Ohio v. American Express Co. ( 2018 )


Menu:
  • (Slip Opinion)              OCTOBER TERM, 2017                                       1
    Syllabus
    NOTE: Where it is feasible, a syllabus (headnote) will be released, as is
    being done in connection with this case, at the time the opinion is issued.
    The syllabus constitutes no part of the opinion of the Court but has been
    prepared by the Reporter of Decisions for the convenience of the reader.
    See United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co., 
    200 U.S. 321
    , 337.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    Syllabus
    OHIO ET AL. v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO. ET AL.
    CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR
    THE SECOND CIRCUIT
    No. 16–1454. Argued February 26, 2018—Decided June 25, 2018
    Respondent credit-card companies American Express Company and
    American Express Travel Related Services Company (collectively,
    Amex) operate what economists call a “two-sided platform,” providing
    services to two different groups (cardholders and merchants) who de-
    pend on the platform to intermediate between them. Because the in-
    teraction between the two groups is a transaction, credit-card net-
    works are a special type of two-sided platform known as a
    “transaction” platform. The key feature of transaction platforms is
    that they cannot make a sale to one side of the platform without sim-
    ultaneously making a sale to the other. Unlike traditional markets,
    two-sided platforms exhibit “indirect network effects,” which exist
    where the value of the platform to one group depends on how many
    members of another group participate. Two-sided platforms must
    take these effects into account before making a change in price on ei-
    ther side, or they risk creating a feedback loop of declining demand.
    Thus, striking the optimal balance of the prices charged on each side
    of the platform is essential for two-sided platforms to maximize the
    value of their services and to compete with their rivals.
    Visa and MasterCard—two of the major players in the credit-card
    market—have significant structural advantages over Amex. Amex
    competes with them by using a different business model, which fo-
    cuses on cardholder spending rather than cardholder lending. To en-
    courage cardholder spending, Amex provides better rewards than the
    other credit-card companies. Amex must continually invest in its
    cardholder rewards program to maintain its cardholders’ loyalty. But
    to fund those investments, it must charge merchants higher fees than
    its rivals. Although this business model has stimulated competitive
    innovations in the credit-card market, it sometimes causes friction
    2                  OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Syllabus
    with merchants. To avoid higher fees, merchants sometimes attempt
    to dissuade cardholders from using Amex cards at the point of sale—
    a practice known as “steering.” Amex places antisteering provisions
    in its contracts with merchants to combat this.
    In this case, the United States and several States (collectively,
    plaintiffs) sued Amex, claiming that its antisteering provisions vio-
    late §1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act. The District Court agreed,
    finding that the credit-card market should be treated as two separate
    markets—one for merchants and one for cardholders—and that
    Amex’s antisteering provisions are anticompetitive because they re-
    sult in higher merchant fees. The Second Circuit reversed. It deter-
    mined that the credit-card market is one market, not two. And it
    concluded that Amex’s antisteering provisions did not violate §1.
    Held: Amex’s antisteering provisions do not violate federal antitrust
    law. Pp. 8–20.
    (a) Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits “unreasonable re-
    straints” of trade. State Oil Co. v. Khan, 
    522 U.S. 3
    , 10. Restraints
    may be unreasonable in one of two ways—unreasonable per se or un-
    reasonable as judged under the “rule of reason.” Business Electronics
    Corp. v. Sharp Electronics Corp., 
    485 U.S. 717
    , 723. The parties
    agree that Amex’s antisteering provisions should be judged under the
    rule of reason using a three-step burden-shifting framework. They
    ask this Court to decide whether the plaintiffs have satisfied the first
    step in that framework—i.e., whether they have proved that Amex’s
    antisteering provisions have a substantial anticompetitive effect that
    harms consumers in the relevant market. Pp. 8–10.
    (b) Applying the rule of reason generally requires an accurate defi-
    nition of the relevant market. In this case, both sides of the two-
    sided credit-card market—cardholders and merchants—must be con-
    sidered. Only a company with both cardholders and merchants will-
    ing to use its network could sell transactions and compete in the cred-
    it-card market. And because credit-card networks cannot make a
    sale unless both sides of the platform simultaneously agree to use
    their services, they exhibit more pronounced indirect network effects
    and interconnected pricing and demand. Indeed, credit-card net-
    works are best understood as supplying only one product—the trans-
    action—that is jointly consumed by a cardholder and a merchant.
    Accordingly, the two-sided market for credit-card transactions should
    be analyzed as a whole. Pp. 10–15.
    (c) The plaintiffs have not carried their burden to show anticompet-
    itive effects. Their argument—that Amex’s antisteering provisions
    increase merchant fees—wrongly focuses on just one side of the mar-
    ket. Evidence of a price increase on one side of a two-sided transac-
    tion platform cannot, by itself, demonstrate an anticompetitive exer-
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)                      3
    Syllabus
    cise of market power. Instead, plaintiffs must prove that Amex’s an-
    tisteering provisions increased the cost of credit-card transactions
    above a competitive level, reduced the number of credit-card transac-
    tions, or otherwise stifled competition in the two-sided credit-card
    market. They failed to do so. Pp. 15–20.
    (1) The plaintiffs offered no evidence that the price of credit-card
    transactions was higher than the price one would expect to find in a
    competitive market. Amex’s increased merchant fees reflect increas-
    es in the value of its services and the cost of its transactions, not an
    ability to charge above a competitive price. It uses higher merchant
    fees to offer its cardholders a more robust rewards program, which is
    necessary to maintain cardholder loyalty and encourage the level of
    spending that makes it valuable to merchants. In addition, the evi-
    dence that does exist cuts against the plaintiffs’ view that Amex’s an-
    tisteering provisions are the cause of any increases in merchant fees:
    Visa and MasterCard’s merchant fees have continued to increase,
    even at merchant locations where Amex is not accepted. Pp. 16–17.
    (2) The plaintiffs’ evidence that Amex’s merchant-fee increases
    between 2005 and 2010 were not entirely spent on cardholder re-
    wards does not prove that Amex’s antisteering provisions gave it the
    power to charge anticompetitive prices. This Court will “not infer
    competitive injury from price and output data absent some evidence
    that tends to prove that output was restricted or prices were above a
    competitive level.” Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobac-
    co Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 237. There is no such evidence here. Output
    of credit-card transactions increased during the relevant period, and
    the plaintiffs did not show that Amex charged more than its competi-
    tors. P. 17.
    (3) The plaintiffs also failed to prove that Amex’s antisteering
    provisions have stifled competition among credit-card companies. To
    the contrary, while they have been in place, the market experienced
    expanding output and improved quality. Nor have Amex’s antisteer-
    ing provisions ended competition between credit-card networks with
    respect to merchant fees. Amex’s competitors have exploited its
    higher merchant fees to their advantage. Lastly, there is nothing in-
    herently anticompetitive about the provisions. They actually stem
    negative externalities in the credit-card market and promote inter-
    brand competition. And they do not prevent competing credit-card
    networks from offering lower merchant fees or promoting their
    broader merchant acceptance. Pp. 18–20.
    
