Hansen v. Newegg.com Americas ( 2018 )


Menu:
  • Filed 7/31/18
    CERTIFIED FOR PUBLICATION
    IN THE COURT OF APPEAL OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA
    SECOND APPELLATE DISTRICT
    DIVISION SEVEN
    M. GEORGE HANSEN et al.,              B271477
    Plaintiffs and Appellants,     (Los Angeles County
    Super. Ct. No. BC566698)
    v.
    NEWEGG.COM AMERICAS, INC.,
    Defendant and Respondent.
    APPEAL from judgment of the Superior Court of Los
    Angeles County, John Shepard Wiley Jr., Judge. Reversed.
    Finkelstein & Krinsk, Jeffrey R. Krinsk, David J. Harris
    and Trenton R. Kashima, for Plaintiffs and Appellants.
    Bird, Marella, Boxer, Wolpert, Nessim, Drooks, Lincenberg
    & Rho, Thomas R. Freeman, Ekwan E. Rhow and David I.
    Hurwitz, for Defendant and Respondent.
    __________________________
    Plaintiff M. George Hansen filed false advertising claims
    under the unfair competition law (Bus. & Prof. Code, § 17200),
    the false advertising law (Bus. & Prof. Code, § 17500 et seq.) and
    the Consumers Legal Remedies Act (Civ. Code, § 1750 et seq.)
    alleging that electronics retailer Newegg.com used fictitious
    former price information in its advertisements that mislead
    customers to believe they were receiving merchandise at a
    discounted price. Hansen further alleged that he had relied on
    fictitious former price information in making two purchases from
    Newegg’s website, and that he would not have made the
    purchases had he known the former price information was false.
    Newegg filed a demurrer arguing that Hansen lacked
    standing to pursue his claims because he had not lost “any money
    or property” (see Bus. & Prof. Code, §§ 17204, 17535) as a result
    of the allegedly false former price representations. More
    specifically, Newegg contended that although Hansen alleged he
    had spent money in reliance on the false former price
    representations, his complaint showed he received the “benefit of
    his bargain,” having obtained the product he wanted at the price
    it was offered. The trial court agreed, and sustained the
    demurrer without leave to amend. We reverse.
    FACTUAL BACKGROUND
    A. Summary of the Complaint
    Plaintiff M. George Hansen filed a class action complaint
    against electronics retailer Newegg.com alleging claims under the
    unfair competition law (Bus. & Prof. Code, § 172001) (UCL), the
    1     Unless otherwise noted, all further statutory citations are
    to the Business and Professions Code.
    2
    false advertising law (§ 17500, et seq.) (FAL) and the Consumer
    Legal Remedies Act (Civ. Code, § 1750 et seq.) (CLRA). The
    complaint alleged that Newegg’s website advertised fictitious
    former price and discount information that was intended to
    induce customers to purchase its products: “When advertising
    products on its website, Newegg displays the price at which it
    offers the product . . . as well as the ‘list’ price. This ‘list’ price is
    displayed in gray struck-through typeface (e.g. ‘$2099.99’)
    directly above [Newegg’s] offer price. [Newegg] further advertises
    that the difference between this ‘list’ price and the offer price is
    some form of discount or purported savings (e.g. ‘Save: $200.00
    (29%)’). Such presentation induces reasonable consumers into
    believing that the ‘list’ price represents either the product’s
    normal price on [Newegg’s] website and/or prevailing price in the
    market. However, these advertised ‘discounts’ are completely
    illusory or grossly overstated. [¶] This is because the ‘list’ price
    used to calculate the quantum of reported ‘savings’ is not the
    prevailing market price for . . . the same product from one of
    Newegg’s competitors or the price charged by Newegg for the
    subject item in the recent and normal course of its business.
    Rather, the ‘list’ price is the highest price the product has ever
    been advertised at, regardless of when that price was advertised,
    or is simply a work of fiction. . . . [¶] The reality is that no
    discount is provided over Newegg’s everyday pricing. Its
    customers are not realizing the savings portrayed or expected by
    purchasing these advertised ‘discounted’ products from Newegg.”
    Hansen’s complaint further alleged that he had relied on
    fictitious former price information when purchasing two
    computer components from Newegg’s website: a “Corsair . . . 850-
    watt Power Supply” and a “Gigabyte Motherboard.” According to
    3
    the complaint, the Corsair power supply was advertised as
    having a former “list” price of $189.99, and an offer price of
    $169.99, resulting in a “$20.00” discount; the Gigabyte
    Motherboard was advertised as having a former “list” price of
    $159.99, and an offer price of $152.99, resulting in a “$7.00”
    discount. Hansen asserted that the true former price of both
    products was equal to or less than the offer price, and that he had
    therefore received no actual discount. Hansen further asserted
    that he would not have purchased the products had he known the
    “true nature of [the] discounts.”
