American President Lines, LLC v. Matson, Inc. ( 2022 )


Menu:
  •                               UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
    AMERICAN PRESIDENT LINES, LLC
    et al.,
    Plaintiffs,
    v.                       Case No. 21-cv-02040 (CRC)
    MATSON, INC. et al.,
    Defendants.
    MEMORANDUM OPINION
    Two groups of companies offer container shipping services between the U.S. mainland
    and Guam: plaintiff American President Lines (“APL”) and defendant Matson. In this Sherman
    Act case, APL, the newcomer to the market, accuses Matson, the incumbent, of monopolizing,
    and attempting to monopolize, the mainland-to-Guam route. Matson has mainly done so, APL
    claims, by bullying would-be APL customers and unfairly leveraging its dominant position in the
    busier route between the U.S. mainland and Hawaiʻi, which federal law prevents APL from
    servicing because it is foreign owned. Matson moves to dismiss the case.
    Finding that APL has adequately alleged an injury to competition, a relevant market,
    monopoly power, and at least some exclusionary conduct on Matson’s part, the Court will permit
    APL’s claims to proceed to discovery, with certain limitations. The Court will, however, dismiss
    the Matson group’s parent company, Matson, Inc., as a defendant because APL has not attributed
    any illegal conduct specifically to it.
    I.    Background1
    The plaintiffs in this case are a trio of related shipping companies, American President
    Lines, LLC, APL Maritime, Ltd., and APL Marine Services, Ltd. (collectively, “APL”). As
    relevant here, APL manages and operates a fleet of ocean vessels that transport container cargo
    from the west coast of the United States to Guam. Am. Compl. ¶¶ 16–18, ECF No. 10. The only
    other fleet offering U.S.-to-Guam container shipping services is owned or operated by a
    competing trio of companies—the Matson defendants, consisting of Matson, Inc., Matson
    Navigation Company, Inc., and Matson Logistics, Inc. (collectively, “Matson”). Id. ¶¶ 19–21,
    35. Matson also transports container cargo from the mainland U.S. to Hawaiʻi. Id. ¶ 38.
    A. Statutory and Regulatory Background
    Before delving further into the details of the relevant players and markets, a bit of
    statutory and regulatory background is in order. A federal statute called the Jones Act governs
    who may operate trans-ocean cargo container vessels between U.S. ports. Subject to certain
    exceptions, the Act permits only American-made and -owned container vessels, manned by an
    American crew, to transport cargo between any two destinations in the United States. 
    46 U.S.C. § 55102
    (b); see also 
    id.
     §§ 12112, 50101(a). As a result, only Jones Act vessels may transport
    cargo between the continental U.S. and Hawaiʻi. Am. Compl. ¶ 27. According to APL’s
    amended complaint, only two companies operate Jones Act vessels that service Hawaiʻi: Matson
    (which APL says controls “at least 70%” of the mainland U.S.-to-Hawaiʻi market) and The
    Pasha Group (which controls the remaining 30-or-so percent). Id. ¶ 38.
    1
    The Court draws much of this background from the allegations in APL’s Amended
    Complaint, which the Court must accept as true at this stage of the case. Matson no doubt
    disputes many of the allegations.
    2
    Crucially here, however, the Jones Act exempts from its requirements vessels carrying
    cargo shipments between the U.S. and Guam. See 
    46 U.S.C. § 12111
    (b). Those vessels still
    must be U.S.-flagged, meaning they must be registered in the United States, but they do not have
    to be U.S.-owned. 
    Id.
     § 12111(a), (b); id. § 12103; Am. Compl. ¶ 28. APL, which is foreign-
    owned, first secured approval to operate a U.S.-flag vessel with service to Guam in December
    2015, Am. Compl. ¶¶ 3, 33, and thereafter began offering services on a fortnightly basis. Id.
    ¶ 33. In 2016, APL added a second U.S.-flagged vessel, which allowed it to expand its Guam
    service to weekly routes. Id.
    APL obtained approval of these vessels from the U.S. Maritime Administration as part of
    the Maritime Security Program (“MSP”). Am. Compl. ¶ 3. That program aims to maintain “a
    fleet of active, commercially viable militarily useful, privately owned vessels to meet national
    defense and other security” needs. See 
    46 U.S.C. § 53102
    (a). In exchange for assisting the U.S.
    in times of war or other emergencies, the government makes multi-million-dollar payments to
    owners and operators of MSP vessels. See Am. Compl. ¶ 32; 
    46 U.S.C. § 53106
    (a); see
    generally 
    id.
     §§ 53101–53111, 53101(2), 53101, 53107. Historically, all MSP vessels could
    carry cargo between the U.S. and Guam. Am. Compl. ¶ 32. That was until Congress inserted a
    provision into the 2018 National Defense Authorization Act (“NDAA”) barring MSP vessels
    from servicing Guam, which APL attributes to Matson’s “aggressive lobbying efforts.” Id. ¶ 34.
    The change in law eliminated the ability of U.S.-flag vessels enrolled in the MSP to transport
    cargo between the U.S. and its territories, including Guam, except for those vessels already
    operating under the MSP prior to the 2018 NDAA’s enactment. Id.; see 
    46 U.S.C. § 53105
    (a).
    3
    As a result of these laws, only APL’s two U.S.-flag ships in the MSP and Matson’s Jones
    Act vessels currently provide container cargo transportation services between the U.S. and
    Guam. Am. Compl. ¶ 35.
    B. The Alleged Markets and Conduct at Issue
    That legal backdrop frames the alleged markets in the case. The amended complaint
    identifies two primary geographic markets: container shipping services between (1) the U.S.
    mainland and Guam and (2) the U.S. mainland and Hawaiʻi. Am. Compl. ¶ 37. APL further
    alleges the existence of smaller geographic submarkets “consisting of each departure-destination
    route” between these locations, id.; for instance, Oakland to Guam is a proposed submarket, as is
    Seattle to Hawaiʻi. 
    Id.
     APL alleges that “[m]ost if not all container cargo” shipped on the U.S.-
    to-Guam and U.S.-to-Hawaiʻi routes leave from ports in Los Angeles, Oakland, or Seattle. 
    Id. ¶ 91
    . It appears, however, that APL does not service the Seattle-to-Guam route, 
    id.
     ¶ 51 n.6; its
    vessels call on Guam only from L.A. or Oakland. 
    Id. ¶¶ 39
    , 51 n.6. APL also does not compete
    along the U.S.-Hawaiʻi route, which according to APL is “five to six times larger” than the U.S.-
    Guam trade. 
    Id. ¶ 43
    .
    The product (or really, service) market at issue is “container cargo shipping services,”
    Am. Compl. ¶ 36, and APL identifies at least three distinct product-based submarkets for such
    cargo: “frozen” containers, “dry” containers, and “chilled” or refrigerated containers. Am.
    Compl. ¶¶ 51 n.6, 80. Although the amended complaint does not make clear what goods or
    products are shipped in each type of container, Matson explains (and APL does not contest) that
    chilled containers carry fresh food. See Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 1, 22–24. APL apparently has
    never competed in the chilled-container submarket because of its “transit time from the U.S.
    West Coast to Guam.” Am. Compl. ¶ 51 n.6. But it does transport frozen and dry cargo
    4
    containers on the U.S.-Guam route. 
    Id.
     APL explains that “[s]hipping containers are standard in
    size,” so most vessels can carry any of these containers, whether frozen, dry, or chilled. 
    Id. ¶ 81
    .
    APL alleges that Matson achieved a monopoly in the cargo container shipping market
    between the U.S. and Guam in 2011, when it acquired “its only existing competitor, Horizon
    Lines, Inc.” Am. Compl. ¶ 2. APL alleges that Matson then jacked up its rates to the detriment
    of shippers and residents of Guam. 
    Id.
     Meanwhile, Matson has also remained dominant along
    the U.S.-to-Hawaiʻi route. APL asserts that, since 2015–2016, Matson’s share of the market on
    that route has been “at least 70%,” with the only other competitor being The Pasha Group. 
    Id. ¶ 38
    .
    As noted, in December 2015, APL entered the U.S.-Guam market with fortnightly service
    from its Oakland and L.A. ports. 
    Id. ¶ 39
    . APL alleges that, since its entry, Matson has
    maintained “at least 70% of the container cargo shipping services between the United States and
    Guam,” based on overall volume. 
    Id. ¶¶ 38, 67
    .
    In response to its market entry, APL alleges that Matson began an onslaught of
    anticompetitive conduct—what Matson’s CEO colorfully called “an ‘axe fight.’” See Am.
    Compl. ¶ 4. APL trains much of its fire at Matson’s customer loyalty program. Under that
    program, shippers receive 25% discounts on both the Guam and Hawaiʻi routes if they use
    Matson for 90% of their shipments on both routes. 
    Id. ¶ 41
    . Or, if customers use Matson for
    90% of their shipments on one of those routes, they receive a 20% discount on that route. 
    Id.
    The discounts apply to the “first dollar,” meaning customers risk losing the discount over their
    entire shipments if they fail to meet the threshold by even a small amount. Id.; Pls.’ Opp’n at 26.
    APL further alleges that when customers nonetheless used APL, Matson notified them that they
    would lose the rates given “to loyal Matson shippers.” 
    Id. ¶ 44
    . The amended complaint also
    5
    alleges “on information and belief” that Matson used “tying arrangements” conditioning its U.S.-
    to-Hawaiʻi favorable shipping terms “on shippers eliminating or drastically curtailing their Guam
    dealings with APL.” 
    Id.
     ¶¶ 49–51. Because customers ship much larger volumes along the
    Hawaiʻi route, APL says, they cannot pass up these discounts or “economically or reasonably use
    APL services” along the Guam route. 
    Id. ¶ 43
    .
    APL further asserts that Matson threatened, boycotted, and punished shippers to steer
    them away from doing business with APL. See, e.g., Am. Compl. ¶ 9 (“Matson threatened to
