, 32 (limiting its analysis to the record in this
    case). And the majority invites the FCC to determine whether
    some “portions of site commissions” are illegitimate and non-
    compensable. Op. at 30. Still, because the majority
    shortchanges the FCC’s authority to reduce excessive,
    monopoly-driven rates, finds “implausible” the agency’s
    reasoned approach to a grave problem, and unnecessarily
    suggests limitations on Chevron deference, I respectfully
    dissent from Sections II.B through II.F of the majority opinion.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 15-1461

Filed Date: 8/4/2017

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 8/8/2017

Authorities (30)

people-of-the-state-of-new-york-public-service-commission-of-the-state-of , 267 F.3d 91 ( 2001 )

Tripoli Rocketry v. Bur ATF , 437 F.3d 75 ( 2006 )

National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners v. ... , 475 F.3d 1277 ( 2007 )

Payne Enterprises, Inc. v. United States of America , 837 F.2d 486 ( 1988 )

New Engl Pub Comm v. FCC , 334 F.3d 69 ( 2003 )

illinois-public-telecommunications-association-v-federal-communications , 117 F.3d 555 ( 1997 )

Skidmore v. Swift & Co. , 65 S. Ct. 161 ( 1944 )

United States v. Mead Corp. , 121 S. Ct. 2164 ( 2001 )

Goldstein v. Securities & Exchange Commission , 451 F.3d 873 ( 2006 )

Lndmrk Leg Fdn v. IRS , 267 F.3d 1132 ( 2001 )

Coburn v. McHugh , 679 F.3d 924 ( 2012 )

american-public-communications-councilpetitioners-v-federal-communications , 215 F.3d 51 ( 2000 )

city-of-brookings-municipal-telephone-company-v-federal-communications , 822 F.2d 1153 ( 1987 )

Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Assn. of United States, Inc. v. State ... , 103 S. Ct. 2856 ( 1983 )

United States v. W. T. Grant Co. , 73 S. Ct. 894 ( 1953 )

United States v. Concentrated Phosphate Export Assn., Inc. , 89 S. Ct. 361 ( 1968 )

Louisiana Pub. Serv. Comm'n v. FCC , 106 S. Ct. 1890 ( 1986 )

Global Crossing Telecommunications, Inc. v. Metrophones ... , 127 S. Ct. 1513 ( 2007 )

New Process Steel, L. P. v. National Labor Relations Board , 130 S. Ct. 2635 ( 2010 )

Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, ... , 104 S. Ct. 2778 ( 1984 )

View All Authorities »