ANR Storage Company v. FERC , 904 F.3d 1020 ( 2018 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued February 22, 2018         Decided September 21, 2018
    No. 16-1285
    ANR STORAGE COMPANY,
    PETITIONER
    v.
    FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION,
    RESPONDENT
    NORTHERN STATES POWER COMPANY - MINNESOTA, ET AL.,
    INTERVENORS
    On Petition for Review of Orders of the
    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
    Mark Sundback argued the cause for petitioner. With him
    on the briefs were Kenneth Wiseman and William Rappolt.
    Kevin Siqveland entered an appearance.
    Lona T. Perry, Deputy Solicitor, Federal Energy
    Regulatory Commission, argued the cause for respondent.
    With her on the brief were David L. Morenoff, General
    Counsel, and Robert H. Solomon, Solicitor.
    Robert I. White, Nancy A. White, James H. Holt, Douglas
    F. John, and Matthew T. Rick were on the joint brief of
    intervenors Canadian Association of Petroleum Producers, et
    al. in support of respondent.
    Before: HENDERSON and KATSAS, Circuit Judges, and
    RANDOLPH, Senior Circuit Judge.
    Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge KATSAS.
    KATSAS, Circuit Judge: The Federal Energy Regulatory
    Commission refused to allow ANR Storage Company to charge
    market-based rates, as opposed to cost-based rates, for its
    natural-gas storage services. That decision rested on FERC’s
    conclusion that ANR had failed to prove that it lacks market
    power. ANR challenges FERC’s decision as both inconsistent
    with prior precedent and internally inconsistent.
    I
    Section 4(a) of the Natural Gas Act requires natural-gas
    companies to charge “just and reasonable” rates in interstate
    markets subject to FERC’s regulatory jurisdiction. 15 U.S.C.
    § 717c(a). This requirement governs not only suppliers of
    natural gas, but also suppliers of natural-gas storage services.
    Schneidewind v. ANR Pipeline Co., 
    485 U.S. 293
    , 295 n.1
    (1988). FERC generally considers cost-based rates to be “just
    and reasonable,” and it allows market-based rates only if the
    seller shows that it lacks power in the relevant markets. N.
    Nat. Gas Co. v. FERC, 
    700 F.3d 11
    , 13 (D.C. Cir. 2012).
    FERC assesses market power in three steps: first, it defines
    the relevant product and geographic markets; second, it
    calculates share and concentration within those markets; and
    third, it considers other relevant factors. Alternatives to
    Traditional Cost-of-Service Ratemaking for Natural Gas
    Pipelines, 
    74 FERC ¶ 61,076
    , 61,231 (1996) (1996 Policy
    2
    Statement). The relevant product market includes both the
    specific service supplied by the firm at issue and “good
    alternatives,” which FERC defines as any other service “that is
    available soon enough, has a price that is low enough, and has
    a quality high enough to permit customers to substitute the
    alternative.” 
    Id.
     (citation omitted). Market share measures a
    firm’s ability to exercise market power unilaterally, whereas
    market concentration, as determined by the Herfindahl-
    Hirschman Index (HHI), measures the ability of sellers to
    exercise market power jointly. 
    Id. at 61,234
    . 1 Relevant
    factors that might prevent the exercise of market power, even
    for dominant competitors in concentrated markets, include the
    absence of entry barriers and the presence of countervailing
    buyer power. 
    Id. at 61,235
    .
    In 2012, petitioner ANR Storage Company sought
    authorization to charge market-based rates for its natural-gas
    storage services.       FERC referred the matter to an
    administrative law judge, who held a hearing, found that ANR
    had failed to show a lack of market power, and thus declined to
    authorize market-based rates. ANR Storage Co., 
    146 FERC ¶ 63,007
     (2014) (Initial Decision).
    On review, the Commission rejected various aspects of the
    ALJ’s reasoning, but ultimately affirmed his decision. ANR
    Storage Co., 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
     (2015) (Opinion No. 538).
    Among other things, FERC determined that the ALJ had erred
    by defining the relevant product market to exclude intrastate
    storage capacity as well as subscribed storage capacity
    1
    HHI is calculated by squaring the market share of each supplier in
    the market, then summing those numbers. HHIs range up to 10,000,
    the index for a market with only one seller; higher numbers indicate
    a more concentrated market. See W. Holmes & M. Mangiaracina,
    Antitrust Law Handbook § 6:5 (2017).
    3
    committed to specific buyers but subject to release. See id.
