Center for Sustainable Economy v. Sally Jewell , 779 F.3d 588 ( 2015 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued September 11, 2014              Decided March 6, 2015
    No. 12-1431
    CENTER FOR SUSTAINABLE ECONOMY,
    PETITIONER
    v.
    SALLY JEWELL AND BUREAU OF OCEAN ENERGY
    MANAGEMENT,
    RESPONDENTS
    AMERICAN PETROLEUM INSTITUTE, ET AL.,
    INTERVENORS
    On Petition for Review of Final Decision
    of the United States Department of Interior
    Michael A. Livermore argued the cause for petitioner.
    With him on the briefs was Steven Sugarman.
    David C. Shilton, Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice,
    argued the cause for respondents. With him on the brief were
    Robert G. Dreher, Acting Assistant Attorney General, and
    John E. Arbab, Attorney.
    Steven J. Rosenbaum, Bradley K. Ervin, Harry M. Ng,
    and Stacy R. Linden were on the brief for intervenors
    American Petroleum Institute, et al. in support of respondents.
    2
    Before: GARLAND, Chief Judge, PILLARD, Circuit Judge,
    and SENTELLE, Senior Circuit Judge.
    Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge PILLARD.
    Dissenting opinion filed by Circuit Judge SENTELLE.
    PILLARD, Circuit Judge: The Outer Continental Shelf
    (OCS) of the United States is a vast underwater expanse
    nearly equal in size to the Australian continent. Beginning a
    few miles from the U.S. coast, where states’ jurisdiction ends,
    the OCS extends roughly two hundred miles into the ocean to
    the seaward limit of the international-law jurisdiction of the
    United States. 1 Billions of barrels of oil and trillions of cubic
    feet of natural gas lie beneath the OCS. 2 There is enough oil
    beneath the OCS to replace America’s oil imports for 30 years
    and enough natural gas to supply all of America’s households
    for more than 80 years. 3 But drilling on the OCS can have
    1
    Federal law formally defines the OCS as the submerged lands,
    subsoil, and seabed lying between the seaward extent of a state’s
    jurisdiction (between three and nine miles, depending on the state)
    and the seaward limits of the United States’ jurisdiction under
    international law (roughly 200 miles). See 43 U.S.C. § 1331(a);
    
    id. § 1301(a).
    2
    Marc Humphries, Cong. Research Serv., RL33493, Outer
    Continental Shelf: Debate Over Oil and Gas Leasing and Revenue
    Sharing 14 (2008).
    3
    See U.S. Energy Info. Admin., DOE/EIA-0383, Annual Energy
    Outlook 2012 with Projections to 2035 62 (June 2012) (predicting
    residential natural gas consumption will remain nearly 5 trillion
    cubic feet per year through 2035); 
    id. at 131
    (predicting the United
    States will continue to import 3-3.5 billion barrels of oil annually
    through 2035). The OCS is estimated to contain as much as 94.5
    3
    potentially devastating effects on the environment. Concerns
    about the OCS’s ecological vulnerability and potential harm
    to coastal tourism led to moratoriums on OCS drilling in the
    Atlantic, the Pacific, parts of the Gulf of Mexico, and parts of
    Alaska for more than a quarter of a century, from 1982 until
    the moratoriums were partially lifted in 2009. 4 In 2010, the
    disaster on the Deepwater Horizon oil rig on the OCS
    renewed debate about the safety of offshore drilling. BP was
    drilling in mile-deep water 52 miles from shore when the
    subsea well ruptured and caused an oil spill spreading over
    thousands of square miles, damaging local economies,
    sensitive coastlines, and valuable wildlife throughout the
    region. 5 Multinational energy companies remain interested in
    offshore drilling on the OCS, and the Department of the
    Interior determined that additional leases for such drilling
    may be appropriate.
    The Outer Continental Shelf Lands Act (OCSLA) created
    a framework to facilitate the orderly and environmentally
    responsible exploration and extraction of oil and gas deposits
    on the OCS. It charges the Secretary of the Interior with
    preparing a program every five years containing a schedule of
    proposed leases for OCS resource exploration and
    development. 6 In light of the potential benefits and costs of
    billion barrels of oil and 449 trillion cubic feet of natural gas.
    See Humphries, supra note 2, at 14.
    4
    See Humphries, supra note 2, at 2, 8-9.
    5
    Dep’t of Interior, Increased Safety Measures for Energy
    Development on the Outer Continental Shelf 1 (2010).
    6
    A leasing program consists of a schedule of proposed lease sales
    and related planning steps for those sales. See 43 U.S.C. § 1344(a).
    It serves as the template for the Government’s leasing of drilling
    rights on the OCS for the five-year period following its preparation.
    Drilling on the OCS requires a lease that is included in the
    4
    OCS development, the Secretary’s program must balance
    competing economic, social, and environmental values in
    determining when and where to make leases available. Those
    obligations are set forth in Section 18 of OCSLA,
    43 U.S.C. § 1344.
    The Center for Sustainable Economy (CSE), an Oregon-
    based nonprofit organization working to “speed the transition
    to a sustainable economy,” Pet. Br. 23, challenges the
    Department of the Interior’s latest leasing program on the
    ground that the 2012-2017 leasing schedule fails to comply
    with the provisions of Section 18(a), which governs how
    Interior is to balance competing economic, social, and
    environmental values, 
    id. § 1344(a)(1),
    (3), quantify and
    assess      environmental        and     ecological      impact,
    
    id. § 1344(a)(2)(A),
    (H), and ensure an equitable distribution
    of benefits and costs between OCS regions and stakeholders,
    
    id. § 1344(a)(2)(B)-(G).
    CSE argues that Interior’s economic
    analysis violates OCSLA’s express terms by failing properly
    to consider environmental and market effects that the agency
    is required to address at the planning stage, and arbitrarily and
    irrationally fails to quantify many of the Program’s costs and
    benefits. CSE also argues that, in preparing its Final
    Programmatic Environmental Impact Statement (“Final EIS”),
    Interior violated the National Environmental Policy Act’s
    (NEPA) procedural requirements by using a biased analytic
    methodology and providing inadequate opportunities for
    public comment at the Draft EIS stage.
    Interior and Intervenor American Petroleum Institute
    (API) defend the Program as compliant with Section 18(a).
    They contend that, in opening up new areas of the OCS for
    approved leasing program, and the lease must contain provisions
    consistent with the approved program. See 
    id. § 1344(d)(3).
                                  5
    leasing, the Program rationally and appropriately balances the
    environmental, social, and economic values at stake. Interior
    and API also challenge CSE’s standing to petition this Court
    for relief, and API further argues that CSE’s NEPA claims are
    unripe. Both argue that CSE failed to preserve at least some
    of its arguments by failing to raise them in its comments to
    the agency.
    We deny CSE’s petition and conclude that: (1) CSE has
    associational standing to petition for review, (2) CSE’s NEPA
    claims are unripe, (3) two of CSE’s Program challenges are
    forfeited, and (4) CSE’s remaining challenges to Interior’s
    adoption of the 2012-2017 leasing schedule fail on their
    merits.
    I.
    Congress enacted OCSLA in 1953 to authorize the
    Secretary of the Interior to administer exploration and
    development of the OCS’s mineral resources. Pub. L. No. 83-
    212, 67 Stat. 462 (1953) (codified as amended at
    43 U.S.C. § 1331 et seq.). The 1953 Act empowered the
    Secretary to grant leases, but it did not establish statutory
    standards or guidelines to govern the Secretary’s decisions.
    California v. Watt (“Watt I”), 
    668 F.2d 1290
    , 1295 (D.C. Cir.
    1981). A quarter of a century later, Congress amended
    OCSLA in response to growing concerns about the United
    States’ dependence on foreign energy sources and
    intensifying awareness of the need for environmental
    safeguards. The 1978 Amendment sought to promote
    “expedited exploration and development of the Outer
    Continental Shelf in order to achieve national economic and
    energy policy goals, assure national security, reduce
    dependence on foreign sources, and maintain a favorable
    balance of payments in world trade,” while also ensuring
    6
    “protection of the human, marine, and coastal environments.”
    Pub. L. No. 95-372, 92 Stat. 629 (1978) codified at
    43 U.S.C. § 1802(1)-(2)). 7    The Amendment transformed
    OCSLA from “essentially a carte blanche delegation of
    authority to the Secretary of Interior,” Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1295
    (quoting H.R. Rep. No. 95-590, at 54 (1977) (Comm.
    Rep.)), into a statute with a “structure for every conceivable
    step to be taken” on the path to development of an OCS
    leasing site. 
    Id. at 1297.
    OCSLA now establishes both a procedural framework
    and a set of substantive requirements to govern how Interior
    opens up areas of the OCS for resource development.
    See 43 U.S.C. §§ 1334, 1337; Ctr. for Biological Diversity v.
    U.S. Dep’t of Interior (“CBD”), 
    563 F.3d 466
    , 472 (D.C. Cir.
    2009). Procedurally, Interior must undertake a four-stage
    process before allowing development of an offshore well,
    with each stage more specific than the last and more attentive
    to the potential benefits and costs of a particular drilling
    project. See 
    CBD, 563 F.3d at 473
    ; Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1297
    .
    In the first stage—the most general—Interior prepares a five-
    year program of proposed lease sales across the whole OCS.
    43 U.S.C. § 1344. In the second stage, Interior issues leases
    in accordance with the program. 
    Id. § 1337(a).
    In the third
    stage, Interior reviews lessees’ exploration plans. 
    Id. § 1340.
    In the fourth stage, Interior and affected state and local
    governments review lessees’ development plans. 
    Id. § 1351.
    Rigorous substantive requirements accompany each
    procedural stage. Congress calls on Interior to strike an
    appropriate balance at each stage between local and national
    environmental, economic, and social needs. In reviewing a
    7
    See H.R. Rep. No. 95-590, at 53-57, 89 (1977) (Comm. Rep.).
    7
    lessee’s exploration plans at the third stage, for example,
    Interior must ensure that, among other things, such plans “will
    not be unduly harmful to aquatic life in the area, result in
    pollution, create hazardous or unsafe conditions, unreasonably
    interfere with other uses of the area, or disturb any site,
    structure, or object of historical or archeological
    significance.” 
    Id. § 1340(g)(3).
    Similarly, in analyzing a
    lessee’s development plans at the fourth stage, Interior must
    ensure, among other things, that such development will not
    “probably cause serious harm or damage . . . to the marine,
    coastal or human environments.” 
    Id. § 1351(h)(1)(D)(i).
    CSE challenges the first stage of the 2012-2017 Leasing
    Program: Interior’s preparation of a five-year schedule of
    proposed leases and related planning steps under Section 18
    of OCSLA. See 
    id. § 1344.
    A program is required to
    “indicat[e], as precisely as possible, the size, timing, and
    location of leasing activity . . . for the five-year period
    following its approval,” 
    id. § 1344(a),
    and is to be prepared in
    a manner consistent with four principles set out in numbered
    paragraphs in Section 18(a). Briefly stated, those four
    principles are that Interior must: (1) account for all relevant
    “economic,      social,     and     environmental       values,”
    