    impose disfavored rates and treatment on shippers to both Hawaiʻi and Guam if they gave cargo
    to APL in the U.S./Guam markets.”); 
    Id. ¶ 49
     (Matson “conditions the availability of shipping
    services in the U.S./Hawai[ʻ]i market[], or discounts, rebates, and/or other favorable shipping
    terms in those markets, on shippers eliminating or drastically curtailing their Guam dealings with
    APL”). APL accuses Matson of retaliating against it directly as well, after APL enhanced its
    services in Guam. 
    Id.
     ¶¶ 58–62. APL alleges that Matson “precipitously” terminated an
    agreement between the two companies relating to APL’s use of Matson vessels to service Asian
    markets from Alaska. 
    Id. ¶ 58
    . When APL found another carrier, Matson allegedly refused to
    allow that carrier to use a Matson-leased terminal to ship APL containers. 
    Id.
     ¶¶ 58–59. And in
    a purported effort to put “an artificial limit on APL’s operation and growth” in the U.S.-Guam
    trade, 
    id. ¶ 64
    , APL says that Matson offered it container cargo slots on Matson vessels, but only
    “if APL would stop calling Guam with its own vessels.” 
    Id. ¶ 63
    .
    As APL sees it, Matson did all this to maintain its monopoly power in both the U.S.-
    Guam and U.S.-Hawaiʻi markets. Matson views things differently, of course, defending its
    actions as “the very definition of competition.” Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 1.
    6
    C. Procedural Background
    The companies are now competitors in court. APL filed suit in July 2021 and amended
    its complaint in September 2021. The amended complaint advances monopoly and attempted-
    monopoly claims under section 2 of the Sherman Act and seeks an injunction under section 16 of
    the Clayton Act. Matson has moved to dismiss the complaint for failure to state a claim under
    Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6). Additionally, Matson filed a Request for Judicial
    Notice, along with a slew of exhibits, which APL largely opposed. See ECF Nos. 16, 19. APL
    countered with a motion to strike certain portions of Matson’s reply brief which Matson
    opposed. See ECF Nos. 23, 24. The Court held a hearing on this array of motions, focusing on
    the motion to dismiss. Most recently, APL filed motion for leave to file a supplemental brief in
    opposition to Matson’s Motion to Dismiss which Matson also opposed. See ECF Nos. 29, 30.
    II.   Legal Standards
    “To survive a motion to dismiss [under Rule 12(b)(6)], a complaint must contain
    sufficient factual matter, accepted as true, to ‘state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.’”
    Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 
    556 U.S. 662
    , 678 (2009) (quoting Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 
    550 U.S. 544
    ,
    570 (2007)). A claim is plausible “when the plaintiff pleads factual content that allows the court
    to draw the reasonable inference that the defendant is liable for the misconduct alleged.” 
    Id.
     A
    court “must treat the complaint’s factual allegations as true and must grant plaintiff the benefit of
    all inferences that can be derived from the facts alleged.” Sparrow v. United Air Lines, Inc., 
    216 F.3d 1111
    , 1113 (D.C. Cir. 2000) (cleaned up). Under Rule 12(b)(6), “a court may ordinarily
    consider only ‘the facts alleged in the complaint, documents attached as exhibits or incorporated
    by reference in the complaint[,] and matters about which the Court may take judicial notice.’”
    7
    Sandoval v. U.S. Dep’t of Justice, 
    322 F. Supp. 3d 101
    , 104 (D.D.C. 2018) (Cooper, J.) (citation
    omitted).
    III. Analysis
    A. Monopolization Claim
    APL alleges that Matson has maintained a monopoly in the container cargo shipping
    market along U.S.-to-Guam shipping routes in violation of section 2 of the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 2
    , and it seeks an injunction under section 16 of the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 26
    ,
    against Matson’s alleged anticompetitive conduct. A monopolization offense in violation of
    section 2 requires “(1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and (2) the
    willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as
    a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.” United States v.
    Microsoft Corp., 
    253 F.3d 34
    , 50 (D.C. Cir. 2001). In other words, a section 2 monopolization
    claim requires both monopoly power and “anticompetitive” or “exclusionary conduct.” 
    Id. at 58
    .
    Matson mounts several lines of attack against the amended complaint. It argues first that
    APL has failed to satisfy threshold Sherman Act requirements concerning antitrust injury, market
    definition, and monopoly power. It then contends that APL has failed to plausibly allege that
    Matson has engaged in anticompetitive conduct. The Court will begin with the threshold issues
    before turning to Matson’s purported conduct.
    1.     Threshold Issues
    Matson contends that the amended complaint fails to allege antitrust injury, a properly
    defined market, and monopoly power. The Court disagrees on all three counts.
    8
    a. Antitrust Injury
    Alleging an “antitrust injury” is “[t]he first prerequisite” of bringing a private antitrust
    action. See Adams v. Pan Am. World Airways, Inc., 
    828 F.2d 24
    , 26 (D.C. Cir. 1987). An
    antitrust injury is an “injury of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows
    from that which makes defendants’ acts unlawful.” Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat,
    Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 489 (1977). “The antitrust laws . . . were enacted for ‘the protection of
    competition not competitors.’” 
    Id. at 488
     (1977) (quoting Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 320 (1962)). Thus, “a civil antitrust plaintiff bears the burden of proving that the
    defendant’s action targeted, or had an actual adverse effect on, competition as a whole in the
    relevant market.” Gross v. Wright, 
    185 F. Supp. 3d 39
    , 49 (D.D.C. 2016) (Cooper, J.) (cleaned
    up). Typical anticompetitive effects “include, but are not limited to, reduction of output, increase
    in price, or deterioration in quality.” See 2301 M Cinema LLC v. Silver Cinemas Acquisition
    Co., 
    342 F. Supp. 3d 126
    , 137 (D.D.C. 2018) (citation omitted). APL alleges those same injuries
    here.
    According to the complaint, Matson’s anticompetitive behavior forecloses APL—
    Matson’s sole competitor—from parts of the U.S.-Guam market, depriving shipping customers
    of the benefits of competition. Am. Compl. ¶ 13 (“Matson’s conduct has not only harmed APL,
    it also has caused substantial harm to the competitive process as well as to consumers of
    container cargo shipping services who have been deprived of the benefits of competition.”).
    Substantial market foreclosure, generally speaking, is a recognized antitrust injury. See 2A
    Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law, ¶ 348(d)(3) (5th ed. 2021) (describing
    how illegal exclusionary conduct can “unduly ‘foreclose’ rival suppliers from the market and
    ultimately weaken them—to the detriment of competition.”).
    9
    Specifically here, APL alleges that Matson has forced some shippers to accept Matson’s
    more expensive shipping services on the U.S.-Guam route or risk Matson imposing unfavorable
    rates and terms if a customer chooses to ship any cargo with APL. Am. Compl. ¶ 9 (“Matson
    threatened to impose disfavored rates and treatment on shippers to both Hawaiʻi and Guam if
    they gave container cargo to APL in the U.S./Guam markets.”); 
    id. ¶ 10
     (“Matson refused to
    promise on-time deliveries for shippers that booked cargo with APL.”); 
    id. ¶ 45
     (“[O]ne of the
    world’s largest automobile manufacturers rejected APL’s offer of a lower rate and awarded its
    Guam container cargo to Matson because it threatened the shipper’s other cargo to Hawaiʻi with
    higher rates and unfavorable service.”). And in some instances, Matson allegedly “conditions
    the availability of shipping services in the U.S./Hawai[ʻ]i market[] . . . on shippers eliminating or
    drastically curtailing their Guam dealings with APL.” 
    Id. ¶ 49
    .
    These allegations implicate quintessential antitrust injuries. Taking APL’s claims as true,
    shipping customers face reduced output (i.e., fewer shipping choices), increased prices, and
    diminished quality of service compared to a market in which APL could fully compete absent
    Matson’s alleged conduct. See 2301 M Cinema LLC, 342 F. Supp. 3d at 137 (identifying
    reduced output, increased price, and diminished quality as antitrust injuries). While APL does
    not provide much detail about the diminished quality or increased prices that customers have
    experienced in retaliation for shipping with APL, the complaint plausibly alleges that a shipping
    customer that would prefer to ship with Matson in Hawaiʻi, and APL in Guam, would be
    deterred from doing so by Matson’s alleged conduct. And forcing consumers to make decisions
    on criteria other than the merits harms competition. See Ameral v. Connell, 
    102 F.3d 1494
    , 1509
    (9th Cir. 1996) (“Another form of antitrust injury is ‘[c]oercive activity that prevents its victims
    10
    from making free choices between market alternatives.’” (quoting Associated Gen. Contractors
    v. Cal. State Council of Carpenters, 
    459 U.S. 519
    , 528 (1983))).
    Matson argues that there can be no antitrust injury because the lower prices from its
    loyalty discounts benefit consumers. Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 14–16. But even if the Court were
    to accept that premise, APL’s allegations of threats and retaliation would still state a potential
    antitrust injury. If customers would prefer to ship with APL but instead ship with Matson to
    avoid retaliation in the form of higher prices or limited services on Hawaiʻi routes, competition