    838 F.3d 179
    , affirmed.
    THOMAS, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which ROBERTS,
    C. J., and KENNEDY, ALITO, and GORSUCH, JJ., joined. BREYER, J., filed a
    4              OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Syllabus
    dissenting opinion, in which GINSBURG, SOTOMAYOR, and KAGAN, JJ.,
    joined.
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)                              1
    Opinion of the Court
    NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in the
    preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested to
    notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States, Wash-
    ington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in order
    that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to press.
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    No. 16–1454
    _________________
    OHIO, ET AL., PETITIONERS v. AMERICAN EXPRESS
    COMPANY, ET AL.
    ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT
    [June 25, 2018]
    JUSTICE THOMAS delivered the opinion of the Court.
    American Express Company and American Express
    Travel Related Services Company (collectively, Amex)
    provide credit-card services to both merchants and card-
    holders. When a cardholder buys something from a mer-
    chant who accepts Amex credit cards, Amex processes the
    transaction through its network, promptly pays the mer-
    chant, and subtracts a fee. If a merchant wants to accept
    Amex credit cards—and attract Amex cardholders to its
    business—Amex requires the merchant to agree to an
    antisteering contractual provision. The antisteering pro-
    vision prohibits merchants from discouraging customers
    from using their Amex card after they have already en-
    tered the store and are about to buy something, thereby
    avoiding Amex’s fee. In this case, we must decide whether
    Amex’s antisteering provisions violate federal antitrust
    law. We conclude they do not.
    I
    A
    Credit cards have become a primary way that consum-
    ers in the United States purchase goods and services.
    2             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the Court
    When a cardholder uses a credit card to buy something
    from a merchant, the transaction is facilitated by a credit-
    card network. The network provides separate but inter-
    related services to both cardholders and merchants. For
    cardholders, the network extends them credit, which
    allows them to make purchases without cash and to defer
    payment until later. Cardholders also can receive rewards
    based on the amount of money they spend, such as airline
    miles, points for travel, or cash back. For merchants, the
    network allows them to avoid the cost of processing trans-
    actions and offers them quick, guaranteed payment. This
    saves merchants the trouble and risk of extending credit
    to customers, and it increases the number and value of
    sales that they can make.
    By providing these services to cardholders and mer-
    chants, credit-card companies bring these parties together,
    and therefore operate what economists call a “two-sided
    platform.” As the name implies, a two-sided platform
    offers different products or services to two different groups
    who both depend on the platform to intermediate between
    them. See Evans & Schmalensee, Markets With Two-
    Sided Platforms, 1 Issues in Competition L. & Pol’y 667
    (2008) (Evans & Schmalensee); Evans & Noel, Defining
    Antitrust Markets When Firms Operate Two-Sided Plat-
    forms, 2005 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 667, 668 (Evans & Noel);
    Filistrucchi, Geradin, Van Damme, & Affeldt, Market
    Definition in Two-Sided Markets: Theory and Practice, 10
    J. Competition L. & Econ. 293, 296 (2014) (Filistrucchi).
    For credit cards, that interaction is a transaction. Thus,
    credit-card networks are a special type of two-sided plat-
    form known as a “transaction” platform. See 
    id., at 301,
    304, 307; Evans & Noel 676–678. The key feature of
    transaction platforms is that they cannot make a sale to
    one side of the platform without simultaneously making a
    sale to the other. See Klein, Lerner, Murphy, & Plache,
    Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Eco-
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           3
    Opinion of the Court
    nomics of Payment Card Interchange Fees, 73 Antitrust
    L. J. 571, 580, 583 (2006) (Klein). For example, no credit-
    card transaction can occur unless both the merchant and
    the cardholder simultaneously agree to use the same
    credit-card network. See Filistrucchi 301.
    Two-sided platforms differ from traditional markets in
    important ways. Most relevant here, two-sided platforms
    often exhibit what economists call “indirect network ef-
    fects.” Evans & Schmalensee 667. Indirect network ef-
    fects exist where the value of the two-sided platform to one
    group of participants depends on how many members of a
    different group participate. D. Evans & R. Schmalensee,
    Matchmakers: The New Economics of Multisided Plat-
    forms 25 (2016). In other words, the value of the services
    that a two-sided platform provides increases as the num-
    ber of participants on both sides of the platform increases.
    A credit card, for example, is more valuable to cardholders
    when more merchants accept it, and is more valuable to
    merchants when more cardholders use it. See Evans &
    Noel 686–687; Klein 580, 584. To ensure sufficient partic-
    ipation, two-sided platforms must be sensitive to the
    prices that they charge each side. See Evans & Schma-
    lensee 675; Evans & Noel 680; Muris, Payment Card
    Regulation and the (Mis)Application of the Economics of
    Two-Sided Markets, 2005 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 515, 532–
    533 (Muris); Rochet & Tirole, Platform Competition in
    Two-Sided Markets, 1 J. Eur. Econ. Assn. 990, 1013
    (2003). Raising the price on side A risks losing participa-
    tion on that side, which decreases the value of the plat-
    form to side B. If participants on side B leave due to this
    loss in value, then the platform has even less value to side
    A—risking a feedback loop of declining demand. See
    Evans & Schmalensee 675; Evans & Noel 680–681. Two-
    sided platforms therefore must take these indirect net-
    work effects into account before making a change in price
    on either side. See Evans & Schmalensee 675; Evans &
    4                OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the Court
    Noel 680–681.1
    Sometimes indirect network effects require two-sided
    platforms to charge one side much more than the other.
    See Evans & Schmalensee 667, 675, 681, 690–691; Evans
    & Noel 668, 691; Klein 585; Filistrucchi 300. For two-
    sided platforms, “ ‘the [relative] price structure matters,
    and platforms must design it so as to bring both sides on
    board.’ ” Evans & Schmalensee 669 (quoting Rochet &
    Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, 37 RAND
    J. Econ. 645, 646 (2006)). The optimal price might require
    charging the side with more elastic demand a below-cost
    (or even negative) price. See Muris 519, 550; Klein 579;
    Evans & Schmalensee 675; Evans & Noel 681. With credit
    cards, for example, networks often charge cardholders a
    lower fee than merchants because cardholders are more
    price sensitive.2 See Muris 522; Klein 573–574, 585, 595.
    In fact, the network might well lose money on the card-
    holder side by offering rewards such as cash back, airline
    miles, or gift cards. See Klein 587; Evans & Schmalensee
    672. The network can do this because increasing the
    number of cardholders increases the value of accepting the
    card to merchants and, thus, increases the number of
    ——————
    1 Ina competitive market, indirect network effects also encourage
    companies to take increased profits from a price increase on side A and
    spend them on side B to ensure more robust participation on that side
    and to stem the impact of indirect network effects. See Evans &
    Schmalensee 688; Evans & Noel 670–671, 695. Indirect network effects
    thus limit the platform’s ability to raise overall prices and impose a
    check on its market power. See Evans & Schmalensee 688; Evans &
    Noel 695.
    2 “Cardholders are more price-sensitive because many consumers
    have multiple payment methods, including alternative payment cards.
    Most merchants, by contrast, cannot accept just one major card because
    they are likely to lose profitable incremental sales if they do not take
    [all] the major payment cards. Because most consumers do not carry
    all of the major payment cards, refusing to accept a major card may
    cost the merchant substantial sales.” Muris 522.
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)                  5
    Opinion of the Court
    merchants who accept it. Muris 522; Evans & Schma-
    lensee 692. Networks can then charge those merchants a
    fee for every transaction (typically a percentage of the
    purchase price). Striking the optimal balance of the prices
    charged on each side of the platform is essential for two-
    sided platforms to maximize the value of their services
    and to compete with their rivals.
    B
    Amex, Visa, MasterCard, and Discover are the four
    dominant participants in the credit-card market. Visa,
    which is by far the largest, has 45% of the market as
    measured by transaction volume.3 Amex and MasterCard
    trail with 26.4% and 23.3%, respectively, while Discover
    has just 5.3% of the market.
    Visa and MasterCard have significant structural ad-
    vantages over Amex. Visa and MasterCard began as bank
    cooperatives and thus almost every bank that offers credit
    cards is in the Visa or MasterCard network. This makes it
    very likely that the average consumer carries, and the
    average merchant accepts, Visa or MasterCard. As a
    result, the vast majority of Amex cardholders have a Visa
    or MasterCard, but only a small number of Visa and Master-
    Card cardholders have an Amex. Indeed, Visa and
    MasterCard account for more than 432 million cards in
    circulation in the United States, while Amex has only 53
    million. And while 3.4 million merchants at 6.4 million
    locations accept Amex, nearly three million more locations
    accept Visa, MasterCard, and Discover.4
    ——————
    3 Allfigures are accurate as of 2013.
    4 Discover entered the credit-card market several years after Amex,
    Visa, and MasterCard. It nonetheless managed to gain a foothold
    because Sears marketed Discover to its already significant base of
    private-label cardholders. Discover’s business model shares certain
    features with Amex, Visa, and MasterCard. Like Amex, Discover
    interacts directly with its cardholders. But like Visa and MasterCard,
    6               OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the Court
    Amex competes with Visa and MasterCard by using a
    different business model. While Visa and MasterCard
    earn half of their revenue by collecting interest from their
    cardholders, Amex does not. Amex instead earns most of
    its revenue from merchant fees. Amex’s business model
    thus focuses on cardholder spending rather than card-
    holder lending. To encourage cardholder spending, Amex
    provides better rewards than other networks. Due to its
    superior rewards, Amex tends to attract cardholders who
    are wealthier and spend more money. Merchants place a
    higher value on these cardholders, and Amex uses this
    advantage to recruit merchants.
    Amex’s business model has significantly influenced the
    credit-card market. To compete for the valuable cardhold-
    ers that Amex attracts, both Visa and MasterCard have
    introduced premium cards that, like Amex, charge mer-
    chants higher fees and offer cardholders better rewards.
    To maintain their lower merchant fees, Visa and Master-
    Card have created a sliding scale for their various cards—
    charging merchants less for low-reward cards and more
    for high-reward cards. This differs from Amex’s strategy,
    which is to charge merchants the same fee no matter the
    rewards that its card offers. Another way that Amex has
    influenced the credit-card market is by making banking
    and card-payment services available to low-income indi-
    viduals, who otherwise could not qualify for a credit card
    and could not afford the fees that traditional banks
    charge. See 2 Record 3835–3837, 4527–4529. In sum,
    Amex’s business model has stimulated competitive inno-
    vations in the credit-card market, increasing the volume of
    transactions and improving the quality of the services.
    Despite these improvements, Amex’s business model
    sometimes causes friction with merchants. To maintain
    ——————
    Discover uses banks that cooperate with its network to interact with
    merchants.
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)                   7
    Opinion of the Court
    the loyalty of its cardholders, Amex must continually
    invest in its rewards program. But, to fund those invest-
    ments, Amex must charge merchants higher fees than its
    rivals. Even though Amex’s investments benefit mer-
    chants by encouraging cardholders to spend more money,
    merchants would prefer not to pay the higher fees. One
    way that merchants try to avoid them, while still enticing
    Amex’s cardholders to shop at their stores, is by dissuad-
    ing cardholders from using Amex at the point of sale. This
    practice is known as “steering.”
    Amex has prohibited steering since the 1950s by placing
    antisteering provisions in its contracts with merchants.
    These antisteering provisions prohibit merchants from
    implying a preference for non-Amex cards; dissuading
    customers from using Amex cards; persuading customers
    to use other cards; imposing any special restrictions,
    conditions, disadvantages, or fees on Amex cards; or pro-
    moting other cards more than Amex. The antisteering
    provisions do not, however, prevent merchants from steer-
    ing customers toward debit cards, checks, or cash.
    C
    In October 2010, the United States and several States
    (collectively, plaintiffs) sued Amex, claiming that its an-
    tisteering provisions violate §1 of the Sherman Act, 26
    Stat. 209, as amended, 
    15 U.S. C
    . §1.5 After a 7-week
    trial, the District Court agreed that Amex’s antisteering
    provisions violate §1. United States v. American Express
    Co., 
    88 F. Supp. 3d 143
    , 151–152 (EDNY 2015). It found
    that the credit-card market should be treated as two
    separate markets—one for merchants and one for card-
    holders. See 
    id., at 171–175.
    Evaluating the effects on the
    ——————
    5 Plaintiffs
    also sued Visa and MasterCard, claiming that their anti-
    steering provisions violated §1. But Visa and MasterCard voluntarily
    revoked their antisteering provisions and are no longer parties to this
    case.
    8             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the Court
    merchant side of the market, the District Court found
    that Amex’s antisteering provisions are anticompetitive
    because they result in higher merchant fees. See 
    id., at 195–224.
      The Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit reversed.
    United States v. American Express Co., 
    838 F.3d 179
    , 184
    (2016). It concluded that the credit-card market is one
    market, not two. 
    Id., at 196–200.
    Evaluating the credit-
    card market as a whole, the Second Circuit concluded that
    Amex’s antisteering provisions were not anticompetitive
    and did not violate §1. See 
    id., at 200–206.
      We granted certiorari, 583 U. S. ___ (2017), and now
    affirm.
    II
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits “[e]very contract,
    combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspir-
    acy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several
    States.” 
    15 U.S. C
    . §1. This Court has long recognized
    that, “[i]n view of the common law and the law in this
    country” when the Sherman Act was passed, the phrase
    “restraint of trade” is best read to mean “undue restraint.”
    Standard Oil Co. of N. J. v. United States, 
    221 U.S. 1
    , 59–
    60 (1911). This Court’s precedents have thus understood
    §1 “to outlaw only unreasonable restraints.” State Oil Co.
    v. Khan, 
    522 U.S. 3
    , 10 (1997) (emphasis added).
    Restraints can be unreasonable in one of two ways. A
    small group of restraints are unreasonable per se because
    they “ ‘ “always or almost always tend to restrict competi-
    tion and decrease output.” ’ ” Business Electronics Corp. v.
    Sharp Electronics Corp., 
    485 U.S. 717
    , 723 (1988). Typi-
    cally only “horizontal” restraints—restraints “imposed by
    agreement between competitors”—qualify as unreasonable
    per se. 
    Id., at 730.
    Restraints that are not unreasonable
    per se are judged under the “rule of reason.” 
    Id., at 723.
    The rule of reason requires courts to conduct a fact-specific
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           9
    Opinion of the Court
    assessment of “market power and market structure . . . to
    assess the [restraint]’s actual effect” on competition.
    Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 
    467 U.S. 752
    , 768 (1984). The goal is to “distinguis[h] between
    restraints with anticompetitive effect that are harmful to
    the consumer and restraints stimulating competition that
    are in the consumer’s best interest.” Leegin Creative
    Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 
    551 U.S. 877
    , 886
    (2007).
    In this case, both sides correctly acknowledge that
    Amex’s antisteering provisions are vertical restraints—
    i.e., restraints “imposed by agreement between firms at
    different levels of distribution.” Business 
    Electronics, supra, at 730
    . The parties also correctly acknowledge
    that, like nearly every other vertical restraint, the anti-
    steering provisions should be assessed under the rule of
    reason. See 
    Leegin, supra, at 882
    ; State 
    Oil, supra, at 19
    ;
    Business 
    Electronics, supra, at 726
    ; Continental T. V., Inc.
    v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 
    433 U.S. 36
    , 57 (1977).
    To determine whether a restraint violates the rule of
    reason, the parties agree that a three-step, burden-
    shifting framework applies. Under this framework, the
    plaintiff has the initial burden to prove that the chal-
    lenged restraint has a substantial anticompetitive effect
    that harms consumers in the relevant market. See 1 J.
    Kalinowski, Antitrust Laws and Trade Regulation
    §12.02[1] (2d ed. 2017) (Kalinowski); P. Areeda & H.
    Hovenkamp, Fundamentals of Antitrust Law §15.02[B]
    (4th ed. 2017) (Areeda & Hovenkamp); Capital Imaging
    Assoc., P. C. v. Mohawk Valley Medical Associates, Inc.,
    
