ZF Meritor LLC v. Eaton Corporation , 696 F.3d 254 ( 2012 )


Menu:
  •                                           PRECEDENTIAL
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
    ______
    Nos. 11-3301 and 11-3426
    ______
    ZF MERITOR, LLC;
    MERITOR TRANSMISSION CORPORATION,
    Appellants, No. 11-3426
    v.
    EATON CORPORATION,
    Appellant, No. 11-3301
    ______
    On Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the District of Delaware
    (D.C. No. 1-06-cv-00623)
    District Judge: Honorable Sue L. Robinson
    ______
    Argued June 26, 2012
    Before: FISHER and GREENBERG, Circuit Judges,
    and OLIVER,* District Judge.
    *
    The Honorable Solomon Oliver, Jr., Chief Judge of
    the United States District Court for the Northern District of
    Ohio, sitting by designation.
    (Filed: September 28, 2012 )
    Caeli A. Higney
    Thomas G. Hungar
    Theodore B. Olson (Argued)
    Cynthia E. Richman
    Geoffrey C. Weien
    Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher
    1050 Connecticut Avenue, N.W., 9th Floor
    Washington, DC 20036
    Erik T. Koons
    William K. Lavery
    Joseph A. Ostoyich
    Baker Botts
    1299 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W.
    The Warner
    Washington, DC 20004
    Donald E. Reid
    Morris, Nichols, Arsht & Tunnell
    1201 North Market Street
    P.O. Box 1347
    Wilmington, DE 19899
    Counsel for Eaton Corporation
    Jay N. Fastow (Argued)
    Dickstein Shapiro
    1633 Broadway
    New York, NY 10019
    2
    Robert B. Holcomb
    Adams Holcomb
    1875 Eye Street. N.W., Suite 810
    Washington, DC 20006
    Christopher H. Wood
    1489 Steele Street, Suite 111
    Denver, CO 80206
    Counsel for ZF Meritor, LLC and
    Meritor Transmission Corp.
    Michael S. Tarringer
    Cafferty Faucher
    1717 Arch Street, Suite 3610
    Philadelphia, PA 19103
    Counsel for American Antitrust
    Institute
    ______
    OPINION OF THE COURT
    ______
    FISHER, Circuit Judge.
    This case arises from an antitrust action brought by ZF
    Meritor, LLC (―ZF Meritor‖) and Meritor Transmission
    Corporation (―Meritor‖) (collectively, ―Plaintiffs‖) against
    Eaton Corporation (―Eaton‖) for allegedly anticompetitive
    practices in the heavy-duty truck transmissions market. The
    practices at issue are embodied in long-term agreements
    3
    between Eaton, the leading supplier of heavy-duty truck
    transmissions in North America, and every direct purchaser of
    such transmissions. Following a four-week trial, a jury found
    that Eaton‘s conduct violated Section 1 and Section 2 of the
    Sherman Act, and Section 3 of the Clayton Act. Eaton filed a
    renewed motion for judgment as a matter of law, arguing that
    its conduct was per se lawful because it priced its products
    above-cost. The District Court disagreed, reasoning that
    notwithstanding Eaton‘s above-cost prices, there was
    sufficient evidence in the record to establish that Eaton
    engaged in anticompetitive conduct—specifically that Eaton
    entered into long-term de facto exclusive dealing
    arrangements—which foreclosed a substantial share of the
    market and, as a result, harmed competition. We agree with
    the District Court and will affirm the District Court‘s denial
    of Eaton‘s renewed motion for judgment as a matter of law.
    We are also called upon to address several other
    issues. Although the jury returned a verdict in favor of
    Plaintiffs on the issue of liability, prior to trial, the District
    Court granted Eaton‘s motion to exclude the damages
    testimony of Plaintiffs‘ expert. The District Court also denied
    Plaintiffs‘ request for permission to amend the expert report
    to include alternate damages calculations. Consequently, the
    issue of damages was never tried and no damages were
    awarded. Plaintiffs cross-appeal from the District Court‘s
    order granting Eaton‘s motion to exclude and the District
    Court‘s subsequent denial of Plaintiffs‘ motion for
    clarification. For the reasons set forth below, we will affirm
    the District Court‘s orders to the extent that they excluded
    Plaintiffs‘ expert‘s testimony based on the damages
    4
    calculations in his initial expert report, but reverse to the
    extent that the District Court denied Plaintiffs‘ request to
    amend the report to submit alternate damages calculations.
    Finally, although the District Court awarded no damages, it
    did enter injunctive relief against Eaton. On appeal, Eaton
    argues that Plaintiffs lack standing to seek injunctive relief
    because they are no longer in the heavy-duty truck
    transmissions market, and have expressed no concrete desire
    to re-enter the market. We agree and will vacate the District
    Court‘s order issuing injunctive relief.
    I. BACKGROUND
    A. Factual Background
    1. Market Background
    The parties agree that the relevant market in this case
    is heavy-duty ―Class 8‖ truck transmissions (―HD
    transmissions‖) in North America. Heavy-duty trucks include
    18-wheeler ―linehaul‖ trucks, which are used to travel long
    distances on highways, and ―performance‖ vehicles, such as
    cement mixers, garbage trucks, and dump trucks. There are
    three types of HD transmissions: three-pedal manual, which
    uses a clutch to change gears; two-pedal automatic; and two-
    or-three-pedal automated mechanical, which engages the
    gears mechanically through electronic controls. Linehaul and
    performance transmissions, which comprise over 90% of the
    5
    market, typically use manual or automated mechanical
    transmissions.1
    There are only four direct purchasers of HD
    transmissions in North America:             Freightliner, LLC
    (―Freightliner‖), International Truck and Engine Corporation
    (―International‖), PACCAR, Inc. (―PACCAR‖), and Volvo
    Group (―Volvo‖). These companies are referred to as the
    Original Equipment Manufacturers (―OEMs‖). The ultimate
    consumers of HD transmissions, truck buyers, purchase
    trucks from the OEMs. Truck buyers have the ability to
    select many of the components used in their trucks, including
    the transmissions, from OEM catalogues called ―data books.‖
    Data books list the alternative component choices, and
    include a price for each option relative to the ―standard‖ or
    ―preferred‖ offerings.      The ―standard‖ offering is the
    component that is provided to the customer unless the
    customer expressly designates another supplier‘s product,
    while the ―preferred‖ or ―preferentially-priced‖ offering is the
    lowest priced component in data book among comparable
    products. Data book positioning is a form of advertising, and
    standard or preferred positioning generally means that
    customers are more likely to purchase that supplier‘s
    components. Although customers may, and sometimes do,
    request components that are not published in a data book,
    doing so is often cumbersome and increases the cost of the
    1
    A third category of heavy-duty trucks, ―specialty‖
    vehicles, such as fire trucks, typically use automatic
    transmissions.