    plausibly has been harmed. The allegations of diminished or eliminated services—such as
    restricting access to Matson’s Hawaiʻi route for customers that ship with APL to Guam—are
    sufficient to constitute an antitrust injury regardless of pricing.
    Matson retorts that “[n]owhere has APL alleged that Matson’s purported conduct has led
    to slower deliveries or otherwise diminished service.” Defs.’ Reply at 4. Perhaps. But APL has
    alleged that Matson “threatened customers of container cargo shipping between the United
    States and Guam with higher rates and unfavorable service on Hawai[ʻ]i and Guam shipments, if
    cargo to Guam were awarded to APL.” Am. Compl. ¶ 45 (emphasis added). This is the crux of
    APL’s foreclosure allegation. To the extent Matson disputes the accuracy of those allegations,
    that raises a factual dispute not fit for resolution on a motion to dismiss.
    Reading the complaint in its most favorable light, as required at this stage, APL has
    sufficiently alleged antitrust injury.
    b. Market Definition
    Another threshold requirement for a valid antitrust claim is a properly defined antitrust
    market. See Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. & Chem. Corp., 
    382 U.S. 172
    , 177
    (1965) (“Without a definition of [the relevant] market there is no way to measure [Defendant’s]
    11
    ability to lessen or destroy competition.”). At its core, an antitrust market is “the area of
    effective competition.” Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 
    138 S. Ct. 2274
    , 2285 (2018) (citation
    omitted). To successfully plead an antitrust market, a plaintiff must allege both a relevant
    product market and a relevant geographic market. Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 324 (1962); FTC v. Facebook, Inc., 
    560 F. Supp. 3d 1
    , 13 (D.D.C. 2021). Those markets
    should include “all products reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purpose[].”
    Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 52
     (cleaned up).
    Defining a market often “involves inquiry into economic realities and industry practice.”
    Nat’l Aviation Trades Ass’n v. C.A.B., 
    420 F.2d 209
    , 213–14 (D.C. Cir. 1969) (citing Brown
    Shoe, 
    370 U.S. at 325
    ). Thus, market definition is predominantly a factual rather than a legal
    inquiry. Facebook, Inc., 560 F. Supp. 3d. at 13 (citing Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Off. Sol., 
    513 F.3d 1038
    , 1045 (9th Cir. 2008)). For this reason, antitrust complaints generally are dismissed
    on market definition grounds only if they are “glaringly deficient” and dismissals on such
    grounds are “relatively rare.” 
    Id.
     at 16–17 (quoting E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. v. Kolon
    Indus., Inc., 
    637 F.3d 435
    , 444 (4th Cir. 2011)). Against this headwind, Matson asserts that
    APL’s defined markets are deficient as a matter of law. Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 17–21. The
    Court disagrees.
    APL alleges two relevant markets: “container cargo shipping services” between the
    mainland U.S. and Guam and between the mainland U.S. and Hawaiʻi.2 Am. Compl. ¶¶ 36–37.
    2
    As the Court reads the complaint, APL describes the U.S.-Guam market as the only
    market where it is foreclosed from competition by Matson’s conduct for purposes of its
    monopolization and attempted monopolization claims. By contrast, the complaint appears to
    define the U.S.-Hawaiʻi market (in which APL cannot compete for other reasons) only to
    contextualize its allegations that Matson leverages its power in that market to coerce customers
    in the U.S.-Guam market.
    12
    In support of its product market definition, APL alleges that “other forms of shipping are not
    reasonably interchangeable with container cargo shipping because they are either far more
    expensive (e.g., airlines), slower and limited in range (e.g., barges), or physically incapable of
    transporting a range of goods (e.g., tankers).” 
    Id.
     ¶¶ 80–84 (referencing industry practice,
    government regulations, and prior conduct in the market to support the proposition that
    “purchasers of container cargo shipping would not respond to even a large price increase for
    these services by switching their cargo to other potential providers of trans-ocean cargo shipping
    such as airliners, barges, or tankers”). In support of its geographic market definitions, APL
    explains that government regulators and industry participants treat U.S.-Guam and U.S.-Hawaiʻi
    as two distinct shipping routes. 
    Id.
     ¶¶ 87–89 (“For customers moving cargo from the United
    States to Guam or Hawai[ʻ]i, other geographic originations or destinations are not reasonably
    interchangeable, and customers would not substitute other originations or destinations in
    response to even large price increases for shipping services [on those routes].”). These product
    and geographic market allegations are sufficient to plead the boundaries of relevant competition,
    particularly when reviewed under the lenient standard for market definition at this stage.
    Matson contends that APL’s inclusion of “other purported geographic markets” is fatal to
    the complaint because “APL’s inability to even try to define a single market is enough reason to
    reject its claims outright.” Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 18 (emphasis in original). Not so. First, APL
    defines the relevant market in the very first paragraph of its complaint as container cargo
    shipping services between the mainland United States and Guam, and APL’s counsel reaffirmed
    this market definition at oral argument. Am. Compl. ¶ 1; Tr. of Oral Arg. at 22. Second, while it
    is true that APL also alleges narrower markets based on the kind of container shipped (chilled,
    frozen, or dry) and ports of departure (Seattle, Los Angeles, or Oakland), Am. Compl. ¶¶ 85, 91,
    13
    the inclusion of these market segments does not sink the complaint because antitrust markets can
    and often do include submarkets. See Brown Shoe, 
    370 U.S. at 325
     (“[W]ithin this broad
    market, well-defined submarkets may exist which, in themselves, constitute product markets for
    antitrust purposes.”); Oxbow Carbon & Mins. LLC v. Union Pac. R.R. Co., 
    81 F. Supp. 3d 1
    , 10
    (D.D.C. 2015) (rejecting arguments concerning inconsistent market definitions because
    “defendants fail[ed] to acknowledge that a relevant market may include cognizable submarkets
    which themselves may constitute the appropriate market for antirust analysis” (cleaned up)). At
    this stage, the Court finds no inconsistency in alleging that there is a market for cargo shipping
    from the U.S. to Guam and also that some customers may not find every port on the west coast to
    be a viable substitute for their shipping needs. Whether the alleged markets, including the
    submarkets, can be supported by economic analysis is a factual question to be answered after
    discovery. For now, Matson has not shown APL’s market definitions to be “glaringly deficient”
    as a matter of law.3
    c. Monopoly Power
    A final threshold element of a monopolization claim is that the defendant has monopoly
    power, meaning sufficient power to “control prices or exclude competition.” Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 51
     (quoting United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 
    351 U.S. 377
    , 391 (1956)).
    To allege monopoly power, a plaintiff can allege either (1) direct evidence that the defendant
    exerts control in the market or (2) that the defendant possesses a dominant share of the relevant
    3
    The Court analyzes APL’s monopoly-power and anticompetitive-conduct allegations in
    the context of the broadest alleged market: container shipping from the U.S to Guam. Because
    the complaint sufficiently alleges anticompetitive conduct in that broadest market, the Court will
    wait to assess the validity and relevance of APL’s narrower markets until further development of
    the factual record.
    14
    market that is protected by entry barriers. Facebook, Inc., 560 F. Supp. 3d at 12–13 (citing
    Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 51
    ). APL alleges both. Because the Court finds sufficient APL’s
    allegations that Matson has a dominant share of the relevant market, it need not assess APL’s
    market-control allegations.
    “Courts generally require a 65% market share to establish a prima facie case of market
    power.” Image Tech. Servs., Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 
    125 F.3d 1195
    , 1206 (9th Cir. 1997)
    (citing Am. Tobacco Co. v. United States, 
    328 U.S. 781
    , 797 (1946)). In addition, plaintiffs
    must allege entry barriers that “prevent new rivals from timely responding to an increase in price
    above the competitive level.” Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 51
    . Barriers to entry are forces that prevent
    a market from “self-correcting,” including “entrenched buyer preferences, high capital entry
    costs and economies of scale.” Image Tech. Servs., 125 F.3d at 1208 (quotation omitted); see
    also ZF Meritor, LLC v. Eaton Corp., 
    696 F.3d 254
    , 284 (3d Cir. 2012) (describing a dominant
    firm as “a barrier to entry”).
    APL alleges that Matson has more than 70% of the overall shipping container volume in
    the U.S.-Guam market. Am. Compl. ¶¶ 67–68. It further claims that Matson’s market position
    is preserved by regulatory barriers, substantial costs, and Matson’s own anticompetitive
    campaign to foreclose competition. 
    Id.
     ¶¶ 69–70 (identifying the Jones Act, Maritime Security
    Program, “high multi-million dollar costs of purchasing and maintaining an ocean container
    transport fleet,” “high ratio of fixed to variable costs,” and Matson’s anticompetitive conduct as
    barriers to entry). By alleging that Matson has sufficient power in the relevant market and