    The complaint alleged Newegg’s use of false or misleading
    former price information violated the UCL (§ 17200) and section
    17501 of the FAL, which specifically regulates advertisements
    that purport to convey the former price of a product. The
    complaint also alleged that Newegg’s conduct violated a provision
    of the CLRA prohibiting the use of false or misleading statements
    regarding price reductions. (See Civ. Code, § 1770, subd. (a)(13).)
    B. Summary of Newegg’s Demurrer
    Newegg filed a demurrer arguing that Hansen lacked
    “standing to . . . assert any claim under the FAL, UCL or CLRA”
    because he had “suffered no loss of money or property as a result
    of Newegg’s actions.” According to Newegg, Hansen’s complaint
    showed he had received the “products he wanted for the prices he
    agreed to pay”; he had not alleged that “the products were
    different than what he wanted, were unsatisfactory in any way,
    or were worth less than what he paid for them.” Accordingly, he
    had suffered no form of “economic injury.”2
    2     Newegg’s demurrer also argued that Hansen’s claims failed
    on their merits because, as a matter of law, a reasonable
    4
    Hansen opposed the demurrer, arguing that under the
    California Supreme Court’s holding in Kwikset Corp. v. Superior
    Court (2011) 
    51 Cal.4th 310
     (Kwikset), a plaintiff may satisfy the
    standing requirements of the UCL and FAL by alleging that he or
    she was “deceived by a product’s label into spending money to
    purchase the product, and would not have purchased it
    otherwise.” (Id. at p. 317.) Hansen contended his complaint
    satisfied those requirements, alleging that: (1) he had relied on
    Newegg’s fictitious former price information when making his
    purchases; and (2) he would not have purchased the products but
    for the false former price representations.
    The trial court agreed with Newegg, concluding that
    Hansen had not satisfied “the standing requirement[s]” because
    his complaint showed he had received the product that he
    ordered “at a price he agreed to pay.” The court explained that
    unlike the plaintiffs in Kwikset, who alleged that the products
    they purchased had been falsely labeled as “Made in the U.S.A,”
    Hansen did not dispute that he had received “[e]xactly what he
    ordered.” The court sustained the demurrer without leave to
    amend, and subsequently entered judgment dismissing the
    matter.
    DISCUSSION
    A. Standard of Review
    “On appeal from a judgment dismissing an action after
    sustaining a demurrer without leave to amend, the standard of
    review is well settled. The reviewing court gives the complaint a
    consumer was not likely to be deceived by its advertising
    practices. The trial court did not address this argument in its
    ruling, and Newegg has not raised the argument on appeal. We
    therefore address only the issue of standing.
    5
    reasonable interpretation, and treats the demurrer as admitting
    all material facts properly pleaded. [Citations.] The court does
    not, however, assume the truth of contentions, deductions or
    conclusions of law. [Citation.] The judgment must be affirmed ‘if
    any one of the several grounds of demurrer is well taken.
    [Citations.]’ [Citation.] However, it is error for a trial court to
    sustain a demurrer when the plaintiff has stated a cause of action
    under any possible legal theory. [Citation.] And it is an abuse of
    discretion to sustain a demurrer without leave to amend if the
    plaintiff shows there is a reasonable possibility any defect
    identified by the defendant can be cured by amendment.
    [Citation.]” (Aubry v. Tri-City Hospital Dist. (1992) 
    2 Cal.4th 962
    , 966-967.)
    B. Summary of Applicable Law
    1. Summary of the UCL, FAL and CLRA
    The UCL prohibits “unfair competition,” which it defines as
    “any unlawful, unfair or fraudulent business act or practice and
    unfair, deceptive, untrue or misleading advertising and any act
    prohibited by [the FAL].” (§ 17200.) “The UCL’s purpose is to
    protect both consumers and competitors by promoting fair
    competition in commercial markets for goods and services.”
    (Kasky v. Nike, Inc. (2002) 
    27 Cal.4th 939
    , 949.) “‘In service of
    that purpose, the Legislature framed the UCL’s substantive
    provisions in ‘“broad, sweeping language”’ [citations] and
    provided ‘courts with broad equitable powers to remedy
    violations’ [citation].” (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th at p. 320.)
    “The state’s false advertising law (§ 17500 et seq.) is equally
    comprehensive within the narrower field of false and misleading
    advertising.” (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th at p. 320.) “‘[A]ny
    violation of the false advertising law . . . necessarily violates the
    6
    UCL.’” (Kasky, 
    supra,
     27 Cal.4th at p. 950.) Section 17500
    “proscribe[s] ‘“not only advertising which is false, but also
    advertising which[,] although true, is either actually misleading
    or which has a capacity, likelihood or tendency to deceive or
    confuse the public.”’ [Citation.]” (Colgan v. Leatherman Tool
    Group, Inc. (2006) 