    996 F.2d 537
    , 543 (CA2 1993). If the plaintiff carries its
    burden, then the burden shifts to the defendant to show a
    procompetitive rationale for the restraint. See 1 Kalinow-
    ski §12.02[1]; Areeda & Hovenkamp §15.02[B]; Capital
    Imaging 
    Assoc., supra, at 543
    . If the defendant makes
    this showing, then the burden shifts back to the plaintiff
    10               OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the Court
    to demonstrate that the procompetitive efficiencies could
    be reasonably achieved through less anticompetitive
    means. See 1 Kalinowski §12.02[1]; Capital Imaging
    
    Assoc., supra, at 543
    .
    Here, the parties ask us to decide whether the plaintiffs
    have carried their initial burden of proving that Amex’s
    antisteering provisions have an anticompetitive effect.
    The plaintiffs can make this showing directly or indirectly.
    Direct evidence of anticompetitive effects would be “ ‘proof
    of actual detrimental effects [on competition],’ ” FTC v.
    Indiana Federation of Dentists, 
    476 U.S. 447
    , 460 (1986),
    such as reduced output, increased prices, or decreased
    quality in the relevant market, see 1 Kalinowski §12.02[2];
    Craftsman Limousine, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co., 
    491 F.3d 381
    , 390 (CA8 2007); Virginia Atlantic Airways Ltd. v.
    British Airways PLC, 
    257 F.3d 256
    , 264 (CA2 2001).
    Indirect evidence would be proof of market power plus
    some evidence that the challenged restraint harms compe-
    tition. See 1 Kalinowski §12.02[2]; Tops Markets, Inc. v.
    Quality Markets, Inc., 
    142 F.3d 90
    , 97 (CA2 1998); Span-
    ish Broadcasting System of Fla. v. Clear Channel Commu-
    nications, Inc., 
    376 F.3d 1065
    , 1073 (CA11 2004).
    Here, the plaintiffs rely exclusively on direct evidence to
    prove that Amex’s antisteering provisions have caused
    anticompetitive effects in the credit-card market.6 To
    assess this evidence, we must first define the relevant
    market. Once defined, it becomes clear that the plaintiffs’
    evidence is insufficient to carry their burden.
    A
    Because “[l]egal presumptions that rest on formalistic
    distinctions rather than actual market realities are gener-
    ally disfavored in antitrust law,” Eastman Kodak Co. v.
    ——————
    6 Although the plaintiffs relied on indirect evidence below, they have
    abandoned that argument in this Court. See Brief for United States 23,
    n. 4 (citing Pet. for Cert. i, 18–25).
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)                    11
    Opinion of the Court
    Image Technical Services, Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 466–467
    (1992), courts usually cannot properly apply the rule of
    reason without an accurate definition of the relevant
    market.7 “Without a definition of [the] market there is no
    way to measure [the defendant’s] ability to lessen or de-
    stroy competition.” Walker Process Equipment, Inc. v.
    Food Machinery & Chemical Corp., 
    382 U.S. 172
    , 177
    (1965); accord, 2 Kalinowski §24.01[4][a]. Thus, the rele-
    vant market is defined as “the area of effective competi-
    tion.” 
    Ibid. Typically this is
    the “arena within which
    significant substitution in consumption or production
    occurs.” Areeda & Hovenkamp §5.02; accord, 2 Kalinow-
    ski §24.02[1]; United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U. S.
    ——————
    7 The plaintiffs argue that we need not define the relevant market in
    this case because they have offered actual evidence of adverse effects on
    competition—namely, increased merchant fees. See Brief for United
    States 40–41 (citing FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists, 
    476 U.S. 447
    (1986), and Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 
    446 U.S. 643
    (1980) (per curiam)). We disagree. The cases that the plaintiffs cite for
    this proposition evaluated whether horizontal restraints had an ad-
    verse effect on competition. See Indiana Federation of 
    Dentists, supra, at 450
    –451, 459 (agreement between competing dentists not to share X
    rays with insurance companies); 
    Catalano, supra, at 644
    –645, 650
    (agreement among competing wholesalers not to compete on extending
    credit to retailers). Given that horizontal restraints involve agree-
    ments between competitors not to compete in some way, this Court
    concluded that it did not need to precisely define the relevant market to
    conclude that these agreements were anticompetitive. See Indiana
    Federation of 
    Dentists, supra, at 460
    –461; 
    Catalano, supra, at 648
    –649.
    But vertical restraints are different. See Arizona v. Maricopa County
    Medical Soc., 
    457 U.S. 332
    , 348, n. 18 (1982); Leegin Creative Leather
    Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 
    551 U.S. 877
    , 888 (2007). Vertical re-
    straints often pose no risk to competition unless the entity imposing
    them has market power, which cannot be evaluated unless the Court
    first defines the relevant market. See 
    id., at 898
    (noting that a vertical
    restraint “may not be a serious concern unless the relevant entity has
    market power”); Easterbrook, Vertical Arrangements and the Rule of
    Reason, 53 Antitrust L. J. 135, 160 (1984) (“[T]he possibly anticompeti-
    tive manifestations of vertical arrangements can occur only if there is
    market power”).
    12             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the Court
    563, 571 (1966). But courts should “combin[e]” different
    products or services into “a single market” when “that
    combination reflects commercial realities.” 
    Id., at 572;
    see
    also Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 336–
    337 (1962) (pointing out that “the definition of the relevant
    market” must “ ‘correspond to the commercial realities’ of
    the industry”).
    As explained, credit-card networks are two-sided plat-
    forms. Due to indirect network effects, two-sided plat-
    forms cannot raise prices on one side without risking a
    feedback loop of declining demand. See Evans & Schma-
    lensee 674–675; Evans & Noel 680–681. And the fact that
    two-sided platforms charge one side a price that is below
    or above cost reflects differences in the two sides’ demand
    elasticity, not market power or anticompetitive pricing.
    See Klein 574, 595, 598, 626. Price increases on one side
    of the platform likewise do not suggest anticompetitive
    effects without some evidence that they have increased the
    overall cost of the platform’s services. See 
    id., at 575,
    594,
    626. Thus, courts must include both sides of the plat-
    form—merchants and cardholders—when defining the
    credit-card market.
    To be sure, it is not always necessary to consider both
    sides of a two-sided platform. A market should be treated
    as one sided when the impacts of indirect network effects
    and relative pricing in that market are minor. See Fil-
    istrucchi 321–322. Newspapers that sell advertisements,
    for example, arguably operate a two-sided platform be-
    cause the value of an advertisement increases as more
    people read the newspaper. 
    Id., at 297,
    315; Klein 579.
    But in the newspaper-advertisement market, the indirect
    networks effects operate in only one direction; newspaper
    readers are largely indifferent to the amount of advertis-
    ing that a newspaper contains. See Filistrucchi 321, 323,
    and n. 99; Klein 583. Because of these weak indirect
    network effects, the market for newspaper advertising
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)                 13
    Opinion of the Court
    behaves much like a one-sided market and should be
    analyzed as such. See Filistrucchi 321; Times-Picayune
    Publishing Co. v. United States, 
    345 U.S. 594
    , 610 (1953).
    But two-sided transaction platforms, like the credit-card
    market, are different. These platforms facilitate a single,
    simultaneous transaction between participants. For credit
    cards, the network can sell its services only if a mer-
    chant and cardholder both simultaneously choose to use
    the network. Thus, whenever a credit-card network sells
    one transaction’s worth of card-acceptance services to a
    merchant it also must sell one transaction’s worth of card-
    payment services to a cardholder. It cannot sell transac-
    tion services to either cardholders or merchants individu-
    ally. See Klein 583 (“Because cardholders and merchants
    jointly consume a single product, payment card transac-
    tions, their consumption of payment card transactions
    must be directly proportional”). To optimize sales, the
    network must find the balance of pricing that encourages
    the greatest number of matches between cardholders and
    merchants.
    Because they cannot make a sale unless both sides of
    the platform simultaneously agree to use their services,
    two-sided transaction platforms exhibit more pronounced
    indirect network effects and interconnected pricing and
    demand. Transaction platforms are thus better under-
    stood as “suppl[ying] only one product”—transactions.
    Klein 580. In the credit-card market, these transactions
    “are jointly consumed by a cardholder, who uses the pay-
    ment card to make a transaction, and a merchant, who
    accepts the payment card as a method of payment.” 
    Ibid. Tellingly, credit cards
    determine their market share by
    measuring the volume of transactions they have sold.8
    ——————
    8 Contrary to the dissent’s assertion, post, at 11–12, merchant ser-
    vices and cardholder services are not complements. See Filistrucchi
    297 (“[A] two-sided market [is] different from markets for complemen-
    14               OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the Court
    Evaluating both sides of a two-sided transaction plat-
    form is also necessary to accurately assess competition.
    Only other two-sided platforms can compete with a two-
    sided platform for transactions. See Filistrucchi 301. A
    credit-card company that processed transactions for mer-
    chants, but that had no cardholders willing to use its card,
    could not compete with Amex. See 
    ibid. Only a company
    that had both cardholders and merchants willing to use its
    network could sell transactions and compete in the credit-
    card market. Similarly, if a merchant accepts the four
    major credit cards, but a cardholder only uses Visa or
    Amex, only those two cards can compete for the particular
    transaction.     Thus, competition cannot be accurately
    assessed by looking at only one side of the platform in
    isolation.9
    For all these reasons, “[i]n two-sided transaction mar-
    kets, only one market should be defined.” 
    Id., at 302;
    see
    also Evans & Noel 671 (“[F]ocusing on one dimension of
    . . . competition tends to distort the competition that actu-
    ally exists among [two-sided platforms]”). Any other
    analysis would lead to “ ‘ “mistaken inferences” ’ ” of the
    kind that could “ ‘ “chill the very conduct the antitrust laws
    are designed to protect.” ’ ” Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown &
    Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 226 (1993); see
    also Matsushita Elec. Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp.,
    ——————
    tary products, in which both products are bought by the same buyers,
    who, in their buying decisions, can therefore be expected to take into
    account both prices”). As already explained, credit-card companies are
    best understood as supplying only one product—transactions—which is
    jointly consumed by a cardholder and a merchant. See Klein 580.
    Merchant services and cardholder services are both inputs to this single
    product. See 
    ibid. 9 Nontransaction platforms,
    by contrast, often do compete with com-
    panies that do not operate on both sides of their platform. A newspaper
    that sells advertising, for example, might have to compete with a
    television network, even though the two do not meaningfully compete
    for viewers. See Filistrucchi 301.
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           15
    Opinion of the Court
    
