In re Cipro Cases I & II , 61 Cal. 4th 116 ( 2015 )


Menu:
  • Filed 5/7/15
    IN THE SUPREME COURT OF CALIFORNIA
    IN RE CIPRO CASES I & II.                      )                  S198616
    )             Ct.App. 4/1 D056361
    )              San Diego County
    )                Super. Ct. Nos.
    )               JCCP 4154/4220
    To protect competition in the marketplace, antitrust law prohibits
    agreements that create or perpetuate monopolies. Patent law, in contrast, grants
    temporary monopolies to inventors to encourage the development of useful
    innovations. We consider here a crucial question at the intersection of these two
    bodies of law: what limits, if any, does antitrust law place on the ability of a patent
    holder to make agreements restricting competition during the life of its patent? In
    particular, when another entity tries to invalidate a patent and enter the
    marketplace, can the patentee pay the would-be competitor to withdraw its
    challenge and refrain from competing until at or near the natural expiration of the
    potentially invalid patent‘s life?
    The answer to this is of special moment to the pharmaceutical industry,
    which has seen a raft of suits in which generic drug manufacturers (generics),
    seeking to introduce lower priced alternatives to patented brand-name drugs, raise
    patent invalidity as a defense to claims of infringement. With increasing
    frequency these cases have settled, with the plaintiff brand-name drug
    manufacturer (brand) making a ―reverse payment‖ to the defendant generic in
    exchange for the generic dropping its patent challenge and consenting to stay out
    of the market. This case involves just such a settlement agreement.
    Under federal antitrust law, these settlements are not immune from
    scrutiny, even if they limit competition no more than a valid patent would have.
    (Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis, Inc. (2013) 570 U.S. ___, ___ [
    186 L. Ed. 2d 343
    , 356, 
    133 S. Ct. 2223
    , 2230] (Actavis).) We conclude the same is true
    under state antitrust law. Some patents are valid; some are not. Sometimes
    competition would infringe; sometimes it would not. Parties illegally restrain
    trade when they privately agree to substitute consensual monopoly in place of
    potential competition that would have followed a finding of invalidity or
    noninfringement. The Court of Appeal ruled to the contrary; we reverse.
    FACTUAL AND PROCEDURAL BACKGROUND
    Bayer AG and Bayer Corporation (collectively Bayer) market Cipro, an
    antibiotic that has been among the most-prescribed and best-selling drugs in the
    world. (Arkansas Carpenters Health and Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG (2d Cir.
    2010) 
    604 F.3d 98
    , 100; In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Lit.
    (E.D.N.Y. 2003) 
    261 F. Supp. 2d 188
    , 194; In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride
    Antitrust Lit. (E.D.N.Y. 2001) 
    166 F. Supp. 2d 740
    , 743.) In 1987, Bayer was
    issued a United States patent on the active ingredient in Cipro, ciprofloxacin
    hydrochloride, a patent that expired in December 2003. (U.S. Patent No.
    4,670,444, col. 22, ll. 32-34, claim 12 (the ‘444 patent); see In re Ciprofloxacin
    Hydrochloride Antitrust Lit. (Fed. Cir. 2008) 
    544 F.3d 1323
    , 1327–1328.) A
    subsidiary and licensee of Bayer obtained Food and Drug Administration (FDA)
    approval to market Cipro in the United States. (In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride
    Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 544 F.3d at p. 1328; In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride
    Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 166 F.Supp.2d at p. 743.) Between 1987 and 2003, Bayer
    2
    was the sole producer of Cipro in the United States and, between 1997 and 2003
    alone, Cipro generated more than $6 billion in gross sales.
    At one time, pioneer drugs like Cipro and the generic drugs that followed
    them were governed by the same FDA approval process.1 Subjecting generic
    drugs to the same ―cumbersome drug approval process [as pioneer drugs] delayed
    the entry of relatively inexpensive generic drugs into the market place,‖ at
    substantial cost to consumers and the government. (Mylan Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
    v. Shalala (D.D.C. 2000) 
    81 F. Supp. 2d 30
    , 32; see H.R.Rep. No. 98-857, 2d Sess.,
    pt. 1, p. 17 (1984), reprinted in 1984 U.S. Code Cong. & Admin. News, at p.
    2650.) To expedite the availability of low cost generic drugs, Congress authorized
    an abbreviated approval process for drugs whose active ingredients had already
    been proven safe and effective in earlier clinical trials. (Drug Price Competition &
    Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984, Pub.L. No. 98-417, tit. I, §§ 101-106 (Sept.
    24, 1984) 98 Stat. 1585, 1585–1597, codified as amended at 21 U.S.C. § 355 (the
    Hatch-Waxman Act); see H.R.Rep. No. 98-857, 2d Sess., pt. 1, pp. 14, 16–17
    (1984), reprinted in 1984 U.S. Code Cong. & Admin. News, pp. 2647, 2649–
    2650.)
    Under the Hatch-Waxman Act, a prospective generic drug manufacturer
    may file a streamlined application asserting the generic drug‘s bioequivalence with
    an existing pioneer drug, thus piggybacking on the safety and efficacy data already
    submitted to the FDA in connection with its approval of the original drug. (21
    U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A)(ii), (iv); see 
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [
    186 L. Ed. 2d 1
         A generic drug is a drug designed to be identical to an already-FDA-
    approved pioneer drug in active ingredients, safety, and efficacy, and thus
    therapeutically equivalent to its brand-name counterpart. (See PLIVA, Inc. v.
    Mensing (2011) 564 U.S. ___, ___, fn. 2 [
    180 L. Ed. 2d 580
    , 588, fn. 2; 
    131 S. Ct. 2567
    , 2574, fn. 2].)
    3
    at p. 354, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2228].) With respect to the patent implications of the
    application, the generic drug manufacturer must make one of four certifications:
    There is no patent for the underlying drug, the patent is expired, the patent will
    expire, or (relevant here) the patent is invalid or will not be infringed by the
    proposed manufacture and sale of the generic drug. (21 U.S.C.
    § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii); Actavis, at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at pp. 353–354, 133 S.Ct. at
    p. 2228].) An applicant that certifies the affected patent is invalid or will not be
    infringed (a ―paragraph IV‖ certification) must give notice to all affected patent
    owners. (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(B).) Submission of an application to manufacture
    a generic version of a drug covered by a patent is a technical act of infringement
    (35 U.S.C. § 271(e)(2)(A); Actavis, at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 354, 133 S.Ct. at
    p. 2228]); to stay approval of the generic version, a patent owner must file an
    infringement lawsuit against the generic drug manufacturer within 45 days (21
    U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iii)). To provide an incentive to assume the risks of
    exposure to such litigation, the first generic manufacturer to file an application and
    prevail is granted a potentially lucrative 180-day exclusivity window in which to
    market its drug without competition from any other generic manufacturer. (21
    U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv); Actavis, at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 354, 133 S.Ct. at
    pp. 2228–2229.)
    In 1991, twelve years before the scheduled expiration of the ‘444 patent,
    defendant Barr Laboratories, Inc., filed an application to market a generic version
    of Cipro. (In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 544 F.3d at
    p. 1328.) Barr‘s application included a paragraph IV certification that the ‘444
    patent was invalid and unenforceable. (Arkansas Carpenters Health and Welfare
    Fund v. Bayer 
    AG, supra
    , 604 F.3d at pp. 101–102; see 21 U.S.C.
    § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii)(IV).) Barr‘s statutory notice to Bayer contended Cipro‘s
    derivation was obvious in light of prior art, the ‘444 patent was an invalid double
    4
    patent, and the patent was the product of inequitable conduct based on Bayer‘s
    withholding of information about preexisting patents from the patent examiner.
    (See 35 U.S.C. §§ 102, 103; In re Longi (Fed. Cir. 1985) 
    759 F.2d 887
    , 892–893.)
    Bayer responded with a patent infringement suit, staying FDA approval, and Barr
    counterclaimed for a declaratory judgment that the ‘444 patent was invalid.2
    In early 1997, Bayer and Barr settled. Under the terms of the settlement,
    Barr agreed to postpone marketing a generic version of Cipro until the ‘444 patent
    expired. It also agreed to a consent judgment affirming the patent‘s validity and to
    modification of the certification in its FDA application from a paragraph IV
    certification, alleging invalidity, to a ―paragraph III‖ certification, seeking to
    market a generic drug upon patent expiration. (Arkansas Carpenters Health and
    Welfare Fund v. Bayer 
    AG, supra
    , 604 F.3d at p. 102; see 21 U.S.C.
    § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii)(III); 21 C.F.R. § 314.94(a)(12)(i)(A)(3) (2014).) In return,
    Bayer agreed to make payments to Barr and to supply it with Cipro for licensed
    resale beginning six months before patent expiration. (See In re Ciprofloxacin
    Hydrochloride Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 544 F.3d at pp. 1328–1329.) This head start
    mirrored the 180-day duopoly the Hatch-Waxman Act would have provided Barr
    if it had succeeded in showing invalidity or noninfringement of Bayer‘s patent.
    2       While the litigation was ongoing, Barr agreed to accept contribution to its
    litigation costs from another generic drug manufacturer, defendant The Rugby
    Group, Inc., a then-subsidiary of defendant Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc., in
    exchange for a share of the benefits of any settlement, judgment, or sale of generic
    ciprofloxacin hydrochloride. (In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 544 F.3d at p. 1328.) In 1998, The Rugby Group, Inc. was acquired by
    defendant Watson Pharmaceuticals, Inc. Generic defendants Barr Laboratories,
    Inc., The Rugby Group, Inc., Watson, and Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc., are
    referred to collectively as Barr.
    5
    (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv).) Barr was to receive Cipro from Bayer at 85
    percent of current price.
    Pursuant to the settlement, between 1997 and 2003, Bayer paid Barr $398.1
    million. In that same period, Bayer‘s profits from sales of Cipro exceeded
    $1 billion. (In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 261
    F.Supp.2d at p. 194.)
    The 1997 settlement between Bayer and Barr produced a wave of state and
    federal antitrust suits. (Arkansas Carpenters Health and Welfare Fund v. Bayer
    
    AG, supra
    , 604 F.3d at p. 102.) This case arises from nine such coordinated class
    action suits brought by indirect purchasers of Cipro in California against Bayer
    and Barr. (See In re Cipro Cases I & II (2004) 
    121 Cal. App. 4th 402
    , fn. *, 406–
    407.) The operative complaint in these coordinated proceedings alleges the Bayer-
    Barr reverse payment settlement violated the Cartwright Act (Bus. & Prof. Code,
    § 16700 et seq.), unfair competition law (id., § 17200 et seq.), and common law
    prohibition against monopolies. The gravamen of the complaint is that the 1997
    agreement preserved Bayer‘s monopoly and ability to charge supracompetitive
    prices at the expense of consumers, and Bayer in turn split these monopoly profits
    with Barr. Class certification was granted and upheld on appeal. (In re Cipro
    Cases I & II, at p. 418.) Thereafter, the parties stayed this action pending
    resolution of consolidated federal challenges to the Bayer-Barr settlement.
    Following a Federal Circuit ruling in favor of Bayer and Barr on federal
    antitrust claims (In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 
    544 F.3d 1323
    ),3 the trial court granted a defense summary judgment. It found decisional
    3      As discussed below, both In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 
    544 F.3d 1323
    and a second decision rejecting a federal antitrust challenge
    to the Cipro settlement, Arkansas Carpenters Health and Welfare Fund v. Bayer
    (footnote continued on next page)
    6
    law under the federal Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. § 1 et seq.) dispositive and held that
    because the settlement agreement did not restrain competition longer than the
    exclusionary scope of the ‘444 patent, it did not violate the Cartwright Act. The
    Court of Appeal affirmed, holding that agreements restraining competition within
    the scope of a patent are lawful unless the patent was procured by fraud or the suit
    to enforce it was objectively baseless. The court held further that, even if there
    were a disputed issue of material fact as to whether Bayer‘s suit to enforce the
    ‘444 patent was objectively baseless, litigation of that theory would be foreclosed
    by exclusive federal court patent jurisdiction.
    We granted review to resolve important unsettled issues of state antitrust
    law. While the case was pending before this court, we entered an order
    formalizing Bayer‘s dismissal from the proceedings pursuant to an approved
    settlement. Barr remains as respondent.
    DISCUSSION
    I.       Reverse Payment Settlements Under the Hatch-Waxman Act
    The Hatch-Waxman Act illustrates the law of unintended consequences.
    Congress wrote into the act a substantial incentive for generics to enter markets
    earlier by offering a 180-day exclusivity period to the first generic filer, and only
    that filer, to challenge a patent. (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv); see Hemphill,
    Paying for Delay: Pharmaceutical Patent Settlement as a Regulatory Design
    Problem (2006) 81 N.Y.U. L.Rev. 1553, 1566, 1578–1579, 1583.) The theory
    was that a generic would be more likely to challenge dubious patents if offered the
    (footnote continued from previous page)
    