    135 Cal.App.4th 663
    , 679.) Section 17501
    specifically limits the use of advertisements that purport to
    convey the former price of a product: “No price shall be
    advertised as a former price of any advertised thing, unless the
    alleged former price was the prevailing market price . . . within
    three months next immediately preceding the publication of the
    advertisement or unless the date when the alleged former price
    did prevail is clearly, exactly and conspicuously stated in the
    advertisement.” As used in section 17501, the term “‘former
    price’ . . . includes but is not limited to the following words and
    phrases when used in connection with advertised prices; ‘formerly
    –,’ ‘regularly –,’ ‘usually –,’ ‘originally –,’ ‘reduced from ___,’ ‘was
    ___ now ___,’ ‘___% off.’” (4 Cal. Code Regs., § 1301.)
    “‘The CLRA makes unlawful . . . various “unfair methods of
    competition and unfair or deceptive acts or practices undertaken
    by any person in a transaction intended to result or which results
    in the sale or lease of goods or services to any consumer.”’
    [Citation.] . . . . [¶] ‘The CLRA sets forth 27 proscribed acts or
    practices. (Civ. Code, § 1770, subd. (a)(1)-(27).)” (Veera v.
    Banana Republic, LLC (2016) 
    6 Cal.App.5th 907
    , 915 (Veera).)
    One of those “proscribed acts” is “[m]aking false or misleading
    statements of fact concerning . . . [the] existence of, or amounts
    of, price reductions.” (Civ. Code, § 1770, subd. (a)(13).)
    7
    2. Summary of the statutes’ standing requirements
    a. Standing under the UCL and the FAL
    In 2004, California passed Proposition 64, which
    “materially curtailed the universe of those who may enforce the[]
    provisions [of the UCL and the FAL.] . . . [W]here once private
    suits could be brought by ‘any person acting for the interests of
    itself, its members or the general public’ [citations], now private
    standing is limited to any ‘person who has suffered injury in fact
    and has lost money or property’ as a result of unfair competition.”
    (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th at pp. 320-321; see also §§ 17204;
    17535.) “The intent of this change was to confine standing to
    those actually injured by a defendant’s business practices and
    curtail the prior practice of filing suits on behalf of ‘“clients who
    have not used the defendant’s product or service, viewed the
    defendant’s advertising, or had any other business dealings with
    the defendant. . . .”’ [Citation.]” (Clayworth v. Pfizer, Inc. (2010)
    
    49 Cal.4th 758
    , 788.) Although “voters clearly intended to
    restrict UCL [and FAL] standing, they just as plainly preserved
    standing for those who had had business dealings with a
    defendant and had lost money or property as a result of the
    defendant’s unfair business practices.” (Ibid.)
    “To satisfy the narrower standing requirements imposed by
    Proposition 64, a party must now (1) establish a loss or
    deprivation of money or property sufficient to qualify as injury in
    fact, i.e., economic injury, and (2) show that that economic injury
    was the result of, i.e., caused by, the unfair business practice or
    false advertising that is the gravamen of the claim.” (Kwikset,
    supra, 51 Cal.4th at p. 322.) “‘[T]he quantum of lost money or
    property necessary to show standing is only so much as would
    suffice to establish injury in fact; [which] . . . is not a substantial
    8
    or insurmountable hurdle. . . . [Citation.]’ [Citation.]” (Veera,
    supra, 6 Cal.App.5th at p. 916 [citing and quoting Kwikset, 
    supra,
    51 Cal.4th at p. 322].) “Because . . . economic injury is itself a
    form of injury in fact, proof of lost money or property will largely
    overlap with proof of injury in fact. [Citation.] If a party has
    alleged or proven a personal, individualized loss of money or
    property in any nontrivial amount, he or she has also alleged or
    proven injury in fact.” (Kwikset, supra, 51 Cal.4th at p. 322.)
    b. Standing under the CLRA
    “To have standing to assert a claim under the CLRA, a
    plaintiff must have ‘suffer[ed] any damage as a result of the . . .
    practice declared to be unlawful.’” (Aron v. U-Haul Co. of
    California (2006) 
    143 Cal.App.4th 796
    , 802; see also Civil Code,
    § 1780, subd. (a) [“Any consumer who suffers any damage as a
    result of the use . . . of a . . . practice declared to be unlawful by
    Section 1770 may bring an action . . .”].) Our Supreme Court has
    interpreted the CLRA’s “any damage” requirement broadly,
    concluding that the “phrase . . . is not synonymous with ‘actual
    damages,’ which generally refers to pecuniary damages.” (Meyer
    v. Sprint Spectrum L.P. (2009) 
    45 Cal.4th 634
    , 640.) Rather, the
    consumer must merely “experience some kind of damage,” or
    “some type of increased costs” as a result of the unlawful practice.
    (Ibid.; Bower v. AT & T Mobility, LLC (2011) 
    196 Cal.App.4th 1545
    , 1556 [“A plaintiff bringing a CLRA cause of action must not
    only be exposed to an unlawful practice but also have suffered
    ‘some kind of damage’”].)