    6
    component. Thus, data book positioning is essential in the
    industry.
    Eaton has long been a monopolist in the market for
    HD transmissions in North America.2 It began making HD
    transmissions in the 1950s, and was the only significant
    manufacturer until Meritor entered the market in 1989 and
    began offering manual transmissions primarily for linehaul
    trucks. By 1999, Meritor had obtained approximately 17% of
    the market for sales of HD transmissions, including 30% for
    linehaul transmissions.      In mid-1999, Meritor and ZF
    Friedrichshafen (―ZF AG‖), a leading supplier of HD
    transmissions in Europe, formed the joint venture ZF Meritor,
    and Meritor transferred its transmissions business into the
    joint venture.3 Aside from Meritor, and then ZF Meritor, no
    significant external supplier of HD transmissions has entered
    the market in the past 20 years.4
    One purpose of the ZF Meritor joint venture was to
    adapt ZF AG‘s two-pedal automated mechanical
    2
    At trial, Eaton disputed that it was a monopolist, but
    on appeal, does not challenge the jury‘s finding that it
    possessed monopoly power in the HD transmissions market
    in North America.
    3
    ZF AG is not a party to this lawsuit.
    4
    ―External‖ transmission sales do not include
    transmissions manufactured by Volvo Group for use in its
    own trucks.
    7
    transmission, ASTronic, which was used exclusively in
    Europe, for the North American market. The redesign and
    testing took 18 months, and ZF Meritor introduced the
    adapted ASTronic model into the North American market in
    2001 under the new name FreedomLine. FreedomLine was
    the first two-pedal automated mechanical transmission to be
    sold in North America.5 When FreedomLine was released,
    Eaton projected that automated mechanical transmissions
    would account for 30-50% of the market for all HD
    transmission sales by 2004 or 2005.
    2. Eaton’s Long-Term Agreements
    In late 1999 through early 2000, the trucking industry
    experienced a 40-50% decline in demand for new heavy-duty
    trucks. Shortly thereafter, Eaton entered into new long-term
    agreements (―LTAs‖) with each OEM. Although long-term
    supply contracts were not uncommon in the industry, and
    were also utilized by Meritor in the 1990s, Eaton‘s new LTAs
    were unprecedented in terms of their length and coverage of
    the market. Eaton signed LTAs with every OEM, and each
    LTA was for a term of at least five years.
    Although the LTAs‘ terms varied somewhat, the key
    provisions were similar. Each LTA included a conditional
    rebate provision, under which an OEM would only receive
    rebates if it purchased a specified percentage of its
    5
    Eaton did not produce a two-pedal automated
    mechanical transmission at the time, and would not fully
    release one until 2004.
    8
    requirements from Eaton.6 Eaton‘s LTA with Freightliner,
    the largest OEM, provided for rebates if Freightliner
    purchased 92% or more of its requirements from Eaton.7
    Under Eaton‘s LTA with International, Eaton agreed to make
    an up-front payment of $2.5 million, and any additional
    rebates were conditioned on International purchasing 87% to
    97.5% of its requirements from Eaton. The PACCAR LTA
    provided for an up-front payment of $1 million, and
    conditioned rebates on PACCAR meeting a 90% to 95%
    market-share penetration target. Finally, Eaton‘s LTA with
    Volvo provided for discounts if Volvo reached a market-share
    penetration level of 70% to 78%.8 The LTAs were not true
    6
    We will refer to these as ―market-share‖ discounts or
    ―market-penetration‖ discounts. It is important to distinguish
    such discounts from quantity or volume discounts. Quantity
    discounts provide the buyer with a lower price for purchasing
    a specified minimum quantity or volume from the seller. In
    contrast, market-share discounts grant the buyer a lower price
    for taking a specified minimum percentage of its purchases
    from the seller. Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp,
    Antitrust Law ¶ 768, at 169 (3d ed. 2008).
    7
    In 2003, Freightliner and Eaton modified the
    agreement from a fixed 92% goal to a sliding scale, which
    entitled Freightliner to different rebates at different market-
    penetration levels.
    8
    The share penetration targets in the Volvo LTA were
    lower because Volvo also manufactured transmissions for use
    in its own trucks. The commitment to Eaton, plus Volvo‘s
    9
    requirements contracts because they did not expressly require
    the OEMs to purchase a specified percentage of their needs
    from Eaton. However, the Freightliner and Volvo LTAs gave
    Eaton the right to terminate the agreements if the share
    penetration goals were not met. Additionally, if an OEM did
    not meet its market-share penetration target for one year,
    Eaton could require repayment of all contractual savings.
    Each LTA also required the OEM to publish Eaton as
    the standard offering in its data book, and under two of the
    four LTAs, the OEM was required to remove competitors‘
    products from its data book entirely. Freightliner agreed to
    exclusively publish Eaton transmissions in its data books
    through 2002, but reserved the right to publish ZF Meritor‘s
    FreedomLine through the life of the agreement. In 2002,
    Freightliner and Eaton revised the LTA to allow Freightliner
    to publish other competitors‘ transmissions, but the revised
    LTA provided that Eaton had the right to ―renegotiate the
    rebate schedule‖ if Freightliner chose to publish a
    competitor‘s transmission. Subsequently, Freightliner agreed
    to a request by Eaton to remove FreedomLine from all of its
    data books. Eaton‘s LTA with International also required that
    International list exclusively Eaton transmissions in its
    electronic data book. International did, however, publish ZF
    Meritor‘s manual transmissions in its printed data book. The
    Volvo and PACCAR LTAs did not require that Eaton
    products be the exclusive offering, but did require that Eaton
    products be listed as the preferred offering. Both Volvo and
    own manufactured products, accounted for more than 85% of
    Volvo‘s needs.
