in Re Application of Detroit Edison Company Re Licensing Rules ( 2018 )


Menu:
  •                            STATE OF MICHIGAN
    COURT OF APPEALS
    In re Application of DETROIT EDISON
    COMPANY re Licensing Rules.
    ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESSES                                         UNPUBLISHED
    ADVOCATING TARIFF EQUITY,                                         February 8, 2018
    Appellant,
    v                                                                 No. 332605
    PSC
    MICHIGAN PUBLIC SERVICE COMMISSION,                               LC No. 00-016020
    TILDEN MINING COMPANY, LC, and EMPIRE
    IRON MINING PARTNERSHIP,
    Appellees,
    and
    DETROIT EDISON COMPANY, INDIANA
    MICHIGAN POWER COMPANY, MICHIGAN
    ELECTRIC & GAS ASSOCIATION, and
    CONSUMERS ENERGY COMPANY,
    Petitioners-Appellees.
    Before: RONAYNE KRAUSE, P.J., and FORT HOOD and O’BRIEN, JJ.
    PER CURIAM.
    Appellant, Association of Businesses Advocating Tariff Equity (ABATE), appeals as of
    right an order of the Michigan Public Service Commission (PSC) maintaining the prohibition on
    Michigan retail electric customers of regulated utilities from bidding demand responses into
    regional wholesale electric power markets. We affirm.
    I. BACKGROUND AND THE UNDERLYING PROCEEDINGS
    This case concerns the complicated relationship between the wholesale and retail electric
    markets and what rules and regulations should govern the participation of retail electric
    -1-
    customers in the wholesale market. The Federal Power Act (FPA), 16 USC 791a et seq., grants
    to the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) the authority to regulate wholesale
    electric energy transactions in interstate commerce. 16 USC 824(b). The power to regulate
    retail sales of electric energy rests with state utility commissions. 
    Id. The production,
    transmission, and sale of electric energy have, over the years, become a
    competitive interstate industry. Electricity now flows through an interconnected grid that covers
    most of the country. FERC v Electric Power Supply Ass’n, ___ US ___; 
    136 S. Ct. 760
    , 768; 
    193 L. Ed. 2d 661
    (2016). FERC has sought to ensure that wholesale electric rates remain reasonable
    by encouraging competition. To further that effort, FERC encouraged the development of
    entities known as wholesale market operators to manage regional wholesale markets. Seven
    wholesale market operators now manage the electric grid that provides much of the electric load,
    i.e., the amount of electricity used, for the country. This cooperation ensures reliable
    transmission of electricity throughout the country. Each market operator conducts an auction to
    set the wholesale price of electricity. 
    Id. In FERC
    v Electric Power Supply Ass’n, the United States Supreme Court explained the
    purpose and procedures of these auctions as follows:
    These wholesale auctions serve to balance supply and demand on a
    continuous basis, producing prices for electricity that reflect its value at given
    locations and times throughout each day. Such a real-time mechanism is needed
    because, unlike most products, electricity cannot be stored effectively. Suppliers
    must generate—every day, hour, and minute—the exact amount of power
    necessary to meet demand from the utilities and other “load-serving entities”
    (LSEs) that buy power at wholesale for resale to users. To ensure that happens,
    wholesale market operators obtain (1) orders from LSEs indicating how much
    electricity they need at various times and (2) bids from generators specifying how
    much electricity they can produce at those times and how much they will charge
    for it. Operators accept the generators’ bids in order of cost (least expensive first)
    until they satisfy the LSEs’ total demand. The price of the last unit of electricity
    purchased is then paid to every supplier whose bid was accepted, regardless of its
    actual offer, and the total cost is split among the LSEs in proportion to how much
    energy they have ordered. So, for example, suppose that at 9 a.m. on August 15
    four plants serving Washington, D.C. can each produce some amount of
    electricity for, respectively, $10/unit, $20/unit, $30/unit, and $40/unit. And
    suppose that LSEs’ demand at that time is met after the operator accepts the three
    cheapest bids. The first three generators would then all receive $30/unit. That
    amount is (think back to Econ 101) the marginal cost—i.e., the added cost of
    meeting another unit of demand—which is the price an efficient market would
    produce. See 1 A. Kahn, The Economics of Regulation: Principles and
    Institutions 65-67 (1988). FERC calls that cost (in jargon that will soon become
    oddly familiar), the locational marginal price, or LMP.