    benefits from various market forces which preserve its position, APL has met its burden of
    plausibly alleging monopoly power.
    15
    Matson contests the sufficiency of APL’s monopoly power allegations on several
    grounds, but none are availing. First, Matson alleges that APL has offered only “bare assertions”
    of monopoly power, citing several cases where claims were dismissed for failing to adequately
    allege monopoly power. Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 21–22. But Matson’s cases are not analogous,
    as those plaintiffs provided little or no factual support for their monopoly power claims. In
    Syncsort Inc. v. Sequential Software, Inc., for example, the complaint merely alleged that the
    defendant “controls the majority of the [market],” which the court found was too cursory to
    support possession of monopoly power. 
    50 F. Supp. 2d 318
    , 330 (D.N.J. 1999). Likewise in
    Korea Kumho Petrochemical v. Flexsys Am. LP, the plaintiff offered no factual support for its
    assertions of market power. No. 07-1057, 
    2008 WL 686834
    , at *9 (N.D. Cal. Mar. 11, 2008)
    (“Although Plaintiff need not necessarily quantify Flexsys’ market share with precision, Plaintiff
    must assert some facts in support of its assertions of market power that suggest those assertions
    are plausible. Plaintiff has not done so.” (emphasis in original)). Even Matson’s best case, FTC
    v. Facebook, involved far less detailed allegations than APL offers here. 560 F. Supp. 3d at 17.
    There, the court rejected the FTC’s bare assertions of monopoly power in an “unusual” market,
    expressing doubt as to what was being measured for the purposes of calculating market share or
    who else was competing in the market. Id. at 17–19. Here, APL has described an easily
    comprehensible market in which it is one of the two participants and has estimated market shares
    for each competitor based on shipping volume. Am. Compl. ¶¶ 35, 67. APL also alleges facts to
    explain how Matson came to possess its dominant position in the market and various barriers to
    16
    entry that preserve that position. Id. at ¶¶ 69–70. These allegations plausibly allege monopoly
    power in a defined market.4
    Next, Matson argues that APL cannot show monopoly power because there are portions
    of the relevant market in which APL does not compete. Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 22–23. The crux
    of Matson’s argument, as the Court understands it, is that APL has chosen not to compete in
    certain segments of the relevant market and thus the only barrier to entry preventing APL from
    contesting Matson’s market dominance is APL itself. Id. Matson grounds its argument in the
    Ninth Circuit’s requirement that an antitrust plaintiff “must show that new rivals are barred from
    entering the market and show that existing competitors lack the capacity to expand their output
    to challenge the predator’s high price” to allege barriers to entry sufficient to preserve monopoly
    power. Rebel Oil Co. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 
    51 F.3d 1421
    , 1439 (9th Cir. 1995) (citation
    omitted).5
    Matson is correct that a competitor’s ability or inability to expand its capacity is a
    relevant inquiry when analyzing barriers to entry. But APL has alleged various market-based
    barriers that could be plausibly read to restrict its own expansion, including “transit time from
    the U.S. West Coast to Guam,” high investment costs, government regulation, and Matson’s
    4
    Matson correctly observes that APL’s references to a “contestable” submarket—a
    market comprised of only the geographic and product submarkets in which APL actively
    competes—creates confusion as to which defined market the Court should analyze for market
    power and anticompetitive effects (or whether such a market is properly defined). Am. Compl.
    ¶¶ 51 n.6. But again, because the Court sustains APL’s claims as to the broadest market of
    container shipping between US-Guam, any contentions regarding this purported submarket do
    not doom the amended complaint.
    5
    Many courts have referenced the Ninth Circuit’s detailed discussion of barriers to entry
    in Rebel Oil, including the D.C. Circuit in Microsoft. 
    253 F.3d at 51
    .
    17
    efforts to foreclose customers in the Guam market. Am. Compl. ¶¶ 51 n.6, 65–70. Matson
    dismisses these barriers, contending that APL has voluntarily hamstrung its own ability to
    compete by “ma[king] a business decision to sail a slower route.” Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 23.
    But whether APL has excess capacity that it has chosen not to employ to counter Matson’s
    alleged monopoly power is a question of fact appropriately answered with the benefit of market
    data developed during discovery. See, e.g., Rebel Oil, 
    51 F.3d at 1441
     (“Excess capacity is a
    technical concept that is difficult to measure without an analysis of a firm’s costs.”).6
    The Court therefore cannot say, as a matter of law, that APL has failed to allege sufficient
    market power and barriers to entry for its claim that Matson possesses monopoly power in the
    relevant market. To the extent Matson contests the factual support for APL’s allegations, it can
    do so after discovery.
    2.      Anticompetitive Conduct
    Having dispensed with Matson’s threshold challenges, the Court turns to whether APL
    has plausibly alleged that Matson acquired or maintained its market power by anticompetitive
    means. Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 58
     (“A firm violates § 2 only when it acquires or maintains, or
    attempts to acquire or maintain, a monopoly by engaging in exclusionary conduct[.]”). Recall,
    APL alleges that Matson engaged in a “campaign of anticompetitive, unlawful exclusion” that
    6
    The other case Matson relies on, Ball Mem’l Hosp., Inc. v. Mut. Hosp. Ins., Inc., is
    similarly unconvincing. There, the Seventh Circuit affirmed the trial court’s denial of a request
    for a preliminary injunction after finding that the defendant did not have power in a market of
    over 1,000 potential participants with “no barriers to entry” for “a fungible product that other
    people can and do supply easily.” 
    784 F.2d 1325
    , 1331–32 (7th Cir. 1986) (analyzing the market
    for health care financing). Moreover, that holding was reached after a hearing that lasted eleven
    days in which more than 30 witnesses testified and over 400 exhibits were introduced. 
    Id. at 1331
    . Thus, this case does not support Matson’s contention that the complaint must be
    dismissed before discovery because Matson disputes whether APL is impeded from expanding in
    some segments of the relevant market.
    18
    foreclosed APL from a substantial share of the relevant market. Am. Compl. ¶¶ 7, 40, 73. While
    APL accuses Matson of engaging in various separate categories of anticompetitive conduct (i.e.,
    threats to customers and suppliers, bundled discounts, tying, lobbying, refusals to deal, attempted
    market allocation), its monopolization and attempted monopolization claims incorporate all the
    alleged conduct collectively. Finding that at least some of Matson’s alleged conduct could
    qualify as exclusionary conduct in violation of the Sherman Act, the Court will allow the
    amended complaint to proceed as to those allegations.
    a. Threats of Retaliation
    APL complains that Matson threatened potential customers and suppliers with adverse
    consequences for doing business with APL in the Guam market. See Am. Compl. ¶ 9 (“Matson
    threatened to impose disfavored rates and treatment on shippers to both Hawai[ʻ]i and Guam if
    they gave container cargo to APL in the U.S./Guam markets.”); Id. ¶ 49 (Matson allegedly
    “conditions the availability of shipping services in the U.S./Hawai[ʻ]i market . . . on shippers
    eliminating or drastically curtailing their Guam dealings with APL”); Id. ¶ 57 (“Matson’s
    punishing of vendors has become known recently in the ocean shipping community in Guam
    and, for example, caused fear of retribution by a large consumer of services and supplies in the
    industry and a necessary carrier to Hawai[‘]i. Some large potential customers declined to ship
    any containers on APL because they could not take the risk of retribution from Matson.”).
    According to APL, these threats dissuade consumers and suppliers from contracting with APL,
    contributing to a substantial foreclosure of the market and ongoing harm to competition. Id.
    ¶¶ 73, 76.
    Similar threats by dominant firms have been held to be exclusionary conduct that violates
    the Sherman Act. In the seminal antitrust case Lorain J. Co. v. United States, a dominant local
    19
    newspaper was found to have violated section 2 of the Sherman Act by threatening to
    discontinue advertising for any customer that also advertised with a competitor. 
    342 U.S. 143
    ,
    152–53 (1951). Likewise, Microsoft was found to have used its monopoly power to stunt
    competition by threatening to boycott distribution of Intel computer chips if Intel helped develop
    cross-platform programs for Microsoft’s competitors. Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 78
     (“[W]e affirm
    the conclusion that Microsoft’s threats to Intel were exclusionary, in violation of § 2 of the
    Sherman Act.”). Accordingly, APL’s similar allegations constitute exclusionary conduct that, if
    true, could violate section 2 of the Sherman Act.
    Matson counters that it cannot threaten to punish customers for disloyalty because it must
    file “reasonable and nondiscriminatory” rates with one of its regulatory bodies. Defs.’ Mot.
    Dismiss at 35 (emphasis in original). But even if it cannot discriminate among customers based
    on price (which itself is a factual question), APL also alleges that Matson has conditioned the
    availability and quality of service on APL’s exclusion, which plausibly describes anticompetitive
    conduct even without an effect on price. Am. Compl. ¶ 49.
    Matson further contests APL allegations of threats and retaliation by labeling them