    For the purposes of this appeal, the parties agree that the
    CLRA’s standing requirements are effectively identical to those of
    the UCL and FAL, and that we may thus analyze the question of
    standing under each statute “concurrently.” (See Veera, supra, 6
    9
    Cal.App.5th at p. 916 [agreeing to consider question of standing
    under the UCL, FAL and CLRA “together” where plaintiff had
    “conceded that . . . the requirements of the CLRA are essentially
    identical to those of the UCL and FAL”].)
    3. Kwikset v. Superior Court
    In Kwikset, 
    supra,
     
    51 Cal.4th 310
    , the California Supreme
    Court addressed Proposition 64’s standing requirements in the
    context of a false advertising claim alleging that the defendant
    had marketed and sold locksets that were “falsely . . . labeled as
    ‘Made in U.S.A.’” (Id. at p. 317.) The complaint alleged that each
    plaintiff “‘was induced to purchase and did purchase
    [d]efendants’ locksets due to the false representation that they
    were “Made in U.S.A., and would not have purchased them if
    they had not been so misrepresented.’” (Id. at p. 319.)
    Defendant filed a demurrer arguing that plaintiffs lacked
    standing because the allegations in the complaint showed they
    had not suffered any form of economic injury. The Court of
    Appeal agreed, concluding that while plaintiffs had alleged an
    injury in fact, they had not alleged any loss of money or property:
    “Plaintiffs spent money to be sure, but . . . they received locksets
    in return, locksets they did not allege were overpriced or
    defective. Thus, while their ‘patriotic desire to buy fully
    American-made products was frustrated,’ that injury was
    insufficient to satisfy the standing requirements of sections
    17204 and 17535.” (Kwikset, supra, 51 Cal.4th at pp. 320-321.)
    The Supreme Court reversed, holding that “plaintiffs who
    can truthfully allege they were deceived by a product’s label into
    spending money to purchase the product, and would not have
    purchased it otherwise, have ‘lost money or property’ within the
    meaning of Proposition 64 and have standing to sue.” (Kwikset,
    10
    supra, 51 Cal.4th at p. 317.) As stated by the Court: “At [the
    pleading] stage, these plaintiffs need only allege economic injury
    arising from reliance on [the defendant’s] misrepresentations.
    According to the . . . complaint, (1) [defendant] labeled certain
    locksets with ‘Made in U.S.A.’ or a similar designation, (2) these
    representations were false, (3) plaintiffs saw and relied on the
    labels for their truth in purchasing [defendant’s] locksets, and (4)
    plaintiffs would not have bought the locksets otherwise. On their
    face, these allegations satisfy all parts of the section 17204
    standing requirement.” (Id. at pp. 327-328.)
    The Court explained that the “marketing industry is based
    on the premise that labels matter—that consumers will choose
    one product over another similar product based on its label and
    various tangible and intangible qualities they may come to
    associate with a particular source. . . . [¶] To some consumers,
    processes and places of origin matter. [Citations.] . . . [¶] In
    particular, to some consumers, the ‘Made in U.S.A.’ label
    matters.” (Kwikset, supra, 51 Cal.4th at pp. 328-329 [footnotes
    omitted].) The Court noted that the “Legislature ha[d]
    recognized the materiality of this [form of] representation by
    specifically outlawing deceptive and fraudulent ‘Made in
    America’ representations.” (Id. at p. 329 [citing § 17533.7
    [prohibiting deceitful representations that a product was “Made
    in the U.S.A.”] and Civ. Code, § 1770, subd. (a)(4) [prohibiting
    deceptive representations of geographic origin].)
    The Court emphasized that under its interpretation of
    Proposition 64, “a plaintiff’s subjective motivations in making a
    purchase” (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th at p. 330, fn. 14) are
    relevant in determining whether the “loss of money or property”
    requirement has been satisfied: “For each consumer who relies
    11
    on the truth and accuracy of a label and is deceived by
    misrepresentations into making a purchase, the economic harm
    is the same: the consumer has purchased a product that he or
    she paid more for than he or she otherwise might have been
    willing to pay if the product had been labeled accurately. This
    economic harm—the loss of real dollars from a consumer’s pocket
    —is the same whether or not a court might objectively view the
    products as functionally equivalent.” (Kwikset, supra, 51 Cal.4th
    at pp. 329-330.)
    The Court also clarified exactly why a consumer’s
    allegation that he or she would not have purchased a product but
    for the defendant’s misrepresentation is sufficient to establish
    economic injury: “From the original purchasing decision we know
    the consumer valued the product as labeled more than the money
    he or she parted with; from the complaint’s allegations we know
    the consumer valued the money he or she parted with more than
    the product as it actually is; and from the combination we know
    that because of the misrepresentation the consumer (allegedly)
    was made to part with more money than he or she otherwise
    would have been willing to expend, i.e., that the consumer paid
    more than he or she actually valued the product. That
    increment, the extra money paid, is economic injury and affords
    the consumer standing to sue.” (Kwikset, supra, at p. 330.)