    10
    PACCAR continued to list ZF Meritor‘s products in their data
    books. In the 1990s, Meritor‘s products were listed in all
    OEM component data books, and in some cases, had
    preferred positioning.
    The LTAs also required the OEMs to ―preferential
    price‖ Eaton transmissions against competitors‘ equivalent
    transmissions. Eaton claims that it sought preferential pricing
    to ensure that its low prices were passed on to truck buyers.
    However, there were no express requirements in the LTAs
    that savings be passed on to truck buyers (i.e., that Eaton‘s
    prices be reduced) and there is evidence that the ―preferential
    pricing‖ was achieved by both lowering the prices of Eaton‘s
    products and raising the prices of competitors‘ products.
    Eaton notes that it was ―common‖ for price savings to be
    passed down to truck buyers, and a Volvo executive testified
    that some of the savings from Eaton products were passed
    down while others were kept to improve profit margins.
    Plaintiffs, however, emphasize that according to an email sent
    by Eaton to Freightliner, the Freightliner LTA required that
    ZF Meritor‘s products be priced at a $200 premium over
    equivalent Eaton products. Likewise, International agreed to
    an ―artificial[] penal[ty]‖ of $150 on all of ZF Meritor‘s
    transmissions as of early 2003, and PACCAR imposed a
    penalty on customers who chose ZF Meritor‘s products.
    Finally, each LTA contained a ―competitiveness‖
    clause, which permitted the OEM to purchase transmissions
    from another supplier if that supplier offered the OEM a
    lower price or a better product, the OEM notified Eaton of the
    competitor‘s offer, and Eaton could not match the price or
    quality of the product after good faith efforts. The parties
    11
    dispute the significance of the ―competitiveness‖ clauses.
    Eaton maintains that Plaintiffs were free to win the OEMs‘
    business simply by offering a better product or a lower price,
    while Plaintiffs argue and presented testimony from OEM
    officials that, due to Eaton‘s status as a dominant supplier, the
    competitiveness clauses were effectively meaningless.
    3. Competition under the LTAs and
    Plaintiffs’ Exit from the Market
    After Eaton entered into its LTAs with the OEMs, ZF
    Meritor shifted its marketing focus from the OEM level to a
    strategy targeted at truck buyers. Also during this time
    period, both ZF Meritor and Eaton experienced quality and
    performance issues with their transmissions. For example,
    Eaton‘s Lightning transmission, which was an initial attempt
    by Eaton to compete with FreedomLine, was ―not perceived
    as a good [product]‖ and was ultimately taken off the market.
    ZF Meritor‘s FreedomLine and ―G Platform‖ transmissions
    required frequent repairs, and in 2002 and 2003, ZF Meritor
    faced millions of dollars in warranty claims.
    During the life of the LTAs, the OEMs worked with
    Eaton to develop a strategy to combat ZF Meritor‘s growth.
    On Eaton‘s urging, the OEMs imposed additional price
    penalties on customers that selected ZF Meritor products,
    ―force fed‖ Eaton products to customers, and sought to
    persuade truck fleets using ZF Meritor transmissions to shift
    to Eaton transmissions. At all times relevant to this case,
    Eaton‘s average prices were lower than Plaintiffs‘ average
    prices, and on several occasions, Plaintiffs declined to grant
    price concessions requested by OEMs. Although Eaton‘s
    12
    prices were generally lower than Plaintiffs‘ prices, Eaton
    never priced at a level below its costs.
    By 2003, ZF Meritor determined that it was limited by
    the LTAs to no more than 8% of the market, far less than the
    30% that it had projected at the beginning of the joint venture.
    ZF Meritor officials concluded that the company could not
    remain viable with a market share below 10% and therefore
    decided to dissolve the joint venture. After ZF Meritor‘s
    departure, Meritor remained a supplier of HD transmissions
    and became a sales agent for ZF AG to ensure continued
    customer access to the FreedomLine. However, Meritor‘s
    market share dropped to 4% by the end of fiscal year 2005,
    and Meritor exited the business in January 2007.
    B. Procedural History
    On October 5, 2006, Plaintiffs filed suit against Eaton
    in the U.S. District Court for the District of Delaware,
    alleging that Eaton used unlawful agreements in restraint of
    trade, in violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    ; acted unlawfully to maintain a monopoly, in violation of
    Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 2
    ; and entered into
    illegal restrictive dealing agreements, in violation of Section 3
    of the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 14
    . Specifically, Plaintiffs
    alleged that Eaton ―used its dominant position to induce all
    heavy duty truck manufacturers to enter into de facto
    exclusive dealing contracts with Eaton,‖ and that such
    agreements foreclosed Plaintiffs from over 90% of the market
    for HD transmission sales. Plaintiffs sought treble damages,
    pursuant to Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 15
    , and
    13
    injunctive relief, pursuant to Section 16 of the Clayton Act,
    
    15 U.S.C. § 26
    .
    On February 17, 2009, Plaintiffs‘ expert, Dr. David
    DeRamus (―DeRamus‖), submitted a report on both liability
    and damages. On May 11, 2009, Eaton filed a motion,
    pursuant to Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc.,
    
    509 U.S. 579
     (1993), to exclude DeRamus‘s testimony. The
    District Court ruled that DeRamus would be allowed to testify
    regarding liability, but excluded DeRamus‘s testimony on the
    issue of damages on the basis that his damages opinion failed
    the reliability requirements of Daubert and the Federal Rules
    of Evidence. ZF Meritor LLC v. Eaton Corp., 
    646 F. Supp. 2d 663
     (D. Del. 2009). Plaintiffs filed a motion for
    clarification, requesting that DeRamus be allowed to testify to
    alternate damages calculations based on other data in his
    expert report, or in the alternative, seeking permission for
    DeRamus to amend his expert report to present his alternate
    damages calculations. The District Court decided to defer
    resolution of the damages issue and bifurcate the case.