    475 U.S. 574
    , 594 (1986) (“ ‘[W]e must be concerned lest a
    rule or precedent that authorizes a search for a particular
    type of undesirable pricing behavior end up by discourag-
    ing legitimate price competition’ ”); 
    Leegin, 551 U.S., at 895
    (noting that courts should avoid “increas[ing] the total
    cost of the antitrust system by prohibiting procompetitive
    conduct the antitrust laws should encourage”). Accordingly,
    we will analyze the two-sided market for credit-card
    transactions as a whole to determine whether the plain-
    tiffs have shown that Amex’s antisteering provisions have
    anticompetitive effects.
    B
    The plaintiffs have not carried their burden to prove
    anticompetitive effects in the relevant market. The plain-
    tiffs stake their entire case on proving that Amex’s agree-
    ments increase merchant fees. We find this argument
    unpersuasive.
    As an initial matter, the plaintiffs’ argument about
    merchant fees wrongly focuses on only one side of the two-
    sided credit-card market. As explained, the credit-card
    market must be defined to include both merchants and
    cardholders. Focusing on merchant fees alone misses the
    mark because the product that credit-card companies sell
    is transactions, not services to merchants, and the compet-
    itive effects of a restraint on transactions cannot be judged
    by looking at merchants alone. Evidence of a price in-
    crease on one side of a two-sided transaction platform
    cannot by itself demonstrate an anticompetitive exercise of
    market power. To demonstrate anticompetitive effects on
    the two-sided credit-card market as a whole, the plaintiffs
    must prove that Amex’s antisteering provisions increased
    the cost of credit-card transactions above a competitive
    level, reduced the number of credit-card transactions, or
    otherwise stifled competition in the credit-card market.
    See 1 Kalinowski §12.02[2]; Craftsman Limousine, Inc.,
    16             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the 
    Court 491 F.3d, at 390
    ; Virginia Atlantic Airways 
    Ltd., 257 F.3d, at 264
    . They failed to do so.
    1
    The plaintiffs did not offer any evidence that the price of
    credit-card transactions was higher than the price one
    would expect to find in a competitive market. As the
    District Court found, the plaintiffs failed to offer any
    reliable measure of Amex’s transaction price or profit
    
    margins. 88 F. Supp. 3d, at 198
    , 215. And the evidence
    about whether Amex charges more than its competitors
    was ultimately inconclusive. 
    Id., at 199,
    202, 215.
    Amex’s increased merchant fees reflect increases in the
    value of its services and the cost of its transactions, not an
    ability to charge above a competitive price. Amex began
    raising its merchant fees in 2005 after Visa and Master-
    Card raised their fees in the early 2000s. 
    Id., at 195,
    199–
    200. As explained, Amex has historically charged higher
    merchant fees than these competitors because it delivers
    wealthier cardholders who spend more money. 
    Id., at 200–201.
    Amex’s higher merchant fees are based on a
    careful study of how much additional value its cardholders
    offer merchants. See 
    id., at 192–193.
    On the other side of
    the market, Amex uses its higher merchant fees to offer its
    cardholders a more robust rewards program, which is
    necessary to maintain cardholder loyalty and encourage
    the level of spending that makes Amex valuable to mer-
    chants. 
    Id., at 160,
    191–195. That Amex allocates prices
    between merchants and cardholders differently from Visa
    and MasterCard is simply not evidence that it wields
    market power to achieve anticompetitive ends. See Evans
    & Noel 670–671; Klein 574–575, 594–595, 598, 626.
    In addition, the evidence that does exist cuts against the
    plaintiffs’ view that Amex’s antisteering provisions are the
    cause of any increases in merchant fees. Visa and Master-
    Card’s merchant fees have continued to increase, even
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           17
    Opinion of the Court
    at merchant locations where Amex is not accepted and,
    thus, Amex’s antisteering provisions do not apply. 
    See 88 F. Supp. 3d, at 222
    . This suggests that the cause of in-
    creased merchant fees is not Amex’s antisteering provi-
    sions, but rather increased competition for cardholders
    and a corresponding marketwide adjustment in the rela-
    tive price charged to merchants. See Klein 575, 609.
    2
    The plaintiffs did offer evidence that Amex increased
    the percentage of the purchase price that it charges mer-
    chants by an average of 0.09% between 2005 and 2010 and
    that this increase was not entirely spent on cardholder
    rewards. 
    See 88 F. Supp. 3d, at 195
    –197, 215. The plain-
    tiffs believe that this evidence shows that the price of
    Amex’s transactions increased.
    Even assuming the plaintiffs are correct, this evidence
    does not prove that Amex’s antisteering provisions gave it
    the power to charge anticompetitive prices. “Market
    power is the ability to raise price profitably by restricting
    output.” Areeda & Hovenkamp §5.01 (emphasis added);
    accord, 
    Kodak, 504 U.S., at 464
    ; Business 
    Electronics, 485 U.S., at 723
    . This Court will “not infer competitive injury
    from price and output data absent some evidence that
    tends to prove that output was restricted or prices were
    above a competitive level.” Brooke Group 
    Ltd., 509 U.S., at 237
    . There is no such evidence in this case. The output
    of credit-card transactions grew dramatically from 2008 to
    2013, increasing 30%. 
    See 838 F.3d, at 206
    . “Where . . .
    output is expanding at the same time prices are increas-
    ing, rising prices are equally consistent with growing
    product demand.” Brooke Group 
    Ltd., supra, at 237
    . And,
    as previously explained, the plaintiffs did not show that
    Amex charged more than its competitors.
    18            OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the Court
    3
    The plaintiffs also failed to prove that Amex’s antisteer-
    ing provisions have stifled competition among credit-card
    companies. To the contrary, while these agreements have
    been in place, the credit-card market experienced expand-
    ing output and improved quality. Amex’s business model
    spurred Visa and MasterCard to offer new premium card
    categories with higher rewards. And it has increased the
    availability of card services, including free banking and
    card-payment services for low-income customers who
    otherwise would not be served. Indeed, between 1970 and
    2001, the percentage of households with credit cards more
    than quadrupled, and the proportion of households in the
    bottom-income quintile with credit cards grew from just
    2% to over 38%. See D. Evans & R. Schmalensee, Paying
    With Plastic: The Digital Revolution in Buying and Bor-
    rowing 88–89 (2d ed. 2005) (Paying With Plastic).
    Nor have Amex’s antisteering provisions ended competi-
    tion between credit-card networks with respect to mer-
    chant fees. Instead, fierce competition between networks
    has constrained Amex’s ability to raise these fees and has,
    at times, forced Amex to lower them. For instance, when
    Amex raised its merchant prices between 2005 and 2010,
    some merchants chose to leave its network. 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 197. And when its remaining merchants com-
    plained, Amex stopped raising its merchant prices. 
    Id., at 198.
    In another instance in the late 1980s and early
    1990s, competition forced Amex to offer lower merchant
    fees to “everyday spend” merchants—supermarkets, gas
    stations, pharmacies, and the like—to persuade them to
    accept Amex. See 
    id., at 160–161,
    202.
    In addition, Amex’s competitors have exploited its
    higher merchant fees to their advantage. By charging
    lower merchant fees, Visa, MasterCard, and Discover have
    achieved broader merchant acceptance—approximately 3
    million more locations than Amex. 
    Id., at 204.
    This
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)          19
    Opinion of the Court
    broader merchant acceptance is a major advantage for
    these networks and a significant challenge for Amex, since
    consumers prefer cards that will be accepted everywhere.
    
    Ibid. And to compete
    even further with Amex, Visa and
    MasterCard charge different merchant fees for different
    types of cards to maintain their comparatively lower mer-
    chant fees and broader acceptance. Over the long run,
    this competition has created a trend of declining merchant
    fees in the credit-card market. In fact, since the first
    credit card was introduced in the 1950s, merchant fees—
    including Amex’s merchant fees—have decreased by more
    than half. See 
    id., at 202–203;
    Paying With Plastic 54,
    126, 152.
    Lastly, there is nothing inherently anticompetitive
    about Amex’s antisteering provisions. These agreements
    actually stem negative externalities in the credit-card
    market and promote interbrand competition. When mer-
    chants steer cardholders away from Amex at the point of
    sale, it undermines the cardholder’s expectation of “wel-
    come acceptance”—the promise of a frictionless transac-
    tion. 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 156. A lack of welcome acceptance
    at one merchant makes a cardholder less likely to use
    Amex at all other merchants. This externality endangers
    the viability of the entire Amex network. And it under-
    mines the investments that Amex has made to encourage
    increased cardholder spending, which discourages invest-
    ments in rewards and ultimately harms both cardholders
    and merchants. Cf. 
    Leegin, 551 U.S., at 890
    –891 (recog-
    nizing that vertical restraints can prevent retailers from
    free riding and thus increase the availability of “tangible
    or intangible services or promotional efforts” that enhance
    competition and consumer welfare). Perhaps most im-
    portantly, antisteering provisions do not prevent Visa,
    MasterCard, or Discover from competing against Amex by
    offering lower merchant fees or promoting their broader
    20               OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    Opinion of the Court
    merchant acceptance.10
    In sum, the plaintiffs have not satisfied the first step of
    the rule of reason. They have not carried their burden of
    proving that Amex’s antisteering provisions have anti-
    competitive effects. Amex’s business model has spurred
    robust interbrand competition and has increased the
    quality and quantity of credit-card transactions. And it is
    “[t]he promotion of interbrand competition,” after all,
    that “is . . . ‘the primary purpose of the antitrust laws.’” 
    Id., at 890.
                          *   *     *
    Because Amex’s antisteering provisions do not unrea-
    sonably restrain trade, we affirm the judgment of the
    Court of Appeals.
    It is so ordered.
    ——————
    10 The plaintiffs argue that United States v. Topco Associates, Inc.,
    