    AG, supra
    , 
    604 F.3d 98
    , were decided under principles later rejected by the United
    States Supreme Court in 
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. ___ [
    186 L. Ed. 2d 343
    , 
    133 S. Ct. 2223
    ].
    7
    carrot of an enormously valuable six-month period in which only it and the brand
    could produce a drug. (Carrier, Unsettling Drug Patent Settlements: A Framework
    for Presumptive Illegality (2009) 108 Mich. L.Rev. 37, 47; Bulow, The Gaming of
    Pharmaceutical Patents in 4 Innovation Policy and the Economy (Jaffe et al.
    edits., 2004) 145, 163; Hemphill, An Aggregate Approach to Antitrust: Using
    New Data and Rulemaking to Preserve Drug Competition (2009) 109 Colum.
    L.Rev. 629, 651.) Otherwise, ―free rider‖ problems might arise: every generic
    would have an incentive to hold back and let some other generic be the one to
    shoulder the risk and litigation costs associated with challenging a patent.
    (Lemley & Shapiro, Probabilistic Patents (2005) 19 J. Econ. Perspectives 75, 88;
    Hemphill, Paying for Delay, at p. 1605.)
    This solution may well have encouraged more generics to file patent
    challenges, but not without creating a series of new problems. In other settings, a
    patentee might have little incentive to buy off a challenger in order to preserve its
    monopoly and continue reaping monopoly profits, for the simple reason that
    paying off the first challenger would simply encourage another challenger, and
    then another, and then another. (See 
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186
    L.Ed.2d at pp. 361–362, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2235].) Two features of the Hatch-
    Waxman Act change this dynamic. First, the 180-day exclusivity period created a
    bottleneck; no one else could receive FDA approval until after its expiration. (21
    U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv)(I); Hemphill, Paying for Delay: Pharmaceutical Patent
    Settlement as a Regulatory Design 
    Problem, supra
    , 81 N.Y.U. L.Rev. at pp. 1560–
    1561, 1586–1587.) Second, other generics tempted to challenge a patent in the
    wake of a settlement with the first-filing generic would have to wait out an
    automatic 30-month stay the brand could obtain just by opposing their requests for
    FDA approval. (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iii); Actavis, at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at
    pp. 361–362, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2235]; Bulow, The Gaming of Pharmaceutical
    8
    Patents in 4 Innovation Policy and the 
    Economy, supra
    , at p. 164.) As a result,
    the brand could effectively pick off ― ‗the most motivated challenger, and the one
    closest to introducing competition‘ ‖ (Actavis, at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at pp. 361–
    362, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2235], quoting Hemphill, Paying for Delay, at p. 1586), with
    all others stuck in line behind that generic (Cotter, Refining the “Presumptive
    Illegality” Approach to Settlements of Patent Disputes Involving Reverse
    Payments: A Commentary on Hovenkamp, Janis & Lemley (2003) 87 Minn.
    L.Rev. 1789, 1801).4
    This legal regime means that, regardless of the degree of likely validity of a
    patent, the brand and first-filing generic have an incentive to effectively establish a
    cartel through a reverse payment settlement. (12 Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust
    Law, supra, ¶ 2046, pp. 341–345; Hovenkamp, Anticompetitive Patent Settlements
    and the Supreme Court’s Actavis Decision (2014) 15 Minn. J. L. Sci. & Tech. 3,
    8–13; see Carrier, Unsettling Drug Patent Settlements: A Framework for
    Presumptive 
    Illegality, supra
    , 108 Mich. L.Rev. at p. 73 [under Hatch-Waxman,
    ―[g]enerics have powerful incentives to file the first patent challenge but little
    incentive to pursue the litigation‖].) Rather than expend litigation costs on either
    side, the brand and generic can reach a settlement that reflects the likely validity or
    invalidity of the patent (stronger patent, smaller settlement; weaker patent, bigger
    settlement), grants the generic a share of monopoly profits, and leaves the brand
    4      Amendments to the Hatch-Waxman Act postdating the settlement in this
    case may have partially alleviated the complete bottleneck problem (Hemphill,
    Paying for Delay: Pharmaceutical Patent Settlement as a Regulatory Design
    
    Problem, supra
    , 81 N.Y.U. L.Rev. at p. 1587), although not issues arising from the
    30-month stay or the reduced incentives for other generics, without the carrot of
    180 days of duopoly, to bring patent challenges (12 Areeda & Hovenkamp,
    Antitrust Law (3d ed. 2012) ¶ 2046, p. 341).
    9
    the sole manufacturer of the product. (Hovenkamp, Anticompetitive Patent
    Settlements, at pp. 12–13.)
    It is likely for this reason that reverse payment settlements, practically
    unheard of before the Hatch-Waxman Act, have proliferated in the years since its
    enactment. (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 362, 133 S.Ct. at
    p. 2235]; Hovenkamp, Anticompetitive Patent 
    Settlements, supra
    , 15 Minn. J. L.
    Sci. & Tech. at pp. 13–16; Hemphill, An Aggregate Approach to Antitrust: Using
    New Data and Rulemaking to Preserve Drug 
    Competition, supra
    , 109 Colum.
    L.Rev. at pp. 647–656.) This is probably not what Congress intended. (Actavis, at
    p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 362, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2235] [the Hatch-Waxman Act‘s
    provisions have ―no doubt unintentionally . . . created special incentives for
    collusion‖]); 
    id. at p.
    ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 360, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2234] [quoting
    remarks of Sen. Hatch and Rep. Waxman decrying as an unintended consequence
    of their legislation collusive agreements to delay competition].) The issue for us is
    what, if anything, state antitrust law has to say about these problems.
    II.    The Intersection Between Antitrust and Patent Law
    A.     The Cartwright Act
    The Legislature enacted the state‘s principal antitrust law, the Cartwright
    Act, to rein in the burgeoning power of monopolies and cartels. (Clayworth v.
    Pfizer, Inc. (2010) 
    49 Cal. 4th 758
    , 772.) The act‘s principal goal is the
    preservation of consumer welfare. (Cianci v. Superior Court (1985) 
    40 Cal. 3d 903
    , 918; Marin County Bd. of Realtors, Inc. v. Palsson (1976) 
    16 Cal. 3d 920
    ,
    935.) The act, like antitrust law in general, ―rest[s] ‗on the premise that the
    unrestrained interaction of competitive forces will yield the best allocation of our
    economic resources, the lowest prices, the highest quality and the greatest material
    progress, while at the same time providing an environment conducive to the
    preservation of our democratic political and social institutions.‘ ‖ (Marin County
    10
    Bd., at p. 935; see National Soc. of Professional Engineers v. United States (1978)
    
    435 U.S. 679
    , 695.) At its heart is a prohibition against agreements that prevent
    the growth of healthy, competitive markets for goods and services and the
    establishment of prices through market forces. (See Speegle v. Board of Fire
    Underwriters (1946) 
    29 Cal. 2d 34
    , 44.) ―The act ‗generally outlaws any
    combinations or agreements which restrain trade or competition or which fix or
    control prices‘ [citation], and declares that, with certain exceptions, ‗every trust is
    unlawful, against public policy and void.‘ ‖ (Pacific Gas & Electric Co. v. County
    of Stanislaus (1997) 
    16 Cal. 4th 1143
    , 1147.)
    The ―trust[s]‖ the act prohibits include any ―combination . . . by two or
    more persons‖ to ―create or carry out restrictions in trade or commerce‖ (Bus. &
    Prof. Code, § 16720, subd. (a)) or to ―prevent competition in manufacturing,
    making, transportation, sale or purchase of merchandise, produce or any
    commodity‖ (id., subd. (c)). Also prohibited is any contract by which two or more
    entities ―[a]gree to pool, combine or directly or indirectly unite any interests that
    they may have connected with the sale . . . of any such article or commodity, that
    its price might in any manner be affected.‖ (Id., subd. (e)(4).) Agreements in
    violation of the act are ―absolutely void and . . . not enforceable at law or in
    equity.‖ (Id., § 16722; see 
    id., § 16726.)
           Though the Cartwright Act is written in absolute terms, in practice not
    every agreement within the four corners of its prohibitions has been deemed
    illegal. (Morrison v. Viacom, Inc. (1998) 
    66 Cal. App. 4th 534
    , 540.) Business and
    Professions Code sections 16720, 16722, and 16726 draw upon the common law
    prohibition against restraints of trade. (Corwin v. Los Angeles Newspaper Service
    Bureau, Inc. (1971) 
    4 Cal. 3d 842
    , 852; People v. Building Maintenance etc. Assn.
    (1953) 
    41 Cal. 2d 719
    , 727; Speegle v. Board of Fire 
    Underwriters, supra
    , 29
    Cal.2d at p. 44.) The earliest common law decisions imposed an absolute rule,
    11
    voiding ―all contracts . . . which in any degree tended to the restraint of trade.‖
    (Wright v. Ryder (1868) 
    36 Cal. 342
    , 357.) But the common law rule was soon
    modified and ―as relaxed, tolerated such [restraints of trade] as were restricted in
    their operations within reasonable limits.‖ (Ibid.; see Vulcan Powder Co. v.
    Hercules Powder Co. (1892) 
    96 Cal. 510
    , 512.) The United States Supreme Court
    looked to the common law in embracing a rule of reason for determining which
    agreements violate federal antitrust law (see Standard Oil Co. v. United States
    (1911) 
    221 U.S. 1
    , 60), and this court thereafter followed suit: ―[I]t may be
    assumed that the broad prohibitions of the Cartwright Act are subject to an implied
    exception similar to the one that validates reasonable restraints of trade under the
    federal Sherman Antitrust Act.‖ (Building Maintenance etc. Assn., at p. 727; see
    Marin County Bd. of Realtors, Inc. v. 
    Palsson, supra
    , 16 Cal.3d at p. 930; Corwin,
    at p. 853.)5 What was true under the common law, however, is true today: ―the
    difficulty lies in determining what are reasonable and what unreasonable
    restrictions.‖ (Wright, at p. 358.)
    B.     Patent Law
    That difficulty is all the greater because antitrust law does not exist in a
    vacuum. The patent laws ―are in pari materia with the antitrust laws and modify
    them pro tanto [to that extent].‖ (Simpson v. Union Oil Co. (1964) 
    377 U.S. 13
    ,
    24.) To promote investment in invention and the public disclosure of new
    discoveries, Congress has seen fit to grant inventors limited statutory monopolies
    5      As we noted in People v. Building Maintenance etc. 
    Assn., supra
    , 41 Cal.2d
    at pages 726–727, a separate section of the Cartwright Act effectively codifies this
    principle: ―It is not unlawful to enter into agreements or form associations or
    combinations, the purpose and effect of which is to promote, encourage or
    increase competition in any trade or industry, or which are in furtherance of
    trade.‖ (Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16725.)
    12
    and the right to exclude competition in the manufacture, use, or sale of the patent‘s
    subject. (35 U.S.C. § 154(a); see Bonito Boats, Inc. v. Thunder Craft Boats, Inc.
    (1989) 
    489 U.S. 141
    , 150–151; Dawson Chemical Co. v. Rohm & Haas Co.
    (1980) 
    448 U.S. 176
    , 215; Sears, Roebuck & Co. v. Stiffel Co. (1964) 
    376 U.S. 225
    , 229.) Accordingly, the issuance of a federal patent creates ―an exception to
    the general rule against monopolies and to the right of access to a free and open
    market.‖ (Precision Co. v. Automotive Co. (1945) 
    324 U.S. 806
    , 816.) While
    ―[t]he limited monopolies granted to patent owners do not exempt them from the
    prohibitions‖ of antitrust law (Standard Oil Co. v. United States (1931) 
    283 U.S. 163
    , 169; see United Shoe Mach. Co. v. United States (1922) 
    258 U.S. 451
    , 463–
    464 [―the rights secured by a patent do not protect the making of contracts in
    restraint of trade‖]), in a given case possession of a patent may provide a defense
    to liability (United States v. Gen. Elec. Co. (1926) 
    272 U.S. 476
    , 488–490; Valley
    Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharmaceuticals (11th Cir. 2003) 
    344 F.3d 1294
    , 1307).
    Courts thus must reconcile the two bodies of law, making ―an adjustment between
    the lawful restraint on trade of the patent monopoly and the illegal restraint
    prohibited broadly by‖ antitrust law. (United States v. Line Material Co. (1948)
    
