Ad Hoc Shrimp Trade Action Comm. v. United States , 925 F. Supp. 2d 1367 ( 2013 )


Menu:
  •                                  Slip Op. 13 -
    UNITED STATES COURT OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE
    AD HOC SHRIMP TRADE ACTION
    COMMITTEE,
    Plaintiff,                      Before: Donald C. Pogue,
    Chief Judge
    v.
    Consol. Court No. 12-002231
    UNITED STATES,
    Defendant.
    OPINION
    [affirming in part and remanding in part the Department of
    Commerce’s final results of antidumping duty administrative review]
    Dated: August 2, 2013
    David A. Yocis, Nathaniel Maandig Rickard and Jordan C.
    Kahn, Picard Kentz & Rowe LLP, of Washington, DC, for Plaintiff Ad
    Hoc Shrimp Trade Action Committee.
    Robert G. Gosselink, Trade Pacific PLLC, of Washington,
    DC, for Plaintiffs Marine Gold Products Ltd., Pakfood Public Co.
    Ltd., Thai Royal Frozen Food Co. Ltd., Thai Union Frozen Products
    Public Co., Ltd., and Thai Union Seafood Co. Ltd.
    Joshua E. Kurland, Trial Attorney, Commercial Litigation
    Branch, Civil Division, U.S. Department of Justice, of Washington,
    DC, for Defendant. Also on the brief were Stuart F. Delery, Acting
    Assistant Attorney General, Jeanne E. Davidson, Director, and
    Patricia M. McCarthy, Assistant Director. Of counsel on the brief
    was Michael T. Gagain, Attorney, Office of the Chief Counsel for
    Import Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce, of Washington,
    DC.
    1
    This action is consolidated with Marine Gold Prods. Ltd. v. United
    States, Court No. 12-00220. Order, Nov. 20, 2012, ECF No. 22.
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                     Page 2
    Pogue, Chief Judge:    This consolidated action seeks review of
    two determinations by the United States Department of Commerce
    (“Commerce”) in the 2010-2011 administrative review of the
    antidumping duty order on certain frozen warmwater shrimp from
    Thailand.2    Specifically, Respondent Plaintiffs3 challenge
    Commerce’s decision not to calculate an individual dumping margin
    for Marine Gold.4    In addition, Plaintiff Ad Hoc Shrimp Trade Action
    Committee (“AHSTAC”) – an association of domestic warmwater shrimp
    producers who participated in this review – challenges Commerce’s
    decision not to reduce respondents’ export prices by the amount of
    antidumping deposits paid for entries of subject merchandise.5
    The court has jurisdiction pursuant to
    Section 516A(a)(2)(B)(iii) of the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended,
    2
    See Certain Frozen Warmwater Shrimp from Thailand, 
    77 Fed. Reg. 40,574
     (Dep’t Commerce July 10, 2012) (final results of antidumping
    duty administrative review) (“Final Results”) and accompanying
    Issues & Decision Mem., A-549-822, ARP 10-11 (July 3, 2012) (“I & D
    Mem.”).
    3
    Respondent Plaintiffs are Marine Gold Products Limited (“Marine
    Gold”), Pakfood Public Company Limited, Thai Royal Frozen Food
    Company Limited, Thai Union Frozen Products Public Company Limited,
    and Thai Union Seafood Company Limited (collectively the
    “Respondents”).
    4
    See Mem. of Points & Auths. in Supp. of [Resp’ts’] [Mot.] for J.
    Upon the Agency R., ECF No. 28 (“Resp’ts’ Br.”). Respondents’
    brief also presents arguments in support of additional challenges
    that Respondents are no longer pursuing. See Pls.’ Reply Mem. in
    Supp. of Rule 56.2 Mot. for J. Upon the Agency R., ECF No. 49, at
    1. This opinion does not address those matters.
    5
    See Mem. of L. in Supp. of Pl. [AHSTAC]’s USCIT Rule 56.2 Mot. for
    J. on the Agency R., ECF No. 29 (“AHSTAC’s Br.”).
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                     Page 3
    19 U.S.C. § 1516a(a)(2)(B)(iii) (2006),6 and 
    28 U.S.C. § 1581
    (c)
    (2006).
    As explained below, Commerce’s Final Results are remanded
    for reconsideration and/or further explanation regarding Commerce’s
    rejection of Marine Gold’s request for individual examination as a
    voluntary respondent.    As also explained below, Commerce’s denial
    of an export price adjustment for the payment of antidumping
    deposits is sustained.
