In re Appraisal of Columbia Pipeline Group, Inc. ( 2019 )


Menu:
  •       IN THE COURT OF CHANCERY OF THE STATE OF DELAWARE
    IN RE APPRAISAL OF COLUMBIA              )     Cons. C.A. No. 12736-VCL
    PIPELINE GROUP, INC.                     )
    MEMORANDUM OPINION
    Date Submitted: May 16, 2019
    Date Decided: August 12, 2019
    Stephen E. Jenkins, Andrew D. Cordo, Marie M. Degnan, ASHBY & GEDDES, P.A.,
    Wilmington, Delaware; Marcus E. Montejo, Kevin H. Davenport, John G. Day,
    PRICKETT, JONES & ELLIOTT, P.A., Wilmington, Delaware; Mark Lebovitch, Jeroen
    van Kwawegen, Christopher J. Orrico, Alla Zayenchik, BERNSTEIN LITOWITZ
    BERGER & GROSSMANN LLP, New York, New York; Attorneys for Petitioners.
    Martin S. Lessner, James M. Yoch, Jr., Paul J. Loughman, YOUNG CONAWAY
    STARGATT & TAYLOR, LLP, Wilmington, Delaware; Brian J. Massengill, Michael A.
    Olsen, Linda X. Shi, MAYER BROWN LLP, Chicago, Illinois; Attorneys for Respondent.
    LASTER, V.C.
    The petitioners brought this statutory appraisal proceeding to determine the fair
    value of the common stock of Columbia Pipeline Group, Inc. The valuation’s effective date
    is July 1, 2016, when TransCanada Corporation completed its acquisition of Columbia (the
    “Merger”). Pursuant to an agreement and plan of merger dated March 17, 2016 (the
    “Merger Agreement”), each share of Columbia common stock was converted into the right
    to receive $25.50 in cash, subject to each stockholder’s right to eschew the consideration
    and seek appraisal. This post-trial decision finds that the fair value of Columbia’s common
    stock on the effective date was $25.50 per share.
    I.       FACTUAL BACKGROUND
    The evidentiary record is vast.1 After an initial spat during the pre-trial process, the
    parties agreed to 716 stipulations of fact, which were a welcome contribution. During a
    five-day trial, the parties submitted 1,472 exhibits, including twenty-one deposition
    transcripts.2 Nine fact witnesses and five experts testified live. The following factual
    1
    Citations in the form “PTO ¶ ––” refer to stipulated facts in the pre-trial order. Dkt.
    397. Citations in the form “[Name] Tr.” refer to witness testimony from the trial transcript.
    Citations in the form “[Name] Dep.” refer to witness testimony from a deposition
    transcript. Citations in the form “JX –– at ––” refer to a trial exhibit with the page
    designated by the last three digits of the control or JX number or, if the document lacked a
    control or JX number, by the internal page number. If a trial exhibit used paragraph
    numbers, then references are by paragraph.
    2
    The parties designated the transcripts as joint exhibits rather than lodging them
    separately. The JX designations made it more difficult to determine during briefing when
    a deposition transcript was being cited and whose testimony it was. It would be more
    helpful to have the deposition transcripts lodged and collected in a separate binder, then
    cited in the form “[Name] Dep.” I offer this point not to criticize the parties’ approach,
    which was a reasonable one, but rather as a suggestion for the future.
    findings represent the court’s effort to distill this record.
    A.     Columbia
    At the time of the Merger, Columbia was a Delaware corporation whose common
    stock traded actively on the New York Stock Exchange under the ticker symbol “CPGX.”
    Columbia developed, owned, and operated natural gas pipeline, storage, and other
    midstream assets. As a midstream company, Columbia did not own or sell the commodities
    that it transported or stored. Columbia’s success depended on its contracts with shippers
    and producers.
    Columbia’s primary operating asset consisted of 15,000 miles of interstate gas
    pipelines running from New York to the Gulf of Mexico. The pipelines served the
    strategically important Marcellus and Utica natural gas basins in Pennsylvania, Ohio, and
    West Virginia. Columbia’s growth-oriented business plan sought to exploit a production
    boom in the Marcellus and Utica basins by expanding its pipeline network and selling the
    additional capacity. See PTO ¶ 248. The plan required billions of dollars in capital
    expenditures, which in turn required large amounts of low-cost financing.
    Columbia itself was a holding company. Its principal asset was an 84.3% interest in
    Columbia OpCo LP (“OpCo”), which owned Columbia’s operating assets. Columbia’s
    largest business divisions operated interstate pipelines. Smaller divisions operated gas-
    gathering and processing systems.
    Columbia also owned a 100% general partner interest and a 46.5% limited partner
    interest in Columbia Pipeline Partners, L.P. (“CPPL”), a master limited partnership
    (“MLP”) whose common units traded on the New York Stock Exchange. CPPL owned the
    2
    other 15.7% interest in OpCo.
    Columbia’s business plan depended upon using CPPL to raise equity financing for
    Columbia’s growth projects. To raise capital using an MLP, a sponsor like Columbia sells
    assets to the MLP, receiving cash in return. Because the MLP is a pass-through entity, it
    can raise capital at a lower cost than the sponsor.3 Columbia planned to use a variant of the
    typical method. Rather than having CPPL buy assets from Columbia, CPPL would buy
    newly issued interests in OpCo, which would use the proceeds to fund Columbia’s growth
    plan.4 Given the magnitude of Columbia’s capital needs, analysts expected that CPPL
    could own over 60% of OpCo by 2020. See, e.g., JX 258 at 13.
    B.     NiSource
    When the process leading to the Merger began, Columbia was not yet a public
    company. It was a subsidiary of NiSource Inc., a publicly traded utility company that today
    serves approximately four million customers in seven states.
    In 2005, Robert Skaggs, Jr. became the CEO of NiSource. He also served as
    chairman of its board of directors. In 2013, Skaggs told the NiSource directors that he
    wanted to retire in a few years. See Taylor Dep. 93. For planning purposes, Skaggs’s
    3
    See Tom Miesner, A Practical Guide to US Natural Gas Transmission Pipeline
    Economics, 8 J. Pipeline Eng’g 111, 112 (2009); Matthew J. McCabe, Comment, Master
    Limited Partnerships’ Cost of Capital Conundrum, 17 U. Pa. J. Bus. L. 319, 325 (2014).
    4
    JX 258 at 2; see JX 886 at 34 (“[Columbia’s] ‘Drop Downs’ are atypical in that
    the transaction is effected through [CPPL] acquiring incremental interests in OpCo . . . .
    [Columbia’s] interest in OpCo is accordingly diluted down.”).
    3
    financial advisor used a target retirement date of March 31, 2016, and cautioned that “the
    single greatest risk” to Skaggs’s retirement plan was his “single company stock position in
    NiSource.” JX 163.
    Stephen Smith was NiSource’s CFO. Smith, who was fifty-two years old in 2013,
    considered fifty-five to be the “magical age” to retire. Smith Dep. 97–98; see JX 199. He
    too targeted a retirement date in 2016.
    Since 2008, Lazard Frères & Co. had been evaluating a spinoff of Columbia as part
    of its regular work for NiSource. See JX 98 at 7–9. Lazard believed that a spinoff could
    unlock major value for NiSource.5 In January 2014, Lazard made a presentation to the
    NiSource board. Consistent with Lazard’s advice, Skaggs and Smith pitched forming
    CPPL as part of the spinoff to provide a financing vehicle for Columbia. See JX 91. For
    much of 2014, the NiSource board weighed its options.
    In summer 2014, The Deal reported that Dominion Resources Inc. was trying to buy
    NiSource. The article described Skaggs as “a willing seller” but only in an all-cash deal at
    a 20% premium. JX 142.
    5
    See 
    id. at 46
    (Lazard anticipating stock-price improvement of up to $12 per share;
    observing that NiSource traded “at a premium valuation relative to its diversified utility
    peers, but at a discount to the blended consolidated multiple implied by MLP valuations
    for [Columbia]”); see also JX 231 at 2 (consulting firm remarking in January 2015 that
    despite “40% drop in gas price since 2014” and “pressure” on “[g]as basin economics,”
    that “original [spinoff] rationale holds: Utilities and [Columbia] are separate businesses,
    the market is supportive of focused players, growth stories and risk profiles are different”).
    See generally Mir Dep. 55–73. As anticipated, separating NiSource, Columbia, and CPPL
    increased their total market capitalization by approximately $4 billion. See JX 404 at 6.
    4
    C.     The Spinoff
    On September 28, 2014, NiSource announced that it would spin off Columbia as a
    separate public company. NiSource also announced the formation of CPPL as the “primary
    funding source” for Columbia’s growth capital. JX 182 at 15. CPPL would go public in
    early 2015. Columbia would follow later that year.
    Columbia’s post-spinoff business plan contemplated “a potential capital investment
    opportunity of $12–15 billion over the next 10 years, positioning the company to provide
    enhanced earnings and dividend growth driven by its projected net investment growth.” JX
    174. The largest components were pipeline expansion and modernization. JX 182 at 14. If
    all went according to plan, then Columbia would triple in size. See PTO ¶ 291. The plan
    envisioned funding the growth by having CPPL issue equity over a sustained period.6
    6
    See Mir Tr. 1197 (“[T]he business plan was dependent on being able to raise a lot
    of equity through the MLP, CPPL. The MLPs at the time were the de facto means of raising
    equity for pipeline and midstream projects.”); JX 300 at 20 (Lazard warning that
    Columbia’s “[f]inancing plan [was] highly dependent on CPPL’s ability to issue equity at
    attractive terms over time”); JX 480 at 7 (Lazard identifying upside of “[s]trong access to
    capital and low cost of CPPL equity” and downside of “CPPL unable to access equity
    market at attractive terms (potentially requiring [Columbia] to issue equity)”); JX 214 at
    17 (CPPL IPO pitch materials indicating CPPL’s equity would “be the primary source of
    new funding for Columbia OpCo expansion capital projects”); JX 277 at 4 (analyst report
    identifying risks like “highly leveraged balance sheet,” growth plan’s execution risk, and
    “financing strategy which relies almost completely on [CPPL’s] ability to access the equity
    capital markets during the next several years”); see also Kittrell Tr. 1052 (“As part of the
    spin, we had been able to launch [CPPL] in January of 2015 and raise just over a billion
    dollars. We also had done a series of debt financings as of the spin for about $3 billion. So
    that gave Columbia $4 billion of permanent capital to kind of come out of the chute with
    as a standalone independent company. That still left $3 to 4 billion of capital that we were
    going to need for ‘16, ‘17, and ‘18.”); JX 96 at 12 (Lazard observing that the “most
    successful” MLPs had “low-risk assets and visible growth opportunities, driven by either
    5
    In December 2014, the NiSource board signed off on Skaggs and Smith leaving
    NiSource and joining Columbia. Skaggs would become CEO and chairman of the board
    for Columbia and CPPL; Smith would become CFO of both entities. Skaggs and Smith
    made the move partly because they did not “want to work forever.” JX 208. By this time,
    two investment banks had told Smith that Columbia would “trade too rich to sell,” and
    Smith sought a third view from Goldman Sachs & Co. See 
    id. Goldman believed
    Skaggs
    and Smith were eyeing “a sale in near term.” 
    Id. On February
    11, 2015, CPPL closed its initial public offering, generating net
    proceeds of approximately $1.17 billion. Under Columbia’s business plan, CPPL did not
    plan to raise additional equity until 2016. JX 304 at 28. In the meantime, Columbia planned
    to draw over $500 million from a revolving credit facility. 
    Id. As part
    of the spinoff, Columbia borrowed $2.75 billion through a private placement
    of debt securities. Columbia used the proceeds to make a $1.45 billion cash distribution to
    NiSource and to refinance its existing debt. See 
    id. Moody’s Investors
    Service rated
    Columbia’s debt at Baa2, one notch above non-investment grade. PTO ¶ 262. Columbia’s
    debt level meant that it could not borrow additional capital to fund its business plan and
    would have to rely on CPPL. See JX 466; JX 1339.
    Columbia anticipated that it would become an acquisition target after the spinoff.
    organic investments or dropdowns from a supportive general partner that is motivated to
    grow IDR distributions [to itself]”).
    6
    As part of its pre-transaction planning, Columbia engaged Lazard as its financial advisor.7
    As of May 2015, Lazard categorized the potential acquirers into four tiers, ranked by their
    ability to pay and likelihood of interest. The first tier consisted of Kinder Morgan, Inc. and
    Energy Transfer Equity, L.P. The second tier included TransCanada, Berkshire Hathaway
    Energy, Dominion, Spectra Energy Corp., NextEra Energy, Enbridge Inc., and The
    Williams Companies. See JX 300 at 35; Mir Dep. 136–48.
    On May 28, 2015, Lazard contacted TransCanada and mentioned that Columbia
    might be for sale after the spinoff. JX 311. A contemporaneous memorandum from
    Skaggs’s financial advisor made the point directly: “[Skaggs] noted that [Columbia] could
    be purchased as early as Q3/Q4 of 2015. I think they are already working on getting
    themselves sold before they even split. This was the intention all along. [Skaggs] sees
    himself only staying on through July of 2016.” JX 324.
    In June 2015, Lazard advised TransCanada against “opening a dialogue” until after
    the spinoff. JX 335. Doing so could jeopardize the spinoff’s tax-free status, which required
    that NiSource not spin off Columbia in anticipation of a sale. See JX 311. Internally,
    TransCanada discussed that “absent a knock out offer, [Columbia] will likely go for a
    market check (to maximize proceeds), which we should be prepared for.” JX 335.
    On July 1, 2015, NiSource completed the spinoff. On its first day of trading,
    Columbia’s stock closed at $30.34 per share.
    7
    JX 167; see Mir Tr. 1195–97. Pre-spinoff, the operative entity was Columbia
    Energy Group, but for simplicity this decision uses “Columbia.”
    7
    From the spinoff until the Merger, Columbia’s board of directors (the “Board”)
    consisted of Skaggs and six outside directors. The lead independent director was Sigmund
    Cornelius, an oil and gas veteran who had worked in the pipeline industry and as the CFO
    of ConocoPhillips. The other directors were Marty Kittrell, Lee Nutter, Deborah Parker,
    Lester Silverman, and Teresa Taylor. Most had served as directors of NiSource before the
    spinoff.
    D.     Early Interest From Possible Buyers
    On July 2, 2015, Columbia engaged Goldman to advise on any unsolicited
    acquisition proposals. JX 347. Over the next two weeks, Dominion and Spectra contacted
    Skaggs to discuss potential strategic transactions. See PTO ¶¶ 391–93. Skaggs viewed the
    Spectra outreach as trivial, but thought Dominion was worth exploring. See JX 359 (Skaggs
    classifying Spectra outreach as “casual pass” and Dominion as “notable/substantive”).
    On July 20, 2015, Dominion expressed interest in buying Columbia for $32.50 to
    $35.50 per share, half stock and half cash. Lazard’s contemporaneous discounted cash flow
    (“DCF”) analysis valued Columbia at $30.75 per share, 5% higher than the trading price.
    See PTO ¶ 395. After discussing the expression of interest with the Board and receiving
    advice from Lazard and Goldman, Skaggs asked Dominion to raise its price to the “upper-
    $30s.” See 
    id. ¶¶ 397–98.
    On August 12, 2015, Columbia and Dominion entered into a non-disclosure
    agreement (an “NDA”). PTO ¶ 400; see JX 416. The parties began due diligence, but on
    August 31, Dominion disengaged. Citing a decline in Columbia’s stock price amid general
    stock market volatility, Dominion indicated that even its floor of $32.50 per share had
    8
    become too high. See PTO ¶ 406.
    By the end of August 2015, Columbia’s stock price had fallen to around $25 per
    share. By late September, it had fallen to around $18 per share.
    Meanwhile, TransCanada continued to examine Columbia as an acquisition target.
    See JX 458. TransCanada’s Senior Vice President for Strategy and Corporate
    Development, François Poirier, was friends with Smith and asked him to dinner on October
    26. See JX 487. It seems likely that other companies were studying Columbia as well, but
    it is unclear to what extent other firms were included in the scope of discovery. The
    petitioners issued subpoenas to Spectra, Berkshire, Dominion, and NextEra. See Dkts. 132,
    170, 176, 217. They also obtained discovery from Goldman and Lazard.
    E.     The Equity Overhang
    During fall 2015, the energy markets deteriorated, and the market for issuances of
    equity by MLPs was “effectively closed.” JX 466; see, e.g., Kittrell Tr. 1053–54 (citing
    “sea change” in MLP market that “has continued to this day”). The new market dynamics
    meant that Columbia could no longer use CPPL to raise equity. See JX 466. With $1 billion
    in short-term funding needs and no capacity to take on more debt, Columbia had to consider
    issuing equity itself, even though its cost of equity had spiked too.8
    The confluence of problems created an “equity overhang.” JX 466. If investors
    8
    See 
    id. Compare JX
    753 at 4 (Skaggs explaining in January 2016 that “for CPPL
    to be a viable equity currency,” prices would have to improve to at least $21 per unit by
    2017 and at least $27 per unit by 2018), with Dkt. 390 Ex. D (stipulated CPPL price chart
    showing prices below $14 per unit in late 2015).
    9
    feared that Columbia could not obtain the capital to achieve anticipated growth rates, then
    they would bid down the stock. The lower price would force Columbia to issue more equity
    to raise the same amount of capital, and Columbia could become “mired in a vicious cycle
    of issuing more and more equity at lower and lower prices.”9
    In a memorandum to the Board dated October 16, 2015, Skaggs summarized
    Columbia’s situation, identifying both problems and potential solutions:
          “[T]he latest intrinsic value studies (which assume that we’re able to fully manage
    CPG’s financing, project execution, and counter-party risks) would suggest that
    CPG’s value has dropped roughly 30%.”
          “Required Equity Financing: We’ve raised almost $4 billion of capital (CPPL
    equity and CPGX debt) – at a very attractive cost of capital – during the first half of
    ’15 to launch CPG as a standalone company. Recall: because of our investment
    grade credit rating commitments, CPG cannot issue long-term debt until 2018.
    Consequently, to support CPG’s committed growth program AND maintain our
    investment grade credit ratings, CPG or CPPL still must issue between $3 billion
    and $4 billion of equity (i.e., +/- 65% of CPG’s current equity market capitalization)
    over the next three years (i.e., $1+ billion of equity per year).”
          “Track 1 – ‘Stay the Course’. Prepare to issue ~$1.0+ billion (~15% of CPG) of
    CPGX equity at +/-$18/share by mid-January. . . . The current thinking is that we
    would need to execute the transaction prior to our YE earnings disclosure (2/15) –
    when we are set to announce yet another increase (~$500 million) in our annual
    Cap-Ex plan (i.e., a near-term expansion of the equity overhang). Downside: if this
    approach doesn’t alleviate the equity overhang (and rather than a positive reaction,
    9
    Id.; see 
    id. (“[I]f there
    is a real or perceived expectation of reduced growth rates,
    all the more pressure is placed on the value of CPG’s currencies, thereby exacerbating the
    challenge.”); Mir Tr. 1198–1202 (discussing equity overhang at Columbia and CPPL
    levels); JX 1351 ¶¶ 100–01 (respondent’s expert opining that “disruption in the MLP
    market and [Columbia’s] equity overhang could have forced [Columbia] into issuing
    increasingly large numbers of shares to raise equity as the market drove down the value of
    [Columbia] shares in expectation of repeated [Columbia] equity issuances” (citing
    Jonathan Berk & Peter DeMarzo, Corporate Finance 888 (4th ed. 2017)).
    10
    CPGX/CPPL languishes), we face the real threat of ongoing value erosion.”
          “Track 2 – ‘Seek a Balance Sheet’. Explore whether Dominion or a select group of
    blue chip strategic players (e.g., MidAmerican ([Berkshire Hathaway Energy]),
    Sempra, Enbridge, TransCanada, and perhaps Spectra) would have a legitimate
    interest in CPG – at a price that’s within CPG’s intrinsic value range. . . . This
    approach would be an attempt to capture/optimize CPG’s intrinsic value (i.e., avoid
    selling 15% of CPGX at a deep discount); position shareholders to participate in the
    potential growth of the combined enterprise; fully fund our growth plan, and exert
    a measure of control over the fate of our employees and other key stakeholders.
    Downside: We believe there is no downside in ‘soft’ overtures to any or all of these
    potential counterparties. This approach shouldn’t ‘put us in play.’”
    JX 466.
    At a Board meeting held on October 19 and 20, 2015, Skaggs recommended a dual-
    track strategy in which Columbia would prepare for an equity offering while engaging in
    exploratory talks with potential strategic or financing partners. PTO ¶ 422. The Board
    agreed.
    F.     Renewed Talks With Possible Buyers
    On October 26, 2015, Skaggs renewed talks with Dominion. Skaggs offered
    exclusivity in return for a prompt offer of approximately $28 per share, but he expected
    Dominion to respond “in the 20–25% premium zip code ($24–$25).”10 That night Smith
    met with Poirier, who said that TransCanada wanted to buy Columbia. PTO ¶ 426; JX 487.
    On October 29, 2015, the Board decided to wait to hear from Dominion before
    responding to TransCanada. JX 1399 at 2. The Board determined that Columbia would
    have to sell substantial public equity unless it received a merger proposal for “around $28
    10
    
    Id. ¶ 425;
    see Skaggs Tr. 862–63; Cornelius Tr. 1133–34; see also JX 493.
    11
    per share.” PTO ¶ 428.
    On November 2, 2015, Dominion indicated that it could not offer $28 per share.
    Dominion proposed either (i) an all-stock merger with Dominion and its partner NextEra
    at an undefined “modest premium” or (ii) a Dominion equity investment in certain
    Columbia subsidiaries or joint ventures. See 
    id. ¶ 430.
    That day, Columbia’s stock closed
    at $21.12. Goldman believed that at this point, Columbia was trading “very close to ‘dcf’
    value, against a backdrop of having traded at a discount to dcf value.” JX 505.
    On November 7, 2015, Skaggs followed up with Dominion about the
    Dominion/NextEra structure. PTO ¶ 436. On November 9, Columbia and TransCanada
    entered into an NDA. 
    Id. ¶ 437.
    Over the next week, Columbia entered into additional
    NDAs with Dominion, NextEra, and Berkshire Hathaway Energy, and the NDA
    counterparties began conducting due diligence.11
    Each NDA contained a standstill provision that prohibited the counterparty from
    making any offer to buy Columbia securities without the Board’s prior written invitation.
    Most of the standstills lasted eighteen months. Each contained a feature colloquially known
    as a “don’t-ask-don’t-waive” provision (a “DADW”), which prohibited the counterparty
    from “making a request to amend or waive” the standstill or the NDA’s confidentiality
    11
    
    Id. ¶¶ 442–49,
    452–54. Goldman regarded Berkshire and TransCanada as the most
    likely buyers, followed by Dominion. See, e.g., JX 499 (“We know D[ominion] is
    interested, but at a price.”). Poirier expected an auction. See JX 528. He encouraged his
    colleagues to act quickly because Columbia had a “massive financing overhang” and was
    preparing to “prefund[] [its] 2016/17 capex with a $1bn equity issuance.” 
    Id. 12 restrictions.
    E.g., JX 526 § 3.
    Although due diligence was getting off the ground, Columbia management did not
    think they could delay an equity offering beyond early December 2015. And waiting until
    the last possible minute to raise equity exposed Columbia to risk. On November 17, 2015,
    the Board authorized management to proceed with the equity offering as early as the week
    of November 30. PTO ¶ 456.
    On November 24, 2015, TransCanada expressed interest in an all-cash acquisition
    at $25 to $26 per share. Berkshire expressed interest in an all-cash acquisition at $23.50
    per share. Both expressions of interest were conditioned on further diligence. Berkshire
    warned that an equity offering would “kill [its] conversation” with Columbia. 
    Id. ¶ 477.
    On November 25, 2015, the Board decided to terminate merger talks and proceed
    with the equity offering. Columbia sent letters to Dominion, NextEra, Berkshire, and
    TransCanada instructing them to destroy the confidential information they had received
    under their NDAs. NextEra was disappointed to lose the opportunity, but Dominion was
    happy to go elsewhere. Dominion had already reached out to Questar Corporation, and in
    February 2016, Dominion announced that it was buying Questar for $4.4 billion,
    effectively ending any prospect for a Columbia-Dominion merger. See, e.g., PTO ¶ 478;
    JX 890.
    Skaggs called TransCanada and Berkshire personally to reject their offers.
    TransCanada’s CEO, Russell Girling, asked if Columbia would forego the equity offering
    if TransCanada “close[d] the gap between $26 and $28 and we get it done before
    Christmas.” JX 588; see also JX 575 at 4. Skaggs said no. He explained that Columbia
    13
    could not risk a failed deal followed by a more expensive equity offering in 2016. See PTO
    ¶ 476; Skaggs Tr. 875–77; see also JX 594.
    The same day, Smith told Poirier that Columbia “probably” would want to pick up
    merger talks “in a few months.” JX 588; accord Poirier Tr. 384. Poirier believed that
    Columbia could have delayed its equity raise until January, but that Columbia went ahead
    to improve its bargaining position. Poirier also doubted whether Columbia’s directors
    shared management’s enthusiasm for a deal. JX 594.
    G.    The Equity Offering
    After the market closed on December 1, 2015, Columbia announced an equity
    offering at $17.50 per share. PTO ¶ 480. Columbia’s stock had closed that day at $19.05.
    