    405 U.S. 596
    , 610 (1972), forbids any restraint that would restrict
    competition in part of the market—here, for example, merchant steer-
    ing. See Brief for Petitioners and Respondents Nebraska, Tennessee,
    and Texas 30, 42. Topco does not stand for such a broad proposition.
    Topco concluded that a horizontal agreement between competitors was
    unreasonable per se, even though the agreement did not extend to every
    competitor in the market. 
    See 405 U.S., at 599
    , 608. A horizontal
    agreement between competitors is markedly different from a vertical
    agreement that incidentally affects one particular method of competi-
    tion. See 
    Leegin, 551 U.S., at 888
    ; Maricopa County Medical 
    Soc., 457 U.S., at 348
    , n. 18.
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)          1
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
    _________________
    No. 16–1454
    _________________
    OHIO, ET AL., PETITIONERS v. AMERICAN EXPRESS
    COMPANY, ET AL.
    ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF
    APPEALS FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT
    [June 25, 2018]
    JUSTICE BREYER, with whom JUSTICE GINSBURG,
    JUSTICE SOTOMAYOR, and JUSTICE KAGAN join, dissenting.
    For more than 120 years, the American economy has
    prospered by charting a middle path between pure lassez-
    faire and state capitalism, governed by an antitrust law
    “dedicated to the principle that markets, not individual
    firms and certainly not political power, produce the opti­
    mal mixture of goods and services.” 1 P. Areeda & H.
    Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶100b, p. 4 (4th ed. 2013)
    (Areeda & Hovenkamp). By means of a strong antitrust
    law, the United States has sought to avoid the danger of
    monopoly capitalism. Long gone, we hope, are the days
    when the great trusts presided unfettered by competition
    over the American economy.
    This lawsuit is emblematic of the American approach.
    Many governments around the world have responded to
    concerns about the high fees that credit-card companies
    often charge merchants by regulating such fees directly.
    See GAO, Credit and Debit Cards: Federal Entities Are
    Taking Actions to Limit Their Interchange Fees, but
    Additional Revenue Collection Cost Savings May Exist
    31–35 (GAO–08–558, 2008). The United States has not
    followed that approach. The Government instead filed
    this lawsuit, which seeks to restore market competition
    over credit-card merchant fees by eliminating a contract­
    2             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    ual barrier with anticompetitive effects. The majority
    rejects that effort. But because the challenged contractual
    term clearly has serious anticompetitive effects, I dissent.
    I
    I agree with the majority and the parties that this case
    is properly evaluated under the three-step “rule of reason”
    that governs many antitrust lawsuits. Ante, at 9–10.
    Under that approach, a court looks first at the agreement
    or restraint at issue to assess whether it has had, or is
    likely to have, anticompetitive effects. FTC v. Indiana
    Federation of Dentists, 
    476 U.S. 447
    , 459 (1986). In doing
    so, the court normally asks whether the restraint may
    tend to impede competition and, if so, whether those who
    have entered into that restraint have sufficient economic
    or commercial power for the agreement to make a negative
    difference. See 
    id., at 459–461.
    Sometimes, but not al­
    ways, a court will try to determine the appropriate market
    (the market that the agreement affects) and determine
    whether those entering into that agreement have the
    power to raise prices above the competitive level in that
    market. See 
    ibid. It is important
    here to understand that in cases under
    §1 of the Sherman Act (unlike in cases challenging a mer­
    ger under §7 of the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S. C
    . §18), it may
    well be unnecessary to undertake a sometimes complex,
    market power inquiry:
    “Since the purpose [in a Sherman Act §1 case] of the
    inquiries into . . . market power is [simply] to deter­
    mine whether an arrangement has the potential for
    genuine adverse effects on competition, ‘proof of actual
    detrimental effects, such as a reduction in output,’ can
    obviate the need for an inquiry into market power,
    which is but a ‘surrogate for detrimental effects.’ ”
    Indiana Federation of 
    Dentists, supra, at 460
    –461
    (quoting 7 P. Areeda, Antitrust Law ¶1511, p. 429 (3d
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)          3
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    ed. 1986)).
    Second (as treatise writers summarize the case law), if
    an antitrust plaintiff meets the initial burden of showing
    that an agreement will likely have anticompetitive effects,
    normally the “burden shifts to the defendant to show that
    the restraint in fact serves a legitimate objective.” 7
    Areeda & Hovenkamp ¶1504b, at 415; see California
    Dental Assn. v. FTC, 
    526 U.S. 756
    , 771 (1999); 
    id., at 788
    (BREYER, J., dissenting).
    Third, if the defendant successfully bears this burden,
    the antitrust plaintiff may still carry the day by showing
    that it is possible to meet the legitimate objective in less
    restrictive ways, or, perhaps by showing that the legiti­
    mate objective does not outweigh the harm that competi­
    tion will suffer, i.e., that the agreement “on balance” re­
    mains unreasonable. 7 Areeda & Hovenkamp ¶1507a,
    at 442.
    Like the Court of Appeals and the parties, the majority
    addresses only the first step of that three-step framework.
    Ante, at 10.
    II
    A
    This case concerns the credit-card business. As the
    majority explains, ante, at 2, that business involves the
    selling of two different but related card services. First,
    when a shopper uses a credit card to buy something from a
    participating merchant, the credit-card company pays the
    merchant the amount of money that the merchant’s cus­
    tomer has charged to his card and charges the merchant a
    fee, say 5%, for that speedy-payment service. I shall refer
    to that kind of transaction as a merchant-related card
    service. Second, the credit-card company then sends a bill
    to the merchant’s customer, the shopper who holds the
    card; and the shopper pays the card company the sum that
    merchant charged the shopper for the goods or services he
    4             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    or she bought. The cardholder also often pays the card
    company a fee, such as an annual fee for the card or an
    interest charge for delayed payment. I shall call that kind
    of transaction a shopper-related card service. The credit-
    card company can earn revenue from the sale (directly or
    indirectly) of each of these services: (1) speedy payment for
    merchants, and (2) credit for shoppers. (I say “indirectly”
    to reflect the fact that card companies often create or use
    networks of banks as part of the process—but I have found
    nothing here suggesting that that fact makes a significant
    difference to my analysis.)
    Sales of the two basic card services are related. A shop­
    per can pay for a purchase with a particular credit card
    only if the merchant has signed up for merchant-related
    card services with the company that issued the credit card
    that the shopper wishes to use. A firm in the credit-card
    business is therefore unlikely to make money unless quite
    a few merchants agree to accept that firm’s card and quite
    a few shoppers agree to carry and use it. In general, the
    more merchants that sign up with a particular card com­
    pany, the more useful that card is likely to prove to shop­
    pers and so the more shoppers will sign up; so too, the
    more shoppers that carry a particular card, the more
    useful that card is likely to prove to merchants (as it
    obviously helps them obtain the shoppers’ business) and so
    the more merchants will sign up. Moreover, as a rough
    rule of thumb (and assuming constant charges), the larger
    the networks of paying merchants and paying shoppers
    that a card firm maintains, the larger the revenues that
    the firm will likely receive, since more payments will be
    processed using its cards. Thus, it is not surprising that a
    card company may offer shoppers incentives (say, points
    redeemable for merchandise or travel) for using its card
    or that a firm might want merchants to accept its card
    exclusively.
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)            5
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    B
    This case focuses upon a practice called “steering.”
    American Express has historically charged higher mer­
    chant fees than its competitors. App. to Pet. for Cert.
    173a–176a. Hence, fewer merchants accept American
    Express’ cards than its competitors’. 
    Id., at 184a–187a.
    But, perhaps because American Express cardholders are,
    on average, wealthier, higher-spending, or more loyal to
    American Express than other cardholders, vast numbers
    of merchants still accept American Express cards. See 
    id., at 156a,
    176a–177a, 184a–187a. Those who do, however,
    would (in order to avoid the higher American Express fee)
    often prefer that their customers use a different card to
    charge a purchase. Thus, the merchant has a monetary
    incentive to “steer” the customer towards the use of a
    different card. A merchant might tell the customer, for
    example, “American Express costs us more,” or “please use
    Visa if you can,” or “free shipping if you use Discover.” See
    
    id., at 100a–102a.
       Steering makes a difference, because without it, the
    shopper does not care whether the merchant pays more to
    American Express than it would pay to a different card
    company—the shopper pays the same price either way.
    But if steering works, then American Express will find it
    more difficult to charge more than its competitors for
    merchant-related services, because merchants will re­
    spond by steering their customers, encouraging them to
    use other cards. Thus, American Express dislikes steer­
    ing; the merchants like it; and the shoppers may benefit
    from it, whether because merchants will offer them incen­
    tives to use less expensive cards or in the form of lower
    retail prices overall. See 
    id., at 92a,
    97a–104a.
    In response to its competitors’ efforts to convince mer­
    chants to steer shoppers to use less expensive cards,
    American Express tried to stop, or at least to limit, steer­
    ing by placing antisteering provisions in most of its con­
    6             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    tracts with merchants. It called those provisions “nondis­
    crimination provisions.” They prohibited steering of the
    forms I have described above (and others as well). See 
    id., at 95a–96a,
    100a–101a. After placing them in its agree­
    ments, American Express found it could maintain, or even
    raise, its higher merchant prices without losing too many
    transactions to other firms. 
    Id., at 195a–198a.
    These
    agreements—the “nondiscrimination provisions”—led to
    this lawsuit.
    C
    In 2010 the United States and 17 States brought this
    antitrust case against American Express. They claimed
    that the “nondiscrimination provisions” in its contracts
    with merchants created an unreasonable restraint of
    trade. (Initially Visa and MasterCard were also defend­
    ants, but they entered into consent judgments, dropping
    similar provisions from their contracts with merchants).
    After a 7-week bench trial, the District Court entered
    judgment for the Government, setting forth its findings of
    fact and conclusions of law in a 97-page opinion.
    
    88 F. Supp. 3d 143
    (EDNY 2015).
    Because the majority devotes little attention to the
    District Court’s detailed factual findings, I will summarize
    some of the more significant ones here. Among other
    things, the District Court found that beginning in 2005
    and during the next five years, American Express raised
    the prices it charged merchants on 20 separate occasions.
    See 
    id., at 195–196.
    In doing so, American Express did
    not take account of the possibility that large merchants
    would respond to the price increases by encouraging shop­
    pers to use a different credit card because the nondiscrim­
    ination provisions prohibited any such steering. 
    Id., at 215.
    The District Court pointed to merchants’ testimony
    stating that, had it not been for those provisions, the large
    merchants would have responded to the price increases by
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           7
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    encouraging customers to use other, less-expensive cards.
    
    Ibid. The District Court
    also found that even though Ameri­
    can Express raised its merchant prices 20 times in this 5­
    year period, it did not lose the business of any large mer­
    chant. 
    Id., at 197.
    Nor did American Express increase
    benefits (or cut credit-card prices) to American Express
    cardholders in tandem with the merchant price increases.
    
    Id., at 196.
    Even had there been no direct evidence of
    injury to competition, American Express’ ability to raise
    merchant prices without losing any meaningful market
    share, in the District Court’s view, showed that American
    Express possessed power in the relevant market. See 
    id., at 195.
       The District Court also found that, in the absence of the
    provisions, prices to merchants would likely have been
    lower. 
    Ibid. It wrote that
    in the late 1990’s, Discover, one
    of American Express’ competitors, had tried to develop a
    business model that involved charging lower prices to
    merchants than the other companies charged. 
    Id., at 213.
    Discover then invited each “merchant to save money by
    shifting volume to Discover,” while simultaneously offer­
    ing merchants additional discounts “if they would steer
    customers to Discover.” 
    Ibid. The court determined
    that
    these efforts failed because of American Express’ (and the
    other card companies’) “nondiscrimination provisions.”
    These provisions, the court found, “denied merchants the
    ability to express a preference for Discover or to employ
    any other tool by which they might steer share to Discov­
    er’s lower-priced network.” 
    Id., at 214.
    Because the provi­
    sions eliminated any advantage that lower prices might
    produce, Discover “abandoned its low-price business model”
    and raised its merchant fees to match those of its
    competitors. 
    Ibid. This series of
    events, the court con­
    cluded was “emblematic of the harm done to the competi­
    tive process” by the “nondiscrimination provisions.” 
    Ibid. 8 OHIO v.
    AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    The District Court added that it found no offsetting pro-
    competitive benefit to shoppers. 
    Id., at 225–238.
    Indeed,
    it found no offsetting benefit of any kind. See 
    ibid. American Express appealed,
    and the U. S. Court of
    Appeals for the Second Circuit held in its favor. 
    838 F.3d 179
    (2016). The Court of Appeals did not reject any fact
    found by the District Court as “clearly erroneous.” See
    Fed. Rule Civ. Proc. 52(a)(6). Rather, it concluded that the
    District Court had erred in step 1 of its rule-of-reason
    analysis by failing to account for what the Second Circuit
    called the credit-card business’s “two-sided market” (or
    “two-sided 
    platform”). 838 F.3d, at 185
    –186, 196–200.
    III
    The majority, like the Court of Appeals, reaches only
    step 1 in its “rule of reason” analysis. Ante, at 10. To
    repeat, that step consists of determining whether the
    challenged “nondiscrimination provisions” have had, or
    are likely to have, anticompetitive effects. See Indiana
    Federation of 
    Dentists, 476 U.S., at 459
    . Do those provi­
    sions tend to impede competition? And if so, does Ameri­
    can Express, which imposed that restraint as a condition
    of doing business with its merchant customers, have suffi­
    cient economic or commercial power for the provision to
    make a negative difference? See 
    id., at 460–461.
                                 A
    Here the District Court found that the challenged provi­
    sions have had significant anticompetitive effects. In
    particular, it found that the provisions have limited or
    prevented price competition among credit-card firms for
    the business of merchants. 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 209. That
    conclusion makes sense: In the provisions, American
    Express required the merchants to agree not to encourage
    customers to use American Express’ competitors’ credit
    cards, even cards from those competitors, such as Discover,
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)            9
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    that intended to charge the merchants lower prices.
    See 
    id., at 214.
    By doing so, American Express has “dis­
    rupt[ed] the normal price-setting mechanism” in the mar­
    ket. 
    Id., at 209.
    As a result of the provisions, the District
    Court found, American Express was able to raise mer­
    chant prices repeatedly without any significant loss of
    business, because merchants were unable to respond to
    such price increases by encouraging shoppers to pay with
    other cards. 
    Id., at 215.
    The provisions also meant that
    competitors like Discover had little incentive to lower their
    merchant prices, because doing so did not lead to any
    additional market share. 
    Id., at 214.
    The provisions
    thereby “suppress[ed] [American Express’] . . . competitors’
    incentives to offer lower prices . . . resulting in higher
    profit-maximizing prices across the network services
    market.” 
    Id., at 209.
    Consumers throughout the economy
    paid higher retail prices as a result, and they were denied
    the opportunity to accept incentives that merchants might
    otherwise have offered to use less-expensive cards. 
    Id., at 216,
    220. I should think that, considering step 1 alone,
    there is little more that need be said.
    The majority, like the Court of Appeals, says that the
    District Court should have looked not only at the market
    for the card companies’ merchant-related services but also
    at the market for the card companies’ shopper-related
    services, and that it should have combined them, treating
    them as a single market. Ante, at 
    14–15; 838 F.3d, at 197
    . But I am not aware of any support for that view in
    antitrust law. 	Indeed, this Court has held to the contrary.
    In Times-Picayune Publishing Co. v. United States, 
    345 U.S. 594
    , 610 (1953), the Court held that an antitrust
    court should begin its definition of a relevant market by
    focusing narrowly on the good or service directly affected
    by a challenged restraint. The Government in that case
    claimed that a newspaper’s advertising policy violated the
    Sherman Act’s “rule of reason.” See 
    ibid. In support of
    10             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    that argument, the Government pointed out, and the
    District Court had held, that the newspaper dominated
    the market for the sales of newspapers to readers in New
    Orleans, where it was the sole morning daily newspaper.
    