    “vague and conclusory.” Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 34–36. But APL offers considerable factual
    support for its allegations, including various examples of specific conduct leveled against both
    customers and suppliers. Am. Compl. ¶¶ 44–46, 48, 55–56 (alleging that Matson threatened
    customers and companies providing maintenance, freight-forwarding, and trucking services to
    APL with worse rates and services). While APL does not identify the companies that it says
    were threatened, Matson cites no authority that doing so is required at this stage.7
    7
    The Court assumes that APL will be able to provide more details supporting its
    allegations of threatening conduct during discovery.
    20
    Accordingly, APL plausibly alleges exclusionary conduct that would give rise to a
    section 2 violation. This finding alone is sufficient to progress APL’s monopolization claim to
    discovery. The Court will proceed to analyze APL’s other allegations, however, in an effort to
    focus the scope of the dispute. See FTC v. Facebook, Inc., 
    581 F. Supp. 3d 34
    , 60–61 (D.D.C.
    2022) (permitting a monopolization claim to survive a motion to dismiss but excluding
    allegations that were “legally infirm” from discovery).
    b. U.S-Guam Loyalty Program
    Besides the “stick” of threats and retaliation, Matson is also alleged to have excluded
    APL from the market with the “carrot” of sizable customer discounts. At issue is Matson’s
    “loyalty program,” which offers consumers a 20% discount if they ship 90% or more of their
    cargo with Matson in the U.S.-Guam market. Am. Compl. ¶ 41. The discounts are “first dollar,”
    meaning customers risk losing the discount over their entire shipments if they fail to meet the
    20% threshold by even a small amount. Id.; Pls.’ Opp’n at 26. APL characterizes the discount
    as “de facto exclusive dealing” that forecloses it from competing for a substantial portion of the
    U.S.-Guam market. Pls.’ Opp’n at 26–28 (emphasis in original); Am. Compl. ¶¶ 7, 51. The
    Court finds, at least at this stage of the litigation, that the loyalty program could plausibly
    constitute an impermissible exclusionary practice.
    As an initial matter, APL labels the discount program a “de facto” exclusivity
    arrangement because only 90% of a customer’s shipping volume is required for eligibility. Am.
    Compl. ¶ 41. A lack of total exclusivity is not fatal to the allegation, APL explains, because
    courts look to the “practical effect” of the allegedly exclusive dealings to determine if an
    exclusionary effect is possible. Pls.’ Opp’n at 27 (citing Tampa Elec. Co. v. Nashville Co., 
    365 U.S. 320
    , 326 (1961)). APL also directs the Court to out-of-circuit precedent holding that total
    21
    exclusivity is not required. Id.; see ZF Meritor, LLC, 696 F.3d at 282–84 (holding that de facto
    partial exclusive dealing arrangements could be actionable under antitrust law). For its part,
    Matson does not cite—and the Court has not independently identified—any federal precedent
    requiring 100% exclusivity. Accordingly, the Court finds that the absence of a total exclusivity
    requirement does not shield Matson’s loyalty program from potential liability.
    To violate the Sherman Act, an exclusivity program must foreclose a “substantial
    percentage” of the relevant market from competition, which has often been cited as about 40% of
    the relevant market. Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at
    70–71. When the defendant is a monopolist,
    however, an even lower percentage may suffice. 
    Id. at 70
     (“[A] monopolist’s use of exclusive
    contracts, in certain circumstances, may give rise to a § 2 violation even though the contracts
    foreclose less than the roughly 40% or 50% share usually required in order to establish a § 1
    violation.”); 11 Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law, ¶ 1821(c) (4th ed. 2018) (“[S]ingle-firm
    foreclosure percentages of less than 30 percent in a properly defined market would seem
    presumptively harmless to competition.”).
    APL generally alleges that “Matson’s anticompetitive conduct has foreclosed APL from a
    substantial share of the market[] for container cargo shipping services between the United States
    and Guam.” Am. Compl. ¶ 73. More to the point, APL states that Matson’s conduct has
    foreclosed “at least 40% to 50% or more of the ‘contestable’ container cargo shipping services in
    the U.S./Guam markets[.]” 8 Id. ¶ 51. It defines the “contestable” market, in turn, as the portions
    8
    APL attributes its “40% to 50% or more” foreclosure figure to more conduct than just
    Matson’s loyalty program. Am. Compl. ¶ 51 (listing “Matson’s loyalty program, exclusive
    dealing, bundled pricing, and tying scheme” as the cause of its foreclosure). This is not an issue,
    however, given that APL does not allege that each action is an independent antitrust violation.
    It instead describes Matson’s activities collectively to support its monopolization and attempted
    monopolization claims. The D.C. Circuit has not ruled on the validity of such “course of
    22
    of the U.S.-Guam market in which APL actually competes, which APL says accounts for 70% of
    container cargo in the full U.S-Guam market. Id. ¶ 51 n.6. The Court is skeptical that the
    “contestable” market is the appropriate market for analyzing the foreclosing effects of Matson’s
    alleged conduct.9 But it need not resolve that issue now because APL has plausibly, albeit
    indirectly, alleged substantial foreclosure in the broader U.S.-Guam market. Read favorably, the
    complaint alleges that APL is foreclosed from more than 35% of the total relevant market.10 An
    alleged foreclosure of 35% is not defective as a matter of law, particularly in light of the Court’s
    conclusion above that APL has plausibly alleged that Matson has monopoly power in the U.S.-
    Guam market.
    Matson contends that APL’s exclusive dealing claim necessarily fails because APL did
    not allege that the discounts used to retain customers would require Matson to set its prices
    conduct” analysis, but other courts have found it possible to consider a series of separate acts that
    independently have anticompetitive effect. See Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 78
     (noting course of
    conduct theory without passing on its validity); LePage’s Inc. v. 3M, 
    324 F.3d 141
    , 162 (3d. Cir.
    2003) (“The relevant inquiry is the anticompetitive effect of 3M’s exclusionary practices
    considered together.”); New York v. Facebook, Inc., 
    549 F. Supp. 3d 6
    , 28 (D.D.C. 2021) (“To
    be clear, it is possible that were a monopolist to embark on a concerted scheme of serial refusals
    to deal with rivals, that scheme or ‘course of conduct’ could amount to a separate and
    independent violation of the Sherman Act.”). Accordingly, the Court will assess the validity of
    the alleged foreclosure without attempting to attribute specific percentages to each alleged
    activity.
    9
    For one, APL uses inconsistent markets to define monopoly power and anticompetitive
    effects. Compare Am. Compl. ¶ 67 (“Matson continues to have substantial monopoly power in
    container cargo shipping services between the United States and Guam. Matson’s share of these
    markets still exceeds 70% of such overall container shipment volume.”) with Am. Compl. ¶ 51
    (“APL is excluded from competing for at least 40% to 50% or more of the ‘contestable’
    container cargo shipping services in the U.S./Guam markets[.]”).
    10
    APL alleges it was foreclosed from more than 50% of the “contestable” market, which
    represents 70% of the total market, meaning it was foreclosed from 35% or more of the total
    market. Am. Compl. ¶ 51 n.6.
    23
    below cost. Defs.’ Reply at 14–16. But Matson does not direct the Court to any binding
    precedent requiring an allegation of predatory pricing in this context and does not adequately
    address a recent case in this district that holds otherwise, FTC v. Surescripts, LLC, 
    424 F. Supp. 3d 92
     (D.D.C. 2020). In denying a motion to dismiss, the court in Surescripts rejected the
    defendant’s theory that discounts used to enforce de facto exclusive dealing contracts must be set
    below cost to constitute exclusionary conduct in violation of section 2. 
    Id. at 102
     (“Like the
    behavior at issue in Microsoft, Surescripts’s alleged practice of charging loyal pharmacies and
    [pharmacy benefit managers] less, and paying loyal [electronic health record systems] greater
    incentives, do not need to constitute predatory pricing for Surescripts’s exclusionary practices to
    constitute illegal maintenance of a monopoly.”). The Court agrees with Surescripts’s reasoning
    and finds that predatory pricing allegations are not necessary for APL to plausibly allege that
    Matson’s loyalty program constitutes anticompetitive exclusive dealing.
    Accordingly, APL has plausibly alleged that Matson’s U.S.-Guam loyalty program
    constitutes anticompetitive conduct in violation of section 2 of the Sherman Act.
    c. Bundled Discounts
    APL next alleges that Matson impermissibly bundles its Hawaiʻi and Guam market
    discounts to foreclose competition in both markets. Am. Compl. ¶ 41. As part of Matson’s
    loyalty program, customers that place at least 90% of their cargo business with Matson in both
    markets receive an additional 5% discount in both markets. 
    Id.
     As a result, APL alleges,
    customers who ship in both markets “cannot economically or reasonably use APL services for
    container cargo shipments with Guam, even if offered at a substantial discount off Matson’s
    stand-alone rates,” because “most Guam shippers ship[] much larger volumes with Hawai[‘]i.”
    Am. Compl. ¶ 43.
    24
    Because “[b]undled discounts generally benefit buyers,” antitrust law is wary of attaching
    liability to a firm that offers customers more for less. See Cascade Health Sols. v. PeachHealth,
    