    STANDARD OF REVIEW
    This court will uphold Commerce’s antidumping
    determinations if they are in accordance with law and supported by
    substantial evidence. 19 U.S.C. § 1516a(b)(1)(B)(i).   Where the
    antidumping statute does not directly address the question before
    the agency, the court will defer to Commerce’s construction of its
    authority if it is reasonable. Timken Co. v. United States, 
    354 F.3d 1334
    , 1342 (Fed. Cir. 2004) (relying on Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v.
    Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 842-43 (1984)).
    DISCUSSION
    I.   Marine Gold’s Voluntary Respondent Request
    Respondents challenge Commerce’s denial of Marine Gold’s
    request for individual examination as a voluntary respondent in
    6
    Further citations to the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended, are to
    the relevant provisions of Title 19 of the U.S. Code, 2006 edition.
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                      Page 4
    this review. Resp’ts’ Br. at 12-18.   Commerce argues that the Court
    should decline to adjudicate the merits of this challenge because
    of Respondents’ alleged failure to exhaust their administrative
    remedies on this issue.7   In the alternative, Commerce contends that
    denying Marine Gold’s request for individual examination comports
    with a reasonable interpretation and application of Commerce’s
    statutory authority because granting the request would have been
    unduly burdensome for the agency. Def.’s Resp. at 16-18; see 19
    U.S.C. § 1677m(a) (providing that Commerce may decline to calculate
    individual weighted average dumping margins for voluntary
    respondents not selected for mandatory examination if “individual
    examination of such exporters or producers would be unduly
    burdensome and inhibit the timely completion of the
    investigation”).   Each argument will be addressed in turn.
    First, the requirement for administrative exhaustion does
    not preclude consideration of Respondents’ claim.   Certainly
    litigants challenging Commerce’s determinations in antidumping
    proceedings are generally limited to the arguments submitted to
    Commerce in their administrative case briefs below. E.g., Ad Hoc
    7
    Def.’s Mem. in Opp’n to Pls.’ Rule 56.2 Mots. for J. Upon the
    Agency R., ECF No. 42 (“Def.’s Resp.”) at 8-13; see Yangzhou
    Bestpak Gifts & Crafts Co. v. United States, 
    716 F.3d 1370
    , 1381
    (Fed. Cir. 2013) (“The court ‘shall, where appropriate, require the
    exhaustion of administrative remedies.’ The doctrine of exhaustion
    provides ‘that no one is entitled to judicial relief . . . until
    the prescribed administrative remedy has been exhausted.’”)
    (quoting 
    28 U.S.C. § 2637
    (d) and Sandvik Steel Co. v. United
    States, 
    164 F.3d 596
    , 599 (Fed. Cir. 1998) (quoting McKart v.
    United States, 
    395 U.S. 185
    , 193 (1969)), respectively).
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                     Page 5
    Shrimp Trade Action Comm. v. United States, __ CIT __, 
    675 F. Supp. 2d 1287
    , 1300 (2009).   But here Respondents argued in their case
    brief, as they do before the court, that Commerce’s decision to
    deny Marine Gold’s request for voluntary respondent status failed
    to comply with 19 U.S.C. § 1677m(a) because Commerce’s finding
    regarding the undue burden of granting Marine Gold’s request was
    unreasonable.8   Thus Commerce was put on notice of Respondents’
    challenge to the agency’s finding of undue burden under 19 U.S.C.
    § 1677m(a).9   That Respondents have now structured their argument to
    take into account relevant legal interpretations that were
    contained in a decision issued subsequent to the filing of their
    case brief below10 does not alter the essence of their legal
    8
    Compare Case Br. of [Resp’ts], A-549-822, ARP 10-11
    (May 11, 2012), Admin. R. Pub. Doc. 146, at 4-8, reproduced in
    Def.’s Resp. pub. app., ECF No. 43, at tab 3, with, Resp’ts’ Br. at
    12-18.
    9
    Cf. Pakfood Pub. Co. v. United States, __ CIT __, 
    724 F. Supp. 2d 1327
    , 1352 (2010) (noting that the exhaustion doctrine requires
    parties to preserve arguments for judicial review by including them
    in their administrative case briefs because doing so puts the
    agency on notice of the relevance of such arguments and affords it
    an opportunity to fully consider and explain its response to
    specific challenges).
