Jacqueline Halbig v. Sylvia Mathews Burwell , 758 F.3d 390 ( 2014 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued March 25, 2014                  Decided July 22, 2014
    No. 14-5018
    JACQUELINE HALBIG, ET AL.,
    APPELLANTS
    v.
    SYLVIA MATHEWS BURWELL, IN HER OFFICIAL CAPACITY AS
    U.S. SECRETARY OF HEALTH AND HUMAN SERVICES, ET AL.,
    APPELLEES
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the District of Columbia
    (No. 1:13-cv-00623)
    Michael A. Carvin argued the cause for appellants. With
    him on the briefs were Yaakov M. Roth and Jonathan Berry.
    Rebecca A. Beynon, E. Scott Pruitt, Attorney General,
    Office of the Attorney General for the State of Oklahoma,
    Patrick R. Wyrick, Solicitor General, Luther Strange,
    Attorney General, Office of the Attorney General for the State
    of Alabama, Sam Olens, Attorney General, Office of the
    Attorney General for the State of Georgia, Patrick Morrisey,
    Attorney General, Office of the Attorney General for the State
    of West Virginia, Jon Bruning, Attorney General, Office of
    the Attorney General for the State of Nebraska, and Alan
    Wilson, Attorney General, Office of the Attorney General for
    2
    the State of South Carolina were on the brief for amici curiae
    Consumer’s Research, et al.
    C. Boyden Gray, Adam J. White, and Adam R.F.
    Gustafson were on the brief for amicus curiae The Galen
    Institute in support of appellants.
    Charles J. Cooper, David H. Thompson, Howard C.
    Nielson, and Michael E. Roman were on the brief for amici
    curiae Senator John Cornyn, et al. in support of appellants.
    John R. Woodrum was on the brief for amicus curiae
    National Federation of Independent Business Legal Center in
    support of appellants.
    Bert W. Rein, William S. Consovoy, John M. Connolly,
    and Ilya Shapiro were on the brief for amici curiae Pacific
    Research Institute, et al. in support of appellants.
    Derek Schmidt, Attorney General, Office of the Attorney
    General for the State of Kansas, Jeffrey A. Chanay, Deputy
    Attorney General, Stephen R. McAllister, Solicitor General,
    Bryan C. Clark, Assistant Solicitor General, Bill Schuette,
    Attorney General, Office of the Attorney General for the State
    of Michigan, and Jon Bruning, Attorney General, Office of
    the Attorney General for the State of Nebraska, were on the
    brief for amici curiae States of Kansas, et al. in support of
    appellants.
    Andrew M. Grossman was on the brief for amici curiae
    Jonathan Adler, et al. in support of appellants.
    Stuart F. Delery, Assistant Attorney General, U.S.
    Department of Justice, argued the cause for appellees. With
    him on the brief were Ronald C. Machen, Jr., U.S. Attorney,
    3
    Beth S. Brinkmann, Deputy Assistant Attorney General, and
    Mark B. Stern and Alisa B. Klein, Attorneys.
    Martha Jane Perkins, Kelly Bagby, Iris Y. Gonzalez, and
    Michael Schuster were on the brief for amici curiae AARP
    and National Health Law Program in support of appellees.
    Mary P. Rouvelas was on the brief for amici curiae The
    American Cancer Society, et al. in support of appellees.
    H. Guy Collier and Ankur J. Goel were on the brief for
    amici curiae Public Health Deans, Chairs, and Faculty in
    support of appellees.
    Elizabeth B. Wydra and Simon Lazarus were on the brief
    for amici curiae Members of Congress and State Legislatures
    in support of appellees.
    Dominic F. Perella, Sean Marotta, and Melinda Reid
    Hatton were on the brief for amicus curiae The American
    Hospital Association in support of appellees.
    Andrew J. Pincus and Brian D. Netter were on the brief
    for amicus curiae America’s Health Insurance Plans in
    support of appellees.
    Matthew S. Hellman and Matthew E. Price were on the
    brief for amici curiae Economic Scholars in support of
    appellees.
    Robert Weiner and Murad Hussain were on the brief for
    amicus curiae Families USA in support of appellees.
    Before: GRIFFITH, Circuit Judge, and EDWARDS and
    RANDOLPH, Senior Circuit Judges.
    4
    Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge GRIFFITH.
    Concurring opinion filed by Senior Circuit Judge
    RANDOLPH.
    Dissenting opinion filed by Senior Circuit Judge
    EDWARDS.
    GRIFFITH, Circuit Judge: Section 36B of the Internal
    Revenue Code, enacted as part of the Patient Protection and
    Affordable Care Act (ACA or the Act), makes tax credits
    available as a form of subsidy to individuals who purchase
    health insurance through marketplaces—known as “American
    Health Benefit Exchanges,” or “Exchanges” for short—that
    are “established by the State under section 1311” of the Act.
    26 U.S.C. § 36B(c)(2)(A)(i). On its face, this provision
    authorizes tax credits for insurance purchased on an Exchange
    established by one of the fifty states or the District of
    Columbia. See 42 U.S.C. § 18024(d). But the Internal
    Revenue Service has interpreted section 36B broadly to
    authorize the subsidy also for insurance purchased on an
    Exchange established by the federal government under
    section 1321 of the Act. See 26 C.F.R. § 1.36B-2(a)(1)
    (hereinafter “IRS Rule”).
    Appellants are a group of individuals and employers
    residing in states that did not establish Exchanges. For reasons
    we explain more fully below, the IRS’s interpretation of
    section 36B makes them subject to certain penalties under the
    ACA that they would rather not face. Believing that the IRS’s
    interpretation is inconsistent with section 36B, appellants
    challenge the regulation under the Administrative Procedure
    Act (APA), alleging that it is not “in accordance with law.” 5
    U.S.C. § 706(2)(A).
    5
    On cross-motions for summary judgment, the district
    court rejected that challenge, granting the government’s
    motion and denying appellants’. See Halbig v. Sebelius, No.
    13 Civ. 623 (PLF), 
    2014 WL 129023
    (D.D.C. Jan. 15, 2014).
    After resolving several threshold issues related to its
    jurisdiction, the district court held that the ACA’s text,
    structure, purpose, and legislative history make “clear that
    Congress intended to make premium tax credits available on
    both state-run and federally-facilitated Exchanges.” 
    Id. at *18.
    Furthermore, the court held that even if the ACA were
    ambiguous, the IRS’s regulation would represent a
    permissible construction entitled to deference under Chevron
    U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    (1984).
    Appellants timely appealed the district court’s orders, and
    we have jurisdiction under 28 U.S.C. § 1291. Our review of
    the orders is de novo, and “[o]n an independent review of the
    record, we will uphold an agency action unless we find it to
    be ‘arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise
    not in accordance with law.’” Holland v. Nat’l Mining Ass’n,
    
    309 F.3d 808
    , 814 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (quoting 5 U.S.C.
    § 706(2)(A)). Because we conclude that the ACA
    unambiguously restricts the section 36B subsidy to insurance
    purchased on Exchanges “established by the State,” we
    reverse the district court and vacate the IRS’s regulation.
    I
    Congress enacted the Patient Protection and Affordable
    Care Act in 2010 “to increase the number of Americans
    covered by health insurance and decrease the cost of health
    care.” Nat’l Fed’n of Indep. Bus. v. Sebelius (NFIB), 132 S.
    Ct. 2566, 2580 (2012). The ACA pursues these goals through
    6
    a complex network of interconnected policies focused
    primarily on helping individuals who do not receive coverage
    through an employer or government program to purchase
    affordable insurance directly. Central to this effort are the
    Exchanges. 42 U.S.C. § 18031(b)(1). Exchanges are
    “governmental agenc[ies] or nonprofit entit[ies]” that serve as
    both gatekeepers and gateways to health insurance coverage.
    See 
    id. § 18031(d)(1).
    Among their many functions as
    gatekeepers, Exchanges determine which health plans satisfy
    federal and state standards, and they operate websites that
    allow individuals and employers to enroll in those that do. See
    
    id. § 18031(b)(1),
    (d)(1)-(d)(4). Section 1311 of the ACA
    delegates primary responsibility for establishing Exchanges to
    individual states. See 
    id. § 18031(b)(1)
    (providing that “[e]ach
    State shall, not later than January 1, 2014, establish an
    American Health Benefit Exchange (referred to in this title as
    an ‘Exchange’) for the State”). However, because Congress
    cannot require states to implement federal laws, see Printz v.
    United States, 
    521 U.S. 898
    , 904-05, 935 (1997), if a state
    refuses or is unable to set up an Exchange, section 1321
    provides that the federal government, through the Secretary of
    Health and Human Services (HHS), “shall . . . establish and
    operate such Exchange within the State.” 42 U.S.C.
    § 18041(c)(1). As of today, only fourteen states and the
    District of Columbia have established Exchanges. The federal
    government has established Exchanges in the remaining
    thirty-six states, in some cases with state assistance but in
    most cases not. See Richard Cauchi, State Actions To Address
    Health Insurance Exchanges, NAT’L CONFERENCE OF STATE
    LEGISLATURES                (May            9,            2014),
    http://www.ncsl.org/research/health/state-actions-to-
    implement-the-health-benefit.aspx.
    Under section 36B, Exchanges also serve as the gateway
    to the refundable tax credits through which the ACA
    7
    subsidizes health insurance. See 26 U.S.C. § 36B(a).
    Generally speaking, section 36B authorizes credits for
    “applicable taxpayer[s],” 
    id., defined as
    those with household
    incomes between 100 and 400 percent of the federal poverty
    line, 
    id. § 36B(c)(1)(A).
    But section 36B’s formula for
    calculating the credit works further limits on who may receive
    the subsidy. According to that formula, the credit is to equal
    the sum of the “premium assistance amounts” for each
    “coverage month.” 
    Id. § 36B(b)(1).
    The “premium assistance
    amount” is based on the cost of a “qualified health plan . . .
    enrolled in through an Exchange established by the State
    under [section] 1311 of the [ACA].” 
    Id. § 36B(b)(2);
    see also
    42 U.S.C. §§ 18021(a)(1), 18031(c)(1) (establishing
    requirements for “qualified health plans”). Likewise, a
    “coverage month” is a month for which, “as of the first day of
    such month the taxpayer . . . is covered by a qualified health
    plan . . . that was enrolled in through an Exchange established
    by the State under section 1311 of the [ACA].” 26 U.S.C.
    § 36B(c)(2)(A)(i). In other words, the tax credit is available
    only to subsidize the purchase of insurance on an “Exchange
    established by the State under section 1311 of the [ACA].”
    But, in a regulation promulgated on May 23, 2012, the
    IRS interpreted section 36B to allow credits for insurance
    purchased on either a state- or federally-established
    Exchange. Specifically, the regulation provided that a
    taxpayer may receive a tax credit if he “is enrolled in one or
    more qualified health plans through an Exchange,” 26 C.F.R.
    § 1.36B-2(a)(1), which the IRS defined as “an Exchange
    serving the individual market for qualified individuals . . . ,
    regardless of whether the Exchange is established and
    operated by a State (including a regional Exchange or
    subsidiary Exchange) or by HHS.” 45 C.F.R. § 155.20
    (emphasis added); see 26 C.F.R. § 1.36B-1(k) (incorporating
    the definition in 45 C.F.R. § 155.20 by reference). In
    8
    promulgating this broader rule, the IRS acknowledged that
    “[c]ommentators disagreed on whether the language in
    section 36B(b)(2)(A) limits the availability of the premium
    tax credit only to taxpayers who enroll in qualified health
    plans on State Exchanges,” but asserted without elaboration
    that “[t]he statutory language of section 36B and other
    provisions of the [ACA],” as well as “the relevant legislative
    history,” supported its view. Health Insurance Premium Tax
    Credit, 77 Fed. Reg. 30,377, 30,378 (May 23, 2012).
    This broader interpretation has major ramifications. By
    making credits more widely available, the IRS Rule gives the
    individual and employer mandates—key provisions of the
    ACA—broader effect than they would have if credits were
    limited to state-established Exchanges. The individual
    mandate requires individuals to maintain “minimum essential
    coverage” and, in general, enforces that requirement with a
    penalty. See 26 U.S.C. § 5000A(a)-(b). The penalty does not
    apply, however, to individuals for whom the annual cost of
    the cheapest available coverage, less any tax credits, would
    exceed eight percent of their projected household income. See
    
    id. § 5000A(e)(1)(A)-(B).
    By some estimates, credits will
    determine on which side of the eight-percent threshold
    millions of individuals fall. See Br. of Economic Scholars in
    Support of Appellees 18. Thus, by making tax credits
    available in the 36 states with federal Exchanges, the IRS
    Rule significantly increases the number of people who must
    purchase health insurance or face a penalty.
    The IRS Rule affects the employer mandate in a similar
    way. Like the individual mandate, the employer mandate uses
    the threat of penalties to induce large employers—defined as
    those with at least 50 employees, see 26 U.S.C.
    § 4980H(c)(2)(A)—to provide their full-time employees with
    health insurance. See generally 
    id. § 4980H(a).
    Specifically,
    9
    the ACA penalizes any large employer who fails to offer its
    full-time employees suitable coverage if one or more of those
    employees “enroll[s] . . . in a qualified health plan with
    respect to which an applicable tax credit . . . is allowed or paid
    with respect to the employee.” 
    Id. § 4980H(a)(2);
    see also 
    id. § 4980H(b)
    (linking another penalty on employers to
    employees’ receipt of tax credits). Thus, even more than with
    the individual mandate, the employer mandate’s penalties
    hinge on the availability of credits. If credits were unavailable
    in states with federal Exchanges, employers there would face
    no penalties for failing to offer coverage. The IRS Rule has
    the opposite effect: by allowing credits in such states, it
    exposes employers there to penalties and thereby gives the
    employer mandate broader reach.
    II
    Before we can turn to the merits of the parties’ dispute,
    we must first address the government’s argument that all
    appellants lack standing and that, even if they have standing,
    the APA does not provide them with a cause of action to
    challenge the IRS Rule. Because we find that appellant David
    Klemencic has standing and a cause of action under the APA,
    we do not reach the issue of our jurisdiction over the
    remaining appellants’ claims. See Mountain States Legal
    Found. v. Glickman, 
    92 F.3d 1228
    , 1232 (D.C. Cir. 1996)
    (explaining that as long as one plaintiff has standing for a
    claim, “we need not consider the standing of the other
    plaintiffs to raise that claim”).
    A
    The “‘irreducible constitutional minimum’” a plaintiff
    must show to establish standing is (1) an injury in fact
    (2) fairly traceable to the alleged conduct of the defendant
    10
    (3) that is likely to be redressed by the relief the plaintiff
    seeks. Sprint Commc’ns Co. v. APCC Servs., Inc., 
    554 U.S. 269
    , 273-74 (2008) (quoting Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife,
    
