Inteliquent, Inc. v. FCC ( 2022 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued November 1, 2021               Decided May 27, 2022
    No. 20-1471
    INTELIQUENT, INC.,
    PETITIONER
    v.
    FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION AND UNITED
    STATES OF AMERICA,
    RESPONDENTS
    On Petition for Review of an Order
    of the Federal Communications Commission
    Kevin King argued the cause for petitioner. With him on
    the briefs were Thomas Parisi, Nicole Antoine, and Ethan A.
    Sachs.
    Philip J. Macres was on the brief for amici curiae Intrado
    Communications, LLC, et al. in support of petitioner.
    Sarah E. Citrin, Counsel, Federal Communications
    Commission, argued the cause for respondents. With her on
    the brief were Robert B. Nicholson and Patrick M. Kuhlmann,
    Attorneys, U.S. Department of Justice, and Jacob M. Lewis,
    Associate General Counsel, Federal Communications
    2
    Commission. Richard K. Welch, Deputy Associate General
    Counsel, entered an appearance.
    Kevin D. Horvitz argued the cause for amicus curiae
    USTelecom - The Broadband Association. With him on the
    brief was Scott H. Angstreich.
    Before: PILLARD and RAO, Circuit Judges, and GINSBURG,
    Senior Circuit Judge.
    Opinion for the Court filed by Senior Circuit Judge GINSBURG.
    GINSBURG, Senior Circuit Judge: Inteliquent, Inc.
    challenges the Federal Communication Commission’s rate cap
    on the provision of tandem switch services, which are links in
    the routing chain for toll-free telephone calls placed from a
    landline. To reduce the incentives for regulatory arbitrage and
    to encourage companies to transition to lower-cost Internet
    Protocol technologies, the FCC set a transitional tariffed rate
    cap of $0.001 per minute for tandem switch services.
    Inteliquent argues the Commission: (1) ignored its evidence
    supporting a rate cap of $0.0017 per minute, (2) impermissibly
    delegated its rate cap decision to USTelecom, a trade
    association, and/or (3) set the rate cap below Inteliquent’s or
    other providers’ costs. For the reasons explained below, we
    deny Inteliquent’s petition for review.
    I.      Background
    Toll-free, or 8YY, calls are a type of call for which the
    recipient rather than the caller pays. When a caller dials an
    8YY number, his or her carrier typically queries a nationwide
    database to determine the owner of that 8YY number. Toll-
    free callers using a landline operating within a “time-division
    multiplexing” (TDM) network — a legacy method of
    3
    transmitting telephone signals — have their calls routed
    through a service switching point, also known as a tandem
    switch. Even if the network does not use a TDM, routing a toll-
    free call made from a landline is at least a three-step process:
    (1) the caller’s local telephone company, or local exchange
    carrier, picks up the signal; (2) which it routes to a tandem
    switch or intermediate switch provider; (3) which then routes
    the call to the interexchange carrier (IXC) providing service to
    the owner of the toll-free number. Tariffs for toll-free calls run
    in reverse of the signal, as depicted below:
    This process applies only to landlines; wireless call routing is
    different because the Commission’s rules prohibit wireless
    providers from paying providers of tandem switching.
    In the order under review (the Order), the FCC set a rate
    cap on tandem switching services, a common alternative for
    setting a rate in the regulation of telecommunications. Prior to
    1990, the largest local exchange carriers were regulated under
    a “cost-plus” system of regulations, in which the rates they
    could charge were based on their costs plus a return on their
    invested capital. That approach changed in 1990 when the
    Commission adopted an order that created “an incentive-based
    system of regulation” in order to “reward companies that
    become more productive and efficient, while ensuring that
    productivity and efficiency gains are shared with ratepayers.”
    4
    See In the Matter of Policy and Rules Concerning Rates for
    Dominant Carriers, 5 FCC Rcd. 6786, 6787, ¶ 1 (1990). The
    1990 order modified the tariff review process for incumbent
    Local Exchange Carriers — those that were once local
    monopolies — by capping their rates and dropping the cap each
    year to encourage them to improve productivity in order to
    continue to profit. Id. at ¶ 2. Since then, the FCC has used rate
    caps in other contexts, including the Order Inteliquent
    challenges here. See, e.g., In re: Core Communications, Inc.,
    
    455 F.3d 267
    , 273 (D.C. Cir. 2006) (discussing rate caps on
    carrier charges for delivering a call to an internet service
    provider); In the Matter of Rules for Interstate Inmate Calling
    Services, Third Report and Order, Order On Reconsideration,
    and Fifth Further Notice Of Proposed Rulemaking, WC
    Docket No. 12-375, FCC 21-60, at *2 (May 24, 2021) (setting
    rate cap for interstate and international calls placed from
    prisons).