    The parties proceeded to trial on liability. On October
    8, 2009, after a four-week trial, the jury returned a complete
    verdict for Plaintiffs, finding that Eaton had violated Sections
    1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, and Section 3 of the Clayton Act.
    Following the verdict, Plaintiffs asked the District Court to
    set a damages trial, but no damages trial was set at that time.
    On October 30, 2009, Plaintiffs supplemented their earlier
    motion for clarification, incorporating additional arguments
    based on developments at trial.
    14
    On November 3, 2009, Eaton filed a renewed motion
    for judgment as a matter of law, or in the alternative, for a
    new trial. Eaton‘s principal argument was that Plaintiffs
    failed to establish that Eaton engaged in anticompetitive
    conduct because Plaintiffs did not show, nor did they attempt
    to show, that Eaton priced its transmissions below its costs.
    Sixteen months later, on March 10, 2011, the District Court
    denied Eaton‘s motion, reasoning that Eaton‘s prices were not
    dispositive, and that there was sufficient evidence for a jury to
    conclude that Eaton‘s conduct unlawfully foreclosed
    competition in a substantial portion of the HD transmissions
    market. ZF Meritor LLC v. Eaton Corp., 
    769 F. Supp. 2d 684
    (D. Del. 2011).
    On August 4, 2011, the District Court denied
    Plaintiffs‘ motion for clarification, and denied Plaintiffs‘
    request to allow DeRamus to amend his expert report to
    include alternate damages calculations. The same day, the
    District Court entered an order awarding Plaintiffs $0 in
    damages. On August 19, 2011, the District Court entered an
    injunction prohibiting Eaton from ―linking discounts and
    other benefits to market penetration targets,‖ but stayed the
    injunction pending appeal. Eaton filed a timely notice of
    appeal and Plaintiffs filed a timely cross-appeal.
    II. JURISDICTION AND STANDARD OF REVIEW
    The District Court had jurisdiction over this case
    pursuant to 
    28 U.S.C. §§ 1331
     and 1337. We have appellate
    jurisdiction under 
    28 U.S.C. § 1291
    .
    15
    We exercise plenary review over an order denying a
    motion for judgment as a matter of law. LePage’s Inc. v. 3M,
    
    324 F.3d 141
    , 145 (3d Cir. 2003) (en banc). A motion for
    judgment as a matter of law should be granted ―only if,
    viewing the evidence in the light most favorable to the
    nonmovant and giving it the advantage of every fair and
    reasonable inference, there is insufficient evidence from
    which a jury reasonably could find liability.‖ 
    Id. at 145-46
    (quoting Lightning Lube, Inc. v. Witco Corp., 
    4 F.3d 1153
    ,
    1166 (3d Cir. 1993)). We review questions of law underlying
    a jury verdict under a plenary standard of review. 
    Id.
     at 146
    (citing Bloom v. Consol. Rail Corp., 
    41 F.3d 911
    , 913 (3d Cir.
    1994)). Underlying legal questions aside, ―[a] jury verdict
    will not be overturned unless the record is critically deficient
    of that quantum of evidence from which a jury could have
    rationally reached its verdict.‖ Swineford v. Snyder Cnty., 
    15 F.3d 1258
    , 1265 (3d Cir. 1994).
    We review a district court‘s decision to exclude expert
    testimony for abuse of discretion. Montgomery Cnty. v.
    Microvote Corp., 
    320 F.3d 440
    , 445 (3d Cir. 2003). To the
    extent the district court‘s decision involved an interpretation
    of the Federal Rules of Evidence, our review is plenary.
    Elcock v. Kmart Corp., 
    233 F.3d 734
    , 745 (3d Cir. 2000). We
    also review a district court‘s decisions regarding discovery
    and case management for abuse of discretion. United States
    v. Schiff, 
    602 F.3d 152
    , 176 (3d Cir. 2010); In re Fine Paper
    Antitrust Litig., 
    685 F.2d 810
    , 817-18 (3d Cir. 1982).
    We review legal conclusions regarding standing de
    novo, and the underlying factual determinations for clear
    16
    error. Interfaith Cmty. Org. v. Honeywell Int’l, Inc., 
    399 F.3d 248
    , 253 (3d Cir. 2005).
    III. DISCUSSION
    A. Effect of the Price-Cost Test
    The most significant issue in this case is whether
    Plaintiffs‘ allegations under Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman
    Act and Section 3 of the Clayton Act are subject to the price-
    cost test or the ―rule of reason‖ applicable to exclusive
    dealing claims. Under the rule of reason, an exclusive
    dealing arrangement will be unlawful only if its ―probable
    effect‖ is to substantially lessen competition in the relevant
    market. Tampa Elec. Coal Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 
    365 U.S. 320
    , 327-29 (1961); United States v. Dentsply Int’l, 
    399 F.3d 181
    , 191 (3d Cir. 2005); Barr Labs., Inc. v. Abbott
    Labs., 
    978 F.2d 98
    , 110 (3d Cir. 1992). In contrast, under the
    price-cost test, to succeed on a challenge to the defendant‘s
    pricing practices, a plaintiff must prove ―that the
    [defendant‘s] prices are below an appropriate measure of [the
    defendant‘s] costs.‖       Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown &
    Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 222 (1993).9
    9
    Although Plaintiffs brought claims under three
    statutes (Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act and Section 3
    of the Clayton Act), our analysis regarding the applicability
    of the price-cost test is the same for all of Plaintiffs‘ claims.
    In order to establish an actionable antitrust violation, a
    plaintiff must show both that the defendant engaged in
    anticompetitive conduct and that the plaintiff suffered
    17
    antitrust injury as a result. Atl. Richfield Co. v. USA
    Petroleum Co., 
    495 U.S. 328
    , 339-40 (1990). Because a lack
    of anticompetitive conduct precludes a finding of antitrust
    injury, the key question for us is whether Eaton engaged in
    anticompetitive conduct. See 
    id. at 339
     (―Antitrust injury
    does not arise . . . until a private party is adversely affected by
    an anticompetitive aspect of the defendant‘s conduct.‖).
    Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act and Section 3 of
    the Clayton Act each include an anticompetitive conduct
    element, although each statute articulates that element in a
    slightly different way. Under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, a
    plaintiff must establish that the defendant was a party to a
    contract, combination or conspiracy that ―imposed an
    unreasonable restraint on trade.‖ 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    ; In re Ins.
    Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 
    618 F.3d 300
    , 314-15 (3d Cir.
    2010). Under Section 2, a plaintiff must demonstrate that the
    defendant willfully acquired or maintained its monopoly
    power in the relevant market. 
    15 U.S.C. § 2
    ; United States v.
    Grinnell Corp., 
    384 U.S. 564
    , 570-71 (1966). ―A monopolist
    willfully acquires or maintains monopoly power when it
    competes on some basis other than the merits.‖ LePage’s Inc.
    v. 3M, 
    324 F.3d 141
    , 147 (3d Cir. 2003) (en banc) (citing
    Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 
    472 U.S. 585
    , 605 n.32 (1985)). Finally, Section 3 of the Clayton Act
    makes it unlawful for a person to enter into an exclusive
    dealing contract where the effect of such an agreement is to
    substantially lessen competition or create a monopoly. 
    15 U.S.C. § 14
    .
    18
    Eaton urges us to apply the price-cost test, arguing that
    Plaintiffs failed to establish that Eaton engaged in
    anticompetitive conduct or that Plaintiffs suffered an antitrust
    injury because Plaintiffs did not prove—or even attempt to
    prove—that Eaton priced its transmissions below an
    appropriate measure of its costs. We decline to adopt Eaton‘s
    unduly narrow characterization of this case as a ―pricing
    practices‖ case, i.e., a case in which price is the clearly
    predominant mechanism of exclusion. Plaintiffs consistently
    argued that the LTAs, in their entirety, constituted de facto
    exclusive dealing contracts, which improperly foreclosed a
    substantial share of the market, and thereby harmed
    competition. Accordingly, as we will discuss below, we must
    evaluate the legality of Eaton‘s conduct under the rule of
    reason to determine whether the ―probable effect‖ of such
    conduct was to substantially lessen competition in the HD
    transmissions market in North America. Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 327-29
    . The price-cost test is not dispositive.
    1. Law of Exclusive Dealing
    Exclusive dealing claims may be brought under
    Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act and Section 3 of the
    Clayton Act. LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 157
    . Additionally, the
    Supreme Court has held that the price-cost test is not confined
    to any one antitrust statute, and applies to pricing practices
    claims under the Sherman Act, the Clayton Act, and the
    Robinson-Patman Act. Brooke Grp. Ltd. v. Brown &
    Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 222-23 (1993); Atl.
    Richfield, 
    495 U.S. at 339-40
    . Thus, regardless of which test
    applies, that test is applicable to each of Plaintiffs‘ claims.
    19
    An exclusive dealing arrangement is an agreement in
    which a buyer agrees to purchase certain goods or services
    only from a particular seller for a certain period of time.
    Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1800a, at 3 (3d ed.
    2011). The primary antitrust concern with exclusive dealing
    arrangements is that they may be used by a monopolist to
    strengthen its position, which may ultimately harm
    competition. Dentsply, 399 F.3d at 191. Generally, a
    prerequisite to any exclusive dealing claim is an agreement to
    deal exclusively. Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 326-27
    ; see
    Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 193-94
    ; Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at
    110 &
    n.24.10 An express exclusivity requirement, however, is not
    necessary, LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 157
    , because we look past
    the terms of the contract to ascertain the relationship between
    the parties and the effect of the agreement ―in the real world.‖
    Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 191, 194
    . Thus, de facto exclusive
    dealing claims are cognizable under the antitrust laws.
    LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 157
    .
    Exclusive dealing agreements are often entered into for
    entirely procompetitive reasons, and generally pose little
    threat to competition. Race Tires Am., Inc. v. Hoosier Racing
    10
    Evidence of an agreement is expressly required
    under Section 1 of the Sherman Act and Section 3 of the
    Clayton Act. See 
    15 U.S.C. §§ 1
     and 14. However, an
    agreement is not necessarily required under Section 2 of the
    Sherman Act, which can provide a vehicle for challenging a
    dominant firm‘s unilateral imposition of exclusive dealing on
    customers. See 
    15 U.S.C. § 2
    ; Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust
    Law ¶ 1821a, at 183 (3d ed. 2011).
    20
    Tire Corp., 
    614 F.3d 57
    , 76 (3d Cir. 2010) (―[I]t is widely
    recognized that in many circumstances, [exclusive dealing
    arrangements] may be highly efficient—to assure supply,
    price stability, outlets, investment, best efforts or the like—
    and pose no competitive threat at all.‖) (quoting E. Food
    Servs. v. Pontifical Catholic Univ. Servs. Ass’n, 
    357 F.3d 1
    , 8
    (1st Cir. 2004)). For example, ―[i]n the case of the buyer,
    they may assure supply, afford protection against rises in
    price, enable long-term planning on the basis of known costs,
    and obviate the expense and risk of storage in the quantity
    necessary for a commodity having a fluctuating demand.‖
    Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 
    337 U.S. 293
    , 306 (1949).
    From the seller‘s perspective, an exclusive dealing
    arrangement with customers may reduce expenses, provide
    protection against price fluctuations, and offer the possibility
    of a predictable market. 
    Id. at 306-07
    ; see also Ryko Mfg. Co.
    v. Eden Servs., 
    823 F.2d 1215
    , 1234 n.17 (8th Cir. 1987)
    (explaining that exclusive dealing contracts can help prevent
    dealer free-riding on manufacturer-supplied investments to
    promote rival‘s products). As such, competition to be an
    exclusive supplier may constitute ―a vital form of rivalry,‖
    which the antitrust laws should encourage. Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 83
     (quoting Menasha Corp. v. News Am. Mktg. In-
    Store, Inc., 
    354 F.3d 661
    , 663 (7th Cir. 2004)).
