Flagship Theatres of Palm Desert, LLC v. Century Theatres, Inc. ( 2020 )


Menu:
  • Filed 9/2/20
    CERTIFIED FOR PUBLICATION
    IN THE COURT OF APPEAL OF THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA
    SECOND APPELLATE DISTRICT
    DIVISION ONE
    FLAGSHIP THEATRES OF PALM             B292609
    DESERT, LLC,
    (Los Angeles County
    Plaintiff and Respondent,     Super. Ct. No. SC090481)
    v.
    CENTURY THEATRES, INC., et al.,
    Defendants and Appellants.
    B299014
    FLAGSHIP THEATRES OF PALM
    DESERT, LLC,                          (Los Angeles County
    Super. Ct. No. SC090481)
    Plaintiff and Appellant,
    v.
    CENTURY THEATRES, INC., et al.,
    Defendants and Respondents.
    APPEAL from a judgment and orders of the Superior Court of
    Los Angeles County, Lisa Hart Cole, Judge. Reversed (B292609).
    Dismissed (B299014).
    Norton Rose Fulbright, Peter H. Mason, Joshua D. Lichtman
    Lesley Holmes, Michael A. Swartzendruber and Barton W. Cox
    for Defendants and Appellants (B292609) and Defendants and
    Respondents (B299014).
    Perkins Coie, Thomas L. Boeder, Elvira Castillo, Donald J.
    Kula, Sunita Bali and Alisha C. Burgin for Plaintiff and Appellant
    (B299014) and Perkins Coie, Thomas L. Boeder, Elvira Castillo and
    Donald J. Kula for Plaintiff and Respondent (B292609).
    _________________________________
    This appeal arises from an antitrust dispute involving the
    licensing of motion pictures to movie theaters for public exhibition.
    Plaintiff Flagship Theatres of Palm Desert, LLC (Flagship), which
    previously owned the movie theater Palme d’Or in the Coachella
    Valley, obtained a jury verdict against defendants Century
    Theatres, Inc. and Cinemark USA, Inc. (collectively, Century),1
    which owned The River, a theater located two miles away from
    Palme d’Or. Century owns a circuit of theaters throughout the
    country as well. The jury found true Flagship’s allegations that
    Century had engaged in a practice known as “circuit dealing”
    by entering into licensing agreements with film distributors that
    covered licenses to play films not just at The River, but at multiple
    other Century-owned theaters as well, and using these agreements
    to pressure distributors into refusing to license films to Palme d’Or.
    1 Cinemark   acquired Century in October 2006. We use
    the term “Century” to refer to both parties. When referring
    individually to either, we use the terms “Cinemark USA” and
    “Century Theatres,” respectively.
    2
    In reaching this verdict, the jury made several more specific
    findings regarding the competitive effects of the agreements,
    including that the agreements harmed competition in the relevant
    market. On appeal (case No. 292609), Century argues substantial
    evidence does not support these findings, that there can be no
    antitrust liability without such evidence, and that the judgment in
    Flagship’s favor should therefore be reversed. In the alternative,
    Century argues that the court committed reversible error by
    admitting into evidence certain testimony and emails Century
    argues are inadmissible prejudicial hearsay, and that the jury’s
    verdict is an impermissible “compromise verdict.”
    We agree with Century that Flagship did not present
    substantial evidence of anticompetitive effects in the relevant
    market. We further agree with Century that this failure of proof
    warrants reversal, as circuit dealing based on multi-theater
    licensing agreements is not per se illegal under the Cartwright Act.
    We therefore reverse the judgment and need not reach Century’s
    remaining arguments on appeal. Nor need we address Flagship’s
    appeal (case No. B299014)2 from the court’s postjudgment order
    awarding Flagship attorney fees in an amount lower than Flagship
    had requested.
    2 Thiscourt granted the parties’ joint motion to consolidate
    oral argument in Century’s appeal (case No. B292609) and
    Flagship’s appeal (case No. B299014) in October 2019. On its
    own motion, the court hereby consolidates the two appeals for all
    purposes.
    3
    FACTUAL AND PROCEDURAL BACKGROUND
    A.    Film Industry Background
    In the motion picture industry, film studios, also known
    as distributors, own the copyrights to films, and grant licenses to
    theaters, also known as exhibitors, to play those films to the general
    public.
    A group of film distributors, referred to as the “major” and
    “mini-major”3 film studios, collectively distribute the majority of
    “first-run commercial films in the United States.” First-run films
    are “new films that exhibitors play immediately following the
    release date.” A “commercial film” is one that has high “grossing
    ability” because it will appeal to a large audience. “[O]n the other
    end of the spectrum” from “commercial films” are the “more artistic
    class movies,” “class title[s] that might come out on a more limited
    release basis.”
    Distributors usually license first-run films on a “day and
    date” basis, meaning they grant licenses to a theater regardless
    of whether nearby theaters are also licensing the film at the same
    time. When two or more theaters are located very close to each
    other, however, distributors license a film to only one of those
    theaters for a period immediately following a film’s initial release.
    This is referred to as a “clearance” situation, or a “competitive
    zone.” A clearance is “an exclusive right that a film distributor
    grants to a theater in connection with the licensing of a film” that
    3 Specifically,seven distributors known as the “majors”—
    Universal, Fox, Paramount, Sony, Disney, Warner Bros., and
    Lionsgate— together with a few “mini-majors,” “account for
    95 percent of the industry.”
    4
    “prohibits the distributor from licensing the film for exhibition
    at certain other theaters . . . while the film is being shown at the
    theater that obtained the clearance.” (Flagship Theatres of Palm
    Desert, LLC v. Century Theatres, Inc. (2011) 
    198 Cal. App. 4th 1366
    ,
    1375 (Flagship I).)
    After the initial period of time covered by a clearance, a
    distributor may choose to license the film to the other theater or
    theaters in the clearance zone. At that point, however, the film is
    no longer a first-run film, but a less lucrative “moveover.”
    Although a clearance by definition means only one theater
    in the zone may exhibit a given film during the clearance period,
    distributors do not necessarily grant clearances to all their films
    to the same theater. Instead, a distributor may choose to allocate
    films between theaters in the zone, granting one theater clearances
    to some films, and the other theater (or theaters) in the zone
    clearances to other films.
    During the relevant time period for this case (2003–2016),
    clearances were common throughout the country.4 A particular
    clearance may violate antitrust laws if it is shown to cause actual
    harm to competition that outweighs any procompetitive benefits of
    the clearance. (Orson, Inc. v. Miramax Film Corp. (3d Cir. 1996)
    