    Id. ¶ 481.
    The below-market offering was oversubscribed and raised net proceeds of $1.4
    billion. At trial, Skaggs described the offering as “an unmitigated disaster” because
    Columbia had “sold 25 percent of the company at 17.50.” Skaggs Tr. 890. Columbia had
    solved its short-term funding needs, but the overhang would persist without a long-term
    solution. See JX 1060 at 6; Poirier Tr. 450; Skaggs Dep. 139.
    After the equity offering, Skaggs met with Columbia’s directors individually to
    pitch them on selling the company. He emphasized that the business plan involved a
    “significant amount of execution risk (both financial and operational).” JX 646.
    In mid-December 2015, Poirier called Smith to reiterate TransCanada’s interest in
    a deal. They scheduled a meeting for January. Smith Tr. 236–37. Smith involved Skaggs
    and Goldman, but no one told the Board that Smith was continuing talks with
    14
    TransCanada.12 Internally, TransCanada believed that the equity offering had made a deal
    “more challenging from a valuation standpoint,” but regarded Columbia as a “very
    strategic” target. Poirier Tr. 445; accord Marchand Tr. 482.
    H.     The Poirier Meeting
    On January 5, 2016, Smith emailed Columbia’s draft 2016 management projections
    to Poirier. JX 680. Goldman prepared talking points for Smith to use with Poirier, and
    Skaggs approved them. See JX 679 (talking points advising that TransCanada could “avoid
    an auction process” with a “preemptive” price because “every dollar matters a lot to our
    Board”); Smith Tr. 248. The talking points were tailored to respond to positions
    TransCanada had taken during negotiations in November 2015, including TransCanada’s
    stance that it was “not inclined to participate in an auction process” because it would take
    “resources to get[] fully comfortable with the growth projects.” JX 575 at 4; see JX 589;
    JX 590. TransCanada had signaled that it would pay extra for exclusivity, and internally it
    was describing its price strategy as “preemptive.” See JX 575 at 4.
    On January 7, 2016, Smith met with Poirier. Smith literally handed him the list of
    talking points. Smith Tr. 247–48. Smith stressed that TransCanada was unlikely to face
    competition from major strategic players, telling TransCanada in substance that Columbia
    12
    See PTO ¶ 500; Smith Tr. 248; see also JX 646 (Goldman: “[TransCanada]
    indicated that they could be ~$28.00/share.”); Poirier Dep. 148 (“The goal posts of 26 and
    30 would translate to 24 and 28 post equity issuance.”).
    15
    had “‘eliminated’ the competition.”13 By doing so, Smith contravened Goldman’s advice
    from 2015 to the effect that “[c]ompetition (real or perceived) is the best way to drive
    bidders to their point of indifference.” JX 505.
    Poirier and Smith portrayed these unusual tactics as a good-faith effort to entice
    TransCanada to bid by assuring TransCanada that it would be worthwhile to engage in due
    diligence.14 But TransCanada was going to bid anyway, as it had before. It seems intuitive
    that Smith’s assurance about TransCanada not facing competition would have undermined
    Columbia’s bargaining leverage. At the same time, it is not clear how much of an effect
    the disclosure had, because TransCanada already knew about the company-specific
    problems that its competitors faced. See Poirier Tr. 435–36 (referring to “other potential
    suitors being distracted” as “public knowledge”).
    Regardless, on January 25, 2016, Girling called Skaggs to express interest in an all-
    cash acquisition in the range of $25 to $28 per share, similar to what TransCanada had
    proposed in November 2018. PTO ¶ 516. That day, Columbia’s stock closed at $17.25.
    13
    See JX 736 at 11; 
    id. (noting that
    Dominion (“capital, HSR”), Enbridge (“complex
    structure”), Energy Transfer Equity (“overextended”), and Kinder Morgan (“out of the
    market”) were unlikely to be suitors for Columbia); Poirier Dep. 149–52.
    14
    See Smith Tr. 343 (“It was to negotiate with him, to basically say . . . the market
    is in disarray. There are number of, you know, big players that are dealing with issues. This
    is your opportunity, you know, to step up to the plate and make an offer that will get the
    attention of the board.”); Poirier Dep. 150–51 (framing Smith’s approach as
    “encouragement to dedicate time and resources” by describing TransCanada’s strong odds
    of success at the right price); Poirier Tr. 435 (“He was simply trying to encourage us to be
    aggressive, that there was an opportunity for us to acquire this company.”).
    16
    I.    TransCanada Obtains Exclusivity.
    In the weeks leading up to Girling’s indication of interest, Skaggs had held a second
    round of one-on-one meetings with the Columbia directors, “priming them for a TC bid.”
    JX 1466; see 
    id. (Goldman indicating
    that Skaggs was “getting questions from the Board
    ‘would you take $26 per share’ – he said every day it gets harder to say no”). Lazard had
    advised Columbia’s management that “[w]hile your valuation has swung widely, the $25–
    28 range is a sensible one given what we have concluded is your DCF value right now.”
    JX 742.
    On January 28 and 29, 2016, the Board met with senior management, Goldman, and
    Columbia’s legal counsel from Sullivan & Cromwell LLP. TransCanada had indicated that
    it would not proceed unless granted exclusivity. The Columbia team considered whether
    to solicit alternative suitors like Dominion or Spectra. The Board determined that
    TransCanada’s indicative range offered a significant premium that outweighed the costs of
    exclusivity. See PTO ¶ 519; Kittrell Tr. 1061–62 (citing Goldman and Lazard’s
    recommendation); Taylor Tr. 1273–74 (citing high odds of closing and “great” premium).
    On February 1, 2016, Columbia granted TransCanada exclusivity through March 2,
    2016, which they later extended by six days (the “Exclusivity Agreement”). PTO ¶¶ 523,
    551. In simplified terms, Columbia could not accept or facilitate an acquisition proposal
    from anyone but TransCanada, except that in response to a “bona fide written unsolicited
    Transaction Proposal that did not result from a breach of” the Exclusivity Agreement,
    Columbia could engage with another party upon notice to TransCanada. In long form, the
    Exclusivity Agreement provided that Columbia could not
    17
    (a) solicit, initiate, encourage or accept any proposals or offers from
    any third person, other than [TransCanada], (i) relating to any acquisition or
    purchase of all or any material portion of the assets of [Columbia] or any of
    its subsidiaries, (ii) to enter into any merger, consolidation, reorganization,
    recapitalization, share exchange or other business combination transaction
    with [Columbia] or any subsidiary of [Columbia], (iii) to enter into any other
    extraordinary business transaction involving or otherwise relating to
    [Columbia] or any subsidiary of [Columbia], or (iv) relating to any
    acquisition or purchase of all or any material portion of the capital stock of
    [Columbia] or any subsidiary of [Columbia] (any proposal or offer described
    in any of clauses (i) through (iv) being a “Transaction Proposal”), or
    (b) participate in any discussions, conversations, negotiations or other
    communications regarding, furnish to any other person any information with
    respect to, or otherwise knowingly facilitate or encourage any effort or
    attempt by any other person to effect a Transaction Proposal;
    provided that in response to a bona fide written unsolicited
    Transaction Proposal that did not result from a breach of this letter agreement
    (an “Unsolicited Proposal”) [Columbia] may, after providing notice to
    [TransCanada] as required by this letter agreement,
    (1) enter into or participate in any discussions, conversations,
    negotiations or other communications with the person making the
    Unsolicited Proposal regarding such Unsolicited Proposal,
    (2) furnish to the person making the Unsolicited Proposal any
    information in furtherance of such Unsolicited Proposal (provided that to the
    extent such information has not been previously provided to [TransCanada],
    [Columbia] shall promptly provide such information to [TransCanada]) or
    (3) approve, recommend, declare advisable or accept, or propose to
    approve, recommend, declare advisable or accept, or enter into an agreement
    with respect to, an Unsolicited Proposal or any subsequent Transaction
    Proposal made by such person as a result of the discussions, conversations
    and negotiations or other communications described in clause (1), if the
    Board of Directors of [Columbia] determines in good faith, after consultation
    with its outside legal counsel, that the failure to do so would reasonably be
    expected to be a breach of its fiduciary duties under applicable law.
    JX 832 (formatting altered). The Exclusivity Agreement further provided that
    [Columbia] immediately shall cease and cause to be terminated all existing
    18
    discussions, conversations, negotiations and other communications with all
    third persons conducted heretofore with respect to any of the foregoing.
    [Columbia] shall
    (x) notify [TransCanada] promptly (and in any event within 24 hours)
    if any Unsolicited Proposal, or any substantive inquiry or contact with any
    person with respect thereto, is made and
    (y) in any such notice to [TransCanada], indicate the material terms
    and conditions of such Unsolicited Proposal, inquiry or contact, in the case
    of clause (y), except to the extent the Board of Directors of [Columbia]
    determines in good faith, after consultation with its outside legal counsel, that
    providing such information would not be in the best interests of [Columbia]
    and its stockholders.
    
    Id. (formatting altered).
    J.     TransCanada Conducts Due Diligence.
    On February 4, 2016, Columbia sent TransCanada a draft of the Merger Agreement.
    By February 5, TransCanada had sixty-nine personnel accessing Columbia’s data room.
    JX 784. A subset of the personnel comprised a clean team that received access to
    Columbia’s customer contracts, enabling TransCanada to assess Columbia’s counterparty
    risk by examining its customers’ creditworthiness. See Poirier Tr. 401–03. The parties have
    referred to these important contracts as “precedent agreements.”15
    15
    Broadly speaking, precedent agreements address future customer needs and can
    help justify pipeline expansion to regulators. E.g., Mayo Dep. 277 (“[Precedent agreements
    are] the agreements signed before the final contract.”). Columbia’s precedent agreements
    covered infrastructure construction and defined the quantities of natural gas to transport,
    transportation path, and terms of service. PTO ¶ 280. A party with access to the precedent
    agreements could discern whether a given Columbia customer “was an ExxonMobil” or “a
    single B grade producer” prone to default in a downturn. See Marchand Tr. 526; see also
    JX 815 (TransCanada due diligence memo finding credit terms relatively disappointing yet
    “normal for U.S. regulated natural gas pipeline projects”); JX 829 (analyst report stating
    19
    TransCanada had indicated that it would submit a bid by February 24, 2016, with
    the caveat that it needed backing from credit rating agencies. On February 19, the credit
    rating agencies warned TransCanada that acquiring Columbia could result in a downgrade.
    One said that TransCanada was “buying a BBB-mid asset and adding leverage.” JX 827.
    The other “observed that the resulting leverage from the transaction would be high in a
    difficult market with heightened counterparty concerns.” PTO ¶ 535. On February 24,
    Girling told Skaggs that TransCanada needed more time to develop a financing plan that
    allowed it to pay $25 to $28 per share without hurting its credit rating. 
    Id. ¶ 544.
    Meanwhile, Columbia and TransCanada continued to exchange drafts of the Merger
    Agreement.
    K.     Columbia Demands A Price.
    On March 4, 2016, the Board directed management to demand a merger proposal
    from TransCanada. On March 5, TransCanada offered $24 per share, below the low end of
    the range it had cited to secure exclusivity. Smith told Poirier that he could not recommend
    $24 per share to the Board, but could recommend $26.50. See PTO ¶ 563. TransCanada
    came back at $25.25, which it characterized as its best and final offer. 
    Id. When Skaggs
    called Girling to reject the offer, Girling said: “I guess that’s it.” JX 901. Skaggs told the
    Board that TransCanada was unlikely to reengage and that “[i]n the meantime, we have
    stopped all deal-work.” 
    Id. Poirier told
    Smith that TransCanada lacked room to move on
    that Columbia “requires credit support for non-I grade customers equivalent to 12–24
    months of demand charges”).
    20
    price. PTO ¶ 566.
    With merger talks on hold, TransCanada’s management debated how to justify
    paying more. 
    Id. ¶ 568;
    JX 912; see JX 907. Its CFO, Don Marchand, thought a deal “at
    $26 would be off-the-charts in terms of premium paid and the market reaction could be
    quite tepid.” PTO ¶ 568. He believed the transaction was “priced close to perfection at the
    $25.25 offer level.” 
    Id. TransCanada’s COO
    thought Columbia was “playing . . . poker to
    see where our barf price is.” JX 911 at 3. Poirier suggested floating a number like $25.75
    or $26, then asking Columbia for another month to find capital and sort out credit rating
    issues. JX 905 at 3. To fund the Merger, TransCanada ultimately would sell more than $7
    billion in assets and raise over $3 billion through the largest subscription receipts offering
    in Canadian history. JX 939; JX 1008 at 8, 13–14.
    On March 6, 2016, TransCanada’s management conveyed that they could support a
    price above $25.25 per share if Columbia’s management would support a price below
    $26.50. See PTO ¶ 569. After consulting with Skaggs and Cornelius, Smith asked Poirier
    to offer $26 per share. 
    Id. ¶¶ 570–71.
    Poirier replied that TransCanada’s board needed until
    March 9 to make a decision.
    L.     The Wall Street Journal Leaks The Merger Talks.
    On March 8, 2016, Columbia learned that the Wall Street Journal was preparing a
    story about TransCanada being in advanced discussions to acquire Columbia.
    TransCanada’s exclusivity expired that night. 
    Id. ¶¶ 579–81.
    On March 9, 2016, TransCanada made a revised offer at $26 per share, with 90% of
    the consideration in cash and 10% in TransCanada stock. The offer was subject to market
    21
    conditions and feedback from credit rating agencies and TransCanada’s underwriters.
    On March 10, 2016, the Board convened to discuss TransCanada’s proposal.16
    Skaggs reminded the Board that TransCanada’s exclusivity had expired. JX 1399 at 13.
    The Board discussed that the news story could lead to inbound offers. After the meeting,
    the Wall Street Journal broke the story.17
    M.     Spectra Reaches Out.
    After seeing the article, Spectra emailed Skaggs to propose merger talks.18 On
    March 11, 2016, the Board decided to renew TransCanada’s exclusivity through March 18,
    subject to further evaluation of Spectra. The Board also instructed management to waive
    the standstills with Berkshire, Dominion, and NextEra. See JX 1399 at 15; see also JX 950.
    The next day, management sent emails waiving the standstills. PTO ¶¶ 603–05.
    16
    In internal emails exchanged on March 10, 2016, TransCanada’s bankers
    discussed that “[t]he [Columbia] board is freaking out and told the management team to
    get a deal done with ‘whatever it takes’.. Oddly, the [Columbia] team has relayed this info
    to [TransCanada].” JX 938. This exchange could suggest that there was a path for
    Columbia to extract additional merger consideration from TransCanada, but the petitioners
    have not briefed this document, and I take no position on it.
    17
    See Ben Dummett et al., Keystone Pipeline Operator TransCanada in Takeover
    Talks, Wall St. J., March 10, 2016, https://www.wsj.com/articles/keystone-pipeline-
    operator-transcanada-in-takeover-talks-1457627686 (“TransCanada . . . is in takeover talks
    with Columbia Pipeline Group Inc., a U.S. natural-gas pipeline operator with a market
    value of about $9 billion. The companies could reach a deal in the coming weeks, according
    to people familiar with the matter.”).
    18
    JX 949. Goldman received calls too. See JX 951 at 3 (“One question [Skaggs]
    asked is shd [sic] we let [TransCanada] know we are getting calls.”); see also JX 948
    (Goldman banker indicating “[n]ot a lot of interest [from Columbia’s management] in
    engaging with Spectra. Would be all-stock deal, they don’t love Spectra’s assets.”).
    22
    On the morning of March 12, 2016, the Board determined that Spectra was unlikely
    to propose a deal superior to TransCanada’s latest offer. See JX 1399 at 15–16. Around
    this time, everyone at Columbia acted as if TransCanada’s exclusivity had already been
    renewed. The Board approved a script “to use with Spectra and other inbounds.” JX 964.
    It stated: “We will not comment on market speculation or rumors. With respect to
    indications of interest in pursuing a transaction, we will not respond to anything other than
    serious written proposals.” JX 1399 at 15–16.
    Based on advice from Goldman and Sullivan & Cromwell, Skaggs proposed to send
    the script to TransCanada. He described this move as a way to reassure TransCanada that
    its deal remained on track, and to pressure TransCanada to agree to an “expedited” closing.
    See JX 964. After the Board met on March 12, Columbia’s in-house counsel asked
    TransCanada to approve the script:
    [O]ur board has agreed to the renewal of the EA for one week subject to your
    agreement that this scripted response would not violate the terms of the EA
    (both in terms of the inbound received in the EA’s gap period and going
    forward until signing, which unfortunately, given the leak, there is a potential
    that we will receive additional inquiries). Please confirm via response to this
    email that [TransCanada] is in agreement with this condition/interpretation
    and we will send over the new EA.
    JX 968 at 2. Asking TransCanada whether the script violated the Exclusivity Agreement
    made no sense. Exclusivity had expired days before. Columbia’s in-house counsel also
    conveyed to TransCanada that Columbia had received “an inbound from a credible, large,
    midstream player,” without saying who it was. JX 973.
    The Board had instructed Goldman to screen Spectra’s calls so that Spectra could
    not talk directly with management. See JX 957; JX 1399 at 15–16. On March 12, Spectra’s
    23
    CFO called Goldman, and Goldman read the script. See JX 974 (Spectra’s CFO: “[The
    Goldman banker] said he had to read from a script that had two messages.”). The Spectra
    CFO told Goldman that “any indication of interest would have to be conditioned on further
    due diligence.” 
    Id. Spectra said
    it could “move quickly” and “be more specific subject to
    diligence,” but the script did not allow for that option. JX 970. As one Goldman banker put
    it: “Does [Spectra] ‘get it’ that they aren’t going to get diligence without a written
    proposal?” 
    Id. The inverted
    approach effectively shut out Spectra. TransCanada had not
    bid without due diligence, and no one else was going to either. See, e.g., JX 1399 at 3
    (discussing TransCanada’s need for “30 to 45 days of due diligence in order to firm up the
    potential offer”).
    Later on March 12, Spectra’s head of M&A made a follow-up call. He said to expect
    a written offer in the “next few days” absent a “major bust.” JX 992. The banker who took
    the call found Spectra’s assurance credible, but Skaggs and Smith were not interested.19
    The Board-approved script meant that Columbia could only entertain a “serious written
    proposal,” which Smith defined as
    19
    See 
    id. (Smith email
    to Goldman and management: “We need to think about what
    the protocol is if we get a letter. Presumably, the Board would have to respond officially,
    we would have to notify [TransCanada] and we should think about what our response is if
    they make it public after being rebuked.”); Skaggs Tr. 1021–22 (“Q. . . . During this stage
    when you were getting an inbound call from the CEO of Spectra, an inbound e-mail from
    the CEO of Spectra, a call from the CFO of Spectra to Goldman Sachs, and a call from the
    chief development officer of Goldman Sachs, did you, Mr. Skaggs, or another member of
    management, do anything to respond to Spectra? And since I’m going to anticipate what
    you’re going to say, other than tell Goldman to look at the script. A. That was it, sir. Q. So
    the answer’s no. A. No.”).
    24
    a bona fide proposal that says I will pay you X for your company. Hard and
    fast. No outs. No anything. No way to wiggle out of anything. This is going
    to happen. You’re going to pay whatever you’re going to pay per share and
    we’re going to sign that agreement and we’re done. I don’t know of any
    company that would do that in that short of a timeframe.
    Smith Tr. 272. Spectra never made a written offer, and TransCanada never faced
    competition or a meaningful threat of competition from the anonymous yet “credible,
    large” industry player that Columbia’s management had described. See Poirier Tr. 417–18.
    N.    TransCanada Changes Its Offer.
    On March 14, 2016, Columbia renewed TransCanada’s exclusivity through March
    18, making it retroactive to March 12. PTO ¶ 617; see JX 978. After the renewal, Skaggs
    learned that TransCanada was revising its offer. See JX 1005; JX 1006. Citing execution
    risk with the stock component, TransCanada reduced its offer from $26 per share to $25.50,
    all cash. PTO ¶ 618. TransCanada threatened that if Columbia did not accept its reduced
    offer, then TransCanada would “issue a press release within the next few days indicating
    its acquisition discussions had been terminated.” 
    Id. Exclusivity terminated
    automatically
    upon receipt of TransCanada’s reduced offer. See JX 978.
    At a telephonic meeting held the same day, the Board acknowledged that
    TransCanada was pushing Columbia to act before Spectra could make an offer.20 The
    Board decided to proceed with TransCanada as long as the termination fee in the Merger
    20
    See JX 1399 at 17 (“The Board . . . acknowledged that proceeding with
    TransCanada on the expedited timetable would mean that the Company would potentially
    be entering into the merger agreement without having the opportunity to consider [the]
    formal proposal from Spectra” that Goldman expected to arrive “in the next few days.”).
    25
    Agreement did not exceed 3% of equity value. See 
    id. On March
    15, 2016, Columbia and
    TransCanada agreed to a termination fee of 3%.
    O.     The Board Approves The Merger Agreement.
    On March 16 and 17, 2016, the Board convened to consider the Merger. Sullivan &
    Cromwell reviewed the Merger Agreement. Goldman and Lazard opined that the
    consideration was fair to Columbia’s stockholders. Goldman presented a DCF analysis that
    valued Columbia’s stock at $18.64–$23.50 per share. JX 1016 at 107. Lazard’s DCF ranges
    valued the stock at $18.88–$24.38 per share on a sum-of-the-parts basis and at $20.00–
    $25.50 per share on a consolidated basis. 
    Id. at 80;
    JX 1136 at 75–76. Other valuation
    methods generated higher and lower ranges.21 The Board determined that there was a
    serious risk that TransCanada would withdraw its offer if Columbia delayed signing to buy
    time for Spectra. The Board also determined that Spectra was unlikely to make a
    competitive offer, if it made one at all.22
    21
    See, e.g., JX 1016 at 78–79, 107; JX 1136 at 66, 74–77.
    22
    See PTO ¶ 625. The Board made a related determination that the renewed
    Exclusivity Agreement prohibited Columbia from soliciting an offer from Spectra or
    anyone else. See 
    id. That was
    inaccurate. The renewed Exclusivity Agreement expired
    upon “written notification to [Columbia] that [TransCanada] has determined that it is no
    longer interested in pursuing a Potential Transaction on terms at least as favorable to the
    stockholders of [Columbia] as the terms discussed . . . on March 10, 2016.” JX 978 at 4.
    TransCanada’s March 10 proposal offered $26 per share. TransCanada’s reduced offer of
    $25.50 per share terminated exclusivity. But if the Columbia directors had considered this
    fact, it would not have changed how they proceeded. When exclusivity terminated the first
    time, the Board acted as if it remained in place, and the script used with Spectra was the
    functional equivalent of exclusivity. See JX 968. The Board worried about losing the
    26
    At the conclusion of the meeting, the Board unanimously approved the Merger
    Agreement. Its terms provided for (i) a $309 million termination fee equal to 3% of the
    Merger’s equity value, (ii) a no-shop provision, and (iii) a fiduciary out that the Board
    could exercise after giving TransCanada four days to match any superior proposal. JX 1025
    §§ 4.02, 7.02(b).
    P.     Columbia’s Stockholders Approve the Merger.
    Columbia held a special meeting of stockholders on June 22, 2016, to consider the
    Merger. Holders of 73.9% of the outstanding shares voted in favor of the Merger. Holders
    of 95.3% of the shares present in person or by proxy at the meeting voted in favor of the
    Merger. PTO ¶¶ 5–6. The Merger closed on July 1, 2016.
    II.      LEGAL ANALYSIS
    “An appraisal proceeding is a limited legislative remedy intended to provide
    shareholders dissenting from a merger on grounds of inadequacy of the offering price with
    a judicial determination of the intrinsic worth (fair value) of their shareholdings.” Cede &
    Co. v. Technicolor, Inc. (Technicolor I), 
    542 A.2d 1182
    , 1186 (Del. 1988). Section 262(h)
    of the Delaware General Corporation Law states that
    the Court shall determine the fair value of the shares exclusive of any element
    of value arising from the accomplishment or expectation of the merger or
    consolidation, together with interest, if any, to be paid upon the amount
    determined to be the fair value. In determining such fair value, the Court shall
    take into account all relevant factors.
    TransCanada offer, and it regarded that risk as outweighing the benefit of an expedited
    solicitation process involving other bidders.
    27
    