    id. § 1344(a)(1);
    (2) use “existing” and “predictive”
    information to account for the interests of all relevant regions
    and stakeholders, 
    id. § 1344(a)(2);
    (3) strike a “proper
    balance” between resource potential and environmental
    impact, 
    id. § 1344(a)(3),
    and (4) assure that the Federal
    8
    Government receives “fair market value for the lands leased
    and the rights conveyed,” 
    id. § 1344(a)(4).
    8
    8
    43 U.S.C. § 1344(a) specifically provides that:
    [ . . .]
    (1) Management of the outer Continental Shelf shall be
    conducted in a manner which considers economic,
    social, and environmental values of the renewable and
    nonrenewable resources contained in the outer
    Continental Shelf, and the potential impact of oil and
    gas exploration on other resource values of the outer
    Continental Shelf and the marine, coastal, and human
    environments.
    (2) Timing and location of exploration, development, and
    production of oil and gas among the oil- and gas-
    bearing physiographic regions of the outer Continental
    Shelf shall be based on a consideration of—
    (A) existing     information     concerning the
    geographical, geological, and ecological
    characteristics of such regions;
    (B) an equitable sharing of developmental benefits
    and environmental risks among the various
    regions;
    (C) the location of such regions with respect to,
    and the relative needs of, regional and
    national energy markets;
    (D) the location of such regions with respect to
    other uses of the sea and seabed, including
    fisheries, navigation, existing or proposed
    9
    This first stage, involving approval of a leasing program,
    carries enormous “practical and legal significance.” Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1299
    . The key national decisions as to the size,
    timing, and location of OCS leasing—as well as the basic
    sealanes, potential sites of deepwater ports,
    and other anticipated uses of the resources and
    space of the outer Continental Shelf;
    (E) the interest of potential oil and gas producers
    in the development of oil and gas resources as
    indicated by exploration or nomination;
    (F) laws, goals, and policies of affected States
    which have been specifically identified by the
    Governors of such States as relevant matters
    for the Secretary’s consideration;
    (G) the relative environmental sensitivity and
    marine productivity of different areas of the
    outer Continental Shelf; and
    (H) relevant environmental and predictive
    information for different areas of the outer
    Continental Shelf.
    (3) The Secretary shall select the timing and location of
    leasing, to the maximum extent practicable, so as to
    obtain a proper balance between the potential for
    environmental damage, the potential for the discovery
    of oil and gas, and the potential for adverse impact on
    the coastal zone.
    (4) Leasing activities shall be conducted to assure receipt
    of fair market value for the lands leased and the rights
    conveyed by the Federal Government.
    10
    economic analyses and justifications for such decisions—are
    made at this first stage. See 43 U.S.C. § 1344(d)(3). The
    Program also creates important reliance interests. Federal,
    state, and local governments, and the companies that
    participate in national and international energy markets, form
    long-term plans on the basis of the leasing program. The
    leasing schedule is therefore “extremely important to the
    expeditious but orderly exploitation of OCS resources.”
    Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1299
    .
    At issue here is the 2012-2017 Program, the eighth five-
    year program Interior has prepared pursuant to the 1978
    Amendment. That Program includes 15 potential lease sales
    in six OCS planning areas: the Western and Central Gulf of
    Mexico, the portion of the Eastern Gulf of Mexico not
    currently under congressional moratorium, and the Chukchi
    Sea, Beaufort Sea, and Cook Inlet planning areas off the coast
    of Alaska. Twelve of the sales are planned for the Gulf of
    Mexico, and one sale each is planned for the three Alaskan
    areas.
    On October 26, 2012, CSE timely petitioned for review
    of Interior’s approval of the 2012-2017 Program. This Court
    has exclusive jurisdiction. See 43 U.S.C. § 1349(c)(1). Our
    analysis of the most recent Program is informed and guided
    by our four prior decisions regarding earlier leasing-program
    challenges. See CBD, 
    563 F.3d 466
    (challenging the 2007-
    2012 Program); Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc. v. Hodel
    (“Hodel”), 
    865 F.2d 288
    (D.C. Cir. 1988) (challenging the
    1987-1992 Program); California v. Watt (“Watt II”), 
    712 F.2d 584
    (D.C. Cir. 1983) (challenging the 1982-1987 Program);
    Watt I, 
    668 F.2d 1290
    (challenging the 1980-1985 Program).
    11
    II.
    We must address standing and ripeness issues at the
    threshold. See, e.g., 
    CBD, 563 F.3d at 475
    . Interior and API
    argue that CSE lacks standing to petition this Court, and API
    contends that CSE’s NEPA claims are unripe. For the reasons
    that follow, we hold that CSE has associational standing (also
    referred to as representational standing) to institute this
    petition, but that its NEPA claims are unripe.
    A.
    CSE has associational standing. An association has
    standing to bring suit on behalf of its members when: (1) “its
    members would otherwise have standing to sue in their own
    right;” (2) “the interests it seeks to protect are germane to the
    organization’s purpose;” and (3) “neither the claim asserted
    nor the relief requested requires the participation of individual
    members in the lawsuit.” Hunt v. Wash. State Apple Adver.
    Comm’n, 
    432 U.S. 333
    , 343 (1977).
    At the threshold, CSE submitted with its opening brief a
    declaration of its President averring that CSE is (and has been
    since its founding) a membership organization, and
    declarations of two members describing their concrete
    interests and confirming that CSE speaks for them in this
    litigation. See Talberth 3d Decl. ¶¶ 3-6; Wilson 2d Decl.;
    Shavelson 2d Decl. Once we determine that CSE is an
    organization eligible to assert standing on behalf of its
    members, we must inquire whether CSE meets all three of the
    Hunt requirements for associational standing.
    First, we consider the standing of the members who came
    forward. An individual has Article III standing to sue when
    she can show: (1) she has suffered an “injury in fact” that is
    concrete and particularized, and actual or imminent rather
    12
    than conjectural or hypothetical; (2) the injury is fairly
    traceable to the challenged action; and (3) it is likely, as
    opposed to merely speculative, that the injury will be
    redressed by a favorable decision. Lujan v. Defenders of
    Wildlife, 
    504 U.S. 555
    , 560-61 (1992).
    Two of CSE’s members, Diane Wilson and Bob
    Shavelson have standing to sue in their own right. Wilson is a
    commercial shrimper in the Gulf of Mexico who also makes
    significant recreational use of Gulf waters and coastlines.
    Wilson 2d Decl. ¶¶ 3-8, 19. Shavelson, an employee at an
    environmental nonprofit organization in south-central Alaska,
    makes significant recreational use of Cook Inlet and other
    Alaskan waters.        Shavelson 2d Decl. ¶¶ 3-5. Their
    declarations state that their economic and aesthetic interests
    would be harmed by additional leasing in the Gulf of Mexico
    and the Beaufort and Chukchi Seas off the Alaskan coast.
    Wilson 2d Decl. ¶¶ 15-17, 22-23; Shavelson 2d Decl. ¶¶ 4-5,
    7-11. Those harms are not conjectural or hypothetical: both
    individuals plan to continue using those specific marine and
    coastal ecosystems for commercial and recreational purposes
    during the years covered by the Program. Wilson 2d Decl. ¶¶
    3-4, 8, 16, 22, 24; Shavelson 2d Decl. ¶¶ 5, 9, 11. Wilson and
    Shavelson each also meet the requirements of causation and
    redressability. A leasing program that used incomplete
    economic analyses that failed rationally to account for
    leasing’s impact on the environment would harm their
    concrete economic and aesthetic interests, and their alleged
    harm would be redressed were we to invalidate the Program.
    See 
    CBD, 563 F.3d at 479
    . We are satisfied that CSE has at
    least two members with standing to sue in their own right.
    Second, the interests CSE seeks to protect are germane to
    its purpose.     The germaneness requirement mandates
    “pertinence between litigation subject and organizational
    13
    purpose.” Humane Soc. of the United States v. Hodel, 
    840 F.2d 45
    , 58 (D.C. Cir. 1988); see also 
    id. at 56-57.
    Germaneness is required for “the modest yet important”
    purpose of “preventing litigious organizations from forcing
    the federal courts to resolve numerous issues as to which the
    organizations themselves enjoy little expertise and about
    which few of their members demonstrably care.” 
    Id. at 57.
    CSE readily meets the germaneness requirement. CSE’s
    bylaws state that a purpose of the organization is “[t]o work
    through administrative and legal processes to promote public
    policies, plans, and programs that are grounded on
    ecologically sound and economically sustainable principles.”
    CSE Bylaws Art. I, § 1. CSE advocates in favor of natural
    resource preservation by, among other things, urging decision
    makers to “incorporat[e] non-market goods and services in
    benefit-cost analyses performed for economic policy making
    and government decisions” and to adopt alternative metrics,
    such as the “Genuine Progress Indicator,” that better account
    for environmental externalities than do traditional measures of
    GNP. See Talberth 3d Decl. ¶ 6.
    CSE’s specific goal in this litigation—to ensure that new
    offshore leasing is authorized only if necessary, economically
    justified, and environmentally safe—is unquestionably
    pertinent to CSE’s core organizational mission of “speed[ing]
    the transition to a sustainable economy” and “to a renewable
    energy platform.” 
    Id. And achieving
    that goal would
    advance CSE members Wilson and Shavelson’s concrete
    interests in the preservation of marine and coastal wildlife and
    ecosystems. This is not a case in which an organization seeks
    to litigate an issue about which it has little expertise and does
    not much care. CSE’s specific expertise is in evaluating the
    environmental costs and benefits of pursuing various energy
    alternatives, with the objective of making sure that agencies’
    14
    decisions accurately and rationally assess those alternatives’
    effects on natural resources. 
    Id. ¶¶ 3,
    6. 9
    Third, neither the claim asserted nor the relief requested
    requires the participation of CSE’s members in the lawsuit.
    Member participation is not required where a “suit raises a
    pure question of law” and neither the claims pursued nor the
    relief sought require the consideration of the individual
    circumstances of any aggrieved member of the organization.
    See Int’l Union, United Auto., Aerospace & Agric. Implement
    Workers of Am. v. Brock, 
    477 U.S. 274
    , 287-88 (1986); see
    also Warth v. Seldin, 
    422 U.S. 490
    , 515 (1975). CSE’s
    petition turns entirely on whether Interior complied with its
    statutory obligations, and the relief it seeks is invalidation of
    agency action. Neither the claims nor the relief require the
    participation of CSE’s members.
    Interior and API protest that CSE is not the kind of
    membership organization the Supreme Court identified in
    Hunt as capable of obtaining associational standing. They
    contend that CSE is a “think tank” with a “broadly defined
    mission” that “serves no discrete, stable group of persons with
    a definable set of common interests.” Resp. Br. 22-24
    (quoting Am. Legal Found. v. FCC, 
    808 F.2d 84
    , 90 (D.C.
    9
    Germaneness requires “pertinence between litigation subject and
    organizational purpose” not, as the dissent contends, germaneness
    of members’ injuries to organizational purpose. Humane Soc. of
    the United States v. 
    Hodel, 840 F.2d at 58-59
    . The difference is a
    significant one. The dissent correctly notes that “[a] book club