    79 F.3d 1358
    , 1372 (Orson).) But clearances have withstood
    antitrust scrutiny on several occasions because they can and often
    do generate a net benefit to consumers by increasing the selection
    of films that theaters offer and stimulating competition on bases
    other than film selection. (See, e.g., ibid.; Three Movies of Tarzana
    v. Pacific Theatres, Inc. (9th Cir. 1987) 
    828 F.2d 1395
    , 1399
    4In 2016, distributors shifted away from granting clearances
    in competitive zones. Paramount is a notable exception, having
    stopped honoring clearances in 2009.
    5
    (Tarzana); Soffer v. Nat’l Amusements Inc. (D.Conn. Jan. 10, 1996,
    No. CIV 3:91CV472(AVC)) 
    1996 WL 194947
    *6 (Soffer) [clearances
    “increased the overall choice of films to customers” in that market].)
    B.    The River and Palme d’Or Theaters
    Century Theaters was an exhibitor that owned 80 theaters,
    including a theater called The River in Rancho Mirage, California.
    In 2006, another exhibitor, Cinemark USA, acquired Century
    Theatres. Following this acquisition, the combined entity (Century)
    operated approximately 300 theaters throughout the country,
    including The River.
    Flagship owned and operated a single theater in Palm Desert,
    Palme d’Or (the Palme), from 2003 until mid-2016.
    Both The River and the Palme were located in the
    Coachella Valley, a collection of towns largely populated by an
    older, more affluent demographic. State Route 111 (Route 111) is
    the valley’s main thoroughfare, facilitating travel between these
    towns, which include Palm Springs, Cathedral City, Palm Desert,
    Rancho Mirage, Indian Wells, and La Quinta. The River and
    the Palme are approximately two miles apart from each other on
    Route 111.
    The Coachella Valley has “a lot of theatres,” most of which
    are located on or minutes off of Route 111. Multiple theaters are
    located “not all that far from” The River and the Palme in terms
    of both drive time and distance. At trial, Flagship witnesses
    testified that the Palme competed for patrons with these theaters,
    including The River, the Mary Pickford 14 in Cathedral City, the
    Regal Rancho 16 in Rancho Mirage, the Regal in Palm Springs,
    the Regal Metro 8 in Indio, and the La Quinta in La Quinta.
    Although the specific driving distances between the Westfield Mall
    in Palm Desert (where the Palme was located) and these other
    6
    theaters are not included in the record on appeal, on the court’s
    own motion, we take judicial notice of these distances as being
    approximately 2 miles, 6 miles, 6 miles, 12.5 miles, 10 miles, and
    6.5 miles, respectively.5
    Differences in what The River and the Palme offered their
    patrons are central to the parties’ arguments on appeal. The River
    has 15 screens and is located in an outdoor shopping area. The
    River is a typical commercial movie theater with stadium seating
    and a typical movie theater concession area. It caters to adult, teen,
    and family audiences.
    The Palme had 10 screens and was located in an indoor
    mall. The Palme is an “art house theater” with a stated mission
    of offering a wide selection of independent, foreign, and other
    artistic class films that otherwise would not be seen in the
    Coachella Valley. Accordingly, the films the Palme exhibited
    excluded “very commercial titles,”6 although the Palme did seek
    5 Evidence   Code section 452, subdivision (h) permits
    judicial notice of “[f]acts . . . that are not reasonably subject
    to dispute and are capable of immediate and accurate
    determination by resort to sources of reasonably indisputable
    accuracy.” (Evid. Code, § 452, subd. (h).) Such facts include
    locations and distances between locations. (See People v. Traugott
    (2010) 
    184 Cal. App. 4th 492
    , 497, fn. 4 [taking judicial notice of
    distance between locations under Evid. Code, § 452, subd. (h)];
    In re Nicole H. (2016) 
    244 Cal. App. 4th 1150
    , 1153 [same];
    see also People v. Posey (2004) 
    32 Cal. 4th 193
    , 215, fn. 9 [taking
    judicial notice of the location of a city under Evid. Code, § 452,
    subd. (h)].)
    6 Examplesof “very commercial” films include the franchises
    Star Wars, X-Men, and Mission: Impossible, as well as Pixar films.
    7
    to show some “high-end adult commercial” pictures.7 This mix
    of offerings was designed to appeal to “sophisticated, discerning
    film fans” seeking “upscale, adult programming.” The theater
    “[did] not have a youth audience, at all,” and instead “focus[ed]”
    on “a cultured adult audience and seniors.”
    When the Palme opened, it made its desired mix of films
    known to distributors. It explained to distributor Sony, for
    example, that the Palme “will not be asking for, nor expecting,
    most Sony product, as this is not a typical mainstream venue.
    Please continue to sell . . . [T]he River all the very commercial
    titles.” Universal similarly understood that the Palme “[was] only
    interested in certain films. They didn’t really care about a lot of
    them.”
    The Palme’s decor and amenities were designed to create an
    upscale art house theater experience as well. Flagship redecorated
    the building’s interior, creating an “elegant” lobby of granite,
    slate, and hand-painted decorations. It had a café that offered
    “gourmet” food and “bistro fare” such as espresso drinks, smoothies
    and “premium desserts.” The theater also had sloped floors to
    accommodate patrons with canes and walkers.
    The Palme pledged to offer “the best selection of art,
    independent, foreign, documentary, experimental, and classic films”
    along with the “best service, the best ambiance, the best café
    7 The  Palme’s business plan therefore called for “a collection
    of main titles” that were “supplement[ed] in the other screens . . .
    with titles that people weren’t very familiar with,” including
    independent and foreign films. “[D]uring the trailers” for first-run
    commercial movies, the Palme “would show all the other films [it
    was] screening at the theatre.”
    8
    menu, the best technical presentation, and the very best overall
    movie-going experience in the desert.”
    C.    The Palme and Its Predecessor’s Difficulty
    Obtaining Licenses to First-Run Films
    The space Flagship operated as the Palme had been in a
    clearance situation with The River for years before the Palme
    opened, and Flagship was aware of this before it chose the space.
    The Palme’s predecessor, The Town theater, obtained some
    first-run film licenses from the major distributors. There is
    conflicting evidence in the record as to how evenly the distributors
    allocated clearances between The River and The Town.
    When the Palme opened in 2003, it was not “awarded a
    high end commercial film for an entire year.” The River routinely
    requested and received clearances over the Palme for such films.
    The Palme continued to have difficulties licensing first-run
    films from the major distributors in the years that followed.
    In some years during the relevant period, one or more major
    distributors did not license a single film to the Palme. For example,
    between 2002 and 2005, Paramount did not license any films to the
    Palme, and in 2003, 2006, and 2014, Universal did not license any
    films to the Palme. On several occasions, the Palme offered to
    license a distributor’s first-run film on terms particularly attractive
    to the distributor—for example, by offering more screens, longer
    runs and a larger film rental payment than did The River, as well
    as a guaranteed minimum film rental—but these offers were
    unsuccessful. Uncontradicted expert testimony based on “Rentrak”
    data reflects, however, that in terms of first-run films overall—
    that is, not just the high grossing films or films from major
    distributors—“the Palme actually had . . . slightly more first[-]run
    films [from November 2003 to June 2016] than [T]he River.” “[O]f
    9
    those 1414 first[-]run films [shown at the Palme], more than half ”—
    55 percent—“were shown no place else in the entire Coachella
    Valley.”
    D.    Flagship Attributes Its Difficulty Obtaining
    Licenses to Century’s “Circuit Dealing” and
    Sues Century
    Flagship sued Century in 2007, alleging that the manner
    in which Century licensed films caused distributors to deny the
    Palme licenses to the most lucrative first-run commercial films,
    and that these film license agreements violated the Cartwright Act,
    California’s antitrust law. (See Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16720 et seq.)
    Specifically, Flagship alleged that Century’s film licensing
    agreements, including agreements with the major and mini-major
    film studios, reflected a practice referred to as “circuit dealing”—
    “ ‘the pooling of the purchasing power of an entire [theater] circuit
    in bidding for films,’ which undermines the competitive process of
    bidding for film licenses ‘theatre by theatre.’ ” (Flagship 
    I, supra
    ,
    198 Cal.App.4th at p. 1375, quoting United States v. Paramount
    Pictures (1948) 
    334 U.S. 131
    , 154 (Paramount Pictures).) The
    United States Supreme Court has recognized two distinct forms of
    circuit dealing. The first “is a form of monopoly leveraging, that is,
    ‘a monopolist’s use of power in one market to gain an advantage in
    a related market.’ (Sullivan & Grimes, The Law of Antitrust: An
    Integrated Handbook (2000) § 3.4b1, p. 106.) For example, one of
    the United States Supreme Court cases concerning circuit dealing
    addressed certain ‘master agreements’ between distributors and
    movie theater circuits that ‘lumped together towns in which
    the [circuits] had no competition and towns in which there were
    competing theaters.’ (United States v. Griffith (1948) 
    334 U.S. 100
    ,
    102–103 . . . .)” (Flagship 
    I, supra
    , 198 Cal.App.4th at p. 1375.)
    10
    The other type of circuit dealing occurs where a theater circuit
    owner does not necessarily have or leverage monopoly power in
    any region, but its “agreements cover[ ] multiple theaters within
    a particular circuit” and “ ‘eliminate the possibility of bidding
    for films theatre by theatre. In that way they eliminate the
    opportunity for the small competitor to obtain the choice
    first[-]runs, and put a premium on the size of the circuit. They
    are, therefore, devices for stifling competition and diverting the
    cream of the business to the large operators.’ ” (Id. at p. 1376,
    quoting Paramount 
    Pictures, supra
    , 334 U.S. at p. 154.)
    For ease of reference, we refer to these two types of
    circuit-dealing claims as “monopoly circuit-dealing claims” and
    “non-monopoly circuit-dealing claims,” respectively.
    Flagship alleged Century engaged in both types of circuit
    dealing. Namely, it alleged that (1) Century leveraged its power as
    the owner of numerous theaters across the country—some in areas
    with little or no competition—to pressure distributors into granting
    The River clearances over the Palme, and (2) Century’s practice of
    negotiating multi-theater licensing agreements exerted pressure on
    distributors to shun the Palme or risk losing business from Century
    outside the Coachella Valley. The complaint also alleged that
    Century exerted further pressure on distributors to grant The River
    clearances over the Palme by licensing multiple films from a
    distributor at once—that is, Century would agree to play an entire
    slate of a distributor’s current films, even the less desirable ones.8
    8 Flagship  does not argue that such multi-film licensing
    agreements (as opposed to multi-theater agreements) constitute a
    form of circuit dealing, nor would such an argument find support in
    the current law.
    11
    Flagship’s lawsuit did not allege that the clearances
    between the two theaters violated the antitrust laws—that is,
    that the clearances were themselves agreements prohibited
    by the Cartwright Act. Rather, Flagship alleged The River’s
    clearances over the Palme were the fruits of Century’s challenged
    circuit-dealing agreements, and thus a product of—but not
    themselves—an antitrust violation. (Flagship 
    I, supra
    ,
    198 Cal.App.4th at pp. 1381–1382.)
    E.    The Palme Closes and the Tristone Palme 10
    Opens in Its Place
    In 2016, the mall where the Palme was located elected not to
    renew Flagship’s lease. Specifically, while Flagship was negotiating
    for a permanent lease of the space, the mall informed Flagship that
    it wanted to lease to a different theater operator, and indicated to
    Flagship that the other exhibitor was willing to pay more. Flagship
    witnesses testified that Flagship had a limited ability to bid for
    the lease due to a lack of “fair access to product” resulting from
    Century’s challenged circuit dealing.
    The Palme closed on June 30, 2016, and the Tristone
    Palme 10 (the Tristone) opened a “[m]atter of days” thereafter
    in the same space. The theater was not renovated prior to the
    Tristone opening, and the new management continued to play
    independent and unique films. Specifically, expert testimony
    reflects that 37 percent of the films shown at the Tristone in its
    first 15 months of business (from July 2016 to September 2017)
    were not offered elsewhere in the Coachella Valley. Nothing in
    the record suggests that the Tristone has since closed.
    12
    F.       The Jury Verdict9
    At trial, Flagship pursued both its monopoly circuit-dealing
    claim, based on Century’s alleged leveraging of monopoly power
    in markets outside the Coachella Valley, and its non-monopoly
    circuit-dealing claim, based on Century’s licensing agreements
    that covered multiple theaters. In its closing argument, Flagship
    reiterated to the jury that it was not challenging the clearances as
    such: “[Flagship did] not contend that clearances in the absence
    of circuit dealing are unlawful. They’re not. Clearances always
    existed in this zone. Clearances don’t play a role in this case.”
    The parties disputed which antitrust analytical framework
    applied to Flagship’s circuit-dealing claims—specifically, whether
    either or both claims were subject to the antitrust “rule of reason,”
    as opposed to a per se rule. As we discuss in more detail below,
    if a per se framework applies, an antitrust plaintiff need only
    prove the act of circuit dealing and is not required to show that the
    conduct resulted in harm to competition. (See Marin County Bd. of
    9 This  case came before this court on two occasions before
    proceeding to trial. First, in 2011, we reversed the trial court’s
    initial summary judgment ruling in Century’s favor based on the
    sufficiency of the evidence to establish antitrust injury. We further
    held that “the court [had] abused its discretion by making discovery
    rulings that impermissibly curtailed Flagship’s efforts to gather
    evidence of circuit dealing” outside the Coachella Valley, and
    reversed the summary judgment ruling on this basis as well.
    (Flagship 
    I, supra
    , 198 Cal.App.4th at p. 1383.) After further
    discovery, the case was dismissed in 2014 on the eve of trial based
    on a spoliation issue. In 2016, we reversed that ruling (see Flagship
    Theatres of Palm Desert, LLC v. Century Theatres, Inc. (May 24,
    2016, B257148) [nonpub. opn.]), and the case ultimately proceeded
    to trial in 2018.
    13
    Realtors, Inc. v. Palsson (1976) 
    16 Cal. 3d 920
    , 930–931 (Palsson).)
    Under the rule of reason, by contrast, the plaintiff must prove that
    the defendant’s conduct harmed competition in the relevant market
    and that any procompetitive justifications for the conduct did not
    outweigh that harm. (See, e.g., Exxon Corp. v. Superior Court
    (1997) 
    51 Cal. App. 4th 1672
    , 1680–1681 (Exxon).)
    The court ultimately concluded that monopoly circuit dealing
    is per se illegal under the Cartwright Act, such that Flagship did
    not need to prove actual harm to competition in order to prevail.
    As to Flagship’s non-monopoly circuit-dealing claim, however,
    the trial concluded that the rule of reason applied. Thus, the
    court instructed the jury that, in order for Flagship to prove its
    non-monopoly circuit-dealing claim, Flagship had to prove both
    the elements of that claim10 and that the multi-theater licensing
    agreements underlying the claim caused an “anticompetitive effect”
    that “outweighed any beneficial effect on competition.”11
    10 The   court identified as the elements of a non-monopoly
    circuit-dealing claim that: (1) Century “was a dominant theatre
    circuit”; (2) Century “pooled its purchasing power to enter into
    licensing agreements for specific films that included multiple
    theatres, including, at least, [T]he River and one or more other
    theatres”; (3) “by entering into such multiple theatre licensing
    agreements, the film distributors were precluded from determining
    on a theatre-by-theatre basis which theatres would be licensed
    for a particular film, thereby eliminating the opportunity for the
    small competitor to obtain the choice first[-]runs”; (4) “[p]laintiff
    was in fact precluded from competing for first[-]run films as a result
    of [Century] entering into multiple theatre licensing agreements”;
    and (5) plaintiff suffered damages as a result.
    11 Although   the latter additional instruction did not
    specifically state that the harm must occur in a defined relevant
    market, the special verdict form required a finding to this effect.
    14
    The jury ultimately found that Century had not “engage[d]
    in the monopoly leveraging form of circuit dealing in violation of
    the California antitrust laws,”12 but that Flagship had proven
    its non-monopoly circuit-dealing claim. In reaching this verdict,
    the jury made several more specific findings, corresponding to the
    components of a rule of reason analysis. Namely, the jury found
    that Century’s multi-theater agreements “cause[d] harm to
    competition in the relevant geographic and product market[ ]
    in the form of . . . decreased output of film,”13 and that “the
    anticompetitive effects of [defendants’] conduct in entering into
    licensing agreements covering multiple theaters outweigh[ed] the
    procompetitive benefits of such conduct in the relevant geographic
    12  The jury was instructed that the elements of such a
    claim were that: (1) Century “possessed sufficient market power
    outside the market where the Palme and [T]he River competed”;
    (2) Century “used its market power by communicating to a film
    distributor that [Century] will not exhibit the distributor’s films
    in [Century] theatres outside the market where the Palme and
    [T]he River competed in order to coerce the distributor to allocate
    films exclusively to [T]he River rather than the Palme”; (3) this
    “use of its market power caused a film distributor to agree to
    license first[-]run films exclusively to [T]he River, rather than to
    the Palme, in a manner contrary to the film distributor’s own best
    interest and that prevents the licensing of films theatre by theatre”;
    and (4) plaintiff suffered damages as a result.
    13 The  jury verdict form references harm to competition in
    the form of either increased prices or reduced output, and does not
    require the jury to indicate which it found to be true. All parties
    acknowledge, however, that Flagship has never argued a price
    effect, and that no evidence regarding pricing was presented at
    trial. We therefore focus solely on the output restriction language
    in the jury’s finding.
    15
    and product markets.” The jury was not asked to make an express
    finding regarding the definition of the relevant market in which
    these anticompetitive effects occurred, but the court instructed
    the jury as to the parties’ competing proposed definitions of the
    relevant market in this case. With respect to the geographic
    scope of the relevant market, the court had instructed that, “[i]n
    connection with your evaluation of [Flagship’s] claim that [Century]
    entered into film licensing agreements covering multiple theatres,
    [Flagship] claims that one relevant geographic market for antitrust
    purposes contains only the Palme and [T]he River. [Century]
    claims that one relevant geographic market for antitrust purposes
    is broader than [T]he River and the Palme, and includes other
    theaters in the greater Coachella Valley.”
    The jury awarded Flagship $1.25 million in damages, which
    was automatically trebled to $3.75 million, pursuant to provisions
    of the Cartwright Act applicable to all successful private antitrust
    suits. (See Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16750, subd. (a) [“Any person who
    is injured in his or her business or property by reason of anything
    forbidden or declared unlawful by this chapter, may sue therefor
    in any court having jurisdiction . . . [and] recover three times the
    damages sustained by him or her.”].)
    G.    Posttrial Motions and Appeals
    Century moved for judgment notwithstanding the verdict
    or, in the alternative, a new trial based on several arguments,
    including those raised in the instant appeal. The court denied the
    motion, noting that as a result of Century’s multi-theater licensing
    practices, “the Palme was unable to show first[-]run films[,] and
    consumers were denied a choice of theaters,” which the court
    deemed to be an anticompetitive effect in the relevant market.
    Finally, the trial court rejected Century’s new trial arguments
    16
    regarding statements Century challenged as hearsay and the jury
    having reached an improper “compromise verdict.” Century timely
    appealed the judgment following the jury’s verdict and the court’s
    order denying Century’s motion for judgment notwithstanding the
    verdict and for a new trial.
    As required by the Cartwright Act, the trial court awarded
    Flagship attorney fees, although not in the amount Flagship
    had requested. (Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16750, subd. (a) [“Any person
    who is injured in his or her business or property by reason of
    anything forbidden or declared unlawful by this chapter, may sue
    therefor . . . shall be awarded a reasonable attorneys’ fee together
    with the costs of the suit.”].) Flagship timely appealed the court’s
    postjudgment order regarding attorney fees.
    DISCUSSION
    On appeal, Century argues that: (1) substantial evidence
    does not support the relevant geographic market definition Flagship
    identified at trial; (2) substantial evidence does not support the
    jury’s finding that Century’s multi-theater licensing agreements
    harmed competition in that or any other market; (3) the court
    committed reversible error by permitting into evidence certain
    testimony and emails Century argues constitute prejudicial,
    inadmissible hearsay; and (4) the jury’s verdict is an impermissible
    “compromise verdict.”
    We need only address Century’s arguments regarding the
    sufficiency of the evidence, as these are dispositive of both appeals.
    I.    APPROPRIATE ANTITRUST ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK
    Flagship first responds to Century’s arguments regarding
    the sufficiency of the evidence by contending that Century’s
    multi-theater licensing agreements are per se illegal under the
    17
    Cartwright Act, rather than subject to the rule of reason, and thus
    that Flagship was not required to prove anticompetitive harm in
    a properly defined market in order to prevail.14 Thus, we must
    first decide whether the rule of reason is in fact the appropriate
    analytical framework for Flagship’s non-monopoly circuit-dealing
    claim. (See Even Zohar Construction & Remodeling, Inc. v. Bellaire
    Townhouses, LLC (2015) 
    61 Cal. 4th 830
    , 837 [“[w]e answer . . .
    questions [of law] through de novo review”].) As discussed below,
    we conclude that it is.
    A.    The Rule of Reason and Per Se Illegality
    Generally
    The distinction between per se and rule of reason analysis
    stems from the fact that the Cartwright Act, like its federal
    counterpart the Sherman Act, prohibits not all agreements
    restraining trade, but rather agreements that unreasonably
    restrain trade. (See Business Electronics v. Sharp Electronics
    (1988) 
    485 U.S. 717
    , 723 (Business Electronics) [Sherman Act];
    