    8 Del. C
    . § 262(h). The statute thus places the obligation to determine the fair value of the
    shares squarely on the court. Gonsalves v. Straight Arrow Publ’rs, Inc., 
    701 A.2d 357
    , 361
    (Del. 1997).
    Because of the statutory mandate, the allocation of the burden of proof in an
    appraisal proceeding differs from a traditional liability proceeding. “In a statutory appraisal
    proceeding, both sides have the burden of proving their respective valuation positions . . .
    .” M.G. Bancorp., Inc. v. Le Beau, 
    737 A.2d 513
    , 520 (Del. 1999). “No presumption,
    favorable or unfavorable, attaches to either side’s valuation . . . .” Pinson v. Campbell-
    Taggart, Inc., 
    1989 WL 17438
    , at *6 (Del. Ch. Feb. 28, 1989). “Each party also bears the
    burden of proving the constituent elements of its valuation position . . . , including the
    propriety of a particular method, modification, discount, or premium.” Jesse A. Finkelstein
    & John D. Hendershot, Appraisal Rights in Mergers and Consolidations, Corp. Prac. Series
    (BNA) No. 38-5th, at A-90 (2010 & 2017 Supp.) [hereinafter Appraisal Rights].
    As in other civil cases, the standard of proof in an appraisal proceeding is a
    preponderance of the evidence. M.G. 
    Bancorp., 737 A.2d at 520
    . A party is not required to
    prove its valuation conclusion, the related valuation inputs, or its underlying factual
    contentions by clear and convincing evidence or to exacting certainty. See Triton Constr.
    Co. v. E. Shore Elec. Servs., Inc., 
    2009 WL 1387115
    , at *6 (Del. Ch. May 18, 2009), aff’d,
    
    2010 WL 376924
    (Del. Jan. 14, 2010) (ORDER). “Proof by a preponderance of the
    evidence means proof that something is more likely than not. It means that certain
    evidence, when compared to the evidence opposed to it, has the more convincing force and
    makes you believe that something is more likely true than not.” Agilent Techs., Inc. v.
    28
    Kirkland, 
    2010 WL 610725
    , at *13 (Del. Ch. Feb. 18, 2010) (internal quotation marks
    omitted).
    “In discharging its statutory mandate, the Court of Chancery has discretion to select
    one of the parties’ valuation models as its general framework or to fashion its own.” M.G.
    
    Bancorp., 737 A.2d at 525
    –26. “The Court may evaluate the valuation opinions submitted
    by the parties, select the most representative analysis, and then make appropriate
    adjustments to the resulting valuation.” Appraisal 
    Rights, supra
    , at A-31 (collecting cases).
    The court also may “make its own independent valuation calculation by . . . adapting or
    blending the factual assumptions of the parties’ experts.” M.G. 
    Bancorp., 737 A.2d at 524
    .
    It is also “entirely proper for the Court of Chancery to adopt any one expert’s model,
    methodology, and mathematical calculations, in toto, if that valuation is supported by
    credible evidence and withstands a critical judicial analysis on the record.” 
    Id. at 526.
    “If
    neither party satisfies its burden, however, the court must then use its own independent
    judgment to determine fair value.” Gholl v. eMachines, Inc., 
    2004 WL 2847865
    , at *5 (Del.
    Ch. Nov. 24, 2004).
    In Tri-Continental Corporation v. Battye, 
    74 A.2d 71
    (Del. 1950), the Delaware
    Supreme Court explained in detail the concept of value that the appraisal statute employs:
    The basic concept of value under the appraisal statute is that the stockholder
    is entitled to be paid for that which has been taken from him, viz., his
    proportionate interest in a going concern. By value of the stockholder’s
    proportionate interest in the corporate enterprise is meant the true or intrinsic
    value of his stock which has been taken by the merger. In determining what
    figure represents the true or intrinsic value, . . . the courts must take into
    consideration all factors and elements which reasonably might enter into the
    fixing of value. Thus, market value, asset value, dividends, earning
    prospects, the nature of the enterprise and any other facts which were known
    29
    or which could be ascertained as of the date of the merger and which throw
    any light on future prospects of the merged corporation are not only pertinent
    to an inquiry as to the value of the dissenting stockholder’s interest, but must
    be considered . . . .23
    Subsequent Delaware Supreme Court decisions have adhered consistently to this definition
    of value.24 Most recently, the Delaware Supreme Court reiterated that “[f]air value is . . .
    23
    
    Id. at 72.
    Although Battye is the seminal Delaware Supreme Court case on point,
    Chancellor Josiah Wolcott initially established the meaning of “value” under the appraisal
    statute in Chicago Corporation v. Munds, 
    172 A. 452
    (Del. Ch. 1934). Citing the “material
    variance” between the Delaware appraisal statute, which used “value,” and the comparable
    New Jersey statute that served as a model for the Delaware statute, which used “full market
    value,” Chancellor Wolcott held that the plain language of the statute required “value” to
    be determined on a “going concern” basis. 
    Id. at 453–55.
    But see Union Ill. 1995 Inv. Ltd.
    P’ship v. Union Fin. Gp., Ltd., 
    847 A.2d 340
    , 355–56 (Del. Ch. 2004) (“This requirement
    that the valuation inquiry focus on valuing the entity as a going concern has sometimes
    been confused as a requirement of § 262’s literal terms. It is not.”). The going-concern
    standard also tracks the judicially endorsed account in which the appraisal statute arose “as
    a means to compensate shareholders of Delaware corporations for the loss of their common
    law right to prevent a merger or consolidation by refusal to consent to such transactions.”
    See, e.g., Alabama By-Products Corp. v. Cede & Co., 
    657 A.2d 254
    , 258 (Del. 1995). As
    Battye explains, the appraisal statute calls for valuing the corporation as a going concern,
    using its operative reality as it then existed as a standalone entity, because that is the
    alternative that the dissenters wished to maintain. 
    Battye, 74 A.2d at 72
    . Commentators
    have questioned the accuracy of the historical trade-off, but it remains part of the
    foundational understanding that has informed the concept of fair value. See Lawrence A.
    Hamermesh & Michael L. Wachter, The Fair Value of Cornfields in Delaware Appraisal
    Law, 31 J. Corp. L. 119, 130 n.52 (2005) (“The historical accuracy of this trade-off story
    is questionable, however, given the fact that the appraisal remedy was often added well
    after the adoption of statutes permitting mergers without unanimous consent.” (citing
    Robert B. Thompson, Exit, Liquidity, and Majority Rule: Appraisal’s Role in Corporate
    Law, 84 Geo L.J. 1, 14 (1995))).
    24
    See, e.g., Montgomery Cellular Hldg. Co. v. Dobler, 
    880 A.2d 206
    , 222 (Del.
    2005); Paskill Corp. v. Alcoma Corp., 
    747 A.2d 549
    , 553 (Del. 2000); Rapid-Am. Corp. v.
    Harris, 
    603 A.2d 796
    , 802 (Del. 1992); Cavalier Oil Corp. v. Harnett, 
    564 A.2d 1137
    ,
    1144 (Del. 1989); Bell v. Kirby Lumber Corp., 
    413 A.2d 137
    , 141 (Del. 1980); Universal
    City Studios, Inc. v. Francis I. duPont & Co., 
    334 A.2d 216
    , 218 (Del. 1975).
    30
    the value of the company to the stockholder as a going concern,” i.e. the stockholder’s
    “proportionate interest in a going concern.” Verition P’rs Master Fund Ltd. v. Aruba
    Networks, Inc., 
    210 A.3d 128
    , 132–33 (Del. 2019).
    The trial court’s “ultimate goal in an appraisal proceeding is to determine the ‘fair
    or intrinsic value’ of each share on the closing date of the merger.” Dell, Inc. v. Magnetar
    Global Event Driven Master Fund Ltd., 
    177 A.3d 1
    , 20 (Del. 2017) (quoting Cavalier 
    Oil, 564 A.2d at 1142
    –43). To accomplish this task, “the court should first envisage the entire
    pre-merger company as a ‘going concern,’ as a standalone entity, and assess its value as
    such.” 
    Id. (quoting Cavalier
    Oil, 564 A.2d at 1144
    ). When doing so, the corporation “must
    be valued as a going concern based upon the ‘operative reality’ of the company as of the
    time of the merger,” taking into account its particular market position in light of future
    prospects. M.G. 
    Bancorp., 737 A.2d at 525
    (quoting Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc.
    (Technicolor IV), 
    684 A.2d 289
    , 298 (Del. 1996)); accord 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 20
    . The
    concept of the corporation’s “operative reality” is important because “[t]he underlying
    assumption in an appraisal valuation is that the dissenting shareholders would be willing
    to maintain their investment position had the merger not occurred.” Technicolor 
    IV, 684 A.2d at 298
    . Consequently, the trial court must assess “the value of the company . . . as a
    going concern, rather than its value to a third party as an acquisition.” M.P.M. Enters., Inc.
    v. Gilbert, 
    731 A.2d 790
    , 795 (Del. 1999).
    “The time for determining the value of a dissenter’s shares is the point just before
    the merger transaction ‘on the date of the merger.’” Appraisal 
    Rights, supra
    , at A-33
    (quoting Technicolor 
    I, 542 A.2d at 1187
    ). Put differently, the valuation date is the date on
    31
    which the merger closes. Technicolor 
    IV, 684 A.2d at 298
    ; accord M.G. 
    Bancorp., 737 A.2d at 525
    . If the value of the corporation changes between the signing of the merger
    agreement and the closing, then the fair value determination must be measured by the
    “operative reality” of the corporation at the effective time of the merger. See Technicolor
    
    IV, 684 A.2d at 298
    .
    The statutory obligation to make a single determination of a corporation’s value
    introduces an impression of false precision into appraisal jurisprudence.
    [I]t is one of the conceits of our law that we purport to declare something as
    elusive as the fair value of an entity on a given date . . . . [V]aluation decisions
    are impossible to make with anything approaching complete confidence.
    Valuing an entity is a difficult intellectual exercise, especially when business
    and financial experts are able to organize data in support of wildly divergent
    valuations for the same entity. For a judge who is not an expert in corporate
    finance, one can do little more than try to detect gross distortions in the
    experts’ opinions. This effort should, therefore, not be understood, as a
    matter of intellectual honesty, as resulting in the fair value of a corporation
    on a given date. The value of a corporation is not a point on a line, but a range
    of reasonable values, and the judge’s task is to assign one particular value
    within this range as the most reasonable value in light of all the relevant
    evidence and based on considerations of fairness.25
    Because the determination of fair value follows a litigated proceeding, the issues that the
    court considers and the outcome it reaches depend in large part on the arguments advanced
    25
    Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc., 
    2003 WL 23700218
    , at *2 (Del. Ch. Dec. 31,
    2003), as revised (July 9, 2004), aff’d in part, rev’d in part on other grounds, 
    884 A.2d 26
    (Del. 2005); accord Finkelstein v. Liberty Dig., Inc., 
    2005 WL 1074364
    , at *12 (Del. Ch.
    Apr. 25, 2005) (“The judges of this court are unremittingly mindful of the fact that a
    judicially selected determination of fair value is just that, a law-trained judge’s estimate
    that bears little resemblance to a scientific measurement of a physical reality. Cloaking
    such estimates in grand terms like ‘intrinsic value’ does not obscure this hard truth from
    any informed commentator.”).
    32
    and the evidence presented.
    An argument may carry the day in a particular case if counsel advance it
    skillfully and present persuasive evidence to support it. The same argument
    may not prevail in another case if the proponents fail to generate a similarly
    persuasive level of probative evidence or if the opponents respond
    effectively.
    Merion Capital L.P. v. Lender Processing Servs., L.P., 
    2016 WL 7324170
    , at *16 (Del.
    Ch. Dec. 16, 2016). Likewise, the approach that an expert espouses may have met “the
    approval of this court on prior occasions,” but may be rejected in a later case if not
    presented persuasively or if “the relevant professional community has mined additional
    data and pondered the reliability of past practice and come, by a healthy weight of reasoned
    opinion, to believe that a different practice should become the norm . . . .” Global GT LP
    v. Golden Telecom, Inc. (Golden Telecom Trial), 
    993 A.2d 497
    , 517 (Del. Ch.), aff’d, 
    11 A.3d 214
    (Del. 2010).
    In this case, the parties proposed three valuation indicators: (i) the deal price minus
    synergies, (ii) Columbia’s unaffected trading price, and (iii) a DCF analysis. The
    petitioners relied on the DCF analysis. The respondent relied on the other two metrics.
    Although technically the respondent in an appraisal proceeding is the surviving company,
    the acquirer is typically the real party in interest on the respondent’s side of the case. In
    this case, that party is TransCanada. Reflecting this reality, this decision refers to the
    respondent’s arguments as TransCanada’s.
    A.     Deal Price
    TransCanada contends that the deal price of $25.50 per share is a reliable indicator
    of fair value if adjusted downward to eliminate elements of value arising from the Merger.
    33
    The petitioners argue that the deal price should receive no weight, but that if it does receive
    weight, then it should be adjusted upward to reflect improvements in value that Columbia
    experienced between signing and closing. As the proponent of using the deal price,
    TransCanada bore the burden of establishing its persuasiveness. Each side bore the burden
    of proving its respective adjustments.
    1.     Guidance Regarding How To Approach The Deal Price
    In three recent decisions, the Delaware Supreme Court has endorsed using the deal
    price in an arm’s-length transaction as evidence of fair value.26 In each decision, the
    Delaware Supreme Court weighed in on aspects of the sale process that made the deal price
    a reliable indicator of fair value, both by describing guiding principles and by applying
    them to the facts of the case. These important decisions illuminate what a trial court should
    consider when assessing the deal price as a valuation indicator.
    a.     DFC
    The first decision—DFC—involved the acquisition of a payday lender (DFC
    Global) by a private equity firm (Lone Star). In re Appraisal of DFC Glob. Corp. (DFC
    Trial), 
    2016 WL 3753123
    , at *1 (Del. Ch. July 8, 2016) (subsequent history omitted). The
    respondent urged the court to rely on the deal price as the most reliable evidence of fair
    value. 
    Id. To assess
    the deal price, the trial court examined the strength of the sale process,
    26
    See 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 135
    ; 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 23
    ; DFC Glob. Corp. v. Muirfield
    Value P’rs, 
    172 A.3d 346
    , 367 (Del. 2017).
    34
    explaining that the deal price “is reliable only when the market conditions leading to the
    transaction are conducive to achieving a fair price.” 
    Id. The pre-signing
    sale process for DFC Global lasted two years, but proceeded in fits
    and starts. In April 2012, DFC Global hired a banker to explore a sale to a private equity
    firm. 
    Id. at *3.
    The banker selected six firms, and a seventh expressed interest
    independently. By September 2012, none had bid, and the banker spent the next year
    reaching out to another thirty-five private equity firms and three potential strategic buyers.
    In September 2013, two private equity firms—Crestview Partners and J.C. Flowers
    & Co.—expressed interest in a joint acquisition. In December 2013, Lone Star expressed
    interest in a transaction at $12.16 per share. After Crestview withdrew from the joint bid,
    J.C. Flowers expressed interest in a transaction at $13.50 per share.
    During due diligence, DFC Global provided both bidders with a lowered set of
    projections, leading Lone Star to reduce its expression of interest to $11 per share. In March
    2014, DFC Global entered into exclusive negotiations with Lone Star. During the
    exclusivity period, DFC Global provided an even lower forecast, and Lone Star dropped
    its formal bid to $9.50 per share. Lone Star gave DFC Global twenty-four hours to accept,
    but later extended the deadline by five days. DFC Global accepted, and the parties
    announced the transaction publicly on April 2, 2014. It closed on June 13, 2014. 
    Id. at *4.
    In the appraisal proceeding, the court first worked through the parties’ DCF
    valuations and the respondent’s comparable-companies analysis. Having done so, the court
    turned to the deal price, describing it as “an appropriate factor to consider” and observing
    that the company “was purchased by a third-party buyer in an arm’s-length sale” after a
    35
    process that “lasted approximately two years and involved [DFC Global’s] advisor
    reaching out to dozens of financial sponsors as well as several potential strategic buyers.”
    
    Id. at *21.
    The court noted that the deal “did not involve the potential conflicts of interest
    inherent in a management buyout or negotiations to retain existing management . . . .” 
    Id. Instead, Lone
    Star took the opposite approach and replaced most of the key executives. 
    Id. At the
    same time, the court expressed concern that DFC Global was facing a period of
    regulatory uncertainty in which it could not access its full range of strategic options. The
    evidence also indicated that Lone Star had “focused its attention on achieving a certain
    internal rate of return and on reaching a deal within its financing constraints, rather than on
    [DFC Global’s] fair value.” 
    Id. at *22.
    The trial court also observed that Lone Star had
    secured exclusivity during a critical phase of the sale process and pressured the company
    into the final price with an exploding offer. 
    Id. at *23.
    The post-signing phase, by contrast,
    was relatively open, with a termination fee that “was reasonable and bifurcated to allow
    for a reduced fee in the event of a superior proposal.” 
    Id. The trial
    court ultimately concluded that each of the three indicators that the parties
    advanced—the DCF analysis, the comparable-companies analysis, and the deal price—had
    limitations. But all three provided meaningful insight into DFC Global’s value, and all
    three fell within a reasonable range. The court therefore averaged them, arriving at a
    valuation of $10.21 per share. 
    Id. That outcome
    reflected a premium of 7.5% over the deal
    price of $9.50 per share.
    On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court reversed. In its first argument for reversal,
    the respondent contended that the Delaware Supreme Court should presume that the deal
    36
    price reflects fair value under specified conditions, effectively asking the Delaware
    Supreme Court to overrule its decision in Golden Telecom, Inc. v. Global GT LP, 
    11 A.3d 214
    (Del. 2010). There, the high court had rejected a similar request to establish a
    presumption, explaining that “Section 262(h) neither dictates nor even contemplates that
    the Court of Chancery should consider the transactional market price of the underlying
    company. Rather, in determining ‘fair value,’ the statute instructs that the court ‘shall take
    into account all relevant factors.’” 
    Id. at 217
    (quoting 
    8 Del. C
    . § 262(h)). The Golden
    Telecom decision observed that “[r]equiring the Court of Chancery to defer—conclusively
    or presumptively—to the merger price, even in the face of a pristine, unchallenged
    transactional process, would contravene the unambiguous language of the statute and the
    reasoned holdings of our precedent.” 
    Id. at 218.
    In DFC, the Delaware Supreme Court again declined to establish a presumption, but
    cautioned that its
    refusal to craft a statutory presumption in favor of the deal price when certain
    conditions pertain does not in any way signal our ignorance to the economic
    reality that the sale value resulting from a robust market check will often be
    the most reliable evidence of fair value, and that second-guessing the value
    arrived upon by the collective views of many sophisticated parties with a real
    stake in the matter is hazardous.
    
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 366
    . The justices also cautioned that “we have little quibble with the
    economic argument that the price of a merger that results from a robust market check,
    against the back drop of a rich information base and a welcoming environment for potential
    buyers, is probative of the company’s fair value.” 
    Id. 37 The
    Delaware Supreme Court then elaborated on what fair value means when
    evaluating a deal price:
    [F]air value is just that, “fair.” It does not mean the highest possible price
    that a company might have sold for had Warren Buffett negotiated for it on
    his best day and the Lenape who sold Manhattan on their worst. . . .
    Capitalism is rough and ready, and the purpose of an appraisal is not to make
    sure that the petitioners get the highest conceivable value that might have
    been procured had every domino fallen out of the company’s way; rather, it
    is to make sure that they receive fair compensation for their shares in the
    sense that it reflects what they deserve to receive based on what would fairly
    be given to them in an arm’s-length transaction.
    
    Id. at 370–71.
    Addressing the merits, the Delaware Supreme Court reversed the trial court’s
    determination of fair value, noting that the trial court had made the following post-trial
    findings of fact:
    i)     the transaction resulted from a robust market search that lasted
    approximately two years in which financial and strategic buyers had
    an open opportunity to buy without inhibition of deal protections;
    ii)    the company was purchased by a third party in an arm’s length sale;
    and
    iii)   there was no hint of self-interest that compromised the market check.
    
    Id. at 349
    (formatting altered). The high court further observed that
    [a]lthough there is no presumption in favor of the deal price, under the
    conditions found by the Court of Chancery, economic principles suggest that
    the best evidence of fair value was the deal price, as it resulted from an open
    process, informed by robust public information, and easy access to deeper,
    non-public information, in which many parties with an incentive to make a
    profit had a chance to bid.
    
    Id. 38 The
    Delaware Supreme Court cited “the failure of other buyers to pursue the
    company when they had a free chance to do so” as one of several “objective factors that
    support the fairness of the price paid . . . .” 
    Id. at 376.
    The high court also observed that
    Lone Star “was subjected to a competitive process of bidding[.]” 
    Id. at 350.
    That finding
    was supported by the competition between Lone Star and J.C. Flowers before signing and
    the passive market check after signing. The Delaware Supreme Court also explained that
    “the fact that the ultimate buyer was alone at the end provides no basis for suspicion” given
    the trial court’s findings that
    i)      there was no conflict of interest;
    ii)     [DFC Global’s investment banker] had approached every logical
    buyer;
    iii)    no one was willing to bid more in the months leading up to the
    transaction before management significantly adjusted downward its
    projections; and
    iv)     management continued to miss its targets after Lone Star was the only
    buyer remaining.
    