    could not assert associational standing to bring a tort action on
    behalf of one of its members bitten by a stranger’s dog.”
    Dissent at 4. But that is because the litigation subject (a dog bite)
    would not be pertinent to the organization’s purpose (reading and
    discussing books).
    15
    Cir. 1987)). As already noted, however, CSE has established
    that it is a traditional membership organization with a defined
    mission that serves a discrete, stable membership with a
    definable set of common interests. See Am. Legal 
    Found., 808 F.2d at 90
    ; Brady Campaign to Prevent Gun Violence v.
    Salazar, 
    612 F. Supp. 2d 1
    , 29 (D.D.C. 2009).
    CSE’s bylaws, along with the declarations of CSE’s
    members and its President, adequately demonstrate that it is
    an organization eligible to assert associational standing.
    CSE’s mission is “to promote public policies, plans, and
    programs that are grounded on ecologically sound and
    economically sustainable principles” through “administrative
    and legal processes.” CSE Bylaws Art. I, § 1; see Talberth 3d
    Decl. ¶ 6; Wilson 2d Decl. ¶ 2; Shavelson 2d Decl. ¶ 2. CSE
    is structured to serve the interests of its members: Formally,
    all of CSE’s current members are voting members entitled to
    elect its Board, no new voting members may join the
    organization unless approved by the present voting
    membership, and Board membership is limited to individuals
    who “have demonstrated a commitment to the mission and
    purposes of [CSE].” CSE Bylaws Art. IV, § 2; see 
    id. Art. III,
    § 1; 
    id. Art. IV,
    § 5; Talberth 4th Decl. ¶ 3; Talberth 3d
    Decl. ¶¶ 4-5. Functionally, CSE’s members and its President
    aver that they participate actively in CSE’s operations, and
    that CSE serves as a vehicle for the vindication of their
    interests. Talberth 3d Decl. ¶¶ 5-8; Wilson 2d Decl. ¶ 2;
    Shavelson 2d Decl. ¶ 2. In sum, CSE’s submissions suffice to
    establish that CSE is a traditional membership organization
    with standing to challenge Interior’s OCS Leasing Program.
    Our dissenting colleague contends that it is
    “inappropriate for the court to rely on [the petitioner’s] post-
    argument submission” of its bylaws and other evidence
    regarding standing, Dissent at 2, maintaining that to do so is
    16
    inconsistent with circuit rules. That is simply not the case. It
    is true that dissenting judges have repeatedly objected to such
    post-argument submissions, making many of the same
    arguments that our colleague makes today. See Americans for
    Safe Access v. Drug Enforcement Admin., 
    706 F.3d 438
    , 452-
    56 (D.C. Cir. 2013) (Henderson, J., dissenting); Public
    Citizen, Inc. v. Nat’l Highway Traffic Safety Admin., 
    489 F.3d 1279
    , 1298-99 (D.C. Cir. 2007) (Sentelle, J., dissenting); Am.
    Library Ass’n v. FCC, 
    401 F.3d 489
    , 496-97 (D.C. Cir. 2005)
    (Sentelle, J., dissenting). At the same time, however, panel
    majorities have consistently rejected those arguments. See
    Americans for Safe 
    Access, 706 F.3d at 444-45
    (“The point
    here is simple: under the law of this circuit, the members of a
    panel retain discretion to seek supplemental submissions on
    standing to fulfill the obligation of the court to determine
    whether the requirements of Article III have been met.
    Circuit Rule 28(a)(7) does not preclude this, nor does the law
    of the circuit.”); Public 
    Citizen, 489 F.3d at 1296
    (“This Court
    ‘retains the discretion to seek supplemental submissions from
    the parties if it decides that more information is necessary to
    determine whether petitioners, in fact, have standing.’”
    (quoting Am. Library 
    Ass’n, 401 F.3d at 494
    )); see also, e.g.,
    Am. Chemistry Council v. Dep’t of Transp., 
    468 F.3d 810
    , 815
    (D.C. Cir. 2006).
    We believe it was appropriate to rely on the petitioner’s
    post-argument submission of its bylaws and other evidence
    regarding standing. As we said in Americans for Safe Access,
    “[i]f the parties reasonably, but mistakenly, believed that the
    initial filings before the court had sufficiently demonstrated
    standing, the court may—as it did here—request supplemental
    affidavits and briefing to determine whether the parties have
    met the requirements for 
    standing.” 706 F.3d at 443
    (citation
    omitted). That is also the situation in this case. Promptly in
    response to API’s motion to dismiss the petition for lack of
    17
    standing, CSE submitted declarations of its President and two
    of its members. Those declarations describe CSE’s mission
    and bylaws, and set forth how CSE operates. CSE sought to
    use those declarations to establish that it is a traditional
    membership organization eligible to invoke associational
    standing under Hunt. See Talberth 3d Decl. ¶¶ 1-6; Wilson 2d
    Decl. ¶¶ 1-2; Shavelson 2d Decl. ¶¶ 1-2. At oral argument,
    the Court requested a copy of CSE’s bylaws to aid it in
    reaching a decision on the standing issue. Oral Arg. Rec. at
    3:25-6:25. CSE provided its bylaws to the Court shortly
    thereafter, and they, too, are a proper ground for our analysis
    here. This case thus presents a familiar mode of compliance
    with our rules: “Although Petitioner[] made a reasonable
    effort to satisfy the command of Circuit Rule 28(a)(7) in [its]
    opening [filing] by advancing evidence and arguments in
    support of standing, the court still had questions regarding
    whether the facts asserted by Petitioner[] were sufficient to
    satisfy the requirements of Article III standing. Therefore, the
    panel majority, adhering to well-established circuit law,
    requested supplemental [filings] after oral arguments.
    Nothing in the text of the rule bars the court from requesting
    such filings.” Americans for Safe 
    Access, 706 F.3d at 444
    .
    B.
    CSE’s NEPA claims are unripe. Interior violated NEPA
    in the Program’s Final EIS, CSE contends, by presenting a
    biased analysis of the so-called “no-action alternative” that
    undervalued OCS non-mineral resources in their natural and
    unaltered state. CSE sees a further NEPA violation insofar as
    Interior denied a meaningful opportunity for comment at the
    Draft EIS stage on Interior’s economic analyses, which CSE
    contends appeared for the first time when Interior
    simultaneously released the Final EIS and Final Economic
    Analysis Methodology, with “a wealth of new assumptions
    18
    and conclusions,” after the opportunity for comment on the
    draft documents had closed. Pet. Br. 59.
    As we recognized in CBD, “[i]n the context of multiple-
    stage leasing programs . . . [the] obligation to fully comply
    with NEPA do[es] not mature until leases are issued,” because
    only at that point has there been an “irreversible and
    irretrievable commitment of 
    resources.” 563 F.3d at 480
    (internal quotation marks omitted). Here, as in CBD, we
    confront a challenge to a multiple-stage program under which
    no lease sale has yet occurred and no irreversible and
    irretrievable commitment of resources has been made. As we
    reasoned in CBD, allowing NEPA challenges to be brought at
    this early stage, “when no rights have yet been implicated, or
    actions taken, would essentially create an additional
    procedural requirement for all agencies adopting any
    segmented program,” that “would impose too onerous an
    obligation, and would require an agency to divert too many of
    its resources at too early a stage in the decision-making
    process.” 
    Id. at 480-81.
    A petitioner “suffer[s] little by
    having to wait until the leasing stage has commenced in order
    to receive the information it requires. In the meantime . . . no
    drilling will have occurred, and consequently, no harm will
    yet have occurred to the animals or their environment.” 
    Id. at 481.
    In light of our holding in CBD, CSE’s NEPA claims
    must be dismissed as unripe.
    CSE and Interior argue, each for a different reason, that
    CSE’s NEPA challenges are ripe. Interior contends that
    because “challenges to [Interior’s] cost-benefit analysis would
    not be cognizable at later stages of the OCS process,” they
    should be considered ripe now. Resp. Br. 52. Interior is
    incorrect. CSE will have an opportunity to raise its NEPA
    claims, including its cost-benefit claims, in response to
    specific lease sales. That holding is at least implicit in CBD
    19
    and Wyoming Outdoor Council v. U.S. Forest Service, 
    165 F.3d 43
    , 49-50 (D.C. Cir. 1999), a case on which CBD
    substantially relies. See 
    CBD, 563 F.3d at 480
    (explaining that
    Petitioners would merely “hav[e] to wait” to bring their
    claims); Wyo. Outdoor 
    Council, 165 F.3d at 50
    (holding that a
    NEPA challenge was “premature” but not “preclude[d]”; once
    leases issued, the petitioner “was free to challenge the Forest
    Service’s NEPA compliance”).
    CSE contends that its NEPA claims are ripe because in
    Hodel, one of our prior decisions regarding an early OCS
    five-year leasing program, we addressed the merits of the
    petitioners’ NEPA challenges. 
    See 865 F.2d at 294-300
    . In
    Hodel, however, the ripeness of the petitioners’ NEPA claims
    (as distinct from their OCSLA claims) was not raised, and the
    court did not address it. In contrast, in CBD, our most recent
    decision addressing an OCS leasing program, we examined
    the ripeness issue in detail before concluding that petitioners’
    NEPA claims were unripe. See 
    CBD, 563 F.3d at 480
    -82.
    We do not set jurisdictional precedents sub silentio. See Ariz.
    Christian Sch. Tuition Org. v. Winn, 
    131 S. Ct. 1436
    , 1448
    (2011). Because Hodel did not consider the potential
    unripeness of the NEPA claims at issue in that case, we
    follow CBD to conclude that CSE’s NEPA claims are unripe.
    III.
    CSE raises six distinct challenges to Interior’s adoption
    of the 2012-2017 Program. All six are grounded in the same
    basic claims: that Interior either violated the dictates of
    Section 18(a) of OCSLA, or failed rationally to strike an
    appropriate balance between environmental costs and national
    energy needs as required under the Administrative Procedure
    Act, or both. Two of those challenges are forfeited because
    20
    they were not properly raised before the agency; the other
    four fail on their merits.
    A.
    Review of a five-year leasing program for compliance
    with OCSLA charts the typical contours of administrative
    review generally. We liberally defer to the agency’s findings
    of fact, upholding facts supported by substantial evidence; we
    review the agency’s policy judgments to ensure that they are
    neither arbitrary nor irrational; and we sustain the agency’s
    interpretation of its authorizing statute so long as we find it to
    be legally permissible. See 
    CBD, 563 F.3d at 484
    ; 
    Hodel, 865 F.2d at 300
    ; Watt 
    II, 712 F.2d at 590-91
    ; Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1300-03
    . Chevron’s two-step standard of review guides our
    deference to Interior’s interpretation of OCSLA. See 
    Hodel, 865 F.2d at 300
    (citing Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Res.
    Def. Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 842-45 (1984)).
    B.
    Two of CSE’s arguments were not preserved. OCSLA’s
    provision for judicial review states that “[s]pecific objections
    to the action of the Secretary shall be considered by the court
    only if the issues upon which such objections are based have
    been submitted to the Secretary during the administrative
    proceedings      related     to   the     actions     involved.”
    43 U.S.C. § 1349(c)(5). That provision embodies the general
    rule of administrative procedure that, “[t]o preserve a legal or
    factual argument, we require its proponent to have given the
    agency a ‘fair opportunity’ to entertain it in the administrative
    forum before raising it in the judicial one.” Nuclear Energy
    Inst., Inc. v. EPA, 
    373 F.3d 1251
    , 1290 (D.C. Cir. 2004)
    (citation omitted); see also United States v. L.A. Tucker Truck
    Lines, Inc., 
    344 U.S. 33
    , 36-37 (1952).
    21
    1.
    CSE argues that Interior violated Section 18(a)(3) by
    failing to quantify potential coastal and onshore impact from
    additional OCS leasing. See 43 U.S.C. § 1344(a)(3); see also
    