    10
    See Resp’ts’ Br. at 15-18 (arguing that Commerce’s denial of
    Marine Gold’s request for voluntary respondent status rendered 19
    U.S.C. § 1677m(a) meaningless because “Commerce failed to show that
    the burden of reviewing Marine Gold as a voluntary respondent would
    have exceeded that presented in the typical antidumping review”)
    (relying on Grobest & I-Mei Indus. (Viet.) Co. v. United States, __
    CIT __, 
    853 F. Supp. 2d 1352
    , 1362-65 (2012) (holding that 19
    U.S.C. § 1677m(a) is rendered meaningless where Commerce applies
    this provision to deny voluntary respondent status without showing
    “that the burden of reviewing a voluntary respondent would exceed
    (footnote continued)
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                       Page 6
    challenge.11   Accordingly, the requirement for administrative
    exhaustion does not preclude consideration of Respondents’ claim.
    As to the merits of Respondents’ challenge, the
    antidumping statute provides that if it is “not practicable” for
    the agency to determine individual weighted average dumping margins
    for each known exporter and producer of the subject merchandise,
    then Commerce is authorized to limit its examination to “a
    reasonable number of exporters or producers.” 19 U.S.C. § 1677f-
    1(c)(2).   Notwithstanding this provision, Commerce is nevertheless
    required to calculate an individual weighted average dumping margin
    “for any exporter or producer not initially selected for individual
    examination under [19 U.S.C. § 1677f-1(c)(2)]” – i.e., for any
    voluntary respondent – if that exporter/producer submits to
    Commerce the information requested from exporters or producers who
    were selected for examination, if “(1) such information is so
    submitted by the date specified . . . for exporters and producers
    that were initially selected for examination . . . and (2) the
    that presented in the typical antidumping or countervailing duty
    review”)); Def.’s Resp. at 8 (arguing that the court should apply
    the exhaustion doctrine because Respondents’ case brief did not
    include the specific argument that Commerce’s reasoning in denying
    Marine Gold’s request for voluntary respondent status renders 19
    U.S.C. § 1677m meaningless).
    11
    Cf. JTEKT Corp. v. United States, 
    642 F.3d 1378
    , 1384 (Fed. Cir.
    2011) (explaining that where a litigant did not have the benefit of
    a subsequently rendered legal decision, and thus could not have
    argued on that specific basis in briefing below, the litigant on
    appeal may rely on such subsequent decisions if the decisions
    support the arguments preserved for appeal).
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                     Page 7
    number of exporters or producers who have submitted such
    information is not so large that individual examination of such
    exporters or producers would be unduly burdensome and inhibit the
    timely completion of the investigation.” 
    Id.
     at § 1677m(a).
    The “unduly burdensome” standard was recognized in a
    prior decision holding that, when considering a request for
    individual examination pursuant to 19 U.S.C. § 1677m(a), Commerce
    “cannot draw its § 1677m(a) analysis so narrowly that it mirrors
    the analysis under § 1677f-1(c)(2)” because doing so would render §
    1677m(a) meaningless. Grobest, __ CIT at __, 853 F. Supp. 2d at
    1364.   Grobest ordered Commerce to individually examine a voluntary
    respondent where the facts that Commerce put forward to support its
    conclusion that such examination would be unduly burdensome merely
    referred to “the same burdens that occur in every review.” Id. at
    1364-65; see id. at 1364 n.12 (listing factual circumstances
    proffered to support Commerce’s conclusion that examination of an
    additional respondent would present an undue burden).   Grobest held
    that to support a finding of undue burden, Commerce must “show that
    the burden of reviewing a voluntary respondent would exceed that
    presented in the typical antidumping of countervailing duty
    review.” Id. at 1365.
    Here, Commerce decided that individually examining Marine
    Gold would present an undue burden and inhibit the timely
    completion of the review based on factual circumstances very
    similar to those presented in Grobest. Compare I & D Mem. cmt. 2 at
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                      Page 8
    16-17, with Grobest, __ CIT at __, 853 F. Supp. 2d at 1364 n.12.12
    As in Grobest, “the facts that Commerce put forward to support that
    conclusion do not distinguish this case from the paradigmatic
    review of an antidumping or countervailing duty order.” Grobest, __
    CIT at __, 853 F. Supp. 2d at 1364.   Indeed, Commerce’s own
    emphasis on prior experience with conducting administrative reviews
    – comparing the expected burden of examining Marine Gold to that of
    examining mandatory respondents in prior reviews13 – suggests that
    12
    Commerce emphasized the volume of data the agency was required to
    examine; the need to issue multiple respondent-specific
    supplemental questionnaires; prior experience showing that
    examination of one of the mandatory respondents is likely to
    necessitate multiple supplemental questionnaires and extensions of
    time; the fact that one of the mandatory respondents had not been
    previously reviewed and so would necessitate extra time to review;
    and the fact that the Import Administration generally, and the
    Operations Office handling this review in particular, was
    conducting multiple concurrent reviews. See I & D Mem. cmt. 2 at
    16. This list of grievances is virtually identical to that
    rejected by the court in Grobest. See Grobest, __ CIT at __, 853 F.