    Id. at 376
    (formatting altered). The Delaware Supreme Court found that “the record does
    not include the sorts of flaws in the sale process that could lead one to reasonably suspect
    that the ultimate price paid by Lone Star was not reflective of DFC’s fair value.” 
    Id. Based on
    this analysis, the Delaware Supreme Court determined that the Court of
    Chancery’s “decision to give one-third weight to each metric was unexplained and in
    tension with the Court of Chancery’s own findings about the robustness of the market
    check.” 
    Id. at 388.
    The senior tribunal therefore remanded the case for the trial court to
    “reassess [its] conclusion as to fair value in light of our decision.” 
    Id. at 388–89.
    39
    b.     Dell
    The second decision—Dell—involved a management buyout of Dell Inc. in which
    its founder and CEO (Michael Dell) teamed up with a private equity firm (Silver Lake) to
    acquire the company. When the merger agreement was signed, the deal price was $13.65
    per share. With the stockholder vote trending against the merger, the buyout group
    increased its bid to $13.75 per share (the “Final Merger Consideration”).
    The respondent contended that the Final Merger Consideration was the best
    evidence of Dell’s fair value on the closing date. In re Appraisal of Dell Inc. (Dell Trial),
    
    2016 WL 3186538
    , at *21 (Del. Ch. May 31, 2016) (subsequent history omitted). To
    analyze this contention, the trial court separately examined the pre- and post-signing phases
    of the transaction process.
    The trial court found that bidding during the pre-signing phase had not produced
    fair value. Three factors contributed to this determination: (i) the bidders’ use of leveraged-
    buyout models to price their bids, (ii) evidence that the stock market had undervalued Dell
    by focusing on its disappointing short-term prospects, and (iii) limited pre-signing
    competition. See 
    id. at *29–37.
    For present purposes, the third factor is most pertinent. The trial court determined
    that pre-signing competition was limited because Dell’s special committee only invited one
    other private equity firm to compete with Silver Lake at any given time, and all of the firms
    priced the deal using the same leveraged-buyout financing model that Silver Lake had used.
    See 
    id. at *9–10,
    *30–31, *37. The committee did not approach strategic buyers during the
    pre-signing phase, in part because one of the committee’s financial advisors (Evercore)
    40
    discouraged the committee from contacting a wider universe of buyers until the go-shop
    process, when the advisor would earn a premium for generating a higher bid. 
    Id. at *6,
    *11.
    The committee’s other financial advisor (JPMorgan) expressed concern about the absence
    of a competitive dynamic and its effect on the bidding. See 
    id. at *6,
    *37.
    Having found that the pre-signing phase failed to support the reliability of the deal
    price, the trial court examined whether the post-signing phase validated it. The merger
    agreement contemplated a go-shop period, and during this phase, two financial sponsors
    emerged with competing recapitalizations. In response, and to secure a favorable
    stockholder vote, the buyout group increased its price to the Final Merger Consideration.
    
    Id. at *14,
    *16–18, *37–38. The trial court found that the results of the go-shop ruled out
    a large gap between the Final Merger Consideration and fair value, because if Dell’s value
    had approached what the petitioners claimed, then a strategic bidder would have
    intervened. But the trial court also concluded that impediments to bidding undercut the
    reliability of the go-shop as a price-discovery tool, citing (i) the magnitude of the
    transaction, (ii) Mr. Dell’s participation in the buyout group, including his financial
    incentives as a net buyer of shares and his valuable relationships with customers, and (iii)
    information asymmetries between the buyout group and competing bidders. See 
    id. at *40–
    44.
    Having concluded that the respondent did not carry its burden of proving the
    reliability of the deal price, the trial court relied on a DCF analysis. After resolving various
    disputes between the parties, the trial court made a fair-value determination of $17.62 per
    share, a result 28% over the deal price. This outcome appeared consistent with the result
    41
    from the sale process, because it exceeded what a financial sponsor would pay under a
    leveraged-buyout model, but was below the level where the valuation gap would be
    sufficiently attractive for a strategic buyer to intervene. It suggested that the company’s
    best option was to remain independent and ride out what appeared to be a trough in the
    stock price. The trial court perceived that this dynamic permitted the buyout group to take
    the company private at a premium to market but at a discount to fair value. See 
    id. at *51.
    On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court reversed. Consistent with its earlier
    decisions in Golden Telecom and DFC, the high court stressed that that “there is no
    requirement that the court assign some mathematical weight to the deal price . . . .” 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 23
    . But on the facts presented, the high court held that the trial court “erred in
    not assigning any mathematical weight to the deal price” under circumstances suggesting
    that “the deal price deserved heavy, if not dispositive weight.” Id.; accord 
    id. at 30
    (“Overall, the weight of evidence shows that Dell’s deal price has heavy, if not overriding,
    probative value.”).
    The Delaware Supreme Court explained that Dell’s sale process featured “fair play,
    low barriers to entry, outreach to all logical buyers, and the chance for any topping bidder
    to have the support of Mr. Dell’s own votes . . . .” 
    Id. at 35.
    In reaching this conclusion, the
    Delaware Supreme Court viewed the pre-signing process favorably, noting that (i) the
    members of the special committee who ran the sale process were “independent,
    experienced . . . and armed with the power to say ‘no,’” (ii) the committee persuaded the
    buyout group to raise its bid six times, from an initial range of $11.22-to-$12.16 to $13.65,
    and (iii) there was “[n]othing in the record [that] suggests that increased competition would
    42
    have produced a better result.” 
    Id. at 11,
    28. The Delaware Supreme Court also cited “leaks
    that Dell was exploring strategic alternatives,” which corroborated Evercore’s assumption
    that “interested parties would have approached the Company before the go-shop if serious
    about pursuing a deal.” 
    Id. at 28.
    Finally, the high court cited JPMorgan’s view that “any
    other financial sponsor would have bid in the same ballpark as Silver Lake.” 
    Id. The Delaware
    Supreme Court also viewed the post-signing process favorably. The
    high court cited the number of parties that the committee’s bankers contacted and the fact
    that the go-shop’s structure was more flexible than other go-shops. 
    Id. at 29.
    As with its
    assessment of the pre-signing phase, the Delaware Supreme Court stressed the absence of
    evidence that another party was interested in proceeding, explaining that “[f]air value
    entails at minimum a price some buyer is willing to pay—not a price at which no class of
    buyers in the market would pay.” Id.; see 
    id. at 32,
    34. The absence of a higher bid meant
    “that the deal market was already robust and that a topping bid involved a serious risk of
    overpayment[,]” which in turn “suggests the price is already at a level that is fair.” 
    Id. at 33.
    Although it reversed the trial court’s finding of fair value, the Delaware Supreme
    Court did not require that the trial court adopt the deal price: “Despite the sound economic
    and policy reasons supporting the use of the deal price as the fair value award on remand,
    we will not give in to the temptation to dictate that result.” 
    Id. at 44.
    The high court left it
    to the trial judge to reach his own conclusion, while “giv[ing] the [trial judge] the discretion
    on remand to enter judgment at the deal price if he so chooses, with no further
    proceedings.” 
    Id. 43 c.
         Aruba
    The third decision—Aruba—involved the acquisition of a technology company
    (Aruba Networks) by a much larger competitor (Hewlett-Packard). See Verition P’rs
    Master Fund Ltd. v. Aruba Networks, Inc. (Aruba Trial), 
    2018 WL 922139
    (Del. Ch. Feb.
    15, 2018) (subsequent history omitted). The respondent asked the court to give heavy
    weight to the deal price. To evaluate its reliability, the trial court examined the sale process
    in light of the Delaware Supreme Court’s decisions in Dell and DFC.
    The pre-signing sale process in Aruba had two phases. In late August 2014, HP
    approached Aruba about a deal. 
    Id. at *7–8.
    Aruba hired an investment banker (Qatalyst),
    and the banker and Aruba management anticipated obtaining a deal for around $30 per
    share. 
    Id. at *9.
    The companies entered into an NDA that restricted HP from speaking with
    Aruba management about post-transaction employment, and HP began conducting due
    diligence. After receiving projections from Aruba, HP determined that with synergies, the
    pro forma value of acquiring Aruba was as high as $32.05 per share. 
    Id. at *11.
    Meanwhile,
    Qatalyst identified thirteen potential partners and approached five of them. For reasons
    having “nothing to do with price,” none was interested. 
    Id. at *10.
    Despite the restriction in the NDA, HP asked Aruba’s CEO, Dominic Orr, to take
    on a key role with the combined entity. Orr replied that he had no objection. 
    Id. at *11.
    The
    parties seemed to be making progress towards a deal, but the HP board of directors balked
    at making a bid without further analysis, recalling the fallout from HP’s disastrous
    acquisition of Autonomy Corporation PLC in 2011. By the end of November 2014, Orr felt
    44
    the process had dragged on long enough, and with the approval of the Aruba board, he
    terminated the discussions. 
    Id. at *12.
    For its part, HP continued to evaluate an acquisition of Aruba. In December 2014,
    HP tapped Barclays Capital Inc. as its financial advisor, a firm that had worked for Aruba
    and had been trying for months to secure the sell-side engagement. 
    Id. at *13.
    On January
    21, 2015, HP’s CEO met Orr for dinner. During the meeting, when HP’s CEO proposed
    resuming merger talks, Orr responded positively and suggested trying to announce a deal
    by early March. But HP’s CEO also told Orr that because Qatalyst had represented
    Autonomy when HP acquired it, HP would not proceed if Aruba used Qatalyst. 
    Id. at *14.
    The Aruba board decided to move forward with the deal and informed Qatalyst
    about HP’s ukase. Aruba was obligated to pay Qatalyst a fee in the event of a successful
    transaction, so it kept Qatalyst on as a behind-the-scenes advisor. From then on, Qatalyst’s
    primary goal was to repair its relationship with HP, and Qatalyst regarded a successful sale
    of Aruba to HP as a key step in the right direction. Aruba also needed a new HP-facing
    banker. It hired Evercore, a firm that was trying to establish a presence in Silicon Valley.
    During the sale process, Evercore likewise sought to please HP, viewing HP as a major
    source of future business. See 
    id. at *9,
    *15–16, *19, *21.
    The ensuing negotiations proceeded quickly. HP had anticipated making an opening
    bid of $24 per share, but after Orr’s enthusiastic response, HP opened at $23.25 per share.
    
    Id. at *16–17.
    Qatalyst reached out to a sixth potential strategic partner, but it was not
    interested. 
    Id. at *17.
    The Aruba board decided to counter at $29 per share. Evercore
    conveyed the number to Barclays, but when Barclays dismissed it, Evercore emphasized
    45
    Aruba’s desire to announce a deal quickly. 
    Id. at *17–18.
    On February 10, 2015, twenty
    days after HP resumed discussions with Orr, the Aruba board agreed to a price of $24.67
    per share. 
    Id. at *19.
    The parties negotiated a merger agreement, and on March 1, 2015,
    the Aruba board approved it.
    The post-signing phase was uneventful. On March 2, 2015, Aruba and HP
    announced the merger. The merger agreement (i) contained a no-shop clause subject to a
    fiduciary out, (ii) conditioned the out for an unsolicited superior proposal on compliance
    with an unlimited match right that gave HP five days to match the first superior proposal
    and two days to match any subsequent increase, and (iii) required Aruba to pay HP a
    termination fee of $90 million, representing 3% of the Aruba’s equity value. No competing
    bidder emerged, and on May 1, 2015, Aruba’s stockholders approved the merger. 
    Id. at *21–22.
    The trial court found that under Dell and DFC, Aruba’s sale process was sufficiently
    reliable to make the deal price a persuasive indicator of fair value. The HP-Aruba
    transaction was an arm’s-length merger. The ultimate decision-makers for Aruba—the
    board and the stockholders—did not face any conflicts of interest. During the sale process,
    Aruba extracted price increases from HP. There was also evidence that the deal price
    credited Aruba with a portion of the substantial synergies that the merger would create.
    And the merger agreement’s deal protections were relatively customary and would not
    have supported a claim for breach of fiduciary duty. 
    Id. at *36–38.
    The trial court therefore
    viewed the HP-Aruba merger as “a run-of-the-mill, third party-deal,” where “[n]othing
    about it appears exploitive.” 
    Id. at *38.
    46
    The trial court next turned to the petitioners’ specific challenges to the deal price.
    The petitioners argued that deal price resulted from a closed-off sale process in which HP
    had not faced a meaningful threat of competition. 
    Id. at *39.
    The trial court rejected that
    contention, noting that the petitioners failed “to point to a likely bidder and make a
    persuasive showing that increased competition would have led to a better result.” 
    Id. (citing Dell,
    177 A.3d at 28–29, 32, 34). The petitioners proved that HP knew that it did not face
    a meaningful threat of competition, but they did not show that anyone else would have paid
    more. 
    Id. at *41.
    Instead, the record showed that none of the six parties that Qatalyst
    contacted was willing to bid, and no one emerged between signing and closing. 
    Id. The petitioners
    next argued that the negotiators’ incentives undermined the sale
    process, citing the desire of Aruba’s bankers to cater to HP and the more subtly divergent
    interests of Aruba’s CEO. The trial court found that although the petitioners proved that
    Aruba could have negotiated more aggressively, they did not prove that “the bankers, [the
    CEO], the Aruba Board, and the stockholders who approved the transaction all accepted a
    deal price that left a portion of Aruba’s fundamental value on the table.” 
    Id. at *44.
    In other portions of the decision, the trial court found that Aruba’s unaffected
    trading price was a reliable indicator of fair value and rejected the parties’ DCF valuations
    as unreliable. These holdings left the trial court with two reliable valuation indicators: the
    unaffected trading price and the deal price. The trial court determined that the unaffected
    trading price was the better measure of the fair value of Aruba’s shares. See 
    id. at *53–55.
    On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court reversed. The high court found that the
    trial court had incorrectly relied on the unaffected trading price, but it accepted the trial
    47
    court’s finding that the deal price was a reliable indicator of fair value. 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 141
    –42.
    Addressing the petitioners’ claim that the sale process lacked a competitive bidding
    dynamic, the Delaware Supreme Court explained that the trial court had misinterpreted
    DFC and Dell as downplaying the value of competition. See 
    id. at 136.
    The Delaware
    Supreme Court emphasized that
    when there is an open opportunity for many buyers to buy and only a few bid
    (or even just one bids), that does not necessarily mean that there is a failure
    of competition; it may just mean that the target’s value is not sufficiently
    enticing to buyers to engender a bidding war above the winning price.
    
    Id. The high
    court then applied this principle to the facts in Aruba:
    Aruba approached other logical strategic buyers prior to signing the deal with
    HP, and none of those potential buyers were interested. Then, after signing
    and the announcement of the deal, still no other buyer emerged even though
    the merger agreement allowed for superior bids. It cannot be that an open
    chance for buyers to bid signals a market failure simply because buyers do
    not believe the asset on sale is sufficiently valuable for them to engage in a
    bidding contest against each other. If that were the jurisprudential
    conclusion, then the judiciary would itself infuse assets with extra value by
    virtue of the fact that no actual market participants saw enough value to pay
    a higher price. That sort of alchemy has no rational basis in economics.
    
    Id. On the
    facts presented, the level of competition in Aruba was sufficient to support the
    reliability of the deal price.
    The Delaware Supreme Court also explained that
    a buyer in possession of material nonpublic information about the seller is in
    a strong position (and is uniquely incentivized) to properly value the seller
    when agreeing to buy the company at a particular deal price, and that view
    of value should be given considerable weight by the Court of Chancery
    absent deficiencies in the deal process.
    48
    
    Id. at 137.
    The high court observed that HP and Aruba went “back and forth over price”
    and that HP had “access to nonpublic information to supplement its consideration of the
    public information available to stock market buyers . . . .” 
    Id. at 139.
    The Delaware
    Supreme Court elsewhere emphasized that “HP had signed a confidentiality agreement,
    done exclusive due diligence, gotten access to material nonpublic information,” and “had
    a much sharper incentive to engage in price discovery than an ordinary trader because it
    was seeking to acquire all shares.” 
    Id. at 140.
    On the facts presented, the extent of the
    negotiations in Aruba was sufficient to support the reliability of the deal price.
    The high court ultimately concluded that Aruba’s sale process was sufficiently
    reliable to render the deal price the best measure of fair value. The Delaware Supreme
    Court declined to use the trial court’s estimate of the deal price minus synergies, instead
    adopting HP’s contemporaneous synergies estimate and remanding with instructions that
    “final judgment be entered for the petitioners in the amount of $19.10 per share plus any
    interest to which the petitioners are entitled.” 
    Id. at 142.
    2.     Applying The Delaware Supreme Court’s Precedents To This Case
    The Delaware Supreme Court’s precedents indicate that the sale process in this case
    was sufficiently reliable to make the deal price a persuasive indicator of fair value. These
    authorities call for rejecting the petitioners’ challenges to the sale process.
    a.      Objective Indicia Of Deal-Price Fairness
    When assessing whether a sale process results in fair value, it is critical to recall that
    “fair value is just that, ‘fair.’” 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 370
    . “[T]he key inquiry is whether the
    dissenters got fair value and were not exploited.” 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 33
    . “The issue in an
    49
    appraisal is not whether a negotiator has extracted the highest possible bid.” 
    Id. Rather, “the
    purpose of an appraisal is . . . to make that [the petitioners] receive fair compensation
    for their shares in the sense that it reflects what they deserve to receive based on what
    would fairly be given to them in an arm’s-length transaction.” 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 370
    –71.
    When applying this standard, the Delaware Supreme Court has cited “objective
    indicia” that “suggest[] that the deal price was a fair price.” 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 28
    ; accord
    
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 376
    . In each of its recent decisions, the Delaware Supreme Court found
    that the objective indicia outweighed the sale processes’ shortcomings. In this case, a
    similar analysis shows that the deal price is a reliable indicator of fair value.
    First, the Merger was an arm’s-length transaction with a third party. See 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 349
    (citing fact that “the company was purchased by a third party in an arm’s length
    sale” as factor supporting fairness of deal price). TransCanada was a pure outsider with no
    prior stock ownership in Columbia.
    Second, the Board did not labor under any conflicts of interest. Six of the Board’s
    seven members were experienced outside directors. Cf. 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 28
    (citing fact
    that special committee was “composed of independent, experienced directors and armed
    with the power to say ‘no’” as factor supporting fairness of deal price). Columbia’s
    stockholders were widely dispersed, and the petitioners have not identified divergent
    interests among them.
    50
    Third, TransCanada conducted due diligence and received confidential insights
    about Columbia’s value.27 Like the acquirer in Aruba, TransCanada “had signed a
    confidentiality agreement, done exclusive due diligence, gotten access to material
    nonpublic information,” and had a “sharp[] incentive to engage in price discovery . . .
    because it was seeking to acquire all shares.” 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 140
    .
    Fourth, during the first pre-signing phase, Columbia contacted other potential
    buyers, and those parties failed to pursue a merger when they had a free chance to do so.
    See 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 376
    (citing “failure of other buyers to pursue the company when
    they had a free chance to do so” as factor supporting fairness of deal price). The degree of
    pre-signing interaction is similar to or compares favorably with the facts in the Delaware
    Supreme Court precedents.28
    27
    See 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 137
    (emphasizing that buyer armed with “material
    nonpublic information about the seller is in a strong position (and is uniquely incentivized)
    to properly value the seller”). But see In re Dunkin’ Donuts S’holders Litig., 
    1990 WL 189120
    , at *9 (Del. Ch. Nov. 27, 1990) (“A bidder’s objective is to identify an underpriced
    corporation and . . . acquire it at the lowest price possible.”); cf. 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 374
    n.145 (rejecting reliance on evidence indicating buyer’s contemporaneous belief that it
    purchased target “at trough pricing”; commenting that “it is in tension with the statute itself
    to argue that the subjective view of post-merger value of the acquirer can be used to value
    the respondent company in an appraisal”; observing “[t]hat a buyer views itself as having
    struck a good deal is far from reliable evidence that the resulting price from a competitive
    bidding process is an unreliable indicator of fair value”).
    28
    See 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 136
    –39, 142 (adopting deal price less synergies as fair
    value where company’s banker contacted six potential buyers after HP’s initial outreach,
    none were interested, sale process terminated, and sale process later resumed as single-
    bidder engagement with HP); 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 28
    (finding competitive pre-signing process
    where Silver Lake competed one-at-a-time with interested parties); 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 350
    ,
    376 (finding “competitive process of bidding” where company’s banker contacted “every
    51
    Fifth, Columbia negotiated with TransCanada and extracted multiple price
    increases. See 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 139
    (citing “back and forth over price”); 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 28
    (citing fact that special committee “persuaded Silver Lake to raise its bid six times”).
    After TransCanada offered $24 per share, Columbia said no. When TransCanada raised its
    offer to $25.25, Columbia again said no. The deal price of $25.50 per share was more than
    any other party had ever seriously offered, including before the equity offering when
    Columbia sold 25% of its stock for less than its trading price.
    Finally, no bidders emerged during the post-signing phase, which is a factor that the
    Delaware Supreme Court has stressed when evaluating a sale process.29 The suite of deal
    protections in the Merger Agreement fell within the norm, making the absence of a topping
    bid significant.
    Considering these factors as a whole, the sale process that led to the Merger bore
    objective indicia of fairness that rendered the deal price a reliable indicator of fair value.
    logical buyer,” three expressed interest, and two named a preliminary price with one
    dropping out before serious negotiations commenced).
    29
    See 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 136
    (“It cannot be that an open chance for buyers to bid
    signals a market failure simply because buyers do not believe the asset on sale is
    sufficiently valuable for them to engage in a bidding contest against each other.”); 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 29
    (“Fair value entails at a minimum a price some buyer is willing to pay—
    not a price at which no class of buyers in the market would pay.”); 
    id. at 33
    (finding that
    absence of higher bid meant “that the deal market was already robust and that a topping
    bid involved serious risk of overpayment,” which “suggests the price is already at a level
    that is fair”).
    52
    b.     Management Conflicts
    As their central theme in this case, the petitioners argue that Skaggs and Smith
    engineered a fire sale of Columbia to obtain personal benefits.30 They cite evidence that
    both had targeted a 2016 retirement date. E.g., JX 163; JX 251. Each had a change-in-
    control agreement that paid out triple the sum of his base salary and target annual bonus if
    he retired after a sale of Columbia. If the sale occurred after July 1, 2018, then the multiple
    would drop from triple to double. PTO ¶¶ 206, 217; Taylor Tr. 1263. When Columbia
    separated from NiSource, both joined Columbia knowing that it was likely to be an
    acquisition target. According to the petitioners, the executives then strived to engineer a
    near-term sale, knowing they would come out ahead even in a sale at less than fair value.
    The Aruba decision involved a sale process where the top executive and the
    company’s investment bankers had conflicting incentives. The CEO wanted to retire, but
    he cared deeply about the company and its employees. When HP proposed to acquire Aruba
    and keep the CEO on to integrate the companies, it offered the perfect path “to an honorable
    personal and professional exit.” Aruba Trial, 
    2018 WL 922139
    , at *5; see 
    id. at *43
    (analyzing CEO’s conflict). Aruba’s investment bankers faced more direct conflicts
    because both wanted to curry favor with HP. Qatalyst was desperate to save its Silicon
    30
    At times, the petitioners also targeted a third executive—Glen Kettering—who
    served as President of Columbia. He was less involved in the sale process than Skaggs and
    Smith, and the petitioners never deposed him. Although Kettering retired after the Merger
    and received change-in-control benefits, the evidence does not support the contention that
    he pushed for an early sale.
    53
    Valley franchise, and Evercore was auditioning for future business. 
    Id. at *43.
    The trial
    court acknowledged the petitioners’ concerns, but found that the conflicting incentives did
    not undermine the deal price as an indicator of fair value:
    The evidence does not convince me that the bankers, Orr, the Aruba Board,
    and the stockholders who approved the transaction all accepted a deal price
    that left a portion of Aruba’s fundamental value on the table. Perhaps
    different negotiators could have extracted a greater share of the synergies
    from HP in the form of a higher deal price. Maybe if Orr had been less eager,
    or if Qatalyst had not been relegated to the back room, then HP would have
    opened at $24 per share. Perhaps with a brash Qatalyst banker leading the
    negotiations, unhampered by the Autonomy incident, Aruba might have
    negotiated more effectively and gotten HP above $25 per share. An outcome
    along these lines would have resulted in HP sharing a greater portion of the
    anticipated synergies with Aruba’s stockholders. It would not have changed
    Aruba’s standalone value. Hence, it would not have affected Aruba’s fair
    value for purposes of an appraisal.
    