    333 U.S. 287
    , 310.)
    At the extremes, this is easy. If a patent were known to be invalid, a private
    agreement nevertheless giving it effect would be plainly illegal. (See Bus. & Prof.
    Code, §§ 16720, 16722, 16726.) Conversely, if a patent were known to be valid,
    an agreement foreclosing competition no more than the statutory monopoly would
    not restrain trade beyond what federal law permitted, and the rights patent law
    affords the patentee would supersede any state law prohibition. Difficulties
    emerge when we move from a hypothetical patent known to be determinately valid
    or invalid to the real world, where validity may be unclear. When assessing the
    antitrust implications of an agreement arising from a patent, the truth about the
    13
    patent‘s validity cannot always be known. The issue is how antitrust and patent
    law should accommodate each other under these conditions of uncertainty.
    III.   The Scope of the Patent Test
    A.     The Court of Appeal and the Scope of the Patent Approach
    The particular accommodation this case calls for arises from an issue of
    virtual first impression under the Cartwright Act: how to apply the statutory bar
    against restraints of trade to patent settlement agreements that limit competition,
    but no more broadly than an injunction enforcing the patent would have, had one
    been obtained. (Cf. In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litigation (6th Cir. 2003) 
    332 F.3d 896
    , 904, fn. 8, 906–909 [deciding the issue under both federal law and the
    Cartwright Act, but without independently analyzing state law].) Rejecting
    plaintiffs‘ argument that agreements of this sort should be deemed uniformly
    illegal, the Court of Appeal resolved the issue by adopting one of several
    competing approaches courts had developed to solve the problem under federal
    antitrust law, the scope of the patent test.6 Under that test, the Court of Appeal
    held, ―a settlement of a lawsuit to enforce a patent does not violate the Cartwright
    Act if the settlement restrains competition only within the scope of the patent,
    unless the patent was procured by fraud or the suit for its enforcement was
    objectively baseless.‖ The scope of the patent test thus gives wide effect to
    patents by essentially presuming their validity in most cases. We conclude, as
    more recent United States Supreme Court authority has now made clear, that this
    6      See In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litigation (2d Cir. 2006) 
    466 F.3d 187
    ; cf. In re Cardizem CD Antitrust 
    Litigation, supra
    , 332 F.3d at pp. 907–909
    (adopting per se rule); In re K-Dur Antitrust Litigation (3d Cir. 2012) 
    686 F.3d 197
    (adopting quick look rule of reason analysis).
    14
    test accords excess weight to the policies motivating patent law, gives insufficient
    consideration to the concerns animating antitrust law, and must be rejected.
    The federal cases the Court of Appeal followed identify three core
    rationales for concluding a patent litigation settlement restricting competition no
    more than a valid patent would is generally lawful. First, patents are presumed
    valid. (35 U.S.C. § 282(a).) Given this presumption, many lower federal courts
    reasoned, an agreement that does not extend monopoly beyond what a patent
    grants imposes no additional injury to competition and, in the absence of anti-
    competitive effects, generally survives antitrust scrutiny. (See In re Ciprofloxacin
    Hydrochloride Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 544 F.3d at p. 1337; In re Tamoxifen Citrate
    Antitrust 
    Litigation, supra
    , 466 F.3d at pp. 212–213; Schering-Plough Corp. v.
    FTC (11th Cir. 2005) 
    402 F.3d 1056
    , 1066–1068.)
    Second, the fundamental purpose of patent law is to promote innovation
    and the disclosure of inventions so that ultimately new discoveries may benefit the
    public at large. (Bonito Boats, Inc. v. Thunder Craft Boats, 
    Inc., supra
    , 489 U.S.
    at pp. 150–151.) To subject exclusions within the scope of a patent to scrutiny and
    potential liability would, lower courts feared, chill innovation and give inventors
    pause in deciding whether to share their creations with the public. (See In re
    Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust 
    Litigation, supra
    , 466 F.3d at p. 203; Schering-Plough
    Corp. v. 
    FTC, supra
    , 402 F.3d at p. 1075; Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva
    