    405 U.S. 555
    , 560-61 (1992)). The district court determined
    that at least one of the appellants, David Klemencic, has
    standing. Klemencic resides in West Virginia, a state that did
    not establish its own Exchange, and expects to earn
    approximately $20,000 this year.1 He avers that he does not
    wish to purchase health insurance and that, but for federal
    credits, he would be exempt from the individual mandate
    because the unsubsidized cost of coverage would exceed eight
    percent of his income. The availability of credits on West
    Virginia’s federal Exchange therefore confronts Klemencic
    with a choice he’d rather avoid: purchase health insurance at a
    subsidized cost of less than $21 per year or pay a somewhat
    greater tax penalty.
    The government primarily questions whether Klemencic
    has suffered an injury in fact. An injury in fact is “a concrete
    and particularized invasion of a legally protected interest.”
    Sprint Commc’ns 
    Co., 554 U.S. at 273
    (internal quotation
    marks omitted). The government characterizes Klemencic’s
    injury as purely ideological and hence neither concrete nor
    particularized. But, although Klemencic admits to being at
    1
    Although West Virginia actually passed legislation
    authorizing the establishment of an Exchange, see W. VA. CODE
    § 33-16G-1 et seq., it subsequently decided to allow the federal
    government to establish the Exchange, in partnership with the state,
    due to cost concerns, see Nat’l Conference of State Legislatures:
    Health Insurance Exchanges or Marketplaces: State Action—May
    2014,     http://www.ncsl.org/Portals/1/Documents/Health/Health_
    Insurance_Exchanges_State_Profiles.pdf#page=49 (last visited
    June 12, 2014).
    11
    least partly motivated by opposition to “government
    handouts,” he has established that, by making subsidies
    available in West Virginia, the IRS Rule will have
    quantifiable economic consequences particular to him. See
    Clapper v. Amnesty Int’l USA, 
    133 S. Ct. 1138
    , 1147 (2013)
    (explaining that a “threatened injury” that is “certainly
    impending” may “constitute injury in fact” (emphasis and
    internal quotation marks omitted)). Those consequences may
    be small, but even an “‘identifiable trifle’” of harm may
    establish standing. Chevron Natural Gas v. FERC, 199 F.
    App’x 2, 4 (D.C. Cir. 2006) (quoting United States v. Students
    Challenging Regulatory Agency Procedures, 
    412 U.S. 669
    ,
    689 n.14 (1973)); see Bob Jones Univ. v. United States, 
    461 U.S. 574
    , 581-82 (1983) (noting that Bob Jones University
    sued for a tax refund of $21.00). Klemencic thus satisfies the
    requirement of establishing an injury in fact, and because that
    injury is traceable to the IRS Rule and redressable through a
    judicial decision invalidating the rule, we find that he has
    standing to challenge the rule. We therefore proceed to
    consider whether Klemencic may mount his challenge under
    the APA.
    B
    The APA provides a cause of action to challenge final
    agency action “for which there is no other adequate remedy in
    a court.” 5 U.S.C. § 704. The government argues that even if
    Klemencic has standing to challenge the IRS Rule, he cannot
    do so under the APA because he has an adequate alternative
    remedy in the form of a tax-refund suit: Klemencic could
    violate the individual mandate, pay the penalty, and then sue
    for a refund, raising the same arguments he makes here. See
    28 U.S.C. § 1346(a)(1); see also 26 U.S.C. § 7422(a). Such a
    remedy is adequate, the government contends, because if
    12
    Klemencic were successful, the suit would make him
    financially whole.
    The APA “embodies the basic presumption of judicial
    review” of agency action. Abbott Labs. v. Gardner, 
    387 U.S. 136
    , 140 (1967). Therefore, in determining whether an
    alternative remedy is adequate, we must give the APA’s
    “generous review provisions” a “hospitable interpretation,”
    such that “only upon a showing of clear and convincing
    evidence of a contrary legislative intent should the courts
    restrict access to judicial review.” 
    Id. at 141
    (internal
    quotation marks omitted); see Garcia v. Vilsack, 
    563 F.3d 519
    , 523 (D.C. Cir. 2009). Under this standard, “[a]n
    alternative remedy will not be adequate . . . if the remedy
    offers only ‘doubtful and limited relief.’” 
    Garcia, 563 F.3d at 522
    (quoting Bowen v. Massachusetts, 
    487 U.S. 879
    , 901
    (1988)). Although “the alternative remedy need not provide
    relief identical to relief under the APA,” it must “offer[] relief
    of the ‘same genre.’” 
    Id. at 522
    (quoting El Rio Santa Cruz
    Neighborhood Health Ctr. v. U.S. Dep’t of Health & Human
    Servs., 
    396 F.3d 1265
    , 1272 (D.C. Cir. 2005)).
    In arguing that a tax refund suit provides an adequate
    alternative remedy, the government emphasizes Klemencic’s
    ability to recover any assessed overpayment, plus interest. But
    that backward-looking relief differs in kind from the
    prospective relief Klemencic could obtain under the APA. See
    
    Bowen, 487 U.S. at 904-05
    (rejecting as “unprecedented” the
    government’s argument that a suit for monetary damages is an
    adequate alternative to prospective relief under the APA).
    Specifically, requiring Klemencic to proceed via refund suit
    would deprive him of the opportunity to obtain a “certificate
    of exemption.” See 45 C.F.R. § 155.605(g)(2). Such
    certificates are a form of safe harbor, allowing an individual
    to obtain an exemption from the mandate’s penalty on the
    13
    basis of projected income, “notwithstanding any [subsequent]
    change     in    an    individual’s    circumstances.”     
    Id. § 155.605(g)(2)(vi).
    Unlike the “prospective[]” assurance
    such certificates offer, 
    id., a refund
    suit would require
    Klemencic to violate the law as it now stands, pay a penalty,
    and only then challenge the assessment of the penalty for that
    previous year based on his actual income. And even if
    Klemencic were to prevail, his relief—financial restitution—
    would be backwards looking, meaning that Klemencic would
    have to repeat the cycle the following year. The government
    offers no suggestion that he could obtain a certificate of
    exemption through a refund action.
    Furthermore, it is not clear that Klemencic could obtain
    any prospective relief through a refund action, let alone that
    which he seeks under his APA claim—namely, a declaration
    that the IRS Rule is invalid and an injunction barring its
    implementation. As we explained in Cohen v. United States,
    the provision authorizing refund suits “does not, at least
    explicitly, allow for prospective relief.” 
    650 F.3d 717
    , 732
    (D.C. Cir. 2011) (en banc); see 26 U.S.C. § 7422(a) (setting
    forth requirements applicable to any “suit or proceeding . . .
    for the recovery . . . of any penalty claimed to have been
    collected without authority” (emphasis added)). And the
    government here does not suggest that it implicitly allows
    such relief, maintaining instead the studied silence as to the
    availability of non-monetary relief that, in Cohen, we
    interpreted as a concession of the limited nature of the
    remedies a refund suit under section 7422 offers. See 
    Cohen, 650 F.3d at 732
    . (noting that, by being “agnostic concerning
    the availability of broad equitable remedies as part of a refund
    suit,” the IRS “unknowingly concedes” that an action under
    section 7422 does not offer prospective relief). We must
    therefore conclude that a tax refund suit is inadequate as an
    alternative remedy: it is “doubtful” that it offers prospective
    14
    relief at all, and the monetary relief it does offer is clearly not
    “of the same genre” as the relief available to appellants under
    the APA. See 
    Garcia, 563 F.3d at 522
    (internal quotation
    marks omitted). Because a tax refund suit thus offers
    Klemencic only “doubtful and limited relief,” 
    Bowen, 487 U.S. at 901
    , we hold that the APA provides him with a cause
    of action to challenge the IRS Rule and turn to the merits of
    his claim.
    III
    On the merits, this case requires us to determine whether
    the ACA permits the IRS to provide tax credits for insurance
    purchased through federal Exchanges. To make this
    determination, we begin by asking “whether Congress has
    directly spoken to the precise question at issue,” for if it has,
    we must give effect to its unambiguously expressed intent.
    Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Res. Def. Council, 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 842-43 (1984). The text of section 36B is only the
    starting point of this analysis. That provision is but one piece
    of a vast, complex statutory scheme, and we must consider it
    both on its own and in relation to the ACA’s interconnected
    provisions and overall structure so as to interpret the Act, if
    possible, “as a symmetrical and coherent scheme.” See FDA
    v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    529 U.S. 120
    , 133
    (2000) (internal quotation marks omitted); Wolf Run Mining
    Co. v. Fed. Mine Safety & Health Review Comm’n, 
    659 F.3d 1197
    , 1200 (D.C. Cir. 2011).
    Although both appellants and the government argue that
    the ACA, read in its totality, evinces clear congressional
    intent, they dispute what that intent actually is. Appellants
    argue that if taxpayers can receive credits only for plans
    enrolled in “through an Exchange established by the State
    under section 1311 of the [ACA],” then the IRS clearly
    15
    cannot give credits to taxpayers who purchased insurance on
    an Exchange established by the federal government. After all,
    the federal government is not a “State,” see 42 U.S.C.
    § 18024(d) (defining “State” to “mean[] each of the 50 States
    and the District of Columbia”), and its authority to establish
    Exchanges appears in section 1321 rather than section 1311,
    see 
    id. § 18041(c)(1).
    The government counters that
    appellants take a blinkered view of the ACA and that sections
    1311 and 1321 of the Act establish complete equivalence
    between state and federal Exchanges, such that when the
    federal government establishes an Exchange, it does so
    standing in the state’s shoes. Furthermore, the government
    argues, whereas appellants’ construction of section 36B
    renders other provisions of the ACA absurd, its own view
    brings coherence to the statute and better promotes the
    purpose of the Act.
    We conclude that appellants have the better of the
    argument: a federal Exchange is not an “Exchange established
    by the State,” and section 36B does not authorize the IRS to
    provide tax credits for insurance purchased on federal
    Exchanges. We reach this conclusion by the following path:
    First, we examine section 36B in light of sections 1311 and
    1321, which authorize the establishment of state and federal
    Exchanges, respectively, and conclude that section 36B
    plainly distinguishes Exchanges established by states from
    those established by the federal government. We then
    consider the government’s arguments that this construction
    generates absurd results but find that it does not render other
    provisions of the ACA unworkable, let alone so unreasonable
    as to justify disregarding section 36B’s plain meaning.
    Finally, turning to the ACA’s purpose and legislative history,
    we find that the government again comes up short in its
    efforts to overcome the statutory text. Its appeals to the
    ACA’s broad aims do not demonstrate that Congress
    16
    manifestly meant something other than what section 36B
    says.
    A
    The crux of this case is whether an Exchange established
    by the federal government is an “Exchange established by the
    State under section 1311 of the [ACA].” We therefore begin
    with the provisions authorizing states and the federal
    government to establish Exchanges. Section 1311 provides
    that states “shall” establish Exchanges. 42 U.S.C.
    § 18031(b)(1). But, as the parties agree, despite its seemingly
    mandatory language, section 1311 more cajoles than
    commands. A state is not literally required to establish an
    Exchange; the ACA merely encourages it to do so. And if a
    state elects not to (or is unable to), such that it “will not have
    any required Exchange operational by January 1, 2014,”
    section 1321 directs the federal government, through the
    Secretary of Health and Human Services, to “establish and
    operate such Exchange within the State.” 
    Id. § 18041(c)(1)
    (emphasis added).
    The phrase “such Exchange” has twofold significance.
    First, the word “such”—meaning “aforementioned,” see
    BLACK’S LAW DICTIONARY 1473 (8th ed. 2004); WEBSTER’S
    THIRD INT’L DICTIONARY 2283 (1981)—signifies that the
    Exchange the Secretary must establish is the “required
    Exchange” that the state failed to establish. In other words,
    “such” conveys what a federal Exchange is: the equivalent of
    the Exchange a state would have established had it elected to
    do so. The meaning of “Exchange” in the ACA reinforces and
    builds on this sense. The ACA defines an “Exchange” as “an
    American Health Benefit Exchange established under [section
    1311 of the ACA].” 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-91(d)(21). If we
    import that definition into the text of section 1321, the
    17
    provision directs the Secretary to “establish . . . such
    American Health Benefit Exchange established under [section
    1311 of the ACA] within the State.” This suggests not only
    that the Secretary is to establish the type of exchange
    described in section 1311, but also that when she does so, she
    acts under section 1311, even though her authority appears in
    section 1321. Thus, section 1321 creates equivalence between
    state and federal Exchanges in two respects: in terms of what
    they are and the statutory authority under which they are
    established.
    The problem confronting the IRS Rule is that subsidies
    also turn on a third attribute of Exchanges: who established
    them. Under section 36B, subsidies are available only for
    plans “enrolled in through an Exchange established by the
    State under section 1311 of the [ACA].” 26 U.S.C.
    § 36B(c)(2)(A)(i) (emphasis added); see also 
    id. § 36B(b)(2)(A).
    Of the three elements of that provision—
    (1) an Exchange (2) established by the State (3) under section
    1311—federal Exchanges satisfy only two: they are
    Exchanges established under section 1311. Nothing in section
    1321 deems federally-established Exchanges to be
    “Exchange[s] established by the State.” This omission is
    particularly significant since Congress knew how to provide
    that a non-state entity should be treated as if it were a state
    when it sets up an Exchange. In a nearby section, the ACA
    provides that a U.S. territory that “elects . . . to establish an
    Exchange . . . shall be treated as a State.”2 42 U.S.C.
    § 18043(a)(1). The absence of similar language in section
    2
    Specifically, the ACA permits territories to be treated as states
    for the limited purposes of sections 1311, 1312, and 1313. See 42
    U.S.C. § 18043(a).
    18
    1321 suggests that even though the federal government may
    establish an Exchange “within the State,” it does not in fact
    stand in the state’s shoes when doing so. See 
    NFIB, 132 S. Ct. at 2583
    (“Where Congress uses certain language in one part
    of a statute and different language in another, it is generally
    presumed that Congress acts intentionally.” (citing Russello v.
    United States, 
    464 U.S. 16
    , 23 (1983))).
    The dissent attempts to supply this missing equivalency
    by pointing to section 1311(d)(1), which provides: “An
    Exchange shall be a governmental agency or nonprofit entity
    that is established by a State.” 42 U.S.C. § 18031(d)(1).
    According to the dissent, (d)(1) means that an Exchange
    established under section 1311 is, by definition, established
    by a state. Therefore, the dissent argues, because federal
    Exchanges are established under section 1311, they too, by
    definition, are established by a state.
    The premise that (d)(1) is definitional, however, does not
    survive examination of (d)(1)’s context and the ACA’s
    structure. The other provisions of section 1311(d) are
    operational requirements, setting forth what Exchanges must
    (or, in some cases, may) do.3 See generally 42 U.S.C.
    § 18031(d)(2)-(7) (listing “[r]equirements”). Read in keeping
    3
    Although we attach little weight to section titles, the title of
    section 1321(c)—“Failure to establish Exchange or implement
    requirements”—reinforces this interpretation. See Gorman v. Nat’l
    Transp. Safety Bd., 
    558 F.3d 580
    , 588 n.5 (D.C. Cir. 2009)
    (recognizing that “headings ‘are of use . . . when they shed light on
    some ambiguous word or phrase’” (ellipsis in original) (quoting
    Bhd. of R.R. Trainmen v. Balt. & O. R. Co., 
    331 U.S. 519
    , 529
    (1947))).
    19
    with that theme, (d)(1) would simply require that an Exchange
    operate as either a governmental agency or nonprofit entity.
    But the dissent would have us construe (d)(1) differently. In
    its view, (d)(1) plays a definitional role unique among section
    1311(d)’s otherwise operational provisions, creating a legal
    fiction that any Exchange is, by definition, established by a
    state, even when, as a matter of fact, it is not. That reading,
    however, would render (d)(1) the odd man out twice over:
    both within section 1311(d) and among the ACA’s other
    definitional provisions, which, unlike (d)(1), employ the
    (unmistakably definitional) formula of “The term ‘X’ means
    . . . .” See, e.g., 42 U.S.C. §§ 300gg-91, 18024; see also 26
    U.S.C. § 4980H(c).
    The dissent’s reading would also require us to overlook
    the fact that section 1311(d) would be a strange place for
    Congress to have buried such a legal fiction. Section 1311,
    after all, concerns Exchanges that are established by states in
    fact; the legal fiction the dissent urges would matter only to
    Exchanges established by the federal government. To accept
    the dissent’s construction would therefore transform (d)(1)
    into the proverbial elephant in the mousehole—the “ancillary
    provision[]” that “alter[s] the fundamental details of a
    regulatory scheme.” Whitman v. Am. Trucking Ass’ns, 
    531 U.S. 457
    , 468 (2001). The Supreme Court has repeatedly held
    that Congress does not legislate in this manner, see id.; accord
    Gonzales v. Oregon, 
    546 U.S. 243
    , 267 (2006), and we see no
    evidence that it did so here.4 Indeed, we are particularly loath
    4
    The government makes its own elephants-in-mouseholes
    argument, asserting that the formula for calculating tax credits
    (located in section 36B(b)) is an odd place to insert a condition that
    the states must establish their own Exchanges if they wish to secure
    tax credits for their citizens. The more natural location, the
    20
    to accept the dissent’s construction given that there are far
    more natural locations to place this fiction, such as section
    1321 or the provision defining the term “Exchange,” 42
    U.S.C. § 300gg-91(d)(21).
    The dissent’s construction of (d)(1) also ignores the
    structural relationship between sections 1311 and 1321. Just
    as section 1311(b)(1) assumes that states will establish
    Exchanges in general, see 42 U.S.C. § 18031(b)(1), section
    government suggests, would have been section 36B(a), which
    authorizes the credit in the first place. See 26 U.S.C. § 36B(a). But
    even under the government’s reading of section 36B(b), the
    statutory formula houses an elephant: namely, the rule that
    subsidies are only available for plans purchased through
    Exchanges. Given that this other crucial limitation on the
    availability of subsidies is found only in section 36B’s formula, the
    government’s contention that the formula is a mere mousehole is
    unpersuasive.
    Equally unpersuasive is the dissent’s suggestion that section
    36B cannot mean what it plainly says because Congress did not use
    an “if/then” formula to signify that credits are available only on
    state-established Exchanges. The dissent cites no authority for
    requiring such magic words, and we perceive none. Section 36B(b)
    also does not employ an “if/then” construction for the requirement
    that credit-eligible coverage be purchased through an Exchange, yet
    neither the government nor dissent disputes that requirement. It is
    simply not the case that Congress expresses conditions only
    through such language. Indeed, in 26 U.S.C. § 35, which
    establishes a tax credit to offset the cost of health insurance for
    certain workers displaced by foreign competition, Congress made
    the availability of the credit turn, in part, on state cooperation
    without employing “if/then” language, simply through its definition
    of the phrase “eligible coverage month.” See 26 U.S.C.
    § 35(e)(2)(A).
    21
    1311(d) assumes that states will carry out the specific
    requirements Exchanges must meet. But if those assumptions
    prove wrong, section 1321 assigns the federal government
    responsibility both to establish the Exchange and to ensure
    that it satisfies the particulars of section 1311(d). See 
    id. § 18041(c)
    (directing the Secretary to “establish and operate
    such Exchange” and to “take such actions as are necessary to
    implement such other requirements” pertaining to
    Exchanges). In other words, section 1321 creates a limited
    scheme of substitution: the requirements assigned to states by
    1311(d) are transferred to the federal government if a state
    fails to establish an Exchange. The specific requirement that
    (d)(1) assumes each state will fulfill is to establish an
    Exchange in the form of “a governmental agency or nonprofit
    entity.” So if a state elects not to participate in the creation of
    an Exchange, section 1321 directs the federal government that
    it must create “a governmental agency or nonprofit entity” to
    serve as the Exchange. Crucially, this construction does not
    entail ignoring the plain meaning of “established by a State”
    in section 1311(d)(1); here, section 1321 tells us to substitute
    the federal government for the state under a certain scenario.
    But there is nothing comparable with respect to section 36B:
    no analogue to section 1321 says that section 36B should be
    read to encompass federally-established Exchanges.
    Accordingly, we reject the dissent’s argument that, because
    federal Exchanges are established under section 1311, they
    are by definition “established by a State.”
    Instead, sections 1311 and 1321 lead us to interpret
    section 36B essentially as appellants do. Those provisions, to
    be sure, establish some degree of equivalence between state
    and federal Exchanges—enough, indeed, that if section 36B
    had authorized credits for insurance purchased on an
    “Exchange established under section 1311,” the IRS Rule
    would stand. But section 36B actually authorizes credits only
    22
    for coverage purchased on an “Exchange established by the
    State under section 1311,” 26 U.S.C. § 36B(c)(2)(A)(i), and
    the government offers no textual basis—in sections 1311 and
    1321 or elsewhere—for concluding that a federally-
    established Exchange is, in fact or legal fiction, established by
    a state. Moreover, as we have noted, that absence is especially
    glaring given that the ACA elsewhere provides that a federal
    territory that establishes an Exchange “shall be treated as a
    State,” 42 U.S.C. § 18043(a), clearly demonstrating that
    Congress knew how to deem a non-state entity to be a “State.”
    Thus, at least in light of sections 1311 and 1321, the meaning
    of section 36B appears plain: a federal Exchange is not an
    “Exchange established by the State.”
    B
    The government argues that we should not adopt the
    plain meaning of section 36B, however, because doing so
    would render several other provisions of the ACA absurd. Our
    obligation to avoid adopting statutory constructions with
    absurd results is well-established. See Pub. Citizen v. U.S.
    Dep’t of Justice, 
    491 U.S. 440
    , 454-55 (1989). Under this
    principle, we will not give effect to a statute’s literal meaning
    when doing so would “render[ the] statute nonsensical or
    superfluous or . . . create[] an outcome so contrary to
    perceived social values that Congress could not have intended
    it.” United States v. Cook, 
    594 F.3d 883
    , 891 (D.C. Cir. 2010)
    (internal quotation marks omitted). But we do not disregard
    statutory text lightly. The Constitution assigns the legislative
    power to Congress, and Congress alone, see U.S. CONST. art.
    I, § 1, and legislating often entails compromises that courts
    must respect. See Barnhart v. Sigmon Coal Co., 
    534 U.S. 438
    ,
    461 (2002). See generally John F. Manning, The Absurdity
    Doctrine, 116 HARV. L. REV. 2387, 2434-2435 (2003)
    (warning that an overbroad application of the absurdity
    23
    doctrine “contradicts the rule-of-law objectives implicit in the
    Constitution’s strict separation of lawmaking from judging”).
    We therefore give the absurdity principle a narrow domain,
    insisting that a given construction cross a “high threshold” of
    unreasonableness before we conclude that a statute does not
    mean what it says. 
    Cook, 594 F.3d at 891
    . A provision thus
    “may seem odd” without being “absurd,” and in such
    instances “it is up to Congress rather than the courts to fix it,”
    even if it “may have been an unintentional drafting gap.”
    Exxon Mobil Corp. v. Allapattah Servs., Inc., 
    545 U.S. 546
    ,
    565 (2005) (internal quotation marks omitted); see also Sierra
    Club v. EPA, 
    294 F.3d 155
    , 161 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (“Because
    our role is not to ‘correct’ the text so that it better serves the
    statute’s purposes, we will not ratify an interpretation that
    abrogates the enacted statutory text absent an extraordinarily
    convincing justification.” (internal quotation marks and
    citation omitted)).
    i
    The government first argues that we must uphold the IRS
    Rule to avoid rendering language in 26 U.S.C. § 36B(f)
    superfluous. Titled “Reconciliation of credit and advance
    credit,” section 36B(f) requires the IRS to reduce a taxpayer’s
    end-of-year credit by the amount of any advance payments
    made by the government to the taxpayer’s insurer to offset the
    cost of monthly premiums. 
    Id. § 36B(f)(1);
    see 42 U.S.C.
    § 18082(c)(2)(A) (authorizing such advance payments). As
    relevant here, section 36B(f) also requires “each Exchange”—
    i.e., both state and federal Exchanges—to report certain
    information to the government. With respect to any health
    plan it provides, an Exchange must report:
    (A) The level of coverage . . . and the period such
    coverage was in effect.
    24
    (B) The total premium for the coverage without regard to
    the credit under this section or cost-sharing reductions
    under section 1402 of [the ACA].
    (C) The aggregate amount of any advance payment of
    such credit or reductions . . . .
    (D) The name, address, and [taxpayer identification
    number (TIN)] of the primary insured and the name
    and TIN of each other individual obtaining coverage
    under the policy.
    (E) Any information provided to the Exchange, including
    any change of circumstances, necessary to determine
    eligibility for, and the amount of, such credit.
    (F) Information necessary to determine whether a
    taxpayer has received excess advance payments.
    26 U.S.C. § 36B(f)(3). The government contends that these
    reporting requirements assume that credits are available on
    federal Exchanges, and it argues that the requirements would
    be superfluous, even nonsensical, as applied to federal
    Exchanges if we were to reject that assumption.
    Not so. Even if credits are unavailable on federal
    Exchanges, reporting by those Exchanges still serves the
    purpose of enforcing the individual mandate—a point the
    IRS, in fact, acknowledged in promulgating a recent
    regulation, 26 C.F.R. § 1.6055-1(d)(1). That regulation
    exempts insurers from 26 U.S.C. § 6055, which otherwise
    would require that, for each policy they issue, insurers report
    to the IRS such information as “the name, address, and TIN of
    the primary insured,” the dates of coverage, and the “amount
    (if any) or any advance payment . . . or of any premium tax
    credit under section 36B with respect to such coverage.” 26
    U.S.C. § 6055(b)(1)(B). The IRS justified the exemption for
    insurers on the ground that “Exchanges must report on this
    coverage under section 36B(f)(3).” Information Reporting of
    25
    Minimum Essential Coverage, 79 Fed. Reg. 13,220, 13,221
    (Mar. 10, 2014); see 26 C.F.R. § 1.6055-1(d)(1).5 The
    government’s claim that section 36B(f)(3)’s reporting
    requirement serves no purpose other than reconciling credits
    is therefore simply not true.6
    Furthermore, holding that credits are unavailable on
    federal Exchanges would not convert the specific reporting
    requirements concerning credits into an “‘empty gesture.’”
    Gov’t Br. 28 (quoting Fund for Animals, Inc. v. Kempthorne,
    