    However, ―[e]xclusive dealing can have adverse
    economic consequences by allowing one supplier of goods or
    services unreasonably to deprive other suppliers of a market
    for their goods[.]‖ Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v.
    Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    , 45 (1984) (O‘Connor, J., concurring),
    abrogated on other grounds by Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep.
    21
    Ink, Inc., 
    547 U.S. 28
     (2006); Barry Wright, 724 F.2d at 236
    (explaining that ―under certain circumstances[,] foreclosure
    might discourage sellers from entering, or seeking to sell in, a
    market at all, thereby reducing the amount of competition that
    would otherwise be available‖).            Exclusive dealing
    arrangements are of special concern when imposed by a
    monopolist. See Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 187
     (―Behavior that
    otherwise might comply with antitrust law may be
    impermissibly exclusionary when practiced by a
    monopolist.‖). For example:
    [S]uppose an established manufacturer has long
    held a dominant position but is starting to lose
    market share to an aggressive young rival. A
    set of strategically planned exclusive-dealing
    contracts may slow the rival‘s expansion by
    requiring it to develop alternative outlets for its
    product, or rely at least temporarily on inferior
    or more expensive outlets. Consumer injury
    results from the delay that the dominant firm
    imposes on the smaller rival‘s growth.
    Phillip Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1802c,
    at 64 (2d ed. 2002). In some cases, a dominant firm may be
    able to foreclose rival suppliers from a large enough portion
    of the market to deprive such rivals of the opportunity to
    achieve the minimum economies of scale necessary to
    compete. Id.; see LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 159
    .
    Due to the potentially procompetitive benefits of
    exclusive dealing agreements, their legality is judged under
    the rule of reason. Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 327
    . The
    22
    legality of an exclusive dealing arrangement depends on
    whether it will foreclose competition in such a substantial
    share of the relevant market so as to adversely affect
    competition. 
    Id. at 328
    ; Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at 110
    . In
    conducting this analysis, courts consider not only the
    percentage of the market foreclosed, but also take into
    account ―the restrictiveness and the economic usefulness of
    the challenged practice in relation to the business factors
    extant in the market.‖ Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at 110-11
    (quoting Am. Motor Inns, Inc. v. Holiday Inns, Inc., 
    521 F.2d 1230
    , 1251-52 n.75 (3d Cir. 1975)). As the Supreme Court
    has explained:
    [I]t is necessary to weigh the probable effect of
    the contract on the relevant area of effective
    competition, taking into account the relative
    strength of the parties, the proportionate volume
    of commerce involved in relation to the total
    volume of commerce in the relevant market
    area, and the probable immediate and future
    effects which pre-emption of that share of the
    market might have on effective competition
    therein.
    Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 329
    . In other words, an exclusive
    dealing arrangement is unlawful only if the ―probable effect‖
    of the arrangement is to substantially lessen competition,
    rather than merely disadvantage rivals. Id.; Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 191
     (―The test [for determining anticompetitive effect]
    is not total foreclosure, but whether the challenged practices
    bar a substantial number of rivals or severely restrict the
    market‘s ambit.‖).
    23
    There is no set formula for evaluating the legality of an
    exclusive dealing agreement, but modern antitrust law
    generally requires a showing of significant market power by
    the defendant, Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 329
    ; Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 74-75
    ; LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 158
    , substantial
    foreclosure, Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 327-28
    ; United States
    v. Microsoft Corp., 
    253 F.3d 34
    , 69 (D.C. Cir. 2001),
    contracts of sufficient duration to prevent meaningful
    competition by rivals, CDC Techs., Inc. v. IDEXX Labs., Inc.,
    
    186 F.3d 74
    , 81 (2d Cir. 1999); Omega Envtl., Inc. v.
    Gilbarco, Inc., 
    127 F.3d 1157
    , 1163 (9th Cir. 1997), and an
    analysis of likely or actual anticompetitive effects considered
    in light of any procompetitive effects, Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 75
    ; Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 194
    ; Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at 111
    .
    Courts will also consider whether there is evidence that the
    dominant firm engaged in coercive behavior, Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 77
    ; SmithKline Corp. v. Eli Lilly & Co., 
    575 F.2d 1056
    , 1062 (3d Cir. 1978), and the ability of customers to
    terminate the agreements, Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 193-94
    . The
    use of exclusive dealing by competitors of the defendant is
    also sometimes considered. Standard Oil, 
    337 U.S. at 309, 314
    ; NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Co., 
    507 F.3d 442
    , 454 (6th Cir.
    2007).
    2. Brooke Group and the Price-Cost test
    We turn now to some fundamental principles regarding
    predatory pricing claims and the price-cost test. ―Predatory
    pricing may be defined as pricing below an appropriate
    measure of cost for the purpose of eliminating competitors in
    the short run and reducing competition in the long run.‖
    Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colo., 
    479 U.S. 104
    , 117 (1986);
    24
    see Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    , 584 n.8 (1986); Advo, Inc. v. Phila. Newspapers,
    Inc., 
    51 F.3d 1191
    , 1198 (3d Cir. 1995). The Supreme Court
    has expressed deep skepticism of predatory pricing claims.
    See Cargill, 
    479 U.S. at
    121 n.17 (―Although the
    commentators disagree as to whether it is ever rational for a
    firm to engage in such conduct, it is plain that the obstacles to
    the successful execution of a strategy of predation are
    manifold, and that the disincentives to engage in such a
    strategy are accordingly numerous.‖) (citations omitted);
    Matsushita, 
    475 U.S. at 589
     (―[P]redatory pricing schemes
    are rarely tried, and even more rarely successful.‖) (citations
    omitted). In the typical predatory pricing scheme, a firm
    reduces the sale price of its product to below-cost, intending
    to drive competitors out of the business. Weyerhaeuser Co. v.
    Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 
    549 U.S. 312
    , 318
    (2007). Then, once competitors have been eliminated, the
    firm raises its prices to supracompetitive levels. 
    Id.