    Supp. 2d at 1364 n.12. As the court explained in that case, none
    of these factual circumstances are extraordinary or suggest an
    undue burden on Commerce because they merely describe the
    administrative burden that Commerce must generally face in any
    antidumping duty administrative review. Accordingly, to permit
    Commerce to reject voluntary respondent requests on these bases
    alone would render § 1677m(a) meaningless because such factual
    circumstances are generally present in every case. See id. at 1364-
    65.
    13
    See I & D Mem. cmt. 2 at 16-17 (emphasizing the burdens of
    previously examining Marine Gold as a mandatory respondent in a
    prior administrative review, including the need for “four
    supplemental questionnaires for which [Commerce] granted eight
    extension requests,” but implicitly demonstrating the comparability
    of this burden to that of examining other respondents in prior
    proceedings, which Commerce describes as similarly involving
    multiple supplemental questionnaires and numerous deadline
    extensions).
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                      Page 9
    what Commerce has here deemed to be undue burden is merely the
    usual burden of conducting a thorough review, which is insufficient
    to satisfy § 1677m(a)’s standard for rejecting a voluntary
    respondent request. Grobest, __ CIT at __, 853 F. Supp. 2d at 1364-
    65.
    This matter is therefore remanded on the same grounds as
    those stated in Grobest. Grobest, __ CIT at __, 853 F. Supp. 2d
    at 1364-65.    On remand, Commerce must either “show that the burden
    of reviewing [Marine Gold] would exceed that presented in the
    typical antidumping or countervailing duty review,” id. at 1365, or
    else review Marine Gold as a voluntary respondent.
    II.   Denial of Antidumping Duty Export Price Adjustment
    Next, AHSTAC argues that Commerce should have reduced the
    export prices calculated in this review by the amount of
    antidumping deposits paid on the subject entries. See AHSTAC’s Br.
    at 8-24.14    Relying on 19 U.S.C. § 1677a(c)(2)(A),15 AHSTAC argues
    14
    Although AHSTAC repeatedly refers to the “final assessed
    antidumping duties” paid on entries of the subject merchandise,
    e.g., AHSTAC’s Br. at 10, this characterization is misleading
    because the subject entries have yet to be liquidated and thus the
    final antidumping duties owed on them have yet to be actually
    assessed. Cf., e.g., Sioux Honey Ass’n v. Hartford Fire Ins. Co.,
    
    672 F.3d 1041
    , 1047 (Fed. Cir. 2012) (describing the United States’
    retroactive antidumping duty assessment system, in which “cash
    deposits [are] collected upon entry [as] estimates of the duties
    that the importer will ultimately have to pay as opposed to
    payments of the actual duties”); Hoogovens Staal BV v. United
    States, 
    22 CIT 139
    , 145, 
    4 F. Supp. 2d 1213
    , 1219 (1998) (“Under
    the [antidumping] statute, final duties are assessed upon
    liquidation of all subject merchandise entered during the period of
    (footnote continued)
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                     Page 10
    that the payment of antidumping deposits on these entries
    constitutes a duty, cost, charge, or expense “incident to bringing
    the subject merchandise from the original place of shipment in the
    exporting country to the place of delivery in the United States,”
    AHSTAC’s Br. at 11 (quoting 19 U.S.C. § 1677a(c)(2)(A)), and must
    therefore be deducted from export price.   Commerce defends its
    decision not to deduct the paid deposits from the export prices
    calculated in this review by relying on its long-standing and
    judicially-affirmed statutory interpretation that antidumping duty
    deposits “are not costs, expenses, or import duties within the
    meaning of [19 U.S.C. § 1677a(c)(2)(A)].”16   As explained below,
    because Commerce’s decision not to reduce export prices by the
    amount of the antidumping deposits paid on the corresponding
    review. The uncertainty of knowing the final amount of duties due
    at the time of entry is simply an inherent part of importing
    merchandise into the United States.”) (internal quotation marks and
    citation omitted).
    15
    (“The price used to establish export price . . . shall be . . .
    reduced by . . . the amount, if any, included in such price,
    attributable to any additional costs, charges, or expenses, and
    United States import duties, which are incident to bringing the
    subject merchandise from the original place of shipment in the
    exporting country to the place of delivery in the United States
    . . . .”).