    472 F.3d 872
    , 878 (D.C. Cir. 2006)). Those requirements
    would still allow the reconciling of credits on state
    Exchanges; as applied to federal Exchanges, they would
    simply be over-inclusive. Over-inclusiveness, however,
    remains a problem even if we were to agree that section 36B
    allows credits on federal Exchanges. Section 36B(f)(3), after
    all, mandates reporting “with respect to any health plan
    provided through the Exchange,” 26 U.S.C. § 36B(f)(3)
    (emphasis added), even though only plans purchased by
    taxpayers with incomes between 100 and 400 percent of the
    federal poverty line may be subsidized, see 
    id. § 36B(a),
    5
    Appellants also suggest that the information collected from
    federal Exchanges could be useful for the “Study on Affordable
    Coverage” mandated by the ACA in that same section. See ACA
    § 1401(c), 124 Stat. at 220.
    6
    The dissent takes a slightly different tack, emphasizing that
    the “principal purpose” of the reporting requirement is to reconcile
    advance and end-of-year payments. Dissenting Op. at 22. We agree
    but fail to see how this helps the government. Reporting by state-
    established Exchanges still would serve this purpose, while
    reporting by federally-established Exchanges would serve the
    secondary purpose implicitly recognized by 26 C.F.R. § 1.6055-
    1(d)(1).
    26
    (c)(1)(A). A weakness common to both views of the
    availability of credits hardly serves as a basis for choosing
    between them.
    ii
    The government next points to the supposedly absurd
    consequences appellants’ interpretation of section 36B would
    have for section 1312 of the ACA, which defines the rights of
    “qualified individuals.” See 42 U.S.C. § 18032. The term
    “‘qualified individual’ means, with respect to an Exchange, an
    individual who— (i) is seeking to enroll in a qualified health
    plan in the individual market offered through the Exchange;
    and (ii) resides in the State that established the Exchange.” 
    Id. § 18032(f)(1)(A).
    If this provision is given its plain meaning,
    then the 36 states with federal Exchanges (that, obviously, the
    states did not establish) have no qualified individuals. That
    outcome is absurd, the government argues, because in its view
    section 1312 restricts access to Exchanges to qualified
    individuals alone. See 45 C.F.R. § 155.20. The absence of
    qualified individuals would mean that federal Exchanges have
    no customers and therefore no purpose. The government
    urges us to avoid this outcome by construing section 1321 to
    authorize the federal government to establish Exchanges “on
    behalf of” states that decline to do so. Gov’t Br. 21 (internal
    quotation marks omitted).
    The government, however, tilts at windmills. It assumes
    that when section 1312(a) states that “[a] qualified individual
    may enroll in any qualified health plan available to such
    individual and for which such individual is eligible,” 42
    U.S.C. § 18032(a)(1), it means that only a qualified individual
    may enroll in such a plan. The obvious flaw in this
    interpretation is that the word “only” does not appear in the
    provision. We have repeatedly emphasized that it is “not our
    27
    role” to “engage in a statutory rewrite” by “insert[ing] the
    word ‘only’ here and there.” Adirondack Med. Ctr. v.
    Sebelius, 
    740 F.3d 692
    , 699-700 (D.C. Cir. 2014); see Lamie
    v. U.S. Tr., 
    540 U.S. 526
    , 538 (2004) (rejecting an
    interpretation that “would have [the Court] read an absent
    word into the statute” because such an interpretation “would
    result ‘not [in] a construction of [the] statute, but, in effect, an
    enlargement of it by the court’” (second and third alterations
    in original) (quoting Iselin v. United States, 
    270 U.S. 245
    , 251
    (1926))); Pub. 
    Citizen, 533 F.3d at 817
    (“Congress knows
    well how to say that disclosures may be made only under
    specified provisions or circumstances, but it did not do so
    here.” (footnote omitted)). Section 1312(a)’s actual language
    simply establishes the right of a qualified individual to enroll
    in any qualified health plan, at any level of coverage.7 On this
    reading, giving the phrase “established by the State” its plain
    meaning creates no difficulty, let alone absurdity. Federal
    Exchanges might not have qualified individuals, but they
    would still have customers—namely, individuals who are not
    “qualified individuals.”8
    7
    Under the ACA, qualified health plans may offer four
    different levels of coverage: bronze, silver, gold, and platinum. The
    level of coverage reflects the percentage of the insured’s medical
    costs that the plan’s benefits are designed to cover. See 42 U.S.C.
    § 18022(d)(1). Lower levels of coverage have higher deductibles
    and thus higher out-of-pocket costs and, as a general matter, lower
    premiums. See id.; see also 
    id. § 18032(a)(2)
    (providing that
    qualified employers may “select[] any level of coverage under
    section 18022(d) . . . to be made available to employees through an
    Exchange”).
    8
    The government warns that interpreting section 1312(a) as a
    non-discrimination provision would allow undocumented aliens to
    shop on Exchanges. Gov’t Br. at 31. But section 1312 specifically
    28
    Several other provisions in section 1312 imply that not
    only “qualified individuals” may participate in an Exchange.
    Take, for example, the provision concerning incarcerated
    convicts. Section 1312(f)(1)(B) states that “[a]n individual
    shall not be treated as a qualified individual if, at the time of
    enrollment, the individual is incarcerated, other than
    incarceration pending the disposition of charges.” 42 U.S.C.
    § 18032(f)(1)(B) (emphasis added). By implying that an
    incarcerated convict may enroll in coverage through an
    Exchange despite not being a “qualified individual,” this
    provision suggests that participation in an Exchange does not
    depend on “qualified individual” status. That proposition
    gains further strength from section 1312(d)(3), which states,
    first, that “[n]othing in this title shall be construed to restrict
    the choice of a qualified individual to enroll or not to enroll in
    a qualified health plan or to participate in an Exchange,” 42
    U.S.C. § 18032(d)(3)(A), and, second, that “[n]othing in this
    title shall be construed to compel an individual to enroll in a
    qualified health plan or to participate in an Exchange,” 
    id. § 18032(d)(3)(B).
    The second provision, which speaks of
    “individual[s]” generally, would be wholly unnecessary if
    only “qualified individuals” were eligible to participate in the
    Exchanges.9
    addresses that concern, providing that aliens not “lawfully present
    in the United States . . . may not be covered under a qualified health
    plan in the individual market that is offered through an Exchange.”
    42 U.S.C. § 18032(f)(3).
    9
    We note that section 1312’s heading, “Consumer Choice,”
    and subsection 1312(a)’s heading, “Choice,” also suggest that the
    purpose of section 1312(a) is primarily to protect choice among
    levels of coverage, not restrict access to Exchanges.
    29
    iii
    The government also claims that a plain meaning reading
    of section 36B would have peculiar effects under 42 U.S.C.
    § 1396a(gg)(1). That provision states that, as a condition of
    receiving Medicaid funds, a State may not tighten its
    Medicaid eligibility standards for adults until “the date on
    which the Secretary determines that an Exchange established
    by the State under [section 1311] is fully operational.” 42
    U.S.C. § 1396a(gg)(1). If a federally-established Exchange is
    not one “established by the State,” the government argues,
    states with federal Exchanges “would never be relieved of
    th[is] . . . requirement,” transforming an “interim measure”
    into a “perpetual obligation.” Gov’t Br. at 33. But appellants
    propose a logical explanation for why the ACA might
    establish this rule: to preserve Medicaid benefits for the
    impoverished residents of states where, as a result of having
    federally-established Exchanges, subsidies are unavailable.
    Cf. Pub. 
    Citizen, 533 F.3d at 817
    (adopting a reasonable
    explanation of a provision’s purpose despite not being able to
    “know for certain what purpose Congress had in mind”). In
    this light, the results produced by giving section 36B its plain
    meaning seem sensible, not absurd.10
    10
    In a footnote, the government identifies another set of
    provisions that supposedly embodies the assumption that federal
    Exchanges are Exchanges “established by the State”: 42 U.S.C.
    § 1397ee(d)(3)(B)-(C). Those provisions instruct states to enroll
    children in coverage “offered through an Exchange established by
    the State under section [1311]” in the event of a funding shortfall in
    a state’s Children’s Health Insurance Program. See 
    id. § 1397ee(d)(3)(B).
    Although we recognize the oddity of requiring
    some states and not others to take this step, we do not see how it
    makes the statute nonsensical or otherwise meets the high threshold
    30
    iv
    The government urges us, in effect, to strike from section
    36B the phrase “established by the State,” on the ground that
    giving force to its plain meaning renders other provisions of
    the Act absurd. But we find that the government has failed to
    make the extraordinary showing required for such judicial
    rewriting of an act of Congress. Nothing about the imperative
    to read section 36B in harmony with the rest of the ACA
    requires interpreting “established by the State” to mean
    anything other than what it plainly says.
    C
    This conclusion places us at a fork in our precedent. One
    line of cases instructs us to cease our inquiry and give effect
    to the statute’s unambiguous language. See Coal. for
    Responsible Regulation, Inc. v. EPA, 
    684 F.3d 102
    , 137 (D.C.
    Cir. 2012) (per curiam) (noting, in the Chevron context, that
    “‘[w]hen the words of a statute are unambiguous . . . judicial
    inquiry is complete’” (ellipsis in original) (quoting Conn.
    Nat’l Bank v. Germain, 
    503 U.S. 249
    , 254 (1992)), aff’d in
    relevant part sub nom. Util. Air Regulatory Grp. v. EPA
    (UARG), 
    134 S. Ct. 2427
    , 2448 (2014); accord Dep’t of
    Housing & Urban Dev. v. Rucker, 
    535 U.S. 125
    , 132-33
    (2002); Hughes Aircraft Co. v. Jacobson, 
    525 U.S. 432
    , 438
    (1999) (“As in any case of statutory construction, our analysis
    of absurdity. The statute remains workable, and nothing suggests
    that in states with federal Exchanges, the federal government could
    not step in and perform the same service for uninsured children.
    The government’s bare citation to the provisions thus hardly
    demonstrates absurdity.
    31
    begins with the language of the statute. And where the
    statutory language provides a clear answer, it ends there as
    well.” (emphasis added) (internal quotation marks and citation
    omitted)); see also Am. Fed’n of Gov’t Emps. v. Shinseki, 
    709 F.3d 29
    , 33 (D.C. Cir. 2013). Another tells us to wade into the
    legislative history in the hope of glimpsing “new light on
    congressional intent.” Sierra Club v. EPA, 
    551 F.3d 1019
    ,
    1027 (D.C. Cir. 2008). But, though we recognize that our
    decision about which path to travel implicates substantial
    theoretical questions of statutory interpretation, its practical
    consequences are less momentous here because both paths
    lead to the same destination. Therefore, assuming arguendo
    that it is proper to consult legislative history when the
    statutory text is clear, we consider what light the ACA’s
    history offers.
    We begin by clarifying the role the ACA’s legislative
    history might play in our analysis. Legislative history is a
    means to an end, to be consulted for evidence of
    congressional intent. See, e.g., Sierra 
    Club, 551 F.3d at 1027
    .
    But legislative history is not the sole, or even the primary,
    source of such evidence. Rather, “[t]he most reliable guide to
    congressional intent is the legislation the Congress enacted.”
    Sierra 
    Club, 294 F.3d at 161
    ; see also Cal. Indep. Sys.
    Operator Corp. v. FERC, 
    372 F.3d 395
    , 400 (D.C. Cir. 2004)
    (“[W]e assume ‘that the legislative purpose is expressed by
    the ordinary meaning of the words used.’” (quoting Sec.
    Indus. Ass’n v. Bd. of Governors of Fed. Reserve Sys., 
    468 U.S. 137
    , 149 (1984))); Engine Mfrs. 
    Ass’n, 88 F.3d at 1088
    (noting that the “most traditional tool” for “determin[ing]
    Congressional intent” is “to read the text”). Where used,
    legislative history plays a distinctly secondary role. Its
    purpose is not to confirm already clear text; clear text speaks
    for itself and requires no “amen” in the historical record. See,
    e.g., Harrison v. PPG Indus., Inc., 
    446 U.S. 578
    , 592 (1980)
    32
    (“[I]t would be a strange canon of statutory construction that
    would require Congress to state in committee reports or
    elsewhere in its deliberations that which is obvious on the
    face of a statute.”). Instead, only when “apparently plain
    language compels an ‘odd result’” might we look to
    legislative history to ensure that the “‘literal application of a
    statute will [not] produce a result demonstrably at odds with
    the intentions of its drafters.’” Engine Mfrs. 
    Ass’n, 88 F.3d at 1088
    (quoting Public 
    Citizen, 491 U.S. at 454
    , and United
    States v. Ron Pair Enters., Inc., 
    489 U.S. 235
    , 242 (1989)).
    Thus, accepting for the sake of argument the government’s
    contention that the results of appellants’ construction of
    section 36B are odd, our inquiry into the ACA’s legislative
    history is quite narrow. In the face of the statute’s plain
    meaning—a federal Exchange is not an “Exchange
    established by the State”—we ask only whether the legislative
    history provides evidence that this literal meaning is
    “demonstrably at odds with the intentions” of the ACA’s
    drafters. Unless evidence in the legislative record establishes
    that it is, we must hew to the statute’s plain meaning, even if
    it compels an odd result. See 
    id. (“[T]here must
    be evidence
    that Congress meant something other than what it literally
    said before a court can depart from plain meaning.”); accord
    Garcia v. United States, 
    469 U.S. 70
    , 75 (1984) (noting that
    “only the most extraordinary showing of contrary intentions
    . . . would justify a limitation on the ‘plain meaning’ of the
    statutory language”); Bldg. & Constr. Trades Dep’t, AFL-CIO
    v. U.S. Dep’t of Labor Wage Appeals Bd., 
    932 F.2d 985
    , 990
    (D.C. Cir. 1991).
    Here, the scant legislative history sheds little light on the
    precise question of the availability of subsidies on federal
    Exchanges. The government points, for example, to a
    Congressional Budget Office report from November 2009,
    before the ACA’s adoption, that calculated the cost of
    33
    subsidies based on the assumption that they would be
    available in all states. But that assumption is as consistent
    with an expectation that all states would cooperate (i.e.,
    establish their own Exchanges) as with an understanding that
    subsidies would be available on federal Exchanges as well.
    Cf. Robert Pear, U.S. Officials Brace for Huge Task of
    Operating Health Exchanges, N.Y. TIMES, at A17 (Aug. 5,
    2012) (“When Congress passed legislation to expand
    coverage two years ago, Mr. Obama and lawmakers assumed
    that every state would set up its own exchange . . . .”). Equally
    unilluminating are floor statements by Senate sponsors of the
    ACA touting the availability and benefits of premium tax
    credits in general, but not addressing the precise issue of
    whether they would be available on federal Exchanges.
    The government and its amici are thus left to urge the
    court to infer meaning from silence, arguing that “during the
    debates over the ACA, no one suggested, let alone explicitly
    stated, that a State’s citizens would lose access to the tax
    credits if the State failed to establish its own Exchange.” Br.
    of Amici Members of Congress and State Legislatures 8. The
    historical record, however, belies this claim. The Senate
    Committee on Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions
    (HELP) proposed a bill that specifically contemplated
    penalizing states that refused to participate in establishing
    “American Health Benefit Gateways,” the equivalent of
    Exchanges, by denying credits to such states’ residents for
    four years. See Affordable Health Choices Act, S. 1679, 111th
    Cong. § 3104(a), (d)(2) (2009). This is not to say that section
    36B necessarily incorporated this thinking; we agree that
    inferences from unenacted legislation are too uncertain to be a
    helpful guide to the intent behind a specific provision. See
    Village of Barrington v. Surface Transp. Bd., 
    636 F.3d 650
    ,
    666 (D.C. Cir. 2011). But the HELP Committee’s bill
    certainly demonstrates that members of Congress at least
    34
    considered the notion of using subsidies as an incentive to
    gain states’ cooperation.
    In any case, even if the historical record were silent, that
    silence is unhelpful to the government. For the court to depart
    from the ACA’s plain meaning, which favors appellants,
    “there must be evidence that Congress meant something other
    than what it literally said,” from which the court can conclude
    that applying the statute literally would be “‘demonstrably at
    odds with the intentions of [the ACA’s] drafters.’” Engine
    Mfrs. 
    Ass’n, 88 F.3d at 1088
    (quoting Ron Pair 
    Enters., 489 U.S. at 242
    ) (emphases added). As Chief Justice Marshall
    wrote, “it is incumbent on those who oppose” a statute’s plain
    meaning “to shew an intent varying from that which the
    words import.” United States v. Fisher, 6 U.S. (2 Cranch)
    358, 386 (1805). Nothing the government or its amici cite
    demonstrates what that precise intent was. And “[i]n the
    absence of such evidence, the court cannot ignore the text by
    assuming that if the statute seems odd to us, i.e., the statute is
    not as we would have predicted beforehand that Congress
    would write it, it could be the product only of oversight,
    imprecision, or drafting error.” Engine Mfrs. 
    Ass’n, 88 F.3d at 1088
    -89; see also 
    id. at 1091
    (“With such a meager record of
    what happened in conference, the court is unable to
    reconstruct the legislative compromises that were made. Even
    if the final product might strike us as unexpected . . . the court
    could not make the leap from such an impression to the
    certainty that such a result was unintentional.”).
    The government, together with the dissent, also leans
    heavily on a more abstract form of legislative history—
    Congress’s broad purpose in passing the ACA—urging the
    court to view section 36B through the lens of the ACA’s
    economic theory and ultimate aims. They emphasize that to
    achieve the goals of “near universal coverage” and
    35
    “lower[ing] health insurance premiums,” 42 U.S.C.
    § 18091(2)(D), (F), the ACA relies on three interrelated
    policies: insurance market reforms prohibiting insurers from
    denying coverage or charging higher premiums based on an
    individual’s health status, see, e.g., 
    id. § 300gg
    (community
    rating requirement); 
    id. § 300gg
    -1 (guaranteed issue
    requirement); the individual mandate, see 26 U.S.C. § 5000A;
    and subsidies to individuals purchasing insurance in the
    individual market, see 
    id. § 36B.
    These policies, the
    government and dissent explain, are like the legs of a three-
    legged stool; remove any one, and the ACA will collapse. The
    insurance market reforms are necessary to expand the
    availability of insurance. The individual mandate is necessary
    to avoid the adverse selection that would result if people
    could exploit the insurance market reforms to wait to
    purchase insurance until they were sick. And subsidies are
    necessary both to make the mandated insurance affordable
    and, in so doing, to expand the reach of the individual
    mandate by reducing the cost of insurance below the
    threshold—eight percent of household income—at which
    taxpayers are exempt from the mandate’s penalty. See 26
    U.S.C. § 5000A(e)(1)(A)-(B). Given this structure, the
    government and dissent argue that it is “inconceivable” to
    think Congress would have risked the ACA’s stability by
    making subsidies conditional on states establishing
    Exchanges.11 Dissenting Op. at 2.
    11
    Appellants do not challenge the government’s account of the
    economic theory behind the ACA, but they contend that the theory
    must be understood through the lens of political reality. In their
    telling, section 36B is the product of legislative compromise to
    secure the support of Nebraska Senator Ben Nelson, the crucial
    sixtieth vote needed to avoid a filibuster. Nelson opposed House
    plans for a national, federally-run exchange, fearing that it would
    36
    set the United States down a path to a single-payer system. See
    Carrie Budoff Brown, Nelson: National Exchange a Dealbreaker,
    POLITICO (Jan. 25, 2010), http://www.politico.com/livepulse/0110/
    Nelson_National_exchange_a_dealbreaker.html. To gain Nelson’s
    support, proponents of the ACA scrapped the national exchange in
    favor of establishing exchanges on a state-by-state basis. This
    change, in turn, required Congress to devise means of inducing
    states to take on the politically and technologically challenging task
    of establishing exchanges. Congress’s solution, appellants maintain,
    was a package of “carrots” and “sticks” for states. The carrots
    included federal grants to states for “activities (including planning
    activities) related to establishing an [Exchange].” 42 U.S.C.
    § 18031(a)(3). The sticks included the prohibition against
    tightening Medicaid eligibility requirements imposed on states that
    do not create their own Exchanges. See 
    id. § 1396a(gg).
    The most
    important incentive of all, appellants argue, was the provision at
    issue here: making premium tax credits available only for
    individual coverage purchased through state-established Exchanges.
    According to appellants, the ACA’s supporters believed no state
    would refuse so good an offer—and, appellants add, perhaps no
    state would have had the IRS not eliminated this incentive by
    proposing and promulgating the IRS Rule, making subsidies
    available regardless of which entity established an Exchange,
    before states had to elect whether to establish Exchanges. See
    Health Insurance Premium Tax Credit, 77 Fed. Reg. 30,377, 30,378
    (May 23, 2012); Health Insurance Premium Tax Credit, 76 Fed.
    Reg. 50,931, 50,934 (Aug. 17, 2011).
    Like the government, however, appellants fail to marshal
    persuasive evidence (apart from the statutory text, that is) in
    support of their theory. Senator Nelson may have opposed a single,
    national exchange, but it does not necessarily follow that he
    opposed making subsidies available on federal fallback Exchanges
    in uncooperative states. Similarly, the fact that the ACA contained
    some incentives to states does not necessarily mean that section
    36B is one of them. Nor does the fact that Congress has conditioned
    federal benefits on state cooperation in other contexts shed light on
    37
    Yet the supposedly unthinkable scenario the government
    and dissent describe—one in which insurers in states with
    federal Exchanges remain subject to the community rating
    and guaranteed issue requirements but lack a broad base of
    healthy customers to stabilize prices and avoid adverse
    selection—is exactly what the ACA enacts in such federal
    territories as the Northern Mariana Islands, where the Act
    imposes guaranteed issue and community rating requirements
    without an individual mandate. See 26 U.S.C. § 5000A(f)(4)
    (exempting residents of such federal territories as Puerto Rico
    and the Northern Mariana Islands from the individual
    mandate by providing that they are automatically treated as
    having “minimum essential coverage”); 42 U.S.C. § 201(f)
    (providing that the Public Health Service Act, where the
    guaranteed issue and community rating requirements appear,
    applies to residents of such territories). This combination,
    predictably, has thrown individual insurance markets in the
    territories into turmoil. See Sarah Kliff, Think Your State Has
    Obamacare Problems? They’re Nothing Compared to Guam,
    WASH.             POST         (Dec.          19,        2013),
    http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2013/12
    /19/think-your-state-has-obamacare-problems-theyre-nothing-
    compared-to-guam/. But HHS has nevertheless refused to
    exempt the territories from the guaranteed issue and
    the precise question of whether Congress did so in section 36B.
    Thus, the most that can be said of appellants’ theory is that it is
    plausible. But we need not endorse appellants’ historical account to
    agree with their construction of section 36B. “Where the statutory
    language is clear and unambiguous, we need neither accept nor
    reject a particular ‘plausible’ explanation for why Congress would
    have written a statute [as it did].” 
    Barnhart, 534 U.S. at 460
    .
    38
    community rating requirements, recognizing that, “[h]owever
    meritorious” the reasons for doing so might be, “HHS is not
    authorized to choose which provisions of the [ACA] might
    apply to the territories.” Letter from Gary Cohen, Director,
    Center for Consumer Information and Insurance Oversight,
    HHS, to Sixto K. Igisomar, Secretary of Commerce,
    Commonwealth of the Northern Mariana Islands (July 12,
    2013), available at http://www.doi.gov/oia/igia/upload/12-3-
    HHS-CMS-CNMI-Letter-igisomar7-12-13.pdf.
    Moreover, the territories are not the only instance where
    the ACA did the unimaginable. A separate title of the ACA,
    known as the Community Living Assistance Services and
    Supports (CLASS) Act, see ACA, Pub. L. No. 111-148,
    §§ 8001-8002, 124 Stat. 119, 828-47 (2010), required the
    Secretary of HHS to establish a long-term care insurance
    program subject to guaranteed issue and community rating
    requirements but unaided by an individual mandate or
    premium subsidies, see 124 Stat. at 834. This recipe for
    adverse selection risk never materialized only because
    Congress, in response to actuarial analyses predicting that the
    CLASS Act would be fiscally unsustainable, repealed the
    provision in 2013.12 See American Taxpayer Relief Act of
    12
    The dissent attempts to distinguish the market targeted by the
    CLASS Act from the individual insurance market by pointing out
    that the CLASS Act contains no individual mandate. In the
    dissent’s view, the omission “of a tool [Congress] knew to be
    important to preventing adverse selection merely indicates that
    Congress had a substantially higher tolerance for the risk of adverse
    selection” in peripheral markets than in the core market. Dissenting
    Op. at 19. This argument, however, assumes the very conclusion at
    issue, taking for granted that the mandate in the individual market
    indeed is as broad as it must be to eliminate all adverse selection
    risk. But the plain language of section 36B suggests that it is not. If
    39
    2012, Pub. L. No. 112-240, § 642, 126 Stat. 2313, 2358
    (2013); Sarah Kliff, The Fiscal Cliff Cuts $1.9 Billion from
    Obamacare. Here’s How, WASH. POST (Jan. 2, 2013),
    http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2013/01
    /02/the-fiscal-cliff-cuts-1-9-billion-from-obamacare-heres-
    how/.
    The CLASS Act and the provisions applicable to the
    territories attest that Congress twice did exactly what the
    government and the dissent insist it never would: introduce
    significant adverse selection risk to insurance markets. This is
    not to say that as Congress did in the CLASS Act and
    territories, so too must it have done in section 36B; perhaps
    Congress was willing to tolerate risks in those corners of the
    insurance market that it never would tolerate at its core. But
    perhaps not. The point is that we don’t know, and in asking us
    to ignore the best evidence of Congress’s intent—the text of
    section 36B—in favor of assumptions about the risks that
    Congress would or would not tolerate—assumptions
    section 36B limits the availability of subsidies and thus curtails the
    reach of the individual mandate, this is evidence that Congress was
    tolerant of adverse selection risk in the core markets, although
    Congress might not have expected the risk to materialize.
    We recognize that, from an economic standpoint, such adverse
    selection risk bodes ill for individual insurance markets. But it
    made no more sense economically in the CLASS Act. Congress
    may simply have miscalculated the consequences of omitting a
    mandate, as its decision to repeal the CLASS Act suggests. In any
    event, whether by error or design, the CLASS Act in clear terms
    created a significant adverse selection risk, which, as Congress and
    the government recognized, could be undone only by subsequent
    legislation, not administrative fiat. Cf. 
    UARG, 134 S. Ct. at 2445
    (“An agency has no power to ‘tailor’ legislation to bureaucratic
    policy goals by rewriting unambiguous statutory terms.”).
    40
    doubtlessly influenced by hindsight—the government and
    dissent in effect urge us to substitute our judgment for
    Congress’s. We refuse. As the Supreme Court explained just
    this term, “an agency may not rewrite clear statutory terms to
    suit its own sense of how the statute should operate.” 
    UARG, 134 S. Ct. at 2446
    . And neither may we. “The role of th[e]
    [c]ourt is to apply the statute as it is written—even if we think
    some other approach might ‘accor[d] with good policy.’”
    Burrage v. United States, 
    134 S. Ct. 881
    , 892 (2014) (quoting
    Comm’r v. Lundy, 51
    6 U.S. 2
    35, 252 (1996)) (third alteration
    in original); see also Lewis v. City of Chicago, 
    560 U.S. 205
    ,
    217 (2010) (“[I]t is not our task to assess the consequences of
    each approach [to interpreting a statute] and adopt the one that
    produces the least mischief. Our charge is to give effect to the
    law Congress enacted.”); United States v. Locke, 
    471 U.S. 84
    ,
    95 (1985) (“[T]he fact that Congress might have acted with
    greater clarity or foresight does not give courts a carte blanche
    to redraft statutes in an effort to achieve that which Congress
    is perceived to have failed to do.”).
    More generally, the ACA’s ultimate aims shed little light
    on the “precise question at issue,” 
    Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842
    —
    namely, whether subsidies are available on federal Exchanges
    because such Exchanges are “established by the State.” As the
    Supreme Court has repeatedly warned, “it frustrates rather
    than effectuates legislative intent simplistically to assume that
    whatever furthers the statute’s primary objective must be the
    law” because “no legislation pursues its purposes at all costs.”
    Rodriguez v. United States, 
    480 U.S. 522
    , 525-26 (1987) (per
    curiam); see also Pension Benefit Guar. Corp. v. LTV Corp.,
    