    515 F.3d 883
    , 895 (9th Cir. 2008). In support of its claim, APL directs the Court to LePage’s,
    
    324 F.3d at
    154–57 where the Third Circuit found a bundled discount to be anticompetitive.11
    Pls.’ Opp’n at 29. As the D.C. Circuit has noted, however, Lepage’s bundled discount holding
    has been “roundly criticized.” FTC v. Church & Dwight Co., 
    665 F.3d 1312
    , 1316–17 (D.C. Cir.
    2011); see also Surescripts, 424 F. Supp. 3d at 102. That said, no binding precedent appears to
    foreclose a bundled discount claim entirely.
    Given that APL’s monopolization claim may proceed, the Court need not decide if APL’s
    bundled discount claim is sufficient alone for antitrust liability. And given the unique market
    conditions alleged—that a lone monopolist in two two-competitor markets is bundling
    substantial discounts in exchange for near exclusivity in both markets—the Court will permit
    discovery as to the bundled discount claims and reserve further judgment until a later stage of the
    case.12
    d. Lobbying
    The Amended Complaint alleges that Matson successfully lobbied Congress to “exclude
    U.S.-flag MSP vessels from calling on Guam after 2018,” restricting potential new entrants from
    the Guam market. Am. Compl. ¶ 65. APL maintains that these lobbying efforts, while not
    11
    APL also claims that Surescripts was a bundled products case, but this is incorrect.
    Pls.’ Opp’n at 29. While Surescripts did offer discounts in two separate but complementary
    markets, the discounts were independent. Surescripts, 424 F. Supp. 3d at 95.
    12
    Because the Court permits discovery on both the U.S.-Hawaiʻi and U.S.-Guam loyalty
    programs, the Court need not rule on APL’s tying or monopoly leveraging claims arising from
    the same facts.
    25
    alleged as a standalone antitrust violation, tend to show that Matson had an intent to monopolize
    the U.S.-Guam market. Pls.’ Opp’n at 36. It is well-established, however, that lobbying is
    immunized from antitrust liability by the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, “regardless of [its] intent or
    purpose.” United Mine Workers of Am. v. Pennington, 
    381 U.S. 657
    , 670 (1965) (“Joint efforts
    to influence public officials do not violate the antitrust laws even though intended to eliminate
    competition.”); E. R.R. Presidents Conf. v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 
    365 U.S. 127
    , 135 (1961)
    (“[N]o violation of the [Sherman] Act can be predicated upon mere attempts to influence the
    passage or enforcement of laws.”). Lobbying efforts are not illegal, either “standing alone or as
    part of a broader scheme itself violative of the Sherman Act.” Pennington, 
    381 U.S. at 670
    (emphasis added).13 The Court thus finds that APL’s allegations concerning Matson’s lobbying
    conduct cannot be used to support an inference of anticompetitive conduct. This determination
    does not affect APL’s monopolization and attempted monopolization claims because, as
    discussed above, APL has already plead sufficient facts to support both.
    e. Slot Proposal
    APL further alleges that on two occasions, “Matson offered APL container cargo ‘slots’
    on Matson’s vessels, if APL would stop calling on Guam with its own vessels.” Am. Compl.
    ¶ 63. APL claims the slots were capped a specific number (90) and that “[t]he rates offered by
    Matson were higher.” 14 Id. ¶¶ 63, 64. Although APL declined the proposal, it alleges that the
    13
    APL does not claim that Matson’s lobbying activities fall under the “mere sham”
    exception to Noerr-Pennington. See E. R.R. Presidents Conf., 
    365 U.S. at 144
     (noting that
    application of the Sherman Act is justified where advocacy is a “mere sham” to cover an
    “attempt to interfere directly with the business relationships of a competitor”).
    14
    The complaint does not explain what “rates” APL is referring to, or the basis for its
    comparison to other rates.
    26
    arrangement would have “effectively allocated the U.S./Guam markets to Matson’s control,
    restricted APL’s competition to non-threatening levels, and further harmed U.S. shippers and
    residents of Guam.” Id. ¶ 12.
    The Court struggles to cabin Matson’s alleged slot proposal. APL labels it as horizontal
    market allocation (or at least attempted market allocation), Pls.’ Opp’n at 33 n.14, which is
    presumptively anticompetitive. United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 
    405 U.S. 596
    , 608 (1972)
    (holding that “an agreement between competitors at the same level of the market structure to
    allocate territories in order to minimize competition” is a per se violation). Matson, on the other
    hand, dismisses the proposal as a benign “slot-charter” arrangement where one competitor agrees
    to ship another competitor’s containers on its vessels—which Matson suggests is a common
    practice in the industry. Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 31. Neither characterization is satisfying, at
    least based on the current pleadings.
    Typical horizontal market allocation schemes involve two competitors agreeing to stay
    out of each other’s territory or avoid encroaching into each other’s product offerings. Matson’s
    proposal, by contrast would enable both APL and Matson to continue to service U.S.-Guam
    routes, albeit using only Matson vessels and with caps on APL’s capacity. But the alleged
    proposal is not an arm’s length slot-rental arrangement either, as Matson suggests. Importantly,
    Matson ignores that the proposal would have required APL to stop servicing Guam with its own
    boats.
    As the Court sees it, APL has alleged an unconsummated proposal to divide capacity in
    the U.S.-Guam market without requiring APL to exit altogether. Such an arrangement could
    raise antitrust concerns to the extent that APL would have been limited in the way that it expands
    and innovates. See 12 Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law, ¶ 2030(c) (4th
    27
    ed. 2019). It could also be viewed as a proposed output restriction, although APL offers no
    allegations concerning the overall market volume or its capacity compared to Matson’s offer of
    90 slots. Without additional briefing on how the proposal should be treated under the antitrust
    laws—including whether it would constitute attempted monopolization—the Court hesitates to
    opine further on how the allegation fits with APL’s two claims. In the meantime, the facts
    concerning Matson’s purported slot offer will be fair game for discovery.
    f. Conduct in Alaska
    As further claimed evidence of Matson’s retaliation and specific intent to monopolize,
    APL points to actions taken by Matson in Alaska. The complaint describes how APL’s entry
    into Guam led Matson to precipitously terminate a long-standing Connecting Carrier Agreement
    between the parties, which had enabled APL to use Matson vessels in Alaska. Am. Compl. ¶¶ 6,
    58. Matson also retaliated, APL claims, by declining “to renew APL’s shop and office lease at
    Pier II” in Alaska, refusing “APL access to dock and terminal facilities” in Kodiak, Alaska, and
    terminating a “shared tug charter agreement.” Id. ¶ 6.
    APL asserts that Matson’s Alaska-related conduct is relevant to the U.S.-Guam market
    because it constitutes retaliation for APL’s entry and continued presence in Guam, confirming
    Matson’s exclusionary conduct and intent. Pls.’ Opp’n at 35. Threats and retaliation, even if
    they occur in a separate market, might reasonably produce an anticompetitive effect in the
    relevant market. Whether the conduct is of such magnitude that it might drive a competitor from
    the relevant market is a question best decided after discovery. The financial impact felt in
    Alaska by both parties—which APL has estimated at millions of dollars for itself and eight
    million dollars for Matson annually—could bear on whether Matson acted with the aim to
    exclude APL from the Guam market. Am. Compl. ¶ 62. And purported comments by Matson
    28
    management in Alaska in response to APL’s complaints for alleged retaliation could reveal
    specific intent, as required for attempted monopolization claims. In any case, as the Court has
    already found sufficient allegations of anticompetitive conduct to support APL’s section 2
    claims, it need not decide at this stage whether the alleged retaliation in Alaska also constitutes
    anticompetitive conduct in the Guam market.
    Matson is correct, however, that its alleged activities in Alaska do not constitute a
    standalone antitrust claim—APL has neither plead a relevant market in Alaska nor alleged
    monopoly power in such a market. See New York v. Facebook, Inc., 
    549 F. Supp. 3d 6
    , 23
    (D.D.C. 2021) (noting that a monopoly maintenance claim requires “the possession of monopoly
    power in the relevant market”); see also Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 81
     (“A court’s evaluation of an
    attempted monopolization claim must include a definition of the relevant market.”).
    So for now, the Court reserves judgment on whether Matson’s Alaska-related activity
    could be used as evidence of Matson’s anticompetitive conduct in Guam. Since Matson’s
    actions in Alaska are only relevant to the extent they result in anticompetitive effects in the
    relevant market—the U.S.-Guam container cargo shipping market—discovery relating to the
    Alaska activities will be accordingly cabined.
    B. Attempted Monopolization Claim
    The Court now turns to APL’s attempted monopolization claim. To succeed on an
    attempted monopolization claim under section 2, plaintiffs must prove “(1) that the defendant has
    engaged in predatory or anticompetitive conduct with (2) a specific intent to monopolize and (3)
    a dangerous probability of achieving monopoly power.” Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 80
     (quoting
    Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 
    506 U.S. 447
    , 456 (1993)). Failing to prove any element of
    the inquiry defeats the claim. 
    Id.
     Because the Sherman Act neither defines the elements of
    29
    attempted monopolization nor “identif[ies] the activities” constituting the offense, courts “must
    examine the facts of each case”—ultimately, what constitutes an offense is “a question of
    proximity and degree.” Spectrum Sports, 
    506 U.S. at
    454–55 (quotation omitted); Microsoft,
    