    The Court noted that a contrary conclusion would
    effectively “bring to an end private consumer enforcement of bans
    on many label misrepresentations. . . . The UCL and false
    advertising law are both intended to preserve fair competition
    and protect consumers from market distortions. [Citations.]
    Contrary to that general purpose, if we were to deny standing to
    consumers who have been deceived by label misrepresentations
    12
    in making purchases, we would impair the ability of consumers to
    rely on labels, place those businesses that do not engage in
    misrepresentations at a competitive disadvantage, and encourage
    the marketplace to dispense with accuracy in favor of deceit.”
    (Kwikset, supra, 51 Cal.4th at pp. 330-331.)
    The Court also addressed the Court of Appeal’s conclusion
    that plaintiffs lacked standing under the UCL because, although
    they had spent money, “they ‘received locksets in return[,]’ . . . .
    and did not allege the locksets were defective, overpriced, or of
    inferior quality.” (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th at pp. 329-330.)
    The Court explained “that nothing in the open-ended phrase ‘lost
    money or property’ supports limiting the types of qualifying
    losses to functional defects of these sorts and excluding the real
    economic harm that arises from purchasing mislabeled products
    in reliance on the truth and accuracy of their labels.” (Kwikset,
    supra, 51 Cal.4th at p. 331.)
    The Court likewise rejected the Court of Appeal’s
    “interrelated” conclusion that plaintiffs lacked standing because
    “consumers who receive a fully functioning product have received
    the benefit of their bargain, even if the product label contains
    misrepresentations that may have been relied upon by a
    particular class of consumers.” (Kwikset, supra, 51 Cal.4th at
    p. 332.) The Court explained that while the “benefit of the
    bargain” theory might apply in cases where the alleged
    misrepresentation was not material in nature, it was inapplicable
    to UCL claims involving a material misrepresentation. According
    to the Court, a “‘misrepresentation is judged to be “material” if “a
    reasonable man would attach importance to its existence or
    nonexistence in determining his choice of action in the
    transaction in question”. . . .’ [Citations].” (Id. at pp. 332-333.)
    13
    The Court concluded that the Legislature’s prohibition on the use
    of false or misleading “Made in the U.S.A.” labels demonstrated
    that it had concluded such representations are in fact material.3
    C. Hansen Has Standing to Pursue His Claims
    Hansen argues that under Kwikset, he has satisfied the
    UCL and FAL’s standing requirements by alleging that: (1)
    Newegg advertised that its products were being offered at a
    discount from their former or original price; (2) these
    representations were false or misleading; (3) Hansen saw and
    relied on the former price representations when purchasing the
    products; and (4) he would not have purchased the products but
    for the false former price representations. Hansen contends that,
    as with the plaintiffs in Kwikset, he has suffered economic injury
    by having “paid more for [a product] than he . . . otherwise
    [would] have been willing to pay if the product had been labeled
    accurately.” (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th at p. 329.)
    Newegg, however, argues that Kwikset is limited to cases in
    which the consumer alleges that he or she “pa[id] more for a
    product than he or she would have been willing to pay but for a
    material misrepresentation about . . . an attribute of that
    product.” According to Newegg, a misrepresentation regarding a
    product’s former price is “fundamentally different than a
    misrepresentation about a product or its attributes. When . . .
    consumer[s] pay[] for and receive [products] at the specified price
    and those products are what they were represented to be, there is
    3     As discussed (see ante at p. 7, post at pp. 19-20), the
    Legislature has also specifically prohibited false former price
    advertising, as it did false labeling of origin. (See § 17501, Civ.
    Code, § 1770, subd. (a).)
    14
    no disparity in economic value to the consumer and therefore no
    economic injury.”
    1. Hinojos v. Kohl’s Corporation
    We are not aware of any published California state court
    decision that has addressed whether a consumer who alleges that
    he or she paid more for a product based on false former price or
    discount information has standing to sue under the UCL and
    FAL. In Hinojos v. Kohl’s Corporation (9th Cir. 2013) 
    718 F.3d 1098
     (Hinojos), however, a unanimous panel of the United States
    Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit concluded that, under
    Kwikset, plaintiffs had standing to pursue such a claim. As in
    this case, the plaintiff in Hinojos filed claims under the UCL, the
    FAL and the CLRA alleging that a company had used fictitious
    former price information on its labels to mislead consumers into
    believing they were receiving a substantial discount. The
    plaintiff also alleged he “‘would not have purchased [the]
    products . . . in the absence of [defendant’s] misrepresentations.’”
    (Id. at p. 1102.) The district court dismissed the complaint,
    “determining that [the plaintiff] did not have standing under the
    UCL or the FAL . . . because [he] had acquired the merchandise
    he wanted at the price advertised.” (Ibid.)