     For such
    a scheme to make economic sense, the firm must recoup the
    losses suffered during the below-cost phase in the
    supracompetitive phase. Id.; see Matsushita, 
    475 U.S. at 589
    (explaining that success under such a scheme is ―inherently
    uncertain‖ because the firm must sustain definite short-term
    losses, but the long-run gain depends on successfully
    eliminating competition).
    In Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco
    Corp., 
    509 U.S. at 222-24
    , the Supreme Court fashioned a
    two-part test that reflected this ―economic reality.‖
    Weyerhaeuser, 
    549 U.S. at 318
    . The Court held that, to
    succeed on a predatory pricing claim, the plaintiff must
    25
    prove: (1) ―that the prices complained of are below an
    appropriate measure of [the defendant‘s] costs‖; and (2) that
    the defendant had ―a dangerous probability . . . of recouping
    its investment in below-cost prices.‖ Brooke Grp., 509 U.S.
    at 222-24 (citations omitted). We are concerned only with the
    first requirement, which has become known as the price-cost
    test. In adopting the price-cost test, the Court rejected the
    notion that above-cost prices that are below general market
    levels or below the costs of a firm‘s competitors are
    actionable under the antitrust laws. Id. at 223. ―Low prices
    benefit consumers regardless of how those prices are set, and
    so long as they are above predatory levels [i.e., above-cost],
    they do not threaten competition.‖ Id. (quoting Atl. Richfield
    Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 
    495 U.S. 328
    , 340 (1990)). Low,
    but above-cost, prices are generally procompetitive because
    ―the exclusionary effect of prices above a relevant measure of
    cost [generally] reflects the lower cost structure of the alleged
    predator, and so represents competition on the merits[.]‖ Id.;
    see Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 488 (1977) (―The antitrust laws . . . were enacted for ‗the
    protection of competition, not competitors.‘‖) (quoting Brown
    Shoe Co. v. United States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 320 (1962)). The
    Court acknowledged that there may be situations in which
    above-cost prices are anticompetitive, but stated that it ―is
    beyond the practical ability of a judicial tribunal‖ to ascertain
    whether above-cost pricing is anticompetitive ―without
    courting intolerable risks of chilling legitimate price-cutting.‖
    Brooke Grp., 509 U.S. at 223 (citing Phillip Areeda &
    Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶¶ 714.2, 714.3 (Supp.
    2002)). ―To hold that the antitrust laws protect competitors
    from the loss of profits due to [above-cost] price competition
    26
    would, in effect, render illegal any decision by a firm to cut
    prices in order to increase market share. The antitrust laws
    require no such perverse result.‖ Id. (quoting Cargill, 
    479 U.S. at 116
    ). Significantly, because ―[c]utting prices in order
    to increase business often is the very essence of competition .
    . . , [i]n cases seeking to impose antitrust liability for prices
    that are too low, mistaken inferences are ‗especially costly,
    because they chill the very conduct that antitrust laws are
    designed to protect.‘‖ Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine
    Commc’ns, Inc., 
    555 U.S. 438
    , 451 (2009) (quoting
    Matsushita, 
    475 U.S. at 594
    ) (additional citations omitted).
    3. Effect of the Price-Cost Test on
    Plaintiffs’ Exclusive Dealing Claims
    Eaton argues that principles from the predatory pricing
    case law apply in this case because Plaintiffs‘ claims are, at
    their core, no more than objections to Eaton offering prices,
    through its rebate program, which Plaintiffs were unable to
    match. Eaton contends that Plaintiffs have identified nothing,
    other than Eaton‘s pricing practices, that incentivized the
    OEMs to enter into the LTAs, and because price was the
    incentive, we must apply the price-cost test.                We
    acknowledge that even if a plaintiff frames its claim as one of
    exclusive dealing, the price-cost test may be dispositive.
    Implicit in the Supreme Court‘s creation of the price-cost test
    was a balancing of the procompetitive justifications of above-
    cost pricing against its anticompetitive effects (as well as the
    anticompetitive effects of allowing judicial inquiry into
    above-cost pricing), and a conclusion that the balance always
    tips in favor of allowing above-cost pricing practices to stand.
    See linkLine, 
    555 U.S. at 451
    ; Brooke Grp., 509 U.S. at 223.
    27
    Thus, in the context of exclusive dealing, the price-cost test
    may be utilized as a specific application of the ―rule of
    reason‖ when the plaintiff alleges that price is the vehicle of
    exclusion. See, e.g., Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp.,
    
    207 F.3d 1039
    , 1060-63 (8th Cir. 2000).
    Here, Eaton argues that the price-cost test is
    dispositive, and therefore that Plaintiffs‘ claims must fail
    because Plaintiffs failed to show that the market-share rebates
    offered by Eaton pursuant to the LTAs resulted in below-cost
    prices. We do not disagree that predatory pricing principles,
    including the price-cost test, would control if this case
    presented solely a challenge to Eaton‘s pricing practices.11
    11
    Despite the arguments of amicus curiae, the
    American Antitrust Institute, our decision in LePage’s v. 3M
    does not indicate otherwise. In LePage’s, we declined to
    apply the price-cost test to a challenge to a bundled rebate
    scheme, reasoning that such a scheme was better analogized
    to unlawful tying than to predatory pricing. See 
    324 F.3d at 155
    . In that case, the plaintiff (LePage‘s) was the market
    leader in sales of ―private label‖ (store brand) transparent
    tape. 
    Id. at 144
    . As LePage‘s market share fell, it brought
    suit against 3M, alleging that 3M, which manufactured
    Scotch tape, some private label tape, and a number of other
    products, leveraged its monopoly power over Scotch brand
    tape and other products to monopolize the private label tape
    market. 
    Id. at 145
    . Specifically, LePage‘s challenged 3M‘s
    multi-tiered bundled rebate program, which offered
    progressively higher rebates when customers increased
    purchases across 3M‘s different product lines. 
    Id.
     The rebate
    28
    programs also set customer-specific target growth rates. 
    Id. at 154
    . The sizes of the rebates were linked to the number of
    product lines in which the targets were met; if a customer
    failed to meet the target for any one product, it would lose the
    rebates across all product lines. 
    Id.
     LePage‘s could not offer
    these discounts because it did not sell the same diverse array
    of products as 3M. 