    Id. at *44.
    On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court accepted the reliability of the deal price
    as a valuation indicator and used it when making its own fair value determination. 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 141
    –42.
    The Dell decision also involved a conflict: Mr. Dell, the company’s founder and top
    executive, was a buy-side participant in the management buyout and would emerge from
    the transaction with a controlling stake. He did not lead the negotiations on the sell side
    (that task fell to the special committee), but the trial court regarded his involvement as a
    factor cutting against the reliability of the deal price. For example, the trial court found that
    Mr. Dell gave the buyout group a leg-up given his relationships within the company and
    his knowledge of its business, and the trial court accepted the testimony of a sale-process
    expert that if bidders competed to pay more than what Mr. Dell’s group would pay, then
    54
    they risked a winner’s curse. Dell Trial, 
    2016 WL 3186538
    , at *42–43. Mr. Dell also was
    a net purchaser of shares in the buyout, so any increase in the deal price cost him money.
    If Mr. Dell kept the size of his investment constant as the deal value
    increased, then Silver Lake would have to pay more and would demand a
    greater ownership stake in the post-transaction entity. Subramanian showed
    that if Mr. Dell wanted to maintain 75% ownership of the post-transaction
    entity, then he would have to contribute an additional $250 million for each
    $1 increase in the deal price. If Mr. Dell did not contribute any additional
    equity and relied on Silver Lake to fund the increase, then he would lose
    control of the post-transaction entity at a deal price above $15.73 per share.
    Because Mr. Dell was a net buyer, any party considering an overbid would
    understand that a higher price would not be well received by the most
    important person at the Company.
    
    Id. at *43
    (footnote omitted). These factors did not make Mr. Dell’s involvement with the
    buyout group preclusive, as that term is used in an enhanced scrutiny case, because Mr.
    Dell testified credibly that he was willing to work with any bidder, and there was evidence
    that two of the buyout group’s competitors had questioned Mr. Dell’s value. But for
    purposes of price discovery in an appraisal case, the trial court perceived that Mr. Dell’s
    involvement and incentives undermined the effectiveness of the sale process and the
    reliability of the deal price. 
    Id. at *44.
    On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court held that Mr. Dell’s involvement in the
    buyout group had not undermined the sale process. See 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 32
    –33. The high
    court noted that “the [trial court] did not identify any possible bidders that were actually
    deterred because of Mr. Dell’s status.” 
    Id. at 34.
    The Delaware Supreme Court also
    emphasized Mr. Dell’s willingness to work with rival bidders during due diligence and the
    absence of evidence that Mr. Dell would have left the company if a rival bidder prevailed.
    
    Id. at 32–34.
    The high court concluded that the lack of a higher bid did not call into question
    55
    the sale process, because “[i]f a deal price is at a level where the next upward move by a
    topping bidder has a material risk of being a self-destructive curse, that suggests the price
    is already at a level that is fair.” 
    Id. at 33.
    In this case, management’s divergent interests fell short of the conflicts that failed
    to undermine the sale process in Dell. The alignment issue confronting Skaggs and Smith
    more closely resembled the negotiators’ incentives in Aruba. Like Aruba’s CEO and its
    bankers, Skaggs and Smith had personal reasons to secure a deal under circumstances
    where disinterested participants might have preferred a standalone option: Their change-
    in-control benefits incentivized them to favor selling Columbia before 2018. To minimize
    the risk of missing that window, it was safer to act sooner rather than later. See In re Rural
    Metro Corp., 
    88 A.3d 54
    , 94–95 (Del. Ch. 2014) (discussing how incentives of
    contingently compensated representative are generally aligned with principal’s but diverge
    over whether to do a deal at all), aff’d sub nom. RBC Capital Mkts., LLC v. Jervis, 
    129 A.3d 816
    (Del. 2015).
    But Skaggs and Smith also had countervailing incentives to pursue the best deal
    possible. Their change-in-control benefits included significant equity components that
    appreciated with a higher deal price. After the Merger, Skaggs retired and received change-
    in-control payments totaling $26.8 million, with over $19 million from equity awards.
    Skaggs received an additional $30 million when the Merger cashed out his nearly 1.2
    million shares and phantom shares of Columbia stock. Smith similarly retired and received
    change-in-control payments totaling $10.9 million, with over $7.3 million from equity
    awards. PTO ¶¶ 654, 656; JX 1370 at 17–18; see JX 1346 ¶¶ 12, 27.
    56
    When directors or their affiliates own “material” amounts of common stock,
    it aligns their interests with other stockholders by giving them a “motivation
    to seek the highest price” and the “personal incentive as stockholders to think
    about the trade off between selling now and the risks of not doing so.”
    Chen v. Howard-Anderson, 
    87 A.3d 648
    , 670–71 (Del. Ch. 2014) (quoting In re Dollar
    Thrifty S’holder Litig., 
    14 A.3d 573
    , 600 (Del. Ch. 2010)); see also Lender Processing,
    
    2016 WL 7324170
    , at *22 (discussing incentive to maximize deal price where target
    managers were net sellers and would not retain jobs post-merger). That said, the equity
    components in the change-in-control benefits did not fully solve the alignment problem,
    because their contingent nature made their recipients more averse to losing a deal, thereby
    limiting their incentive to push for the final nickel or quarter. See Rural 
    Metro, 88 A.3d at 94
    –95 (discussing how incentives of contingently compensated representative and
    principal diverge during final negotiations).
    In sum, there is evidence to support the petitioners’ theory, and I have considered it
    seriously. Ultimately, however, I cannot credit it. Although Skaggs and Smith wanted to
    retire, they were professionals who took pride in their jobs and wanted to do the right thing.
    They were not going to arrange a fire sale for below Columbia’s standalone value, and the
    Board would not have let them.
    Consistent with their incentives and professional responsibilities, Skaggs and Smith
    rejected opportunities for a quick sale. When Dominion expressed interest at an all-time
    high valuation, Skaggs demanded more. Instead of taking what they could get from
    Berkshire or TransCanada in fall 2015, Skaggs and Smith recommended a dilutive equity
    raise. JX 534; JX 1399 at 2–3. When Columbia told TransCanada that it was pursuing the
    57
    equity raise, Girling offered a prompt deal at a higher price. JX 588. Skaggs thought that
    was too risky for Columbia and declined. A Columbia director recognized that by pursuing
    the equity raise, Skaggs and Smith had opted for “BIG, at least near, financial hits to your
    net worth.” JX 621.
    When negotiations with TransCanada resumed, Skaggs remained focused on
    obtaining a fair price. While awaiting TransCanada’s formal offer in February 2016,
    Skaggs told Cornelius that “if the cash portion of the initial salvo [is] below $25, I would
    be inclined to not even counter.” JX 855. When TransCanada offered $24, Skaggs and
    Smith said it was a nonstarter. See PTO ¶ 563. TransCanada came back at $25.25, and
    Skaggs recommended that the Board reject it. JX 1399 at 10; Skaggs Tr. 908–10; see
    Cornelius Tr. 1142–43. The Board agreed, and after Skaggs told Girling, Lazard and
    Skaggs believed the deal had died and that Columbia would be proceeding with its
    standalone plan. See JX 901; JX 906; JX 913.
    The most troubling event in the deal timeline is Smith’s one-on-one meeting with
    Poirier, when he explained that TransCanada lacked competition. But Columbia did not
    take TransCanada’s $24 per share offer, or even its $25.25 offer. Skaggs and the Board
    held out for a higher price, ultimately obtaining the Merger consideration of $25.50.
    There is some evidence that if the Board had said no to $25.50 per share, then
    TransCanada would have looked for ways to go back up to $26. See Poirier Tr. 420–21.
    That prospect is insufficient to undermine the deal price for appraisal purposes. See 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 33
    (explaining that fair value in an appraisal is not a measure of “whether a
    negotiator has extracted the highest possible bid”); accord 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 370
    .
    58
    The evidence does not convince me that the Skaggs, Smith, and the Board accepted
    a deal price that left a portion of Columbia’s fundamental value on the table. As in Aruba,
    perhaps different negotiators could have done better. If they had, then the higher price
    would have resulted in TransCanada sharing a portion of the anticipated synergies with
    Columbia’s stockholders. It would not have affected whether Columbia’s stockholders
    received fair value.
    c.       Claims Of Favoritism During The Pre-Signing Process
    In their second attack on the sale process, the petitioners contend that the pre-signing
    phase “yields no reliable indication of fair value” because Columbia favored TransCanada
    over opportunities with other buyers. See Dkt. 428 at 73–74. It is true that Columbia began
    to favor TransCanada over time, but that was because a deal with TransCanada offered
    higher and more certain value than the alternatives.
    The Aruba decision illustrates how a targeted pre-signing process can evolve to
    focus on a single bidder without undermining the deal price as an indicator of fair value.
    There, the initial phase of the sale process involved outreach to five potential strategic
    partners, and Aruba’s banker later contacted a sixth. All declined to bid. During the second
    phase of the process, Aruba effectively engaged in a single-bidder negotiation with HP,
    and the petitioners proved that HP knew that it did not face a meaningful threat of
    competition. Aruba Trial, 
    2018 WL 922139
    , at *40–41. As the high court made clear on
    appeal, this fact pattern did not mean that there was insufficient competition, nor did it
    render the deal price unfair. See 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 136
    (“[W]hen there is an open
    opportunity for many buyers to buy and only a few bid (or even just one bids), that does
    59
    not necessarily mean that there is a failure of competition; it may just mean that the target’s
    value is not sufficiently enticing to buyers to engender a bidding war above the winning
    price.”).
    The sale process in this case followed a similar pattern. It is true that Columbia did
    not treat all bidders identically, but Columbia’s actions did not result in an ineffective sale
    process or unreliable deal price. Rather than favoring TransCanada throughout, Columbia
    initially expected Dominion to be the logical buyer. After TransCanada’s unsolicited
    outreach to Smith in October 2015, Columbia remained focused on Dominion, believing
    that it could pay more. See PTO ¶ 428. In early November 2015, when Dominion said it
    could not meet the Board’s ask of $28 per share, Lazard recommended broadening the
    process with private outreach to TransCanada, Berkshire, and Spectra to “put pressure on
    [Dominion].” JX 503 at 2–3. Goldman agreed and recommended conducting a broader
    market test only if the private process failed to produce a bid materially greater than $24
    per share. See JX 505.
    The targeted pre-signing process ultimately included Dominion, NextEra,
    TransCanada, and Berkshire, but not Spectra. The petitioners fault Columbia for not
    pursuing Spectra, but they failed to prove that more vigorous pursuit “would have produced
    a better result.” 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 28
    . On November 3, 2015, Spectra’s CEO emailed
    Skaggs to request a meeting or telephone call “in the next couple of weeks to discuss what
    we may be able to accomplish together.” JX 500. The two talked by phone on November
    9. During the call, Spectra’s CEO “referenced potential strategic opportunities for
    Columbia and Spectra, but provided no specifics . . . and did not request a follow-up
    60
    meeting or conversation.” PTO ¶ 438. Skaggs told Spectra to move quickly, because
    otherwise Columbia would end talks and proceed with an equity offering. Skaggs Tr. 960;
    see 
    id. at 871.
    After the call, Spectra went “radio silent.” Skaggs Tr. 879; accord JX 541.
    On November 17, Skaggs reported to the Board that Spectra’s CEO “had again expressed
    interest in a potential strategic transaction . . . but had only spoken in terms of generic
    transaction considerations and had not provided a specific, actionable proposal or requested
    a substantive follow-up.” PTO ¶ 456. In a November 25 update to the Board, Skaggs
    confirmed that “no additional word had been received” from Spectra. 
    Id. ¶ 471.
    Spectra
    had a “free chance” to pursue Columbia during the pre-signing phase. 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 376
    . Spectra’s failure to act does not undermine the fairness of the deal price.
    The petitioners next claim that Columbia gave more information to TransCanada
    than to others in November 2015. The simple answer is that the bidders requested different
    levels of information. Berkshire was the most demanding.31 TransCanada was next, and
    both TransCanada and Berkshire asked for redacted precedent agreements. Dominion did
    not receive them because it did not ask.
    The petitioners also complain that Skaggs gave TransCanada and Berkshire an
    informal bid deadline of November 24, 2015, without sharing the deadline with Dominion.
    31
    Smith Tr. 316; see JX 562 (Goldman describing Berkshire’s requests as atypically
    granular for “early [] M&A dialogue”); JX 555 (Berkshire requesting separate operating
    models for each OpCo subsidiary); JX 550 (detailed Berkshire diligence questionnaire);
    JX 565 (same); JX 568 (same); JX 551 (responding to Berkshire request about MLP tax
    structure); JX 554 (same). See generally PTO ¶¶ 460–66 (describing Berkshire diligence).
    61
    Columbia told all of the parties it contacted to act quickly before Columbia pivoted to an
    equity offering, so Dominion knew there was time pressure. See Skaggs Tr. 960–61. By
    November 22, because of extensive interactions with TransCanada and Berkshire,
    Columbia management expected imminent indications of interest from those firms.
    Dominion “ha[d] been radio silent.” JX 569. Sure enough, TransCanada and Berkshire
    made prompt bids, and Dominion did not. The petitioners cite an email from November
    25, 2015 in which Dominion’s partner, NextEra, expressed surprise when Columbia called
    off the sale process to pursue an equity offering, saying that the deadline “was news to us—
    we were working on it.” JX 592. Dominion and NextEra knew they had to move quickly,
    and had they been more interested, they would have. There is no evidence that an
    expression of interest from Dominion and NextEra would have been sufficiently
    competitive and sufficiently actionable to cause Columbia to forego the equity offering and
    agree to a preemptive transaction at a higher value than the Merger.
    The petitioners likewise claim that Columbia unduly favored TransCanada after the
    equity offering. As it did throughout the process, Columbia pursued the best opportunity.
    Columbia first focused on Dominion. Because of Dominion’s reticence, Columbia next
    focused on Berkshire and TransCanada. After the equity offering, Berkshire withdrew for
    good, calling Columbia’s business model “fundamentally broken.” See JX 547.
    TransCanada, by contrast, called to express continued interest. That call spurred Smith’s
    meeting with TransCanada in January 2016. See Smith Tr. 323; accord 
    id. at 234.
    As with the evidence regarding management conflicts, Smith’s one-on-one meeting
    with Poirier is the most serious evidence of favoritism towards TransCanada. But as noted
    62
    in the section on management’s incentives, Columbia did not take TransCanada’s $24 per
    share offer, or even its $25.25 offer. Skaggs and the Board forced Columbia to pay $25.50.
    The results of Columbia’s negotiations compare favorably with the facts in Aruba and
    DFC. During the meat of the negotiations in Aruba, the company focused exclusively on
    HP, which knew that it was not facing competition. HP had anticipated offering $24 per
    share and then giving ground. When Aruba’s CEO responded with enthusiasm to HP’s
    approach, HP instead made an opening bid of $23.25. Although HP later increased its bid,
    after adjusting for a corrected share count, HP described the deal price of $24.67 as “the
    new $24.00.” See Aruba Trial, 
    2018 WL 922139
    , at *39–41. Likewise, in DFC, Lone Star
    was the only bidder that negotiated price with DFC Global, and rather than increasing its
    bid, Lone Star lowered it twice. See DFC Trial, 
    2016 WL 3753123
    , at *3–4.
    The petitioners make similar arguments about Columbia’s decision to grant
    exclusivity to TransCanada and to treat the exclusivity as effectively remaining in place
    even after it terminated. As with Smith’s meeting with Poirier, the fact that only one bidder
    bids “does not necessarily mean that there is a failure of competition . . . .” 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 136
    . The trial court in DFC found that DFC Global had granted Lone Star
    exclusivity at an inopportune point in the negotiations and that Lone Star had pressured the
    company with an exploding offer. See DFC Trial, 
    2016 WL 3753123
    , at *23. But those
    factors did not undermine the reliability of the deal price given the objective indicia of
    fairness that were also present in this case. See 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 349
    –50, 375–76.
    As with their arguments about management incentives, the petitioners have
    mustered evidence that supports their theory of bidder favoritism, but they failed to show
    63
    that Columbia favored TransCanada to a degree that left fundamental value on the table.
    The Board and management believed that TransCanada was the optimal buyer to pursue,
    which is why they gave TransCanada exclusivity and continued to deal with TransCanada.
    See PTO ¶ 519. Put simply, “[n]othing in the record suggests that increased competition
    would have produced a better result.” 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 28
    .
    d.     The Standstills
    The petitioners appear to argue that the standstills distinguish this case from those
    where the deal price was reliable despite weak interest from potential suitors. They assert
    that Columbia permitted TransCanada to breach its standstill by reengaging after the equity
    offering, while at the same time failing to waive the standstills that bound rival bidders.
    Although the Board ultimately waived the standstills with Dominion, NextEra, and
    Berkshire in March 2016, the petitioners say it should have done so sooner, claiming that
    by that point TransCanada had an insurmountable head start towards a transaction.
    Each party that engaged with Columbia during fall 2015 entered into an NDA
    containing a standstill provision substantially in the form of the following:
    In consideration for being furnished with Evaluation Material by [Columbia],
    each Party (each such Party in such context, the “Standstill Party”) agrees
    that until the date that is eighteen months after the date of this [NDA], unless
    [Columbia’s] board of directors otherwise so specifically requests in writing
    in advance, the Standstill Party shall not, and shall cause its Representatives
    not to . . . directly or indirectly,
    (A) acquire or offer to acquire, or seek, propose or agree to acquire . .
    . beneficial ownership . . . or constructive economic ownership . . . of any
    securities or material assets of [Columbia], including rights or options to
    acquire such ownership,
    (B) seek or propose to influence, advise, change or control the
    64
    management, board of directors, governing instruments or policies or affairs
    of [Columbia], including by means of a solicitation of proxies . . . , contacting
    any person relating to any of the matters set forth in this [NDA] or seeking
    to influence, advise or direct the vote of any holder of voting securities of
    [Columbia] or making a request to amend or waive this provision or any other
    provision of this Section 3 or of Section 1 or Section 2 or
    (C) make any public disclosure, or take any action that could require
    the other Party to make any public disclosure, with respect to any of the
    matters that are the subject of this [NDA]. . . .
    JX 526 § 3 (formatting altered); see PTO ¶ 455. The standstills prohibited the
    counterparties from “seek[ing]” to acquire Columbia or influence its management without
    the Board’s prior written invitation.
    The petitioners proved at trial that TransCanada breached its standstill several times.
    The first breach occurred in mid-December 2015, when Poirier called Smith to convey
    TransCanada’s continued interest in acquiring Columbia. The second breach occurred
    when Poirier and Smith met in January 2016. There are other instances.32
    32
    E.g., JX 746 (Skaggs writing to Board on January 26, 2016: “Consistent with our
    recent one-on-one conversations about a potential inbound overture, TransCanada’s . . .
    CEO called me on Monday afternoon (1/25) to outline a proposition to acquire CPG.”).
    Before Poirier and Smith met in January 2016, Poirier assured Smith that he could
    share due diligence materials without TransCanada breaching the standstill. See JX 485 at
    2 (“My understanding is that our respective counsels have talked, and that we are ok to
    proceed with exchanging information. As we destroyed all non public [sic] information, in
    addition to the data room index, would it be possible to receive again the information you
    previously sent, including the board summaries?”). At trial, Poirier unpersuasively
    rationalized his overtures to Smith as complying with the standstill because he “wasn’t
    submitting a formal offer for the company.” Poirier Tr. 387. Poirier is an experienced
    investment banker. He should have understood the standstill’s scope. When pushed, he
    cited unspecified legal advice from TransCanada’s counsel. See id.; 
    id. at 454.
    65
    The petitioners posit that but for their own standstills, Berkshire, Dominion, or
    NextEra would have competed with TransCanada in spring 2016, driving up the deal price.
    But there is no evidence that Dominion or NextEra had any interest in reengaging with
    Columbia after the equity offering, and Berkshire refused to do so.33
    In March 2016, Columbia waived the standstills. If Berkshire, Dominion, or
    NextEra wanted to bid, then they could have done so in the post-signing phase (but they
    did not). Their failure to do so resembles the fact pattern in Aruba, which cited the absence
    of bidding during a passive post-signing market check as supporting the fairness of the
    price. See 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 136
    (“[A]fter signing and the announcement of the deal, still
    no other buyer emerged even though the merger agreement allowed for superior bids.”).
    On January 22, 2016, TransCanada’s in-house counsel drafted an email to
    Columbia’s in-house counsel opining that an upcoming call between Girling and Skaggs
    would not breach the standstill, because although “there may be some broad discussion
    regarding valuation of [Columbia],” Girling would not make an offer to buy. JX 735. The
    point of talking numbers was to facilitate a bid, thus breaching the standstill.
    TransCanada’s in-house counsel concluded her email by seeking confirmation that
    TransCanada would not breach the standstill “in the event [that it made] a verbal or written
    offer or proposal.” 
    Id. That request
    effectively sought waiver of the DADW, also a breach.
    33
    The petitioners advance a similar argument about the threat of massive tax
    liability deterring potential acquirers from buying Columbia. NiSource spun off Columbia
    in a tax-free transaction, but an acquirer could become liable for the tax if it had negotiated
    to buy Columbia before the spinoff and then bought it afterwards. See I.R.C. § 355(c)(2),
    (e); Tres. Reg. § 1.355-7(b)(3)(iii); Rev. Rul. 2005-2 C.B. 684. The petitioners cite an April
    2016 email in which TransCanada’s CFO cited “rumblings, that we are unable to confirm
    or refute, that Enbridge may have had prior discussions with NiSource that could impact
    the tax-free status of the spin of Columbia.” JX 1108. With the potential exception of
    TransCanada, there is no direct evidence of anyone negotiating with NiSource before the
    spinoff. See, e.g., JX 311 (circumstantial evidence of TransCanada and Lazard engaging in
    talks before spinoff). The petitioner failed to carry their burden of proof on this issue.
    66
    The DFC decision also involved a passive post-signing market check in which no bidders
    emerged. 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 359
    .
    The evidence does not show that the standstills undermined the fairness of the deal
    price. None of the standstill parties wanted to bid, and they in fact did not bid.
    e.     Claims About An Information Vacuum
    In a variant of their arguments about bidder favoritism, the petitioners contend that
    Skaggs and Smith misled the Board or otherwise ran the sale process unsupervised. They
    posit that but for these actions, the Board would have engaged more vigorously with other
    bidders. If credited, these arguments would show that the Board could have gotten more
    than fair value, but they would not show that the deal price fell below that mark. See 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 370
    (noting that “the purpose of an appraisal is not to make sure that the
    petitioners get the highest conceivable value that might have been procured had every
    domino fallen out of the company’s way”).
    On different facts, fraud on the board could lead to a deal price below fair value. In
    this case, the petitioners’ assertions are largely unsupported. The Board received a steady
    flow of information, with Skaggs regularly keeping the directors informed through written
    memos, presentations during meetings, and one-on-one communications.34
    34
    By February 2016, Skaggs was updating the Board on an at least weekly basis.
    See, e.g., JX 780; JX 785; JX 806; JX 808; JX 830; JX 846; JX 852; JX 855. By March,
    Skaggs was updating the Board on a near-daily basis. See, e.g., JX 874; JX 913; JX 929;
    JX 939; JX 945; JX 962; JX 964; JX 995; JX 1004; JX 1007; JX 1010.
    67
    The petitioners contend that Skaggs misled the Board in November 2015 by failing
    to report that Spectra asked for a meeting, but Skaggs testified credibly that he regarded
    Spectra’s passes as “casual passes” that “weren’t serious.” Skaggs Tr. 946. The petitioners
    also say that Skaggs should have told the Board that he gave TransCanada and Berkshire a
    bid deadline of November 24, 2015, without sharing the deadline with the other suitors.
    The better view of the evidence is that Skaggs told all of the interested parties that they had
    to move quickly before Columbia pivoted to an equity offering in December. TransCanada
    and Berkshire received more specific guidance because they showed the most interest. The
    petitioners also assert that Skaggs should have told the Board that not all suitors received
    the same due diligence in November 2015, but the bidders got what they requested.
    As with the petitioners’ other challenges to the sale process, their best argument
    centers on Smith’s meeting with Poirier on January 7, 2016. Smith sent Poirier confidential
    due diligence materials and assured him that TransCanada faced no competition. The Board
    did not authorize the meeting or the disclosures.35 And although Skaggs generally was
    forthcoming with the Board, in this instance Skaggs told the Board that TransCanada had
    reached out to Smith, without mentioning that Smith met with Poirier and without reporting
    Smith’s unauthorized disclosures. See JX 698.
    35
    See, e.g., Kittrell Tr. 1107–08 (“Q. . . . And it’s fair to say that the board never
    authorized management to tell any potential bidder that Columbia had eliminated the
    competition for a competing bid. Right? A. The board would never have given that specific
    direction.”); accord Kittrell Dep. 164 (describing Smith’s strategy as “counterintuitive”).
    68
    The petitioners have identified a flaw in the process, but they have not shown that
    it led to a price below fair value. After Poirier’s meeting with Smith, TransCanada
    proposed a price range similar to its indication from before the equity offering. Columbia
    declined and pushed back.
    The petitioners also assert that when the Board met on January 28 and 29, 2016,
    Skaggs “manipulate[d] the Board into approving a TransCanada bid.” Dkt. 428 at 21–22.
    Skaggs presented a chart discussing what the directors “would have to believe” about
    Columbia’s future trading price to reject a merger proposal at $26 per share, and Skaggs
    recommended that the Columbia directors accept an offer at $26 unless they believed
    Columbia would trade at $30.11 in 2017. JX 753 at 9. Goldman prepared the initial version
    of the chart, and at trial, the petitioners pressed Skaggs on why his version omitted a column
    which showed that the directors should be indifferent to an offer at $26 per share if they
    believed Columbia would trade at $27.69 at a 8.5% cost of equity in 2016. See Skaggs. Tr.
    982–90. In reality, Skaggs’ chart was Goldman’s summary of the other charts it had
    prepared. Compare JX 753 at 9, with JX 726 at 4. The absent column came from a chart
    that Skaggs did not present. Skaggs did not mislead the Board by presenting the summary
    chart in its entirety.
    Finally, the petitioners fault Skaggs for not telling the Board that on March 12, 2016,
    Spectra requested due diligence and promised a written offer “in the next few days,” or that
    Goldman thought Spectra was “serious.” JX 992. The Board had previously approved a
    script that required a “serious written proposal” as a condition to diligence. Skaggs
    prepared for an offer from Spectra by having Goldman get an ability-to-pay analysis ready.
    69
    See JX 1009. Goldman determined that at a price of $25.50, Spectra risked a credit
    downgrade and dilution until 2019.36 Spectra never made a written offer.
    The petitioners did not prove that the Board was misled or deprived of material
    information. The petitioners did prove that management at times knew more about the sale
    process, which is inevitable because directors do not run companies on a day-to-day basis.
    The record does not show that informational differences led to a deal price below fair value.
    f.     The Stockholder Vote
    In an entire fairness case, the unitary entire fairness standard “embraces questions
    of when the transaction was timed, how it was initiated, structured, negotiated, disclosed
    to the directors, and how the approvals of the directors and the stockholders were
    obtained.” Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 
    457 A.2d 701
    , 711 (Del. 1983). Drawing on an entire
    fairness case, TransCanada posits that the informed approval of disinterested stockholders,
    especially by a large margin, “is compelling evidence that the price was fair.” ACP Master,
    Ltd. v. Sprint Corp., 
    2017 WL 3421142
    , at *29 (Del. Ch. July 21, 2017), aff’d, 
    2018 WL 1905256
    (Del. Apr. 23, 2018) (ORDER). The petitioners take the opposite tack and argue
    that if they can show defects in the stockholder approval process, such as disclosure
    violations, then that should undermine a claim that the deal price reflects fair value.
    It is not self-evident that stockholder approval should have the same implications
    for an appraisal proceeding as an entire fairness case, given that the former is a statutory
    36
    See JX 1022; JX 1016 at 20; see also Mir Tr. 1212 (describing Lazard’s view that
    Spectra was “not a credible or capable buyer”).
    70
    remedy that turns solely on inadequacy of price, while the latter is a liability proceeding in
    which the entire fairness test is used to determine whether fiduciaries have breached their
    duties.37 The entire fairness test can apply to a wide range of transactions, only some of
    which require stockholder approval under the Delaware General Corporation Law. A
    complex body of law governs the extent to which stockholder approval lowers the standard
    of review from entire fairness to the business judgment rule, shifts who bears the burden
    of proving fairness, or operates as evidence of fairness under the unitary entire fairness test.
    See, e.g., ACP Master, 
    2017 WL 3421142
    , at *16–19, *29. When an appraisal proceeding
    follows a long-form merger like the one in this case, stockholder approval is a statutory
    prerequisite. See 
    8 Del. C
    . § 251(c). The Merger would not have closed (and appraisal
    rights would not have been triggered) unless the stockholders approved the transaction.
    How different levels of stockholder approval should affect the valuation inquiry is
    something that our cases have yet to work out.
    In this case, TransCanada argues that holders of approximately 95.3% of the shares
    that were present in person or by proxy at Columbia’s meeting of stockholders favored the
    Merger. Under Delaware law, a merger requires the approval of holders of a majority of
    the outstanding shares, making that the appropriate denominator for consideration. See 8
    37
    See generally Charles Korsmo & Minor Myers, Reforming Modern Appraisal
    Litigation, 41 Del. J. Corp. L. 279, 320–25 (2017) (comparing appraisal with fiduciary
    review with primary focus on deals without a controlling stockholder); Charles Korsmo &
    Minor Myers, Appraisal Arbitrage and the Future of Public Company M&A, 92 Wash. U.
    L. Rev. 1551, 1607–09 (2015) (same).
    