    253 F.3d at 80
     (quoting United States v. Am. Airlines, Inc., 
    743 F.2d 1114
    , 1118 (5th Cir.
    1984)).
    As explained above, APL has plead sufficient facts to allege an antitrust injury, a relevant
    market, and anticompetitive conduct for a claim for monopolization, related to Matson’s conduct
    in the U.S.-Guam market. APL maintains that this same conduct supports an attempted
    monopolization claim. See Am. Compl. ¶ 97; Pls.’ Opp’n 22–23. The relevant questions, then,
    are whether APL has adequately alleged that Matson engaged in the alleged conduct with a
    “specific intent” to monopolize and that it reached a “dangerous probability” of success.
    Courts can infer specific intent to monopolize from “conduct that has no legitimate
    business justification but to destroy or damage competition.” City of Moundridge v. Exxon
    Mobil Corp, 
    471 F. Supp. 2d 20
    , 42–43 (D.D.C. 2007) (citation omitted). A plaintiff adequately
    pleads specific intent where “it is otherwise apparent from the character” of the alleged
    anticompetitive actions—as with actions that “eliminat[e] a viable means of competition” or
    “channel[] customers away from the competition.” 
    Id. at 43
     (citation omitted). But conclusory
    allegations won’t do; specific intent must be supported by factual assertions. See 
    id.
     (finding no
    specific intent because plaintiff alleged intent “in a conclusory fashion,” without any facts to
    support the claim).
    APL attempts to show specific intent through its allegations that Matson threatened to
    punish numerous potential APL customers. For instance, Matson allegedly threatened shippers,
    including freight forwarders, with higher rates and reduced services for their Hawaiʻi cargo if
    30
    they placed container cargo with APL along the U.S.-Guam route. Am. Compl. ¶ 44–48.
    Maintaining market power by employing threats lacks a “business justification,” and therefore
    reflects an intent to restrict competition. APL also points to comments by Matson officials to
    show specific intent. Matson’s chief executive allegedly threatened APL with an “axe fight” if it
    continued to operate in Guam. Id. ¶ 4. And, in responding to a complaint by APL about
    allegedly exclusionary actions in Alaska, Matson management in that state supposedly said that
    APL “had brought it on itself by calling Guam.” Id. ¶ 61. These comments, if they were made,
    may well have been rhetorical or taken out of context. But because intent may be inferred from a
    defendant’s words, APL’s allegations in this regard are sufficient at this stage of the case. Tops
    Mkts., Inc. v. Quality Mkts., Inc., 
    142 F.3d 90
    , 101 (2d Cir. 1998) (finding specific intent where
    defendants’ “officials frequently affirmed their stated goal of preventing” plaintiff’s entrance
    into market”).
    The third element of an attempted monopolization claim—a “dangerous probability of
    success”—is met here too. In this fact-intensive inquiry, the plaintiff must (1) “define the
    relevant market” and (2) “demonstrate that substantial barriers to entry protect that market.”
    Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 81
    . As noted earlier, plaintiffs have defined a relevant market—U.S.-
    Guam cargo shipping routes—and have demonstrated substantial barriers to entry. See 
    id.
    (“Defining a market for an attempted monopolization claim involves the same steps as defining a
    market for a monopoly maintenance claim.”).
    Although the D.C. Circuit does not appear to have established a threshold market share
    percentage that plaintiffs must meet to establish dangerous probability of success, other courts
    have. See Neumann v. Reinforced Earth Co., 
    786 F.2d 424
    , 428 (D.C. Cir. 1986) (suggesting
    that a “share of 30% or less presumptively disproves requisite power” but deciding the case on
    31
    other grounds). The market share attributed to Matson here—at least 70% of the relevant
    market—easily meets the requirement established by those courts. See Tops Mkts., 142 F.3d at
    100 (holding that market share exceeding 72% “at the time when defendants took other
    anticompetitive actions is sufficient . . . to create a genuine factual issue as to whether there was
    a dangerous probability”); McGahee v. N. Propane Gas Co., 
    858 F.2d 1487
    , 1506 (11th Cir.
    1988) (holding that a 60% to 65% market share could “create a genuine issue of material fact as
    to whether there was a dangerous probability of success”); see also M & M Med. Supplies &
    Serv., Inc. v. Pleasant Valley Hosp., Inc., 
    981 F.2d 160
    , 168 (4th Cir. 1992) (“[C]laims involving
    greater than 50% share should be treated as attempts at monopolization when the other elements
    for attempted monopolization are also satisfied.”). The Court thus finds that APL’s allegations
    are “sufficient to put the [defendants] on notice of the nature of [plaintiff’s] claim
    for attempted monopolization in the market[.]” WAKA LLC v. DC Kickball, 
    517 F. Supp. 2d 245
    , 252 (D.D.C. 2007).
    IV. Motion to Dismiss Matson, Inc. and Matson Logistics, Inc.
    In addition to moving to dismiss APL’s claims, Matson seeks dismissal of two of the
    three named defendants: Matson, Inc. and Matson Logistics, Inc.
    The complaint does not attribute specific conduct to the three corporate defendants; it
    simply lumps them all together as “Matson.” The parties appear to agree that Matson, Inc. is the
    group’s parent holding company; Matson Navigation Company, Inc. is a direct subsidiary that
    provides the ocean shipping services mainly at issue in this case; and Matson Logistics, Inc. is a
    second-level subsidiary that provides logistical ground support to Matson Navigation. See Am.
    Compl. ¶¶ 19–21; Defs.’ Mot. Dismiss at 37–39; see also Matson, Inc., Annual Report (Form 10-
    K at 9) (Feb. 25, 2022); Mintz v. FDIC, 
    729 F. Supp. 2d 276
    , 278 n.2 (D.D.C. 2010) (taking
    32
    judicial notice of the relationship between two corporate entities since it is a “highly relevant and
    easily verifiable fact”).
    A complaint should “say enough to give the defendant ‘fair notice of what the plaintiff’s
    claim is and the grounds upon which it rests.’” Tellabs, Inc. v. Makor Issues & Rts., Ltd., 
    551 U.S. 308
    , 319 (2007) (quoting Dura Pharms., Inc. v. Broudo, 
    544 U.S. 336
    , 346 (2005)). This
    principle applies to each named defendant.
    APL’s complaint does not meet that standard with respect to Matson, Inc. “It is a general
    principle of corporate law deeply ingrained in our economic and legal systems that a parent
    corporation . . . is not liable for the acts of its subsidiaries.” United States v. Bestfoods, 
    524 U.S. 51
    , 61 (1998) (quotation omitted). Each corporation is treated as a “distinct juridical entity,”
    even if it is owned by another individual or entity. Alkanani v. Aegis Def. Servs., LLC, 
    976 F. Supp. 2d 1
    , 8 (D.D.C. 2013). A parent corporation can be held directly liable if (a) the alleged
    wrong can be traced back to the parent corporation, or (b) the parent directly participates in the
    alleged wrong. Doe v. Bank of Am. Corp., 
    273 F. Supp. 3d 203
    , 209 (D.D.C. 2017) (citation
    omitted).
    The complaint fails to allege facts indicating that any of the alleged anti-competitive
    conduct was undertaken by, or can be traced to, Matson, Inc. specifically. APL’s sole argument
    to the contrary centers on two allegations: first, that “Matson’s” CEO threatened APL with an
    “axe fight” if APL continued servicing Guam, Am. Compl. ¶ 4, and, second, that he either made
    the slot-charter proposal discussed above or was “at a lunch” where it was discussed, 
    id. ¶¶ 12, 63
    . Matson contends that these alleged actions may be imputed to Matson, Inc. Pls.’ Opp’n at
    43 (citing United States v. Cadillac Overall Supply Co., 
    568 F.2d 1078
     (5th Cir. 1978)).
    33
    Neither allegation suffices. As an initial matter, the complaint does not identify
    “Matson’s” CEO as the CEO of Matson, Inc. Moreover, even if all three defendants share the
    same CEO (as appears to be the case), the complaint provides no basis to infer that the CEO
    engaged in any of his alleged conduct on behalf of Matson, Inc. as opposed to its operational
    shipping business. And in any case, promising a proverbial “axe fight” may (or may not) be
    evidence of anti-competitive intent, but it does not constitute standalone anti-competitive
    conduct. (The slot proposal is more complicated, as previously discussed).
    The Court reaches a different conclusion with respect to Matson Logistics, Inc. While
    APL does not attribute conduct to that entity specifically, the complaint alleges a number of
    threats and retaliatory acts implicating the ground-support portion of Matson’s shipping business.
    For instance, Matson allegedly retaliated “against a trucking company in Guam,” punished a
    “warehouse and trucking company in Guam,” coerced “a parts distributor in Guam,” prohibited
    the “use of terminal, docks, and storage areas in Alaska in retaliation against APL,” and
    “terminated a shop and pier lease in Alaska.” Pls.’ Opp’n at 43; see also ¶¶ 55–56, 59–60. It can
    be reasonably inferred from the context of the complaint that these acts were allegedly
    undertaken by, or at least involved, Matson Logistics. If discovery proves otherwise, Matson can
    renew its request to dismiss Matson Logistics from the case. In the meantime, the Court will
    retain it as a defendant alongside Matson Navigation.
    V.    Motion for Judicial Notice, Motion to Strike, Motion for Leave
    Finally, APL moves to strike portions of Matson’s brief that rely on extrinsic material
    and factual assertions. Mot. Strike, ECF No. 23-1. APL also moves to file a supplemental brief
    in opposition to Matson’s Motion to Dismiss. Mot. for Leave to File Suppl. Br., ECF No. 29.
    Separately, Matson asks the Court to take judicial notice of exhibits filed in support of its Motion
    34
    to Dismiss. Mot. Judicial Notice, ECF No. 16. At the motion to dismiss stage, a court is
    “limited to the ‘four corners of the complaint, as well as any documents attached as exhibits or
    incorporated by reference in the complaint, or documents upon which the plaintiff’s complaint
    necessarily relies[,]’” as well as facts “of which the Court may take judicial notice.” Brown v.
    Gov’t of District of Columbia, 
    390 F. Supp. 3d 114
    , 122 (D.D.C. 2019) (quoting Tyson v.
    Brennan, 
    306 F. Supp. 3d 365
    , 369 (D.D.C. 2017); Ashbourne v. Hansberry, 
    245 F. Supp. 3d 99
    ,
    103 (D.D.C. 2017), aff’d, 
    894 F.3d 298
     (D.C. Cir. 2018)). The Court has not relied on Matson’s
    exhibits, or any extrinsic factual assertions made by Matson in its motions. The Court has also
    not relied on APL’s supplemental brief in support of its opposition. These motions will therefore
    be denied as moot.
    VI. Conclusion
    For the reasons explained above, the Court will deny Matson’s motion to dismiss as to
    APL’s monopolization and attempted monopolization claims against defendants Matson
    Navigation Company, Inc. and Matson Logistics, Inc., and grant it as to APL’s claims against
    Matson, Inc. Because the Court has not relied on any of the contested material in the request for
    judicial notice, the Court will deny as moot Matson’s request for judicial notice, APL’s motion
    to strike filed in response to that request, and APL’s motion for leave to file a supplemental brief.
    A separate Order accompanies this Memorandum Opinion.
    CHRISTOPHER R. COOPER
    United States District Judge
    Date: September 30, 2022
    35
    