    496 U.S. 633
    , 646-47 (1990); MetroPCS Cal., LLC v. FCC,
    
    644 F.3d 410
    , 414 (D.C. Cir. 2011) (“‘The Act must do
    everything necessary to achieve its broad purpose’ is the
    slogan of the enthusiast, not the analytical tool of the
    arbiter.”). Thus, if legislative intent is to be our lodestar, we
    41
    cannot assume, as the government does, that section 36B
    single-mindedly pursues the ACA’s lofty goals.
    The fact is that the legislative record provides little
    indication one way or the other of congressional intent, but
    the statutory text does. Section 36B plainly makes subsidies
    available only on Exchanges established by states. And in the
    absence of any contrary indications, that text is conclusive
    evidence of Congress’s intent. Cf. Ethyl Corp. v. EPA, 
    51 F.3d 1053
    , 1063 (D.C. Cir. 1995) (“At best, the legislative
    history is cryptic, and this surely is not enough to overcome
    the plain meaning of the statute.”). To hold otherwise would
    be to say that enacted legislation, on its own, does not
    command our respect—an utterly untenable proposition.
    Accordingly, applying the statute’s plain meaning, we find
    that section 36B unambiguously forecloses the interpretation
    embodied in the IRS Rule and instead limits the availability of
    premium tax credits to state-established Exchanges.
    IV
    We reach this conclusion, frankly, with reluctance. At
    least until states that wish to can set up Exchanges, our ruling
    will likely have significant consequences both for the millions
    of individuals receiving tax credits through federal Exchanges
    and for health insurance markets more broadly. But, high as
    those stakes are, the principle of legislative supremacy that
    guides us is higher still. Within constitutional limits, Congress
    is supreme in matters of policy, and the consequence of that
    supremacy is that our duty when interpreting a statute is to
    ascertain the meaning of the words of the statute duly enacted
    through the formal legislative process. This limited role
    serves democratic interests by ensuring that policy is made by
    elected, politically accountable representatives, not by
    appointed, life-tenured judges.
    42
    Thus, although our decision has major consequences, our
    role is quite limited: deciding whether the IRS Rule is a
    permissible reading of the ACA. Having concluded it is not,
    we reverse the district court and remand with instructions to
    grant summary judgment to appellants and vacate the IRS
    Rule.
    RANDOLPH, Senior Circuit Judge, concurring: A Supreme
    Court tax decision, and a tax decision of this court, flatly reject
    the position the government takes in this case.
    As Judge Griffith’s majority opinion—which I fully
    join—demonstrates, an Exchange established by the federal
    government cannot possibly be “an Exchange established by the
    State.” To hold otherwise would be to engage in distortion, not
    interpretation. Only further legislation could accomplish the
    expansion the government seeks.
    In the meantime, Justice Brandeis’ opinion for the Supreme
    Court in Iselin v. United States is controlling: “What the
    government asks is not a construction of a statute, but, in effect,
    an enlargement of it by the court, so that what was omitted,
    presumably by inadvertence, may be included within its scope.
    To supply omissions transcends the judicial function.” 
    270 U.S. 245
    , 251 (1926). We held the same in National Railroad
    Passenger Corp. v. United States, 
    431 F.3d 374
    , 378 (D.C. Cir.
    2005), citing not only Iselin but also Lamie v. United States
    Trustee, 
    540 U.S. 526
    , 538 (2004), which reaffirmed Iselin’s
    “longstanding” interpretative principle.
    EDWARDS, Senior Circuit Judge, dissenting: This case is
    about Appellants’ not-so-veiled attempt to gut the Patient
    Protection and Affordable Care Act (“ACA”). The ACA
    requires every State to establish a health insurance
    “Exchange,” which “shall be a governmental agency or
    nonprofit entity that is established by a State.” 42 U.S.C.
    § 18031(b)(1), (d)(1). The Department of Health and Human
    Services (“HHS”) is required to establish “such Exchange”
    when the State elects not to create one. 
    Id. § 18041(c)(1)
    .
    Taxpayers who purchase insurance from an Exchange and
    whose income is between 100% and 400% of the poverty line
    are eligible for premium subsidies. 26 U.S.C. § 36B(a),
    (c)(1)(A). Appellants challenge regulations issued by the
    Internal Revenue Service (“IRS”) and HHS making these
    subsidies available in all States, including States in which
    HHS has established an Exchange on behalf of the State. In
    support of their challenge, Appellants rely on a specious
    argument that there is no “Exchange established by the State”
    in States with HHS-created Exchanges and, therefore, that
    taxpayers who purchase insurance in these States cannot
    receive subsidies.
    As explained below, there are three critical components to
    the ACA: nondiscrimination requirements applying to
    insurers; the “individual mandate” requiring individuals who
    are not covered by an employer to purchase minimum
    insurance coverage or to pay a tax penalty; and premium
    subsidies which ensure that the individual mandate will have a
    broad enough sweep to attract enough healthy individuals into
    the individual insurance markets to create stability. These
    components work in tandem. At the time of the ACA’s
    enactment, it was well understood that without the subsidies,
    the individual mandate was not viable as a mechanism for
    creating a stable insurance market.
    Appellants’ proffered construction of the statute would
    permit States to exempt many people from the individual
    2
    mandate and thereby thwart a central element of the ACA. As
    Appellants’ amici candidly acknowledge, if subsidies are
    unavailable to taxpayers in States with HHS-created
    Exchanges, “the structure of the ACA will crumble.” Scott
    Pruitt, ObamaCare’s Next Legal Challenge, WALL ST. J.,
    Dec. 1, 2013. It is inconceivable that Congress intended to
    give States the power to cause the ACA to “crumble.”
    Appellants contend that the phrase “Exchange established
    by the State” in § 36B unambiguously bars subsidies to
    individuals who purchase insurance in States in which HHS
    created the Exchange on the State’s behalf. This argument
    fails because “the words of a statute must be read in their
    context and with a view to their place in the overall statutory
    scheme.” Nat’l Ass’n of Home Builders v. Defenders of
    Wildlife, 
    551 U.S. 644
    , 666 (2007) (internal quotation marks
    omitted). When the language of § 36B is viewed in context –
    i.e., in conjunction with other provisions of the ACA – it is
    quite clear that the statute does not reveal the plain meaning
    that Appellants would like to find.
    Because IRS and HHS have been delegated authority to
    jointly administer the ACA, this case is governed by the
    familiar framework of Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural
    Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    (1984). Under
    Chevron, if “the statute is silent or ambiguous with respect to
    the specific issue,” we defer to the agency’s construction of
    the statute, so long as it is “permissible.” 
    Id. at 843.
    The
    Government’s permissible interpretation of the statute easily
    survives review under Chevron. The Act contemplates that an
    Exchange created by the federal government on a State’s
    behalf will have equivalent legal standing with State-created
    Exchanges. 42 U.S.C. § 18041. And the ACA would be self-
    defeating if taxpayers who purchase insurance from an HHS-
    created Exchange are deemed ineligible to receive subsidies.
    3
    Appellants’ argument cannot be squared with the clear
    legislative scheme established by the statute as a whole.
    Apparently recognizing the weakness of a claim that rests
    solely on § 36B, divorced from the rest of the ACA,
    Appellants attempt to fortify their position with the
    extraordinary argument that Congress tied the availability of
    subsidies to the existence of State-established Exchanges to
    encourage States to establish their own Exchanges. This claim
    is nonsense, made up out of whole cloth. There is no credible
    evidence in the record that Congress intended to condition
    subsidies on whether a State, as opposed to HHS, established
    the Exchange. Nor is there credible evidence that any State
    even considered the possibility that its taxpayers would be
    denied subsidies if the State opted to allow HHS to establish
    an Exchange on its behalf.
    The majority opinion ignores the obvious ambiguity in the
    statute and claims to rest on plain meaning where there is none
    to be found. In so doing, the majority misapplies the
    applicable standard of review, refuses to give deference to the
    IRS’s and HHS’s permissible constructions of the ACA, and
    issues a judgment that portends disastrous consequences. I
    therefore dissent.
    I.   STANDARD OF REVIEW
    The first question a reviewing court must ask in a case of
    this sort is whether the disputed provisions of the statute are
    clear beyond dispute. “If a court, employing traditional tools
    of statutory construction, ascertains that Congress had an
    intention on the precise question at issue, that intention is the
    law and must be given effect.” 
    Chevron, 467 U.S. at 843
    n.9.
    In determining whether a statutory provision is ambiguous,
    4
    however, a court must evaluate it within the context of the
    statute as a whole:
    [A] reviewing court should not confine itself to
    examining a particular statutory provision in isolation.
    Rather, the meaning – or ambiguity – of certain words or
    phrases may only become evident when placed in context.
    . . . It is a fundamental canon of statutory construction
    that the words of a statute must be read in their context
    and with a view to their place in the overall statutory
    scheme.
    Nat’l Ass’n of Home 
    Builders, 551 U.S. at 666
    (citations,
    alteration, and internal quotation marks omitted); see also
    FDA v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    529 U.S. 120
    ,
    132-33 (2000); Davis v. Mich. Dep’t of Treasury, 
    489 U.S. 803
    , 809 (1989).
    In other words, “[t]he plainness or ambiguity of statutory
    language is determined by reference to the language itself, the
    specific context in which that language is used, and the
    broader context of the statute as a whole.” Robinson v. Shell
    Oil Co., 
    519 U.S. 337
    , 341 (1997). The Supreme Court just
    recently reiterated this principle, making it clear that even
    when a statute is not “a chef d’oeuvre of legislative
    draftsmanship” – as the ACA is not – courts must bear “in
    mind the fundamental canon of statutory construction that the
    words of a statute must be read in their context and with a
    view to their place in the overall statutory scheme.” Util. Air
    Regulatory Grp. v. EPA, No. 12-1146, 
    2014 WL 2807314
    , at
    *9 (June 23, 2014) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    When a “court determines Congress has not directly
    addressed the precise question at issue, the court does not
    simply impose its own construction on the statute.” Chevron,
    