    The Ninth Circuit reversed, explaining that Kwikset had
    identified “precisely what a plaintiff must allege when he wishes
    to satisfy the economic injury requirement in a case involving
    false advertising: ‘[a] consumer who relies on a product label and
    challenges a misrepresentation contained therein can satisfy the
    standing requirement of section 17204 by alleging . . . that he or
    she would not have bought the product but for the
    misrepresentation.’ [Citation.]” (Hinojos, supra, 718 F.3d at
    p. 1104 [citing and quoting Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th at p. 330].)
    15
    The Ninth Circuit concluded the plaintiff had satisfied those
    requirements by alleging that “the advertised discounts conveyed
    false information about the goods he purchased, i.e., that the
    goods he purchased sold at a substantially higher price [from the
    defendant] in the recent past and/or in the prevailing market. He
    also alleges that he would not have purchased the goods in
    question absent this misrepresentation. This is sufficient under
    Kwikset.” (Ibid.)
    In its analysis, the court rejected two “interrelated”
    arguments the defendant had raised regarding the scope of
    Kwikset’s holding. First, defendant asserted that Kwikset was
    “limited [to] . . . cases involving ‘factual misrepresentations about
    the composition, effects, origin, and substance of advertised
    products’”; second, the defendant argued that the rationale of
    Kwikset did not apply to false discount claims because, in such
    cases, “there [is] ‘no difference in value between the product “as
    labeled” and the product “as it actually is,” because the products
    . . . are one and the same.’” (Hinojos, supra, 718 F.3d at p. 1104.)
    The Ninth Circuit explained that both arguments were
    predicated on the same assumption: that “when a merchant
    misrepresents the ‘regular’ price of his wares, it does not
    misrepresent the innate value of those wares so the misled
    consumer has suffered no economic injury; he gets the product he
    expected at the price he expected.” (Ibid.)
    The court concluded, however, that “Kwikset [could not] be
    so easily limited,” explaining that just as “a product’s origin or
    composition” matters to some consumers, “a product’s ‘regular’ or
    ‘original’ price matters [to other customers]; it provides important
    information about the product’s worth and the prestige that
    ownership of that product conveys. [Citations.] Misinformation
    16
    about a product’s ‘normal’ price is, therefore, significant to many
    consumers in the same way as a false product label would be.
    [Citation.] That, of course, is why retailers like [the defendant]
    have an incentive to advertise false ‘sales.’ It is also why the
    California legislature has prohibited them from doing so.”
    (Hinojos, supra, 718 F.3d at pp. 1105-1106 [citing § 17501.)4
    2. The Ninth Circuit correctly applied California law
    We agree with the Ninth Circuit’s conclusion that under
    Kwikset, the UCL and FAL’s standing requirements are satisfied
    when a consumer has alleged that he or she relied on fictitious
    former price information in making a purchase, and would not
    have made the purchase but for the misrepresentation. Kwikset
    plainly states that a “consumer who relies on a product label and
    challenges a misrepresentation contained therein can satisfy the
    standing requirement of section 17204 by alleging, as plaintiffs
    have here, that he or she would not have bought the product but
    for the misrepresentation.” (Kwikset, supra, 51 Cal.4th at
    p. 330.) The Court’s decision contains no language limiting that
    rule to misrepresentations regarding the physical characteristics
    or “attributes” of a product.
    Nor does the decision suggest, as Newegg posits, that a
    consumer must allege the product he or she received was worth
    less than, or not functionally equivalent to, the product as it was
    advertised. To the contrary, Kwikset held that a consumer’s
    4     The Ninth Circuit also held that plaintiff had standing to
    assert his CLRA claim, concluding that “any plaintiff who has
    standing under the UCL’s and FAL’s ‘lost money or property’
    requirement will, a fortiori, have suffered ‘any damage’ for
    purposes of establishing CLRA standing.” (Hinojos, supra, 718
    F.3d at p. 1108.)
    17
    subjective willingness to pay more for the product than he or she
    would have been willing to pay in the absence of the
    misrepresentation is itself a form of economic injury “whether or
    not a court might objectively view the products as functionally
    equivalent.” (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th at pp. 329-330.)