    16
    I & D Mem. cmt. 3 at 22-23 (citing, inter alia, Certain Cold-
    Rolled Carbon Steel Flat Products from Korea, 
    63 Fed. Reg. 781
    ,
    [787] (Dep’t Commerce Jan. 7, 1998) (final results of antidumping
    duty administrative review); Hoogovens Staal, 22 CIT at 146,
    
    4 F. Supp. 2d at 1220
    ; AK Steel Corp. v. United States, 
    21 CIT 1265
    , 1280, 
    988 F. Supp. 594
    , 607 (1997)).
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                    Page 11
    entries was based on a reasonable interpretation of an ambiguous
    statutory provision,17 this decision is sustained.
    AHSTAC is correct that in order to achieve a fair
    comparison between export price and normal value, the antidumping
    statute directs Commerce to make certain adjustments designed “to
    permit comparison of the two prices at a similar point in the chain
    of commerce.”18   But while it is true that the antidumping deposit
    paid on entries of subject merchandise has no corollary within the
    normal value of a foreign like product, it is not, strictly
    speaking, an additional cost included in the export price because
    it is a refundable security deposit to   ensure that the importer
    17
    Wheatland Tube Co. v. United States, 
    495 F.3d 1355
    , 1359-60 (Fed.
    Cir. 2007) (“[I]t is clear that Congress has not defined or
    explained the meaning or scope of ‘United States import duties’ as
    set forth in 19 U.S.C. § 1677a(c)(2)(A). . . . Thus, because
    Congress has not directly spoken to the precise question at issue,
    this court finds that the statute is ambiguous and proceeds to step
    two of Chevron. Under Chevron step two, . . . this court must give
    deference to [Commerce]’s interpretation of the statute . . . if
    the agency’s interpretation is reasonable.”) (internal quotation
    marks omitted) (relying on Chevron, 
    467 U.S. at 843-44
    ); see also
    AK Steel, 21 CIT at 1280 & n.12, 988 F. Supp. at 608 & n.12
    (holding that the antidumping statute is ambiguous regarding
    whether or not antidumping deposits constitute “import duties” or
    “additional costs, charges, and expenses” in the context of export
    price adjustment).
    18
    Torrington Co. v. United States, 
    68 F.3d 1347
    , 1352 (Fed. Cir.
    1995); see also Smith-Corona Grp. v. United States, 
    713 F.2d 1568
    ,
    1571-72 (Fed. Cir. 1983) (explaining that Commerce must adjust both
    normal value and export price “in an attempt to reconstruct the
    price at a specific, ‘common’ point in the chain of commerce, so
    that the value can be fairly compared on an equivalent basis”).
    For example, the export price is reduced by the cost of delivering
    the subject merchandise from the exporting country to the United
    States, 19 U.S.C. § 1677a(c)(2)(A), because this additional cost is
    not a part of normal value and so distorts the comparison.
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                     Page 12
    does not purchase its merchandise below fair value.     If upon review
    of the relevant pricing data Commerce determines that the subject
    entries were purchased at fair prices, then the importer will be
    refunded its deposit; but if the review reveals that the entries
    were obtained at prices below normal value, then the deposit may be
    forfeited and, to the extent that the deposit is exceeded by the
    actual antidumping duties owed, will require additional payment.
    19 U.S.C. § 1673f; Sioux Honey, 
    672 F.3d at 1047
    .
    As the antidumping deposit merely serves to provide an
    incentive to ensure fair export prices, rather than to burden
    importers with additional costs, Commerce’s practice of not
    reducing export price by the amount of antidumping deposits paid on
    the subject merchandise has repeatedly been upheld because making
    such an adjustment would result in double-counting.19    AHSTAC now
    argues that in fact there is no such risk of double-counting.
    AHSTAC’s Br. at 13.   As shown below, however, AHSTAC is incorrect.
    To illustrate why an antidumping deposit adjustment to
    export price would result in double-counting, consider a simple
    hypothetical involving just one arms-length transaction per year.
    19
    E.g., Hoogovens Staal, 22 CIT at 146, 
    4 F. Supp. 2d at 1220
    (upholding “Commerce’s long-standing policy and practice” of not
    treating antidumping deposits as import duties or costs); AK Steel,
    21 CIT at 1280, 988 F. Supp. at 607 (upholding Commerce’s
    explanation that reducing export prices to account for antidumping
    duties “would result in double-counting”); PQ Corp. v. United
    States, 
    11 CIT 53
    , 67, 
    652 F. Supp. 724
    , 737 (1987) (“If deposits
    of estimated antidumping duties entered into the calculation of
    present dumping margins, then those deposits would work to open up
    a margin where none otherwise exists.”).