    Palsson, supra
    , 16 Cal.3d at pp. 930–931 [“In general, only
    unreasonable restraints of trade are prohibited [by the Cartwright
    Act].”].)
    The Cartwright Act states that “[e]xcept as provided in
    this chapter, every trust is unlawful, against public policy and
    void.” (Bus. & Prof. Code, § 16726.) Section 16720 defines the
    term “trust” as “a combination of capital, skill or acts by two or
    more persons” for certain enumerated anticompetitive purposes,
    14 Flagship also argues that, even if the rule of reason applies,
    substantial evidence supports the jury’s findings under the rule
    of reason as well. We address these arguments in the Discussion
    section II, post.
    18
    including “[t]o create or carry out restrictions in trade or
    commerce.” (Id., § 16720, subd. (a).) That prohibition is analogous
    to the catchall language of section 1 of the Sherman Act, which
    prohibits “[e]very contract, combination . . . , or conspiracy, in
    restraint of trade or commerce.” (15 U.S.C. § 1; see Aguilar v.
    Atlantic Richfield Co. (2001) 
    25 Cal. 4th 826
    , 838.)
    “The term ‘restraint of trade’ . . . refers not to a particular list
    of agreements, but to a particular economic consequence, which
    may be produced by quite different sorts of agreements in varying
    times and circumstances.” (Business 
    Electronics, supra
    , 485 U.S.
    at p. 731.) Nevertheless, “there are certain agreements or practices
    which because of their pernicious effect on competition and lack of
    any redeeming virtue are conclusively presumed to be unreasonable
    and therefore illegal without elaborate inquiry as to the precise
    harm they have caused or the business excuse for their use.”
    (Northern Pac. R. Co. v. United States (1958) 
    356 U.S. 1
    , 5; NYNEX
    Corp. v. Discon, Inc. (1998) 
    525 U.S. 128
    , 133 (NYNEX) [certain
    practices “so often prove so harmful to competition and so rarely
    prove justified that the antitrust laws do not require proof that
    an agreement of that kind is, in fact, anticompetitive in the
    particular circumstances”].) These “manifestly anticompetitive”
    practices constitute unreasonable restraints of trade under any
    circumstances, and are thus per se violations of antitrust law.
    (Chavez v. Whirlpool Corp. (2001) 
    93 Cal. App. 4th 363
    , 369
    (Chavez); see Northern Pac. R. Co. v. United 
    States, supra
    , at p. 5.)
    Modern United States Supreme Court cases caution, however, that
    these types of practices are few, and the Court has “been slow . . .
    to extend per se analysis to restraints imposed in the context
    of business relationships where the economic impact of certain
    19
    practices is not immediately obvious.” (FTC v. Indiana Federation
    of Dentists (1986) 
    476 U.S. 447
    , 458–459, italics omitted.)
    When a challenged practice does not fall into such a per se
    category, a court determines whether the practice unreasonably
    restrains trade by assessing its actual competitive effects under
    the rule of reason. (See Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v.
    PSKS, Inc. (2007) 
    551 U.S. 877
    , 886–887 (Leegin).) The rule of
    reason weighs the anticompetitive effects of the conduct in the
    relevant market against its procompetitive effects, and determines
    whether, on balance, the practice harms competition. (See, e.g.,
    ibid.; 
    Exxon, supra
    , 51 Cal.App.4th at pp. 1680–1681.) In engaging
    in this balancing, “a court may consider ‘the facts peculiar to
    the business in which the restraint is applied, the nature of the
    restraint and its effects, and the history of the restraint and
    the reasons for its adoption.’ ” (In re Cipro Cases I & II (2015)
    
    61 Cal. 4th 116
    , 146, quoting United States v. Topco Associates,
    Inc. (1972) 
    405 U.S. 596
    , 607 (Topco).)
    Subjecting conduct to rule of reason scrutiny thus does not
    reflect a conclusion that the conduct is somehow innocuous or
    likely to be legal. Practices scrutinized under the rule of reason
    may hold tremendous potential to harm competition and violate
    the antitrust laws. (See, e.g., 
    Leegin supra
    , 551 U.S. at p. 894
    [acknowledging several “risks of unlawful conduct” resulting
    from certain restraints reviewed under the rule of reason].)
    Rather, the defining feature of conduct evaluated under the rule
    of reason, as opposed to conduct deemed per se illegal, is that,
    “[n]otwithstanding” those risks, it “cannot be stated with any
    degree of confidence that [the conduct] ‘always or almost always
    tend[s] to restrict competition and decrease output,’ ” because
    the practice “can have either procompetitive or anticompetitive
    20
    effects, depending upon the circumstances.” (Ibid.) Thus, further
    evidentiary investigation into those specific circumstances and
    relevant market characteristics is necessary in order to determine
    its competitive effects. Rule of reason balancing serves this
    purpose.
    B.    Paramount Pictures Is Not Dispositive
    With this general understanding of the rule of reason and
    per se antitrust analytical frameworks in mind, we turn to the more
    specific issue of which should apply to Flagship’s non-monopoly
    circuit-dealing claim.
    Our discussion of this issue must begin with Paramount
    
    Pictures, supra
    , 
    334 U.S. 131
    , the United States Supreme Court’s
    last word on circuit dealing. Although the Court analyzed these
    claims under the Sherman Act, “federal cases interpreting
    the Sherman Act are applicable to problems arising under the
    Cartwright Act.” 
    (Palsson, supra
    , 16 Cal.3d at p. 925.)
    Paramount Pictures is a 1948 decision arising from the
    Department of Justice’s (DOJ) federal antitrust prosecution of
    numerous film industry participants, including several movie
    studios that owned production, distribution, and exhibition
    (i.e., theater) facilities. (Paramount 
    Pictures, supra
    , 334 U.S.
    at pp. 140-141.) The action sought to enjoin a long list of the
    distributors’ practices. These practices included certain clearances
    (id. at pp. 145–146), block booking (id. at pp. 156–157), franchising
    agreements (id. at p. 155), and, most notably for our purposes,
    certain types of film licensing agreements between distributors and
    exhibitors that reflected circuit dealing (id. at pp. 153–155). The
    DOJ’s complaint also alleged horizontal and vertical price-fixing
    conspiracies, through which the defendants set minimum theater
    admission prices. (Id. at p. 142.) The district court concluded that,
    21
    through these and other practices and agreements, the defendants
    monopolized and restrained trade in the distribution and exhibition
    of films nationwide. (Id. at pp. 141, 154.)
    The Supreme Court affirmed the district court’s conclusion
    that these practices constituted federal antitrust violations.
    (Paramount 
    Pictures, supra
    , 334 U.S. at pp. 174–175.) With respect
    to circuit dealing, the Supreme Court explained that the challenged
    film licensing agreements with theaters were “unlawful restraints
    of trade in two respects. In the first place, they eliminate the
    possibility of bidding for films theatre by theatre. In that way they
    eliminate the opportunity for the small competitor to obtain the
    choice first[-]runs, and put a premium on the size of the circuit.
    They are, therefore, devices for stifling competition and diverting
    the cream of the business to the large operators.” (Id. at p. 154.)
    Second, “the pooling of the purchasing power of an entire circuit
    in bidding for films is a misuse of monopoly power insofar as it
    combines the theatres in closed towns with competitive situations.”
    (Id. at pp. 154–155.) These two explanations correspond to the two
    variants of circuit-dealing claims discussed above: non-monopoly
    circuit-dealing claims and monopoly circuit-dealing claims,
    respectively. The Supreme Court treated all the film licensing
    agreements in Paramount Pictures as per se illegal under the
    federal antitrust laws. (See ibid.; see also United States v. 
    Griffith, supra
    , 334 U.S. at pp. 108–109 [companion case to Paramount
    Pictures addressing monopoly circuit dealing only].)
    Paramount Pictures ultimately resulted in a series of consent
    decrees that effected “a fundamental restructuring of the industry.”
    (Redwood Theatres, Inc. v. Festival Enterprises, Inc. (1988)
    