    Pharmaceuticals, supra
    , 344 F.3d at p. 1308.)
    Third, there is a general policy in favor of settlement, perhaps more so in
    patent litigation. (In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust 
    Lit., supra
    , 544
    F.3d at p. 1333; In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust 
    Litigation, supra
    , 466 F.3d at
    p. 202; Schering-Plough Corp. v. 
    FTC, supra
    , 402 F.3d at pp. 1072–1073.) Patent
    litigation settlements ―may benefit the public by introducing a new rival into the
    market, facilitating competitive production, and encouraging further innovation.‖
    15
    (Schering-Plough Corp., at p. 1075.) Conversely, a legal regime that hampers
    settlement ―may actually decrease product innovation by amplifying the period of
    uncertainty around a drug manufacturer‘s ability to research, develop, and market
    the patented product or allegedly infringing product.‖ (Ibid.; see In re Tamoxifen
    Citrate Antitrust Litigation, at p. 203.)
    B.      Federal Trade Commission v. Actavis
    The Court of Appeal‘s adoption of the scope of the patent test was the
    product not of an analysis of the Cartwright Act‘s text, policy, or history, but of an
    assessment of procedural and policy-based aspects of patent law. The soundness
    of its choice of test thus depends on the extent to which that patent law assessment
    was sound. In 
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. ___ [
    186 L. Ed. 2d 343
    , 
    133 S. Ct. 2223
    ],
    issued after the Court of Appeal‘s decision and after our grant of review, the
    Supreme Court reversed a federal decision holding Hatch-Waxman reverse
    payment settlement agreements ― ‗immune from antitrust attack so long as [their]
    anticompetitive effects fall within the scope of the exclusionary potential of the
    patent.‘ ‖ (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 353, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2227].) In the
    course of its opinion, the Supreme Court dismantled the underpinning of each of
    the cases the Court of Appeal had found persuasive.
    First, the Supreme Court rejected the scope of the patent test‘s foundational
    presumption that the holder of a challenged patent enjoys all the rights attendant to
    ownership of a valid patent: ―to refer . . . simply to what the holder of a valid
    patent could do does not by itself answer the antitrust question. The patent here
    may or may not be valid, and may or may not be infringed.‖ (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570
    U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 356, 133 S.Ct. at pp. 2230–2231].) To be sure, a
    valid patent allows the patentee to exclude others from the market, ―[b]ut an
    invalidated patent carries with it no such right.‖ (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at
    p. 356, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2231].) Patent litigation ―put[s] the patent‘s validity at
    16
    issue, as well as its actual preclusive scope‖; simply because a settlement curtails
    testing and ultimate resolution of that issue, courts should not thereafter treat
    patent law and its presumptions as conclusively establishing the challenged
    patent‘s legitimate scope. (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 357, 133 S.Ct. at
    p. 2231].)
    Second, the core policies underlying patent law are more nuanced than the
    cases applying a scope of the patent test had recognized, and the incentives to
    innovate far sturdier than those courts had feared. Patents carry with them a
    frequent cost—monopoly premiums the public must bear. (See Lear, Inc. v.
    Adkins (1969) 
    395 U.S. 653
    , 670.) The willingness to pay that cost depends upon
    a quid pro quo: ― ‗the public interest in granting patent monopolies‘ exists only to
    the extent that ‗the public is given a novel and useful invention‘ in ‗consideration
    for its grant.‘ ‖ (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 358, 133
    S.Ct. at p. 2232].) Accordingly, patent policy does not support unquestioned
    protection of every inventor‘s rights, but instead favors ―eliminating unwarranted
    patent grants so the public will not ‗continually be required to pay tribute to
    would-be monopolists without need or justification.‘ ‖ (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d
    at p. 359, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2233].) Vigorous testing for validity is thus desirable in
    order to weed out patents that shield a monopoly without offering corresponding
    public benefits. (See Aronson v. Quick Point Pencil Co. (1979) 
    440 U.S. 257
    ,
    264; United States v. Glaxo Group Ltd. (1973) 
    410 U.S. 52
    , 58; Edward Katzinger
    Co. v. Chicago Mfg. Co. (1947) 
    329 U.S. 394
    , 400–401.)7
    7      As commentators have noted, an excess of invalid patents is one of the
    principal problems in modern patent law. (See Ford, Patent Invalidity Versus
    Noninfringement (2013) 99 Cornell L.Rev. 71, 74 & fn. 11 [discussing substantial
    scholarship on the point].) The pro-patent-challenge policy is particularly strong
    in the Hatch-Waxman Act setting, given the 180-day exclusivity bounty Congress
    (footnote continued on next page)
    17
    Third, the Supreme Court explained that while the policy favoring
    settlement of patent litigation offers some support for limiting scrutiny of
    agreements restraining competition only within the scope of a patent, it ultimately
    is not dispositive. (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at pp. 360,
    364, 133 S.Ct. at pp. 2234, 2238].) Settlements are generally a positive good, but
    not always; settlements of the sort challenged in Actavis, the court observed, can
    amount to ―payment in return for staying out of the market‖ and permit monopoly
    premiums still to be charged and simply divided up between the patent holder and
    patent challenger; ―[t]he patentee and the challenger gain; the consumer loses.‖
    (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 361, 133 S.Ct. at pp. 2234, 2235].) Such anti-
    competitive effects will not always be justified, and an antitrust action to test a
    settlement‘s legality may be warranted and feasible. (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at
    pp. 361–364, 133 S.Ct. at pp. 2235–2237].) Fears of chilling even legitimate
    settlements are overstated; all that allowing antitrust scrutiny does is remove the
    incentive to settle as a way to split monopoly profits. (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d
    at p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2237].) Because the scope of the patent test overvalues
    the policies underlying patent law at the expense of the equally relevant policies
    underlying antitrust law, the court concluded, it cannot stand under federal law.
    (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 357, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2231].)
    (footnote continued from previous page)
    adopted as an incentive to bring such challenges. (See 21 U.S.C.
    § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv); 12 Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law, supra, ¶ 2046,
    p. 340; Carrier, Unsettling Drug Patent Settlements: A Framework for
    Presumptive 
    Illegality, supra
    , 108 Mich. L.Rev. at pp. 43, 64; ante, pp. 7–8.)
    18
    C.      The Scope of the Patent Test’s Validity Under State Law
    Barr contends Actavis is distinguishable because it involved a public
    prosecution under the Federal Trade Commission Act (15 U.S.C. § 45 et seq.), not
    a private antitrust suit, and this court should embrace the scope of the patent test as
    a matter of state antitrust law.
    We agree Actavis is not dispositive on matters of state law. Indeed, even if
    Actavis had been a private Sherman Act case, its conclusions would not dictate
    how the Cartwright Act must be read. ―Interpretations of federal antitrust law are
    at most instructive, not conclusive, when construing the Cartwright Act, given that
    the Cartwright Act was modeled not on federal antitrust statutes but instead on
    statutes enacted by California‘s sister states around the turn of the 20th century.‖
    (Aryeh v. Canon Business Solutions, Inc. (2013) 
    55 Cal. 4th 1185
    , 1195; see State
    of California ex rel. Van de Kamp v. Texaco, Inc. (1988) 
    46 Cal. 3d 1147
    , 1164.)
    That said, nothing in the United States Supreme Court‘s discussion of the legal
    rules at the boundary between antitrust and patent law hinged on the happenstance
    that the case under review involved a public prosecutor. Accordingly, that
    circumstance neither adds to nor detracts from the persuasive force the discussion
    would otherwise have.
    What does affect the weight to be accorded Actavis is the extent to which
    its analysis establishes the metes and bounds of patent law and policy. Patent law
    is federal law. (U.S. Const., art. I, § 8, cl. 8; see Bonito Boats, Inc. v. Thunder
    Craft Boats, 
    Inc., supra
    , 489 U.S. at pp. 146–157.) The United States Supreme
    Court is the final arbiter of questions of patent law and the extent to which
    interpretations of antitrust law—whether state or federal—must accommodate
    patent law‘s requirements, and Actavis is its latest word on the subject. If under
    Actavis patent law demands extensive deference to patents‘ presumed validity and
    the consecration of a broad range of agreements otherwise facially illegal under
    19
    state law, we must abide by that judgment. Conversely, if the accommodation
    necessitated by patent policy is somewhat narrower than previously understood,
    we again must treat that determination as conclusive and reconsider the proper
    domain of state antitrust law in light of that cession of territory.
    Barr asserts Actavis is alternatively distinguishable on the ground the
    underlying patent there was far weaker than the underlying patent here.8 But
    Actavis‘s analysis was not contingent on a particular level of uncertainty
    surrounding the patent before it. Instead, the court simply recognized that any
    patent might, or might not, be valid. (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186
    L.Ed.2d at p. 356, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2231]; see 
    id. at p.
    ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 367,
    133 S.Ct. at p. 2240] (dis. opn. of Roberts, C.J.) [recognizing the problem ―that
    we‘re not quite certain if the patent is actually valid, or if the competitor is
    infringing it,‖ a problem ―that is always the case‖ in patent disputes].) Indeed, a
    critical insight undergirding Actavis is that patents are in a sense probabilistic,
    rather than ironclad: they grant their holders a potential but not certain right to
    exclude.
    The uncertainty concerning a patent‘s validity is a by-product of the
    realities surrounding patent issuance and the legal regime Congress and the courts
    have established for patent enforcement. In the first instance, a patent ―simply
    represents a legal conclusion reached by the Patent Office. Moreover, the legal
    conclusion is predicated on factors as to which reasonable men can differ widely.
    Yet the Patent Office is often obliged to reach its decision in an ex parte
    8      After the settlement, Bayer submitted the ‘444 patent to the Patent and
    Trademark Office for reexamination and obtained reaffirmation that it was not
    invalid. (See 35 U.S.C. § 302.) Later patent challenges by litigants other than
    Barr were unsuccessful. (See In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Lit.
    (E.D.N.Y. 2005) 
    363 F. Supp. 2d 514
    , 519–520.)
    20
    proceeding, without the aid of the arguments which could be advanced by parties
    interested in proving patent invalidity.‖ (Lear, Inc. v. 
    Adkins, supra
    , 395 U.S. at
    p. 670.) That decision is constrained by time and resource pressures; facing an
    enormous backlog, patent examiners may average less than 20 hours spent on each
    application. (Ford, Patent Invalidity Versus 
    Noninfringement, supra
    , 99 Cornell
    L.Rev. at pp. 87–89; Lemley & Shapiro, Probabilistic 
    Patents, supra
    , 19 J. Econ.
    Perspectives at p. 79; Lemley, Rational Ignorance at the Patent Office (2001) 95
    Nw.U. L.Rev. 1495, 1499–1500.) Given this underlying reality, Congress has
    elected not to make the issuance of a patent conclusive but, rather, subject to
    validation or invalidation in court proceedings. (35 U.S.C. § 282; see, e.g., Alice
    Corp. Pty. Ltd. v. CLS Bank Int’l (2014) 573 U.S. ___ [
    189 L. Ed. 2d 296
    , 
    134 S. Ct. 2347
    ]; Walker Process Equipment, Inc. v. Food Machinery & Chemical Corp.
    (1965) 
    382 U.S. 172
    , 176.) A patent is, in effect, a right to ask the government to
    exercise its power to keep others from using an invention without consent. (Zenith
    Corp. v. Hazeltine (1969) 
    395 U.S. 100
    , 135.) Whether a court will do so—
    whether it will issue an injunction—will depend on actual proof of validity.
    The differential application of collateral estoppel adds another layer of
    uncertainty. A finding that a patent is invalid operates in rem and estops the
    patentee from asserting validity against the world. (Blonder-Tongue v. University
    Foundation (1971) 
    402 U.S. 313
    , 349–350.) In contrast, a finding that a patent is
    valid operates only on the parties and does not extend from one infringement case
    to the next. A future challenger with new or better information may subsequently
    raise, and succeed on, an invalidity defense to a charge of infringement. (In re
    Swanson (Fed. Cir. 2008) 
    540 F.3d 1368
    , 1377; Ethicon, Inc. v. Quigg (Fed. Cir.
    1988) 
    849 F.2d 1422
    , 1429, fn. 3 [― ‗A patent is not held valid for all purposes but,
    rather, not invalid on the record before the court‘ ‖ and ― ‗simply remains valid
    21
    until another challenger carries‘ ‖ the burden of showing invalidity].) Each case
    may show only that a patent has not been invalidated, yet.
    If the assertion of patent rights leads to a court injunction excluding a
    competitor from the marketplace, there is no antitrust problem. If instead the
    assertion leads to a private settlement agreement, there is a potential antitrust
    problem. With a settlement, any restraint arises directly from the private
    agreement and only indirectly from the patent, which remains in the background,
    motivating the parties‘ actions according to their assessments of its strength. That
    a patent has not (yet) been invalidated may allow some confidence about its
    fundamental enforceability, but does not allow a court to skip entirely an antitrust
    analysis of competitive restraints within the patent‘s scope on the assumption that
    its validity has been established. The scope of the patent test is flawed precisely
    because it assumes away whatever level of uncertainty a given patent—the ‘444
    patent here, no less than the one at issue in Actavis—may be subject to.9
    9      The Actavis treatment of patents as in some sense probabilistic rests on a
    substantial body of scholarship suggesting patents are best understood this way.
    (See, e.g., Lemley & Shapiro, Probabilistic 
    Patents, supra
    , 19 J. Econ.
    Perspectives at pp. 75–76, 95; Shapiro, Antitrust Analysis of Patent Settlements
    Between Rivals (Summer 2003) 17 Antitrust 70, 75; Leffler & Leffler, The
    Probabilistic Nature of Patent Rights (Summer 2003) 17 Antitrust 77; Shapiro,
    Antitrust Limits to Patent Settlements (2003) 34 RAND J. Econ. 391, 395.)
    Others, including the Actavis dissenters, have disagreed, insisting a patent
    ultimately is always only valid or invalid, whether we know it yet or not. (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 372, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2244] (dis. opn. of
    Roberts, C.J.); Schildkraut, Patent-Splitting Settlements and the Reverse Payment
    Fallacy (2004) 71 Antitrust L.J. 1033; McDonald, Hatch-Waxman Patent
    Settlements and Antitrust: On “Probabilistic” Patent Rights and False Positives
    (Spring 2003) 17 Antitrust 68.) The Supreme Court majority‘s views are
    conclusive as to which side of this philosophical divide over the proper treatment
    of patents is correct, and we follow them.
    22
    Aside from its attempts to distinguish Actavis, Barr argues a 1953
    California decision predating the recent federal Hatch-Waxman Act decisions
    favors the scope of the patent test for Cartwright Act challenges to patent
    settlements. (See Fruit Machinery Co. v. F.M. Ball & Co. (1953) 
    118 Cal. App. 2d 748
    , 758.) We do not read that opinion so broadly.
    In Fruit Machinery, six canning companies formed a corporation and
    licensed to it rights under a fruit pitter patent owned by one of the companies. In
    turn, the licensee contracted with each of the six, sublicensing to them the right to
    build and own a specified number of pitters and to lease additional pitters in
    exchange for payment of royalties. A dispute over nonpayment of royalties arose
    between the licensee and one of the six companies. The company raised as a
    defense to payment that the contractual arrangements gave the six companies an
    unlawful monopoly on pitter ownership and were thus unenforceable. The Court
    of Appeal found no antitrust violation, explaining: ―Defendant has not shown that
    the parties, in executing and carrying out the sublicense agreement in suit,
    exercised rights or powers not accorded them by the patent law or abused any
    rights or powers accorded them by that law.‖ (Fruit Machinery Co. v. F.M. Ball
    & 
    Co., supra
    , 118 Cal.App.2d at p. 762, italics added.) The Court of Appeal
    distinguished other cases involving antitrust violations as involving a ―patentee or
    his assignee [who] went beyond that which was necessary or incidental to the
    scope of his patent and brought himself within the proscription of the antitrust
    laws.‖ (Id. at p. 763.)
    Fruit Machinery does not stand for the proposition that any restraints of
    trade within the scope of a patent are valid. Rather, it recognizes trade restraints
    that exceed those authorized by a patent may be invalid and, moreover, that the
    ―abuse[]‖ of patent rights may also run afoul of antitrust law. (Fruit Machinery
    Co. v. F.M. Ball & 
    Co., supra
    , 118 Cal.App.2d at p. 762.) The court responded to
    23
    the concern that the corporate licensee might use its exclusive patent rights to
    charge far higher royalties for leased than owned pitters not by saying such a
    differential would automatically be lawful, as within the scope of any patent
    rights, but by saying only ―that such has not happened yet‖ and it would not
    presume a ―[f]uture violation . . . of the antitrust laws.‖ (Ibid.)
    No other California authority Barr has cited, nor any we have found,
    establishes the scope of the patent test is applicable under the Cartwright Act.
    Even if such precedent existed, we would be forced to reexamine it in light of
    Actavis. The scope of the patent test insulates from antitrust scrutiny virtually any
    agreement that restrains trade no more than the patent itself would have, if valid.
    State law must yield to federal, but we cannot under the guise of patent law carve
    into the Legislature‘s enactments a larger exception than federal law dictates, and
    Actavis shows such a broad exemption is not required. Accordingly, we conclude
    the scope of the patent test is inapplicable to Cartwright Act claims.
    IV.    Analysis of Reverse Payment Patent Settlements
    Having joined the United States Supreme Court in rejecting the scope of the
    patent test, we consider what rubric courts should instead apply under state law to
    reverse payment patent settlements.
    A.      Antitrust Analysis Under the Cartwright Act
    As discussed, although the prohibitions of the Cartwright Act are framed in
    superficially absolute language, deciding antitrust illegality is not as simple as
    identifying whether a challenged agreement involves a restraint of trade. (See
    Chicago Board of Trade v. United States (1918) 
    246 U.S. 231
    , 238 [pointing out
    that ―[e]very agreement concerning trade . . . restrains‖ (italics added)].) Instead,
    the Cartwright Act and Sherman Act carry forward the common law
    24
    understanding that ―only unreasonable restraints of trade are prohibited.‖ (Marin
    County Bd. of Realtors, Inc. v. 
    Palsson, supra
    , 16 Cal.3d at p. 930.)
    Under the traditional rule of reason, ―inquiry is limited to whether the
    challenged conduct promotes or suppresses competition.‖ (Fisher v. City of
    Berkeley (1984) 
    37 Cal. 3d 644
    , 672, affd. sub nom. Fisher v. Berkeley (1986) 
    475 U.S. 260
    .) To determine whether an agreement harms competition more than it
    helps, a court may consider ―the facts peculiar to the business in which the
    restraint is applied, the nature of the restraint and its effects, and the history of the
    restraint and the reasons for its adoption.‖ (United States v. Topco Associates, Inc.
    (1972) 
    405 U.S. 596
    , 607; see Corwin v. Los Angeles Newspaper Service Bureau,
    
    Inc., supra
    , 4 Cal.3d at p. 854.) In a typical case, this may entail expert testimony
    on such matters as the definition of the relevant market (Corwin, at p. 855) and the
    extent of a defendant‘s market power (Fisherman’s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v.
    Superior Court (2003) 
    114 Cal. App. 4th 309
    , 334–339; Roth v. Rhodes (1994) 
    25 Cal. App. 4th 530
    , 542–543).
    Rule of reason inquiry is not required in every case; we and the United
    States Supreme Court have partially simplified the analysis by identifying
    categories of agreements or practices that can be said to always lack redeeming
    value and thus qualify as per se illegal. (See Northern Pac. R. Co. v. United States
    (1958) 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 5; Marin County Bd. of Realtors, Inc. v. 
    Palsson, supra
    , 16
    Cal.3d at pp. 930–931; Oakland-Alameda County Builders’ Exchange v. F. P.
    Lathrop Constr. Co. (1971) 
    4 Cal. 3d 354
    , 360–362.) ―The per se rule reflects an
    irrebuttable presumption that, if the court were to subject the conduct in question
    to a full-blown inquiry, a violation would be found under the traditional rule of
    reason.‖ (Fisher v. City of 
    Berkeley, supra
    , 37 Cal.3d at p. 666.)
    More recently, a third category, quick look rule of reason analysis, has
    emerged. (California Dental Assn. v. FTC (1999) 
    526 U.S. 756
    , 769–770; see
    25
    FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists (1986) 
    476 U.S. 447
    , 459–460; NCAA v.
    Board of Regents of Univ. of Okla. (1984) 
    468 U.S. 85
    , 109–110.) Under the
    quick look approach, applicable to cases where ―an observer with even a
    rudimentary understanding of economics could conclude that the arrangements in
    question would have an anticompetitive effect on customers and markets,‖ a
    defendant may be asked to come forward with procompetitive justifications for a
    challenged restraint without the plaintiff having to introduce elaborate market
    analysis first. (California Dental Assn., at p. 770.)
    There was a time when this court and the United States Supreme Court
    treated the choice between per se and rule of reason analysis as a necessary
    threshold inquiry involving rigidly distinct analytic boxes. In more recent years,
    however, the Supreme Court has explained, ―[t]he truth is that our categories of
    analysis of anticompetitive effect are less fixed than terms like ‗per se,‘ ‗quick
    look,‘ and ‗rule of reason‘ tend to make them appear.‖ (California Dental Assn. v.
    