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                      Page 13
    Assume a normal value (“NV”) (after all relevant adjustments) of
    $110.   Prior to the imposition of an antidumping duty order,
    Commerce investigates whether the merchandise is being sold in the
    United States at less than its normal value.   Assume that during
    its investigation, Commerce calculates an export price (“EP”)
    (after all relevant adjustments) of $100.   Assuming an affirmative
    injury finding by the International Trade Commission, an
    antidumping duty order is issued and an estimated duty deposit rate
    is set for the producer/exporter in question at 10 percent ((NV –
    EP) / EP = (110 – 100) / 100 = 0.1 = 10 percent).20   For each entry
    of subject merchandise from this producer/exporter made subsequent
    to the effective date of the antidumping duty order, the importer
    of record must now pay an antidumping deposit in the amount of 10
    percent of the export price.   Importantly, however, the actual
    antidumping duties owed on such entries are not calculated until
    one year following the issuance of the antidumping duty order, at
    which time (if a review is requested) the actual export prices of
    such entries are compared to contemporaneous normal values and an
    actual antidumping duty assessment rate is calculated.   If the
    review reveals that export prices have now risen to match normal
    value, then the dumping margin (and so the antidumping duty
    20
    To arrive at the weighted average dumping margins that will form
    the basis for antidumping duty assessment for each
    producer/exporter, Commerce divides its aggregate normal-to-export
    price comparisons by the aggregate export prices of the subject
    merchandise. See 
    19 U.S.C. § 1677
    (35)(B).
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                     Page 14
    assessment rate) will be zero, and the antidumping deposit will be
    returned in full (with interest).
    Continuing the hypothetical, assume that the next U.S.
    sale of subject merchandise that occurs after imposition of the
    antidumping duty order is made at an export price of $110 (after
    all relevant adjustments, but not including any adjustment for the
    antidumping deposit).   Thus the importer pays $110 for the
    merchandise, as well as a 10 percent ($11) antidumping deposit.
    Assume for the sake of simplicity that this is the only transaction
    involving the subject merchandise during the first period of
    review.   In reviewing this transaction to assess actual antidumping
    duties owed under the antidumping duty order, Commerce will compare
    the export price to the merchandise’s normal value (which remains
    at $110).   And here we come to the matter at issue.
    AHSTAC’s argument implies that Commerce should deduct
    from the export price the $11 antidumping deposit paid by the
    importer.   Under this approach, the weighted average dumping margin
    (and so the actual antidumping duty assessment rate) for this
    transaction would be (NV – EP) / EP = (110 – (110 – 11)) / 110 =
    (110 – 99) / 110 = 11/110 = 0.1 = 10 percent.   Because the duty
    assessment rate is equivalent to the antidumping deposit rate on
    the transaction, the importer would not receive any portion of its
    deposit back.   Thus, under AHSTAC’s proposed statutory
    interpretation, the importer pays a total of $121 (the $110 export
    price plus the $11 antidumping duty), even though normal value is
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                     Page 15
    only $110.    In other words, this approach would force the importer
    to pay an antidumping duty even where the importer bought at normal
    value prices.
    Under Commerce’s long-standing and judicially-approved
    practice, on the other hand, the dumping (if any) is equalized by
    the assessment of antidumping duties, but the cessation of
    purchases at dumped prices is rewarded with the return of the
    deposit.   Thus, Commerce does not reduce the (adjusted) export
    price by the amount of the importer’s deposit (which the importer
    expects to be refunded if it buys at fair value): (NV – EP) / EP =
    (110 – 110) / 110 = 0, so the deposit is refunded to the importer,
    and the importer appropriately pays only the fair price ($110
    export price plus the $11 antidumping deposit, minus the $11
    deposit refund = $110, which is equivalent to normal value).
    As this hypothetical makes clear, Commerce’s explanation
    that reducing export price by the amount of the antidumping deposit
    would result in double-counting is logical.    Reducing the export
    price by the amount of the antidumping deposit before comparing the
    export price to normal value would essentially force the importer
    to pay twice – once when paying an export price raised to normal
    value from the previously dumped price, and again when paying an
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                  Page 16
    antidumping duty notwithstanding having already paid a non-dumped
    export price.21
    AHSTAC also argues that the non-reimbursement regulation
    – pursuant to which Commerce reduces the export prices paid by
    importers whose antidumping duties are reimbursed by the producers
    or exporters of subject merchandise – provides support for its
    position. See AHSTAC’s Br. at 21-22 (relying on 19 C.F.R.