    id. § 1344(a)(1).
    CSE objects that Interior’s quantitative cost-
    benefit analysis assumes that coastal and onshore impact of
    OCS leasing can be mitigated to zero through “permit[]-
    related mitigation” at later program stages. J.A. 04675
    (Bureau of Ocean Energy Mgmt., U.S. Dep’t of the Interior,
    BOEM 2012-025, Forecasting Environmental and Social
    Externalities Associated with OCS Oil & Gas Development:
    The Revised Offshore Environmental Cost Model 95 (June
    2012)). Assigning zero cost, CSE contends, is irrational and
    violates our precedents interpreting Section 18(a). See 
    Hodel, 865 F.2d at 311
    (valuing wetlands lost to OCS-related
    infrastructure); Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1317
    (explaining that
    “consideration of environmental damage” may not be
    “postponed or foregone” to a later program stage). CSE
    contends that zeroing out at the initial, program stage
    important costs related to OCS leasing defers their
    consideration until a later program stage, in violation of
    Section 18(a)(3). Interior responds that it “specifically
    considered coastal and onshore impacts, including
    infrastructure issues”—albeit more qualitatively—“when
    performing the balancing required by Section 18(a)(3).”
    Resp. Br. 34.
    We do not determine the adequacy of Interior’s
    consideration, however, because CSE forfeited that claim.
    CSE failed to put Interior fairly on notice of the objection that
    its particular cost-benefit methodology inadequately
    quantified the coastal and onshore impact of additional OCS
    leasing. A footnote in CSE’s reply brief points to CSE’s own
    comment as grounds to find the issue preserved, but only two
    22
    passages in that forty-page comment even obliquely refer to
    potential damage to ecosystems generally, and the feasibility
    of quantifying such costs. One passage asserts that Interior
    failed to account for the “benefits . . . generated by a diverse
    array of ecosystem services provided by marine and terrestrial
    ecosystems affected by OCS leasing activities” and that “the
    reduction in these ecosystem service benefits should be
    counted as a Program cost.” J.A. 4314 (Ctr. for Sustainable
    Econ., Net Public Benefits Analysis of the Proposed Outer
    Continental Shelf Oil & Gas Leasing Program 16 (Feb.
    2012)). The second passage notes that “[s]uch losses can, and
    have been[,] quantified with peer-reviewed methods available
    to [Interior],” and provides one such estimate. 
    Id. at 4314-15.
    Those snippets did not fairly raise CSE’s objection. Read
    in the light most favorable to CSE, they suggest that Interior
    should have quantitatively accounted for the harms to marine
    and terrestrial ecosystems in its estimates of Program costs,
    and that such costs can be quantified. The question in
    determining whether an issue was preserved, however, is not
    simply whether it was raised in some fashion, but whether it
    was raised with sufficient precision, clarity, and emphasis to
    give the agency a fair opportunity to address it. See, e.g., RI
    Consumers’ Council v. Fed. Power Comm’n, 
    504 F.2d 203
    ,
    212 (D.C. Cir. 1974). With the benefit of hindsight and
    guided by petitioner’s briefing to the sentences on the specific
    pages where the issue was mentioned, we see a connection
    between the comment and the current objection. Interior did
    not have anything close to the kind of explanation we do now,
    however, nor the same opportunity to parse the record and
    decipher the claims arguably latent in only a few sentences.
    Even looking only at CSE’s own forty-page comment, it is
    hardly apparent in context that CSE was making what it now
    puts forward as an objection to the methodology by which
    Interior considered new leasing’s anticipated coastal and
    23
    onshore impacts. Interior received 280,189 comments on the
    2012-2017 Program, some of them dense and lengthy. We
    cannot conclude on this record that CSE fairly raised the
    objection it now presses to Interior’s method of assessing
    OCS drilling’s coastal and onshore effects.
    CSE does not attempt to explain how its two cited
    passages fairly raised its objections. When the government
    argues an issue is forfeited because it was not fairly raised,
    petitioners must explain why the issue was raised in a fashion
    sufficient to preserve it. Whether an objection is fairly raised
    depends on, among other things, the size of the record, the
    technical complexity of the subject, and the clarity of the
    objection. See, e.g., Nat’l Ass’n of Mfrs. v. U.S. Dep’t of
    Interior, 
    134 F.3d 1095
    , 1111 (D.C. Cir. 1998). As we have
    previously explained, “[t]he fact that, buried in hundreds of
    pages of technical comments . . . some mention is made [of an
    argument related to a claim brought on judicial review] . . . is
    insufficient to preserve the issue for review on appeal.” 
    Id. Because CSE’s
    comment did not provide Interior a fair
    opportunity to address CSE’s challenge, the argument is not
    preserved for our review.
    2.
    CSE also claims that Interior’s cost-benefit analysis is
    flawed because it was based on “the irrational assumption that
    all OCS leases will be developed.” Pet. Br. 32. According to
    CSE, most leases are never developed or are substantially
    delayed in development. A cost-benefit analysis that predicts
    that every OCS lease granted under the 2012-2017 Program
    will be developed, and developed promptly, would thus fail to
    account accurately for Interior’s experience with the leasing
    program. Any such assumption would, in CSE’s view,
    significantly distort Interior’s assessment of the benefits of
    24
    additional OCS leasing, and warrant vacating it as arbitrary
    and capricious.
    That claim, too, was not preserved, because CSE has not
    identified anything in the administrative record that could be
    construed as fairly raising it before the agency. CSE
    concedes its own failure to raise the point, but contends in its
    reply brief that another organization publicly commented on
    it.     See J.A. 4398 (Oceana Comment on the Draft
    Programmatic EIS for 2012-2017 Leasing Program, at 6).
    The comment CSE cites, however, did not address the
    adequacy of Interior’s cost-benefit analysis of projected lease
    development. It merely made the general point that no new
    leasing needed to be undertaken on the OCS for the next
    several years because lessees wanting to drill could instead
    develop inactive leases. See 
    id. That comment
    does not even
    indirectly make the claim CSE now advances, and therefore
    did not give Interior a fair opportunity to address it. See, e.g.,
    Koretoff v. Vilsack, 
    707 F.3d 394
    , 398 (D.C. Cir. 2013)
    (explaining that “[w]e require the argument petitioner
    advances to be raised before the agency, not merely the same
    general legal issue” (internal quotation marks and brackets
    omitted)).
    C.
    CSE’s first preserved challenge to the Leasing Program is
    that Interior’s cost-benefit methodology for evaluating new
    leasing on the OCS is irrational and violates Section 18. CSE
    particularly critiques Interior’s evaluation of the costs of
    forgoing drilling, i.e., choosing a “no-leasing option,” in
    Alaska. We begin our review by describing the relevant
    aspects of Interior’s methodology.
    The OCS is divided into four regions (Alaska, Pacific,
    Gulf of Mexico, and Atlantic) and, within those regions, 26
    25
    planning areas. Those regions and planning areas divide the
    OCS into discrete, though basically arbitrary, geographic
    sections. Pursuant to Section 18(a)(3), Interior conducts a
    cost-benefit analysis of offering each program area for
    drilling.      Interior’s cost-benefit analysis compared
    environmental and social costs of proposed OCS leasing in
    each program area with environmental and social costs of not
    authorizing additional leases on the OCS for the duration of
    the 2012-2017 Leasing Program. The agency sought to
    quantify “environmental costs (ecology and air quality) and
    social costs (recreation, property values, subsistence harvests,
    and commercial fishing[)], in addition to costs from activities
    associated with exploration, development, production and
    transportation that might occur with new OCS production and
    its most likely replacement.” J.A. 1872-73 (emphasis added).
    Interior makes clear that it used the replacement-cost
    methodology that CSE challenges in considering whether to
    propose additional OCS leasing: For each program area it
    considered, Interior determined that “the environmental and
    social costs of relying on substitute sources of energy are
    equal to or greater than the costs from producing area
    resources.” J.A. 1873.
    Interior’s inclusion of replacement energy costs in its net-
    cost analysis rests on the somewhat counterintuitive notion
    that not drilling for fossil fuels on the OCS would harm the
    environment. Interior’s premise is that, if the natural gas and
    oil obtainable from the OCS were not extracted, American
    energy users would turn to other sources to meet their energy
    needs. There are, in other words, opportunity costs of
    decisions not to drill. Interior’s projected substitute sources
    for OCS oil and gas include renewable and alternative energy
    sources, and reduced consumption. Interior also reasonably
    assumed, however, that the principal substitutes for forgone
    oil and gas from OCS leasing would be increased oil, natural
    26
    gas (and some coal) extracted from onshore sites, and oil (and
    some gas) transported from overseas. Meeting national
    energy demands from those sources carries its own
    environmental risks and harms, distinct from the familiar risks
    associated with extraction from the OCS, which Interior
    determined should be taken into account in evaluating OCS
    leasing.
    The dominant costs Interior attributed to obtaining energy
    from likely substitute fuel sources were air pollution from
    increased onshore extraction, and air pollution and potential
    near-shore oil spills from increased reliance on tankers to
    import substitute fuel, as well as other social and
    environmental disturbances. Interior reasonably assumed that
    the onshore natural gas extraction that would substitute for
    forgone OCS natural gas would occur nearer to domestic
    population centers, and so intensify such populations’
    pollution exposure. Similarly, Interior reasonably assumed
    that importation of substitute oil would increase tanker air
    emissions and near-shore oil spills along United States coastal
    and port areas. Interior concluded that, per unit of production,
    potential pollution from extracting oil and gas from the OCS
    many miles off shore would have less adverse impact on
    human health and property values than potential pollution on
    or near shore, close to densely populated and coastal areas.
    Interior reasonably chose an analytical approach that
    captured what it concluded are two significant elements of
    environmental and social assessment. First, in accounting for
    national costs of obtaining substitute energy, Interior assessed
    such projected costs wherever in the United States they were
    likely physically to occur; it did not restrict its assessment to
    costs that would be felt within an OCS Region or area’s
    geographic boundaries. Interior understood that the costs of
    forgoing leasing in favor of substitute sources—air pollution,
    27
    oil spills, and other disturbances—do not necessarily fall in
    any OCS Project Region, but are often experienced onshore,
    near shore, or in OCS areas not under consideration for
    leasing. If leasing on the OCS in Alaska were forgone, for
    example, environmental disturbances from any substitute
    source—such as fracking in Appalachia, drilling in
    Oklahoma, or importing Venezuelan oil or Trinidadian natural
    gas via tanker—would not be experienced in Alaska, but in
    Appalachia, Oklahoma, or along the coastal regions and ports
    trafficked by tankers from the source countries.
    Second, Interior attributed to each OCS planning area a
    proportionate share of the aggregate nationwide
    environmental and social costs that it calculated would arise
    from forgoing exploitation of the energy in that OCS area. If
    Interior estimated that a particular program area could
    produce 25 percent of the natural gas under the leasing
    program as a whole, it assigned to that area, as costs of
    forgoing leasing, 25 percent of the total national
    environmental and social cost associated with forgoing all
    OCS gas leasing and instead obtaining substitutes. Interior’s
    approach thereby sought to attribute to each OCS area a
    proportionate share of the national environmental costs of
    obtaining elsewhere the energy that the economy would
    demand if energy were not made available under an expanded
    OCS leasing program. The core idea of that economic
    attribution is that, if extracting natural gas from the Alaskan
    OCS would cause less net social and environmental harm
    nationwide than would obtaining natural gas from substitute
    sources, Interior’s cost-benefit analysis should favor leasing
    on the Alaskan OCS over forgoing it.
    CSE argues that Interior’s attribution methodology is
    irrational and violates Section 18, which CSE reads to require
    that Interior only attribute costs to OCS areas if they
    28
    physically arise within those areas. CSE points to the
    statutory requirement that Interior assess the relative
    “developmental benefits and environmental risks among the
    various [OCS] regions,” 43 U.S.C. § 1344(a)(2)(B), as well as
    each OCS area’s “relative environmental sensitivity,”
    