    71 Del. C
    . § 251(c). Under this voting standard, a non-vote counts the same as a “no” vote. In
    Columbia’s case, holders of 73.9% of its shares voted in favor of the Merger, making the
    rate of approval perhaps not as high as it might appear. Neither side introduced expert
    testimony or other evidence that would enable the court to assess the degree to which this
    level of approval reflected an endorsement of the deal price, other than recognizing the
    obvious fact that a majority of the outstanding shares approved it.
    The petitioners argue that the court should not give any weight to stockholder
    approval in this case because the proxy statement that Columbia distributed to its
    stockholders was materially misleading. See JX 1136 (the “Proxy”). The petitioners cite a
    list of issues, but three are most significant.
    The first concerns an omission and a misleading partial disclosure about Columbia’s
    NDAs. The Proxy disclosed that Columbia had entered into NDAs in November 2015 with
    Parties B, C, and D, but the Proxy did not disclose that the NDAs contained standstills,
    much less DADWs. The Proxy then disclosed misleadingly that “[u]nlike TransCanada,
    none of Party B, Party C or Party D sought to re-engage in discussions with [Columbia]
    after discussions were terminated in November 2015.” 
    Id. at 46.
    The Proxy failed to
    provide the additional disclosure that all four parties were subject to standstills with
    DADWs, that TransCanada breached its standstill, and that Columbia opted to ignore
    TransCanada’s breach.
    In an effort to blunt these issues, TransCanada points out that the Proxy disclosed
    that “none of Party A, Party B, Party C or Party D would be subject to standstill obligations
    that would prohibit them from making an unsolicited proposal to the Board following
    72
    announcement of entry into the merger agreement with TransCanada.” 
    Id. at 60.
    TransCanada cites a secondary source indicating that some 80% of surveyed NDAs
    contained standstills and 64% contained DADWs, then argues that stockholders should
    have known that the NDAs contained these restrictions and that Columbia waived them.
    Stockholders should not have had to guess about whether the NDAs contained these
    powerful provisions, and while it was true that the restrictions did not apply post-signing,
    the Proxy created the misleading impression that Parties B, C, and D were not bound by
    standstills during the pre-signing period.
    These problems with the Proxy were material. A reasonable stockholder would have
    found it significant that TransCanada and Parties B, C, and D were bound by standstills in
    fall 2015 and that TransCanada was permitted to breach its standstill to pursue the Merger.
    A leading treatise on mergers and acquisitions identifies benefits to standstills, but also
    warns of potential dangers.
    [I]t may well be that the presence of [standstill] provisions will cause third
    parties to put their highest and best prices on the table in any pre-signing
    market check or auction since, for them, there will be no “tomorrow.”
    However, such provisions, especially if coupled with either a provision that
    prohibits the target from waiving the prohibition or one which does not
    permit the third party from requesting [sic] a waiver undercuts the
    effectiveness of the post-signing market check.
    Lou R. Kling & Eileen T. Nugent, Negotiated Acquisitions of Companies, Subsidiaries and
    Divisions § 4.04[6][b], at 4-92 (2019 ed.) (footnotes omitted). The limitations imposed by
    the standstills and DADWs made their presence material to Columbia’s stockholders.
    The petitioners next cite the Proxy’s failure to disclose that Skaggs and Smith were
    planning to retire in 2016. TransCanada disputes the factual claim, arguing that Skaggs was
    73
    open to continuing work and observing that the Board wanted Smith to stay on as CFO
    after the Merger. It was not inevitable that Skaggs or Smith would retire in 2016, but they
    wanted to and did. See, e.g., JX 1034 (Smith asking advisor immediately after signing:
    “[D]o you think I can retire now?”). Although this decision has found that Skaggs and
    Smith’s desire to retire did not undermine the sale process, a reasonable stockholder would
    have regarded their plans as material. See, e.g., In re Lear Corp. S’holder Litig., 
    926 A.2d 94
    , 114 (Del. Ch. 2007) (“[A] reasonable stockholder would want to know an important
    economic motivation of the negotiator singularly employed by a board to obtain the best
    price for the stockholders, when that motivation could rationally lead that negotiator to
    favor a deal at a less than optimal price, because the procession of a deal was more
    important to him, given his overall economic interest, than only doing a deal at the right
    price.”).
    Finally, the petitioners cite the Proxy’s partial disclosure regarding Smith’s meeting
    with Poirier on January 7, 2016. See JX 1136 at 46. The Proxy failed to mention that Smith
    invited a bid and told Poirier that TransCanada did not face competition. TransCanada
    downplays the meeting as preliminary and immaterial given the generous deal price.
    Stockholders could decide how much weight to give the information, but the information
    itself was material.
    The petitioners proved that the Proxy contained material misstatements and
    omissions. In light of the flawed Proxy, this decision does not give any weight to the
    stockholder vote for purposes of evaluating the reliability of the deal price.
    74
    g.     The Deal Protections
    The petitioners contend that the deal protection measures in the Merger Agreement
    undermined the effectiveness of the sale process. Under the Delaware Supreme Court’s
    precedents, the deal protections did not have that effect.
    The Merger Agreement contained a no-shop clause with a fiduciary out. As is
    customary, the Merger Agreement provided broadly that Columbia could not solicit,
    provide information to, or engage in discussions with any party other than TransCanada,
    then created an exception identifying circumstances under which Columbia could respond
    to an interested party. The first half of Section 4.02(a) of the Merger Agreement established
    the broad prohibition, stating:
    The Company agrees that, except as permitted by this Section 4.02, neither
    it nor any of its Subsidiaries nor any of the officers and directors of it or its
    Subsidiaries shall, and it shall instruct and use its reasonable best efforts to
    cause its and its Subsidiaries’ employees, investment bankers, attorneys,
    accountants and other advisors or representatives (such officers, directors,
    employees, investment bankers, attorneys, accountants and other advisors or
    representatives, collectively, “Representatives”) not to, directly or indirectly:
    (i) initiate, solicit or encourage any, or the making of any, inquiry,
    indication of interest, proposal or offer that constitutes, or could reasonably
    be expected to lead to, any Acquisition Proposal;
    (ii) engage in, continue or otherwise participate in any discussions or
    negotiations regarding, or provide any information or data to any Person
    relating to, any inquiry, indication of interest, proposal or offer that
    constitutes, or could reasonably be expected to lead to, an Acquisition
    Proposal; or
    (iii) otherwise knowingly facilitate any effort or attempt to make any
    inquiry, indication of interest, proposal or offer that constitutes, or could
    reasonably be expected to lead to, an Acquisition Proposal.
    JX 1025 § 4.02(a) (the “No-Shop Clause”) (formatting altered).
    75
    The second half of Section 4.02(a) of the Merger Agreement carved out the
    exception to the general prohibition. It stated:
    Notwithstanding anything in the foregoing to the contrary, prior to the time
    the Company Requisite Vote is obtained, the Company may, subject to the
    Company providing prior notice to Parent,
    (A) provide information in response to a request therefor by a Person
    who has made a bona fide written Acquisition Proposal that did not result
    from a breach of this Section 4.02 if the Company receives from the Person
    requesting such information an executed confidentiality agreement on terms
    not less restrictive to the other party than those contained in the
    Confidentiality Agreement (it being understood that such confidentiality
    agreement need not prohibit the making, or amendment, of an Acquisition
    Proposal but which shall not prohibit the Company from fulfilling its
    obligations under this Section 4.02); provided, however, that the Company
    shall promptly after the execution thereof provide a true and complete copy
    to Parent of any such confidentiality agreement and any such information to
    the extent not previously provided to Parent, in each case, redacted, if
    necessary, to remove the identity of the Person making the proposal or offer;
    or
    (B) engage or participate in any discussions or negotiations with any
    Person who has made such an unsolicited bona fide written Acquisition
    Proposal, if and only to the extent that,
    (x) prior to taking any action described in clause (A) or (B)
    above, the board of directors of the Company determines in good faith
    (after consultation with its outside legal counsel) that the failure to
    take such action would reasonably be expected to result in a breach of
    the directors’ fiduciary duties under applicable Law and
    (y) in each such case referred to in clause (A) or (B) above, the
    board of directors of the Company has determined in good faith based
    on the information then available and after consultation with its
    outside legal counsel and its financial advisor that such Acquisition
    Proposal either constitutes a Superior Proposal or could reasonably be
    expected to result in a Superior Proposal. . . .
    
    Id. § 4.02(a)
    (the “Superior-Proposal Out”) (formatting altered).
    76
    Importantly for present purposes, the Superior-Proposal Out permitted Columbia to
    provide due diligence information in response to “a request therefor by a Person who has
    made a bona fide written Acquisition Proposal,” subject only to the bidder entering into an
    NDA “on terms not less restrictive to the other party than those contained in” the NDA
    with TransCanada. It also provided that the NDA did not have to contain a standstill,
    thereby eschewing the deal lawyer’s trick of turning the requirement that the bidder sign
    an equivalent confidentiality agreement into a powerful backdoor defensive measure. The
    provision also authorized Columbia to redact the name of the person making written
    Acquisition Proposal. This aspect of the provision did not require a superior-proposal
    determination before furnishing due diligence, nor did it impose any delay before Columbia
    could comply. Cf. In re Compellent Techs., Inc. S’holder Litig., 
    2011 WL 6382523
    , at *6–
    8 (Del. Ch. Dec. 9, 2011) (discussing a radically buyer-friendly version of superior-
    proposal out and possible alternative formulations). The definition of Acquisition Proposal
    made this aspect of the provision easy to satisfy by defining that term as
    any proposal or offer . . . relating to any transaction or series of transactions
    involving
    (A) any direct or indirect sale, lease, transfer, exchange, acquisition
    or purchase of any assets or one or more businesses that constitute more than
    fifteen percent (15%) of the net revenues, net income, or assets of the
    Company and its Subsidiaries, taken as a whole, or more than fifteen percent
    (15%) of the total voting power of any class of equity securities of the
    Company,
    (B) any direct or indirect sale, exchange, transfer or other disposition,
    tender offer or exchange offer or similar transaction that, if consummated,
    would result in any Person or “group” . . . acquiring beneficial or record
    ownership of more than fifteen percent (15%) of the total voting power of
    any class of securities of the Company, or
    77
    (C) any merger, reorganization, consolidation, share exchange,
    business combination, recapitalization, liquidation, joint venture,
    partnership, dissolution or similar transaction involving the Company (or any
    Subsidiary or Subsidiaries . . . whose business constitutes more than fifteen
    percent (15%) of the net revenues, net income or consolidated assets of the
    Company and its Subsidiaries, taken as a whole).
    JX 1025 § 4.02(b)(i) (formatting altered).
    The Superior-Proposal Out required that before engaging or participating in any
    discussions or negotiations, Columbia had to made additional determinations. First, the
    Board had to determine “in good faith (after consultation with its outside legal counsel)
    that the failure to take such action would reasonably be expected to result in a breach of
    the directors’ fiduciary duties under applicable Law.” Second, the Board had to determine
    that the Acquisition Proposal “either constitutes a Superior Proposal or could reasonably
    be expected to result in a Superior Proposal,” with that term defined as
    a bona fide written Acquisition Proposal that did not result from a breach of
    this Section 4.02 relating to any acquisition or purchase by a Person or group
    of Persons of
    (A) assets that generate more than fifty percent (50%) of the
    consolidated total revenues of the Company and its Subsidiaries, taken as a
    whole, (B) assets that constitute more than fifty percent (50%) of the
    consolidated total assets of the Company and its Subsidiaries, taken as a
    whole, or (C) more than fifty percent (50%) of the total voting power of the
    equity securities of the Company,
    in each case, that the board of directors of the Company determines in good
    faith (after consultation with its financial advisor and outside legal counsel)
    [1] is reasonably likely to be consummated in accordance with its terms,
    taking into account
    (x) the timing and likelihood of consummation of the proposal
    (including whether such Acquisition Proposal is contingent on receipt
    78
    of third party financing or is terminable by the acquiring Person or
    group upon payment of a termination fee),
    (y) all legal, financial and regulatory aspects of the Acquisition
    Proposal and
    (z) the Person or group making the Acquisition Proposal
    (including in respect of the potential effects of any actions that might
    be required by any Government Antitrust Entity in connection with
    the consummation of such transaction), and
    [2] if consummated, would result in a transaction more favorable to the
    Company’s stockholders from a financial point of view than the Merger.
    
    Id. § 4.02(b)(ii)
    (formatting altered; Arabic numerals added). This dimension of the
    Superior-Proposal Out contained relatively middle-of-the-road standards for its exercise.
    Cf. Compellent, 
    2011 WL 6382523
    , at *6–8.
    The Merger Agreement also contained a no-change-of-recommendation provision
    with its own fiduciary out. As with the structure of the No-Shop Clause and Superior-
    Proposal Out, the provision first broadly prohibited the Board from taking any action or
    agreeing to take any action to (i) change its recommendation in favor of the Merger, (ii)
    recommend any Acquisition Proposal, (iii) cause or permit Columbia to enter into any letter
    of intent, agreement in principle, acquisition agreement, or merger agreement regarding
    any Acquisition Proposal, other than a confidentiality agreement as contemplated by the
    Superior-Proposal Out, or (iv) take any action to exempt an Acquisition Proposal from any
    takeover statute. JX 1025 § 4.02(c) .The Merger Agreement then provided that if Columbia
    received a Superior Proposal and the Board determined that its fiduciary duties required it,
    then the Board could change its recommendation or, if it wished, terminate the Merger
    Agreement for purposes of entering into an agreement with respect to Superior Proposal.
    79
    Before taking either step, Columbia had to give TransCanada notice that the Board
    intended to take that action, and TransCanada then would have four business days to match
    the Superior Proposal. The matching right was unlimited, and any new or revised Superior
    Proposal triggered an additional matching period of four business days. The pertinent
    provisions stated:
    Notwithstanding anything to the contrary set forth in [the no-change-of-
    recommendation provision], prior to the time [that stockholder approval of
    the Merger] is obtained and so long as the Company is in compliance with
    [No-Shop Clause]:
    (i) the board of directors of the Company may
    (A) effect a Change of Recommendation in response to a
    Superior Proposal that is not otherwise withdrawn at the time of the
    Change of Recommendation or
    (B) cause the Company to terminate this Agreement for the
    purpose of entering into a definitive agreement with respect to a
    Superior Proposal that is not otherwise withdrawn at the time of such
    termination (provided that the Company shall have paid the
    Termination Payment prior to or concurrently with such termination),
    which definitive agreement the Company shall enter into concurrently
    with or immediately following such termination,
    in either case, if and only if the board of directors of the
    Company determines in good faith (after consultation with its
    financial advisor and outside legal counsel) that the failure to take any
    such action would be inconsistent with the directors’ fiduciary duties
    under applicable Law; provided, however, that the board of directors
    of the Company may not take any such action unless
    (1) the Company first provides written notice to Parent
    (a “Superior Proposal Notice”) advising Parent that the board
    of directors of the Company intends to either effect a Change
    of Recommendation or terminate this Agreement pursuant to
    Section 7.01(c)(i), which notice shall specify the reasons
    therefor and include the material terms and conditions of the
    80
    applicable Superior Proposal and attach a copy of the most
    current draft of any written agreement relating thereto,
    (2) during the four (4) Business Day period following
    receipt by Parent of the Superior Proposal Notice (the
    “Superior Proposal Negotiation Period”) (it being understood
    that the first Business Day following the day on which a
    Superior Proposal Notice is received shall be the first day of
    the Superior Proposal Negotiation Period), the Company
    negotiates in good faith with Parent and its Representatives, to
    the extent requested by Parent, with respect to any revisions to
    the terms of the transactions contemplated by this Agreement
    proposed by Parent; provided, however, that if during any
    Superior Proposal Negotiation Period there shall occur any
    subsequent amendment to any material term of the applicable
    Superior Proposal, the Company shall provide a new Superior
    Proposal Notice and a new Superior Proposal Negotiation
    Period shall commence (provided that, with respect to any
    Superior Proposal, each new Superior Proposal Negotiation
    Period that commences shall be for a period of four (4) days,
    except that in no event shall any new Superior Proposal
    Negotiation Period shorten the four (4) Business Day duration
    of the first Superior Proposal Negotiation Period) and
    (3) at or after 5:00 p.m., New York City time, on the last
    day of the Superior Proposal Negotiation Period, the board of
    directors of the Company (after consultation with its financial
    advisor and outside legal counsel) determines that the Superior
    Proposal would continue to be a Superior Proposal, taking into
    account any changes to the terms of this Agreement theretofore
    agreed to by Parent in writing . . . .
    