    PP 106–08, 162–63. After expanding the relevant product
    and geographic markets beyond those used by the ALJ, FERC
    recalculated ANR’s share to be 16.12% of the market for
    working gas and 15.16% of the market for daily deliverability,2
    and it calculated the HHIs for these respective markets to be
    951 and 1,010. Id. PP 183–213. FERC acknowledged that it
    had granted market-based rate authority to other natural-gas
    companies with similar shares, and it characterized the relevant
    HHIs as “low.” Id. PP 214–15. However, it expressed
    concern that ANR was the largest competitor in the market for
    working gas, and that a significant part of that market consisted
    of intrastate or subscribed storage capacity. Id. P 219. FERC
    ultimately concluded:
    Based on the size of the applicant in relation to
    the market, the relative lack of current
    competitors providing firm interstate storage
    service, the need for a substantial number of
    other facilities among the good alternatives to
    shift operations in order to offer firm interstate
    service, and also considering the fact that
    [ANR] is not a new entrant but a strong
    incumbent, the Commission finds that [ANR]
    has not met its evidentiary burden to show it
    lacks significant market power in the relevant
    markets.
    Id. P 220.
    2
    “Working gas” refers to the total amount of gas that may be
    withdrawn from a facility, whereas “daily deliverability” refers to the
    amount of gas that can be withdrawn in one day. Given the
    fluctuating and uncertain demand for natural gas over time, FERC
    considers both to be important market measures.
    4
    After FERC denied rehearing in large part, ANR Storage
    Co., 
    155 FERC ¶ 61,279
     (2016) (Rehearing Order), ANR
    sought review in this Court. We have jurisdiction under 15
    U.S.C. § 717r(b).
    II
    Under the Administrative Procedure Act, the question
    before us is whether FERC’s refusal to allow ANR to charge
    market-based rates was “arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of
    discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with law.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(A). To determine the answer, we focus on the
    reasons stated in the orders under review; we neither supply our
    own reasoning for the agency decision, SEC v. Chenery Corp.,
    
    332 U.S. 194
    , 196 (1947), nor consider the agency’s post-hoc
    rationalizations, Nat’l Petrochemical & Refiners Ass’n v. EPA,
    
    630 F.3d 145
    , 164 (D.C. Cir. 2010). Rather, the agency
    decision itself must be “reasonable and reasonably explained.”
    Nw. Corp. v. FERC, 
    884 F.3d 1176
    , 1179 (D.C. Cir. 2018). In
    particular, the decision must give a “reasoned analysis” to
    justify the disparate treatment of regulated parties that seem
    similarly situated, W. Deptford Energy, LLC v. FERC, 
    766 F.3d 10
    , 21 (D.C. Cir. 2014), and its reasoning cannot be internally
    inconsistent, see, e.g., Sierra Club v. EPA, 
    884 F.3d 1185
    ,
    1194–96 (D.C. Cir. 2018).
    ANR raises a host of challenges to FERC’s decision. We
    reject most of them, but conclude that two have merit.
    A
    ANR contends that FERC’s finding of market power
    conflicts with its own precedent. Primarily, ANR argues that
    shares around 16% cannot establish market power, at least in
    unconcentrated markets.        However, FERC has long
    5
    recognized that “market shares and HHIs alone do not give a
    comprehensive view of all important factors.” 1996 Policy
    Statement, 74 FERC at 61,235. Moreover, we cannot fault
    FERC’s analysis that, even in an unconcentrated market, a 16%
    share held by “the single largest storage provider,” Opinion No.
    538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    , P 219, is more concerning than
    comparable shares held by “new entrants to competitive
    markets that were dominated by other entities,” 
    id.
     P 215.
    Finally, we reject ANR’s contention that FERC’s decision is
    inconsistent with any of the prior reasoned decisions addressed
    at length by the parties. Instead, we conclude that FERC has
    reasonably distinguished decisions involving storage providers
    facing dominant competitors, e.g., Wyckoff Gas Storage Co.,
    
    105 FERC ¶ 61,027
    , PP 47–61 (2003); storage markets linked
    to large and highly competitive production markets in the Gulf
    Coast region, e.g., Copiah Storage, LLC, 
    121 FERC ¶ 61,272
    ,
    PP 24–25 (2007), reh’g granted on other grounds, 
    123 FERC ¶ 61,082
     (2008); and interruptible storage service that
    competes with other related products and services, e.g.,
    ONEOK Gas Storage, LLC, 
    90 FERC ¶ 61,283
    , 61,955 (2000).
    Nonetheless, we agree with ANR on one critical point—
    that FERC did not adequately distinguish its past decisions
    involving ANR’s principal competitor, DTE Energy Company.