    200 Cal. App. 3d 687
    , 694 (Redwood); see Paramount 
    Pictures, supra
    ,
    334 U.S. at p. 179 (dis. opn. of Frankfurter, J.) [“terms of the decree
    22
    in this litigation amount, in effect, to the formulation of a regime for
    the future conduct of the movie industry”].) These decrees required,
    inter alia, that the studios divest themselves of their interests in
    certain downstream distribution and exhibition operations, and
    that they license films for exhibition on a “theater by theater”
    basis, “solely upon the merits and without discrimination in favor
    of affiliates, old customers, or others.” (Paramount 
    Pictures, supra
    ,
    at p. 164, fn. 17.)
    In the over 70 years since Paramount Pictures, the United
    States Supreme Court has not revisited the issue of circuit dealing.
    The California Supreme Court has never addressed the issue.
    Although Paramount Pictures provides crucial guidance on
    circuit-dealing claims, it is not dispositive here. This is because
    Paramount Pictures addresses circuit dealing in the context of a
    unique and distinguishable set of market conditions: vertically
    integrated film distributors who employed a broad range of
    anticompetitive practices, including horizontal coordination, to
    maintain their monopoly power over an entire industry. No such
    broad network of restrictions, nor any horizontal coordination, was
    even alleged here,15 and the jury rejected the idea that Century had
    market power. Nor are modern film studios vertically integrated
    in any way with the theaters that exhibit their films to the public.
    “Formerly, the distributors controlled circuits of theatres, and
    15 Flagship neither alleged, nor offered any evidence
    suggesting, that there was a broader hub-and-spoke conspiracy
    between and among the distributors, or that any of the distributors
    was vertically integrated with any exhibitor entity. Rather,
    Flagship’s theory involved multiple agreements, each between one
    distributor and Century, which is neither owned nor controlled by
    any distributor.
    23
    commonly attempted to lessen competition at the exhibitor level by
    using their vertical leverage through such devices as block booking,
    direct discrimination against independent exhibitors, joint
    operation of theatres, and conspiracy to fix prices and establish
    uniform clearances. The charge of circuit dealing [in Paramount
    Pictures] was colored by this evidence of conspiracy and vertical
    leverage; not only were some of the circuits controlled by affiliates,
    but in many instances there was ‘cooperation among the major
    defendants in their respective capacities as distributors and
    exhibitors.’ ” 
    (Redwood, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.3d at p. 697, quoting
    United States v. Paramount Pictures (S.D.N.Y. 1946) 
    66 F. Supp. 323
    , 346.)
    This unique constellation of market conditions and practices
    presented in Paramount Pictures was key to the district court’s
    decision—which, as to the substance of the alleged Sherman Act
    violations, the high court upheld without caveat. For example,
    the district court noted that its assessment of the film licensing
    agreements should be considered “in view of the history and
    relation to the moving picture business of the various parties
    to this action.” (United States v. Paramount 
    Pictures, supra
    ,
    66 F.Supp. at p. 346.) And on remand from the Supreme Court’s
    seminal decision, the district court pointed more specifically to
    the relationship between the defendants, noting that the studio
    defendants “must be viewed collectively rather than independently
    as to the power which they exercised . . . over the market by
    their theater holdings.” (United States v. Paramount Pictures
    (S.D.N.Y. 1949) 
    85 F. Supp. 881
    , 894, italics added.) In this context,
    the holding in Paramount Pictures served a unique purpose:
    “unravel[ing] the effects of the [film] distributors’ past domination
    of film exhibition.” 
    (Redwood, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.3d at p. 697.)
    24
    The United States District Court for the Southern District
    of New York recognized as much in an order, issued during
    the pendency of the instant appeal, that terminates the consent
    decrees resulting from Paramount Pictures. (See United States v.
    Paramount Pictures, Inc. (S.D.N.Y. Aug. 7, 2020, No. MISC.
    19-544 (AT)) 
    2020 WL 4573069
    *1.) The district court did so at
    the request of the DOJ’s antitrust division in connection with the
    division’s “initiative to review, and where appropriate, terminate
    or modify ‘legacy antitrust judgments that no longer protect
    competition’ because of ‘changes in industry conditions, changes in
    economics, changes in law, or for other reasons.’ ” (Id. at pp. *1–*2.)
    In concluding that terminating the Paramount Pictures decrees
    would be in the public interest, the district court described them
    as addressing a horizontal cartel (id. at p. *1), and noted that “[t]he
    [d]ecrees [have] put an end to [d]efendants’ collusion and cartel
    and, in their absence, the market long-ago reset to competitive
    conditions. Both the market structure and distribution system that
    facilitated that collusion are no longer the same.” (Id. at p. *4.)
    In sum, although we must and do follow the Supreme Court’s
    guidance in Paramount Pictures regarding competitive concerns
    associated with circuit dealing—in particular, their potential to
    stunt growth of small theaters or create barriers to entry for new
    entrants in the market for film exhibition—we do not read the
    decision as concluding that all multi-theater license agreements,
    under all circumstances, are per se illegal under federal (or
    California) antitrust law. (See 
    Redwood, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.3d
    at p. 697 [noting Paramount Pictures “must be understood in
    light of its peculiar facts and context” and that “[t]oday, the
    issues surrounding circuit dealing have acquired a very different
    industrial context”].)
    25
    C.    Relevant Precedent and Antitrust Legal Principles
    We must therefore look beyond Paramount Pictures to
    determine whether and under what circumstances, if at all, per se
    treatment might be appropriate for non-monopoly circuit-dealing
    claims. Below, we consider two primary sources of relevant
    authority in this regard: (1) general developments in federal
    and California antitrust law governing vertical restraints
    since Paramount Pictures, and (2) the few cases that address
    circuit-dealing claims, comprised of a single California Court of
    Appeal decision and a handful of federal district court decisions.
    (See 
    Palsson, supra
    , 16 Cal.3d at p. 925 [“federal cases interpreting
    the Sherman Act are applicable to problems arising under the
    Cartwright Act”].)
    1.    Developments in federal and California
    antitrust law regarding vertical restraints
    since Paramount Pictures
    In antitrust law parlance, a film licensing agreement
    is a “vertical restraint,” meaning it is an agreement between
    entities at “different levels of the market structure”— a film
    studio supplying film licenses (the supplier level) and a theater
    exhibiting the studio’s films to the public (the retail level).
    
    (Topco, supra
    , 405 U.S. at p. 608; see 
    Tarzana, supra
    , 828 F.2d
    at p. 1399 [concluding clearances are vertical restraints]; 
    Redwood, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.3d at pp. 703–707 [analyzing non-monopoly
    circuit dealing as a vertical restraint].) Thus, general antitrust
    law principles regarding vertical restraints are a logical source of
    guidance on the proper analytical framework for circuit-dealing
    claims under the Cartwright Act.
    The United States Supreme Court’s approach to vertical
    restraints has changed significantly since Paramount Pictures.
    26
    Namely, over the past several decades, the Court has repeatedly
    held that vertical restraints are to be analyzed under the rule of
    reason, rather than deemed per se illegal under the Sherman Act.
    (See, e.g., 
    Leegin, supra
    , 551 U.S. at p. 898 [resale price
    maintenance]; 
    NYNEX, supra
    , 525 U.S. at p. 130 [vertical boycott
    agreement]; Continental T. V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc. (1977)
    
    433 U.S. 36
    , 57–58 (Sylvania) [non-price geographic restrictions
    in franchising agreement].) This approach is a result of the
    “substantial scholarly and judicial authority supporting [the]
    economic utility” of vertical restraints in many instances, which
    “in varying forms, are widely used in our free market economy.”
    (
    Sylvania, supra
    , at pp. 57–58.) For example, although vertical
    restraints plainly restrict intrabrand competition, in doing so they
    can stimulate interbrand competition—“ ‘the primary concern of
    antitrust law’ ” (Business 
    Electronics, supra
    , 485 U.S. at p. 724;
    quoting 
    Sylvania, supra
    , 433 U.S. at p. 52, fn. 19)—“by allowing
    the manufacturer to achieve certain efficiencies in the distribution
    of [its] products.”16 (
    Sylvania, supra
    , at p. 54; 
    Leegin, supra
    , at
    16 “The  extreme example of a deficiency of interbrand
    competition is monopoly, where there is only one manufacturer.
    In contrast, intrabrand competition is the competition between the
    distributors—wholesale or retail—of the product of a particular
    manufacturer. [¶] The degree of intrabrand competition is wholly
    independent of the level of interbrand competition confronting the
    manufacturer. Thus, there may be fierce intrabrand competition
    among the distributors of a product produced by a monopolist
    and no intrabrand competition among the distributors of a product
    produced by a firm in a highly competitive industry. But when
    interbrand competition exists, as it does among television
    manufacturers, it provides a significant check on the exploitation
    of intrabrand market power because of the ability of consumers to
    27
    p. 890.) Vertical restraints can also “allow[ ] the manufacturer
    to achieve certain efficiencies in the distribution of his products.”
    (
    Sylvania, supra
    , at p. 54 [“[t]hese ‘redeeming virtues’ are implicit
    in every decision sustaining vertical restrictions under the rule
    of reason”].) Based on these and other potential procompetitive
    benefits, the Supreme Court has concluded that one cannot say
    any particular type of vertical restraint—even vertical restraints
    regarding price—“ ‘ “always or almost always tend[s] to restrict
    competition and decrease output.” ’ ” (Business 
    Electronics, supra
    ,
    at p. 723; see 
    Leegin, supra
    , at p. 894.) As such, rule of reason
    scrutiny is appropriate.
    Cases discussing two types of vertical restraints are
    particularly instructive in analyzing Flagship’s non-monopoly
    circuit-dealing claims: vertical boycotts and exclusive dealing.
    A “vertical boycott” occurs when “ ‘entities at different levels of
    distribution combine to deny a competitor at one level the benefits
    enjoyed by the members of the vertical combination.’ ” (Marsh v.
    Anesthesia Services Medical Group, Inc. (2011) 
    200 Cal. App. 4th 480
    , 494 (Marsh).) Exclusive dealing occurs when there is an
    “ ‘agreement between a vendor and a buyer that prevents the buyer
    from purchasing a given good from any other vendor.’ ” (Aerotec
    International v. Honeywell International (9th Cir. 2016) 
    836 F.3d 1171
    , 1180 (Aerotec), quoting Allied Orthopedic v. Tyco Health Care
    Group (9th Cir. 2010) 
    592 F.3d 991
    , 996 & fn. 1.) These two types
    of vertical restraints are at least partially analogous to Flagship’s
    non-monopoly circuit-dealing claim, in that Flagship argues
    substitute a different brand of the same product.” (
    Sylvania, supra
    ,
    433 U.S. at p. 52, fn. 19.)
    28
    Century’s multi-theater licensing agreements caused studios to
    license first-run films only to Century in the relevant geographic
    market as Flagship defines it (the Rancho Mirage clearance zone).
    Thus, Flagship’s claim could be understood as implying several
    vertical group boycotts—that is, agreements between each
    studio and Century to boycott a competing theater (the Palme).
    Alternatively, Flagship’s claim could be understood as implying
    several exclusive dealing arrangements—that is, agreements
    between each studio and Century that the studio will deal
    exclusively with Century in the Rancho Mirage clearance zone.
    In 
    NYNEX, supra
    , 
    525 U.S. 128
    , the Supreme Court applied
    the rule of reason to a vertical group boycott claim. Specifically,
    the Court concluded that an alleged agreement between a supplier
    and buyer that the buyer would boycott a competing supplier “for
    an improper reason” was not per se illegal under the Sherman Act.
    (Id. at p. 133.) The complaint in NYNEX alleged that the defendant
    had monopoly power, that the purpose of the challenged agreement
    was “to drive [the competing supplier] from the market” (id. at
    p. 137), and that the defendants’ conduct increased prices to
    consumers. (Id. at pp. 136–138.) The Court did not find these
    allegations sufficient to warrant per se treatment, and expressly
    rejected the suggestion that any “special motive” of parties to a
    vertical boycott “could make a significant difference” in this regard.
    (Id. at p. 138.) Rather, the Court made the broad pronouncement
    that “antitrust law does not permit the application of the per se rule
    in the boycott context in the absence of a horizontal agreement.”17
    (Id. at p. 138.)
    17 Although NYNEX acknowledged the possibility that
    a vertical agreement restricting price might warrant per se
    29
    Sherman Act challenges to exclusive dealing arrangements
    are likewise analyzed under the rule of reason. (See Jefferson
    Parish Hospital Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde (1984) 
    466 U.S. 29
    ;
    id. at pp. 45-46
    (conc. opn. of O’Connor, J.), abrogated on other grounds
    in Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc. (2006) 
    547 U.S. 28
    , 34 [characterizing agreement the majority described as subject
    to the rule of reason as an exclusive dealing arrangement subject
    to the rule of reason]; 
    Aerotec, supra
    , 836 F.3d at p. 1180, fn. 2
    [“[b]ecause exclusive dealing arrangements provide ‘well-recognized
    economic benefits . . . including the enhancement of interbrand
    competition,’ we apply the rule of reason rather than a per se
    analysis”]; see also, e.g., Eisai, Inc. v. Sanofi Aventis U.S., LLC
    (3d Cir. 2016) 
    821 F.3d 394
    , 403 [exclusive dealing arrangements
    can “offer consumers various economic benefits” and thus are
    “judged under the rule of reason”].) Federal courts also apply
    the rule of reason to exclusive dealing agreements in the movie
    theater industry specifically—namely, to clearances. (See, e.g.,
    
    Tarzana, supra
    , 828 F.2d at p. 1399 [because clearances are vertical
    restraints, they “are reasonable if they are likely to promote
    interbrand competition without overly restricting intrabrand
    competition”]; 
    Orson, supra
    , 79 F.3d at p. 1372.)
    The California Supreme Court has not yet addressed the
    general treatment of vertical restraints under the Cartwright Act,
    nor has it considered exclusive dealing or vertical group boycott
    claims more specifically. But California Courts of Appeal generally
    analyze vertical restraints under the rule of reason. (See Exxon,
    treatment, the Court has since held that vertical agreements
    regarding resale prices are also subject to the rule of reason, and
    for largely the same reasons that non-price vertical restraints are.
    (See 
    Leegin, supra
    , 551 U.S. at pp. 
    890–894.) 30 supra
    , 51 Cal.App.4th at p. 1681 [where an antitrust plaintiff
    alleges vertical restraints, facts must be pleaded showing “some
    anticompetitive effect in the larger, interbrand market”]; Bert G.
    Gianelli Distributing Co. v. Beck & Co. (1985) 
    172 Cal. App. 3d 1020
    , 1044 (Gianelli Distributing) [same], disapproved of on
    other grounds by Dore v. Arnold Worldwide, Inc. (2006) 
    39 Cal. 4th 384
    ; see also Theme Promotions v. News America Marketing FSI
    (9th Cir. 2008) 
    546 F.3d 991
    , 1000 [“California courts have
    determined that vertical restraints of trade, including exclusive
    dealing contracts, are not per se unreasonable but instead are
    subject to a ‘rule of reason’ analysis”] (italics omitted).) And
    our state Courts of Appeal have also more specifically held that,
    absent some horizontal component or leveraging of monopoly
    power, neither exclusive dealing arrangements nor vertical
    group boycotts are per se violations of the Cartwright Act. (See
    Fisherman’s Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court (2003)
    
    114 Cal. App. 4th 309
    , 335 (Fisherman’s Wharf) [“exclusive dealing
    arrangements are not deemed illegal per se” but rather “tested
    under a rule of reason”]; 
    Marsh, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.4th at p. 494
    [rule of reason applies to “vertical boycott[s]”]; Gianelli 
    Distributing, supra
    , 172 Cal.App.3d at pp. 1045, 1047 [applying rule of reason to
    vertical agreement between manufacturer and distributor to shift
    business away from competing distributer]; see also Antitrust,
    UCL and Privacy Section, Cal. Lawyers Association, Cal. Antitrust
    and Unfair Competition Law (rev. ed. 2019) § 2.09 [“purely
    vertical group boycotts are reviewed under the rule of reason”];
    id., § 3.08 [“[i]n
    California, as under federal law, exclusive dealing
    arrangements are not deemed necessarily illegal per se; rather, they
    are generally analyzed under the rule of reason”] (fn. omitted).)
    Rather, a plaintiff alleging such violations must prove net harm
    31
    to competition under the rule of reason. (See Fisherman’s 
    Wharf, supra
    , 114 Cal.App.4th at p. 335; 
    Marsh, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.4th
    at p. 494.) These decisions apply largely the same logic as the
    United States Supreme Court decisions discussed above (see, e.g.,
    Dayton Time Lock Service Inc. v. Silent Watchman Corp. (1975)
    