    id. § 1344(a)(2)(G).
    According to CSE, Congress would not
    have worded the statute that way unless it meant to require
    Interior to attribute to a particular OCS area only those
    environmental benefits and costs of forgoing exploration and
    development that physically occur there.
    Implicit in CSE’s position is that environmental effects
    that do not occur in any OCS area should be treated as
    irrelevant to Interior’s environmental calculus under OCSLA.
    For example, the costs of increased air pollution due to
    increased onshore natural gas extraction in the center of the
    country to substitute for forgone OCS drilling might not
    accrue within any OCS area and thus, under CSE’s
    methodology, would not be counted at all. CSE’s further
    implication is that inter-area comparisons should favor
    drilling in OCS areas that would be more harmed by resort to
    substitute sources, even if drilling in a different OCS area
    would equally reduce demand for the same substitute sources
    and their attendant harms, and would itself be less directly
    damaging.
    CSE contends that limiting attribution of costs to the
    areas in which they physically occur would accurately
    recognize that forgoing new OCS production in Alaska is
    more socially and environmentally beneficial than forgoing
    production in the Gulf of Mexico. Looking at the Alaskan
    OCS areas, the benefits of forgoing leasing in the pristine
    Alaskan wilderness are significant, while its costs are, in
    CSE’s analysis, “miniscule compared to [the costs of forgoing
    leasing in] non-Alaskan OCS areas.” Pet. Br. 27. Alaska is
    29
    lightly populated, relatively rural, far from major oil shipping
    lanes, and not rich in non-OCS fossil fuels, so any policy
    switch to substitute sources of oil and gas would be unlikely
    to involve environmentally harmful energy extraction or
    transportation in the Alaskan OCS areas.            Social and
    environmental costs physically felt on the Alaskan OCS
    would be quite low—rarely, if ever, outweighing the area-
    specific benefits of forgoing drilling there. In contrast, the
    Gulf’s OCS Region contains major shipping routes and ports
    that would receive added traffic from increased reliance on
    imported fuel, so significant risks and accompanying costs of
    oil spills from importing substitute oil would be physically
    experienced in the Gulf. Air pollution from onshore drilling
    in Texas also could affect the Gulf’s OCS Region. Thus, if
    attributed only where they occur, such substitute-source costs
    would tend to offset the area-specific benefits of forgoing
    leasing in the Gulf. CSE’s approach accordingly favors
    drilling in those areas that also happen to be where costs of
    substitute energy sources would be concentrated. The relative
    benefits of forgoing drilling in Alaska thus appear much
    greater under CSE’s methodology than under Interior’s.
    Interior’s approach, however, was neither expressly
    proscribed by the statute nor unreasonable. As a statutory
    matter, under Chevron, (1) unless its view is contrary to
    Congress’s clear intent (2) we defer to an agency’s reasonable
    construction of its governing 
    statute. 467 U.S. at 842-43
    . No
    clear congressional intent forecloses Interior’s construction of
    OCSLA.        Section 18(a) requires consideration of the
    particular ecological characteristics and environmental
    sensitivities of the various program areas, but does not specify
    30
    precisely how they must be considered.           43 U.S.C. §
    1344(a)(2)(B), (G). 10
    Interior’s decision to tabulate costs nationally and
    allocate them proportionally was reasonable. Its national
    focus comports with Section 18(a)’s directive that the
    Secretary develop a leasing program “which [s]he determines
    will best meet national energy needs.” 43 U.S.C. § 1344(a).
    It is also consistent with the statute’s broader statement of
    congressional purpose to treat “the [OCS] [a]s a vital national
    resource reserve held by the Federal Government for the
    public, which should be made available for expeditious and
    orderly development, subject to environmental safeguards, in
    a manner which is consistent with the maintenance of
    competition and other national needs.” 
    Id. § 1332(3).
    Those
    provisions, with their national focus, can reasonably be
    interpreted to support Interior’s understanding of Section
    18(a). Nothing in Section 18(a) requires CSE’s methodology
    over Interior’s.
    As a policy matter, Interior made a reasonable and
    considered judgment to allocate national social and
    environmental costs of substitute energy to OCS program
    areas in proportion to their energy-producing potential. If
    Interior had instead chosen to recognize only those costs of
    forgone production (e.g., those associated with increased
    imports) to the extent that they were physically experienced
    within the program area of the leasing under consideration, its
    analysis would have differed significantly. It could not have
    10
    We do not decide whether Section 18(a) would have permitted
    Interior, had it so chosen, to limit its substitute-energy cost
    considerations to OCS-harming costs, or whether, as CSE urges,
    the agency might permissibly have attributed costs only to the
    particular OCS area in which they physically would occur.
    31
    accounted for costs of an OCS area’s no-lease option that
    would be felt outside that area, or outside the OCS. It would
    also have impeded Interior’s ability to make cost-benefit
    comparisons between potential leasing in different program
    areas. It would have favored new leasing in the Gulf over
    new leasing in Alaska, for example, without regard for how
    little oil the Gulf of Mexico’s OCS might contain, or how
    great might be the untapped energy potential of the Alaskan
    OCS.
    Interior instead reasonably determined that the relative
    costs of leasing in various OCS program areas should take
    into account each area’s potential to minimize total national
    environmental impact. Its methodology recognizes that the
    national social and environmental costs of substitute energy
    demanded by a no-lease option are largely unaffected by the
    location of the no-lease option; they are a function of the
    amount of energy extraction forgone, and can be avoided by
    drilling anywhere for a commensurate amount of energy.
    Interior recognizes that, if a methodology only takes account
    of the costs of substitute energy when those costs happen to
    fall within the OCS program area under consideration, the
    methodology will arbitrarily favor drilling there to avoid those
    costs—even though, separately considered, the costs of
    drilling itself might be lower elsewhere.
    In sum, CSE’s proposed methodology would effectively
    prioritize the cleanliness of remote Alaskan wilderness areas,
    whereas Interior’s methodology also accounts for the
    harmfulness of onshore and near-shore pollution associated
    with substitute energy sources. Interior counts those costs
    wherever they occur within the United States, and attributes
    them to OCS areas in proportion to the area’s potential energy
    reserves. Doing so means that Interior counts as more costly
    pollution affecting densely populated areas that impinges
    32
    more immediately on human health and welfare than pollution
    occurring far from most human life. Interior’s judgments may
    be debatable. Some, like CSE, may reasonably conclude they
    are not the best judgments. But they are legally permissible.
    We hold that Interior’s decision to take a national
    perspective, and to attribute nationwide environmental and
    social costs to particular OCS areas in proportion to the
    amount of production expected from each area if leasing and
    production were allowed there, was both reasonable and
    consistent with Section 18(a) of OCSLA.
    D.
    CSE maintains that the economic analysis underlying the
    Program irrationally fails to track the proportion of OCS
    energy consumed by the American public. According to
    CSE, that failure means that Interior is not complying with the
    statutory mandate to develop OCS resources to meet “national
    energy      needs.”          43 U.S.C. § 1344(a);       See also
    