    Ibid. But this Court
    reversed. We explained that “every
    newspaper is a dual trader in separate though interde­
    pendent markets; it sells the paper’s news and advertising
    content to its readers; in effect that readership is in turn
    sold to the buyers of advertising space.” 
    Ibid. We then added:
         “This case concerns solely one of those markets. The
    Publishing Company stands accused not of tying sales
    to its readers but only to buyers of general and classi­
    fied space in its papers. For this reason, dominance in
    the advertising market, not in readership, must be de­
    cisive in gauging the legality of the Company’s unit
    plan.” 
    Ibid. Here, American Express
    stands accused not of limiting or
    harming competition for shopper-related card services, but
    only of merchant-related card services, because the chal­
    lenged contract provisions appear only in American Ex­
    press’ contracts with merchants. That is why the District
    Court was correct in considering, at step 1, simply
    whether the agreement had diminished competition in
    merchant-related services.
    B
    The District Court did refer to market definition, and
    the majority does the same. Ante, at 11–15. And I recog­
    nize that properly defining a market is often a complex
    business. Once a court has identified the good or service
    directly restrained, as Times-Picayune Publishing Co.
    requires, it will sometimes add to the relevant market
    what economists call “substitutes”: other goods or services
    that are reasonably substitutable for that good or service.
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           11
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    See, e.g., United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co.,
    
    351 U.S. 377
    , 395–396 (1956) (explaining that cellophane
    market includes other, substitutable flexible wrapping
    materials as well). The reason that substitutes are in­
    cluded in the relevant market is that they restrain a firm’s
    ability to profitably raise prices, because customers will
    switch to the substitutes rather than pay the higher prices.
    See 2B Areeda & Hovenkamp ¶561, at 378.
    But while the market includes substitutes, it does not
    include what economists call complements: goods or ser­
    vices that are used together with the restrained product,
    but that cannot be substituted for that product. See 
    id., ¶565a, at
    429; Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical
    Services, Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 463 (1992). An example of
    complements is gasoline and tires. A driver needs both
    gasoline and tires to drive, but they are not substitutes for
    each other, and so the sale price of tires does not check the
    ability of a gasoline firm (say a gasoline monopolist) to
    raise the price of gasoline above competitive levels. As a
    treatise on the subject states: “Grouping complementary
    goods into the same market” is “economic nonsense,” and
    would “undermin[e] the rationale for the policy against
    monopolization or collusion in the first place.” 2B Areeda
    & Hovenkamp ¶565a, at 431.
    Here, the relationship between merchant-related card
    services and shopper-related card services is primarily
    that of complements, not substitutes. Like gasoline and
    tires, both must be purchased for either to have value.
    Merchants upset about a price increase for merchant-
    related services cannot avoid that price increase by becom­
    ing cardholders, in the way that, say, a buyer of newspa­
    per advertising can switch to television advertising or
    direct mail in response to a newspaper’s advertising price
    increase. The two categories of services serve fundamen­
    tally different purposes. And so, also like gasoline and
    tires, it is difficult to see any way in which the price of
    12            OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    shopper-related services could act as a check on the card
    firm’s sale price of merchant-related services. If anything,
    a lower price of shopper-related card services is likely to
    cause more shoppers to use the card, and increased shop­
    per popularity should make it easier for a card firm to
    raise prices to merchants, not harder, as would be the case
    if the services were substitutes. Thus, unless there is
    something unusual about this case—a possibility I discuss
    below, see infra, at 13–20—there is no justification for
    treating shopper-related services and merchant-related
    services as if they were part of a single market, at least
    not at step 1 of the “rule of reason.”
    C
    Regardless, a discussion of market definition was legally
    unnecessary at step 1. That is because the District Court
    found strong direct evidence of anticompetitive effects
    flowing from the challenged restraint. 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at
    207–224. As I 
    said, supra, at 7
    , this evidence included
    Discover’s efforts to break into the credit-card business by
    charging lower prices for merchant-related services, only
    to find that the “nondiscrimination provisions,” by pre­
    venting merchants from encouraging shoppers to use
    Discover cards, meant that lower merchant prices did not
    result in any additional transactions using Discover credit
    cards. 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 213–214. The direct evidence
    also included the fact that American Express raised its
    merchant prices 20 times in five years without losing any
    appreciable market share. 
    Id., at 195–198,
    208–212. It
    also included the testimony of numerous merchants that
    they would have steered shoppers away from American
    Express cards in response to merchant price increases
    (thereby checking the ability of American Express to raise
    prices) had it not been for the nondiscrimination provi­
    sions. See 
    id., at 221–222.
    It included the factual finding
    that American Express “did not even account for the pos­
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)            13
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    sibility that [large] merchants would respond to its price
    increases by attempting to shift share to a competitor’s
    network” because the nondiscrimination provisions pro­
    hibited steering. 
    Id., at 215.
    It included the District
    Court’s ultimate finding of fact, not overturned by the
    Court of Appeals, that the challenged provisions “were
    integral to” American Express’ “[price] increases and
    thereby caused merchants to pay higher prices.” 
    Ibid. As I explained
    above, this Court has stated that “[s]ince
    the purpose of the inquiries into market definition and
    market power is to determine whether an arrangement
    has the potential for genuine adverse effects on competi­
    tion, proof of actual detrimental effects . . . can obviate the
    need for” those inquiries. Indiana Federation of 
    Dentists, 476 U.S., at 460
    –461 (internal quotation marks omitted).
    That statement is fully applicable here. Doubts about the
    District Court’s market-definition analysis are beside the
    point in the face of the District Court’s findings of actual
    anticompetitive harm.
    The majority disagrees that market definition is irrele­
    vant. See ante, at 11–12, and n. 7. The majority explains
    that market definition is necessary because the nondis­
    crimination provisions are “vertical restraints” and
    “[v]ertical restraints often pose no risk to competition
    unless the entity imposing them has market power, which
    cannot be evaluated unless the Court first determines the
    relevant market.” Ante, at 11, n. 7. The majority thus, in
    a footnote, seems categorically to exempt vertical re­
    straints from the ordinary “rule of reason” analysis that
    has applied to them since the Sherman Act’s enactment in
    1890. The majority’s only support for this novel exemption
    is Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.,
    
    551 U.S. 877
    (2007). But Leegin held that the “rule of
    reason” applied to the vertical restraint at issue in that
    case. See 
    id., at 898
    –899. It said nothing to suggest that
    vertical restraints are not subject to the usual “rule of
    14            OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    reason” analysis. See also infra, at 24.
    One critical point that the majority’s argument ignores
    is that proof of actual adverse effects on competition is,
    a fortiori, proof of market power. Without such power, the
    restraints could not have brought about the anticompeti­
    tive effects that the plaintiff proved. See Indiana Federa-
    tion of 
    Dentists, supra, at 460
    (“[T]he purpose of the in­
    quiries into market definition and market power is
    to determine whether an arrangement has the potential
    for genuine adverse effects on competition” (emphasis
    added)). The District Court’s findings of actual anticom­
    petitive harm from the nondiscrimination provisions thus
    showed that, whatever the relevant market might be,
    American Express had enough power in that market to
    cause that harm. There is no reason to require a separate
    showing of market definition and market power under
    such circumstances. And so the majority’s extensive
    discussion of market definition is legally unnecessary.
    D
    The majority’s discussion of market definition is also
    wrong. Without raising any objection in general with the
    longstanding approach I describe 
    above, supra, at 10
    –11,
    the majority agrees with the Court of Appeals that the
    market for American Express’ card services is special
    because it is a “two-sided transaction platform.” Ante, at
    2–5, 12–15. The majority explains that credit-card firms
    connect two distinct groups of customers: First, merchants
    who accept credit cards, and second, shoppers who use the
    cards. Ante, at 2; 
    accord, 838 F.3d, at 186
    . The majority
    adds that “no credit-card transaction can occur unless both
    the merchant and the cardholder simultaneously agree to
    use to the same credit-card network.” Ante, at 3. And it
    explains that the credit-card market involves “indirect
    network effects,” by which it means that shoppers want a
    card that many merchants will accept and merchants
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           15
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    want to accept those cards that many customers have and
    use. 
    Ibid. From this, the
    majority concludes that “courts
    must include both sides of the platform—merchants and
    cardholders—when defining the credit-card market.”
    Ante, at 12; 
    accord, 838 F.3d, at 197
    .
    1
    Missing from the majority’s analysis is any explanation
    as to why, given the purposes that market definition
    serves in antitrust law, the fact that a credit-card firm can
    be said to operate a “two-sided transaction platform”
    means that its merchant-related and shopper-related
    services should be combined into a single market. The
    phrase “two-sided transaction platform” is not one of
    antitrust art—I can find no case from this Court using
    those words. The majority defines the phrase as covering
    a business that “offers different products or services to two
    different groups who both depend on the platform to in­
    termediate between them,” where the business “cannot
    make a sale to one side of the platform without simultane­
    ously making a sale to the other” side of the platform.
    Ante, at 2. I take from that definition that there are four
    relevant features of such businesses on the majority’s
    account: they (1) offer different products or services, (2) to
    different groups of customers, (3) whom the “platform”
    connects, (4) in simultaneous transactions. See 
    ibid. What is it
    about businesses with those four features
    that the majority thinks justifies a special market-
    definition approach for them? It cannot be the first two
    features—that the company sells different products to
    different groups of customers. Companies that sell multi­
    ple products to multiple types of customers are common­
    place. A firm might mine for gold, which it refines and
    sells both to dentists in the form of fillings and to inves­
    tors in the form of ingots. Or, a firm might drill for both
    oil and natural gas. Or a firm might make both ignition
    16            OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    switches inserted into auto bodies and tires used for cars.
    I have already explained that, ordinarily, antitrust law
    will not group the two nonsubstitutable products together
    for step 1 purposes. Supra, at 10–11.
    Neither should it normally matter whether a company
    sells related, or complementary, products, i.e., products
    which must both be purchased to have any function, such
    as ignition switches and tires, or cameras and film. It is
    well established that an antitrust court in such cases looks
    at the product where the attacked restraint has an anti­
    competitive effect. Supra, at 9; see Eastman 
    Kodak, 504 U.S., at 463
    . The court does not combine the customers
    for the separate, nonsubstitutable goods and see if “over­
    all” the restraint has a negative effect. See ibid.; 2B
    Areeda & Hovenkamp ¶565a. That is because, as I have
    explained, the complementary relationship between the
    products is irrelevant to the purposes of market-definition.
    