    5 467 U.S. at 843
    . Rather, “the question for the court is whether
    the agency’s answer is based on a permissible construction of
    the statute,” 
    id., that is,
    whether the agency’s interpretation is
    “manifestly contrary to the statute,” 
    id. at 844.
    See, e.g., Mayo
    Found. for Med. Educ. & Research v. United States, 
    131 S. Ct. 704
    , 711 (2011) (deferring to the agency’s interpretation
    because the statute did not speak with “the precision
    necessary” to definitively answer the question, and the
    agency’s interpretation was not “manifestly contrary to the
    statute”).
    Appellants argue that Chevron deference is unwarranted
    because some of the provisions at issue “are codified in a
    chapter of Title 42 . . . the domain of HHS, not the IRS,” and
    the “IRS has no power to enforce or administer those
    provisions.” Br. for Appellants at 46. Appellants’ position is
    mistaken. Chevron applies because IRS and HHS are tasked
    with administering the provisions of the ACA in coordination.
    See 42 U.S.C. § 18082(a); Nat’l Ass’n of Home 
    Builders, 551 U.S. at 665
    (applying Chevron deference to a regulation
    promulgated by the National Marine Fisheries Service and the
    Fish and Wildlife Service “acting jointly”). Here, there is no
    issue of one agency interpreting the statute in a way that
    conflicts with the other agency’s interpretation. The IRS’s rule
    defines “Exchange” by reference to the HHS’s definition,
    which provides that subsidies are available to low-income
    taxpayers purchasing insurance on an Exchange “regardless of
    whether the Exchange is established and operated by a State
    . . . or by HHS.” 45 C.F.R. § 155.20; 26 C.F.R. § 1.36B-1(k).
    Appellants also argue that Chevron deference is precluded
    by the canon that “tax credits ‘must be expressed in clear and
    unambiguous terms.’” Br. for Appellants at 51 (quoting Yazoo
    & Miss. Valley R.R. Co. v. Thomas, 
    132 U.S. 174
    , 183 (1889)).
    Again, Appellants’ position is mistaken. The Supreme Court
    6
    has made clear that “[t]he principles underlying [the] decision
    in Chevron apply with full force in the tax context.” Mayo
    
    Found., 131 S. Ct. at 713
    .
    Chevron plainly applies to this case. And this court is
    obliged to defer to the IRS’s and HHS’s “permissible”
    interpretations of the ACA. 
    Chevron, 467 U.S. at 843
    .
    II. ANALYSIS
    Appellants’ argument focuses almost entirely on 26
    U.S.C. § 36B, considered in isolation from the other
    provisions of the ACA. Repeating the phrase “Exchange
    established by the State” as a mantra throughout their brief,
    Appellants contend that this language unambiguously
    indicates that § 36B(b) conditions refundable tax credits on a
    State – and not HHS – establishing an Exchange.
    Appellants’ argument unravels, however, when the phrase
    “established by the State” is subject to close scrutiny in view
    of the surrounding provisions in the ACA. See Brown &
    
    Williamson, 529 U.S. at 132
    (“The . . . ambiguity . . . of certain
    . . . phrases may only become evident when placed in
    context.”). In particular, § 36B has no plain meaning when
    read in conjunction with § 18031(d)(1) and § 18041(c). And,
    more fundamentally, the purported plain meaning of § 36B(b)
    would subvert the careful policy scheme crafted by Congress,
    which understood when it enacted the ACA that subsidies
    were critically necessary to ensure that the goals of the ACA
    could be achieved. Simply put, § 36B(b) interpreted as
    Appellants urge would function as a poison pill to the
    insurance markets in the States that did not elect to create their
    own Exchanges. This surely is not what Congress intended.
    7
    Perhaps because they appreciate that no legitimate method
    of statutory interpretation ascribes to Congress the aim of
    tearing down the very thing it attempted to construct,
    Appellants in this litigation have invented a narrative to
    explain why Congress would want health insurance markets to
    fail in States that did not elect to create their own Exchanges.
    Congress, they assert, made the subsidies conditional in order
    to incentivize the States to create their own exchanges. This
    argument is disingenuous, and it is wrong. Not only is there no
    evidence that anyone in Congress thought § 36B operated as a
    condition, there is also no evidence that any State thought of it
    as such. And no wonder: The statutory provision presumes the
    existence of subsidies and was drafted to establish a formula
    for the payment of tax credits, not to impose a significant and
    substantial condition on the States.
    It makes little sense to think that Congress would have
    imposed so substantial a condition in such an oblique and
    circuitous manner. See Whitman v. Am. Trucking Ass’ns, 
    531 U.S. 457
    , 468 (2001) (“Congress . . . does not alter the
    fundamental details of a regulatory scheme in vague
    terms . . . .”). The simple truth is that Appellants’ incentive
    story is a fiction, a post hoc narrative concocted to provide a
    colorable explanation for the otherwise risible notion that
    Congress would have wanted insurance markets to collapse in
    States that elected not to create their own Exchanges.
    In the end, the question for this court is whether § 36B
    unambiguously operates as a condition limiting the tax
    subsidies that Congress understood were a necessary part of a
    functioning insurance market to only those States that created
    their own exchange. The phrase “Exchange established by the
    State,” standing alone, suggests the affirmative. But there is
    powerful evidence to the contrary – both in § 36B and the
    8
    provisions it references, and in the Act as a whole – that shows
    Appellants’ argument to be fatally flawed.
    It is not the prerogative of this court to interpret the
    ambiguities uncovered in the ACA. Congress has delegated
    this authority to the IRS and HHS. And the interpretation
    given by these agencies is not only permissible but also the
    better construction of the statute because § 36B is not clearly
    drafted as a condition, because the Act empowers HHS to
    establish exchanges on behalf of the States, because parallel
    provisions indicate that Congress thought that federal
    subsidies would be provided on HHS-created exchanges, and,
    most importantly, because Congress established a careful
    legislative scheme by which individual subsidies were
    essential to the basic viability of individual insurance markets.
    A. Appellants’ “Plain Meaning” Argument Viewed in
    Context
    In arguing that the ACA clearly and unambiguously bars
    subsidies to individuals who purchase insurance in States in
    which HHS created the Exchange on the State’s behalf,
    Appellants rest on a narrow, out-of-context interpretation of
    § 36B(b) and § 36B(c)(2)(A)(i). Br. for Appellants at 16.
    Appellants argue that because there is no “Exchange
    established by the State” in States with HHS-created
    Exchanges, taxpayers who purchase insurance in these States
    cannot receive subsidies. This plain meaning argument, which
    views § 36B in isolation, is simplistic and wrong.
    We cannot read § 36B in isolation; we must also consider
    the specific context of the provision and the “broader context
    of the statute as a whole.” 
    Robinson, 519 U.S. at 341
    . And
    viewing the matter through this wider lens, as we must, the
    provision which initially might appear plain is far from
    9
    unambiguous. To begin with, as the Government points out,
    § 36B refers to premiums for health plans enrolled in through
    “an Exchange established by the State under 1331 [i.e., 42
    U.S.C. § 18031].” 26 U.S.C. § 36B(b) (emphasis added). The
    cross-referenced provision – 42 U.S.C. § 18031 – contains
    language indicating that all States are required to establish an
    exchange under the section. See 42 U.S.C. § 18031(b)(1)
    (“Each State shall . . . establish an American Health Benefit
    Exchange . . . .”); see also 
    id. § 18031(d)(1)
    (“An Exchange
    shall be a governmental agency or nonprofit entity that is
    established by a State.” (emphasis added)). In other words, if
    our statutory universe consisted only of these two provisions,
    it would be clear that § 36B intended that residents in all
    States would receive subsidies because all States were
    required to create such exchanges by the section of the Act
    referenced in § 36B.
    Of course, the ACA is broader than just § 36B and
    § 18031, and in 42 U.S.C. § 18041 it permits a State to elect to
    allow HHS to establish the Exchange on behalf of the State. In
    such circumstances, however, the Act requires HHS to
    establish and operate “such Exchange.” 
    Id. § 18041(c)
    (emphasis added). The use of “such” can reasonably be
    interpreted to deem the HHS-created Exchange to be the
    equivalent of an Exchange created in the first instance by the
    State. That is, when HHS creates an exchange under
    § 18041(c), it does so on behalf of the State, essentially
    standing in its stead. Put differently, under the ACA, an
    Exchange within a State is a given. The only question is
    whether the State opts to create the Exchange on its own or
    have HHS do it on its behalf. On this view, “established by the
    State” is term of art that includes any Exchange within a State.
    Indeed, the Act says as much when it defines the term
    “Exchange” as “a governmental agency or nonprofit entity
    10
    that is established by a State.” 42 U.S.C. § 18031(d)(1). It is
    clear that § 18031 is the source of the definition of the term
    “Exchange” under the Act. See 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-91(d)(21)
    (defining “Exchange” for purpose of Public Health Service
    Act to mean what it does in § 18031); 
    id. § 18111
    (incorporating the definitions in § 300gg-91 for purpose of
    Title I of the ACA). It is also clear that § 18031 defines every
    “Exchange” under the Act as “a governmental agency or
    nonprofit entity that is established by a State.” 
    Id. § 18031(d)(1)
    (emphasis added). Because § 18041(c)
    authorizes the federal government to establish “Exchanges,”
    the phrase “established by the State” in § 18031 must be broad
    enough to accommodate Exchanges created by the HHS on a
    State’s behalf. Section 36B expressly incorporates this broad
    definition of “Exchange” when it uses the phrase an
    “Exchange established by the State under [§ 18031].” 26
    U.S.C. § 36B(b) (emphasis added). Therefore, the phrase
    “established by the State” in § 36B is reasonably understood to
    take its meaning from the cognate language in the incorporated
    definition in § 18031, which embraces Exchanges created by
    HHS on the State’s behalf. See, e.g., Gustafson v. Alloyd Co.,
    Inc., 
    513 U.S. 561
    , 570 (1995) (noting “the normal rule of
    statutory construction that identical words used in different
    parts of the same act are intended to have the same meaning”
    (internal quotation marks omitted)). These provisions belie the
    “plain meaning” that Appellants attempt to attribute to § 36B.
    What is more, Appellants’ interpretation of the operative
    language in § 36B sits awkwardly with the section’s structure.
    Subsection (a) provides tax credits to any “applicable
    taxpayer,” defined in reference to the poverty line and without
    regard to what the taxpayer’s State has or has not done. 26
    U.S.C. § 36B(a), (c)(1)(A). Subsection (b) then establishes a
    numerical formula for calculating the amount of the subsidy.
    
    Id. § 36B(b).
    It is only in the context of this numerical formula
    11
    and its definition of “coverage month” that the purported
    condition is found. 
    Id. § 36B(b)(1),
    (c)(2)(A)(i). If Congress
    intended to create a significant condition on taxpayer
    eligibility for subsidies of the sort advocated by Appellants,
    one would expect that it would say so plainly and clearly. See
    Am. Trucking 
    Ass’ns, 531 U.S. at 468
    . There is no “if/then” or
    other such conditional language in § 36B. Instead, if
    Appellants are to be believed, Congress thought it appropriate
    to incentivize significant State action (creating Exchanges)
    through an oblique and indirect condition. This is an
    implausible reading of the statute.
    The simple truth is that the phrase “established by the
    State” in § 36B does not have the plain meaning that
    Appellants would like. The inquiry does not end with a narrow
    look at § 36B. That provision must be read in conjunction with
    § 18031(d)(1) and § 18041(c); and these provisions, read
    together, defy any claim of plain meaning.
    Furthermore, in order to address the question before us,
    this court is obliged to consider § 36B in “the broader context
    of the statute as a whole.” 
    Robinson, 519 U.S. at 341
    ; see also
    Zuni Pub. Sch. Dist. No. 89 v. Dep’t of Educ., 
    550 U.S. 81
    , 98
    (2007) (looking to “basic purpose and history” of statute). The
    Supreme Court’s recent decision in Michigan v. Bay Mills
    Indian Community, 
    134 S. Ct. 2024
    (2014), which Appellants
    cite, is not to the contrary. See also Util. Air Regulatory Grp.,
    