    FTC, supra
    , 526 U.S. at p. 779.) ―[T]here is generally no categorical line to be
    drawn between restraints that give rise to an intuitively obvious inference of
    anticompetitive effect and those that call for more detailed treatment. What is
    required, rather, is an enquiry meet for the case, looking to the circumstances,
    details, and logic of a restraint.‖ (Id. at pp. 780–781.) The emergence of quick
    look rule of reason analysis did not signal the supplanting of the traditional per
    se/rule of reason dichotomy with a new trichotomy (Polygram Holding, Inc. v.
    FTC (D.C. Cir. 2005) 
    416 F.3d 29
    , 35), but rather a shift to ― ‗ ―something of a
    sliding scale‖ ‘ ‖ in antitrust analysis. (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186
    L.Ed.2d at p. 364, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2237].)
    This more nuanced approach makes equal sense for claims under the
    Cartwright Act. Like the federal antitrust statutes, nothing in the text of the
    Cartwright Act dictates the precise details of the per se and rule of reason
    26
    approaches; these are but useful tools the courts have developed over time to carry
    out the broad purposes and give meaning to the general phrases of the antitrust
    statutes. (See National Soc. of Professional Engineers v. United 
    States, supra
    , 435
    U.S. at p. 688.) It is consistent with the common law tradition at the root of our
    antitrust laws to describe, as the United States Supreme Court now has, the
    analytic approach as involving a continuum, with the ―the circumstances, details,
    and logic‖ of a particular restraint (California Dental Assn. v. 
    FTC, supra
    , 526
    U.S. at p. 781) dictating how the courts that confront the restraint should analyze
    it. In lieu of an undifferentiated one-size-fits-all rule of reason, courts may
    ―devise rules . . . for offering proof, or even presumptions where justified, to make
    the rule of reason a fair and efficient way to prohibit anticompetitive restraints and
    to promote procompetitive ones.‖ (Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v.
    PSKS, Inc. (2007) 
    551 U.S. 877
    , 898–899; see Fisher v. City of 
    Berkeley, supra
    ,
    37 Cal.3d at pp. 671–677 [tailoring the rule of reason to account for differences
    between private and municipal government actions].)
    It follows that we must consider not simply whether per se or rule of reason
    analysis applies to reverse payment patent settlements. To the extent rule of
    reason analysis applies, as we will conclude it does, we must also consider how
    the analysis should be structured to most efficiently differentiate between
    reasonable and unreasonable restraints of trade in this context. (See California
    Dental Assn. v. 
    FTC, supra
    , 526 U.S. at p. 781.)
    B.     The Competitive Harm from Purchasing an Extension of
    Monopoly
    We begin with the proposition that agreements to establish or maintain a
    monopoly are restraints of trade made unlawful by the Cartwright Act. (Lowell v.
    Mother’s Cake & Cookie Co. (1978) 
    79 Cal. App. 3d 13
    , 23; Dimidowich v. Bell &
    Howell (9th Cir. 1986) 
    803 F.2d 1473
    , 1478.) Under general antitrust principles, a
    27
    business may permissibly develop monopoly power, i.e., ―the power to control
    prices or exclude competition‖ (United States v. DuPont & Co. (1956) 
    351 U.S. 377
    , 391), through the superiority of its product or business acumen. To acquire
    or maintain that power through agreement and combination with others, however,
    is quite a different matter. (United States v. Grinnell Corp. (1966) 
    384 U.S. 563
    ,
    570–571.)
    Pursuant to this rule, businesses may not engage in a horizontal allocation
    of markets, with would-be competitors dividing up territories or customers.
    (United States v. Topco Associates, 
    Inc., supra
    , 405 U.S. at pp. 608, 612; Vulcan
    Powder Co. v. Hercules Powder 
    Co., supra
    , 96 Cal. at pp. 514–515; Guild
    Wineries & Distilleries v. J. Sosnick & Son (1980) 
    102 Cal. App. 3d 627
    , 633–635.)
    Such allocations afford each participant an ―enclave . . . , free from the danger of
    outside incursions,‖ in which to exercise monopoly power and extract monopoly
    premiums. (United States v. Sealy, Inc. (1967) 
    388 U.S. 350
    , 356.)
    Similarly, a firm may not ―pay[] its only potential competitor not to
    compete in return for a share of the profits that firm can obtain by being a
    monopolist.‖ (Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva 
    Pharmaceuticals, supra
    , 344 F.3d at
    p. 1304.) In Palmer v. BRG of Ga., Inc. (1990) 
    498 U.S. 46
    , for example, two
    competing bar review course providers did just that. One provider agreed to
    withdraw from a particular state market in exchange for the second provider
    paying the withdrawing provider a share of subsequent profits and agreeing in
    return not to compete outside that state market. In a per curiam opinion, the
    United States Supreme Court summarily declared the agreement unlawful on its
    face. (Id. at pp. 49–50; see Getz Bros. & Co. v. Federal Salt Co. (1905) 
    147 Cal. 115
    , 119 [payment for agreement not to compete and to discourage others from
    competing is illegal]; Wright v. 
    Ryder, supra
    , 36 Cal. at p. 359 [agreement not to
    28
    compete in California market violates common law prohibition on restraints of
    trade].)
    Second, these principles extend into the patent arena to prohibit a patentee‘s
    purchase of a potential competitor‘s consent to stay out of the market. Antitrust
    law condemns a patentee‘s payment ―to maintain supracompetitive prices to be
    shared among the patentee and the challenger rather than face what might have
    been a competitive market.‖ (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at
    p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2236].) This is so even when the patent is likely valid: ―The
    owner of a particularly valuable patent might contend, of course, that even a small
    risk of invalidity justifies a large payment. But, be that as it may, the payment (if
    otherwise unexplained) likely seeks to prevent the risk of competition. And, as we
    have said, that consequence constitutes the relevant anticompetitive harm.‖ (Ibid.)
    Actavis embraces the insights of Professor Carl Shapiro and others that the
    relevant benchmark in evaluating reverse payment patent settlements should be no
    different from the benchmark in evaluating any other challenged agreement: What
    would the state of competition have been without the agreement? In the case of a
    reverse payment settlement, the relevant comparison is with the average level of
    competition that would have obtained absent settlement, i.e., if the parties had
    litigated validity/invalidity and infringement/noninfringement to a judicial
    determination. (Shapiro, Antitrust Limits to Patent 
    Settlements, supra
    , 34 RAND
    J. Econ. at p. 396; see Addanki & Butler, Activating Actavis: Economic Issues in
    Applying the Rule of Reason to Reverse Payment Settlements (2014) 15 Minn. J. L.
    Sci. & Tech. 77, 93; Lemley & Shapiro, Probabilistic 
    Patents, supra
    , 19 J. Econ.
    Perspectives at p. 94; Willig & Bigelow, Antitrust Policy Toward Agreements that
    Settle Patent Litigation (2004) 49 Antitrust Bull. 655, 664, 677–679.) Consider a
    patent with a 50 percent chance of being upheld. After litigation, on average,
    consumers would be subject to a monopoly for half the remaining life of the
    29
    patent. A settlement that allowed a generic market entry at the midpoint of the
    time remaining until expiration would replicate the expected level of competition;
    the period of exclusion would reflect the patent‘s strength. But a settlement that
    delayed entry still longer would extend the elimination of competition beyond
    what the patent‘s strength warranted; to the extent it did, the additional elimination
    of the possibility of competition would constitute cognizable anticompetitive
    harm. (See 
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at
    p. 2236].)
    Barr argues that the procompetitive or anticompetitive effects of a
    settlement must be measured by comparison to the entire remaining life of a
    patent. We disagree. Actavis makes clear that for antitrust purposes patents are no
    longer to be treated as presumptively ironclad. This means the period of exclusion
    attributable to a patent is not its full life, but its expected life had enforcement
    been sought. This expected life represents the baseline against which the
    competitive effects of any agreement must be measured.10 If an agreement only
    replicates the likely average result of litigation, any exclusion is a function of the
    underlying patent strength; if it extends exclusion beyond that point, this further
    exclusion from the marketplace—and the attendant anticompetitive effect—is
    attributable to the agreement. Actavis thus represents an application of the settled
    principle that ―[t]he owner of a patent cannot extend his statutory grant by contract
    or agreement. A patent affords no immunity for a monopoly not fairly or plainly
    10     To be clear, because the relevant baseline is the result that would have
    occurred in the absence of any agreement, it is not a cognizable harm simply to
    show that the parties might have elected a different settlement agreement more
    favorable to competition and consumers. There is no statutory right to have
    parties enter the agreement most favorable to competition, only a prohibition
    against entering agreements that harm competition.
    30
    within the grant.‖ (U.S. v. Masonite Corp. (1942) 
    316 U.S. 265
    , 277.) The
    measure of the statutory grant, and the limit on the monopoly that may be
    preserved by agreement, is the average expected duration that would have resulted
    from judicial testing.
    This method of analysis, and of assessing anticompetitive harm, is not
    materially different from that applied in any other garden-variety antitrust case.
    Every case involves a comparison of a challenged agreement against a prediction
    about—a probabilistic assessment of—the expected competition that would have
    arisen in its absence. (Shapiro, Antitrust Analysis of Patent Settlements Between
    