    See supra, at 10
    –11.
    The majority disputes my characterization of merchant-
    related and shopper-related services as “complements.”
    See ante, at 14, n. 8. The majority relies on an academic
    article which devotes one sentence to the question, saying
    that “a two-sided market [is] different from markets for
    complementary products [e.g., tires and gas], in which
    both products are bought by the same buyers, who, in
    their buying decisions, can therefore be expected to take
    into account both prices.” Filistrucchi, Geradin, Van
    Damme, & Affeldt, Market Definition in Two-Sided Mar­
    kets: Theory and Practice, 10 J. Competition L. & Econ.
    293, 297 (2014) (Filistrucchi). I agree that two-sided
    platforms—at least as some academics define them, but
    see infra, at 19–20—may be distinct from some types of
    complements in the respect the majority mentions (even
    though the services resemble complements because they
    must be used together for either to have value). But the
    distinction the majority mentions has nothing to do with
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           17
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    the relevant question. The relevant question is whether
    merchant-related and shopper-related services are substi-
    tutes, one for the other, so that customers can respond to a
    price increase for one service by switching to the other
    service. As I have explained, the two types of services are
    not substitutes in this way. Supra, at 11–12. And so the
    question remains, just as before: What is it about the
    economic relationship between merchant-related and
    shopper-related services that would justify the majority’s
    novel approach to market definition?
    What about the last two features—that the company
    connects the two groups of customers to each other, in
    simultaneous transactions? That, too, is commonplace.
    Consider a farmers’ market. It brings local farmers and
    local shoppers together, and transactions will occur only if
    a farmer and a shopper simultaneously agree to engage in
    one. Should courts abandon their ordinary step 1 inquiry
    if several competing farmers’ markets in a city agree that
    only certain kinds of farmers can participate, or if a farm­
    ers’ market charges a higher fee than its competitors do
    and prohibits participating farmers from raising their
    prices to cover it? Why? If farmers’ markets are special,
    what about travel agents that connect airlines and pas­
    sengers? What about internet retailers, who, in addition
    to selling their own goods, allow (for a fee) other goods-
    producers to sell over their networks? Each of those busi­
    nesses seems to meet the majority’s four-prong definition.
    Apparently as its justification for applying a special
    market-definition rule to “two-sided transaction plat­
    forms,” the majority explains that such platforms “often
    exhibit” what it calls “indirect network effects.” Ante, at 3.
    By this, the majority means that sales of merchant-related
    card services and (different) shopper-related card services
    are interconnected, in that increased merchant-buyers
    mean increased shopper-buyers (the more stores in the
    card’s network, the more customers likely to use the card),
    18            OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    and vice versa. See 
    ibid. But this, too,
    is commonplace.
    Consider, again, a farmers’ market. The more farmers
    that participate (within physical and esthetic limits), the
    more customers the market will likely attract, and vice
    versa. So too with travel agents: the more airlines whose
    tickets a travel agent sells, the more potential passengers
    will likely use that travel agent, and the more potential
    passengers that use the travel agent, the easier it will
    likely be to convince airlines to sell through the travel
    agent. And so forth. Nothing in antitrust law, to my
    knowledge, suggests that a court, when presented with an
    agreement that restricts competition in any one of the
    markets my examples suggest, should abandon traditional
    market-definition approaches and include in the relevant
    market services that are complements, not substitutes, of
    the restrained good. 
    See supra, at 10
    –11.
    2
    To justify special treatment for “two-sided transaction
    platforms,” the majority relies on the Court’s decision in
    United States v. Grinnell Corp., 
    384 U.S. 563
    , 571–572
    (1966). In Grinnell, the Court treated as a single market
    several different “central station services,” including
    burglar alarm services and fire alarm services. 
    Id., at 571.
    It did so even though, for consumers, “burglar alarm ser­
    vices are not interchangeable with fire alarm services.”
    
    Id., at 572.
    But that is because, for producers, the services
    were indeed interchangeable: A company that offered one
    could easily offer the other, because they all involve “a
    single basic service—the protection of property through
    use of a central service station.” 
    Ibid. Thus, the “commer­
    cial realit[y]” that the Grinnell Court relied on, ibid., was
    that the services being grouped were what economists call
    “producer substitutes.” See 2B Areeda & Hovenkamp
    ¶561, at 378. And the law is clear that “two products
    produced interchangeably from the same production facili­
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)          19
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    ties are presumptively in the same market,” even if they
    are not “close substitutes for each other on the demand
    side.” 
    Ibid. That is because
    a firm that produces one such
    product can, in response to a price increase in the other,
    easily shift its production and thereby limit its compet-
    itor’s power to impose the higher price. See 
    id., ¶561a, at
    379.
    Unlike the various types of central station services at
    issue in Grinnell Corp., however, the shopper-related and
    merchant-related services that American Express provides
    are not “producer substitutes” any more than they are
    traditional substitutes. For producers as for consumers,
    the services are instead complements. Credit card compa­
    nies must sell them together for them to be useful. As a
    result, the credit-card companies cannot respond to, say,
    merchant-related price increases by shifting production
    away from shopper-related services to merchant-related
    services. The relevant “commercial realities” in this case
    are thus completely different from those in Grinnell Corp.
    (The majority also cites Brown Shoe Co. v. United States,
    
    370 U.S. 294
    , 336–337 (1962), for this point, but the
    “commercial realities” considered in that case were that
    “shoe stores in the outskirts of cities compete effectively
    with stores in central downtown areas,” and thus are
    part of the same market.         
    Id., at 338–339.
       Here,
    merchant-related services do not, as I have said, compete
    with shopper-related services, and so Brown Shoe Co. does
    not support the majority’s position.) Thus, our precedent
    provides no support for the majority’s special approach
    to defining markets involving “two-sided transaction
    platforms.”
    3
    What about the academic articles the majority cites?
    The first thing to note is that the majority defines “two-
    sided transaction platforms” much more broadly than the
    20            OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    economists do. As the economists who coined the term
    explain, if a “two-sided market” meant simply that a firm
    connects two different groups of customers via a platform,
    then “pretty much any market would be two-sided, since
    buyers and sellers need to be brought together for markets
    to exist and gains from trade to be realized.” Rochet &
    Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, 37 RAND
    J. Econ. 645, 646 (2006). The defining feature of a “two-
    sided market,” according to these economists, is that “the
    platform can affect the volume of transactions by charging
    more to one side of the market and reducing the price paid
    by the other side by an equal amount.” 
    Id., at 664–665;
    accord, Filistrucchi 299. That requirement appears no­
    where in the majority’s definition. By failing to limit its
    definition to platforms that economists would recognize
    as “two sided” in the relevant respect, the majority carves
    out a much broader exception to the ordinary antitrust
    rules than the academic articles it relies on could possibly
    support.
    Even as limited to the narrower definition that econo­
    mists use, however, the academic articles the majority
    cites do not support the majority’s flat rule that firms
    operating “two-sided transaction platforms” should always
    be treated as part of a single market for all antitrust
    purposes. Ante, at 13–15. Rather, the academics explain
    that for market-definition purposes, “[i]n some cases, the
    fact that a business can be thought of as two-sided may be
    irrelevant,” including because “nothing in the analysis of
    the practices [at issue] really hinges on the linkages be­
    tween the demands of participating groups.” Evans &
    Schmalensee, Markets With Two-Sided Platforms, 1 Is­
    sues in Competition L. & Pol’y 667, 689 (2008). “In other
    cases, the fact that a business is two-sided will prove
    important both by identifying the real dimensions of com­
    petition and focusing on sources of constraints.” 
    Ibid. That flexible approach,
    however, is precisely the one the
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           21
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    District Court followed in this case, by considering the
    effects of “[t]he two-sided nature of the . . . card industry”
    throughout its analysis. 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 155.
    Neither the majority nor the academic articles it cites
    offer any explanation for why the features of a “two-sided
    transaction platform” justify always treating it as a single
    antitrust market, rather than accounting for its economic
    features in other ways, as the District Court did. The
    article that the majority repeatedly quotes as saying that
    “ ‘[i]n two-sided transaction markets, only one market
    should be defined,’ ” ante, at 14–15 (quoting Filistrucchi
    302), justifies that conclusion only for purposes of as­
    sessing the effects of a merger. In such a case, the article
    explains, “[e]veryone would probably agree that a payment
    card company such as American Express is either in the
    relevant market on both sides or on neither side . . . . The
    analysis of a merger between two payment card platforms
    should thus consider . . . both sides of the market.” 
    Id., at 301.
    In a merger case this makes sense, but is also mean­
    ingless, because, whether there is one market or two, a
    reviewing court will consider both sides, because it must
    examine the effects of the merger in each affected market
    and submarket. See Brown Shoe 
    Co., 370 U.S., at 325
    .
    As for a nonmerger case, the article offers only United
    States v. Grinnell as a justification, see Filistrucchi 303,
    and as I have already 
    explained, supra, at 16
    –18, Grinnell
    does not support this proposition.
    E
    Put all of those substantial problems with the majority’s
    reasoning aside, though. Even if the majority were right
    to say that market definition was relevant, and even if the
    majority were right to further say that the District Court
    should have defined the market in this case to include
    shopper-related services as well as merchant-related
    services, that still would not justify the majority in affirm­
    22            OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    ing the Court of Appeals. That is because, as the majority
    is forced to admit, the plaintiffs made the factual showing
    that the majority thinks is required. See ante, at 17.
    Recall why it is that the majority says that market
    definition matters: because if the relevant market includes
    both merchant-related services and card-related services,
    then the plaintiffs had the burden to show that as a result
    of the nondiscrimination provisions, “the price of credit-
    card transactions”—considering both fees charged to
    merchants and rewards paid to cardholders—“was higher
    than the price one would expect to find in a competitive
    market.” Ante, at 16. This mirrors the Court of Appeals’
    holding that the Government had to show that the “non­
    discrimination provisions” had “made all [American Ex­
    press] customers on both sides of the platform—i.e., both
    merchants and cardholders—worse off 
    overall.” 838 F.3d, at 205
    .
    The problem with this reasoning, aside from it being
    wrong, is that the majority admits that the plaintiffs did
    show this: they “offer[ed] evidence” that American Express
    “increased the percentage of the purchase price that it
    charges merchants . . . and that this increase was not
    entirely spent on cardholder rewards.” Ante, 17 (citing 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 195–197, 215). Indeed, the plaintiffs did
    not merely “offer evidence” of this—they persuaded the
    District Court, which made an unchallenged factual find­
    ing that the merchant price increases that resulted from
    the nondiscrimination provisions “were not wholly offset
    by additional rewards expenditures or otherwise passed
    through to cardholders, and resulted in a higher net price.”
    