    52 Cal. App. 3d 1
    , 6 [“Exclusive-dealing contracts are not necessarily
    invalid. They may provide an incentive for the marketing of new
    products and a guarantee of quality-control distribution.”]; Gianelli
    
    Distributing, supra
    , 172 Cal.App.3d at p. 1045, citing 
    Sylvania, supra
    , 433 U.S. at pp. 51–52, 58–59.)
    2.   California and federal cases addressing
    circuit dealing since Paramount Pictures
    We turn next to the modern cases that have considered
    circuit-dealing claims since the Paramount Pictures decision and
    the developments in antitrust jurisprudence outlined above.18
    18 We  do not discuss some of the Sherman Act cases Flagship
    cites that predate the significant changes in federal antitrust law
    (and, in some cases, the significant changes in the film industry)
    outlined in the Discussion section I.C.1 (see pp. 26-31, ante) and
    thus are not instructive. (See Beech Cinema v. Twentieth Century-
    Fox Film (2d Cir. 1980) 
    622 F.2d 1106
    ; Columbia Pictures Corp. v.
    Charles Rubenstein, Inc. (8th Cir. 1961) 
    289 F.2d 418
    ; Fox West
    Coast Theatres Corp. v. Paradise T. Bldg. Corp. (9th Cir. 1958) 
    264 F.2d 602
    ; Bordonaro Bros. Theatres v. Paramount Pictures (2d Cir.
    1949) 
    176 F.2d 594
    .) Moreover, none of these cases addresses the
    correct analytical framework for circuit-dealing claims, but rather
    various other issues not directly relevant to this appeal, such as the
    sufficiency of evidence supporting the existence of the conspiracy
    alleged.
    32
    a.    California circuit-dealing cases
    Only two California decisions have addressed the issue:
    
    Redwood, supra
    , 
    200 Cal. App. 3d 687
    , and this court’s decision in
    Flagship 
    I, supra
    , 
    198 Cal. App. 4th 1366
    . In Flagship I, we did not
    have occasion to decide which analytical framework to apply to any
    type of circuit-dealing claims.19
    Redwood, by contrast, provides a detailed discussion
    of the issue, drawing from sources similar to those we survey
    above. First, the court “acknowledged that the United States
    Supreme Court held circuit dealing per se unlawful under the
    Sherman Act but also recognized that both federal antitrust
    law and the structure of the film industry have undergone
    considerable development since the late 1940’s.” (Flagship 
    I, supra
    ,
    198 Cal.App.4th at p. 1377, citing 
    Redwood, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.3d
    at pp. 697–698.) The court proceeded to survey antitrust law in
    several related areas, including boycotts and vertical restraints,
    as well as the significant changes in the film industry discussed
    above, noting that “[t]oday, the issues surrounding circuit dealing
    have acquired a very different industrial context” 
    (Redwood, supra
    ,
    at p. 697), and that, “ ‘[w]ith the elimination of a motion picture
    industry vertically integrated downward to the exhibitor level,
    19 The  parties raised this issue in Flagship I. (Flagship 
    I, supra
    , 198 Cal.App.4th at p. 1386.) At the time, however, they had
    not briefed all the legal issues relevant to deciding which antitrust
    analytical framework applied, and the record was insufficient to
    determine the exact nature of Flagship’s circuit-dealing claims. (Id.
    at pp. 1386–1387.) We noted that “[t]he type of circuit[-]dealing
    claim at issue might influence the analysis of whether the per se
    rule or the rule of reason should apply,” in that it “might make
    certain authorities or analogies more relevant than others,” and
    declined to decide the issue. (Ibid.)
    33
    the significance of a distributor’s refusal to do business with
    an independent shifts dramatically.’ ” (Id. at p. 698, quoting
    Southway Theatres, Inc. v. Georgia Theatre Co. (5th Cir. 1982)
    
    672 F.2d 485
    , 498.) In light of these changed market conditions,
    the modern antitrust approach to vertical restraints, and the need
    to understand Paramount Pictures “in light of its peculiar facts
    and context” 
    (Redwood, supra
    , at p. 697), the Redwood court
    ultimately concluded that the plaintiff ’s non-monopoly circuit-
    dealing claim was subject to the rule of reason analysis under the
    Cartwright Act. (Id. at p. 713.)
    b.     Federal circuit-dealing cases
    Finally, we consider a handful of federal district court cases
    that have discussed circuit-dealing claims.
    Some of these decisions note that Paramount Pictures
    requires per se treatment for all forms of circuit dealing. (See
    Cobb Theatres III, LLC v. AMC Entertainment Holdings (N.D.Ga.
    2015) 
    101 F. Supp. 3d 1319
    , 1342 (Cobb); 2301 M Cinema LLC v.
    Silver Cinemas Acquisition Co. (D.D.C. 2018) 
    342 F. Supp. 3d 126
    ,
    132 (Silver Cinemas); Reading International, Inc. v. Oaktree Capital
    Management LLC (S.D.N.Y. Jan. 8, 2007, No. CV 03-1895 (PAC))
    
    2007 WL 39301
    *7 (Reading).)
    Both Cobb and Silver Cinemas are motion to dismiss
    decisions in which the relevant antitrust analytical framework
    was not at issue.20 In both cases, the complaint alleged that the
    20 In Cobb, the defendants did argue in their reply brief
    that the rule of reason, rather than a per se analysis, applied to all
    circuit-dealing claims, but the court did not address the argument
    except to note that “[d]efendants suggest that circuit dealing
    should be scrutinized under the rule of reason. Even if that were
    34
    defendant theater-circuit owner had leveraged its market power
    to obtain clearances and that it had negotiated clearances for
    multiple theaters simultaneously. (See Silver 
    Cinemas, supra
    ,
    342 F.Supp.3d at pp. 133–135; 
    Cobb, supra
    , 101 F.Supp.3d at
    p. 1343.) The complaints in both cases also alleged monopoly
    power. (Silver 
    Cinemas, supra
    , at pp. 134–135, 137–138; 
    Cobb, supra
    , at pp. 1335, 1339–1342.) These decisions concluded that
    the respective complaints had sufficiently alleged both forms of
    circuit dealing to avoid dismissal.
    In Reading, the district court granted a summary judgment
    motion in favor of the defendant on numerous causes of action,
    and noted that, if the plaintiff was ever attempting to assert any
    circuit-dealing claims, it had abandoned them. (
    Reading, supra
    ,
    