    2014 WL 2807314
    , at *9 (reaffirming that courts must bear “in
    mind the fundamental canon of statutory construction that the
    words of a statute must be read in their context and with a
    view to their place in the overall statutory scheme” (internal
    quotation marks omitted)). Nothing in Bay Mills or Utility Air
    Regulatory Group purport to undermine the commonsense
    principle – repeatedly endorsed by the Court – that the
    operative text must be understood in its statutory context, nor
    12
    the subsidiary principle, which follows from the first, that
    evidence of meaning drawn from the broader statutory context
    can render the operative text ambiguous on a particular
    question of law. Appellants’ argument in this case is illogical
    when cast in the context of the statute as a whole.
    B. The Statute Read as a Whole
    1.   The “Three-Legged Stool” and the Indispensable
    Role of the Tax Subsidies
    Appellants’ interpretation is implausible because it would
    destroy the fundamental policy structure and goals of the ACA
    that are apparent when the statute is read as a whole. A key
    component to achieving the Act’s goal of “near-universal
    coverage” for all Americans is a series of measures to reform
    the individual insurance market. 42 U.S.C. § 18091(2)(D).
    These measures – nondiscrimination requirements applying to
    insurers, the individual mandate, and premium subsidies –
    work in tandem, each one a necessary component to ensure the
    basic viability of each State’s insurance market. Because
    premium subsidies are so critical to an insurance market’s
    sustainability, Appellants’ interpretation of § 36B would, in
    the words of Appellants’ amici, cause “the structure of the
    ACA [to] crumble.” Scott Pruitt, ObamaCare’s Next Legal
    Challenge, WALL ST. J., Dec. 1, 2013.
    This point is essential and worth explaining in detail. The
    ACA has been described as a “three-legged stool” in view of
    its three interrelated and interdependent reforms. Br. for
    Economic Scholars at 7. The first “leg” of the ACA is the
    “guaranteed issue” and “community rating” provisions, which
    prohibit insurers from denying coverage based on health status
    or history, 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-1, and require insurers to offer
    coverage to all individuals at community-wide rates, 
    id. 13 §
    300gg(a). But such nondiscrimination provisions cannot
    function alone because of the problem of “adverse selection.”
    When insurers cannot deny coverage or charge sick or high-
    risk individuals higher premiums, healthy people delay
    purchasing insurance (knowing they will not be denied
    coverage if and when they become sick), and insurers’ risk
    pools thus become skewed toward high-risk individuals (as
    they are the only ones willing to pay the premiums). The result
    is that insurers wind up paying more per average on each
    policy, which leads them to increase the community-wide rate,
    which, in turn, serves only to exacerbate the “adverse
    selection” process (as now only those who are really sick will
    find insurance worthwhile). This is the so-called “death-
    spiral,” which Congress understood would doom each State’s
    individual insurance market in the absence of a multifaceted
    reform program. Nat’l Fed’n of Indep. Bus. v. Sebelius, 132 S.
    Ct. 2566, 2626 (2012) (Ginsburg, J., concurring in part and
    dissenting in part).
    This is where the individual mandate, the second “leg” of
    the ACA, comes in. Congress recognized:
    [I]f there were no requirement, many individuals would
    wait to purchase health insurance until they needed care.
    By significantly increasing health insurance coverage, the
    [individual coverage] requirement, together with the other
    provisions of this Act, will minimize this adverse
    selection and broaden the health insurance risk pool to
    include healthy individuals, which will lower health
    insurance premiums. The requirement is essential to
    creating effective health insurance markets in which
    improved health insurance products that are guaranteed
    issue and do not exclude coverage of pre-existing
    conditions can be sold.
    14
    42 U.S.C. § 18091(2)(I). Accordingly, the Act requires each
    individual who is not covered by an employer to purchase
    minimum coverage or to pay a tax penalty. 26 U.S.C.
    § 5000A(a)-(b). But recognizing that individuals cannot be
    made to purchase what they cannot afford, Congress provided
    that the mandate would not apply if the cost of insurance
    exceeds eight percent of the taxpayer’s income after subsidies.
    
    Id. § 5000A(e)(1).
    The third “leg” of the ACA is the subsidies. The subsidies
    ensure that the individual mandate will have a broad enough
    sweep to attract enough healthy individuals into the individual
    insurance markets to create stability, i.e., to prevent an
    adverse-selection death spiral. Without the subsidies, the
    individual mandate is simply not viable as a mechanism for
    creating a stable insurance market: the lowest level of
    coverage for typical subsidy-eligible participants will cost
    23% of income, meaning that these individuals will be exempt
    from the mandate. Id.; Br. for Economic Scholars at 17-18.
    Congress was informed of the importance of the subsidies to
    the overall legislative scheme. See Roundtable Discussion on
    Expanding Health Care Coverage: Hearing Before the Senate
    Comm. On Finance, 111th Cong. 504 (2009) (statement of
    Sandy Praeger, Comm’r of Insurance for the State of Kansas)
    (“State regulators can support these reforms to the extent they
    are coupled with an effective and enforceable individual
    purchase mandate and appropriate income-sensitive subsidies
    to make coverage affordable.” (emphasis added)); see also
    CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE, AN ANALYSIS OF HEALTH
    INSURANCE PREMIUMS UNDER THE PATIENT PROTECTION AND
    AFFORDABLE CARE ACT 24 (Nov. 30, 2009), (estimating that
    approximately 78% of people purchasing their own coverage
    would receive subsidies). It is thus no surprise that Congress
    provided generous subsidies in the ACA and, importantly,
    expressly linked the operation of the individual mandate to the
    15
    cost of insurance after taking account of the subsidies. 26
    U.S.C. § 5000A(e)(1)(B)(ii).
    If nothing else, it is clear that premium subsidies are an
    essential component of the regulatory framework established
    by the ACA. If, as Appellants contend, a State could block
    subsidies by electing not to establish an Exchange, this would
    exempt a large number of taxpayers from the individual
    mandate, cause the risk pool to skew toward higher risk
    people, and effectively cut the heart out of the ACA. This is
    one of the points that was made in the joint opinion by Justice
    Scalia, Justice Kennedy, Justice Thomas, and Justice Alito in
    National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius:
    Without the federal subsidies, individuals would lose the
    main incentive to purchase insurance inside the exchanges,
    and some insurers may be unwilling to offer insurance
    inside of exchanges. With fewer buyers and even fewer
    sellers, the exchanges would not operate as Congress
    intended and may not operate at 
    all. 132 S. Ct. at 2674
    (Scalia, Kennedy, Thomas, and Alito, JJ.,
    dissenting) (emphasis added); see also Br. for the Appellees at
    38 (“Insurers in States with federally-run Exchanges would
    still be required to comply with guaranteed-issue and
    community rating rules, but, without premium tax subsidies to
    encourage broad participation, insurers would be deprived of
    the broad policy-holder base required to make those reforms
    viable.”). This “adverse selection” is precisely what Congress
    sought to avoid when it enacted the individual mandate. 42
    U.S.C. § 18091(2)(I). It is unfathomable that Congress
    intended to allow States to effectively nullify the individual
    mandate, which it recognized was necessary to the viability of
    an individual insurance market subject to the “guaranteed
    issue” and “community rating” requirements.
    16
    Section 36B cannot be interpreted divorced from the
    ACA’s unmistakable regulatory scheme in which premium
    subsidies are an indispensable component of creating viable
    and stable individual insurance markets. Due regard for the
    carefully crafted legislative scheme casts § 36B in a clearer
    light. “Congress . . . does not alter the fundamental details of a
    regulatory scheme in vague terms or ancillary provisions—it
    does not, one might say, hide elephants in mouseholes.” Am.
    Trucking 
    Ass’ns, 531 U.S. at 468
    . If Congress meant to deny
    subsidies to taxpayers in States with HHS-created Exchanges
    – thereby initiating an adverse-selection death-spiral that
    would effectively gut the statute in those States – one would
    expect to find this limit set forth in terms as clear as day. But
    the subsection defining which taxpayers are eligible for
    subsidies make no mention of State-established Exchanges.
    Subsidies are available to an “applicable taxpayer,” 26 U.S.C.
    § 36B(a), and “applicable taxpayer” is defined as any
    individual whose household income for the taxable year is
    between 100% and 400% of the poverty line, 
    id. § 36B(c)(1)(A).
    A comparison with the ACA’s Medicaid expansion
    condition offers a striking case in point. This condition
    demonstrates that Congress knew how to speak clearly and
    provide notice to States when it intended to condition funding
    on State behavior. The Medicaid provision lays out an express
    conditional statement in the form of “if, then”: “If the
    Secretary, after reasonable notice and opportunity for
    hearing,” determines that the State is not in compliance with
    the Medicaid-expansion requirements, the Secretary “shall
    notify such State agency that further payments will not be
    made to the State.” 42 U.S.C. § 1396c (emphasis added). This
    provision stands in stark contrast to § 36B. The formula for
    calculating subsidies does not say, for example, “If a State
    17
    does not create an Exchange, its taxpayers shall be ineligible
    for premium credit subsidies,” or “If coverage is purchased on
    an Exchange established by HHS, premium credit subsidies
    will not be available.” Furthermore, § 1396c ensures that
    States receive notice before Medicaid funding is withheld. In
    contrast, there is no similar notice to States that their taxpayers
    will be denied subsidies if the State elects to have HHS create
    an Exchange on its behalf.
    The majority thinks it unremarkable that Congress would
    condemn insurance markets in States with federally-created
    Exchanges to an adverse-selection death spiral. It reaches this
    conclusion by observing that, in peripheral statutory
    provisions, Congress has twice created insurance markets that
    suffered from the defect of having guaranteed issue
    requirements without the other measures (such as a mandate or
    subsidies) necessary to ensure the soundness of the market.
    Congress did this, the majority notes, in the provisions
    covering the Northern Mariana Islands and other federal
    territories, see 26 U.S.C. § 5000A(f)(4); 42 U.S.C. § 201(f),
    and in the Community Living Assistance Services and
    Supports (CLASS) Act, Pub. L. No. 111-148, §§ 8001-8002,
    124 Stat. 119, 828-47 (2010).
    This argument entirely misses the point. These peripheral
    statutory provisions say nothing about the core provisions of
    the ACA at issue here, as both the majority and the Appellants
    recognize. In both provisions, Congress purposely decided not
    to impose an individual mandate. That is a crucial difference.
    The Government and supporting amici’s position in this case
    relies on Congress’ express recognition that the individual
    mandate, “together with the other provisions of this Act, will
    minimize . . . adverse selection,” and that, as such, the
    mandate “is essential to creating effective health insurance
    markets” with guaranteed-issue requirements. 42 U.S.C.
    18
    § 18091(2)(I) (emphasis added). This recognition, together
    with Congress’ linking the mandate to the subsidies available
    to taxpayers, 26 U.S.C. § 5000A(e)(1)(B)(ii), demonstrates
    that Congress appreciated that subsidies would be an integral
    part of ensuring that the individual mandate reached broadly
    enough to secure the viability of the insurance market. By not
    imposing individual mandates in the peripheral markets
    identified by the majority (i.e., in the territories and the
    CLASS Act), Congress displayed a willingness to tolerate the
    risk that these markets would succumb to adverse selection.
    Congress displayed no such willingness here; in the markets
    covered by the core provisions of the ACA, Congress imposed
    an individual mandate linked to subsidies as an “essential” tool
    to ensure market viability. 42 U.S.C. § 18091(2)(I).
    Appellants suggest that because Congress enacted
    peripheral statutory provisions covering territories and in the
    CLASS Act without including measures to ensure a broad base
    of healthy customers to stabilize prices and avoid adverse
    selection, it is reasonable to assume that Congress did the
    same thing with respect to the core provisions of the ACA. But
    this argument gets it backwards. The CLASS Act and the
    provisions covering the federal territories importantly
    demonstrate that when Congress determined to expose an
    insurance market to significant adverse selection risk, it
    specifically declined to enact an individual mandate. In other
    words, Congress acted intentionally when it passed the
    CLASS Act and the provisions covering the federal territories
    without an individual mandate. The core provisions of the
    ACA include an individual mandate, which of course indicates
    that Congress meant to treat the core provisions of the ACA
    differently.
    Appellants’ arguments to the contrary are perplexing, to
    say the least. Congress’ omissions of an individual mandate –
    19
    which it recognized as an “essential” tool to prevent adverse
    selection, 42 U.S.C. § 18091(2)(I) – from the peripheral
    statutory provisions cited by the majority are not evidence that
    Congress had some monolithic statute-wide tolerance of the
    risk that insurance markets might succumb to adverse
    selection. To the contrary, Congress’ intentional omissions in
    these peripheral insurance markets of a tool it knew to be
    important to preventing adverse selection merely indicates that
    Congress had a substantially higher tolerance for the risk of
    adverse selection in such markets vis-à-vis the core markets
    where it did impose the individual mandate. The CLASS Act
    and the provisions covering the territories thus do not rebut the
    Government’s structural argument. Indeed, if anything, the
    subsequent history concerning the territories and the CLASS
    Act serve only to highlight that Congress was correct in its
    judgment that an individual mandate – accompanied by
    subsidies to ensure its scope was sufficiently large – was
    necessary to stave off adverse selection in insurance markets.
    As Appellants note, without an individual mandate, the
    CLASS Act was “unworkable,” which led Congress to repeal
    it. Reply Br. for Appellants at 15.
    The Government and supporting amici’s structural
    argument in this case cannot be dismissed as idle meanderings
    into legislative history. It is apparent from the statutory text of
    the ACA that Congress understood (1) the importance of a
    broadly applicable individual mandate that works “together
    with the other provisions” to ensure the viability of an
    insurance market against the threat of adverse selection, 42
    U.S.C. § 18091(2)(I), and (2) the necessity of taxpayer
    subsidies to broaden the scope of the individual mandate, see
    26 U.S.C. § 5000A(e)(1)(B)(ii). In giving short shrift to the
    clear statutory scheme adopted by Congress when it enacted
    the core provisions of the ACA, the majority has ignored
    congressional intent and improperly rejected the reasonable
    20
    interpretations of HHS and IRS. In sum, the majority has
    drawn the wrong lesson from the CLASS Act and the
    provisions covering federal territories, which demonstrate just