    id. § 1344(a)(2)(C)
    (requiring Interior to consider “the relative
    needs of [] regional and national energy markets”);
    
    id. § 1332(3)
    (“the [OCS] is a vital national resource” to be
    developed to meet “national needs”); 
    id. § 1802(2)(A)
    (a
    policy underlying OCSLA is “to meet the Nation’s energy
    needs”). In CSE’s view, any OCS energy sold in foreign
    markets cannot have been produced to meet America’s
    “national needs.” We reject that claim. Interior did not need
    to earmark where OCS fuel is finally consumed in order
    rationally to consider national energy needs. Interior’s
    analyses of energy markets were reasonable on the facts
    before it.
    OSCLA does not mandate that Interior track what
    proportion of OCS-derived fuels are consumed in the United
    States. CSE equates the statutory mandate that Interior
    33
    consider the nation’s “energy needs” with only one potential
    element of those needs: meeting current demand for domestic
    consumption of finished energy products. The Act’s mandate
    is not so confined. National energy needs may be addressed
    by Interior’s consideration of total energy production
    capacity, without regard to where the energy would ordinarily
    be consumed. Any capacity that is developed domestically
    helps to ensure that the United States has available domestic
    sources of fuel for domestic consumption as needed, for
    example, in the event of international conflict, natural
    disaster, unexpected foreign fuel shortages, or price volatility
    in international markets. See 43 U.S.C. § 1802(1) (listing
    “assur[ing] national security, reduc[ing] dependence on
    foreign sources, and maintain[ing] a favorable balance of
    payments in world trade” among OCSLA’s express
    purposes); see also J.A. 1849, 1853 (Bureau of Ocean Energy
    Mgmt., U.S. Dep’t of the Interior, Proposed Final Outer
    Continental Shelf Oil & Gas Leasing Program: 2012-2017
    (June 2012)). OSCLA thus cannot be read, as CSE suggests,
    to require Interior to monitor the ultimate consumption point
    of OCS energy.
    There is nothing irrational about Interior’s choice in
    developing the 2012-2017 Program not to earmark the point
    of consumption of OCS-derived energy. In considering the
    impact of additional OCS leasing on domestic demand,
    Interior reasonably assessed additional leasing’s impact on
    domestic and international fuel markets. Because oil and
    natural gas are fungible and traded on integrated global
    markets, it does not matter precisely where any particular
    barrel of oil or cubic foot of natural gas is consumed. A
    barrel of OCS fuel consumed abroad has a direct impact on
    America’s domestic energy supply. If a barrel of Alaskan
    OCS-derived oil is consumed in northern Canada, freeing a
    barrel of southern Canadian oil for import into the United
    34
    States, the net effect on the United States’ domestic fuel
    supply is the same as if the Alaskan oil were consumed in the
    United States. For that reason, Interior does not need to label
    and follow OCS oil from platform to port to consumer in
    order to find that it helps to meet the United States’ national
    energy needs; it is enough for Interior to take into account
    OCS fuel’s impact on national and international energy
    markets. See 43 U.S.C. § 1344(a)(2)(C) (requiring Interior to
    consider “the relative needs of [] regional and national energy
    markets” in determining the location and timing of new OCS
    leasing).
    In the 2012-2017 Program, for example, Interior took
    careful account of future global and domestic oil and natural
    gas demand. Drawing on United States Energy Information
    Administration (“EIA”) forecasts, Interior projected out to
    2035 the demand for OCS fuel in national and international
    energy markets. J.A. 1848-62. Interior concluded that the
    United States would remain a net oil importer through 2035,
    J.A. 1851, 1853, but may become a net exporter of natural gas
    as early as 2016, J.A. 1851-52, 1855. Interior also expects that
    global energy demand will increase over the next several
    decades, leading to upward price pressure as “economies such
    as those of China and India” increase their crude oil
    consumption. J.A. 1854. Higher global prices would hinder
    American consumers’ ability to meet their energy needs. OCS
    oil could help to mitigate those adverse price effects. Interior
    thus has rationally considered available projections of
    national energy needs.
    CSE adds a wrinkle to its protest based on the fact that
    Interior only assessed the markets for unprocessed fuels, not
    markets for gasoline, diesel, and kerosene (“finished
    petroleum products”) that are refined from unprocessed OCS
    fuel. CSE contends that demand in markets for unprocessed
    35
    fuels could reflect domestic refinery demand—i.e., demand
    for crude oil to be refined in the United States for
    consumption abroad—rather than demand for American
    consumption. CSE claims that the market for unprocessed oil
    is a poor proxy for assessing the impact of additional OCS
    leasing on the nation’s “energy needs” because much of the
    energy derived from the OCS and temporarily “needed” in
    refineries here ends up exported as finished petroleum
    products consumed overseas.
    CSE’s point is well taken in general, but Interior’s
    reliance on data regarding unprocessed fuels was in this case
    reasonable. Interior’s decision not to account separately for
    data on finished petroleum product markets did not
    significantly affect its assessment of the nation’s “energy
    needs” and “energy markets,” 43 U.S.C. §§ 1344(a)(2)(C),
    1802(2)(A). The weight of the evidence is that American
    crude oil demand will primarily reflect domestic demand for
    finished petroleum products over the next half century.
    See U.S. Energy Info. Admin., DOE/EIA-0383, Annual
    Energy Outlook 2012 with Projections to 2035 131 (June
    2012) (“Appendix A”) (projecting that the United States will
    consume ninety-eight percent of its “liquid fuels and other
    petroleum” through 2035) cross-cited at J.A. 1849. Interior is
    permitted, under Chevron, to use markets for crude oil and
    natural gas as proxies for the nation’s “energy markets” and
    “energy needs,” as long as doing so is reasonable. In light of
    the difficulty of predicting the behavior of energy markets
    over decades-long time horizons, we have long afforded
    Interior substantial latitude to attempt to predict long-term
    energy market demand. See Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1309
    . Given
    the latitude that Watt I affords, and the fact that the EIA
    estimates that the overwhelming majority of refined
    petroleum products will be consumed domestically over that
    time span, Interior’s 2012-2017 Leasing Program reasonably
    36
    uses markets for crude oil and natural gas (domestic and
    international) as proxies for the nation’s energy needs. 11
    Contrary to CSE’s contentions, Interior reasonably
    concluded that what matters in determining whether OCS-
    derived fuel meets national needs is not whether the
    additional OCS fuel is consumed domestically, but whether it
    helps to satisfy domestic needs for fuel security and net
    supply, both in the aggregate and over time. Interior’s
    consideration of the impact of OCS production on national
    energy needs was adequate without specific tracking of the
    final consumption point of finished OCS fuels.
    E.
    CSE argues that, in allowing new OCS leasing between
    2012 and 2017, Interior irrationally assumed that all of the
    11
    OCSLA does not make assessment of the impact of OCS leasing
    on markets for finished petroleum products mandatory under
    Chevron step one, but it also does not permit Interior to ignore
    those markets entirely. In CBD, we concluded that OCSLA was
    sufficiently ambiguous to permit Interior to forgo consideration of
    climate-related effects of burning OCS-derived fossil fuels, and to
    allow Interior to limit its consideration of the environmental impact
    of OCS 
    leasing. 563 F.3d at 485
    . The statutory ambiguity in the
    words “energy markets,” 43 U.S.C. § 1344(a)(2)(C), and “energy
    needs,” 
    id. § 1802(2)(A)
    , is narrower. Interior is not required to
    map out the supply and demand in every downstream petroleum
    product market. Such markets and needs may be understood to
    encompass every type of energy and every type of energy market
    affected by OCS leasing, including markets for consumer fuels.
    The terms “energy markets” and “energy needs,” however, do
    mandate that Interior reasonably assess the impact of additional
    OCS leasing on the nation’s supply of energy when necessary, not
    just the effect on the national supply of unrefined fossil fuels.
    37
    energy produced by the new leases would be consumed
    domestically, thereby implying in its projections that any
    forgone OCS leasing would require a commensurate increase
    in either onshore domestic production or importation for
    domestic consumption. CSE contends that Interior failed to
    consider that the United States may soon become a net
    exporter of fossil fuels. It therefore irrationally failed, in
    CSE’s view, to consider that forgone OCS production could
    merely lead to reduced fuel exports, with no need to increase
    imports or onshore excavation to meet domestic demand.
    That claim, like the previous one, misapprehends
    Interior’s analysis. CSE’s contention that Interior irrationally
    assumed that all OCS-derived fuel would be consumed
    domestically is factually incorrect. In summarizing the results
    of its economic model in its Program and Economic Analysis
    Methodology, Interior recounted its predictions that forgoing
    additional leasing on the OCS would cause an increase in the
    use of substitute fuels such as renewables, coal, imported oil
    and natural gas, and a reduction in overall domestic energy
    consumption from greater efforts to conserve in the face of
    higher prices. J.A. 1859-60, 1976. Interior considered not
    only the potential need for substitute sources of fuel for the
    domestic market likely to result from deferral of additional
    OCS production, but also decreases in oil imports and natural
    gas exports. J.A. 4873 cited at J.A. 1859. As explained
    above, Interior sought to predict domestic and global energy
    demand over the life of the leasing program, 
    see supra
    Part
    III.D, concluding that the United States would remain a net
    importer of oil through 2035, while shifting during the same
    period to net exportation of natural gas.            J.A. 1851;
    See generally J.A. 1848-62. Interior predicted that net oil
    imports would increase to make up for the shortfall in
    domestic oil supply, J.A. 1857-59, and it specifically took
    account of reductions in natural gas exports, as well as
    38
    sharply lower domestic natural gas demand due to substitution
    effects, in the event of no new OCS leasing, see J.A. 4873
    cited at J.A. 1859.
    Because Interior carefully considered the impact that
    forgoing new OCS leasing would have on the nation’s energy
    needs, and did not ignore the possibility that the United States
    could become a net exporter of some fuels over the next half
    century, CSE’s challenge to Interior’s domestic-needs
    analysis lacks merit.
    F.
    CSE argues that Section 18 of OCSLA required Interior
    explicitly to quantify the “informational value,” also known
    as the “option value,” of delaying OCS leasing. Section 18
    requires Interior to schedule the leasing of OCS mineral
    resources at the time that best meets national energy needs.
    See 43 U.S.C. § 1344(a). Interior could authorize new leasing
    this year, next year, or in fifty years. Every day that Interior
    waits has a cost insofar as valuable fuel that could be used
    today instead lies dormant. See Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1320
    . But
    waiting also has benefits, including what is referred to as
    informational value. More is learned with the passage of
    time: Technology improves. Drilling becomes cheaper, safer,
    and less environmentally damaging. Better tanker technology
    renders oil tanker spills less likely and less damaging. The
    true costs of tapping OCS energy resources are better
    understood as more becomes known about the damaging
    effects of fossil fuel pollutants. Development of energy
    efficiencies and renewable energy sources reduces the need to
    rely on fossil fuels. As safer techniques and more effective
    technologies continue to be developed, the costs associated
    with drilling decline. There is therefore a tangible present
    economic benefit to delaying the decision to drill for fossil
    39
    fuels to preserve the opportunity to see what new technologies
    develop and what new information comes to light.
    Economists have crafted techniques for quantifying, in at least
    some situations, such informational value or option value of
    delaying decisions. 12
    CSE builds its informational-value claim out of two
    principles articulated in Section 18 and our prior opinions.
    First, Section 18 requires Interior to evaluate the advantages
    and disadvantages of delaying and forgoing leasing in
    determining when leases should issue. See 43 U.S.C. §
    1344(a)(3), (a)(2)(H). Second, Interior must quantify costs
    when possible, especially where those costs are “not
    inherently insusceptible of quantitative analysis.” Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1319
    . CSE contends that, because the informational
    value of delay is a relevant cost and it is susceptible of
    quantification, Interior acted irrationally in failing to quantify
    it.
    We are not persuaded that the informational value of
    delay is yet so readily quantifiable that Interior acted
    unreasonably in choosing not to quantify it in this planning
    cycle. Rather than assign a specific dollar value in the 2012-
    12
    The informational value of delay is also the option value of delay
    because an effectively irreversible decision that can be made at the
    time of an actor’s choosing is, in economic terms, a kind of option.
    Financial options—the right to buy or sell a security at a specified
    price within a set time—are the most familiar options, but any
    decision in which one of the available choices is “delay the
    decision” behaves like an option. Such options are sometimes
    called “real options” to distinguish them from financial options.
    See, e.g., Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Embedded Options
    and the Case Against Compensation in Contract Law, 104 Colum.
    L. Rev. 1428, 1460 (2004).
    40
    2017 Program to delaying leasing on the OCS, Interior
    qualitatively considered the informational value of delay. In
    its evaluation of alternatives in the Programmatic EIS, for
    example, Interior considered whether to “[d]elay sales until
    further evaluation of oil spill response, drilling safety reform,
    and baseline environmental conditions [were] collected and
    analyzed,” “[d]efer deepwater leasing in the [Gulf of Mexico]
    planning areas,” and “[d]evelop alternative/renewable energy
    sources as a complete or partial substitute for oil and gas
    leasing on the OCS.” J.A. 2147-48. The Proposed Final
    Program also described the process Interior is developing to
    “continue to use incoming scientific information and
    stakeholder feedback to proactively determine, in advance of
    any potential sale, which specific areas offer the greatest
    resource potential while minimizing potential conflicts with
    environmental and subsistence considerations.” J.A. 1755. In
    part on the basis of its qualitative assessment of the
    informational value of delay, Interior chose to postpone
    leasing in the Chukchi and Beaufort Sea program areas until
    late in the Program to allow gathering of additional
    information. J.A. 1842.
    CSE does not dispute that Interior qualitatively
    considered the informational value of delay; it argues that
    Interior’s failure to assess the informational value of delay
    quantitatively was irrational. We are persuaded, however,
    that the methodology for valuing the informational
    advantages of delaying offshore oil development is not
    sufficiently well established to render irrational Interior’s
    decision not to use it in the 2012-2017 Program. Our
    decisions afford greater leeway to Interior to evaluate
    qualitatively costs that are difficult to quantify. See, e.g.,
    Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1317
    -18. “Where existing methodology or
    research in a new area of regulation is deficient, the agency
    necessarily enjoys broad discretion to attempt to formulate a
    41
    solution to the best of its ability on the basis of available
    information.” Watt 
    II, 712 F.2d at 600
    (quoting Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1301
    n.18). To that end, in making timing decisions,
    Interior is generally “free to choose any methodology so long
    as it is not irrational.” 
    CBD, 563 F.3d at 488
    (internal
    quotation marks omitted).
    CSE neither identifies in the record, nor itself puts
    forward, a methodology for pricing the informational value of
    delay in the context of offshore oil and gas leasing that is
    sufficiently established to render arbitrary or irrational
    Interior’s decision to opt instead for a qualitative analysis.
    When reviewing the rationality of Interior’s methodological
    selections, we have looked to, among other factors, whether
    the methodology has been “performed extensively in the
    past.” Watt 
    II, 712 F.2d at 600
    . CSE acknowledges that there
    is no established practice of quantifying informational values
    stemming from environmental impacts in the petroleum
    industry, and that Interior has never before sought to
    undertake such an analysis. See Pet. R. Br. 23.
    The difficulties in undertaking such a quantitative
    analysis are great. Pricing the value of delay would require
    Interior to make complex estimates of the pace and nature of
    likely future trends in the development of various
    technological and scientific fields affecting drilling,
    transportation, oceanography, and alternative energy. Interior
    would also be required to attempt to quantify the value of
    future, as-yet-unknown benefits and harms of OCS
    development, and the probability of countervailing
    developments that could enhance those benefits or mitigate
    those harms. Many difficult choices would need to be made
    and justified, and a “substantial amount of data” would need
    to be gathered. Michael A. Livermore, Patience Is an
    Economic Virtue: Real Options, Natural Resources, and
    42
    Offshore Oil, 84 U. Colo. L. Rev. 581, 639 (2013). Even if
    Interior had an adequate methodology in hand, it might
    rationally have viewed such an unprecedented analysis as
    unduly time-consuming and error-prone.           As we have
    explained in prior opinions, “the final decision as to how
    much analysis is necessary in view of the available data must
    be the agency’s, subject to judicial review only for obviously
    incorrect results or methodology.” Watt 
    II, 712 F.2d at 600
    (quoting Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1317
    n. 224); see also 
    Hodel, 865 F.2d at 309
    . So, too, here. Interior acted reasonably in
    employing qualitative, rather than quantitative, measures of
    the informational value of delay.
    Our holding is a narrow one. In preparing a five-year
    program, the agency is not permitted to substitute qualitative
    assessments for well-established quantitative methods
    whenever it deems such substitutions convenient. See 
    Hodel, 865 F.2d at 308-09
    . But Interior permissibly concluded that
    Section 18 does not require it to employ methods of cost-
    benefit analysis at the “frontiers of scientific knowledge.”
    See Watt 
    II, 712 F.2d at 600
    (quoting Watt 
    I, 668 F.2d at 1301
    ). Had the path been well worn, it might have been
    irrational for Interior not to follow it.            Under the
    circumstances it faced, Interior might permissibly have blazed
    a new trail. It was not, however, required to do so. We
    therefore reject CSE’s argument that Interior acted irrationally
    in failing to quantify the informational value of delay. We are
    satisfied that Interior’s qualitative analysis of the benefits of
    delaying leasing was adequate, and that methods for
    quantifying the time value of delaying leasing on the OCS are
    not yet so well established that Interior was required to use
    them in developing the 2012-2017 Leasing Program.
    43
    ***
    For the foregoing reasons, we deny the petition for
    review.
    SENTELLE, Senior Circuit Judge, dissenting: I respectfully
    cannot join my colleagues’ opinion and judgment denying the
    petition for review. I dissent, not because I disagree with my
    colleagues’ reasoning, nor because I would sustain the petition.
    Rather, I would dismiss the petition for lack of standing.
    Therefore, I would not reach the merits of the case, and I express
    no disagreement with my colleagues’ decision on the same.
    As the majority rightly notes, we must address standing “at
    the threshold.” Maj. Op. at 11 (citing Center for Biological
    Diversity v. Dep’t of Interior, 
    563 F.3d 466
    , 475 (D.C. Cir.
    2009)). “The party invoking federal jurisdiction,” in this case
    petitioner, “bears the burden of establishing [standing].” Lujan
    v. Defenders of Wildlife, 
    504 U.S. 555
    , 561 (1992). Petitioner,
    Center for Sustainable Economy (CSE), has not borne that
    burden. CSE asserts that it has associational standing. To
    establish associational standing to bring an action on behalf of
    its members, an association must bear its burden with respect to
    three elements, showing that:
    (1) its members would otherwise have standing to sue in
    their own right;
    (2) the interests it seeks to protect are germane to the
    organization’s purpose; and
    (3) neither the claim asserted nor the relief requested
    requires the participation of individual members in the
    lawsuit.
    Hunt v. Wash. State Apple Adver. Comm’n, 
    432 U.S. 333
    , 343
    (1977). In its original filings, CSE failed to show even that it
    was a membership organization of the sort recognized in
    precedent as capable of asserting associational standing under
    Hunt. It was only after oral argument that CSE, at this court’s
    2
    prompting, came forward to file its bylaws and other evidence
    purporting to show its standing to bring this action. Intervenor
    American Petroleum Institute objects that it would be
    inappropriate for the court to rely on that post-argument
    submission. I agree.
    In 2002, this “court was compelled to remind all petitioners
    of first principles, namely, they must assure us that they meet
    Article III’s case or controversy requirement if their standing is
    not ‘self evident’ from the record.” Americans for Safe Access
    v. Drug Enforcement Admin., 
    706 F.3d 438
    , 452 (D.C. Cir.
    2013) (Henderson, J., dissenting) (quoting Sierra Club v. EPA,
    