    Rivals, supra
    , 17 Antitrust at p. 70.) Every restraint of trade condemned for
    suppressing market entry involves uncertainties about the extent to which
    competition would have come to pass. (Hemphill, An Aggregate Approach to
    Antitrust: Using New Data and Rulemaking to Preserve Drug 
    Competition, supra
    ,
    109 Colum. L.Rev. at p. 637.) No matter; as the leading antitrust treatise notes,
    ―the law does not condone the purchase of protection from uncertain competition
    any more than it condones the elimination of actual competition.‖ (12 Areeda &
    Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law, supra, ¶ 2030b, p. 220; see U.S. v. Microsoft Corp.
    (D.C. Cir. 2001) 
    253 F.3d 34
    , 79 (en banc) [―it would be inimical to the purpose of
    the Sherman Act to allow monopolists free reign to squash nascent, albeit
    unproven, competitors at will‖].) The antitrust laws foreclose agreements
    eliminating ―the risk of competition‖—the competitive market that ―might have
    been.‖ (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at
    p. 2236].) Purchasing freedom from the possibility of competition, whether done
    by a patentee or anyone else, is illegal. An agreement to exchange consideration
    for elimination of any portion of the period of competition that would have been
    expected had a patent been litigated is a violation of the Cartwright Act.
    31
    C.     The Structure of the Rule of Reason as Applied to Patent
    Settlements
    We consider next how to identify whether the parties‘ settlement agreement
    eliminates competition beyond the point at which competition would have been
    expected in the absence of an agreement. Only if the agreement limits competition
    beyond that point, the point the strength of the patent would have justified, is there
    an antitrust issue.
    1.    Plaintiff‘s Prima Facie Case
    We conclude a third-party plaintiff challenging a reverse payment patent
    settlement must show four elements: (1) the settlement includes a limit on the
    settling generic challenger‘s entry into the market; (2) the settlement includes cash
    or equivalent financial consideration flowing from the brand to the generic
    challenger; and the consideration exceeds (3) the value of goods and services other
    than any delay in market entry provided by the generic challenger to the brand, as
    well as (4) the brand‘s expected remaining litigation costs absent settlement. We
    explain these elements in turn.
    That a plaintiff challenging a reverse payment settlement must establish the
    settlement limits the challenging generic‘s entry is self-evident. If the settlement
    contains no component of delay and permits the generic to enter the market and
    compete fully and immediately, there is no restraint of trade and no potential for
    antitrust concern.
    As well, a plaintiff must establish a reverse payment—financial
    consideration flowing from the brand to the generic challenger.11 In the absence
    11     To some extent, the settlement agreement challenged here is a relic. Cash
    reverse payments were not uncommon in the 1990s, but shortly thereafter brands
    and generics began using a wide range of other forms of consideration to
    accomplish reverse payment. (See Hemphill, An Aggregate Approach to
    Antitrust: Using New Data and Rulemaking to Preserve Drug 
    Competition, supra
    ,
    (footnote continued on next page)
    32
    of payment, one would expect rational parties that settle to select a market entry
    point roughly corresponding to their joint expectation as to when entry would have
    occurred, on average, if the patent‘s validity and infringement had been fully
    litigated. (Hovenkamp et al., Anticompetitive Settlement of Intellectual Property
    Disputes (2003) 87 Minn. L.Rev. 1719, 1762.) If market entry were substantially
    later than the generic thought it could obtain through litigation, the generic would
    be unwilling to settle and forgo the additional profits it thought it could earn from
    an earlier entry; conversely, if the entry were substantially earlier than the brand
    thought it could obtain through litigation, the brand would not settle and forgo an
    additional period of monopoly. Absent payment, one can accept an agreement to
    postpone market entry as a fair approximation of the expected level of competition
    that would have obtained had the parties litigated; absent payment, any delay in
    entry may be attributed to the effective strength of the challenged patent, rather
    than the settlement agreement. (See ibid.; Carrier, Payment After Actavis (2014)
    100 Iowa L.Rev. 7, 17.)
    Third, a plaintiff must establish the consideration to the generic challenger
    exceeds the value of any other collateral products or services provided by the
    generic to the brand. As the Supreme Court noted, the concern that a reverse
    payment raises will depend in part on ―its independence from other services for
    which it might represent payment.‖ (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186
    (footnote continued from previous page)
    109 Colum. L.Rev. at pp. 647–658.) Because the Cipro settlement involved cash,
    we need not define precisely what noncash forms of consideration will qualify, but
    courts considering Cartwright Act claims should not let creative variations in the
    form of consideration result in the purchase of freedom from competition escaping
    detection.
    33
    L.Ed.2d at p. 364, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2237].) A ―payment may reflect compensation
    for other services that the generic has promised to perform—such as distributing
    the patented item or helping to develop a market for that item.‖ (Id. at p. ___ [186
    L.Ed.2d at p. 362, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2236.) If payment is no more than would be
    expected as compensation for additional products or services, then the agreement
    includes no additional consideration for delay and we can trust that any limit on
    competition is a legitimate consequence of the patent‘s strength and the
    contracting parties‘ expectations concerning its exclusionary power.
    Considerable caution is in order in evaluating settlements that include side
    agreements for generic products or services. Historically, it appears brands and
    generics have engaged in business dealings outside the settlement context far less
    often than in it. (Hemphill, An Aggregate Approach to Antitrust: Using New Data
    and Rulemaking to Preserve Drug 
    Competition, supra
    , 109 Colum. L.Rev. at
    pp. 663–668.) A side agreement involving difficult-to-value assets might
    conceivably be added to a patent settlement to provide cover for the purchase of
    additional freedom from competition. (Id. at pp. 632–633, 669; Bulow, The
    Gaming of Pharmaceutical Patents in 4 Innovation Policy and the 
    Economy, supra
    , at pp. 169–171; Carrier, Unsettling Drug Patent Settlements: A Framework
    for Presumptive 
    Illegality, supra
    , 108 Mich. L.Rev. at p. 79.) This court long ago
    established that side deals should not be permitted to serve as fig leaves for
    agreements to eliminate competition. In Getz Bros. & Co. v. Federal Salt 
    Co., supra
    , 
    147 Cal. 115
    , the parties entered an agreement to exchange money for (1)
    an agreement not to compete and to discourage competition in the salt trade and
    (2) more than 1,000 pounds of salt. Precisely how much of the payment was
    attributable to the actual provision of salt we could not say, but so long as any
    portion of the payment was attributable to the covenant not to compete—and we
    34
    viewed it as ―plain . . . that part of it, at least, was‖—the deal as a whole was an
    illegal restraint of trade. (Id. at p. 118.)
    Fourth, a plaintiff must establish the amount of the payment, over and
    above the value of collateral products or services from the generic, also exceeds
    the brand‘s anticipated future litigation costs. In some cases, a ―reverse payment
    . . . may amount to no more than a rough approximation of the litigation expenses
    saved through the settlement. . . . Where a reverse payment reflects traditional
    settlement considerations, such as avoided litigation costs or fair value for
    services, there is not the same concern that a patentee is using its monopoly profits
    to avoid the risk of patent invalidation or a finding of noninfringement. In such
    cases, the parties may have provided for a reverse payment without having sought
    or brought about the anticompetitive consequences we mentioned above.‖
    (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 362, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2236].)
    A rational brand might be indifferent as between (1) actually litigating or (2)
    settling, with market entry at the point expected, on average, from asserting its
    patent in litigation and a payment to the generic in an amount up to what would
    have been spent in that litigation. It is thus necessary to evaluate the reverse
    payment‘s ―scale in relation to the payor‘s anticipated future litigation costs.‖ (Id.
    at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 364, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2237].)
    We consider briefly the allocation of burdens of proof and production.
    Unless a challenged settlement agreement includes both a restraint on generic
    competition and a reverse payment to the generic in excess of both brand litigation
    costs and generic collateral products and services, there is no reason to assume the
    settlement includes any element of purchased freedom from competition, as
    opposed to a limit on competition flowing naturally, and lawfully, from the
    perceived strength of the brand‘s patent. Accordingly, the burden of proof as to
    35
    these elements rests with the Cartwright Act plaintiff. (See Aguilar v. Atlantic
    Richfield Co. (2001) 
    25 Cal. 4th 826
    , 861.)
    The burden of producing evidence (see Evid. Code, §§ 110, 550) is a
    slightly different matter. ― ‗Where the evidence necessary to establish a fact
    essential to a claim lies peculiarly within the knowledge and competence of one of
    the parties, that party has the burden of going forward with the evidence on the
    issue although it is not the party asserting the claim.‘ ‖ (Sanchez v. Unemployment
    Ins. Appeals Bd. (1977) 
    20 Cal. 3d 55
    , 71.) This is so with regard to both a settling
    party‘s own litigation costs and the existence and value of any collateral products
    or services provided as part of a patent settlement; these are matters about which
    the settling parties will necessarily have superior knowledge.12 Accordingly, once
    a plaintiff has shown an agreement involving a reverse payment and delay, the
    defendants have the burden of coming forward with evidence of litigation costs
    and the value of collateral products and services.13 If the defendants fail to do so,
    because, e.g., there was no side agreement or because they do not dispute the
    collective amounts fall short of any payment to the generic, the plaintiff has
    satisfied its burden on these points. If instead the defendants do so, the plaintiff
    must carry the ultimate burden of persuasion that any reverse payment exceeds
    litigation costs and the value of collateral products or services.
    12      We do not suggest a defendant‘s testimony concerning the value conveyed
    in side agreements is entitled to any more weight than the plaintiff‘s, only that the
    defendants have the initial burden of introducing evidence of agreements for the
    purchase of other products or services sufficiently valuable to explain any
    payment.
    13      Here, the brand, Bayer, settled out of the antitrust case, and Barr would not
    be in a superior position with regard to knowledge of Bayer‘s future patent
    litigation costs, so the burden of production on this point would remain with
    plaintiffs.
    36
    We further conclude that a showing of the above elements is not only
    necessary but also sufficient to make out a prima facie case that the settlement is
    anticompetitive. If a brand is willing to pay a generic more than the costs of
    continued litigation, and more than the value of any collateral benefits, in order to
    settle and keep the generic out of the market, there is cause to believe some
    portion of the consideration is payment for exclusion beyond the point that would
    have resulted, on average, from simply litigating the case to its conclusion.
    Otherwise, the brand would have had little incentive to settle at such a high price.
    Moreover, the larger the gap, the stronger the inference one can draw.
    A wealth of economic scholarship and analysis supports this inference.
    Because the profit that can be earned under monopoly conditions is greater than
    the combined profit that can be earned under duopoly conditions,14 a brand and
    generic have a substantial incentive to settle at the latest market entry date
    possible, with the brand paying a portion of monopoly profits to compensate the
    generic for what it would have earned with an earlier entry.15 If the parties can
    14     While this is a broadly shared economic tenet, it has also been empirically
    demonstrated by the FDA in the current context. (See FDA, Center for Drug
    Evaluation and Research, Generic Competition and Drug Prices (2010) online at
     [last visited May 7,
    2015].) Indeed, in its briefing Barr effectively concedes this is the case here:
    ―[E]ach day of early entry would have cost Bayer more given the price of its
    branded product than it would have benefitted Barr given the price of its generic
    product.‖
    15      
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at pp. 361–362, 133 S.Ct.
    at pp. 2234–2235]; see, e.g., Hovenkamp, Anticompetitive Patent Settlements and
    the Supreme Court’s Actavis 
    Decision, supra
    , 15 Minn. J. L. Sci. & Tech. at pages
    8–13; Mungan, Reverse Payments, Perverse Incentives (2013) 27 Harv. J. Law &
    Tech. 1, 5–6, 27, 34; Elhauge & Krueger, Solving the Patent Settlement Puzzle
    (2012) 91 Tex. L.Rev. 283, 289; Kades, Whistling Past the Graveyard: The
    Problem with the Per Se Legality Treatment of Pay-for-Delay Settlements (2009) 5
    (footnote continued on next page)
    37
    share monopoly profits through a reverse payment from the brand to the generic,
    the generic no longer has motivation to hold out for its best estimate of the average
    entry point it could obtain through litigation. Instead, the parties‘ interests align in
    favor of maximizing their combined wealth by extending the monopoly for as long
    as possible. Once payment to the generic exceeds what the brand is otherwise
    receiving from it in products and services or would have spent to litigate, a court
    may fairly presume the settling parties have engaged in such conduct and should
    be put to the burden of coming forward with a procompetitive justification for
    their settlement. (Elhauge & Krueger, Solving the Patent Settlement 
    Puzzle, supra
    , 91 Tex. L.Rev. at pp. 297–304; see Edlin et al., Activating Actavis (2013)
    28 Antitrust 16, 22, appen.; Lemley & Shapiro, Probabilistic 
    Patents, supra
    , 19 J.
    Econ. Perspectives at p. 93; Shapiro, Antitrust Limits to Patent 
    Settlements, supra
    ,
    34 RAND J. Econ. at p. 408.)
    Barr argues this degree of scrutiny will stifle innovation. But Congress was
    not authorized to, and did not, grant inventors eternal monopolies; instead, it
    approved a scheme that presumptively represents the appropriate balance between
    promoting innovation and allowing competition. Reverse payment patent
    settlements may enable the parties to extend the monopoly beyond that point.
    (Elhauge & Krueger, Solving the Patent Settlement 
    Puzzle, supra
    , 91 Tex. L.Rev.
    (footnote continued from previous page)
    Competition Policy Internat. 143, 148–150; Leffler & Leffler, Settling the
    Controversy over Patent Settlements in Antitrust Law and Economics (Kirkwood
    edit., 2004) 475, 480–484; Willig & Bigelow, Antitrust Policy Toward Agreements
    that Settle Patent 
    Litigation, supra
    , 49 Antitrust Bull. at page 659; Bulow, The
    Gaming of Pharmaceutical Patents in 4 Innovation Policy and the 
    Economy, supra
    , at page 166; Shapiro, Antitrust Limits to Patent 
    Settlements, supra
    , 34
    RAND J. Econ. at pages 394–395.
    38
    at pp. 295–304; Lemley & Shapiro, Probabilistic 
    Patents, supra
    , 19 J. Econ.
    Perspectives at p. 93; Leffler & Leffler, Efficiency Trade-Offs in Patent Litigation
    Settlements: Analysis Gone Astray? (2004) 39 U.S.F. L.Rev. 33, 37–38; Shapiro,
    Antitrust Analysis of Patent Settlements Between 
    Rivals, supra
    , 17 Antitrust at
    p. 73.) Indeed, insufficient scrutiny of such settlements has the potential to
    hamper innovation by allowing weak patents to offer the exact same exclusionary
    potential and monopoly possibilities as strong ones,16 thus steering innovator
    incentives away from more costly true innovation and toward cheaper, less
    socially valuable pseudoinnovation. (See Mungan, Reverse Payments, Perverse
    
    Incentives, supra
    , 27 Harv. J. Law & Tech. at pp. 42–44; Elhauge & Krueger,
    Solving the Patent Settlement Puzzle, at pp. 294–295.)
    Relatedly, Barr expresses concern that close scrutiny of reverse payment
    settlements will chill some generics from challenging patents, to the detriment of
    consumers. But any challenge that results in the brand simply paying the generic
    not to compete—a potentially common outcome absent scrutiny—does nothing to
    enhance competition, and deterring such challenges accordingly represents no loss
    to consumers. Moreover, standard economic theory suggests reducing unfettered
    access to reverse payment settlements would chill generic challenges to strong,
    16      See In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust 
    Litigation, supra
    , 466 F.3d at
    page 211 (noting the ―troubling dynamic‖ that ―[t]he less sound the patent or the
    less clear the infringement, and therefore the less justified the monopoly enjoyed
    by the patent holder, the more a rule permitting settlement is likely to benefit the
    patent holder by allowing it to retain the patent‖); Hemphill, An Aggregate
    Approach to Antitrust: Using New Data and Rulemaking to Preserve Drug
    