    As part of its push to improve telecommunications
    practices, the FCC in 2011 reformed intercarrier compensation
    for toll calls. See In the Matter of Connect America Fund, 26
    FCC Rcd. 17663 (2011). In that order, the Commission
    adopted a presumption that pricing should move to a “bill-and-
    keep” model, in which a carrier bills only its own retail
    customers instead of billing other carriers in the path of a phone
    signal in order to cover its costs. That order did not apply to
    toll-free calls, in part because the companies providing tandem
    switching services for toll-free calls must receive payment
    from either the interexchange carrier or the local exchange
    carrier. In the Order under review here, however, the FCC
    transitioned “end office charges” for toll-free calls — that is,
    charges local carriers bill to IXCs for connecting their users to
    the IXC’s users — to a bill-and-keep model over three years,
    beginning in July 2021. Because tandem switch providers have
    5
    no retail customers to bill, the Commission did not transition
    tandem switching tariffs to bill-and-keep.
    After the FCC transitioned the toll market to the bill-and-
    keep model, the toll-free calling industry was beset by arbitrage
    schemes. These schemes take several forms, but we need
    explicate only one of them, “traffic pumping,” to illustrate the
    flaws in Inteliquent’s petition. In that scheme, a tandem switch,
    local telephone operator, or bulk termination service provider
    — any firm that purchases and routes 8YY traffic — has a high
    enough price/cost margin to make it profitable for it to pay
    others to place robocalls to toll-free numbers and route those
    calls over its facilities. The design of the scheme is depicted
    below:
    The arbitrageur — the LEC in the figure above — profits from
    the tariff fee for switching, minus the cost of providing the
    switching service and the cost of paying a robocaller to place
    the calls. This is possible, in part, because the competitive
    intermediate switch carriers’ tariffs are not based upon their
    costs; instead, they are capped at the rates charged by the
    incumbent LEC, see 
    47 C.F.R. § 51.911
    (c). The perversity of
    the arbitrage is compounded because the caller, even if it is a
    robocaller, does not pay for the toll-free call and therefore has
    no incentive to select the provider with the lowest rates.
    6
    In combination, these conditions create a market distortion
    because LECs originating toll-free calls not only lack the
    incentive to minimize intercarrier compensation and tandem
    switching charges, they also have an incentive to inflate those
    charges fraudulently through robocalling. As a result, arbitrage
    and this sort of fraud was widespread and increasing; indeed,
    AT&T submitted a study during the notice and comment period
    for the Order showing that 83% of all originating toll-free
    traffic in 2019 was part of such a scheme. These schemes cause
    system disruptions, congest incoming lines, and thereby impair
    carriers’ ability to complete legitimate calls. They also burden
    the owners of the toll-free number with sorting real calls from
    the many robocalls.
    To combat these schemes, the FCC in 2020 adopted the
    Order, aimed at making arbitrage unprofitable by bringing the
    price of switching toll-free calls to a point closer to the
    providers’ costs. Because arbitrageurs rely upon a high per-
    call profit margin in order to compensate robocallers, a low
    enough rate cap would minimize the incentive to arbitrage.
    Although setting the rate cap low enough to discourage
    arbitrage without putting providers out of business seems
    simple in principle, the Commission’s job was made more
    difficult because none of the commentors on its proposed order
    submitted data on its costs. Consequently, the FCC was left to
    discern as best it could, without information about a key
    component of the equation — providers’ costs — the rate cap
    that would discourage LECs or tandem switchers from
    encouraging, or engaging in, arbitrage.          Lacking that
    information, the Commission decided to adopt the lower of two
    rate caps proposed by commenters; USTelecom, a nationwide
    trade association, proposed a cap of $0.001 per minute based
    upon a midpoint rate calculated from data provided by its
    largest members. Inteliquent proposed a cap almost twice as
    high, to wit $0.0017 per minute. Unlike Inteliquent, which is a
    7
    single, independent tandem switch provider, USTelecom
    represents a large number and a wide range of market
    participants — including LECs, IXCs, and tandem switching
    providers. Because USTelecom’s footprint is so broad, and its
    members overwhelmingly supported its proposed cap, the FCC
    concluded USTelecom’s suggested cap of $0.001 was
    reasonable and would not set prices below providers’ costs.