    Moreover, as Hinojos noted, interpreting Kwikset in the
    manner Newegg proposes would effectively preclude consumers
    from bringing false advertising claims predicated on deceptive
    former price and discount information, despite the fact that the
    Legislature has specifically prohibited that practice. (§ 17501,
    Civ. Code, § 1770, subd. (a).) Kwikset makes clear that
    Proposition 64 was not intended to eliminate consumers’ ability
    to pursue UCL and FAL claims for misleading advertisements
    that induced them to make a purchase they would not have
    otherwise made. (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th at pp. 330-331; see
    also (Hinojos, supra, 718 F.3d at p. 1106 [“Kwikset emphasized
    that Proposition 64 was enacted not to eliminate individual
    consumer suits when the consumer was actually deceived by a
    misleading advertisement”].)5
    5     Newegg contends that limiting Kwikset in the manner it
    has proposed would not preclude all forms of consumer suits
    challenging the use of false or misleading former price
    information. According to Newegg, this form of claim would still
    be available to consumers who can show that they “could have
    purchased the product elsewhere for less money absent the
    misrepresentation.” Kwikset, however, held that a consumer’s
    decision to pay more for a product than he or she would have but
    for the misrepresentation is itself a form of economic injury: “[I]n
    the eyes of the law, a buyer forced to pay more than he or she
    would have is harmed at the moment of purchase, and further
    inquiry into such subsequent transactions, actual or
    18
    Newegg argues there are several reasons why we should
    decline to follow Hinojos and hold that Kwikset does not extend to
    fictitious former price claims in which the plaintiff has not
    challenged any representation related to the product other than
    its purported former price. First, Newegg argues that, unlike a
    consumer who is willing to pay more for a product that was
    manufactured in the United States, a consumer such as Hansen
    “cannot rationally claim he was willing to pay more money for the
    [product he purchased] because he believed they were discounted
    than he would have been willing to pay had he known they were
    not discounted.” Newegg appears to contend that, as a matter of
    law, a rational consumer would not pay more for a product based
    on its advertised former price. Thus, under Newegg’s rationale, it
    would be irrational for a consumer to be willing to pay $50 for a
    sweater that is advertised as having had an original price of
    $100, but be unwilling to pay $50 for that same sweater in the
    absence of the advertised discount. According to Newegg, a
    rational consumer would not be affected by this discount
    information because “the economic value [of the product] is the
    same regardless [of] the price’s status as a ‘discount.’”
    This argument ignores a simple fact: Our Legislature has
    adopted multiple statutes that specifically prohibit the use of
    deceptive former price information and misleading statements
    regarding the amount of a price reduction. (See § 17501; Civ.
    Code, § 1770, subd. (a)(13).) These statutes make clear that,
    contrary to Newegg’s assertions, our Legislature has concluded
    “reasonable people can and do attach importance to [a product’s
    former price] in their purchasing decisions.” (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51
    hypothesized, ordinarily is unnecessary.” (Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51
    Cal.4th at p. 334.)
    19
    Cal.4th at p. 333 [statutory prohibition on use of deceitful “Made
    in U.S.A.” labels shows that reasonable consumers do rely on that
    form on information]; see also id. at p. 329 [Legislature’s
    prohibition on deceitful Made in the U.S.A. labels demonstrates
    “the materiality of this representation”].) As noted in Hinojos,
    this conclusion is supported by empirical research showing that
    the presence of a higher original price affects consumers’
    perceptions “about the product’s worth,” and increases their
    willingness to buy the product. (Hinojos, supra, 718 F.3d at
    p. 1106.)
    Newegg next asserts that Hinojos conflicts with prior
    California case law holding that “a consumer who pays the
    specified price for a product and receives that product has
    obtained the ‘benefit of the bargain and cannot therefore show an
    economic injury’ – absent specific allegations such as the product
    was different than it was represented to be, unsatisfactory in
    some manner, or worth less than the amount paid.” In support,
    Newegg cites two decisions, Time v. Hall (2008) 
    158 Cal.App.4th 847
     (Time), and Petersen v. Cellco Partnership (2008) 
    164 Cal.App.4th 1583
     (Petersen), which cites Time and was written by
    the same court. In both cases, the court concluded the plaintiffs
    lacked standing to pursue UCL claims because their pleadings
    demonstrated they had “received the benefit of their bargain,
    having obtained the [advertised product] at the bargained for
    price.” (Petersen, supra, 164 Cal.App.4th at p. 1591; see also
    Time, supra, 158 Cal.App.4th at p. 855 [plaintiff lacked standing
    because he had received the advertised product in exchange for
    the advertised price, and had not alleged it was “worth less than
    what he paid for it”].)
    20
    These cases, however, were decided before Kwikset, which
    held that the “benefit of the bargain” theory has no relevance
    when the misrepresentation underlying the UCL claim is
    material in nature. (See Kwikset, 51 Cal.4th at pp. 332-333; see
    also Hinojos, supra, 718 F.3d at p. 1107 [“‘benefit of the bargain’
    rationale was explicitly rejected in Kwikset” for UCL claims that
    allege a material misrepresentation].) As explained above, our
    Legislature’s decision to prohibit the use of false and misleading
    former price information shows that it has deemed such
    misrepresentations to be material.6
    Finally, Newegg argues that cases from several other
    jurisdictions have rejected similar “false discount claims,” and
    asserts that Hinojos “is the sole exception.” However, none of the
    decisions Newegg cites address claims brought under California’s
    UCL or FAL, nor do they involve an application of Kwikset.
    Instead, the cases apply other state court’s interpretations of
    those state’s false advertising laws.