    As in any market, when wholesale buyers’ demand for electricity
    increases, the price they must pay rises correspondingly; and in those times of
    peak load, the grid’s reliability may also falter. Suppose that by 2 p.m. on August
    -2-
    15, it is 98 degrees in D.C. In every home, store, or office, people are turning the
    air conditioning up. To keep providing power to their customers, utilities and
    other LSEs must ask their market operators for more electricity. To meet that
    spike in demand, the operator will have to accept more expensive bids from
    suppliers. The operator, that is, will have to agree to the $40 bid it spurned
    before—and maybe, beyond that, to bids of $50 or $60 or $70. In such periods,
    operators often must call on extremely inefficient generators whose high costs of
    production cause them to sit idle most of the time. See Energy Primer 41-42. As
    that happens, LMP—the price paid by all LSEs to all suppliers—climbs ever
    higher. And meanwhile, the increased flow of electricity through the grid
    threatens to overload transmission lines. See 
    id., at 44.
    As every consumer
    knows, it is just when the weather is hottest and the need for air conditioning most
    acute that blackouts, brownouts, and other service problems tend to occur.
    Making matters worse, the wholesale electricity market lacks the self-
    correcting mechanism of other markets. Usually, when the price of a product
    rises, buyers naturally adjust by reducing how much they purchase. But
    consumers of electricity—and therefore the utilities and other LSEs buying power
    for them at wholesale—do not respond to price signals in that way. To use the
    economic term, demand for electricity is inelastic. That is in part because
    electricity is a necessity with few ready substitutes: When the temperature
    reaches 98 degrees, many people see no option but to switch on the AC. And still
    more: Many State regulators insulate consumers from short-term fluctuations in
    wholesale prices by insisting that LSEs set stable retail rates. See 
    id., at 41,
    43-
    44. That, one might say, short-circuits the normal rules of economic behavior.
    Even in peak periods, as costs surge in the wholesale market, consumers feel no
    pinch, and so keep running the AC as before. That means, in turn, that LSEs must
    keep buying power to send to those users—no matter that wholesale prices spiral
    out of control and increased usage risks overtaxing the grid.
    But what if there were an alternative to that scenario? Consider what
    would happen if wholesale market operators could induce consumers to refrain
    from using (and so LSEs from buying) electricity during peak periods. Whenever
    doing that costs less than adding more power, an operator could bring electricity
    supply and demand into balance at a lower price. And simultaneously, the
    operator could ease pressure on the grid, thus protecting against system failures.
    That is the idea behind the practice at issue here: Wholesale demand response, as
    it is called, pays consumers for commitments to curtail their use of power, so as to
    curb wholesale rates and prevent grid breakdowns. See 
    id., at 44-46.
    These demand response programs work through the operators’ regular
    auctions. Aggregators of multiple users of electricity, as well as large-scale users
    like factories or big-box stores, submit bids to decrease electricity consumption by
    a set amount at a set time for a set price. The wholesale market operators treat
    those offers just like bids from operators to increase supply. The operators, that
    is, rank order all the bids—both to produce and to refrain from consuming
    electricity—from least to most expensive, and then accept the lowest bids until
    -3-
    supply and demand come into equipoise. And, once again, the LSEs pick up the
    cost of all those payments. So, to return to our prior example, if a store submitted
    an offer not to use a unit of electricity at 2 p.m. on August 15 for $35, the operator
    would accept that bid before calling on the generator that offered to produce a unit
    of power for $40. That would result in a lower LMP—again, wholesale market
    price—than if the market operator could not avail itself of demand response
    pledges. See ISO/RTO Council, Harnessing the Power of Demand: How ISOs
    and RTOs Are Integrating Demand Response Into Wholesale Electricity Markets
    40-43 (2007) (estimating that, in one market, a demand response program
    reducing electricity usage by 3% in peak hours would lead to price declines of 6%
    to 12%). And it would decrease the risk of blackouts and other service problems.