    Id., at 215
    (emphasis added).
    In the face of this problem, the majority retreats to
    saying that even net price increases do not matter after
    all, absent a showing of lower output, because if output is
    increasing, “ ‘rising prices are equally consistent with
    growing product demand.’ ” Ante, at 18 (quoting Brooke
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           23
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 237 (1993)). This argument, unlike the price
    argument, has nothing to do with the credit-card market
    being a “two-sided transaction platform,” so if this is the
    basis for the majority’s holding, then nearly all of the
    opinion is dicta. The argument is also wrong. It is true as
    an economic matter that a firm exercises market power by
    restricting output in order to raise prices. But the rele­
    vant restriction of output is as compared with a hypothet­
    ical world in which the restraint was not present and
    prices were lower. The fact that credit-card use in general
    has grown over the last decade, as the majority says, see
    ante, at 17–18, says nothing about whether such use
    would have grown more or less without the nondiscrimina­
    tion provisions. And because the relevant question is a
    comparison between reality and a hypothetical state of
    affairs, to require actual proof of reduced output is often to
    require the impossible—tantamount to saying that the
    Sherman Act does not apply at all.
    In any event, there are features of the credit-card mar­
    ket that may tend to limit the usual relationship between
    price and output. In particular, merchants generally
    spread the costs of credit-card acceptance across all their
    customers (whatever payment method they may use),
    while the benefits of card use go only to the cardholders.
    See, e.g., 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 216; Brief for John M. Connor
    et al. as Amici Curiae 34–35. Thus, higher credit-card
    merchant fees may have only a limited effect on credit-
    card transaction volume, even as they disrupt the market­
    place by extracting anticompetitive profits.
    IV
    A
    For the reasons I have stated, the Second Circuit was
    wrong to lump together the two different services sold, at
    step 1. But I recognize that the Court of Appeals has not
    24             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    yet considered whether the relationship between the two
    services might make a difference at steps 2 and 3. That is
    to say, American Express might wish to argue that the
    nondiscrimination provisions, while anticompetitive in
    respect to merchant-related services, nonetheless have an
    adequate offsetting procompetitive benefit in respect to its
    shopper-related services. I believe that American Express
    should have an opportunity to ask the Court of Appeals to
    consider that matter.
    American Express might face an uphill battle. A Sher­
    man Act §1 defendant can rarely, if ever, show that a pro-
    competitive benefit in the market for one product offsets
    an anticompetitive harm in the market for another. In
    United States v. Topco Associates, Inc., 
    405 U.S. 596
    , 611
    (1972), this Court wrote:
    “If a decision is to be made to sacrifice competition in
    one portion of the economy for greater competition in
    another portion, this . . . is a decision that must be
    made by Congress and not by private forces or by the
    courts. Private forces are too keenly aware of their
    own interests in making such decisions and courts are
    ill-equipped and ill-situated for such decisionmaking.”
    American Express, pointing to vertical price-fixing
    cases like our decision in Leegin, argues that comparing
    competition-related pros and cons is more common than I
    have just suggested. 
    See 551 U.S., at 889
    –892. But
    Leegin held only that vertical price fixing is subject to the
    “rule of reason” instead of being per se unlawful; the “rule
    of reason” still applies to vertical agreements just as it
    applies to horizontal agreements. See 
    id., at 898
    –899.
    Moreover, the procompetitive justifications for vertical
    price-fixing agreements are not apparently applicable to
    the distinct types of restraints at issue in this case. A
    vertically imposed price-fixing agreement typically in­
    volves a manufacturer controlling the terms of sale for its
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           25
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    own product. A television-set manufacturer, for example,
    will insist that its dealers not cut prices for the manufac­
    turer’s own televisions below a particular level. Why
    might a manufacturer want its dealers to refrain from
    price competition in the manufacturer’s own products?
    Perhaps because, for example, the manufacturer wants to
    encourage the dealers to develop the market for the manu­
    facturer’s brand, thereby increasing interbrand competi­
    tion for the same ultimate product, namely a television
    set. This type of reasoning does not appear to apply to
    American Express’ nondiscrimination provisions, which
    seek to control the terms on which merchants accept other
    brands’ cards, not merely American Express’ own.
    Regardless, I would not now hold that an agreement
    such as the one before us can never be justified by pro-
    competitive benefits of some kind. But the Court of Ap­
    peals would properly consider procompetitive justifications
    not at step 1, but at steps 2 and 3 of the “rule of reason”
    inquiry. American Express would need to show just how
    this particular anticompetitive merchant-related agree­
    ment has procompetitive benefits in the shopper-related
    market. In doing so, American Express would need to
    overcome the District Court’s factual findings that the
    agreement had no such effects. See 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at
    224–238.
    B
    The majority charts a different path. Notwithstanding
    its purported acceptance of the three-step, burden-shifting
    framework I have described, ante, at 9–10, the majority
    addresses American Express’ procompetitive justifications
    now, at step 1 of the analysis, see ante, at 18–20. And in
    doing so, the majority inexplicably ignores the District
    Court’s factual findings on the subject.
    The majority reasons that the challenged nondiscrimi­
    nation provisions “stem negative externalities in the credit­
    26            OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    card market and promote interbrand competition.” Ante,
    at 19. The “negative externality” the majority has in mind
    is this: If one merchant persuades a shopper not to use his
    American Express card at that merchant’s store, that
    shopper becomes less likely to use his American Express
    card at other merchants’ stores. 
    Ibid. The majority wor­
    ries that this “endangers the viability of the entire [Ameri­
    can Express] network,” ibid., but if so that is simply a
    consequence of American Express’ merchant fees being
    higher than a competitive market will support. “The
    antitrust laws were enacted for ‘the protection of competi-
    tion, not competitors.’ ” Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA
    Petroleum Co., 
    495 U.S. 328
    , 338 (1990). If American
    Express’ merchant fees are so high that merchants suc­
    cessfully induce their customers to use other cards, Ameri­
    can Express can remedy that problem by lowering those
    fees or by spending more on cardholder rewards so that
    cardholders decline such requests. What it may not do is
    demand contractual protection from price competition.
    In any event, the majority ignores the fact that the
    District Court, in addition to saying what I have just said,
    also rejected this argument on independent factual
    grounds. It explained that American Express “presented
    no expert testimony, financial analysis, or other direct
    evidence establishing that without its [nondiscrimination
    provisions] it will, in fact, be unable to adapt its business
    to a more competitive market.” 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 231. It
    further explained that the testimony that was provided on
    the topic “was notably inconsistent,” with some of Ameri­
    can Express’ witnesses saying only that invalidation of the
    provisions “would require American Express to adapt its
    current business model.” 
    Ibid. After an extensive
    discus­
    sion of the record, the District Court found that “American
    Express possesses the flexibility and expertise necessary
    to adapt its business model to suit a market in which it is
    required to compete on both the cardholder and merchant
    Cite as: 585 U. S. ____ (2018)           27
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    sides of the [credit-card] platform.” 
    Id., at 231–232.
    The
    majority evidently rejects these factual findings, even
    though no one has challenged them as clearly erroneous.
    Similarly, the majority refers to the nondiscrimination
    provisions as preventing “free riding” on American Ex­
    press’ “investments in rewards” for cardholders. Ante, at
    19–20; see also ante, at 7 (describing steering in terms
    suggestive of free riding). But as the District Court ex­
    plained, “[p]lainly . . . investments tied to card use (such
    as Membership Rewards points, purchase protection, and
    the like) are not subject to free-riding, since the network
    does not incur any cost if the cardholder is successfully
    steered away from using his or her American Express
    card.” 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 237. This, I should think, is an
    unassailable conclusion: American Express pays rewards
    to cardholders only for transactions in which cardholders
    use their American Express cards, so if a steering effort
    succeeds, no rewards are paid. As for concerns about free
    riding on American Express’ fixed expenses, including its
    investments in its brand, the District Court acknowledged
    that free-riding was in theory possible, but explained that
    American Express “ma[de] no effort to identify the fixed
    expenses to which its experts referred or to explain how
    they are subject to free riding.” Ibid.; see also 
    id., at 238
    (American Express’ own data showed “that the network’s
    ability to confer a credentialing benefit trails that of its
    competitors, casting doubt on whether there is in fact any
    particular benefit associated with accepting [American
    Express] that is subject to free riding”). The majority does
    not even acknowledge, much less reject, these factual
    findings, despite coming to the contrary conclusion.
    Finally, the majority reasons that the nondiscrimination
    provisions “do not prevent Visa, MasterCard, or Discover
    from competing against [American Express] by offering
    lower merchant fees or promoting their broader merchant
    acceptance.” Ante, at 20. But again, the District Court’s
    28             OHIO v. AMERICAN EXPRESS CO.
    BREYER, J., dissenting
    factual findings were to the contrary. As I laid out above,
    the District Court found that the nondiscrimination provi­
    sions in fact did prevent Discover from pursuing a low­
    merchant-fee business model, by “den[ying] merchants the
    ability to express a preference for Discover or to employ
    any other tool by which they might steer share to Discov­
    er’s lower-priced network.” 
    88 F. Supp. 3d
    , at 214; 
    see supra, at 7
    . The majority’s statements that the nondis­
    crimination provisions are procompetitive are directly
    contradicted by this and other factual findings.
    *    *     *
    For the reasons I have explained, the majority’s decision
    in this case is contrary to basic principles of antitrust law,
    and it ignores and contradicts the District Court’s detailed
    factual findings, which were based on an extensive trial
    record. I respectfully dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 16-1454

Judges: Clarence Thomas

Filed Date: 6/25/2018

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 7/25/2023

Authorities (24)

Spanish Broadcasting System of Florida, Inc. v. Clear ... , 376 F.3d 1065 ( 2004 )

tops-markets-inc-plaintiff-appellant-cross-appellee-v-quality-markets , 142 F.3d 90 ( 1998 )

Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services, Inc. , 112 S. Ct. 2072 ( 1992 )

Virgin Atlantic Airways Limited v. British Airways Plc , 257 F.3d 256 ( 2001 )

Capital Imaging Associates, P.C. v. Mohawk Valley Medical ... , 996 F.2d 537 ( 1993 )

United States v. Detroit Timber & Lumber Co. , 26 S. Ct. 282 ( 1906 )

Continental T. v. Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc. , 97 S. Ct. 2549 ( 1977 )

Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc. , 100 S. Ct. 1925 ( 1980 )

Times-Picayune Publishing Co. v. United States , 73 S. Ct. 872 ( 1953 )

United States v. E. I. Du Pont De Nemours & Co. , 76 S. Ct. 994 ( 1956 )

Federal Trade Commission v. Indiana Federation of Dentists , 106 S. Ct. 2009 ( 1986 )

Business Electronics Corp. v. Sharp Electronics Corp. , 108 S. Ct. 1515 ( 1988 )

Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. , 127 S. Ct. 2705 ( 2007 )

Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp. , 104 S. Ct. 2731 ( 1984 )

Brown Shoe Co. v. United States , 82 S. Ct. 1502 ( 1962 )

Walker Process Equipment, Inc. v. Food MacHinery & Chemical ... , 86 S. Ct. 347 ( 1965 )

Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co. , 110 S. Ct. 1884 ( 1990 )

Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp. , 113 S. Ct. 2578 ( 1993 )

State Oil Co. v. Khan , 118 S. Ct. 275 ( 1997 )

California Dental Ass'n v. Federal Trade Commission , 119 S. Ct. 1604 ( 1999 )

View All Authorities »