    Inteliquent and other tandem switch providers, including
    amici Peerless Network, Inc. and Intrado Communications,
    LLC objected. They argued that a rate cap of $0.0017 per
    minute, based upon a weighted national average of
    Inteliquent’s own rates, would better ensure rates were not
    capped below providers’ costs.
    II.     Standard of Review
    The parties devote a lot of attention to the degree of
    deference we should accord the Commission’s Order but their
    dispute is not material to the outcome here. 1            The
    Administrative Procedure Act “requires that agency action be
    reasonable and reasonably explained.” FCC v. Prometheus
    Radio Project, 
    141 S. Ct. 1150
    , 1158 (2021). “Judicial review
    under that standard is deferential, and a court may not
    1
    The FCC claims we owe the Order greater deference because
    it is a transitional or interim order. See AT&T, Inc. v. FCC, 
    886 F.3d 1236
    , 1249-53 (D.C. Cir. 2018) (discussing deference to a rate that
    did not reach the Commission’s ultimate goal of universal broadband
    access); see also Competitive Telecommunications Association
    (CTA) v. FCC, 
    87 F.3d 522
    , 531 (D.C. Cir. 1996). Inteliquent
    counters that the Commission’s interim rate does not change the
    degree of deference we afford the agency because, as we also said in
    CTA, “[E]ven an interim rule expected to be in place for only a brief
    time is subject to review, or agencies would be free to act
    unreasonably for that time.” 
    Id.
    8
    substitute its own policy judgment for that of the agency.” 
    Id.
    “A court simply ensures that the agency has acted within a zone
    of reasonableness and, in particular, has reasonably considered
    the relevant issues and reasonably explained the decision.” 
    Id.
    Because the Order is “reasonable and reasonably explained”
    we need not determine whether additional deference to the
    Commission is warranted. See 
    id.
    The Administrative Procedure Act requires that we “hold
    unlawful and set aside agency action, findings, and conclusions
    found to be . . . arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or
    otherwise not in accordance with law.” 
    5 U.S.C. §§ 706
    (2) &
    (2)(A). Prior to adopting any regulation, the FCC must
    “examine the relevant data and articulate a satisfactory
    explanation for its action including a rational connection
    between the facts found and the choice made.” Motor Vehicle
    Manufacturers Association of U.S., Inc. v. State Farm Mutual
    Automobile Insurance Co., 
    463 U.S. 29
    , 43 (1983) (cleaned
    up). Here this means the Commission “cannot ignore evidence
    that undercuts its judgment; and it may not minimize such
    evidence without adequate explanation.” Genuine Parts Co. v.
    EPA, 
    890 F.3d 304
    , 312 (D.C. Cir. 2018).
    III.       Merits
    The FCC adopted the rate cap on tandem switching
    services to discourage arbitrage in toll-free calling and
    encourage adoption of lower-cost technologies. Although
    Inteliquent does not dispute these rationales, it argues that the
    Commission acted arbitrarily and capriciously in setting the
    rate cap for tandem switching at $0.001 per-minute for three
    reasons: (1) the FCC ignored the data Inteliquent submitted
    showing its weighted national average rates; (2) the
    Commission should not have relied upon USTelecom’s
    proposal as much as it did; and (3) the FCC needed to show the
    9
    cap was above providers’ costs. We first discuss the
    Commission’s justifications for the rate cap, then turn to
    Inteliquent’s arguments against it.
    A. Arbitrage and Lower-cost Technology
    Inteliquent concedes that the rate cap reduces arbitrage
    and encourages adoption of lower-cost Internet Protocol
    technologies, the very points the FCC says justify the rate cap.
    Inteliquent, however, claims the Commission’s “decision is []
    unreasonable because it fails to take [providers’] cost into
    account.”