    Wholesale market operators began using demand response some 15 years
    ago, soon after they assumed the role of overseeing wholesale electricity sales.
    Recognizing the value of demand response for both system reliability and
    efficient pricing, they urged FERC to allow them to implement such programs.
    See, e.g., PJM Interconnection, L.L.C., Order Accepting Tariff Sheets as
    Modified, 95 FERC ¶ 61,306 (2001), California Independent System Operator
    Corp., Order Conditionally Accepting for Filing Tariff Revisions, 91 FERC
    ¶ 61,256 (2000). And as demand response went into effect, market participants of
    many kinds came to view it—in the words of respondent Electric Power Supply
    Association (EPSA)—as an “important element[] of robust, competitive
    wholesale electricity markets.” App 94, EPSA, Comments on Proposed Rule on
    Demand Response Compensation in Organized Wholesale Energy Markets (May
    12, 2010).
    Congress added to the chorus of voices praising wholesale demand
    response. In the Energy Policy Act of 2005, 119 Stat. 594 (EPAct), it declared as
    “the policy of the United States” that such demand response “shall be
    encouraged.” §1252(f), 119 Stat. 966, 16 U.S.C. §2642 note. In particular,
    Congress directed, the deployment of “technology and devices that enable
    electricity customers to participate in . . . demand response systems shall be
    facilitated, and unnecessary barriers to demand response participation in
    energy . . . markets shall be eliminated.” 
    Ibid. [FERC, 136 S Ct
    at 768-770
    (footnotes omitted).]
    On October 17, 2008, FERC issued a rule entitled “Wholesale Competition in Regions
    with Organized Electric Markets,” 125 FERC ¶ 61,071 (2008) (Docket Nos. RM07-19-000 and
    AD07-7-000) (commonly known as “Order 719”), to promote demand response programs.
    Order 719 required the operator of a regional transmission grid, known as a regional
    transmission organization (RTO), to amend its rules to allow aggregators of retail electric
    -4-
    customers to bid demand response resources from those customers directly into the RTO’s
    wholesale market in accordance with specified criteria.1
    On August 13, 2009, Detroit Edison, Indiana Michigan Power Company, and Michigan
    Electric & Gas Association filed a joint application requesting that the PSC conduct an
    investigation to construct appropriate procedures to allow retail customers to participate in
    demand response. The applicants also requested that the PSC preclude the participation of retail
    customers in wholesale markets until it issued a ruling. In response, the PSC issued an order
    inviting comments from interested parties, and also restricted Michigan retail electric customers
    from participating in any RTO wholesale market during the pendency of the proceeding.
    In an order entered on December 2, 2010, the PSC rejected the assertion from various
    parties, including ABATE, that it lacked the jurisdiction to prohibit retail customers from
    participating in organized wholesale power markets, noting that in Order 719 and Order 719-A,
    FERC recognized the authority of a state regulating body to determine if and how retail
    customers, either directly or through ARCs, could participate in wholesale power markets.2
    On March 15, 2011, FERC issued a rule entitled “Demand Response Compensation in
    Organized Wholesale Markets,” 134 FERC ¶ 61,187 (2011) (Docket No. RM10-17), commonly
    known as “Order 745.” In this order, the FERC directed that RTOs must pay demand response
    participants the full locational marginal price (LMP) during the periods when a net benefits test
    was satisfied.
    Energy industry associations challenged Order 745 and, in FERC v Electric Power
    Supply Ass’n, 410 US App DC 103; 753 F3d 216 (2014), rev’d 
    136 S. Ct. 760
    (2016), the United
    States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia vacated Order 745. The court held that
    Order 745 violated the FPA because it invaded the right of states to regulate retail sales of
    electricity. 
    Id. at 224.
    However, in FERC v Electric Power Supply Ass’n, the United States
    Supreme Court reversed that decision and remanded the matter for further proceedings. The
    Supreme Court held that Order 745 did not violate the FPA because demand response practices
    directly affected wholesale rates for electricity. 