    21
    Contrary to AHSTAC’s argument, this result is unchanged by the
    circumstances presented here, where the producer/exporter also
    served as the importer who paid the antidumping deposit.
    See AHSTAC’s Br. at 10 (emphasizing that two respondents acted as
    their own importers). Just like the antidumping deposit paid by
    any other importer, the deposits at issue here will be refunded in
    the event that the administrative review reveals that normal values
    did not exceed export prices; deducting the deposits from the
    export prices prior to their comparison to normal value “would
    reduce the U.S. price – and increase the margin – artificially.”
    Hoogovens Staal, 22 CIT at 146, 
    4 F. Supp. 2d at 1220
    . Moreover,
    the distortion remains even where export prices do not rise to
    fully match normal value. Assume that in the original unfair
    pricing investigation Commerce calculated a (properly adjusted)
    normal value of $150 and a (properly adjusted) export price of
    $100, thereby setting an antidumping deposit rate at 50 percent
    ((150-100)/100). Assume that only one entry of subject merchandise
    is made prior to final antidumping duty assessment at liquidation.
    In reviewing that entry, Commerce calculates an export price of
    $120 and a normal value of $150. Without any deduction for the 50
    percent antidumping deposit, Commerce would calculate a final
    antidumping duty assessment rate for this entry at 25 percent
    ((150-120)/120), such that the importer would pay a total of $150
    ($120 export price plus $30 antidumping duty (25 percent of export
    price)), thereby exactly matching the merchandise’s normal value.
    But with a deduction to export price for the antidumping deposit,
    the assessment rate would be 75 percent ((150-(120-60))/120 =
    90/120). In this scenario, the importer would pay a total of $210
    ($120 in export price plus $90 antidumping duty (75 percent of
    export price)) even though normal value is only $150.
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                    Page 17
    § 351.402(f)(1)(i) (2012) (the “non-reimbursement regulation”).22
    But this claim is similarly unpersuasive.
    AHSTAC argues that where, as here, the producer/exporter
    also acts as the importer, the circumstances are indistinguishable
    from those leading to an export price reduction pursuant to the
    non-reimbursement regulation.23   But the non-reimbursement
    regulation exists to ensure that the antidumping duty order’s
    incentive for importers to buy at non-dumped prices is not negated
    by exporters who sell at dumped prices while removing the
    importer’s exposure to antidumping liability.24   The regulation does
    not entail, as AHSTAC suggests, treating antidumping duties as
    22
    (“In calculating the export price (or the constructed export
    price), [Commerce] will deduct the amount of any antidumping duty
    . . . which the exporter or producer: (A) Paid directly on behalf
    of the importer; or (B) Reimbursed to the importer.”).
    23
    AHSTAC’s Br. at 22 (“[O]n what grounds does Commerce distinguish
    the reimbursement situation from the undisputed facts of this case
    . . . ? The record is devoid of any answer to this question .
    . . .”).
    24
    Hoogovens Staal, 22 CIT at 143, 
    4 F. Supp. 2d at 1218
     (“The [non-
    ]reimbursement regulation provides that the calculation of U.S.
    price include an adjustment for the amount of any antidumping
    duties reimbursed or paid by the exporter. . . . Without the
    regulation, a foreign exporter or producer could assume the cost of
    antidumping duties owed and thereby nullify the effect of the
    duties in the U.S. market.”) (citations omitted). Although
    Hoogovens Staal concerned 
    19 C.F.R. § 353.26
     (1994) – the
    predecessor to the current non-reimbursement regulation, 
    19 C.F.R. § 351.402
    (f) – the substance of the regulation remained unchanged
    when the regulation was renumbered. See Antidumping Duties;
    Countervailing Duties, 
    62 Fed. Reg. 27,296
     (Dep’t Commerce May 19,
    1997) (final rule) (announcing the final renumbering).
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                    Page 18
    costs or charges to be deducted from export price to achieve a fair
    comparison.