    For example, in Kim v. Carter’s (7th Cir. 2010) 
    598 F.3d 362
     (Kim), which Newegg characterizes as “the leading case” in
    6      The same court that decided Time and Peterson—Division
    Three of the Fourth District—also wrote the decision that the
    Supreme Court reversed in Kwikset. Division Three’s conclusion
    that the Kwikset plaintiffs lacked standing to pursue their false
    advertising claims appears to have been based on the same
    “benefit of the bargain” reasoning that it had previously
    employed in Hall and Petersen. (See Kwikset, 
    supra,
     51 Cal.4th
    at pp. 319-320, 332 [explaining that Court of Appeal found
    plaintiffs lacked standing because they had received “the benefit
    of their bargain,” namely “locksets that were not [were not
    alleged to be] overpriced or defective”].) The Supreme Court
    explicitly rejected that analysis.
    21
    this subject area, plaintiffs filed a complaint under the Illinois
    Consumer Fraud and Deceptive Business Practices Act (ICFA)
    alleging that defendant had advertised a fictitious “suggested”
    price for its products that mislead consumers to believe “they
    were realizing significant savings.” (Id. at p. 363.) The Seventh
    Circuit explained that to maintain a private action under the
    ICFA, a plaintiff must establish that he or she suffered “actual
    damages” as a result of the challenged conduct. The Seventh
    Circuit further explained that, in the context of false advertising
    claims, Illinois state courts had interpreted the “actual damages”
    provision to require the consumer to show that defendant’s
    conduct “caus[ed] [him or] her to pay ‘more than the actual value
    of the property.’” (Id. at p. 365.) Applying that standard, the
    Seventh Circuit concluded that plaintiffs’ claim failed because
    they had not alleged the products they received were actually
    worth less than what they had paid.
    Similarly, in Belcastro v. Burberry Limited (S.D.N.Y.
    Feb. 23, 2017, No. 16-CV-1080) 
    2017 WL 744596
     (Belcastro), the
    plaintiff filed claims under New York and Florida law alleging
    that the defendant had used a fictitious retail price in advertising
    its clothing. As in this case, plaintiff further alleged he would not
    have made the purchase in the absence of the false pricing
    information. The district court dismissed the claim, explaining
    that New York and Florida law both required plaintiff to show
    “the defendant’s deception” had caused him to pay more for the
    product than it was actually worth. (See 
    id.
     at pp. *4-*6.)
    The court specifically distinguished Hinojos, noting that
    the Ninth Circuit’s decision addressed “standing under [an
    unrelated] California statutory cause of action.” (Belcastro,
    supra, at p. *5.) The court further explained that Hinojos was of
    22
    “limited relevance” because, “[u]nder California law, a plaintiff
    sufficiently alleges injury based on allegations that the
    defendant’s false advertising caused them subjectively to assign a
    higher value to the good than they would have otherwise. Simply
    alleging that plaintiff would not have made the same purchasing
    decision but for the misrepresentation is not adequate under New
    York [or Florida] law.” (Ibid.)7
    As Belcastro implicitly acknowledges, California law is
    different. The Supreme Court has concluded that to establish
    standing under California’s UCL and FAL, a consumer need only
    allege that he or she relied on a misrepresentation when
    purchasing the product, and that he or she would not have
    purchased the product but for the representation. (Kwikset,
    7      The other false discount cases Newegg cites likewise
    involve the application of other state courts’ interpretation of
    their own false advertising laws. (See e.g., Carters Johnson v.
    Jos. A. Bank Clothiers, Inc. (S.D. Ohio, Aug. 19, 2014, No. 2:13-
    cv-756) 
    2014 WL 4129576
    , *4 [under Ohio’s Consumer Sales
    Practices Act, plaintiff was required to plead and prove “actual
    damages,” which, under Ohio law, is “measured by calculating
    ‘the difference between the value of property as it was
    represented to be and its actual value at the time of its
    purchase’’”]; Shaulis v. Nordstrom (1st Cir. 2017) 
    865 F.3d 1
    , 10-
    11 [under the Massachusetts Supreme Judicial Court’s
    interpretation of the Massachusetts’s false advertising law,
    plaintiff’s allegation that she was induced to make a purchase
    she would not have made but for the “false sense of value created
    by” defendant’s fictitious discount did not qualify as a cognizable
    injury].)
    23
    supra, 51 Cal.4th at p. 317.) Hansen satisfied both of those
    requirements.8
    DISPOSITION
    The trial court’s judgment is reversed. Hansen shall
    recover his costs on appeal.
    ZELON, Acting P. J.
    We concur:
    SEGAL, J.
    FEUER, J.
    8     For purpose of this appeal, Newegg has conceded that if
    Hansen has standing to pursue his UCL and FAL claims, he also
    has standing to pursue his CLRA claim, which requires only that
    plaintiff claim to have suffered “‘some form of damage.’” (Bower,
    supra, 196 Cal.App.4th at p. 1556.) Because we conclude Hansen
    has adequately alleged “economic injury” for purposes of UCL
    standing, we likewise conclude he has standing to pursue his
    CLRA claim.
    24