    2007 WL 39301
    at p. *6.) The court then went on to note in dicta
    that “[e]ven if the [c]ourt liberally construed [p]laintiffs’ complaint
    to include a claim for circuit dealing, [p]laintiffs would not prevail,”
    because “no reasonable jury could find a conspiracy between [the
    defendant theater] and its distributors.” (Id. at p. *7.) In this
    context, the decision notes that “[p]laintiffs are correct that circuit
    dealing is per se anticompetitive,” but does not discuss or rely
    further on this characterization. (Ibid., italics omitted.) The court
    goes on to note, somewhat in tension with the implication that all
    circuit dealing is per se illegal that “Paramount [Pictures] merely
    condemned using these national relationships [between theaters
    and studios] to leverage master licensing agreements
    nationwide.” (Id. at p. *8.)
    Still other federal district court cases have applied the rule
    of reason to what appear in substance to be circuit-dealing claims,
    true, the [c]ourt’s analysis here would not change.” (
    Cobb, supra
    ,
    101 F.Supp.3d at p. 1343.)
    35
    citing the general rule that vertical restraints are no longer illegal
    per se. (See Cinema Village Cinemart, Inc. v. Regal Entertainment
    Group (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 29, 2016, No. CV 15-05488 (RJS)) 
    2016 WL 5719790
    (Cinema Village), affd. (2d Cir. 2017) 708 F.Appx. 29;
    Six West Retail Acquisition, Inc. v. Sony Picture Theatre
    Management Corp. (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 31, 2004, No. Civ. 97-5499) 
    2004 WL 691680
    (Six West).) For example, in Cinema Village, the court
    applied the rule of reason to “claims that various film distributors
    have refused to license first-run films to [plaintiff theater] as a
    result of exclusive dealing agreements (‘clearances’) with [defendant
    theater]” (Cinema 
    Village, supra
    , 
    2016 WL 5719790
    at p. *1), and
    that defendant theater had “extracted these agreements from
    the film distributors, against their economic interests, by using its
    considerable market power as a major nationwide theater chain.”
    (Ibid.) In Six West, the court cited Paramount Pictures for the
    proposition that “relationships that eliminate the opportunity
    for small theatres to obtain first[-]run films stifle competition and
    violate [s]ection 1 [of the Sherman Act],” and applied the rule of
    reason to what it termed a “relationship licensing claim,” based
    on a “voluntary relationship between an exhibitor and distributor
    [that] ‘hinder[s] other exhibitors’ ability to acquire quality movies.’ ”
    (Six 
    West, supra
    , 
    2004 WL 691680
    at p. *8.) Neither decision
    appears to view its application of the rule of reason as in tension
    with Paramount Pictures.
    Given the limited extent to which, if at all, these federal
    district court decisions appear to analyze the question of the
    appropriate analytical framework for non-monopoly circuit-dealing
    claims, they do not provide much meaningful guidance, either
    individually or viewed as a whole, on that issue.
    36
    D.    Flagship’s Non-Monopoly Circuit-Dealing Claim
    Is Subject to the Rule of Reason
    Based on the foregoing survey of relevant federal and
    California law and film industry developments, we conclude that
    the trial court correctly required Flagship to show actual net harm
    to competition under the rule of reason in order to prevail on its
    non-monopoly circuit-dealing claim. We agree with Redwood’s
    thoughtful analysis of the unique legal and industrial context to
    which the holding in Paramount Pictures is tethered. We further
    agree that the connection between the rule of reason and vertical
    restraints in modern antitrust law—a connection that, since
    Redwood discussed it, has graduated from a trend to a fundamental
    tenet—is key to selecting the proper analytical framework for
    non-monopoly circuit-dealing claims.
    The recent federal district court decision terminating the
    Paramount Pictures consent decrees (see p. 25, ante), similarly
    observed that both the industry and federal antitrust law have
    changed since Paramount Pictures, such that many practices
    deemed per se illegal in the 1940’s would not and should not be
    per se illegal in the modern movie theater industry under modern
    antitrust law. (See United States v. Paramount Pictures, 
    Inc., supra
    , 
    2020 WL 4573069
    at p. *6 [“[d]ecrees’ treatment of certain
    conduct as per se illegal and subject to criminal penalties . . .
    prohibits conduct that today may be deemed legal and beneficial
    to competition and consumers”] (italics omitted).) The order more
    specifically comments in dicta that circuit-dealing claims are today
    subject to rule of reason scrutiny: “The legal framework used to
    evaluate the [d]ecrees’ film licensing practices—including block
    booking, circuit dealing, and resale price maintenance—has also
    changed. Although per se illegal seventy years ago, today, courts
    37
    would analyze such restraints under the rule of reason—evaluating
    the specific market facts to determine whether a practice’s
    anticompetitive harm outweighs its procompetitive benefits.” (Ibid,
    italics omitted.)
    We note that Redwood cabins its holding in a manner
    suggesting that the rule of reason may not always apply to
    non-monopoly circuit-dealing claims. Specifically, the court noted
    that there was “no evidence of predatory intent” and no evidence
    that “the alleged agreements were dictated by the exhibitor,
    concerned with its own position, rather than granted in the exercise
    of the distributors’ independent discretion . . . reflect[ing] the
    perceived business advantages to the distributors of dealing with
    large theatre circuits.” 
    (Redwood, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.3d at p. 703.)
    With these caveats, the court held that the showing before it
    “plainly f[ell] short of the evidentiary threshold required to sustain
    a boycott theory of per se liability.” (Ibid.) This appears to leave
    open the possibility that a non-monopoly circuit-dealing claim based
    on film licensing agreements that have a predatory purpose, are
    dictated unilaterally by the defendant theater, and/or are beneficial
    to that theater and not the licensing distributor, might present
    candidates for per se Cartwright Act liability. Indeed, Flagship
    argues as much in its attempts to distinguish Redwood based
    on Century’s “pressur[ing]” distributors to enter into licensing
    agreements covering multiple theaters.
    We find Flagship’s arguments in this regard unpersuasive
    and, to the extent Redwood supports them, we disagree with its
    holding. Redwood “explicitly based its reasoning on federal law and
    precedents.” (Orchard Supply Hardware v. Home Depot USA, Inc.
    (N.D.Cal. 2013) 
    939 F. Supp. 2d 1002
    , 1011.) But the United States
    Supreme Court’s subsequent decision in NYNEX has since “clarified
    38
    that an unlawful group boycott claim must involve some horizontal
    arrangement.” (Ibid. [rejecting, on this basis, plaintiff ’s reliance on
    Redwood for the proposition that “the Cartwright Act might permit
    it to allege a group boycott even in the absence of any arrangement
    between horizontal competitors”]; see 
    NYNEX, supra
    , 525 U.S.
    at p. 138.) Indeed, the agreement at issue in NYNEX had the sole
    purpose of driving a competitor out of the market, yet the Court
    declined to apply a per se framework on this basis, reserving such
    treatment solely for boycotts with a horizontal component.21 (Ibid.)
    We are thus unpersuaded by the argument that per se treatment
    is appropriate where, as here, a theater-circuit owner has not
    leveraged its monopoly power in obtaining film licenses, but rather,
    as Flagship asserts the evidence reflects, “pressure[d]” a distributor
    into a multi-film licensing agreements—even if those agreements
    primarily or exclusively benefit the theater-circuit owner. The
    potential procompetitive benefits of an exclusive dealing or group
    boycott agreement—which California and federal courts have
    repeatedly recognized—are not negated or prevented when the
    parties to the vertical agreement have any particular motive.
    21 For this same reason, in the wake of NYNEX, we
    do not find Flagship’s citation to Movie 1 & 2 v. United Artists
    Communications (9th Cir. 1990) 
    909 F.2d 1245
    , to be persuasive
    authority for the proposition that non-horizontal “group boycotts
    that directly or indirectly cut off necessary access to customers
    or suppliers” are per se Sherman Act violations. (Id. at p. 1253.)
    Movie 1 & 2 is also inapposite in that it involved a boycott with
    horizontal components. (Id. at p. 1248 [distributor defendants
    alleged to have concertedly refused to deal with plaintiff theater
    and to have assisted with a split agreement between one distributor
    defendant and a theater defendant].)
    39
    More broadly, we see nothing categorically pernicious about
    film licensing agreements that cover “two or more theatres in
    a particular circuit and allow the exhibitor to allocate the film
    rental paid among the theatres as it sees fit” (Paramount 
    Pictures, supra
    , 334 U.S. at p. 154), such that non-monopoly circuit-dealing
    claims based thereon warrant per se treatment. Certainly, as the
    Supreme Court recognized many years ago, such agreements hold
    the potential to block new market entrants, or stunt the ability
    of smaller theaters to serve as viable competitive threats to
    their larger counterparts. (See ibid.) These consequences might
    ultimately harm consumers by increasing prices, reducing product
    quality, and/or reducing output to an extent that outweighs any
    countervailing procompetitive benefits of the agreements. But
    the fact that such agreements might so harm competition does
    not mean they always will. In Paramount Pictures, the certainty
    of harm to competition was sealed by the vertically integrated
    relationship between studios and theaters, as well as by the
    host of other anticompetitive practices these entities employed.
    The Supreme Court thus deemed per se treatment appropriate.
    But such certainty no longer exists. Even acknowledging how
    important first-run films are to theaters, it comports neither with
    modern antitrust law, nor modern economic and movie theater
    industry realities, to render all multi-theater licensing agreements
    per se anticompetitive and illegal.
    It is important to note that we are not addressing the
    appropriate standard for monopoly circuit-dealing claims, which
    require a showing of market power and may be more closely
    analogized to tying than to exclusive dealing or vertical boycott. We
    leave that question for another day, as the jury rejected Flagship’s
    40
    monopoly circuit-dealing claim, even under the per se standard the
    trial court determined should apply thereto.
    In sum, we conclude that a Cartwright Act plaintiff asserting
    a non-monopoly circuit-dealing claim must prove not only that
    a theater-circuit owner entered into film licensing agreements
    covering more than one of its theaters, but that such agreements
    caused net harm to competition, as determined by the balancing
    of anti and procompetitive effects under the rule of reason. When
    understood in context, Paramount Pictures does not require a
    contrary conclusion, nor could a contrary conclusion be reconciled
    with the treatment of vertical restraints—including specifically
    vertical boycott agreements, exclusive dealing agreements, and
    clearances—under California and federal antitrust law.
    II.   SUFFICIENCY OF THE EVIDENCE SUPPORTING JURY’S
    FINDING OF COMPETITIVE HARM IN THE RELEVANT MARKET
    We turn next to Century’s arguments that the evidence
    presented at trial does not sufficiently support Flagship’s proposed
    relevant geographic market (the Rancho Mirage clearance zone)
    or the jury’s finding that the challenged agreements harmed
    competition in the relevant market.
    We review such issues for substantial evidence, meaning
    we must resolve all conflicts in the evidence in favor of the
    respondent, and “indulge in” “all legitimate and reasonable
    inferences . . . to uphold the verdict if possible.” (Crawford v.
    Southern Pacific Co. (1935) 
    3 Cal. 2d 427
    , 429.) Under this
    standard of review, “the power of the appellate court begins and
    ends with a determination . . . whether there is any substantial
    evidence, contradicted or uncontradicted, which will support the
    conclusion reached by the jury. When two or more inferences
    can be reasonably deduced from the facts, the reviewing court is
    41
    without power to substitute its deductions for those of the trial
    court.” (Ibid.; see also Estate of Teed (1952) 
    112 Cal. App. 2d 638
    , 644 [“[s]ubstantial evidence” is “ ‘such relevant evidence
    as a reasonable [person] might accept as adequate to support a
    conclusion’ ”].)
    A.    Role of Geographic Market Definition Generally
    To assess “direct evidence of anticompetitive effects . . . in
    the relevant market . . . we must first define the relevant market.”
    (Ohio v. American Express Co. (2018) 585 U.S. __ [
    138 S. Ct. 2274
    ,
    2284-2285] (American Express).) Thus, under the rule of reason, an
    antitrust plaintiff must establish the boundaries of the market in
    which the plaintiff maintains the defendant harmed competition—
    otherwise, the finder of fact will not know where to look in
    assessing anti and procompetitive effects of a practice. (See
    ibid. [“ ‘[w]ithout a
    definition of [the] market there is no way to measure
    [the defendant’s] ability to lessen or destroy competition’ ”], quoting
    Walker Inc. v. Food Machinery (1965) 
    382 U.S. 172
    , 177; see Ralph
    C. Wilson Industries v. Chronicle Broadcast (9th Cir. 1986) 
    794 F.2d 1359
    , 1363 [“[t]o determine whether competition has been harmed,
    the relevant market must be defined”].)
    “The United States Supreme Court has declared that
    the relevant market is determined by considering ‘commodities
    reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes.’
    (United States v. du Pont & Co. (1956) 
    351 U.S. 377
    , 395 . . . .) Or,
    in other words, the relevant market is composed of products that
    have reasonable interchangeability for the purpose for which they
    are produced. (Id. at p. 404 . . . .)” (
    Exxon, supra
    , 51 Cal.App.4th
    at p. 1682.) This concept “encompasses notions of geography
    as well as product use, quality, and description. The geographic
    market extends to the ‘ “area of effective competition” . . . where
    42
    buyers can turn for alternate sources of supply.’ ” (Oltz v. St. Peter’s
    Community Hosp. (9th Cir. 1988) 
    861 F.2d 1440
    , 1446, quoting
    Moore v. Jas. H. Matthews & Co. (9th Cir. 1977) 
    550 F.2d 1207
    ,
    1218.) Thus, sellers offering products consumers would consider
    substitutes within the geographic area in which those buyers are
    willing to travel to purchase those products comprises the relevant
    market because the “groups of sellers or producers” in this area
    “have actual or potential ability to deprive each other of significant
    levels of business.” (Thurman Industries, Inc. v. Pay ’N Pak Stores,
    Inc. (9th Cir. 1989) 
    875 F.2d 1369
    , 1374 (Thurman).)
    B.    The Jury’s Finding Involving Relevant Market
    Century challenges the sufficiency of the evidence to support
    a finding that the relevant geographic market was as Flagship
    defined it—that is, the Rancho Mirage clearance zone. But the
    jury did not make any finding as to what the relevant market
    was. Although the court relayed to the jury what Century and
    Flagship’s respective proposed definitions of the relevant market
    were, the verdict form did not ask the jury to identify which (if
    either) definition the jury accepted. Instead, the verdict form asked
    the jury to determine a broader issue that involved “the relevant
    market,” but without defining that term. Specifically, the form
    asked whether “[the defendants’] conduct cause[d] harm to
    competition in the relevant geographic and product markets in
    the form of increased prices or decreased output of film.” (Italics
    added.)
    That the jury answered this question in the affirmative
    does not necessarily imply that the jury accepted Flagship’s
    definition. The jury could have accepted the definition proffered
    by the defense, but nevertheless concluded the defendants had
    caused anticompetitive harm in that more broadly defined market.
    43
    Therefore, in order to test the sufficiency of the evidence to support
    the jury’s finding of anticompetitive effects in “the geographic and
    product markets,” we must consider whether substantial evidence
    supports that competition was harmed in either the relevant
    geographic market posited by Flagship (Rancho Mirage) or the
    relevant geographic market posited by Century (the Coachella
    Valley).
    C.    Sufficiency of the Evidence to Support a Finding
    of Competitive Harm in the Geographic Market
    as Defined by Flagship (the Rancho Mirage
    Clearance Zone)
    1.    Flagship’s proposed geographic market
    Although Century challenges only Flagship’s geographic
    market definition, not its product market definition, the former is a
    function of the latter. Namely, “[Flagship] claims that the product
    market is the market for licensing of first[-]run films,” a market
    in which distributors sell licenses, theaters buy licenses, and
    moviegoers do not participate at all.22 (Italics added.) According
    to Flagship, because the Palme and The River are located in the
    Rancho Mirage clearance zone, they only need licenses to play
    22 The  idea that licenses for first-run films are
    interchangeable products—or, for that matter, that tickets
    to view first-run films are interchangeable products—is
    counterintuitive, given that there may be significant differences
    between any given first-run film and another. In concrete terms,
    it is hard to understand how the right to exhibit, or the right to
    view, an R-rated action movie is interchangeable with the right
    to exhibit or view a G-rated animated film. Given the role of
    first-run films as a group in the economics of the movie theater
    business, however, movie theater industry cases appear to have
    accepted this concept, and the parties do not challenge it here.
    44
    films in that zone, so licenses for other cities would not be viable
    substitute products for them. Moreover, Flagship argues, The River
    and the Palme are in a clearance situation in Rancho Mirage,
    meaning a distributor would only ever license any first-run film to
    one or the other theater there. Flagship argues that the geographic
    market is thus the “competitive zone” in which these clearances
    were granted: the Rancho Mirage clearance zone.
    To support its geographic market, Flagship points to
    extensive evidence reflecting industry recognition of the Rancho
    Mirage clearance zone, and testimony that The River is the only
    theater with which the Palme competed to obtain film licenses
    from distributors. For example, it cites testimony of exhibitors and
    distributors that the Palme and The River were the only theaters
    that competed in Rancho Mirage. Flagship argues evidence of such
    “ ‘ “commercial realities of the industry” ’ ” supports its proposed
    relevant geographic market.
    Certainly, ample evidence establishes that only the Palme
    and The River competed for film licenses in the Rancho Mirage
    clearance zone, as they were the only two theaters in this zone.
    But neither this, nor any other evidence Flagship presented at
    trial suggests that consumers in the Rancho Mirage clearance zone
    could not or would not travel outside of that zone to view a film—
    for example, at the Regal Rancho or Mary Pickford theaters located
    approximately 6 miles away from the Palme and approximately 4.5
    to 5.5 miles away from The River. (See fn. 5 ante, taking judicial
    notice of distances between theaters.) Indeed, none of the evidence
    Flagship identifies speaks to substitutability from the perspective of
    the movie-viewing consumer at all.
    This is a crucial point, because the Cartwright Act’s purpose
    is to “protect and promote competition for the benefit of consumers”
    45
    