    Competition, supra
    , 109 Colum. L.Rev. at page 638 (treating patents as
    conclusively valid until expiration ―produces the absurd result that an ironclad
    patent and a trivial patent have the same exclusionary force‖); Bulow, The Gaming
    of Pharmaceutical Patents in Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 
    4, supra
    , at page 167.
    39
    likely valid patents more than challenges to weak patents. The effect would be to
    increase the value of strong patents, while still leaving generics incentives to
    challenge weak patents. (Mungan, Reverse Payments, Perverse 
    Incentives, supra
    ,
    27 Harv. J. Law & Tech. at p. 7.) This consequence presents no reason to scale
    back scrutiny of these settlements.
    Finally, Barr argues that in some cases only a reverse payment can bridge
    the differences between the brand and generic challenger and make settlement
    possible. Perhaps; but as the Supreme Court has made clear, ordinarily ―the fact
    that a large, unjustified reverse payment risks antitrust liability does not prevent
    litigating parties from settling their lawsuit.‖ (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___
    [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2237].) Parties can still use financial
    considerations to bridge small gaps arising from differing subjective perceptions
    of their probabilities of success in litigation; what they cannot do is use money to
    bridge their differences over the point when competitive entry is economically
    desirable, for that gap is not one antitrust law permits would-be competitors to
    bridge by agreement: ―If the basic reason [the parties prefer a reverse payment
    settlement] is a desire to maintain and to share patent-generated monopoly profits,
    then, in the absence of some other justification, the antitrust laws are likely to
    forbid the arrangement.‖ (Ibid.) That some settlements might no longer be
    possible absent a payment in excess of litigation costs is no concern if the ones
    now barred would simply have facilitated the sharing of monopoly profits.
    Barr relies on one commentary showing that some theoretically possible
    settlements involving payments exceeding the sum of expected litigation costs and
    the value of other products and services might enhance consumer welfare. (Harris
    et al., Activating Actavis: A More Complete Story (2014) 28 Antitrust 83.) The
    principal conclusion is that introducing brand risk aversion into the settlement
    model opens up a region of possible settlements involving supralitigation cost
    40
    payments that nevertheless increase consumer welfare by enabling earlier generic
    market entry dates.17 What is not shown is that such settlements are at all likely in
    practice. Although a brand and generic may through payment of money be able to
    settle on an earlier entry date than would arise from litigation, their incentive (if
    left undeterred by the antitrust regime) remains to settle on a far later entry date
    for still larger sums of money, as even some of the leading economists
    highlighting the relevance of risk aversion recognize. (Willig & Bigelow,
    Antitrust Policy Toward Agreements that Settle Patent 
    Litigation, supra
    , 49
    Antitrust Bull. at p. 659.) Attempts to quantitatively estimate the frequency with
    which risk aversion would produce an efficient settlement despite payment in
    excess of litigation costs suggest such occurrences would be exceedingly rare.
    (Leffler & Leffler, The Probabilistic Nature of Patent 
    Rights, supra
    , 17 Antitrust
    at pp. 79–80; Leffler & Leffler, Settling the Controversy over Patent Settlements
    in Antitrust Law and 
    Economics, supra
    , at p. 504; see Bulow, The Gaming of
    Pharmaceutical Patents in 4 Innovation Policy and the 
    Economy, supra
    , at
    p. 167.) Thus, while we do not discount the possibility, it affords no reason to
    expand plaintiff‘s prima facie case beyond the elements discussed.
    We also observe that the outlined prima facie showing will suffice, without
    more, to raise a presumption of the patentee‘s market power. Proving that a
    restraint has anticompetitive effects often requires the plaintiff to ― ‗delineate a
    17      The Harris model also addresses the effects of asymmetric information, but
    different perspectives on the likelihood of success are unlikely to alone render it
    possible for a supralitigation-costs reverse payment settlement to be efficient.
    (Elhauge & Krueger, Solving the Patent Settlement 
    Puzzle, supra
    , 91 Tex. L.Rev.
    at pp. 300–303, 325–329.) Money may be needed to bridge the gap between the
    parties‘ expectations, but a rational brand asked to pay more than its litigation
    costs to persuade a generic with different perceptions would, in the ordinary case,
    presumably just litigate.
    41
    relevant market and show that the defendant plays enough of a role in that market
    to impair competition significantly,‘ ‖ i.e., has market power. (Roth v. 
    Rhodes, supra
    , 25 Cal.App.4th at p. 542.) Here, proof of a sufficiently large payment is a
    surrogate: ―the ‗size of the payment from a branded drug manufacturer to a
    prospective generic is itself a strong indicator of power‘—namely, the power to
    charge prices higher than the competitive level.‖ (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at
    p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 362, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2236].) Logically, a patentee would
    not pay others to stay out of the market unless it had sufficient market power to
    recoup its payments through supracompetitive pricing. (Ibid.) Consequently,
    proof of a reverse payment in excess of litigation costs and collateral products and
    services raises a presumption that the settling patentee has market power sufficient
    for the settlement to generate significant anticompetitive effects.
    2.     Defendants‘ Rebuttal
    Once a plaintiff has made out a prima facie case that a reverse payment
    patent settlement has anticompetitive effects, a court ―must weigh these
    anticompetitive effects against the possible justifications‖ for the challenged
    restraint. (Marin County Bd. of Realtors, Inc. v. 
    Palsson, supra
    , 16 Cal.3d at
    p. 937.) At this point, we deem it appropriate to shift the burden to the defendants
    to offer legitimate justifications and come forward with evidence that the
    challenged settlement is in fact procompetitive. (See Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16725
    [―[i]t is not unlawful to enter‖ an agreement ―to promote, encourage, or increase
    competition‖]; 
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 362, 
    133 S. Ct. 42
    at p. 2236] [―An antitrust defendant may show in the antitrust proceeding that
    legitimate justifications are present.‖].)18
    Plaintiffs argue we should declare every reverse payment in excess of
    litigation costs and collateral products and services a per se violation of the
    Cartwright Act. We are unwilling to declare every settlement payment of a certain
    size illegal. Like the United States Supreme Court, we cannot say with reasonable
    certainty—yet—that we have posited every possible justification that might render
    a particular reverse payment settlement procompetitive. (See 
    Actavis, supra
    , 570
    U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 362, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2236].) The theoretical
    possibility that a settlement in excess of litigation costs and collateral services
    could be procompetitive, while insufficient to alter the plaintiff‘s prima facie case,
    is nevertheless sufficient for us to reject a categorical rule and instead afford
    defendants the opportunity to demonstrate a given settlement is the exception.
    This does not mean any justification will do. An antitrust defendant cannot
    argue a settlement is procompetitive simply because it allows competition earlier
    than would have occurred if the brand had won the patent action; as Actavis and
    our previous discussion make clear, the relevant baseline is the average period of
    competition that would have obtained in the absence of settlement. (See 
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2236].)19
    18     See also FTC v. Indiana Federation of 
    Dentists, supra
    , 476 U.S. at
    pages 459–461; National Soc. of Professional Engineers v. United 
    States, supra
    ,
    435 U.S. at page 693; 7 Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law (3d ed. 2010)
    ¶¶ 1504b, 1507c, pages 402–403, 430.
    19      This point also addresses Barr‘s argument that causation is lacking in
    reverse payment cases because absent a settlement, the parties would have
    litigated, the patentee would likely or surely have won, and consumers would have
    been no better off. At the time of settlement, the outcome of future litigation is
    uncertain, and an agreement that ―seeks to prevent the risk of competition‖ causes,
    (footnote continued on next page)
    43
    Likewise, consideration of whether the agreement is justified as
    procompetitive will not turn on whether the patent would ultimately have been
    proved valid or invalid. Agreements must be assessed as of the time they are
    made (Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva 
    Pharmaceuticals, supra
    , 344 F.3d at p. 1306), at
    which point the patent‘s validity is unknown and unknowable. Just as later
    invalidation of a patent does not prove an agreement when made was
    anticompetitive (
    id. at pp.
    1306–1307), later evidence of validity will not
    automatically demonstrate an agreement was procompetitive.20 Antitrust law
    condemns the purchase of freedom from competition; what matters is whether a
    settlement postpones market entry beyond the average point that would have been
    expected at the time in the absence of agreement. (See In re Aggrenox Antitrust
    Lit. (D. Conn., Mar. 23, 2015, No. 3:14-md-2516 (SRU)) __ F.Supp.3d __ [2015
    U.S.Dist. Lexis 35634, *38] [―The salient question is not whether the fully-
    litigated patent would ultimately be found valid or invalid—that may never be
    known—but whether the settlement included a large and unjustified reverse
    payment leading to the inference of profit-sharing to avoid the risk of
    competition.‖].)
    To determine whether such a settlement has occurred under state law, as
    under federal law, ―it is normally not necessary to litigate patent validity.‖
    (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2236].)
    (footnote continued from previous page)
    i.e., has as a ―consequence . . . the relevant anticompetitive harm.‖ (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2236].)
    20     Some kinds of evidence may also be suspect: once a brand and generic
    challenger settle, their incentives align in favor of arguing that the patent was
    stronger and more clearly infringed than it may have appeared at the time.
    44
    ―An unexplained large reverse payment itself would normally suggest that the
    patentee has serious doubts about the patent‘s survival. And that fact, in turn,
    suggests that the payment‘s objective is to maintain supracompetitive prices to be
    shared among the patentee and the challenger rather than face what might have
    been a competitive market—the very anticompetitive consequence that underlies
    the claim of antitrust unlawfulness. . . . In a word, the size of the unexplained
    reverse payment can provide a workable surrogate for a patent‘s weakness, all
    without forcing a court to conduct a detailed exploration of the validity of the
    patent itself.‖ (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at pp. 2236–2237].)
    3.     The Plaintiff‘s Ultimate Burden
    The ultimate burden throughout rests with the plaintiff to show that a
    challenged settlement agreement is anticompetitive. (Bert G. Gianelli Distributing
    Co. v. Beck & Co. (1985) 
    172 Cal. App. 3d 1020
    , 1048.) Once the plaintiff has
    made out a prima facie case that a reverse payment patent settlement is
    anticompetitive, however, the plaintiff thereafter need only show that any
    procompetitive justifications proffered by the defendants are unsupportable. (See
    Polygram Holding, Inc. v. 
    FTC, supra
    , 416 F.3d at pp. 37–38.)
    The ultimate question in reverse payment settlement cases is whether an
    agreement involves ―significant unjustified anticompetitive consequences.‖
    (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 364, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2238].)
    The prima facie case requires the plaintiff to eliminate the possibility that litigation
    costs or other products or services could explain the consideration paid the
    generic. If a plaintiff does so and thereafter can dispel each additional justification
    the defendants put forward to explain the consideration, the conclusion follows
    that the settlement payment must include, in part, consideration for additional
    delay in entering the market. That payment for delay is condemned by the
    45
    Cartwright Act, as by federal antitrust law, and its purchase as part of a settlement
    agreement is an unlawful restraint of trade.
    *             *              *
    We summarize the structure of the rule of reason applicable to reverse
    payment patent settlements. To make out a prima facie case that a challenged
    agreement is an unlawful restraint of trade, a plaintiff must show the agreement
    contains both a limit on the generic challenger‘s entry into the market and
    compensation from the patentee to the challenger. The defendants bear the burden
    of coming forward with evidence of litigation costs or valuable collateral products
    or services that might explain the compensation; if the defendants do so, the
    plaintiff has the burden of demonstrating the compensation exceeds the reasonable
    value of these. If a prima facie case has been made out, the defendants may come
    forward with additional justifications to demonstrate the settlement agreement
    nevertheless is procompetitive. A plaintiff who can dispel these justifications has
    carried the burden of demonstrating the settlement agreement is an unreasonable
    restraint of trade under the Cartwright Act.
    D.     Preemption
    Barr argues federal preemption concerns narrowly constrain how reverse
    payment patent settlements must be analyzed under state law. According to Barr,
    any rule more stringent than the traditional, unstructured rule of reason would fall
    prey to obstacle preemption, which ―arises when ‗ ―under the circumstances of [a]
    particular case, [the challenged state law] stands as an obstacle to the
    accomplishment and execution of the full purposes and objectives of
    Congress.‖ ‘ ‖ (Viva! Internat. Voice for Animals v. Adidas Promotional Retail
    Operations, Inc. (2007) 
    41 Cal. 4th 929
    , 936.) We disagree; the rule we adopt is in
    harmony with Actavis, which offered only broad outlines and explicitly left to
    46
    other courts the task of developing a framework for analyzing the anticompetitive
    effects of reverse payment patent settlements. (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___
    [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 364, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2238].)
    State antitrust law ordinarily is fully compatible with federal law. States
    have regulated against monopolies and unfair competition for longer than the
    federal government, and federal law is intended only ―to supplement, not displace,
    state antitrust remedies.‖ (California v. ARC America Corp. (1989) 
    490 U.S. 93
    ,
    102; see 
    id. at pp.
    101–102 & fn. 4; Partee v. San Diego Chargers Football Co.
    (1983) 
    34 Cal. 3d 378
    , 382.) ―[T]he Cartwright Act is broader in range and deeper
    in reach than the Sherman Act‖ (Cianci v. Superior 
    Court, supra
    , 40 Cal.3d at
    p. 920); this greater domain has never been thought to pose supremacy clause
    problems. To the contrary, in light of the established state role, a presumption
    against preemption applies. (ARC America Corp., at p. 101.)
    Barr argues that to avoid conflicting with federal patent law, state antitrust
    law must cohere with the federal rule that patents are presumed valid. (See 35
    U.S.C. § 282.) But as we have discussed, the Patent Act‘s allocation of a burden
    of proof is no more than a procedural device. It does not insulate settlements of
    patent disputes from federal antitrust scrutiny (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___
    [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 356, 133 S.Ct. at pp. 2230–2231]), nor does it insulate them
    from state antitrust scrutiny. The agnostic stance toward patent validity our
    structured rule of reason adopts is identical to that embraced by the United States
    Supreme Court under federal antitrust law: a patent may or may not be valid or
    infringed. (Ibid.) What matters instead is simply whether a payoff to eliminate
    the possibility of competition has occurred. (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 363,
    133 S.Ct. at p. 2236.) If federal antitrust law can conduct that inquiry without
    offense to patent law, so too can the state antitrust law it was designed to
    supplement.
    47
    Additionally, Barr argues the rule we adopt must be no more favorable to
    reverse payment patent settlement challenges than would be the case under
    Actavis. The supposed rationale is that Actavis identifies precisely the
    accommodation patent law requires of antitrust law, such that deviation would
    pose an obstacle to congressional patent objectives.
    If Actavis had established a special rule limiting antitrust scrutiny of reverse
    payment settlements in order to preserve the incentives created by the patent
    system, we might agree. But the lesson of Actavis is that nothing in the patent
    laws or the Hatch-Waxman Act dictates such a special rule; that a settlement
    resolves a patent dispute does not ―immunize the agreement from antitrust attack.‖
    (
    Actavis, supra
    , 570 U.S. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 356, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2230].)
    Instead, such agreements may, like any other form of agreement restraining trade,
    be examined for unjustified anticompetitive effects. (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at
    p. 364, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2238].) As for how such an examination is to be conducted,
    Actavis reverts solely to antitrust considerations. (Id. at p. ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at
    p. 364, 133 S.Ct. at pp. 2237–2238].) In selecting a test to apply—to the extent
    the Supreme Court does, as opposed to ―leav[ing] to the lower courts the
    structuring of the present rule-of-reason antitrust litigation‖ (
    id. at p.
    ___ [186
    L.Ed.2d at p. 364, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2238])—the Court looks to whether its
    experience with the economics of reverse payment settlements is sufficient to
    allow it, yet, to require particular modifications to rule-of-reason analysis (
    id. at p.
    ___ [186 L.Ed.2d at p. 363, 133 S.Ct. at p. 2237]).
    Where the choice of a test rests solely on economic analysis, no patent law
    preemption concerns arise. Instead, the issue reduces to a problem in the relation
    between federal and state antitrust law, and there the Supreme Court has been
    quite clear that states may depart from federal rules—or, here, accept an invitation
    to develop a gap in the law explicitly left by the Supreme Court—absent evidence
    48
    of a clear congressional purpose to the contrary. (California v. ARC America
    