    FERC, 136 S. Ct. at 766-767
    . The Supreme
    Court also concluded that FERC’s order that demand response providers be compensated at the
    LMP was not arbitrary and capricious. 
    Id. at 767.
    1
    In Order 719-A, 128 FERC ¶ 61,059 (2009), FERC prohibited market operators from accepting
    bids including aggregated demand response from customers of utilities that distributed up to 4
    million megawatt-hours (MWh) of electricity during the previous year, unless the utility’s
    regulating body authorized such aggregation.
    2
    The PSC directed that within 120 days of the issuance of final FERC orders, utilities with
    electric distribution exceeding four million MWhs were to file contested cases and proposed
    tariffs related to the participation of retail customers in wholesale markets. Subsequently, the
    PSC withdrew its directive that utilities should file contested case hearings within a specified
    period, agreeing with the PSC Staff that such proceedings should not begin until all matters
    before the FERC were completed.
    -5-
    Subsequently, on March 29, 2016, the PSC issued an order maintaining the prohibition on
    Michigan retail electric customers, either individually or through aggregators, from bidding
    demand response resources into regional wholesale markets. The PSC’s order states:
    In light of the U.S. Supreme Court’s decision and the filings in this docket,
    the Commission remains unpersuaded that it should now lift the ban that was
    placed into effect by the prior orders in this docket. The following concerns were
    raised regarding aggregation of demand response resources for sale in the
    wholesale market: (1) operational issues for Michigan jurisdictional utilities, on
    both the real-time and long-term bases, especially with respect to capacity
    planning and procurement as well as emergency operations; (2) lack of
    Commission oversight of third-party aggregators; (3) the possibility that
    customers may enroll a demand response resource in more than one demand
    response program; and (4) cross-subsidization. The comments did not adequately
    address these concerns, and therefore the Commission believes the prohibition
    should remain in place. The Commission does not intend by this order to
    foreclose the possibility of third party aggregation forever, but finds that, for the
    present, the prohibition should remain in place. The Commission agrees with
    EnerNOC [a company that contracts with utilities to provide demand response
    resources] that closing this docket will provide an opportunity for meaningful
    conversations on demand response outside of a contested case. The Commission
    is also focused on addressing demand response opportunities and barriers, and
    time-of-use rates, through other proceedings, such as today’s order in Case No. U-
    17936 et al.
    THEREFORE, IT IS ORDERED that Michigan retail electric customers
    (either individually or through aggregators) of Commission jurisdictional electric
    utilities are prohibited from bidding demand response resources into regional
    transmission operator wholesale markets, and this docket is closed.
    The Commission reserves jurisdiction and may issue further orders as
    necessary.
    ABATE has claimed an appeal from the PSC’s March 29, 2016, order.
    II. STANDARD OF REVIEW
    The standard of review for PSC orders is narrow and well defined. A final order of the
    PSC must be authorized by law and be supported by competent, material, and substantial
    evidence on the whole record. Const 1963, art 6, § 28; Attorney General v Pub Serv Comm, 
    165 Mich. App. 230
    , 235; 418 NW2d 660 (1987). Pursuant to MCL 462.25, all rates, fares, charges,
    classification and joint rates, regulations, practices, and services prescribed by the PSC are
    presumed, prima facie, to be lawful and reasonable. Mich Consol Gas Co v Pub Serv Comm,
    
    389 Mich. 624
    , 635-636; 209 NW2d 210 (1973). A party aggrieved by an order of the PSC has
    the burden of proving by clear and convincing evidence that the order is unlawful or
    unreasonable. MCL 462.26(8). To establish that a PSC order is unlawful, the appellant must
    show that the PSC failed to follow a mandatory statute or abused its discretion in the exercise of
    -6-
    its judgment. In re MCI Telecom Complaint, 
    460 Mich. 396
    , 427; 596 NW2d 164 (1999). An
    order is unreasonable if it is not supported by the evidence. Associated Truck Lines, Inc v Pub
    Serv Comm, 
    377 Mich. 259
    , 279; 140 NW2d 515 (1966).