    292 F.3d 895
    , 900 (D.C. Cir. 2002)). Lest there be any question
    as to our own jurisdiction to create such a quasi-legislative rule
    in an opinion as the one announced in Sierra Club, we thereafter
    codified the mandate in D.C. Circuit Rule 28(a)(7):
    In cases involving direct review in this court of
    administrative actions, the brief of the appellant or
    petitioner must set forth the basis for the claim of standing.
    This section, entitled “Standing,” must follow the summary
    of argument and immediately precede the argument. When
    the appellant’s or petitioner’s standing is not apparent from
    the administrative record, the brief must include arguments
    and evidence establishing the claim of standing. See Sierra
    Club v. EPA, 
    292 F.3d 895
    , 900-01 (D.C. Cir. 2002). If the
    evidence is lengthy, and not contained in the administrative
    record, it may be presented in a separate addendum to the
    brief. If it is bound with the brief, the addendum must be
    separated from the body of the brief (and from any other
    addendum) by a distinctly colored separation page. Any
    addendum exceeding 40 pages must be bound separately
    from the brief.
    3
    As Judge Henderson notes in her Americans for Safe Access
    dissent, “our precedent and our rules seem to have been honored
    more in the breach than in 
    compliance,” 706 F.3d at 453
    , as we
    have repeatedly been forgiving of the obligation imposed on but
    unmet by litigants. See, e.g., Americans for Safe 
    Access, supra
    ;
    Pub. Citizen, Inc. v. Nat’l Highway Traffic Safety Admin., 
    489 F.3d 1279
    , 1297 (D.C. Cir. 2007); see also 
    id. at 1297-99
    (Sentelle, J., dissenting).
    I am particularly troubled by our departure from the rule in
    the present case, because I am not convinced that petitioner has
    established standing, even in the late-filed support.
    As noted above, associational standing requires the
    association to show that
    (1) its members would otherwise have standing to sue in
    their own right;
    (2) the interests it seeks to protect are germane to the
    organization’s purpose; and
    (3) neither the claim asserted nor the relief requested
    requires the participation of individual members in the
    lawsuit.
    Maj. Op. at 11 (quoting 
    Hunt, 432 U.S. at 343
    ). It would appear
    to me that the current claim of associational standing founders
    on the relationship between the first and second elements.
    Petitioner asserts that two named members of the association
    have established “that their economic and aesthetic interests
    would be harmed by additional leasing in the Gulf of Mexico
    and the Beaufort and Chukchi Seas off the Alaskan coast.”
    Petitioner claims germaneness on the basis of CSE’s purpose, as
    stated in its bylaws, e.g., “‘[t]o work through administrative and
    4
    legal processes to promote public policies, plans, and programs
    that are grounded on ecologically sound and economically
    sustainable principles.’” Maj. Op. at 13 (quoting CSE Bylaws
    Art. I, § 1). The majority may be correct that the members have
    standing based on their aesthetic and economic interest, but
    those are not the same interests claimed by petitioner in the
    germaneness assertion. The purpose claimed by petitioner does
    not represent the sort of interests which we normally hold
    protected in standing analysis. Political and philosophical
    interests are normally protected, if at all, by the political
    branches, not the courts. See, e.g., Gettman v. Drug
    Enforcement Admin., 
    290 F.3d 430
    , 433 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (“Mere
    interest as an advocacy group is not enough [to establish
    standing].”). It would seem to me self-evident that for the first
    two elements to serve the function of establishing substitute
    standing, an Article III jurisdictional requirement, they must
    encompass the protection of the same interest. A book club
    could not assert associational standing to bring a tort action on
    behalf of one of its members bitten by a stranger’s dog. I
    question whether even the late-filed material establishes the
    standing element of jurisdiction.
    Because I am unconvinced that standing was ever
    established, I respectfully dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 12-1431