    The agency should consider any reasonable cost
    information in the record but may then balance policy
    considerations beyond costs in setting a rate. See CTA, 
    87 F.3d at
    529 (citing National Association of Regulatory Utility
    Commissioners v. FCC, 
    737 F.2d 1095
    , 1137 (D.C. Cir. 1984))
    (“The FCC is not required to establish purely cost-based
    rates.”). Here the Commission considered but declined to rely
    upon the outdated and unrepresentative cost information
    Inteliquent submitted in favor of using a reasonable proxy for
    costs, namely, the proposal made by USTelecom. The
    Commission’s decision to set the rate cap at $0.001 per minute,
    then, was reasonable if the record supports its determination
    that a lower rate cap would better deter arbitrage or encourage
    a shift to lower-cost technologies and was reasonably
    calculated to avoid setting the cap below providers’ costs. See
    National Rural Telecommunications Ass’n v. FCC, 
    988 F.2d 174
    , 178 (D.C. Cir. 1993). Inteliquent says the Commission’s
    explanation of its choice merely states the obvious, namely,
    that a lower rate “seemed better calibrated to deter arbitrage.”
    Inteliquent is correct in saying the Commission’s rationale
    is simple but the company ignores that, in its effort to deter
    10
    arbitrage, the FCC wanted to adopt not just the lowest rate cap
    but the lowest rate cap above providers’ costs. The
    Commission’s explanation for choosing the lower of the two
    proposed rate caps to deter arbitrage need not be more
    complicated than that because the incentive structure for
    carriers to engage in arbitrage is not more complicated. Put
    simply, a lower profit margin allows less room to redirect
    profits to robocallers in exchange for generating phony toll-free
    calls. The FCC’s Order made clear the connection between
    arbitrage and its decision to select a lower rate cap, quoting a
    submission from Verizon: “[A]s long as 8YY tandem-switched
    transport rates remain high . . . there will be strong incentives
    for carriers to engage in such arbitrage schemes.” In the Matter
    of 8YY Access Charge Reform (“8YY Reform”), WC Docket
    No. 18-156, 
    2020 WL 6055137
    , at *17 (Oct. 9, 2020).
    Therefore, the record supports the Commission’s anti-arbitrage
    rationale for selecting USTelecom’s lower rate cap submission
    over Inteliquent’s nearly 70% higher submission. Further,
    Inteliquent does not challenge the Commission’s finding that a
    higher rate cap “could retard the transition to [Internet-
    Protocol-based] networks.” 
    Id. at *20
    . It follows that the
    record supports the Commission’s decision to set a rate cap on
    tandem switching services as low as possible — though
    preferably above providers’ costs — in order to deter arbitrage
    and encourage transition to lower-cost technologies.
    B. Inteliquent’s Data
    We now turn to Inteliquent’s arguments against the
    reasonableness of the rate cap. First, Inteliquent claims the
    FCC ignored the company’s data and failed to explain its
    reason for doing so. In fact, however, the Commission
    acknowledged Inteliquent’s submission and pointed out flaws
    that undermined the utility of the study Inteliquent submitted.
    First, the study was based upon rates Inteliquent charged but
    11
    did not include rates charged by any other carrier; therefore, it
    did not demonstrate that Inteliquent’s rates were representative
    of tandem switch service providers generally. Second, the
    study produced a weighted national average of rates rather than
    a weighted national average of costs, which provided the FCC
    little if any assistance in setting a rate cap above providers’
    costs. Although Inteliquent argues those rates reflected costs
    at one time, the Commission responds, correctly, that the
    incumbent providers’ rates Inteliquent relies upon have not
    been exclusively cost-based since 1990: “those cost studies are
    almost three decades old and, given the generally declining
    costs of providing telecommunications service . . . almost
    certainly overstate carriers’ current costs.” In short, the FCC
    did not ignore Inteliquent’s submission; the Commission
    considered Inteliquent’s data and reasonably explained its
    decision not to rely upon it.
    Citing Radio-Television News Directors Association v.
    FCC, 
    184 F.3d 872
    , 887 n.20 (D.C. Cir. 1999), Inteliquent next
    argues that even if its data were old and possibly flawed, the
    FCC could not disregard them because it had no more recent or
    more credible data to support its rate decision. It is true the
    Commission may not disregard relevant evidence, but here
    Inteliquent’s evidence was not relevant to the agency’s goals
    of reducing arbitrage and encouraging the adoption of lower
    cost technology. Indeed, Radio-Television supports this
    conclusion because the study we there faulted the FCC for
    ignoring directly laid out the potential costs of the challenged
    rule. See 
    id.
     Here, by contrast, Inteliquent’s study was not
    nearly so relevant; instead, as the Commission pointed out,
    being old and outdated, it was only weakly related to the
    current costs of providing tandem switch services.