    A reviewing court gives due deference to the PSC’s administrative expertise, and is not to
    substitute its judgment for that of the PSC. Attorney General v Pub Serv Comm No 2, 237 Mich
    App 82, 88; 602 NW2d 225 (1999). We give respectful consideration to the PSC’s construction
    of a statute that the PSC is empowered to execute, and we will not overrule that construction
    absent cogent reasons. If the language of a statute is vague or obscure, the PSC’s construction
    serves as an aid to determining the legislative intent, and will be given weight if it does not
    conflict with the language of the statute or the purpose of the Legislature. However, the
    construction given to a statute by the PSC is not binding on the courts. In re Complaint of Rovas
    Against SBC Mich, 
    482 Mich. 90
    , 103-109; 754 NW2d 259 (2008). Whether the PSC exceeded
    the scope of its authority is a question of law that we review de novo. In re Complaint of
    Pelland Against Ameritech Mich, 
    254 Mich. App. 675
    , 682; 658 NW2d 849 (2003).
    III. ANALYSIS
    On appeal, ABATE argues that the PSC lacked the authority to prohibit retail electric
    customers from bidding demand response resources into RTO wholesale markets. It asserts that
    in the absence of specific authority, FERC’s Orders 719 and 745 control and allow retail
    customers or aggregators to participate in RTO wholesale markets. We disagree.
    The PSC has only the authority granted to it by statute. The grant of power must be
    specific; a doubtful power does not exist. Union Carbide Corp v Pub Serv Comm, 
    431 Mich. 135
    , 148-150; 428 NW2d 322 (1988).
    The FPA reserves to the states the authority to regulate retail electric services. Section
    824(b) of the FPA, 16 USC 824(b)(1), provides:
    The provisions of this subchapter shall apply to the transmission of
    electric energy in interstate commerce and to the sale of electric energy at
    wholesale in interstate commerce, but except as provided in paragraph (2) shall
    not apply to any other sale or deprive a State or State commission of its lawful
    authority now exercised over the exportation of hydroelectric energy which is
    transmitted across a State line. The Commission shall have jurisdiction over all
    facilities for such transmission or sale of electric energy, but shall not have
    jurisdiction, except as specifically provided in this subchapter and subchapter III
    of this chapter, over facilities used for the generation of electric energy or over
    facilities used in local distribution or only for the transmission of electric energy
    in intrastate commerce, or over facilities for the transmission of electric energy
    consumed wholly by the transmitter.
    The PSC is the relevant electric retail regulatory authority in Michigan, MCL 460.1 (establishing
    the PSC), and it is “vested with complete power and jurisdiction to regulate all public utilities,”
    and has “the power and jurisdiction to regulate all rates, fares, fees, charges, services, rules,
    conditions of service, and all other matters pertaining to the formation, operation, or direction of
    -7-
    public utilities.” MCL 460.6(1). The PSC’s jurisdiction “shall be deemed to extend to and
    include the control and regulation, including the fixing of rates and charges, of all public utilities
    within this state . . . .” MCL 460.54.
    ABATE’s essential argument is that FERC allows retail customers or aggregators to
    participate in RTO wholesale markets, and that the PSC lacks the authority to prohibit such
    participation. ABATE’s argument is without merit. In FERC v Electric Power Supply 
    Ass’n, 136 S. Ct. at 780
    , the United States Supreme Court specifically recognized that Order 745 “allows
    any State regulator to prohibit its customers from making demand response bids in the wholesale
    market.” ABATE’s argument rests on the fact that no specific statute authorizes the PSC to
    prohibit retail customers or aggregators from participating in RTO wholesale markets. However,
    the lack of a statute authorizing the PSC to take a specific action does not mandate a conclusion
    that the PSC cannot take that action. The PSC’s general ratemaking and regulatory authority has
    been recognized as encompassing the power to take specific actions. For example, in In re
    Application of Mich Consol Gas Co, 
    281 Mich. App. 545
    ; 761 NW2d 482 (2008), this Court held
    that the PSC’s general ratemaking power authorized it to approve a certain surcharge,
    notwithstanding the absence of a specific statute addressing the topic. This Court held that the
    authorization of the surcharge was within the PSC’s general ratemaking power. 