    (Chavez, supra
    , 93 Cal.App.4th at p. 375, italics added), and
    “[c]onsumer welfare is a principal, if not the sole, goal of antitrust
    laws.” (Cianci v. Superior Court (1985) 
    40 Cal. 3d 903
    , 918–919,
    citing 
    Palsson, supra
    , 16 Cal.3d at p. 935.) The purpose of the
    rule of reason is likewise consumer-focused. (See 
    Leegin, supra
    ,
    551 U.S. at p. 886 [goal of rule of reason is to “distinguish[ ]
    between restraints with anticompetitive effect that are harmful to
    the consumer and restraints stimulating competition that are in
    the consumer’s best interest”], italics added.) And to the extent
    the antitrust laws protect competition more broadly, “[c]ompetition
    is not just rivalry among sellers. It is rivalry for the custom of
    buyers” (United States v. Bethlehem Steel Corporation (S.D.N.Y.
    1958) 
    168 F. Supp. 576
    , 592), such that “ ‘[a]ny definition of line of
    commerce which ignores the buyers and focuses on what the sellers
    do, or theoretically can do, is not meaningful.’ ” (Westman Com’n
    Co. v. Hobart Intern., Inc. (10th Cir. 1986) 
    796 F.2d 1216
    , 1221,
    quoting United States v. Bethlehem Steel 
    Corporation, supra
    , at
    p. 592.) Moreover, any such focus on competition more broadly
    is merely a means to protect the consumer. (See Feldman v.
    Sacramento Bd. of Realtors, Inc. (1981) 
    119 Cal. App. 3d 739
    , 748
    (Feldman) [“the purpose of antitrust laws is primarily to protect
    the consuming public by healthy competition, and only secondarily
    to protect the individual competitor”].)
    Accordingly, all antitrust movie theater industry cases of
    which this court is aware have defined the relevant geographic
    market based on the area in which consumers—that is,
    moviegoers—are willing to travel to see movies. (See, e.g., 
    Orson, supra
    , 79 F.3d at p. 1372 [summary judgment for defendant
    inappropriate where evidence potentially supported that challenged
    clearances caused anticompetitive effects in a market defined by
    46
    the choices available to “art film consumers in Center City”]; 
    Cobb, supra
    , 101 F.Supp.3d at p. 1336 [relevant geographic market for
    circuit-dealing claims sufficiently alleged as clearance zone based
    on moviegoers “not [being] willing to travel outside of the area to
    watch movies because of significant population density and heavy
    traffic congestion”]; 
    Reading, supra
    , 
    2007 WL 39301
    at p. *11
    [relevant geographic market defined as “the ‘ “area of effective
    competition . . . to which the purchaser [here, moviegoers] can
    practicably turn for supplies” ’ ”], quoting United States v. Eastman
    Kodak Co. (2d Cir. 1995) 
    63 F.3d 95
    , 104.)
    “[I]f the purchaser, i.e., the moviegoer, can go beyond
    the defined market for supplies, i.e., movies, then the geographic
    market is too narrowly defined.” (
    Reading, supra
    , 
    2007 WL 39301
    ,
    at p. *11, italics omitted.) This focus makes sense when one
    considers that, whatever is occurring in the distributor-facing
    portion of the market—that is, the portion in which exhibitors
    license films from distributors—consumers’ choices about
    where they will go to see a movie are what ultimately determine
    competing theaters’ “actual or potential ability to deprive each
    other of significant levels of business.” 
    (Thurman, supra
    , 875 F.2d
    at p. 1374.) Thus, “[f]or antitrust purposes, the proper inquiry is
    how consumers, not suppliers, view the market” and “the fact that
    industry professionals consider [Rancho Mirage] a separate zone for
    licensing purposes . . . has little relevance in the antitrust context.”
    (
    Reading, supra
    , 
    2009 WL 39301
    at p. *12.)
    Therefore, although there may well be a market for film
    licenses in the Rancho Mirage clearance zone, it is a market
    of questionable, if any, significance under the antitrust laws.
    This is particularly true in this case, given that much of the
    anticompetitive harms Flagship alleges occurred in the relevant
    47
    market were suffered by movie-going consumers, whose choices
    and preferences played no role in how Flagship defines the
    geographic boundaries of its proposed relevant market.
    2.    Anticompetitive effects in Flagship’s
    proposed geographic market
    Even assuming, arguendo, that Rancho Mirage could serve as
    a proper antitrust relevant geographic market in this case, Flagship
    failed to offer substantial evidence of anticompetitive effects in that
    market. In arguing to the contrary, Flagship identifies three types
    of harm in the Rancho Mirage market for film licenses. We address
    each in turn below.
    a.    Reduction in the output of film licenses in
    the Rancho Mirage clearance zone
    Flagship first argues that the challenged agreements reduced
    the output of film licenses in the Rancho Mirage clearance zone.
    Reduction in output is a form of competitive harm recognized by
    the antitrust laws. (See American 
    Express, supra
    , 585 U.S. at p. __
    [138 S.Ct. at p. 2284] [“direct evidence of anticompetitive effects
    would be ‘ “proof of actual detrimental effects [on competition],” ’ ”
    “such as reduced output, increased prices, or decreased quality
    in the relevant market”], quoting FTC v. Indiana Federation of
    
    Dentists, supra
    , 476 U.S. at p. 460.) Here, however, substantial
    evidence does not support a finding of reduced output. As discussed
    above, a clearance zone is a geographic area in which, by definition,
    a distributor will grant only one license to exhibit each first-run
    film. Thus, in a clearance zone like Rancho Mirage, there will
    always be only as many film licenses issued as there are first-run
    films to license. The challenged agreements affect not how many
    licenses each distributor issues, but how (if at all) the distributor
    48
    will divide up a static number of licenses between the theaters in
    the zone.
    Flagship did not argue below and does not argue on appeal
    that the general practice of granting clearances in Rancho Mirage
    harmed competition.23 Rather, under Flagship’s theory of the case,
    Century used circuit dealing to assure that distributors granted all
    clearance licenses or at least the most lucrative clearance licenses
    to The River, rather than, as is the case in many other clearance
    zones, allocating licenses between the theaters in the zone. As a
    23  Nor do the antitrust laws view this as inherently
    anticompetitive—rather, in order for a clearance to violate
    the antitrust laws, a plaintiff must show something beyond
    the inherent limitations a clearance places on the number of film
    licenses granted for a particular film in a particular area. “[T]he
    reasonableness of a clearance under section 1 of the Sherman Act
    depends on the competitive stance of the theaters involved and
    the clearance’s effect on competition, especially the interbrand
    competition.” (
    Orson, supra
    , 79 F.3d at p. 1372; see 
    Tarzana, supra
    , 828 F.2d at p. 1399 [clearances “are reasonable if they are
    likely to promote interbrand competition without overly restricting
    intrabrand competition”].) The Ninth Circuit has identified the
    following factors for the purposes of analyzing the competitive
    effects of a clearance beyond the inherent limitation on the number
    of licenses awarded in the clearance zone: (1) “the proximity of
    the theaters”; (2) “the location of theaters with respect to major
    thoroughfares”; (3) “whether transportation barriers exist between
    the theaters”; (4) “whether the plaintiff theater bid on the
    clearances”; (5) “whether the plaintiff acknowledged that his
    theater was substantially competitive with the defendant”;
    (6) “whether the theaters drew customers from the same
    geographical area”; and (7) “whether the theaters advertised
    throughout the same geographical area.” 
    (Soffer, supra
    , 
    1996 WL 194947
    at p. *4, citing 
    Tarzana, supra
    , 828 F.2d at p. 1399.)
    49
    result, Flagship argues, “distributors decreased their output of film
    with respect to the Palme, denying it access to the vast majority
    of profitable, first-run, commercial films.” (Italics added.) Thus,
    Flagship’s argument identifies a reduction not in the total number
    of film licenses granted in Rancho Mirage (which is necessarily
    capped in a clearance situation), but rather a reduction in the
    percentage of such licenses allocated to the Palme. This is not
    a reduction in overall output that harms competition, but rather
    a reduction in what one competitor received that harms a single
    competitor. The latter does not satisfy a plaintiff ’s burden under
    the antitrust rule of reason to show an “actual adverse effect on
    competition as a whole in the relevant market[.] [T]o prove it has
    been harmed as an individual competitor will not suffice.” (Capital
    Imaging v. Mohawk Valley Medical Assoc. (2d Cir. 1993) 
    996 F.2d 537
    , 543 [“Insisting on proof of harm to the whole market fulfills
    the broad purpose of the antitrust law that was enacted to ensure
    competition in general, not narrowly focused to protect individual
    competitors. Were the law construed otherwise, routine disputes
    between business competitors would be elevated to the status
    of an antitrust action, thereby trivializing the [Sherman] Act
    because of its too ready availability.”]; see also Southern California
    Institute of Law v. TCS Educ. System (C.D.Cal. Apr. 5, 2011,
    Civ. No. 10–8026 (JAK)), 
    2011 WL 1296602
    *10 [“[s]ection one
    claimants must plead and prove a reduction of competition in the
    market in general and not mere injury to their own positions as
    competitors in the market”]; see also RLH Industries, Inc. v. SBC
    Communications, Inc. (2005) 
    133 Cal. App. 4th 1277
    , 1285–1286
    [explaining that “the antitrust law is ‘concern[ed] with the
    protection of competition, not competitors’ ”], quoting Brown
    Shoe Co. v. United States (1962) 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 320.)
    50
    Thus, substantial evidence does not support a finding of
    competitive harm based on a reduction in output in Flagship’s
    proposed relevant market, even if we were to recognize that market
    for antitrust purposes.
    b.    Reduction in consumer choice of theaters
    in the Rancho Mirage clearance zone
    Flagship next argues that the agreements harmed
    competition in Rancho Mirage by causing moviegoers there to
    have fewer theaters from which to choose when they want to
    view first-run films. But Flagship offered no evidence suggesting
    consumers cannot or will not travel outside the Rancho Mirage
    clearance zone to see a movie. As noted above, Flagship defined
    that area as the relevant market based on where exhibitors buy
    licenses—not where consumers buy movie tickets. Flagship offered
    no evidence on the latter point. Thus, no evidence supports this
    type of harm to consumers in the Rancho Mirage zone. (See
    
    Marsh, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.4th at p. 495 [“ ‘it is plaintiff ’s burden
    to make the required showing of a “ ‘substantially adverse effect
    on competition in the relevant market’ ” ’ ”], quoting 
    Exxon, supra
    ,
    51 Cal.App.4th at p. 1681.)
    Nor would antitrust law necessarily view such an effect
    as competitive harm, even if substantial evidence did support it.
    First, the idea that removing one theater from a list of potential
    options for viewing a film constitutes competitive harm is
    inconsistent with the approach federal appellate courts take to
    analyzing clearances. Clearances necessarily deprive consumers
    of at least one theater choice in which to view a film, yet courts
    require an antitrust plaintiff challenging a clearance to prove
    some harm to competition beyond that in order for the clearance
    to violate the antitrust laws. (See fn. 23, ante.) Second, at least
    51
    one court has concluded in the specific context of circuit dealing
    that “the mere possibility that a consumer might have to see his or
    her first choice movie at his or her second choice theatre or his or
    her second choice movie at his or her first choice theatre[ ] is not an
    actionable restraint of trade.” (Six 
    West, supra
    , 
    2004 WL 691680
    at p. *10; see also 
    Reading, supra
    , 
    2007 WL 39301
    at pp. *13–*14
    [same]; Cinema 
    Village, supra
    , 
    2016 WL 5719790
    at p. *5 [finding
    that facts asserted “merely establishe[d] that . . . consumers must
    watch first-run films at one theater rather than at another” but
    “[w]ithout more, that state of affairs does not constitute actionable
    harm”] (italics added).) Finally, antitrust law generally does not
    view the elimination of a particular competitor—without more—
    as harm to competition. (See Austin v. McNamara (9th Cir. 1992)
    