    Corp., supra
    , 490 U.S. at p. 103.)
    We note as well that the structured rule of reason we adopt is consistent
    with, not an obstacle to, congressional patent and health care goals in two specific
    ways. First, considerable research and analysis suggests the broad availability of
    reverse payment settlements favors weak patents and channels investment
    resources toward suboptimal innovation prospects. (See ante, pp. 38–39.) To the
    extent careful scrutiny of such settlements promotes the very innovation the patent
    laws were intended to promote, it cannot stand as an obstacle to congressional
    objectives.
    Second, a fundamental goal of the Hatch-Waxman Act is to enhance
    generic competition and thereby lower prices. Congress rued the ―serious anti-
    competitive effects‖ of existing rules for generic drug approval, rules that resulted
    in ―the practical extension of the monopoly position of the patent holder beyond
    the expiration of the patent.‖ (H.R.Rep. No. 98-857, 2d Sess., pt. 2, p. 4 (1984),
    reprinted in 1984 U.S. Code Cong. & Admin. News, p. 2688.) The substantial
    reworking of those rules to ease generic approval was designed to ―make available
    more low cost generic drugs‖ (Id., pt. 1, p. 14, reprinted in 1984 U.S. Code Cong.
    & Admin. News, p. 2647) and reduce costs for consumers and government-funded
    health care alike (
    id. at p.
    17, reprinted in 1984 U.S. Code Cong. & Admin. News,
    p. 2650). By ferreting out anticompetitive agreements that limit generic market
    entry and sustain costly monopolies, a structured rule of reason serves those goals
    and poses no obstacle to congressional objectives.21
    21      A second federalism concern raised by the Court of Appeal, that state
    antitrust scrutiny would intrude on the exclusivity of federal court patent
    jurisdiction (see 28 U.S.C. § 1338(a)), likewise presents no issue. This exclusive
    (footnote continued on next page)
    49
    E.       Application
    The trial court and Court of Appeal treated the ‘444 patent as ironclad and
    used the entire period until its expiration as the relevant benchmark in order to
    assess whether the parties‘ settlement agreement had anticompetitive effects. This
    was error.
    Barr argues we nevertheless should affirm because in the course of their
    respective opinions the trial court and Court of Appeal purported to apply the rule
    of reason in addition to the scope of the patent test. But the rule of reason these
    courts applied is not the structured rule of reason for reverse payment patent
    settlements we articulate today to effectuate the purposes of the Cartwright Act.
    Rather, in each instance the courts simply concluded that because the agreement
    did not exclude competition beyond what the ‘444 patent would have permitted
    (assuming it were valid), the agreement necessarily had no anticompetitive effect
    and was not unlawful under the rule of reason. The same misapprehension
    underlying the lower courts‘ scope of the patent analysis, that for antitrust
    purposes patents are ironclad, also underlay their rule of reason analysis.
    Accordingly, we must reverse.
    (footnote continued from previous page)
    jurisdiction does not prevent state courts from deciding state law claims
    incidentally touching on the validity of a patent. (Caldera Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
    v. Regents of University of California (2012) 
    205 Cal. App. 4th 338
    , 353–356.)
    Moreover, the ―slim category‖ of state law claims subject to exclusive federal
    patent jurisdiction includes only those that ― ‗necessarily raise‘ ‖ a federal patent
    issue. (Gunn v. Minton (2013) 568 U.S. ___, ___ [
    185 L. Ed. 2d 72
    , 79, 
    133 S. Ct. 1059
    , 1065].) As we have discussed, it is entirely possible to resolve an antitrust
    challenge to a reverse payment patent settlement without adjudicating the patent‘s
    validity.
    50
    V.     Unfair Competition Law and Common Law Monopoly Claims
    The trial court entered judgment against plaintiffs on their unfair
    competition and common law monopoly claims using the same reasoning it
    applied to the Cartwright Act claim. Because that reasoning was erroneous, we
    reverse on these claims as well.
    51
    DISPOSITION
    We reverse the Court of Appeal‘s judgment and remand for further
    proceedings consistent with this opinion.
    WERDEGAR, J.
    WE CONCUR:
    CANTIL-SAKAUYE, C. J.
    CHIN, J.
    CORRIGAN, J.
    LIU, J.
    CUÉLLAR, J.
    KRUGER, J.
    52
    See last page for addresses and telephone numbers for counsel who argued in Supreme Court.
    Name of Opinion In re Cipro Cases I & II
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Unpublished Opinion
    Original Appeal
    Original Proceeding
    Review Granted XXX 
    200 Cal. App. 4th 442
    Rehearing Granted
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Opinion No. S198616
    Date Filed: May 7, 2015
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Court: Superior
    County: San Diego
    Judge: Richard E. L. Strauss
    __________________________________________________________________________________
    Counsel:
    Lieff, Cabraser, Heimann & Bernstein, Eric B. Fastiff, Brendan Glackin, Jordan Elias, Dean M. Harvey;
    Joseph Saveri Law Firm, Joseph R. Saveri, Lisa J. Leebove; Krause, Kalfayan, Benink & Slavens, Ralph B.
    Kalfayan; Zwerling, Schachter & Zwerling, Dan Drachler; Durie Tangri and Mark A. Lemley for Plaintiffs
    and Appellants.
    The Kralowec Law Group and Kimberly A. Kralowec for Consumer Attorneys of California as Amicus
    Curiae on behalf or Plaintiffs and Appellants.
    Michael A. Carrier; Zelle Hofmann Voelbel & Mason and Judith A. Zahid for 49 Professors as Amici
    Curiae on behalf or Plaintiffs and Appellants.
    Mark A. Lemley for 78 Intellectual Property Law, Antitrust Law, Economics and Business Professors as
    Amici Curiae on behalf or Plaintiffs and Appellants.
    Richard M. Brunell; Zelle Hofmann Voelbel & Mason and Judith A. Zahid for American Antitrust Institute
    as Amicus Curiae on behalf or Plaintiffs and Appellants.
    Edleson & Rezzo, Joann F. Rezzo; Karcher Harmes, Kathryn E. Karcher; Stinson Morrison Hecker,
    Stinson Leonard Street, David E. Everson, Heather S. Woodson and Victoria L. Smith for Defendants and
    Respondents Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc., The Rugby Group, Inc., and Watson Pharmaceuticals, Inc.
    Luce, Forward, Hamilton & Scripps, McKenna Long & Aldridge, Charles A. Bird, Christopher J. Healey,
    Todd R. Kinnear; Jones Day, Kevin D. McDonald; Bartlit Beck Herman Palenchar & Schott and Peter B.
    Bensinger, Jr., for Defendant and Respondent Bayer Corporation.
    Kirkland & Ellis, Jay P. Lefkowitz, Edwin John U, Karen N. Walker and Gregory L. Skidmore for
    Defendant and Respondent Barr Laboratories, Inc.
    1
    Page 2 – counsel continued – S198616
    Counsel:
    Richard A. Samp, Cory L. Andrews; Law Offices of Mark E. Foster and Mark E. foster for Washington
    Legal Foundation as Amicus Curiae on behalf of Defendants and Respondents.
    Munger , Tolles & Olson, Jeffrey I. Weinberger, Adam R. Lawton, Guha Krishnamurthi, Rohit K. Singla
    and Michelle T. Friedland for The Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America as Amicus
    Curiae on behalf of Defendants and Respondents.
    Stevens & Lee, Joseph Wolfson; Duane Morris and Paul J. Killion for Generic Pharmaceutical Association
    as Amicus Curiae on behalf of Defendants and Respondents.
    Kamala D. Harris, Attorney General, Edward C. DuMont, State Solicitor General, Kathleen E. Foote,
    Assistant Attorney General, Janill L. Richards, Deputy State Solicitor General, and Cheryl L. Johnson,
    Deputy Attorney General, for California Attorney General, as Amicus Curiae.
    2
    Counsel who argued in Supreme Court (not intended for publication with opinion):
    Mark A. Lemley
    Durie Tangri
    217 Leidesdorff Street
    San Francisco, CA 94111
    (415) 362-6666
    Edwin John U
    Kirkland & Ellis
    655 Fifteenth Street, N.W.
    Washington, D.C. 20005
    (202) 879-5000
    3
    

Document Info

Docket Number: S198616

Citation Numbers: 61 Cal. 4th 116

Filed Date: 5/7/2015

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/12/2023

Authorities (50)

Valley Drug Company v. Geneva Pharmaceuticals, Inc. , 344 F.3d 1294 ( 2003 )

Schering-Plough Corp. v. Federal Trade Commission , 402 F.3d 1056 ( 2005 )

United States v. Microsoft Corp , 253 F.3d 34 ( 2001 )

In Re: Cardizem Cd Antitrust Litigation. Louisiana ... , 332 F.3d 896 ( 2003 )

John M. Dimidowich, Dba Micro Image v. Bell & Howell , 803 F.2d 1473 ( 1987 )

Arkansas Carpenters Health & Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG , 604 F.3d 98 ( 2010 )

In Re Paolo Longi , 759 F.2d 887 ( 1985 )

Aguilar v. Atlantic Richfield Co. , 107 Cal. Rptr. 2d 841 ( 2001 )

Viva! International Voice for Animals v. Adidas Promotional ... , 63 Cal. Rptr. 3d 50 ( 2007 )

Oakland-Alameda County Builders' Exchange v. F. P. Lathrop ... , 4 Cal. 3d 354 ( 1971 )

Pacific Gas & Electric Co. v. County of Stanislaus , 16 Cal. 4th 1143 ( 1997 )

PolyGram Holding, Inc. v. Federal Trade Commission , 416 F.3d 29 ( 2005 )

Ethicon, Inc. v. Donald J. Quigg, Commissioner of Patents & ... , 849 F.2d 1422 ( 1988 )

In Re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Lit. , 544 F.3d 1323 ( 2008 )

People v. Building Maintenance Contractors' Ass'n , 41 Cal. 2d 719 ( 1953 )

Partee v. San Diego Chargers Football Co. , 34 Cal. 3d 378 ( 1983 )

Speegle v. Board of Fire Underwriters , 29 Cal. 2d 34 ( 1946 )

Marin County Board of Realtors, Inc. v. Palsson , 16 Cal. 3d 920 ( 1976 )

Sanchez v. Unemployment Insurance Appeals Board , 20 Cal. 3d 55 ( 1977 )

Getz Bros. Co. v. Federal Salt Co. , 147 Cal. 115 ( 1905 )

View All Authorities »