    As ANR explains, FERC has permitted two of DTE’s
    subsidiary companies, Washington 10 Storage Corporation and
    Michigan Consolidated Gas Company (MichCon), to charge
    market-based rates for the last decade. When FERC granted
    that approval, DTE’s market share was over 18% for working
    gas and 17% for daily deliverability—slightly higher than
    ANR’s current shares. See Petition for Authorization to
    Charge Market-Based Rates at 8, Wash. 10 Storage Corp.,
    Docket No. PR08-26-000 (FERC May 30, 2008); Petition for
    Authorization to Charge Market-Based Rates at 10, Mich.
    Consol. Gas Co., Docket No. PR09-10-000 (FERC Dec. 23,
    6
    2008). Moreover, DTE was then a strong, established
    competitor, just as ANR is today. And by FERC’s own
    reckoning, ANR and DTE appear virtually indistinguishable
    with respect to their current market power: Critically, both
    companies compete in the same Central Great Lakes Market
    for natural-gas storage services. See Opinion No. 538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    , PP 141, 192–95. 3 And whereas FERC
    calculated ANR’s shares to be 16.12% of the market for
    working gas and 15.16% of the market for daily deliverability,
    
    id.
     P 213, its figures also indicate that DTE’s current shares are
    14.48% of the market for working gas and 18.02% of the
    market for daily deliverability, see 
    id.
     PP 195, 213; J.A. 1495,
    which hardly seem dispositively different.
    Despite these obvious similarities between the two leading
    suppliers in the relevant markets, the administrative orders at
    issue barely even mentioned FERC’s disparate treatment of the
    two companies. The ALJ tersely asserted that the MichCon
    order contained “no substantive analysis,” Initial Decision, 
    146 FERC ¶ 63,007
    , P 453, and the Commission itself simply
    noted—without further discussion—that the ALJ had declined
    to follow MichCon, Opinion No. 538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    ,
    P 83. The mere observation that MichCon was unreasoned
    does not satisfy FERC’s burden to provide some reasonable
    justification for treating ANR and DTE differently.
    3
    In this case, FERC found that ANR and DTE compete in a
    “Central Great Lakes” geographic market that encompasses
    Michigan, Illinois, Indiana, Ohio, and western Ontario. See
    Opinion No. 538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    , PP 113, 141, 192–95. In
    approving market rates for MichCon, FERC found that MichCon
    competed in a substantially similar “Great Lakes” geographic market
    that encompassed Michigan, northern Illinois, northern Indiana, and
    western Ontario. See Petition at 7–8, Mich. Consol. Gas Co.,
    Docket No. PR09-10-000 (FERC Dec. 23, 2008).
    7
    Before this Court, FERC suggests two variations on this
    theme. First, it notes that Washington 10’s application to
    charge market-based rates, unlike ANR’s, was unopposed.
    Putting aside the fact that MichCon’s application was opposed,
    this observation, too, fails to provide any reasonable
    justification for treating ANR and DTE differently. Second,
    FERC notes that the MichCon approval was effected through
    an order styled as a settlement, in which FERC purported to
    agree with MichCon that neither FERC, MichCon, “nor any
    other party shall be deemed to have approved, accepted,
    agreed, or otherwise consented to any principle or issue in this
    proceeding.” Letter Order at 4, Mich. Consol. Gas Co.,
    Docket Nos. PR09-10-000, PR09-10-001 (May 21, 2009).
    Despite this disclaimer, FERC could not lawfully have granted
    MichCon market-based rate authority unless it concluded that
    the company lacked power in the relevant market. See N. Nat.
    Gas Co., 700 F.3d at 13. Moreover, whatever the effect of the
    MichCon order as a settlement of claims between FERC and
    MichCon, neither of those parties could contract away FERC’s
    statutory duty—imposed by the APA and owed to all other
    regulated parties—to provide some reasonable justification for
    any adverse treatment relative to similarly situated competitors.
    Without more, FERC’s observation that its favorable treatment
    of DTE affiliates was effected through one unopposed order
    and one settlement provides no such justification.
    In its brief to this Court, FERC proposed a different
    justification for treating DTE better than ANR. According to
    FERC, when the DTE affiliates sought to charge market-based
    rates, their market power was checked because DTE’s largest
    competitor—ANR—charged cost-based rates. But when
    ANR sought to charge market-based rates, its market power
    posed a greater concern because ANR’s largest competitor—
    DTE—already was charging market rates. We frankly doubt
    that FERC may pick winners and losers in this way, based on
    8
    which of two otherwise indistinguishable competitors happens
    to win a race to the FERC equivalent of a courthouse.