    979 F.2d 728
    , 738–739 [The plaintiff “was required to show not
    merely injury to himself as a competitor, but rather injury to
    competition. Even ‘the elimination of a single competitor,
    standing alone, does not prove anticompetitive effect.’ ”]; Kaplan v.
    Burroughs Corp. (1979) 
    611 F.2d 286
    , 291 [“[e]ven if sufficient proof
    of intent and causation are introduced, the elimination of a single
    competitor, standing alone, does not prove anticompetitive effect”].)
    Although many first-run films were not available at the Palme,
    they were “still . . . available, presumably in whatever number is
    demanded by consumers,” such that the reduction in the number
    shown at the Palme reflects, “at most, a slight reduction in
    competition between [the Palme and The River] regarding
    the [exhibition] of [first-run films].” (ECC v. Toshiba America
    Consumer Products, Inc. (2d Cir. 1997) 
    129 F.3d 240
    , 245.) “It is
    settled, however, that to sustain a[n antitrust] claim, a plaintiff
    ‘must . . . show more than just an adverse effect on competition
    among different sellers of the same product’ ” (ibid.), and instead
    52
    demonstrate harm to competition in a manner that negatively
    affects “the consuming public.” (See, e.g., 
    Feldman, supra
    ,
    119 Cal.App.3d at p. 748.)
    c.    Barriers to entry in the Rancho Mirage
    clearance zone
    Flagship further implies that the challenged agreements
    caused harm to competition in that they created barriers for
    theaters trying to enter or expand operations in the Rancho
    Mirage clearance zone. Specifically, citing Redwood, Flagship
    argues that Century’s multi-theater licensing agreements
    “entrench the position of established motion picture exhibitors
    and pose formidable barriers to entrepreneurs seeking to enter
    (or expand operations) in the theatre business” 
    (Redwood, supra
    ,
    200 Cal.App.3d at p. 708), “a competitive harm the antitrust laws
    seek to prevent.”
    We do not disagree that such barriers may well result from
    certain multi-film licensing agreements. But no evidence in the
    record supports that this happened here with Century’s licensing
    agreements. To the contrary, the evidence shows that the Tristone
    entered the market immediately following the Palme’s closure,
    apparently unaffected by the theoretical barriers Flagship posits.
    Nor is there any evidence in the record suggesting that the Tristone
    has been unable to expand because of barriers created by Century’s
    licensing agreements.
    In the absence of evidence suggesting Century’s agreements
    created barriers to entry, Flagship quotes Redwood for the
    proposition that an exhibitor “may be placed at a grave competitive
    disadvantage” and that circuit-dealing agreements “may present
    serious antitrust questions.” 
    (Redwood, supra
    , 200 Cal.App.3d at
    p. 707, italics added.) Such a theoretical possibility—even one
    53
    recognized in appellate authority—is not a substitute for evidence
    of anticompetitive harm. “[T]here is really only one way to prove
    an adverse effect on competition under the rule of reason: by
    showing actual harm to consumers in the relevant market.”
    (See MacDermid Printing Solutions LLC v. Cortron Corp. (2d Cir.
    2016) 
    833 F.3d 172
    , 182.) Accepting the mere potential for
    anticompetitive harm as actual harm effectively resurrects the
    per se standard we rejected above. (See 
    NYNEX, supra
    , 525 U.S.
    at p. 133 [practices deemed per se illegal “do not require proof
    that an agreement . . . is, in fact, anticompetitive in the particular
    circumstances”].) Because non-monopoly circuit dealing is not
    per se illegal, the mere possibility that restricting access to a
    unique product may, under certain circumstances, have the
    economic effects Flagship identifies does not, without more, provide
    substantial evidence to support its non-monopoly circuit-dealing
    claim.
    D.    Sufficiency of Evidence to Establish Competitive
    Harm in the Broader Market as Defined by
    Century (the Coachella Valley)
    1.    Century’s proposed geographic market
    Century “contends that the relevant product market
    is the exhibition to consumers of first[-]run films,” a market
    in which exhibitors are the suppliers, and moviegoers are the
    purchasers. (Italics added.) In defining the geographic bounds
    of this market, Century therefore focuses on the ability and
    willingness of moviegoers to travel to theaters in nearby cities
    in order to see first-run films. Based on this analysis, Century
    defined the relevant geographic market as the Coachella Valley.
    Substantial evidence supports this definition. Numerous
    percipient witnesses, including the film buyer for the Palme,
    54
    acknowledged that the Palme and The River competed for
    customers with at least five theaters in the Coachella Valley. For
    example, one of the Palme’s co-owners testified that, before the
    La Quinta was built, the Palme “compete[d] for patrons” with
    five other theaters, and that “the market for patrons in that area
    consisted” of the Mary Pickford, the Regal Rancho, the Regal
    in Palm Springs, and the Regal Metro 8 in Indio. Distributors
    likewise testified that The River and the Palme competed with
    other theaters for patrons. Uncontested expert testimony also
    supports such a geographic market. Namely, Century’s economic
    expert testified that it was “reasonable to . . . conclude that all
    [Coachella Valley theaters] are part of the relevant geographic
    market,” based on the relatively short distances and drive times
    between The River and other theaters in the Coachella Valley,
    as well as customer survey responses indicating that 75 percent
    or more of moviegoers surveyed in each Coachella Valley city
    considered The River their favorite theater. The Coachella Valley
    theaters identified above are between approximately 6–10 miles
    away from the Palme.
    Moreover, unlike the market suggested by Flagship, the
    geographic (and product) market Century proposed to the jury is
    consistent with the approach to relevant market definition in all
    other movie theater industry and circuit-dealing cases of which this
    court is aware. (See pp. 47–48, ante.)
    2.    Anticompetitive effects in Century’s
    proposed geographic market
    Flagship argues that even if the Coachella Valley constitutes
    the relevant geographic market, substantial evidence still supports
    that the challenged multi-theater licensing agreements harmed
    competition in that broader market. Specifically, Flagship
    55
    identifies two types of anticompetitive harm in the Coachella Valley
    market. We address each in turn below, and conclude that neither
    can support the jury’s finding.
    a.    Reduction in output of unique films in
    the Coachella Valley
    First, Flagship points to evidence that the Palme exhibited
    independent and artistic films not exhibited at any other Coachella
    Valley theater, and that the Palme’s closure, which Flagship
    attributes to Century’s licensing practices, thus reduced the output
    of such unique films. Flagship argues that the Palme’s closure
    likewise reduced any competitive pressure to play such films that
    other theaters may have felt as a result of the Palme playing them.
    First, we note that the record does not include substantial
    evidence supporting that the challenged licensing agreements
    proximately caused the Palme to go out of business. The only
    evidence in this regard to which Flagship cites is testimony of
    the Palme’s co-owner that Flagship had a “limited . . . ability to
    bid for the lease” due to a lack of “fair access to product” resulting
    from Century’s challenged circuit dealing. This is speculation, not
    substantial evidence. (See California Shoppers, Inc. v. Royal Globe
    Ins. Co. (1985) 
    175 Cal. App. 3d 1
    , 45.)
    Moreover, even if the evidence did support that the Palme
    closed as a result of the challenged agreements, we are not
    aware of any evidence speaking to the total number of unique
    or independent films exhibited in the Coachella Valley after the
    Palme’s closure. There is thus nothing from which a jury could
    reasonably infer that the total number of independent films
    exhibited in the Coachella Valley dropped following the Palme’s
    closure. When asked to identify such evidence during the hearing
    before this court, Flagship suggested that the record contains
    56
    testimony establishing that over 700 unique films would not be
    shown in the Coachella Valley as a result of the Palme’s closure.
    This misconstrues the testimony. Century’s expert did opine that,
    during the 13 years the Palme was in business, the Palme exhibited
    approximately 700 films not exhibited elsewhere in the Coachella
    Valley. But he offered no opinion—nor does the record contain any
    evidence suggesting—that such films did not or could not find a
    home after the Palme’s closure.
    Indeed, the evidence in the record regarding other theaters’
    exhibition of independent or unique films supports an opposite
    conclusion. Namely, there was evidence that at least one theater
    competed with the Palme for licenses to independent films,
    as well as evidence that the Tristone, which began showing
    films immediately after the Palme’s closure, played unique and
    independent films.24
    b.    Loss of unique art house theater in the
    Coachella Valley
    Flagship next argues that the challenged agreements caused
    a reduction in output of a unique and valuable type of theater.
    Specifically, it argues the Palme’s closure denied consumers a
    “specialty theater with one-of-a-kind features” that offered a
    “singular combination of upscale amenities and senior-friendly
    24 Century’s expert economist calculated more specifically
    that 37 percent of the first-run films shown at the Tristone in its
    15 years were not exhibited at any other Coachella Valley theater.
    Although this represents a drop from the 55 percent he calculated
    for the Palme over the course of its approximately 13-year
    existence, this does not provide a basis for concluding that the
    overall number of independent films at all Coachella Valley
    theaters dropped as a result of the Palme’s closure.
    57
    design.” Like Flagship’s argument regarding a posited reduction
    in unique films following the Palme’s closure, this argument
    fails because there is (1) no evidence in the record to support
    the inference that the Palme closed as a result of the challenged
    agreements, and (2) no evidence in the record regarding what
    other theaters in the Coachella Valley offered patrons in this
    regard, either before or after the Palme’s closure. Without evidence
    regarding the amenities offered at theaters outside the Rancho
    Mirage clearance zone, the record cannot support a finding that
    the Palme was the only theater in the Coachella Valley that offered
    certain amenities. Perhaps more importantly, there is no evidence
    in the record supporting that, following the Palme’s closure, the
    Tristone stopped offering the same amenities and overall theater
    experience that the Palme had offered in that same space days
    earlier.
    This distinguishes the case at bar from 
    Cobb, supra
    ,
    
    101 F. Supp. 3d 1319
    , on which Flagship relies for this point.
    In Cobb, a federal district court concluded that a complaint
    challenging the use of clearances to prevent movie theaters,
    offering a unique “CinéBistro” experience from entering or
    effectively competing in the relevant market sufficiently alleged
    harm to competition, because these effects diminished the quality of
    theaters offered to consumers. (Id. at pp. 1326, 1335.) Specifically,
    “the [c]omplaint allege[d] in detail . . . the various amenities that
    [plaintiff ’s CinéBistros theater] and [the other theaters in the
    alleged market] respectively offer consumers, often drawing stark
    differences . . . [and] alleged more than a mere substitution of
    competitors” (id. at p. 1335), rather, that “consumers are being
    forced to purchase a product that is less desirable and of inferior
    quality.” (Ibid.) Here, there is nothing suggesting that the Tristone
    58
    offers a theater experience that is different from—let alone inferior
    to—that which the Palme had offered in the exact same space.
    To the contrary, there is testimony that the Tristone did not
    remodel the space.
    Flagship bore the burden of establishing harm to competition,
    so to the extent it now argues a reduction in the overall output
    of independent art house films, or the loss of a unique art house
    theater reflects such harm, Flagship must identify evidence of those
    overall losses. Pointing to the fact that the Palme was an art house
    theater that played many unique films and that it is now closed
    does not satisfy that burden.
    We therefore conclude that substantial evidence does not
    support the jury’s finding of anticompetitive effects in the relevant
    market, whether that market is defined as the Rancho Mirage
    clearance zone or the Coachella Valley. Because, as discussed
    in detail in the Discussion section I, ante, Flagship’s non-monopoly
    circuit-dealing claim was subject to the rule of reason, the lack of
    substantial evidence to support a finding of anticompetitive harm
    mandates reversal of the judgment. Because we reverse the
    judgment on this basis, we need not reach Century’s third and
    fourth arguments regarding a new trial.
    We likewise need not address Flagship’s separate appeal
    challenging the amount of attorney fees awarded below, as Flagship
    is no longer the prevailing party and thus not entitled to attorney
    fees.
    59
    DISPOSITION
    As to Century Theatres, Inc. and Cinemark USA, Inc.’s
    appeal (B292609), the judgment in favor of Flagship Theatres
    of Palm Desert is reversed. Accordingly, the postjudgment
    order granting Flagship Theatres of Palm Desert’s attorney
    fees is likewise reversed. Century Theatres, Inc. and Cinemark
    USA, Inc. are entitled to recover their costs on appeal in case
    No. B292609.
    As to Flagship Theatres of Palm Desert’s appeal (case
    No. B299014), the appeal is dismissed as moot. The parties
    shall bear their own costs on appeal in case No. B299014.
    CERTIFIED FOR PUBLICATION.
    ROTHSCHILD, P. J.
    We concur:
    BENDIX, J.
    SINANIAN, J.*
    *Judge of the Los Angeles Superior Court, assigned by the
    Chief Justice pursuant to article VI, section 6 of the California
    Constitution.
    60
    

Document Info

Docket Number: B292609

Filed Date: 9/2/2020

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/3/2020

Authorities (34)

Westman Commission Company, Cross-Appellant v. Hobart ... , 796 F.2d 1216 ( 1986 )

Electronics Communications Corp. v. Toshiba America ... , 129 F.3d 240 ( 1997 )

Bordonaro Bros. Theatres v. Paramount Pictures , 176 F.2d 594 ( 1949 )

United States v. Eastman Kodak Co., a Corporation of New ... , 63 F.3d 95 ( 1995 )

Orson, Inc. T/a Roxy Screening Rooms v. Miramax Film Corp. ... , 79 F.3d 1358 ( 1996 )

Capital Imaging Associates, P.C. v. Mohawk Valley Medical ... , 996 F.2d 537 ( 1993 )

Stuart M. Kaplan, as Trustee in Bankruptcy for Palmer Data ... , 611 F.2d 286 ( 1980 )

Allied Orthopedic Appliances Inc. v. Tyco Health Care Group ... , 592 F.3d 991 ( 2010 )

ralph-c-wilson-industries-inc-v-chronicle-broadcasting-co-miami-valley , 794 F.2d 1359 ( 1986 )

Thurman Industries, Inc. v. Pay 'N Pak Stores, Inc. , 875 F.2d 1369 ( 1989 )

Southway Theatres, Inc. v. Georgia Theatre Company , 672 F.2d 485 ( 1982 )

george-austin-md-v-james-v-mcnamara-md-james-r-st-john-md , 979 F.2d 728 ( 1992 )

arlie-mack-moore-evanell-e-moore-alfred-l-paulson-and-mary-e-paulson , 550 F.2d 1207 ( 1977 )

the-movie-1-2-a-general-partnership-v-united-artists-communications , 909 F.2d 1245 ( 1990 )

Aguilar v. Atlantic Richfield Co. , 107 Cal. Rptr. 2d 841 ( 2001 )

Marin County Board of Realtors, Inc. v. Palsson , 16 Cal. 3d 920 ( 1976 )

Cianci v. Superior Court , 40 Cal. 3d 903 ( 1985 )

three-movies-of-tarzana-v-pacific-theatres-inc-columbia-pictures , 828 F.2d 1395 ( 1987 )

Crawford v. Southern Pacific Co. , 3 Cal. 2d 427 ( 1935 )

United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc. , 85 F. Supp. 881 ( 1949 )

View All Authorities »