Citation Numbers: 414 U.S. App. D.C. 255, 779 F.3d 588

Filed Date: 3/6/2015

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/12/2023

Authorities (20)

Center for Biological Diversity v. US Dept. of Interior , 563 F.3d 466 ( 2009 )

Sierra Club v. Environmental Protection Agency , 292 F.3d 895 ( 2002 )

American Legal Foundation v. Federal Communications ... , 808 F.2d 84 ( 1987 )

Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc. v. Donald P. Hodel, ... , 865 F.2d 288 ( 1988 )

Natl Assn Mftr v. DOI , 134 F.3d 1095 ( 1998 )

Gettman v. Drug Enforcement Administration , 290 F.3d 430 ( 2002 )

rhode-island-consumers-council-and-division-of-public-utilities-and , 504 F.2d 203 ( 1974 )

Nuclear Energy Institute, Inc. v. Environmental Protection ... , 373 F.3d 1251 ( 2004 )

Humane Society of the United States v. Donald P. Hodel, ... , 840 F.2d 45 ( 1988 )

American Chemistry Council v. Department of Transportation , 468 F.3d 810 ( 2006 )

Wyoming Outdoor Council v. United States Forest Service , 165 F.3d 43 ( 1999 )

state-of-california-acting-by-and-through-governor-edmund-g-brown-jr , 668 F.2d 1290 ( 1981 )

Warth v. Seldin , 95 S. Ct. 2197 ( 1975 )

Brady Campaign to Prevent Gun Violence v. Salazar , 612 F. Supp. 2d 1 ( 2009 )

United States v. L. A. Tucker Truck Lines, Inc. , 73 S. Ct. 67 ( 1952 )

Hunt v. Washington State Apple Advertising Comm'n , 97 S. Ct. 2434 ( 1977 )

International Union, United Automobile, Aerospace, & ... , 106 S. Ct. 2523 ( 1986 )

Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife , 112 S. Ct. 2130 ( 1992 )

Arizona Christian School Tuition Organization v. Winn , 131 S. Ct. 1436 ( 2011 )

Chevron U. S. A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, ... , 104 S. Ct. 2778 ( 1984 )

View All Authorities »