    Most important, Inteliquent never suggested how its rate
    data could be used to calculate costs, even old costs; instead, it
    12
    argues in its reply brief for the first time that the Commission
    could have used some unspecified means to calculate
    providers’ costs from the rate data it submitted and then used
    that information to adjust USTelecom’s proposed rate cap. The
    FCC was not required to make a complicated, perhaps
    impossible, adjustment to USTelecom’s proposal. Instead, the
    Commission was required only to explain why Inteliquent’s
    submission did not bear upon the problems the Order sought to
    address, which is what it did.
    Inteliquent next argues the FCC may not dismiss as dated
    a study aggregating and weighting the “current rates for
    tandem services” because they are still the lawful rates and
    presumably, therefore, still just and reasonable. But the FCC
    did not approve the prior benchmark rates because they were
    the uniquely reasonable rates; the Commission approved them
    because it found those rates were within the zone of reasonable
    rates. See WorldCom, Inc. v. FCC, 
    238 F.3d 449
    , 462 (D.C.
    Cir. 2001) (“The relevant question is ‘whether the agency’s
    numbers are within a “zone of reasonableness,” not whether its
    numbers are precisely right.’” (quoting Hercules Inc. v. EPA,
    
    598 F.2d 91
    , 107-08 (D.C. Cir. 1978))). That does not mean a
    lower rate could not also be within the zone of reasonableness.
    Put another way, Inteliquent’s argument would be a reason to
    reject the Commission’s rate cap only if the FCC had
    previously determined each rate in Inteliquent’s study was the
    lowest just and reasonable rate. Because Inteliquent has made
    no such showing, its arguments about its data submission do
    not show the Commission’s rate cap is arbitrary and capricious.
    C. USTelecom’s Proposal
    Inteliquent next argues the Commission arbitrarily
    adopted USTelecom’s proposed rate cap despite its lack of cost
    justification. Inteliquent’s argument assumes the FCC must
    13
    adopt cost-based rates, which we have already seen is not
    correct. See CTA, 
    87 F.3d at 532
    , supra p. 9. The same is true
    of the rates Inteliquent cited in its own data as “cost-based”;
    those were benchmark rates, drawn from the tariffs of
    incumbent local service providers, and did not reflect the costs
    of those incumbent carriers. As noted previously, the
    Commission abandoned cost-based ratemaking for its current
    rate cap approach so that firms would have the incentive to
    lower their costs in order to increase their profits, which was
    also one of its reasons for capping rates for tandem switching.
    Finally, even if the FCC needed some evidence the rate cap was
    above providers’ costs, it reasonably relied upon evidence that
    many carriers already provided service at or below $0.001 per
    minute, and upon the overwhelming support of the numerous
    and diverse members of USTelecom.
    Inteliquent next argues the FCC, in accepting
    USTelecom’s proffered rate, failed to exercise its independent
    judgment. It is true the Commission may neither rely upon a
    commenter’s proposal without analyzing the support for that
    proposal, see City of New Orleans v. SEC, 
    969 F.2d 1163
    , 1167
    (D.C. Cir. 1992), nor delegate its decision-making authority to
    a private party, see Texas Office of Public Utility Counsel v.
    FCC, 
    265 F.3d 313
    , 328 (5th Cir. 2001). Here, however, the
    FCC did neither. In City of New Orleans v. SEC we vacated an
    agency’s finding because it relied upon a submission
    containing “no explanation or underlying support” and did not
    “ascertain[] the accuracy of the data contained in the study,”
    which taken together suggested the agency did not engage in
    reasoned decision-making. See 
    969 F.2d at 1167
    . Here, in
    contrast, the FCC reached its decision by analyzing the various
    arbitrage studies and comparing the submissions of
    USTelecom, Inteliquent, and others. The accuracy of the data
    upon which the FCC relied was not questioned; indeed,
    Inteliquent never argues USTelecom’s members were not
    14
    willing to accept $0.001 per minute as the rate cap — and
    therefore that the information USTelecom’s members provided
    through their revealed preference in accepting the proposal was
    inaccurate. It argues instead that the FCC should not have
    inferred the members’ support for the $0.001 rate cap implies
    their costs are less than $0.001. Considering, however, that
    USTelecom’s members are for-profit enterprises, we can
    hardly imagine an inference more reasonable. To have
    required that the association’s proposal be supplemented with
    cost data from its member firms would have complicated the
    proceeding to no purpose.