    Nonetheless, we need not definitively resolve this question
    now. Because FERC did not even hint at its first-to-apply
    rationale in the orders under review, we cannot affirm on that
    basis. See Chenery Corp., 
    332 U.S. at 196
    . Accordingly, we
    need not and do not prejudge whether FERC may develop on
    remand a reasonable justification for such an approach.
    At oral argument, FERC floated one final proposed
    justification—that the market metrics of Washington 10 and
    MichCon, as relatively small affiliates of DTE, may be
    meaningfully different from those of DTE and thus ANR. At
    first glance, this rationale seems difficult to reconcile with
    FERC’s longstanding practice of attributing to each company
    the capacity of all affiliates. See, e.g., Opinion No. 538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    , P 193 (“Concerning affiliates, the [1996]
    Policy Statement requires that applicants aggregate the
    capacity of affiliated companies into one estimate.”). But
    because this rationale likewise was not asserted in the orders
    under review, we may not affirm on this ground, and we do not
    foreclose further development of this point on remand.
    On the record before us, ANR and DTE seem
    indistinguishable as leading competitors with virtually
    identical shares in the same relevant markets. Because FERC
    did not provide any reasonable justification for allowing DTE
    affiliates but not ANR to charge market-based rates, its
    decision is arbitrary and capricious.
    B
    ANR also challenges FERC’s market-power analysis
    regarding two particular categories of storage capacity: (i)
    storage in the intrastate as opposed to interstate market, and (ii)
    9
    storage already subscribed, but subject to capacity release. 4
    FERC trifurcated its analysis of these possible competitive
    alternatives to ANR’s service: first, it included them in the
    relevant product market; second, it deemed them “good
    alternatives”; but third, it deemed them not sufficiently good
    alternatives to constrain ANR’s exercise of market power.
    ANR contends that FERC’s analysis on these points was
    internally inconsistent. We agree.
    On the question of market definition, FERC explained that
    a relevant product market encompasses all goods or services
    “reasonably interchangeable” with those supplied by the
    company at issue, consistent with settled antitrust principles.
    Opinion No. 538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    , P 59 (citing United
    States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 
    351 U.S. 377
    , 395
    (1956)). Applying that definition, FERC concluded that
    interstate and intrastate storage services are reasonably
    interchangeable for two reasons. First, on the supply side of
    the market, “[f]acilities providing intrastate storage service
    need only alter their regulatory status in order to provide
    interstate storage service,” 
    id.
     P 107, and such providers can
    “quickly enter the interstate market upon a price increase,” 
    id.
    P 108. Second, on the demand side, “use of existing intrastate
    storage reduces the overall demand for interstate storage and
    can serve to discipline an anti-competitive price increase in the
    interstate storage market.” 
    Id.
     FERC therefore concluded
    that, “while distinctions between intrastate and interstate
    natural gas markets may be meaningful from a legal
    4
    “Capacity release” describes a transaction in which the holder of
    a contract to store or transport natural gas sells that right to another
    company seeking storage or transportation services. See, e.g., Pan-
    Alberta Gas, Ltd. v. FERC, 
    251 F.3d 173
    , 174–75 (D.C. Cir. 2001).
    10
    perspective, they are not meaningful from the perspective of
    market price formation.” 
    Id.
    FERC reinforced these conclusions in its analysis of
    competitive alternatives. Consistent with the 1996 Policy
    Statement, FERC stated that “a good alternative must be
    available soon enough, have a price low enough, and have a
    quality high enough to permit customers to substitute the
    alternative for the applicant’s service.” 
    Id.
     P 142. Then, it
    concluded that intrastate storage was a “good alternative” to
    interstate storage. In particular, it determined that suppliers of
    intrastate storage may obtain the necessary approval from
    FERC to enter the interstate market “soon enough to potentially
    discipline any attempt by [ANR] to raise prices above
    competitive levels.” 
    Id.
     P 163. Likewise, it concluded that
    subscribed capacity “that may reasonably be expected to
    become available” though a release also was a “good
    alternative.” 
    Id.
     P 162. For these reasons, FERC reversed
    the ALJ’s exclusion from the market of various intrastate and
    subscribed storage capacity. See 
    id.
     PP 186–211.5
    FERC then turned on a dime. Despite its inclusion of
    intrastate and subscribed facilities as good alternatives in the
    relevant market, FERC found “concerning” the “sheer number”
    of such facilities that would need to “enter the interstate market
    with available capacity” in order to constrain ANR. 
    Id.
     P 219.
    5
    We are uncertain how FERC viewed the relationship between the
    inquiries into product market and good alternatives. Compare, e.g.,
    Opinion No. 538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    , P 60 (“The Commission
    measures reasonable interchangeability of services in the same
    manner as it determines good alternatives.”), with 
    id.