    To the contrary, Commerce’s application of the non-
    reimbursement regulation supports the agency’s reasoning that
    making an antidumping deposit deduction to export price in the
    absence of reimbursement would result in double-counting because
    Commerce applies the non-reimbursement regulation – which requires
    an export price deduction for reimbursed duty payments – by
    effectively double-counting the dumping margin.25   It follows that
    25
    See, e.g., Nereida Trading Co. v. United States, __ CIT __, 
    683 F. Supp. 2d 1348
    , 1353 (2010) (“Because [an importer] had not filed
    a certificate of non-reimbursement . . ., Customs doubled the
    assessed duty margin . . . .”); Uruguay Round Agreements Act,
    Statement of Administrative Action, H.R. Rep. No. 103-316 (1994) at
    886, reprinted in 1994 U.S.C.C.A.N. 4040, 4211 (noting that
    Commerce’s practice in applying the non-reimbursement regulation
    “is to instruct Customs to double the duties if the importer fails
    to furnish a certificate of non-reimbursement to Customs prior to
    liquidation of entries”). To see why this is so, assume that,
    during the investigation upon which an antidumping duty order is
    based, Commerce calculated a (properly adjusted) normal value of
    $110 and a (properly adjusted) export price of $100, thereby
    setting an antidumping deposit rate of 10 percent ((110-100)/100).
    After the antidumping duty order goes into effect, the importer
    must now pay a 10 percent deposit on entries of subject
    merchandise, which will be refunded only if the importer buys at
    non-dumped prices. But now assume that the exporter promises to
    reimburse the importer for the 10 percent deposit, permitting the
    importer to continue to buy at dumped prices without threat of
    losing its deposit. Assume that only one entry of subject
    merchandise is made prior to final antidumping duty assessment at
    liquidation. In reviewing that entry, Commerce calculates an
    export price of $100 and a normal value of $110. In the absence of
    the non-reimbursement regulation, the weighted-average dumping
    margin (and so the actual antidumping duty assessment rate) for
    that entry would be 10 percent ((110-100)/100). But acting
    pursuant to the non-reimbursement regulation (based on the
    exporter’s agreement to reimburse the importer for its antidumping
    (footnote continued)
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                   Page 19
    where, as here, the circumstances do not support a finding of
    reimbursement,26 deducting the antidumping duty deposit payments
    from the export price would arbitrarily double-count the dumping
    margin.
    Therefore, because Commerce’s decision not to reduce
    export prices by the amount of antidumping deposits paid on subject
    entries was, as explained above, based on a reasonable
    interpretation of an ambiguous statutory provision, this decision
    is sustained.
    liability), Commerce deducts the reimbursed deposit (10 percent of
    100 = 10) from the export price (100 – 10 = 90), thereby
    effectively doubling the dumping margin ((110-90)/100 = 20/100 = 20
    percent). Thus, contrary to AHSTAC’s argument, Commerce’s
    application of the non-reimbursement regulation supports Commerce’s
    reasoning that, where this regulation is not applicable, deducting
    antidumping duty deposit payments from the export price would
    result in an arbitrary double-counting of the dumping margin.
    26
    As Commerce explained, the non-reimbursement regulation is
    inapplicable here because “the respondents are not reimbursing or
    paying the assessed duties on behalf of the importer – they are
    paying the duties as the importer.” I & D Mem. cmt. 3 at 24;
    see also 
    id.
     (“This position is consistent with [Commerce]’s
    uniformly-applied interpretation of 
    19 C.F.R. § 351.402
    (f)(1)(i)
    that a party cannot ‘reimburse’ itself when acting as its own
    importer of record.”) (citing Brass Sheet and Strip from Germany,
    Am. Issues & Decision Mem., A-428-602, ARP 08-09 (Oct. 28, 2010)
    (adopted in 
    75 Fed. Reg. 66,347
     (Dep’t Commerce Oct. 28, 2010)
    (amended final results of antidumping duty administrative review))
    cmt. 9; Circular Welded Non-Alloy Steel Pipe and Tube from Mexico,
    
    63 Fed. Reg. 33,041
    , 33,044 (Dep’t Commerce June 17, 1998) (final
    results of antidumping duty administrative review)); AHSTAC’s Br.
    at 21 (“AHSTAC recognizes that Commerce’s practice is not to apply
    the [non-reimbursement] regulation [when the producer/exporter acts
    as the importer of record] . . . .”).
    Consol. Court No. 12-00223                                     Page 20
    CONCLUSION
    For all of the foregoing reasons, Commerce’s Final
    Results are sustained except with regard to Commerce’s rejection of
    Marine Gold’s request for individual examination as a voluntary
    respondent.   This issue is remanded for further consideration,
    consistent with this opinion.   Commerce shall have until September
    9, 2013, to complete and file its remand results.     Plaintiffs shall
    have until September 23, 2013, to file comments.     The parties shall
    have until October 3, 2013, to file any reply.
    It is SO ORDERED.
    ____________________________
    Donald C. Pogue, Chief Judge
    Dated: August 2, 2013
    New York, NY