    Inteliquent next argues the FCC could not adopt
    USTelecom’s findings because they are not representative of
    the industry. Specifically, Inteliquent points out the midpoint
    rate USTelecom proposed was based upon the experience of
    large carriers only. Inteliquent is correct, but USTelecom
    members of all sizes nevertheless agreed to the rate, which
    implies it was above their costs as well. Indeed, the FCC said
    as much at the outset of the Order, recognizing that “not all
    carriers have endorsed the USTelecom proposal,” but it has
    support of “carriers whose size and business models vary
    significantly.” 8YY Reform, 
    2020 WL 6055137
    , at *8 n.73. In
    addition, USTelecom adopted its suggested rate of $0.001 per
    minute with the support of the same incumbent carriers upon
    which Inteliquent’s rate study was based; in other words,
    Inteliquent’s rate data are no more representative of the
    industry as a whole. 
    Id.
    Inteliquent next criticizes the Commission’s reliance upon
    the support of Bandwidth Technologies, another commenter,
    for the $0.001 rate cap on the ground that Bandwidth does not
    provide independent tandem switch services. As an initial
    matter, the petitioner overstates the Commission’s reliance
    upon Bandwidth’s support; the FCC pointed to Bandwidth’s
    15
    assent to the rate cap merely to point out that not only
    USTelecom’s members supported its proposal.                More
    fundamental, Inteliquent’s assertion that Bandwidth does not
    provide the same kind of services as Inteliquent is not correct;
    it does, but it uses a lower-cost, internet-based technology. In
    any event, Inteliquent’s argument that its own legacy
    technology deserves special cost consideration conflicts with
    the Commission’s stated purpose of encouraging adoption of
    lower cost technologies; we cannot substitute Inteliquent’s
    preferred policy of maintaining old technology for the
    Commission’s contrary policy.
    In sum, the FCC did not delegate its decision-making to
    USTelecom.      Nor did the FCC improperly rely upon
    USTelecom’s proposal despite the lack of explicit cost data
    supporting the proposal.
    D. Cost-justification of the Rate Cap
    Inteliquent and the amici argue broadly that the rate cap
    the FCC has adopted is below some tandem switch providers’
    costs and therefore unreasonable. It is true, as Inteliquent
    notes, that the FCC may not ignore “costs that the Commission
    acknowledges to be legitimate,” Global Tel*Link v. FCC, 
    866 F.3d 397
    , 413 (D.C. Cir. 2017), but as discussed above, other
    considerations may justify its departure from cost-based rates,
    see CTA, 
    87 F.3d at 532
    . Next, as the FCC and USTelecom
    point out, Inteliquent never provided evidence that the rate cap
    is below its costs, nor does it claim that now. Instead, it argues
    the rate cap is below its current weighted national average rate,
    but it produced no authority suggesting it is entitled to that rate.
    Therefore, it was reasonable for the Commission to conclude
    that Inteliquent’s data did not prove it needed to continue
    charging its current rates to remain profitable.
    16
    Inteliquent then argues that the agreement of USTelecom’s
    membership to a $0.001 per minute rate cap does not
    demonstrate that the rate is above-cost because its members
    may cross-subsidize by shifting costs to “tandem connection
    charges.” Although that is possible, there is no record evidence
    that USTelecom’s members will cross-subsidize tandem
    switch services capped at $0.001. In addition, the FCC points
    out that the independent tandem switch providers among
    USTelecom’s members, which could not cross-subsidize,
    nonetheless agreed to the rate cap.
    Finally, Inteliquent argues the rate cap is below-cost for
    some rural carriers, pointing to a letter in the record that so
    asserts. As the Commission points out, however, the letter does
    not contain any supporting data and Inteliquent made no effort
    to reconcile the letter with the support of USTelecom’s rural
    members. Finally, even if Inteliquent is correct that the rate is
    below cost for a small number of providers, Inteliquent cites no
    precedent, and we are aware of none, requiring the FCC to set
    a rate cap above the costs of the highest cost provider.
    IV.     Conclusion
    Inteliquent’s petition rests upon weak data and an outdated
    approach to price regulation. Incentive-based regulation need
    not accommodate the high-cost practices of every regulated
    firm, particularly when exigent circumstances, in this instance
    widespread arbitrage, provide the impetus for the agency’s
    order. Further, Inteliquent’s submission did not show the
    Commission’s rate cap was below cost for itself or for any
    other provider.
    The FCC Order setting the rate cap for tandem switching
    services at $0.001 per minute was not arbitrary and capricious;
    therefore, the petition for review is
    17
    Denied.