    the opposite of the conclusion reached by the majority.
    2.   The Advance Payment Reporting Requirements of
    § 36B(f)(3)
    One of the subsections in § 36B – which is the section
    upon which Appellants stake their case – makes it clear that
    Congress intended that taxpayers on HHS-created Exchanges
    would be eligible for subsidies. Subsection (f), entitled
    “Reconciliation of credit and advance credit,” tasks the IRS
    with reducing the amount of a taxpayer’s end-of-year premium
    tax credit under § 36B by the sum of any advance payments of
    the credit. 26 U.S.C. § 36B(f). Crucially, subsection (f)
    establishes reporting requirements that expressly apply to
    HHS-created Exchanges. 
    Id. § 36B(f)(3)
    (citing 42 U.S.C.
    § 18041(c)). These reporting requirements mandate that
    Exchanges provide certain information to the IRS, including
    the “aggregate amount of any advance payment of such
    credit”; information needed to determine the taxpayer’s
    “eligibility for, and the amount of, such credit”; and
    “[i]nformation necessary to determine whether a taxpayer has
    received excess advance payments.” 
    Id. § 36B(f)(3)
    (C), (E),
    (F). The self-evident primary purpose of these requirements –
    reconciling end-of-year premium tax credits with advance
    payments of such credits – could not be met with respect to
    Exchanges created by HHS on behalf of a State if these
    Exchanges were not authorized to deliver tax credits. Indeed,
    HHS-created Exchanges would have nothing to report
    regarding subsidies were they barred from giving any. It is
    thus plain from subsection (f) that Congress intended credits
    under § 36B to be available to taxpayers in States with HHS-
    created Exchanges.
    21
    Appellants’ attempts to minimize the importance of the
    reporting requirements are specious. They first argue that,
    even if credits are unavailable on federally-created Exchanges,
    the reporting provision would nevertheless serve a purpose: to
    enforce the individual mandate to buy insurance. This amounts
    to a sleight of hand. The argument ignores the clear purpose –
    apparent from the statutory text – of subsection (f) and its
    reporting requirements. The purpose is front and center in the
    subsection’s title – “Reconciliation of credit and advance
    credit,” 
    id. § 36B(f)
    – and is reinforced by the wording and
    structure of the provision. Consistent with its title, subsection
    (f) charges the IRS with reconciling the ultimate tax credit to
    be paid with any advanced payments of the credit, 
    id. § 36B(f)
    (1), including advance payments that “exceed the
    credit allowed” for the tax year, 
    id. § 36B(f)
    (2). The IRS, of
    course, can accomplish these tasks only if it has adequate
    information, and the next paragraph, § 36B(f)(3), establishes
    the reporting requirements that ensure that the IRS has the
    information it needs to satisfy the terms of the statute. See 
    id. § 36B(f)
    (3)(C), (E), (F) (requiring disclosure of information
    concerning advanced payments of tax credits). Obviously,
    some of the information covered by subsection (f)(3) will also
    assist in enforcing the individual mandate. But much of the
    information required to be disclosed by subsection (f)(3) is
    irrelevant to the purpose hypothesized by Appellants (i.e., to
    enforcing the mandate). See 
    id. § 36B(f)
    (3)(F) (mandating the
    reporting of “[i]nformation necessary to determine whether a
    taxpayer has received excess advance payments”); 
    id. § 5000A(e)(1)(A)-(B)
    (in determining whether an individual is
    exempted from the mandate, the statute takes account of the
    “amount of the credit allowable,” but not the amount of excess
    advance payments).
    22
    In a letter submitted to the court before oral argument,
    Appellants cited an IRS regulation, 26 C.F.R. § 1.6055-
    1(d)(1), that addresses information reporting requirements. “In
    order to reduce the compliance burden on” insurers, the IRS
    decided not to require insurers “to report under section 6055
    for coverage under individual market qualified health plans
    purchased through an Exchange because Exchanges must
    report on this coverage under section 36B(f)(3).” Information
    Reporting of Minimum Essential Coverage, 79 Fed. Reg.
    13,220, 13,221 (Mar. 10, 2014). Appellants seem to think that
    this regulation somehow vindicates their view of § 36B(f)(3),
    but their argument makes no sense. That the IRS determined
    that additional reporting by insurers in specified circumstances
    was unnecessary does not imply that Congress drafted
    § 36B(f)(3) solely to enforce the individual mandate, as
    Appellants would have it. What is clear here is that §
    36B(f)(3) establishes reporting requirements for the principal
    purpose of requiring disclosure of information concerning
    advanced payments of tax credits, a purpose which cannot be
    squared with Appellants’ interpretation under which no credits
    are available on federally-created Exchanges.
    Appellants also argue that the reporting provisions in
    subsection § 36B(f) are already over-inclusive because they
    apply to plans serving taxpayers who, by reason of their
    income, are ineligible for subsidies. The implication suggested
    by Appellants – and accepted too easily by the majority – is
    that the reporting requirements in § 36B(f)(3) already suffer
    from over-inclusiveness (since such taxpayers will have
    neither credits nor advance payments) and that there is thus
    little reason to be concerned about the additional over-
    inclusiveness generated by Appellants’ interpretation of
    § 36B. Framing the issue in this manner obscures a
    fundamental difference. Interpreting § 36B to foreclose credits
    on federally-created Exchanges would not merely increase the
    23
    “over-inclusiveness” of § 36B(f)(3)’s reporting requirements;
    it would render certain of the reporting requirements pointless
    as to every single taxpayer on an HHS-created Exchange. This
    is a nonsensical interpretation because Congress enacted the
    § 36B(f)(3) reporting requirements to apply to HHS-created
    Exchanges. 
    Id. § 36B(f)(3)
    (citing 42 U.S.C. § 18041(c)). The
    provision is powerful evidence that Congress intended that tax
    credits be available on federally-created Exchanges.
    3.   Other Provisions
    There are two other provisions of the ACA that strongly
    support the Government’s claim that the statute, read as a
    whole, permits taxpayers who purchase insurance in non-
    electing States to receive subsidies. First, the statute defines a
    “qualified individual” as a person who “resides in the State
    that     established       the    Exchange.”        42     U.S.C.
    § 18032(f)(1)(A)(ii). There is no separate definition of
    “qualified individual” for States with HHS-created Exchanges.
    If an HHS-created Exchange does not count as established by
    the State it is in, there would be no individuals “qualified” to
    purchase coverage in the 34 States with HHS-created
    Exchanges. This would make little sense.
    Second, in a subparagraph entitled “Assurance of
    exchange coverage for targeted low-income children unable to
    be provided child health assistance as a result of funding
    shortfalls,” the ACA requires States to “ensure” that low-
    income children who are not covered under the State’s child
    health plan are enrolled in a health plan that is offered through
    “an Exchange established by the State under [§ 18031].”
    42 U.S.C. § 1397ee(d)(3)(B). Here again, the statute simply
    presumes that the existence of such State-established
    exchanges. The statute’s objective of “assur[ing] exchange
    coverage for targeted low-income children” would be largely
    24
    lost if States with HHS-created Exchanges are excluded. There
    is nothing in the statute to indicate that Congress meant to
    exclude benefits for low-income children in the 34 States in
    which HHS has established an Exchange on behalf of the
    State.
    *    *    *
    In view of the foregoing, Appellants’ reliance on Bay
    Mills is entirely misplaced. In citing that case, Appellants
    simply cherry pick language which appears favorable to their
    side but which does not reflect the Court’s reasoning. It is true,
    of course, that courts have no “roving license” to disregard a
    statute’s unambiguous 
    meaning. 134 S. Ct. at 2034
    . This was
    an important point in Bay Mills because it was undisputed in
    that case that the plaintiff’s position could not be squared with
    the plain meaning of the statute. And the plaintiff in Bay Mills
    failed “to identify any specific textual or structural features of
    the statute to support its proposed result.” 
    Id. at 2033
    (emphasis added). Bay Mills is plainly inapposite. Here, by
    contrast, there is considerable evidence – textual and structural
    – to render the ACA ambiguous on the question whether
    § 36B operates to bar tax subsidies in States in which HHS has
    established an Exchange on behalf of the State. And, as shown
    above, when the ACA is read as a whole – including its
    “textual [and] structural features,” “purpose,” “history and
    design,” 
    id. at 2033-34
    – it is clear that the Government’s
    interpretation of the ACA is permissible and reasonable, and,
    therefore, entitled to deference under Chevron.
    25
    C. Appellants’       Extraordinary       Subsidies-As-Incentive
    Argument
    The foregoing examination of the statute shows that when
    the terms of § 36B are read “with a view to their place in the
    overall statutory scheme,” Nat’l Ass’n of Home 
    Builders, 551 U.S. at 666
    , Appellants’ plain meaning argument fails.
    Appellants obviously recognize that their argument resting on
    § 36B in isolation, apart from the rest of the ACA, is
    ridiculous. This is clear because, in an effort to bolster their
    claim, Appellants proffer the extraordinary argument that
    Congress limited subsidies to State-run Exchanges as an
    incentive to encourage States to set up their own Exchanges.
    Br. for Appellants at 28. As noted above, this argument is
    nonsense. Appellants have no credible evidence whatsoever to
    support their subsidies-as-incentive theory.
    The record indicates that, when the ACA was enacted, no
    State even considered the possibility that its taxpayers would
    be denied subsidies if the State opted to allow HHS to
    establish an Exchange on its behalf. Not one. Indeed no State
    even suggested that a lack of subsidies factored into its
    decision whether to create its own Exchange. Br. of Members
    of Congress and State Legislatures at 24-25 & n.30 (citing
    authorities). “States were motivated by a mix of policy
    considerations, such as flexibility and control, and ‘strategic’
    calculations by ACA opponents, not the availability of tax
    credits.” 
    Id. at 24-25
    n.30 (citing authorities). The fact that all
    States recognized and protested the Medicaid expansion
    condition, while no State raised any concern over the
    purported subsidy-condition shows that Appellants’ argument
    is at best fanciful. See Br. for the Appellees at 42 (“[T]he
    twenty-six plaintiff states in [Nat’l Fed’n of Indep. Bus., 
    132 S. Ct. 2566
    ,] repeatedly contrasted the Medicaid eligibility
    expansion with the ‘real choice that the ACA offers States to
    26
    create exchanges or have the federal government do so.’”
    (quoting Br. for State Pet’rs on Medicaid, Florida v. HHS, No.
    11-400, 
    2012 WL 105551
    , at *51 (2012))).
    The legislative history also indicates that Congress
    assumed subsidies would be available on HHS-created
    Exchanges. First, earlier proposals for the legislation and an
    earlier version of the House Bill provided that the federal
    government would establish and operate Exchanges. Halbig v.
    Sebelius, 
    2014 WL 129023
    , at *17 (D.D.C. Jan. 15, 2014)
    (citing Reconciliation Act of 2010, H.R. 4872 §§ 141(a),
    201(a) (2010) (version reported in the House on March 17,
    2010); H. REP. NO. 111–443, at 18, 26 (2013)). When the
    legislation was modified so that States could operate their own
    Exchanges, the Senate Finance Committee expressly
    acknowledged that the federal government could “establish
    state exchanges.” 
    Id. (citing S.
    REP. NO. 111–89, at 19 (2009)
    (“If these [state] interim exchanges are not operational within
    a reasonable period after enactment, the Secretary [of HHS]
    would be required to contract with a nongovernmental entity
    to establish state exchanges during this interim period.”)
    (emphasis added)).
    In addition, the three House Committees with jurisdiction
    over the ACA legislation issued a fact sheet explaining that
    States would have a choice whether to create their own
    Exchanges or have one run by the federal government, and
    “the Exchanges” would make health insurance more
    affordable. The fact sheet recognized income level as the only
    criteria for subsidy-eligibility. Br. for Members of Congress
    and State Legislatures at 11-12. The Joint Committee on
    Taxation also reported that the subsidies would be available to
    those who purchase insurance through “an exchange.” 
    Id. at 12.
    And Congressional Budget Office estimates assumed that
    subsidies would be available nationwide. Letter from Douglas
    27
    W. Elmendorf, Director, CBO, to Rep. Darrell E. Issa,
    Chairman, House Committee on Oversight and Government
    Reform (Dec. 6, 2012) (“To the best of our recollection, the
    possibility that those subsidies would only be available in
    states that created their own exchanges did not arise during the
    discussions CBO staff had with a wide range of
    Congressional staff when the legislation was being
    considered.” (emphasis added)).
    The truth is that there is nothing in the record indicating
    that, aside from wanting to afford States flexibility, Congress
    preferred State-run to HHS-run Exchanges. Appellants have
    not explained why Congress would want to encourage States
    to operate Exchanges rather than the federal government doing
    so, nor is there any indication that Congress had this goal.
    “[T]he purpose of the tax credits was not to encourage States
    to set up their own Exchanges. Indeed, making the tax credits
    conditional on state establishment of the Exchanges would
    have empowered hostile state officials to undermine the core
    purpose of the ACA, a result that [the] architects of the ACA
    wanted to avoid, not encourage.” Br. for Members of Congress
    and State Legislatures at 22.
    Furthermore, Appellants assume without any basis that
    denying taxpayers premium subsidies would put political
    pressure on States to create Exchanges. This assumption runs
    counter to Appellants’ own theory of harm: After all,
    Appellants object to the subsidies because they impose
    additional financial obligations on individuals and employers
    by triggering the individual mandate and assessable payments
    for employers. These obligations would not attach if the
    subsidies were not available in the State. Because the subsidies
    trigger additional costs for individuals and employers, it is not
    obvious that they would be popular among taxpayers or cause
    taxpayers to pressure their States to create Exchanges.
    28
    The single piece of evidence that Appellants cite to
    support their claim that Congress intended to restrict subsidies
    to State-run Exchanges is an article by a law professor. Br. for
    Appellants at 40 (citing Timothy S. Jost, Health Insurance
    Exchanges: Legal Issues, O’Neill Inst., Georgetown Univ.
    Legal Ctr., no. 23 (Apr. 7, 2009)). There is no evidence,
    however, that anyone in Congress read, cited, or relied on this
    article.
    III. CONCLUSION
    The Supreme Court has made it clear that “[t]he plainness
    or ambiguity of statutory language is determined by reference
    to the language itself, the specific context in which that
    language is used, and the broader context of the statute as a
    whole.” 
    Robinson, 519 U.S. at 341
    . We cannot review a
    “particular statutory provision in isolation . . . . It is a
    fundamental canon of statutory construction that the words of
    a statute must be read in their context and with a view to their
    place in the overall statutory scheme.” Nat’l Ass’n of Home
    