    Id. § 4.02(d)(i)
    (formatting altered). A separate fiduciary out permitted the Board to change
    its recommendation in response to an “Intervening Event,” defined as “an event, fact,
    occurrence, development or circumstance that was not known to” the Board “as of the date
    of this Agreement (or if known, the consequences of which were not known to the board
    of directors of the Company as of the date of this Agreement) . . . .” 
    Id. § 4.02(d)(ii).
    Unlike
    81
    with a Superior Proposal, the Board could not terminate the Merger Agreement in response
    to an Intervening Event.
    If the Board terminated the Merger Agreement in response to a Superior Proposal
    or if Columbia’s stockholders failed to approve the Merger, then Columbia was required
    to (i) pay TransCanada a $309 million termination fee and (ii) reimburse TransCanada for
    “authorization, preparation, negotiation, execution and performance” expenses not to
    exceed $40 million. 
    Id. § 7.02(c).
    Those amounts represented 3.42% of the total equity
    value of the Merger, which was $10.2 billion. TransCanada believed that a Superior
    Proposal would “effectively require total consideration greater than $26.27 per share”
    because the termination fee was equivalent to 77 cents per share, or roughly 3% of $25.50.
    JX 1093 at 6. The $40 million expense reimbursement would increase the per-share figure
    by another 10 cents.
    Although these provisions created obstacles for competing bidders, they did not
    undermine the sale process for appraisal purposes. Commentators have perceived that
    under the Delaware Supreme Court’s recent appraisal decisions, a sale process will
    function as a reliable indicator of fair value if it would pass muster if reviewed under
    82
    enhanced scrutiny in a breach of fiduciary duty case.38 The combination of deal protection
    measures would not have supported a claim for breach of fiduciary duty.39
    38
    Compare Lawrence A. Hamermesh & Michael L. Wachter, Finding the Right
    Balance in Appraisal Litigation: Deal Price, Deal Process, and Synergies, 73 Bus. Law.
    961, 962 (2018) (commending outcomes in Dell and DFC and arguing that “the Delaware
    courts’ treatment of the use of the deal price to determine fair value does and should mirror
    the treatment of shareholder class action fiduciary duty litigation”), and 
    id. at 982–83
    (citing Dell and DFC and observing, “What we discern from the case law, however, is a
    tendency to rely on deal price to measure fair value where the transaction would survive
    enhanced judicial scrutiny . . . . Thus, in order to determine whether to use the deal price
    to establish fair value, the Delaware courts are engaging in the same sort of scrutiny they
    would have applied under Revlon if the case were one challenging the merger as in breach
    of the directors’ fiduciary duties.” (footnote omitted)), with Charles Korsmo & Minor
    Myers, The Flawed Corporate Finance of Dell and DFC Global, 68 Emory L.J. 221, 269
    (2018) (criticizing Dell and DFC as “conflat[ing] questions of fiduciary duty liability with
    the valuation questions central to appraisal disputes”).
    39
    See, e.g., Dent v. Ramtron Int’l Corp., 
    2014 WL 2931180
    , at *8–10 (Del. Ch. June
    30, 2014) (rejecting fiduciary challenge to “(1) a no-solicitation provision; (2) a standstill
    provision; (3) a change in recommendation provision; (4) information rights for [the
    acquirer]; and (5) a $5 million termination fee” where termination fee represented 4.5% of
    equity value and change-of-recommendation provision included unlimited match right); In
    re Novell, Inc. S’holder Litig., 
    2013 WL 322560
    , at *10 (Del. Ch. Jan. 3, 2013) (describing
    “the no solicitation provision, the matching rights provision, and the termination fee” as
    “customary and well within the range permitted under Delaware law” and observing that
    “[t]he mere inclusion of such routine terms does not amount to a breach of fiduciary duty”);
    In re Answers Corp. S’holders Litig., 
    2011 WL 1366780
    , at *4 & n.47 (Del. Ch. Apr. 11,
    2011) (describing “a termination fee plus expense reimbursement of 4.4% of the Proposed
    Transaction’s equity value, a no solicitation clause, a ‘no-talk’ provision limiting the
    Board’s ability to discuss an alternative transaction with an unsolicited bidder, a matching
    rights provision, and a force-the-vote requirement” as “standard merger terms” that “do not
    alone constitute breaches of fiduciary duty” (quoting In re 3Com S’holders Litig., 
    2009 WL 5173804
    , at *7 (Del. Ch. Dec. 18, 2009))); In re Atheros Commc’ns, Inc. S’holder
    Litig., 
    2011 WL 864928
    , at *7 n.61 (Del. Ch. Mar. 4, 2011) (same analysis for no-
    solicitation provision, matching right, and termination fee); In re 3Com, 
    2009 WL 5173804
    , at *7 & n.37 (also same analysis for no-solicitation provision, matching right,
    and termination fee (collecting authorities)).
    83
    The facts of Aruba involved a similar suite of deal protections. The merger
    agreement in that case “prohibited Aruba from soliciting competing offers and required the
    Aruba Board to continue to support the merger, subject to a fiduciary out and an out for an
    unsolicited superior proposal” and included a termination fee equal to 3% of the merger’s
    equity value. Aruba Trial, 
    2018 WL 922139
    , at *21, *38. The matching rights were similar
    too: HP had “an unlimited match right, with five days to match the first superior proposal
    and two days to match any subsequent increase, and during the match period Aruba had to
    negotiate exclusively and in good faith with HP.” 
    Id. at *38
    (footnote omitted). Viewing
    the deal protections holistically, the Delaware Supreme Court found that potential buyers
    had an open chance to bid, which supported the high court’s use of a deal-price-less-
    synergies metric to establish fair value. See 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 136
    .
    The outcome in Aruba comports with guidance from a frequently cited treatise,
    which identifies “critical aspects” of a merger agreement that does not “preclude or
    impermissibly impede a post-signing market check.” Kling & Nugent, supra, § 4.04[6][b],
    at 4-89 to -90.
    First, the economics of the executed agreement must be such that it does not
    unduly impede the ability of third parties to make competing bids. Types of
    arrangements that might raise questions in this regard include asset lock-ups,
    stock lock-ups, no-shops, force-the-vote provisions, and termination fees.
    The operative word is “unduly;” the impact will vary depending upon the
    actual type of device involved and its specific terms.
    ***
    Second, the target should be permitted to disclose confidential information
    to any third party who has on its own (i.e., not been solicited) “shown up” in
    the sense that it has submitted a proposal or, at a minimum, an indication of
    interest which is, or which the target believes is, reasonably likely to lead to
    84
    (and who is capable of consummating) a higher competing bid. In this regard,
    the target should also be able to negotiate with such third parties. This
    removes any informational advantage that the initial (anointed) purchaser
    may have.
    ***
    Finally, the target board of directors should have the contractual right,
    without violating the acquisition agreement, to withdraw or modify its
    recommendation to shareholders with respect to the transaction provided for
    in the executed acquisition agreement.
    
    Id. at 4-90
    to -94.1 (footnotes omitted). Using this framework, the deal protections did not
    preclude or impermissibly impede a post-signing market check. Columbia waived the
    standstills with Dominion, NextEra, and Berkshire before signing the Merger Agreement,
    so those provisions did not operate as a constraint during the post-signing period. Any party
    could obtain due diligence simply by submitting a bona fide written Acquisition Proposal
    and entering into the required confidentiality agreement; the initial Acquisition Proposal
    did not itself have to be a Superior Proposal. If the competing bidder then made an
    Acquisition Proposal that either constituted or could reasonably be expected to result in a
    Superior Proposal, and if the Board determined that its fiduciary duties required it, then the
    Board could negotiate with the competing bidder. And if the competing bidder made a
    Superior Proposal that TransCanada was unable or unwilling to match, then the Board
    could withdraw or modify its recommendation in support of the Merger Agreement. Going
    beyond what the treatise describes, Columbia could take the additional step of terminating
    the Merger Agreement and entering into an agreement regarding the Superior Proposal,
    subject only to paying a termination fee and expense reimbursement equal to 3.42% of the
    Merger’s equity value.
    85
    The petitioners try to bolster their argument about the deal protections by
    contending that the Proxy distorted the informational content of the post-signing phase by
    creating the false impression that Parties B, C, and D were never subject to standstills,
    which they say a competing bidder would take into account when deciding whether to
    intervene. Under this view, if those parties and TransCanada had been conducting due
    diligence in November 2015, and if only TransCanada renewed its interest later on, then a
    party considering a competing bid might reasonably believe that TransCanada was paying
    top dollar because only TransCanada had decided to proceed. Under those circumstances,
    a potential competing bidder might view Columbia as fully vetted and decline to bid
    because of the winner’s curse.40 But a potential topping bidder might be more likely to take
    the risk of competing with TransCanada if it perceived that TransCanada had been able to
    move forward while standstills blocked its competitors. In that case, the competing bidder
    might think there was value that had not yet been priced.
    This argument presents a variation of the winner’s-curse theory that the Delaware
    Supreme Court rejected in Dell. There, the trial court found that Mr. Dell’s participation
    40
    Cf. In re Toys “R” Us, Inc. S’holder Litig., 
    877 A.2d 975
    , 1015 (Del. Ch. 2005)
    (“[I]n his scholarly work Subramanian argues that [the] combination of a termination fee
    and matching rights raises the fears second bidders have of suffering a ‘winner’s curse.’
    This is the anxiety that a first bidder will match the initial topping bid, only to refuse to
    match the next topping gambit, leaving the second bidder having paid more than was
    economically rational. This fear, Subramanian points out, is further exacerbated by the
    common circumstance that first bidders often have superior information on the target, and
    presumably know when to say when. Of course, the other side of this story is that the first
    bidder has taken the risk, suffered the search and opportunity costs, and done the due
    diligence required to establish the bidding floor.”).
    86
    gave the buyout group advantages that competing bidders would struggle to overcome and
    which therefore would deter bidding. See Dell Trial, 
    2016 WL 3186538
    , at *36, *42–44.
    The Delaware Supreme Court explained that “the likelihood of a winner’s curse can be
    mitigated through a due diligence process where buyers have access to all necessary
    information.” 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 32
    . The high court also cited the trial court’s observation
    that strategic buyers “are less subject to the winner’s curse because they typically possess
    industry-specific expertise and have asset-specific valuations that incorporate synergies.”
    
    Id. (internal quotation
    marks omitted). Finally, the Delaware Supreme Court emphasized
    the absence of evidence that another party was interested, explaining that “[f]air value
    entails at minimum a price some buyer is willing to pay—not a price at which no class of
    buyers in the market would pay.” 
    Id. at 29.
    Similarly in this case, any competing bidder could gain access to due diligence by
    submitting a bona fide written Acquisition Proposal and entering into a confidential
    agreement. Moreover, all of the likely bidders were strategic buyers. Most importantly, the
    petitioners have not shown that anyone would have made a topping bid. Columbia’s sale
    process involved most of the parties that its bankers thought would be interested, including
    Berkshire, Dominion, and NextEra. See JX 499. Each knew that it was subject to a
    standstill, and each would have believed that others were similarly bound. None wanted to
    buy Columbia at anything near TransCanada’s price. Spectra was never bound by a
    standstill, yet did not bid. There is no persuasive evidence that any other party wanted to
    bid. The evidence instead shows that no one wanted to bid. As in Dell, the most plausible
    87
    explanation is that “a topping bid involved a serious risk of overpayment.” 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 33
    . That in turn suggests that the deal price was “already at a level that is fair.” 
    Id. The petitioners
    failed to show that the Proxy distorted bidder behavior during the
    post-signing phase. More broadly, the petitioners failed to prove that the deal protection
    measures undermined the validity of the deal price. The better view of the evidence is that
    if a bidder had been serious, then it would have come forward.
    h.      The Sale Process Was Reliable.
    TransCanada proved by a preponderance of the evidence that the sale process made
    the deal price a persuasive indicator of fair value. The sale process was not perfect, and the
    petitioners highlighted its flaws, but the facts of this case, when viewed as a whole,
    compare favorably or are on par with the facts in DFC, Dell, and Aruba.
    In reaching this conclusion, I recognize the existence of other decisions that have
    sought to apply the teachings of DFC and Dell, and which have declined to rely on the deal
    price as an indicator of fair value.41 The petitioners have cited similarities between aspects
    of the sale processes in those cases and aspects of the sale process in this case, arguing that
    the deal price here was unreliable.
    41
    See Blueblade Capital Opportunities LLC v. Norcraft Cos., 
    2018 WL 3602940
    ,
    at *23–27 (Del. Ch. July 27, 2018); In re Appraisal of AOL, Inc., 
    2018 WL 1037450
    , at
    *8–10 (Del. Ch. Feb. 23, 2018) (subsequent history omitted). After post-trial briefing and
    argument in this case, this court took a similar approach in In re Appraisal of Jarden
    Corporation, 
    2019 WL 3244085
    , at *24–25 (Del. Ch. July 19, 2019).
    88
    In this decision, I have attempted to adhere to the principles expressed in DFC, Dell,
    and Aruba and to take into account how those decisions applied those principles to the
    facts. Those factual applications have important implications for the outcome here.
    I also continue to regard it as important that the Delaware Supreme Court’s
    decisions in Dell and DFC reversed trial court decisions for failing to give adequate weight
    to the deal price. In each case, the Delaware Supreme Court regarded the sale process as
    sufficiently good that the deal price deserved “heavy, if not dispositive, weight.” 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 23
    ; see 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 349
    , 351. The decisions did not address when a sale
    process would be sufficiently bad that a trial court could give the deal price no weight. The
    decisions also did not address when a sale process that was not as good would still be good
    enough for a trial court to give the deal price weight. Technically, the holdings did not
    delineate when a sale process was sufficiently good that the trial court should give it heavy
    if not dispositive weight. The Delaware Supreme Court could have believed the sale
    processes in DFC and Dell warranted that level of consideration without excluding the
    possibility that a not-as-good sale process could deserve the same treatment. I thus do not
    believe that the Delaware Supreme Court’s favorable comments regarding the sale
    processes in Dell and DFC establish minimum requirements for other sale processes to
    meet before the deal price can be considered as a persuasive indicator of fair value.
    The Aruba decision points in the same direction. There, the trial court found the sale
    process to be sufficiently reliable to use the deal price as a valuation indicator, but declined
    to give it weight. The Delaware Supreme Court accepted that the sale process was
    sufficiently reliable and used the deal price as the exclusive basis for its own fair value
    89
    determination. As with Dell and DFC, the Aruba decision did not have to address when a
    sale process was sufficiently bad that a trial court could decline to rely on the deal price.
    The sale process in this case had aspects that compare favorably with the processes
    in DFC, Dell, and Aruba. It also had aspects that differed from the processes in those cases.
    On balance, TransCanada proved that the deal price is a reliable indicator of fair value.
    3.     The Synergies Deduction
    “[I]t is widely assumed that the sale price in many M&A deals includes a portion of
    the buyer’s expected synergy gains, which is part of the premium the winning buyer must
    pay to prevail and obtain control.” 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 371
    . “In an arm’s-length, synergistic
    transaction, the deal price generally will exceed fair value because target fiduciaries
    bargain for a premium that includes . . . a share of the anticipated synergies . . . .” Olson v.
    ev3, Inc., 
    2011 WL 704409
    , at *10 (Del. Ch. Feb. 21, 2011). “[S]ection 262(h) requires
    that the Court of Chancery discern the going concern value of the company irrespective of
    the synergies involved in a merger.” M.P.M. 
    Enters., 731 A.2d at 797
    . To derive an
    estimate of fair value, the court must exclude “any synergies or other value expected from
    the merger giving rise to the appraisal proceeding itself . . . .” Golden Telecom 
    Trial, 993 A.2d at 507
    . “Of course, estimating synergies and allocating a reasonable portion to the
    seller certainly involves imprecision, but no more than other valuation methods, like a DCF
    analysis . . . .” 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 141
    .
    TransCanada announced a total of $250 million in target annual synergies, with
    $150 million attributable to cost and revenue synergies and $100 attributable to financing
    synergies. PTO ¶¶ 555, 632, 642; see Marchand Tr. 489–490. The financing synergies
    90
    resulted predominantly from TransCanada generating funds at its lower cost of capital, then
    channeling them through offshore financing structures to generate tax advantages.
    Marchand Tr. 490.
    The petitioners have questioned the financing synergies because they were not
    labeled “synergies.” In a board presentation, TransCanada labeled the cost and revenue
    saving as “synergies” and the financing benefits as “offshore.”42 The label is not
    dispositive. See Marchand Tr. 518. The Merger created value if it enabled TransCanada to
    finance Columbia’s business plan using its lower cost of capital. To the extent that value
    is included in the transaction price, it is value arising from the accomplishment or
    expectation of the Merger that must be deducted under Section 262(h).
    TransCanada asked its valuation expert, Mark Zmijewski, to value the synergies.
    Using a standard DCF methodology, Zmijewski calculated the net present value of the
    synergies at $4.64 per share. JX 1351 Ex. VI-3. Zmijewski did not use a DCF analysis to
    value Columbia, and he disagreed with many aspects of the DCF analysis prepared by the
    petitioners’ expert, so there is some irony in Zmijewski using it here. In Highfields, this
    court declined to use a synergies estimate that the respondent’s expert prepared using a
    DCF analysis, in part because the respondent’s expert had not used a DCF methodology
    42
    JX 935 at 12. In the presentation, TransCanada estimated $150 million in
    financing synergies. TransCanada lowered this estimate to $100 million for purposes of
    communicating to the markets, viewing the lower number as more realistic and achievable.
    See Marchand Tr. 494–96.
    91
    when rendering his other valuation opinions. See Highfields Capital, Ltd. v. AXA Fin., Inc.,
    