Document Info

Docket Number: Civil Action No. 2021-2040

Judges: Judge Christopher R. Cooper

Filed Date: 9/30/2022

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 9/30/2022

Authorities (36)

H. Floyd McGahee v. Northern Propane Gas Company , 858 F.2d 1487 ( 1988 )

lepages-incorporated-lepages-management-company-llc , 324 F.3d 141 ( 2003 )

United States v. Cadillac Overall Supply Company , 568 F.2d 1078 ( 1978 )

United States v. American Airlines, Inc. And Robert L. ... , 743 F.2d 1114 ( 1984 )

ball-memorial-hospital-inc-v-mutual-hospital-insurance-inc-doing , 784 F.2d 1325 ( 1986 )

E.I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co. v. Kolon Industries, Inc. , 637 F.3d 435 ( 2011 )

United States v. Microsoft Corp , 253 F.3d 34 ( 2001 )

Rebel Oil Co. v. Atlantic Richfield Co. , 51 F.3d 1421 ( 1995 )

Amarel v. Connell , 102 F.3d 1494 ( 1996 )

Sparrow, Victor H. v. United Airlines Inc , 216 F.3d 1111 ( 2000 )

Newcal Industries v. Ikon Office Solution , 513 F.3d 1038 ( 2008 )

Albert Neumann v. The Reinforced Earth Company , 786 F.2d 424 ( 1986 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Church & Dwight Co. , 665 F.3d 1312 ( 2011 )

national-aviation-trades-association-and-butler-aviation-company-v-civil , 420 F.2d 209 ( 1969 )

American Tobacco Co. v. United States , 66 S. Ct. 1125 ( 1946 )

Ohio v. American Express Co. , 201 L. Ed. 2d 678 ( 2018 )

Syncsort Inc. v. Sequential Software, Inc. , 50 F. Supp. 2d 318 ( 1999 )

Waka LLC v. Dc Kickball , 517 F. Supp. 2d 245 ( 2007 )

Mintz v. Federal Deposit Insurance , 729 F. Supp. 2d 276 ( 2010 )

CITY OF MOUNDRIDGE, KS. v. Exxon Mobil Corp. , 471 F. Supp. 2d 20 ( 2007 )

View All Authorities »