    Id. at 547-550.
    In this case, the PSC’s power to regulate service and conditions of service as set out in MCL
    460.6(1) is sufficient authority for the PSC to determine that retail electric customers or
    aggregators should be prohibited from participating in wholesale markets. The PSC did not
    exceed its statutory authority by prohibiting retail electric customers or aggregators from
    participating in demand response wholesale markets.
    ABATE also argues that the PSC denied retail customers and aggregators due process by
    precluding their participation in the wholesale market without first conducting a contested case
    hearing. We disagree.
    An administrative decision, such as a case decided by the PSC, is conducted as either a
    contested or a non-contested case. A “contested case” is defined as “a proceeding, including
    rate-making, price-fixing, and licensing, in which a determination of the legal rights, duties, or
    privileges of a named party is required by law to be made by an agency after an opportunity for
    an evidentiary hearing.” MCL 24.203(3). A non-contested case is any determination that does
    not fall within this definition. Mich Ass’n of Home Builders v Dep’t of Labor & Economic
    Growth Dir, 
    481 Mich. 496
    , 498; 750 NW2d 593 (2008).
    This proceeding began in August 2009 when Detroit Edison, Indiana Michigan Power
    Company, and Michigan Electric & Gas Association filed an application requesting that the PSC
    investigate rules and regulations regarding the participation of retail electric customers in the
    wholesale market, as recently authorized by Order 719, and make appropriate determinations
    regarding that participation. The application specifically requested that during the pendency of
    the proceeding the PSC preclude retail customers from participating in the wholesale market.
    Significantly, the application did not seek a contested case hearing in this matter.
    This matter was not a contested case as that term is defined in MCL 24.203(3) from the
    outset, but rather was a vehicle to explore the issue of retail electric customer participation in the
    -8-
    wholesale markets. The matter was not designed to determine rates or any legal duties of any
    party, and due process did not require the holding of a contested case.
    Finally, ABATE argues that the PSC’s decision to continue the prohibition on retail
    electric customer participation in the wholesale market was arbitrary and capricious because it
    lacked reasoned analysis. We disagree.3
    This Court has observed that the terms “arbitrary” and “capricious” are defined as
    follows:
    Arbitrary means fixed or arrived at through an exercise of will or by caprice,
    without consideration or adjustment with reference to principles, circumstances or
    significance, and capricious means apt to change suddenly, freakish or whimsical.
    [Mich Farm Bureau v Dep’t of Environmental Quality, 
    292 Mich. App. 106
    , 141;
    807 NW2d 866 (2011) (quotation marks and citation omitted).]
    ABATE’s argument that the PSC’s order precluding retail customers from participating
    in wholesale markets is arbitrary and capricious because it was not based on evidence or
    reasoning is not supported by the record. The PSC opened this case in response to an
    application. The PSC solicited and received voluminous comments from many parties, including
    ABATE. The PSC considered those comments, along with the FERC’s Orders 719 and 745, and
    the United States Supreme Court’s decision in FERC v Electric Power Supply Ass’n before
    making a final determination. The PSC listed four concerns, which it concluded were not
    adequately addressed, and so left the ban on retail participation in the wholesale market in place
    for the present time. The PSC specifically stated that it did not intend by this order to foreclose
    forever the possibility of retail participation in the wholesale market, but concluded that for the
    present its original prohibition should remain effective. The PSC provided a reasoned
    explanation for its decision. The fact that ABATE disagrees with the PSC’s decision does not
    make the decision arbitrary or capricious. Mich Farm 
    Bureau, 292 Mich. App. at 141
    .
    Affirmed.
    /s/ Amy Ronayne Krause
    /s/ Karen M. Fort Hood
    /s/ Colleen A. O'Brien
    3
    The parties dispute whether the arbitrary and capricious standard applies in this case. Because
    this does not affect the outcome of our decision, we assume for purposes of this appeal that it
    applies.
    -9-