    939 A.2d 34
    , 60–61 (Del. Ch. 2007).
    The real question is the extent to which the deal price included synergies.
    TransCanada’s CFO testified that the deal price included 100% of the estimated synergies.
    See Marchand Tr. 490–91. Zmijewski tried to support this testimony by analyzing the
    reaction of TransCanada’s stock to the announcement of the Merger. He found that
    TransCanada’s share price dropped, which was consistent with the view that the Merger
    was a “bad deal for . . . TransCanada” and a “good deal for Columbia.” Zmijewski Tr.
    1447–48. Zmijewski’s analysis operated at the level of the overall deal price; it did not
    address the more detailed level of the synergy deduction. See JX 1350 ¶¶ 63–65.
    The contemporaneous evidence does not indicate that TransCanada allocated
    synergies to Columbia, much less all of the synergies. TransCanada relies on a presentation
    to its board that references the full value of both the cost and financing synergies and claims
    it shows that the synergies were fully allocated to Columbia. See JX 935 at 12. The page
    where these figures appear calculates transaction multiples by taking enterprise values for
    Columbia that were implied by various prices per share, then dividing those multiples by
    EBITDA metrics, some of which add synergy figures. See 
    id. This table
    does not indicate
    that the synergies were allocated to Columbia, and the “football field” page in the
    presentation places the deal price comfortably within TransCanada’s DCF valuation of
    Columbia without synergies. See 
    id. at 6.
    TransCanada also observes that after Columbia
    rejected its offer of $25.25 per share, Poirier suggested attempting to identify additional
    synergies that could justify increasing the offer. See JX 911 at 1, 4. TransCanada says that
    92
    if it had not already priced the synergies into its offer, then there would have been no need
    to search for additional synergies. But the email exchange shows a range of views among
    TransCanada executives about the amount that TransCanada should be willing to pay. The
    email does not suggest that TransCanada had topped out its bid with all of the synergies
    going to Columbia.
    Other internal TransCanada documents focus only on cost synergy estimates of
    $150 million per year. See JX 878 at 48; JX 886 at 28. One informative package of
    materials for the TransCanada board of directors values Columbia at $26.51 per share using
    a DCF methodology, then values the cost synergies at $1.93 per Columbia share, with a
    sensitivity range of $1.89 to $2.61 per share. See JX 1008 at 54; accord JX 1018 at 1, 24,
    26. The deal price of $25.50 per share falls comfortably within TransCanada’s valuation
    ranges without any allocation of synergies. See JX 1008 at 50; JX 1018 at 22; JX 1365 ¶¶
    91–92. It also appears, as TransCanada argues, that there were many sources for merger-
    related value creation that justified paying a premium over Columbia’s trading price, and
    the cost, revenue, and financing synergies were simply the easiest to quantify. See, e.g., JX
    1027 (synergy overview). But the fact that TransCanada perceived synergies does not mean
    that the deal price included them.43
    43
    The petitioners argue that the alternative is zero, relying on an article from 1987
    that Zmijewski cited in his report. See JX 9. The authors examined a sample of tender offers
    from 1963 to 1984 and observed that “[o]nly when competing bids are actually made do
    we observe greater returns to target shareholders and a dissipation of the initial gains to the
    stockholders of the bidding firms.” 
    Id. at 22–23.
    The petitioners argue that Columbia never
    solicited competing bids, so Columbia could not have extracted any synergies. The article
    does not support this claim. It finds that targets extract a share of surplus even in single-
    93
    Given this evidence, I am not able to credit TransCanada’s position that Columbia
    received 100% of synergies worth $4.64 per share. TransCanada bore the burden of proving
    a downward adjustment for synergies. TransCanada did not meet its burden of proof.
    TransCanada likely could have justified a smaller synergy deduction, but it claimed a larger
    and unpersuasive one. This decision therefore declines to make any downward adjustment
    to the deal price.
    4.     Change In Value Between Signing And Closing
    Because the valuation date in an appraisal is the date on which the merger closes,
    fair value must be determined based on the “operative reality” at the effective time. See
    Technicolor 
    IV, 684 A.2d at 298
    . The deal price provides an indication of the value of the
    company on the date of signing. It does not necessarily provide an indication of the value
    of the company on the date of closing. In this case, over three months passed between the
    signing of the Merger Agreement on March 17, 2016, and the closing of the Merger on
    July 1, 2016. The petitioners contend that Columbia’s value increased during this period.
    As the party arguing for an upward adjustment to the deal price, the petitioners bore the
    burden of proof on this issue.
    By treating the petitioners as having argued that Columbia’s value increased
    between signing and closing, this decision is giving the petitioners the benefit of the doubt
    bidder contests, but also finds that only in multi-bidder contests do the returns to bidders
    dissipate. The article thus supports the view that TransCanada did not share all of its
    synergies with Columbia. It does not support the view that TransCanada did not share any
    of its synergies with Columbia.
    94
    on an argument they did not explicitly make. The petitioners argued that if the court
    adopted Columbia’s unaffected trading price as an indicator of fair value, then it should
    make an upwards adjustment because Columbia’s value would have increased by the time
    of closing. The petitioners did not make the same argument about the deal price, but the
    same logic applies. Using either the unaffected trading price or the deal price results in a
    temporal gap between the valuation indicator and the closing date. In this case, the date for
    the unaffected trading price was March 9, 2016. The parties signed the Merger Agreement
    on March 17. The deal closed on July 1. The length of the intervening periods differs by
    only eight days.
    The problem with giving the petitioners the benefit of the doubt on this argument is
    that they did not suggest a means of adjusting the deal price to reflect the increases in value
    that resulted from the factors they cite. Perhaps an expert could have constructed a metric,
    but the petitioners in this case did not provide one. For purposes of adjusting the deal price,
    the petitioners failed to satisfy their burden of proof.
    The petitioners’ arguments for an upward adjustment are also unpersuasive in their
    own right. They contend that Columbia’s value increased because the market for CPPL’s
    equity recovered and because commodity prices improved. The petitioners did not provide
    persuasive evidence on either point.
    a.      An Improved Market For CPPL Equity
    In their first argument for an upward adjustment, the petitioners contend that
    Columbia’s value increased between signing and closing because the market for CPPL’s
    peers recovered. They proposed using changes in indices of peer companies to translate
    95
    those developments into an increased trading price for CPPL. They also cite circumstantial
    evidence that CPPL’s trading price was rising in late February and early March 2016,
    possibly suggesting an upward trend that would have continued if Columbia had not
    announced the Merger. See Dkt. 390 Ex. D.
    The petitioners’ theory builds on the fact that after the spinoff, CPPL’s trading price
    declined as part of broader investor dissatisfaction with MLPs. Columbia recognized that
    it could not use CPPL to raise the growth capital needed for its business plan, so it explored
    less attractive alternatives like a parent-level equity raise. The petitioners argue that if
    CPPL’s trading price had recovered, then Columbia could have used CPPL to fund its
    business plan.
    As their primary evidence of a price change, the petitioners cite the Alerian MLP
    Index and the Alerian Natural Gas MLP Index (the “Gas Index”), both of which improved
    by approximately 17% between signing and closing.44 CPPL’s price did not improve during
    the same period; it fell. The petitioners address this difficulty by pointing to two analyst
    reports and to internal emails from a petitioner fund, which suggest that CPPL’s trading
    price dropped after the announcement of the Merger because market participants feared
    44
    The petitioners also rely on a Wells Fargo research report that mentions that
    certain MLPs had success raising capital in 2016, but it did not focus on natural gas MLPs.
    See JX 1468. The successful equity raises largely involved blue-chip sponsors, offered
    preferred units that Columbia could not support because of its debt load, or were completed
    through at-the-market raises, a technique that could not have sustained Columbia’s
    business plan. See Adamson Tr. 1333–40, 1406–09.
    96
    that TransCanada would not transfer assets to CPPL to the same degree as Columbia would
    have on a standalone basis. See JX 1069 at 8; JX 1056; JX 1061.
    There are several problems with the petitioners’ reliance on the indices. The broader
    Alerian MLP Index is a poor proxy for CPPL. It consists of firms that transport or store
    energy commodities generally, and it tends to tracks the price of crude oil. See Jeffers Tr.
    743–44; Jeffers Dep. 75; see also JX 740 at 9–10. The Gas Index provides a better proxy,
    but the petitioners’ industry expert testified that the higher prices and lower yields
    associated with that index resulted from the announcement of the Merger, which restored
    the market’s faith in natural gas MLPs. See Goodof Tr. 151. To the extent his testimony
    accurately captured the reasons for the change, then any increase in value implied by the
    Gas Index would have resulted from the accomplishment or expectation of the Merger and
    would need to be excluded under Section 262(h). In actuality, TransCanada demonstrated
    that the lower yields resulted from changes in the composition of the Gas Index. See JX
    1470; Goodof Tr. 152–54. TransCanada also demonstrated that the lower yields did not
    reach the level that Columbia needed to use CPPL to fund its business plan. See Adamson
    Tr. 1338–39. The change in the Gas Index does not persuasively support an increase in
    Columbia’s value.
    More broadly, Columbia’s inability to raise growth capital through CPPL reflected
    investors’ wider concerns about MLPs. Because of developments in the broader MLP
    industry, this model of raising capital was fundamentally broken. See JX 547; JX 1345 at
    72–76. It was particularly broken at Columbia, which faced additional difficulties in raising
    capital because of its high debt load. See Adamson Tr. 1332–37. A three-month uptick in
    97
    the two Alerian indices does not prove that Columbia fixed its model and does not support
    an increase in Columbia’s value.
    b.     An Improved Market For Commodities
    In their second argument, the petitioners cite changes in commodity prices. They
    point out that after the spinoff, Columbia’s trading price dropped as energy stocks fell out
    of favor because of a decline in commodity prices. They argue that as commodity prices
    recovered, energy stocks recovered. They point out that between signing and closing, the
    prices of natural gas and natural gas futures increased by 58.79% and 55.15%, respectively.
    See PTO ¶¶ 685, 690.
    One difficulty with this argument is that Columbia’s stock price did not recover with
    commodity prices. It remained stagnant until the Merger leaked on March 9, 2016. See
    Dkt. 390 Ex. A. The bigger difficulty with this argument is something everyone agrees on:
    Columbia’s value does not depend on commodity prices, except at the extremes when ultra-
    low commodity prices could affect the creditworthiness of Columbia’s counterparties. See
    PTO ¶¶ 293–94. The petitioners correctly point out that the declining stock market hurt
    Columbia in fall 2015, and they say that the mirror-image trend should benefit Columbia
    on the upside. But in fall 2015, the declining market hurt Columbia because it could not
    use CPPL to raise equity capital. Columbia then faced the prospect of raising equity capital
    by issuing its own shares in a declining market, which would dilute Columbia’s value and
    threaten a downward spiral. The problems that Columbia faced from a declining market
    did not reflect operational problems. They reflected constrained financing alternatives. The
    commodity-price story does not support an increase in Columbia’s value.
    98
    5.     The Conclusion Regarding The Deal Price
    TransCanada proved that the deal price is a reliable indicator of fair value.
    TransCanada failed to prove that the consideration provided in the Merger included
    synergies of $4.64 per share. The petitioners failed to prove that Columbia’s value
    increased between signing and closing, and they failed to prove how any change in value
    could be translated into an adjustment to the deal price. The market-tested indicator for the
    fair value of Columbia is therefore $25.50 per share.
    B.     The Unaffected Trading Price
    TransCanada contends that the unaffected trading price of Columbia’s stock is a
    strong indicator of Columbia’s fair value. The petitioners contend that the court should not
    give any weight to Columbia’s trading price. As the proponent of this valuation metric,
    TransCanada bore the burden of demonstrating its reliability.
    Both sides retained experts who rendered opinions on the persuasiveness of the
    unaffected trading price as an indicator of fair value. TransCanada relied on Zmijewski,
    who is an emeritus professor of finance at the University of Chicago and a consultant at
    Charles River Associates. The petitioners relied on Eric Talley, a professor of law at
    Columbia University and co-director of the Millstein Center for Global Markets and
    Corporate Ownership.
    The parties debated many issues relating to the unaffected trading price, including
    (i) whether the trading price could provide insight into fundamental value, (ii) whether the
    trading price contained an implicit minority discount, (iii) whether investors lacked access
    to or the trading price otherwise failed to incorporate material information about
    99
    Columbia’s value, and (iv) whether investor sentiment about broader trends in the energy
    markets artificially depressed Columbia’s trading price. This decision could devote many
    pages to parsing through the competing expert testimony, the parties’ evidentiary
    showings, and their legal arguments.
    Ultimately, however, Delaware precedent demonstrates that a reliable trading price
    is not a prerequisite to a reliable determination of fair value based on a deal-price-less-
    synergies metric. Consequently, assuming TransCanada failed to prove that the trading
    price was a reliable indicator of fair value, that ruling would not undermine this court’s
    ability to rely on the deal price. Indeed, even if the petitioners proved affirmatively that the
    trading price was an unreliable indicator of fair value, that finding would not undermine
    this court’s ability to rely on the deal price. On the facts of this case, the deal-price-less-
    synergies metric is the most reliable approach, making the analysis of the trading price
    comparatively unimportant.
    The Delaware cases that have developed the deal-price-less-synergies metric
    demonstrate that a reliable trading price is not a prerequisite to a reliable deal-price-based
    determination of fair value. The Union Illinois decision was the first time a Delaware court
    deployed the deal-price-less-synergies metric,45 and that decision used it as the exclusive
    45
    As precedent for the deal-price-less-synergies metric, the Union Illinois decision
    cited three cases: M.P.M. Enterprises, Cooper v. Pabst Brewing Company, 
    1993 WL 208763
    (Del. Ch. June 8, 1993), and Van de Walle v. Unimation, Inc., 
    1991 WL 29303
    (Del. Ch. Mar. 7, 1991). See Union 
    Illinois, 847 A.2d at 343
    (citing the three cases and
    stating that “our case law recognizes that when there is an open opportunity to buy a
    company, the resulting market price is reliable evidence of fair value”).
    100
    The Pabst decision appears to be the first Delaware case to determine fair value by
    drawing on the pricing of the deal that gave rise to the appraisal proceeding, but the Pabst
    court did so in a manner that differed from Union Illinois. After a public auction involving
    competitive bidding by multiple suitors, G. Heileman Brewing Company acquired Pabst
    Brewing Company through a structurally coercive, two-tiered tender offer, in which
    Heileman paid $32 per share in the first step and squeezed out the remaining stockholders
    in the back-end merger for a package of subordinated debentures with a face value of $24
    per share. Pabst, 
    1993 WL 208763
    , at *2, *8. The court rejected all of the parties’ valuation
    methods, forcing the court to “make a determination based upon its own analysis.” 
    Id. at *8.
    The court reached a fair value conclusion of $27 per share by blending the front-end
    and back-end consideration to reach a value of $29.50, and then deducting a control
    premium, which the court estimated “did not exceed $2.50 per share.” 
    Id. at *8,
    *10. The
    court did not equate the control premium with a synergies-based deduction.
    After Pabst, the concept of a deal price metric next surfaced in M.P.M. Enterprises.
    The petitioners were minority stockholders in privately held company that was sold to a
    third-party buyer. The trial court valued the company using a DCF analysis. The respondent
    appealed, asserting that the trial court erred by failing to give weight to the transaction price
    and relying heavily on Van de Walle, a breach of fiduciary duty action in which a controlled
    company was sold to a third party and all stockholders received consideration having the
    same value. As one of many reasons for entering judgment in favor of the defendants, the
    Van de Walle court cited the arm’s-length negotiations between the seller and the buyer. In
    an eloquent turn of phrase that has figured prominently in twenty-first century appraisal
    decisions, the Van de Walle court observed that “[t]he fact that a transaction price was
    forged in the crucible of objective market reality (as distinguished from the unavoidably
    subjective thought process of a valuation expert) is viewed as strong evidence that the price
    is fair.” 
    1991 WL 29303
    , at *17. In M.P.M. Enterprises, however, the Delaware Supreme
    Court distinguished Van de Walle as a breach of fiduciary duty case and observed that “[a]
    fair merger price in the context of a breach of fiduciary duty claim will not always be a fair
    value in the context of determining going concern 
    value.” 731 A.2d at 797
    . The high court
    did express agreement with “the general statement made by the Court in Van de Walle” to
    the effect that “[a] merger price resulting from arms-length negotiations where there are no
    claims of collusion is a very strong indication of fair value.” 
    Id. But the
    high court again
    cautioned that “in an appraisal action, that merger price must be accompanied by evidence
    tending to show that it represent the going concern value of the company rather than just
    the value of the company to one specific buyer.” 
    Id. Citing the
    trial court’s broad discretion
    when assessing fair value, the high court in M.P.M. Enterprises affirmed the trial court.
    101
    basis for valuing a privately held company. See Union 
    Illinois, 847 A.2d at 343
    (“UFG was
    not a public company and therefore its shares were not listed for trading on a stock
    exchange.”). The foundational decision for the deal-price-less-synergies metric thus
    deployed it in the absence of any trading price, much less a reliable trading price. See 
    id. at 357,
    364 (awarding “the value of the Merger Price net of synergies” after finding that
    the deal price was “the most reliable evidence of fair value” and “giving 100% weight to
    that factor”).
    Three years after Union Illinois, the Highfields decision was next to deploy the deal-
    price-less-synergies metric, and the first to use it for a widely held, publicly traded firm.
    See 
    Highfields, 939 A.2d at 61
    (giving 75% weight to deal-price-less-synergies metric).
    The court regarded the trading price as an unreliable indicator of fair value, because the
    “stock price included an element of value reflecting merger speculation leading up to [the
    merger’s] announcement.” 
    Id. at 58.
    Even so, the court had no difficulty finding that after
    deducting synergies, the deal price was a reliable indicator where it “resulted from an
    arm’s-length bargaining process where no structural impediments existed that might
    prevent a topping bid.” 
    Id. at 59.
    The Highfields decision shows that the deal-price-less-
    synergies metric does not require a reliable trading price.
    After Highfields, the deal-price metric lay dormant for six years before returning to
    prominence in a string of five decisions issued between 2013 and 2015. 46 Each of those
    46
    Merion Capital LP v. BMC Software, Inc., 
    2015 WL 6164771
    (Del. Ch. Oct. 21,
    2015); LongPath Capital, LLC v. Ramtron Int’l Corp., 
    2015 WL 4540443
    (Del. Ch. June
    30, 2015); Merlin P’rs LP v. AutoInfo, Inc., 
    2015 WL 2069417
    (Del. Ch. Apr. 30, 2015);
    102
    decisions determined fair value based solely on the deal price, and in finding that the deal
    price was reliable, each decision focused predominantly on whether the merger resulted
    from a “proper transactional process.”47 The decisions did not view the reliability of the
    deal price as turning on the reliability of the trading price. Only one of the decisions
    considered the reliability of the trading price. In AutoInfo, the petitioners argued that the
    company “was thinly traded and lacked financial analyst coverage[,]” which led to “the
    market underpric[ing] the company because it was ignorant of its potential.” AutoInfo,
    
    2015 WL 2069417
    , at *12. The court rejected this argument as a basis for undermining the
    deal price as an indicator of fair value, explaining that “the Merger price does not reflect
    the value that a potentially uniformed market attributed to AutoInfo.” 
    Id. The court
    noted
    that the deal price generated a premium of 22% over the unaffected trading price and
    concluded that “[w]hile the market may have been uninformed about AutoInfo before the
    sale process, it subsequently gained ample information” by virtue of the sale process. 
    Id. In re
    Appraisal of Ancestry.com, Inc., 
    2015 WL 399726
    (Del. Ch. Jan. 30, 2015); Huff
    Fund Inv. P’ship v. CKx, Inc., 
    2013 WL 5878807
    (Del. Ch. Nov. 1, 2013). At the trial level
    in Golden Telecom, this court stated that “an arms-length merger price resulting from an
    effective market check is entitled to great weight in an appraisal.” Golden Telecom 
    Trial, 993 A.2d at 507
    . The trial court in Golden Telecom declined to apply the deal-price-less-
    synergies metric on the facts of the case because two large stockholders holding a
    combined 44% of the equity stood on both sides of the transaction and a special committee
    treated the deal as if the company had a controlling stockholder. 
    Id. at 508–09.
           47
    Ramtron, 
    2015 WL 4540443
    , at *20; see BMC, 
    2015 WL 6164771
    , at *14
    (“robust, arm’s-length sales process”); Ancestry.com, 
    2015 WL 399726
    , at *16 (“[T]he
    process here . . . appears to me to represent an auction of the Company that is unlikely to
    have left significant stockholder value unaccounted for.”).
    103
    The reliability of the sale process rendered irrelevant the potential unreliability of the
    trading price.
    The decisions that followed Highfields and preceded the Delaware Supreme Court’s
    decision in DFC thus illustrate a general rule that trading-price reliability is not a
    prerequisite for deal-price reliability. DFC does not suggest a contrary rule. The DFC
    decision cited with approval both Union Illinois, where the trial court used the deal price
    for a privately held company, and multiple post-Highfields rulings that had relied on the
    deal price without regard to the trading price or despite evidence that it was unreliable. See
    
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 363
    n.84.
    Dell also does not suggest a contrary rule. The Delaware Supreme Court found that
    both the trading price and the deal price were reliable indicators of value. See 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 5-7
    , 24-27, 35. The high court did not hold that its finding as to the latter depended
    on the former. Instead, the Dell decision regarded the trial court’s treatment of the trading
    price and the deal price as independent sources of error.
    The Delaware Supreme Court’s most recent appraisal decision cuts the same way.
    In Aruba, the Delaware Supreme Court held that the trial court erred by relying on the
    unaffected trading price. The high court indicated that the trading price was unreliable
    partly because the market had not received information about Aruba’s strong earnings. See
    
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 138
    –39. At the same time, the decision accepted the trial court’s finding
    that the deal price was a reliable valuation indicator. See 
    id. at 141–42.
    The Delaware
    Supreme Court pointed to HP’s “access to nonpublic information to supplement its
    consideration of the public information available to stock market buyers,” including that it
    104
    “knew about Aruba’s strong quarterly earnings before the market did, and likely took that
    information into account when pricing the deal.” 
    Id. at 139.
    The reliability of the deal price
    thus operated independently of the trading price. Like DFC, the Aruba decision cited Union
    Illinois and Highfields with approval. See 
    id. at 135
    n.41.
    Based on these authorities, this decision does not have to make a finding regarding
    the reliability of the trading price as a condition to relying on the deal price. It remains
    conceivable that there could be a case where the parties anchored deal negotiations off the
    trading price, but this is not that case. All of the bidders, including TransCanada, submitted
    expressions of interest based on their views of Columbia’s value. Although the various
    parties at times referred to market premiums when discussing bids or potential bids, the
    bids were not priced at a premium over the trading price. TransCanada’s chief concern
    about the trading price was that Columbia might demand a big premium, creating a risk of
    overpayment. See, e.g., JX 594 (Poirier remarking that “[if] the stock trades up,
    [Columbia’s] pricing expectations will increase accordingly, and this transaction will be
    challenging for us.”).
    As in Aruba, TransCanada submitted its formal bids after conducting extensive due
    diligence and receiving considerable non-public information, including (i) long-term
    management projections and (ii) the precedent agreements that secured Columbia’s growth
    projects. TransCanada and Columbia then went back and forth over price based on the
    confidential information that Columbia possessed and TransCanada had obtained. These
    efforts “improved the parties’ ability to estimate” Columbia’s “going-concern value over
    that of the market as a whole.” 
    Aruba, 210 A.3d at 139
    .
    105
    To reiterate, if the petitioners proved that the trading price in this case was an
    unreliable indicator of fair value, then it would not undermine the reliability of the deal
    price given the manner in which Columbia proceeded. This decision therefore has not
    parsed the parties’ many arguments about the trading price. I have considered that form of
    market evidence, and having done so, I regard the deal price as a more reliable indicator of
    value. Relying on the trading price would only inject error into the fair value determination.
    C.     The Discounted Cash Flow Method
    The petitioners contend that the court should determine Columbia’s fair value using
    a DCF analysis prepared by their expert, William Jeffers. He valued Columbia at $32.47
    per share. TransCanada did not submit its own DCF analysis. Instead, Zmijewski critiqued
    Jeffers’s model. As the proponent of valuing Columbia based on the work of their expert,
    the petitioners bore the burden of proving the reliability of his valuation.
    The DCF method is a technique that is generally accepted in the financial
    community. “While the particular assumptions underlying its application may always be
    challenged in any particular case, the validity of [the DCF] technique qua valuation
    methodology is no longer open to question.” Campbell-Taggart, 
    1989 WL 17438
    , at *8
    n.11. It is a “standard” method that “gives life to the finance principle that firms should be
    valued based on the expected value of their future cash flows, discounted to present value
    in a manner that accounts for risk.” Andaloro v. PFPC Worldwide, Inc., 
    2005 WL 2045640
    ,
    at *9 (Del. Ch. Aug. 19, 2005).
    The DCF model entails three basic components: an estimation of net cash
    flows that the firm will generate and when, over some period; a terminal or
    residual value equal to the future value, as of the end of the projection period,
    106
    of the firm’s cash flows beyond the projection period; and finally a cost of
    capital with which to discount to a present value both the projected net cash
    flows and the estimated terminal or residual value.
    In re Radiology Assocs., Inc. Litig., 
    611 A.2d 485
    , 490 (Del. Ch. 1991) (internal quotation
    marks omitted).
    In Dell and DFC, the Delaware Supreme Court cautioned against using the DCF
    methodology when market-based indicators are available. In Dell, the high court explained
    that “[a]lthough widely considered the best tool for valuing companies when there is no
    credible market information and no market check, DCF valuations involve many inputs—
    all subject to disagreement by well-compensated and highly credentialed experts—and
    even slight differences in these inputs can produce large valuation gaps.” 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 37
    –38. The high court warned that when market evidence is available, “the Court of
    Chancery should be chary about imposing the hazards that always come when a law-trained
    judge is forced to make a point estimate of fair value based on widely divergent partisan
    expert testimony.” 
    Id. at 35.
    Making the same point conversely in DFC, the Delaware
    Supreme Court advised that a DCF model should be used in appraisal proceedings “when
    the respondent company was not public or was not sold in an open market check . . . .”
    
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 369
    n.118. The high court commented that “a singular discounted cash
    flow model is often most helpful when there isn’t an observable market price.” 
    Id. at 370.
    This case is not one where a DCF valuation is likely to provide a reliable indication
    of fair value. Columbia was publicly traded, widely held, and sold in a process that began
    with pre-signing outreach and finished with an open, albeit passive, post-signing market
    107
    check. Jeffers’s valuation of $32.47 per share stands in contrast with contemporaneous
    market evidence.
          Jeffers’s valuation is 27% higher than the deal price of $25.50 per share.
          Jeffers’s valuation is 64% higher than the unaffected trading price of $19.75 per
    share.48
          Jeffers’s opinion that the value of Columbia materially exceeded the deal price
    conflicts with the market behavior of other potential strategic acquirers who had
    shown interest in Columbia, and who did not step forward to top TransCanada’s
    price.
    Dell and DFC teach that a trial court should have greater confidence in market indicators
    and less confidence in a divergent expert determination. See 
    Dell, 177 A.3d at 35
    –38; 
    DFC, 172 A.3d at 369
    –70 & n.118.
    Consistent with the Delaware Supreme Court’s observations in Dell and DFC,
    Jeffers’s DCF valuation had many inputs, and Zmijewski questioned a number of them.
    The proper choices were matters of legitimate debate, and the outcome of those debates
    generated large swings in the valuation output.
    For Columbia, the swings were particularly large because management’s business
    plan (the “0&12 Plan”) forecasted major capital expenditures between 2016 and 2021,
    resulting in projected negative cash flow of nearly $4 billion during that period. See
    48
    For reasons previously discussed, this decision has not relied on the unaffected
    trading price as a valuation metric and has not made a finding as to whether or not the trading
    price was reliable. The significant distance between the trading price of $19.75 and expert
    valuation of $32.47 per share is nevertheless worth observing, because it suggests that at
    least one of these metrics, and possibly both, is wrong.
    108
    Zmijewski Tr. 1457–58. As a result, all of the positive value derived from the terminal
    period. In Jeffers’s calculation, the terminal value represented 125% of his valuation of
    Columbia. Jeffers Tr. 783–85. Given this fact, small changes in the assumptions and inputs
    that generated the terminal value, such as the discount rate, growth rate, or base-year free
    cash flow, had a much larger effect on the valuation of Columbia than they would on a
    typical valuation. See Zmijewski Tr. 1457–58. This court has questioned the utility of a
    DCF in a case where the terminal value represented 97% of the result, finding that “[t]his
    back-loading highlights the very real risks” presented by using that methodology and
    “undermin[ing] the reliability of applying the DCF technique.”49
    For example, Jeffers used a beta derived from a five-year regression of weekly
    returns. Based on his review of the forward pricing curves for natural gas and crude oil,
    Zmijewski argued that Jeffers should have used a shorter period. Zmijewski also pointed
    49
    Union 
    Illinois, 847 A.2d at 361
    ; see In re Appraisal of Solera Hldgs., Inc., 
    2018 WL 3625644
    , at *32 (Del. Ch. July 30, 2018) (discounting petitioners’ DCF analysis in
    part because “nearly 88% of the petitioners’ enterprise valuation is attributable to periods
    after the five year Hybrid Case Projections”). In Union Illinois and Solera, as in this case,
    growth rates drove the back-loading of the valuation. In other decisions, when valuators
    used an exit multiple to derive the terminal value, this court has criticized valuations where
    a high percentage of value resulted from the terminal period because “the entire exercise
    amounts to little more than a special case of the comparable companies approach.” Gray v.
    Cytokine Pharmasciences, Inc., 
    2002 WL 853549
    , at *9 (Del. Ch. Apr. 25, 2002)
    (criticizing a valuation on this basis where the terminal value accounted for over 75% of
    the total value); see Gholl, 
    2004 WL 2847865
    , at *13 (criticizing discounted cash flow
    valuation where exit multiples method for calculating terminal year value resulted in the
    terminal value representing over 70% of its total present value); Prescott Gp. Small Cap.
    v. Coleman Co., Inc., 
    2004 WL 2059515
    , at *24-25 (Del. Ch. Sept. 8, 2004) (same criticism
    of terminal value derived using exit multiple method that comprised 70% to 80% of present
    value).
    109
    out that Columbia’s financial advisors both used betas derived from two-year regressions
    of weekly observations, and TransCanada’s financial advisor used a beta derived from a
    one-year regression of daily observations. Using a two-year regression of weekly returns
    would lower the output of the Jeffers DCF model to $18.10 per share. See Zmijewski Tr,
    1463–67; JX 1368 ¶ 94.
    In another example, Jeffers separately valued Columbia’s three sources of cash
    flow: its operating income, its distributions from its limited partner interest in CPPL, and
    its distributions from its general partner interest in CPPL. But Zmijewski pointed out that
    Jeffers treated all three as if they were subject to identical risks, thereby underestimating
    the cost of capital for the limited partner and general partner interests. Correcting Jeffers’s
    discount rates for these cash flows would lower his valuation to a range of $18.96 to $19.23
    per share. See Zmijewski Tr. 1458–60; JX 1368 ¶ 108.
    A final example involves the terminal value calculation. Jeffers used a perpetuity
    growth rate of 3%. The Proxy indicates that Lazard’s DCF analysis implied perpetuity
    growth rates from 1.4% to 1.9%, and that Goldman’s was 1% to 2%. See JX 1136 at 65,
    75. Reducing Jeffers’s terminal growth rate to 1.5% would lower his valuation to $17.28
    per share. See JX 1368 Ex. V-2.
    The wide swings in output that result from legitimate debate over reasonable inputs
    undermine the reliability of Jeffers’s DCF model. And the experts’ debates went further,
    with Zmijewski raising significant questions about the reliability of the Jeffers model’s
    core input (Columbia’s management projections). Although the preparation of the 0&12
    Plan started with a bottoms-up process, senior management added a “growth wedge” or
    110
    “initiative layer” to meet top-down targets. Zmijewski Tr. 1454–56; see also JX 491. These
    add-ons assumed significant returns on unidentified projects that lacked customers or
    regulatory approval. See Adamson Tr. 1317–18; Skaggs Tr. 881–82; Mayo Dep. 273. This
    too raised fundamental questions about the reliability of Jeffers’s DCF analysis as a whole.
    If this were a case where a reliable market-based metric was not available, then the
    court might have to call the balls and strikes of the valuation inputs. In this case, the DCF
    technique “is necessarily a second-best method to derive value.” Union 
    Illinois, 847 A.2d at 359
    . This decision therefore does not use it. See Solera, 
    2018 WL 3625644
    , at *32.
    III.      CONCLUSION
    The fair value of Columbia’s common stock at the effective date was $25.50 per
    share. The legal rate of interest, compounded quarterly, shall accrue on the appraised value
    from the effective date until the date of payment. The parties shall cooperate on a form of
    final order. If there are additional issues for the court to resolve before entering a final
    order, then the parties shall submit a joint letter within fourteen days that identifies them
    and proposes a path to conclude this case at the trial level.
    111