     PP 58–110,
    142–65 (separately analyzing product market and good alternatives).
    Either way, the point is that FERC repeatedly described intrastate
    and fully subscribed capacity as economically meaningful
    substitutes, not merely theoretical ones.
    11
    For that reason, together with ANR’s status as a market leader,
    FERC concluded that ANR had not proven a lack of market
    power. See 
    id.
     P 220. Likewise, on rehearing, FERC
    reiterated its view that neither the demand nor supply impacts
    of intrastate and subscribed facilities would prevent ANR’s
    exercise of market power. Rehearing Order, 
    155 FERC ¶ 61,279
    , P 37.
    We recognize that substitutability is a question of degree,
    so it is possible that, for imperfect substitutes, there may be
    only limited shifting of consumption or production.
    Nonetheless, under normal antitrust standards, which FERC
    affirmatively invoked, Opinion No. 538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    ,
    PP 59–61, it makes little sense to conclude that alternatives
    within the relevant product market do not discipline
    anticompetitive price increases. To the contrary, the market
    includes only the “arena within which significant substitution
    in consumption or production occurs,” taking into account all
    relevant “commercial realities.” Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 
    138 S. Ct. 2274
    , 2285 (2018) (emphasis added) (citations omitted).
    More to the point, FERC itself, in deeming intrastate capacity
    to be a good alternative within the relevant product market,
    determined that intrastate suppliers could shift “easily,”
    “quickly,” and “economically” into the interstate market, and
    that “distinctions between interstate and intrastate natural gas
    … are not meaningful from the perspective of market price
    formation.” Opinion No. 538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    , PP 107–
    08 (emphasis added). Likewise, FERC included in the market
    not all subscribed capacity that theoretically might become
    available, but only capacity “that may reasonably be expected
    to become available.” 
    Id.
     P 162. Given this entire analysis,
    we fail to see how FERC could then conclude that any “delay”
    in supply shifts would be intolerably “concerning.” See 
    id.
    P 219.
    12
    Before this Court, FERC stresses that Opinion No. 538
    engaged in a detailed analysis of each of ANR’s possible
    competitive alternatives. True enough, but that very analysis
    determined that the intrastate storage facilities and subscribed
    facilities at issue were good alternatives within the relevant
    market. FERC did not suggest that these facilities would be
    incapable of checking ANR. See Opinion No. 538, 
    153 FERC ¶ 61,052
    , PP 186–210.
    The intervenors, who include customers and competitors
    of ANR, press a different point. They contend that, even if it
    is relatively easy for intrastate storage providers to obtain from
    FERC the necessary regulatory approval to provide interstate
    storage services, intrastate providers face various other
    restrictions on such shifting—including prohibitions imposed
    under state, local, or Canadian law. Because FERC did not
    adopt such reasoning in its administrative orders (or even in
    this Court), we cannot affirm on that basis. See Chenery
    Corp., 
    332 U.S. at 196
    . Again, however, we leave the issue
    open for further exploration on remand.
    There may be good reasons why intrastate or fully
    subscribed facilities would not check ANR’s exercise of
    market power, but FERC’s conclusion to that effect is
    inconsistent with most of it analysis on this point. Because
    FERC’s decision is internally inconsistent, it is arbitrary and
    capricious.
    C
    ANR’s other contentions lack merit. We note them only
    briefly, to avoid unnecessary litigation on remand.
    First, ANR challenges certain adverse rulings made by
    FERC on rehearing: the exclusion from the relevant market of
    13
    two previously included competitors (Dominion Transmission
    and NiSource, Inc.) and the attribution to ANR of the entire
    storage capacity of an affiliated company (Eaton Rapids). We
    find no error in these rulings, which would have increased
    ANR’s market shares at least slightly above the ones calculated
    in Opinion No. 538. Because FERC has not yet assessed the
    significance of these rulings, if any, we leave that issue open
    on remand.
    Second, ANR contends that FERC made certain
    computational errors in Opinion No. 538 itself. On rehearing,
    FERC concluded that these alleged errors were immaterial to
    its overall assessment. We cannot disagree, though we expect
    FERC to correct any outstanding errors on remand if it chooses
    to perform new calculations to account for its changed position
    regarding Dominion, NiSource, and Eaton Rapids.
    Finally, ANR contends that FERC failed to adequately
    consider other factors bearing on market power, such as the
    asserted lack of entry barriers and the mitigating measures
    proposed by ANR to protect its customers. We conclude that
    FERC permissibly rejected these arguments.
    III
    For the reasons given, we grant the petition for review, set
    aside the Commission’s orders, and remand for further
    proceedings consistent with this opinion.
    So ordered.
    14