    Builders, 551 U.S. at 666
    . Following these precepts and
    reading the ACA as a whole, it is clear that the statute does not
    unambiguously provide that individuals who purchase
    insurance from an Exchange created by HHS on behalf of a
    State are ineligible to receive a tax credit. The majority
    opinion evinces a painstaking effort – covering many pages –
    attempting to show that there is no ambiguity in the ACA. The
    result, I think, is to prove just the opposite. Implausible results
    would follow if “established by the State” is construed to
    exclude Exchanges established by HHS on behalf of a State.
    This is why the majority opinion strains fruitlessly to show
    plain meaning when there is none to be found.
    29
    The IRS’s and HHS’s constructions of the statute are
    perfectly consistent with the statute’s text, structure, and
    purpose, while Appellants’ interpretation would “crumble” the
    Act’s structure. Therefore, we certainly cannot hold that that
    the agencies’ regulations are “manifestly contrary to the
    statute.” This court owes deference to the agencies’
    interpretations of the ACA. Unfortunately, by imposing the
    Appellants’ myopic construction on the administering
    agencies without any regard for the overall statutory scheme,
    the majority opinion effectively ignores the basic tenets of
    statutory construction, as well as the principles of Chevron
    deference. Because the proposed judgment of the majority
    defies the will of Congress and the permissible interpretations
    of the agencies to whom Congress has delegated the authority
    to interpret and enforce the terms of the ACA, I dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 14-5018

Citation Numbers: 411 U.S. App. D.C. 199, 758 F.3d 390

Judges: Edwards, Griffith, Randolph

Filed Date: 7/22/2014

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 8/31/2023

Authorities (55)

Village of Barrington, Ill. v. Surface Transp. Bd. , 636 F.3d 650 ( 2011 )

Fund for Animals v. Kempthorne, Dirk , 472 F.3d 872 ( 2006 )

Sierra Club v. Environmental Protection Agency , 551 F.3d 1019 ( 2008 )

El Rio Santa Cruz Neighborhood Health Center, Inc. v. U.S. ... , 396 F.3d 1265 ( 2005 )

Cohen v. United States , 650 F.3d 717 ( 2011 )

Sierra Club v. Environmental Protection Agency , 294 F.3d 155 ( 2002 )

United States v. Cook , 594 F.3d 883 ( 2010 )

Wolf Run Mining Co. v. Federal Mine Safety & Health Review ... , 659 F.3d 1197 ( 2011 )

CA Indep Sys Oprtr v. FERC , 372 F.3d 395 ( 2004 )

Mountain States Legal Foundation v. Dan Glickman, Secretary ... , 92 F.3d 1228 ( 1996 )

Building and Construction Trades Department, Afl-Cio v. ... , 932 F.2d 985 ( 1991 )

Holland, Michael H. v. Barnhart, Jo Anne B. , 309 F.3d 808 ( 2002 )

Garcia v. Vilsack , 563 F.3d 519 ( 2009 )

Gorman v. National Transportation Safety Board , 558 F.3d 580 ( 2009 )

Ethyl Corporation v. Environmental Protection Agency, ... , 51 F.3d 1053 ( 1995 )

National Railroad Passenger Corp. v. United States , 431 F.3d 374 ( 2005 )

Yazoo & Mississippi Valley Railroad v. Thomas , 10 S. Ct. 68 ( 1889 )

Iselin v. United States , 46 S. Ct. 248 ( 1926 )

Public Citizen v. United States Department of Justice , 109 S. Ct. 2558 ( 1989 )

Department of Housing and Urban Development v. Rucker , 122 S. Ct. 1230 ( 2002 )

View All Authorities »