    Id. at 155
    .
    Relying on Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson
    Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
     (1993), 3M argued that its
    bundled rebate program was lawful because the rebates never
    resulted in below-cost pricing. We disagreed, reasoning that
    the principal anticompetitive effect of 3M‘s bundled rebates
    was analogous to an unlawful tying arrangement: when
    offered by a monopolist, the rebates ―may foreclose portions
    of the market to a potential competitor who does not
    manufacture an equally diverse group of products and who
    therefore cannot make a comparable offer.‖ LePage’s, 324 at
    155.
    For several reasons, we interpret LePage’s narrowly.
    Most important, in light of the analogy drawn in LePage’s
    between bundled rebates and unlawful tying, which ―cannot
    exist unless two separate product markets have been linked,‖
    Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 
    466 U.S. 2
    , 21
    (1984), abrogated on other grounds by Ill. Tool Works Inc. v.
    Indep. Ink, Inc., 
    547 U.S. 28
     (2006), LePage’s is inapplicable
    where, as here, only one product is at issue and the plaintiffs
    have not made any allegations of bundling or tying. The
    reasoning of LePage’s is limited to cases in which a single-
    product producer is excluded through a bundled rebate
    29
    program offered by a producer of multiple products, which
    conditions the rebates on purchases across multiple different
    product lines. Accordingly, we join our sister circuits in
    holding that the price-cost test applies to market-share or
    volume rebates offered by suppliers within a single-product
    market. See NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Co., 
    507 F.3d 442
    , 452 (6th
    Cir. 2007); Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp., 
    207 F.3d 1039
    , 1061 (8th Cir. 2000); Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT
    Grinnell Corp., 
    724 F.2d 227
    , 236 (1st Cir. 1983).
    Additionally, several of the bases on which we
    distinguished Brooke Group have been undermined by
    intervening Supreme Court precedent, which counsels caution
    in extending LePage’s. For example, we indicated in
    LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 151
    , that Brooke Group might be
    confined to the Robinson-Patman Act, but the Supreme Court
    has made clear that the standard adopted in Brooke Group
    also applies to predatory pricing claims under the Sherman
    Act. Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber
    Co., 
    549 U.S. 312
    , 318 n.1 (2007). Additionally, LePage’s,
    
    324 F.3d at 151-52
    , suggested that Brooke Group is not
    applicable in cases involving monopolists, but the Supreme
    Court has since applied Brooke Group‘s price-cost test to
    claims against a monopolist, Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine
    Commc’ns, Inc., 
    555 U.S. 438
    , 447-48 (2009), and a
    monopsonist, Weyerhaeuser, 
    549 U.S. at 320-25
    . Finally, we
    observed in LePage’s that, in the years following Brooke
    Group, the Supreme Court had only cited the case four times
    (and for unrelated propositions), but since LePage’s, the
    Court has reaffirmed and extended Brooke Group. See
    30
    The lesson of the predatory pricing case law is that, generally,
    above-cost prices are not anticompetitive, and although there
    may be rare cases where above-cost prices are
    anticompetitive in the long run, it is ―beyond the practical
    ability‖ of courts to identify those rare cases without creating
    an impermissibly high risk of deterring legitimate
    procompetitive behavior (i.e., price-cutting). linkLine, 
    555 U.S. at 452
    ; Weyerhaeuser, 
    549 U.S. at 318-19
    ; Brooke Grp.,
    509 U.S. at 223. These principles extend to above-cost
    discounting or rebate programs, which condition the
    discounts or rebates on the customer‘s purchasing of a
    specified volume or a specified percentage of its requirements
    from the seller. See NicSand, 
    507 F.3d at 451-52
     (applying
    price-cost test to a challenge to up-front payments offered by
    a supplier to several large retailers on the basis that such
    payments were ―nothing more than ‗price reductions offered
    to the buyers for the exclusive right to supply a set of stores
    under multi-year contracts‘‖); Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1060-63
     (applying price-cost test to volume discounts and
    market-share discounts offered by a manufacturer); Barry
    Wright, 
    724 F.2d at 232
     (applying the price-cost test to
    uphold discounts linked to a requirements contract); see also
    linkLine, 
    555 U.S. at 447-48
    ; Weyerhaeuser, 
    549 U.S. at 325
    .
    In doing so, the Court emphasized the importance of Brooke
    Group in light of ―developments in economic theory and
    antitrust jurisprudence,‖ and downplayed the significance of
    seemingly inconsistent circuit court antitrust precedent from
    the 1950s and 1960s, some of which we referenced in
    LePage’s. See linkLine, 
    555 U.S. at
    452 n.3.
    31
    Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 79
     (―[I]t is no more an act of
    coercion, collusion, or [other anticompetitive conduct] for [a
    supplier] . . . to offer more money to [a customer] than it is
    for such [a] supplier[] to offer the lowest . . . prices.‖).
    Moreover, a plaintiff‘s characterization of its claim as
    an exclusive dealing claim does not take the price-cost test off
    the table. Indeed, contracts in which discounts are linked to
    purchase (volume or market share) targets are frequently
    challenged as de facto exclusive dealing arrangements on the
    grounds that the discounts induce customers to deal
    exclusively with the firm offering the rebates. Hovenkamp ¶
    1807a, at 132.        However, when price is the clearly
    predominant mechanism of exclusion, the price-cost test tells
    us that, so long as the price is above-cost, the procompetitive
    justifications for, and the benefits of, lowering prices far
    outweigh any potential anticompetitive effects. See Brooke
    Grp., 509 U.S. at 223; Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1062
    (noting that there is always a legitimate business justification
    for lowering prices: attempting to attract additional business).
    In each of the cases relied upon by Eaton, the Supreme
    Court applied the price-cost test, regardless of the way in
    which the plaintiff cast its grievance, because pricing itself
    operated as the exclusionary tool. For example, in Cargill,
    Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc., the plaintiff argued that a
    proposed merger between vertically integrated firms violated
    Section 7 of the Clayton Act because the result of the merger
    would have been to substantially lessen competition or create
    a monopoly. 
    479 U.S. at 114
    . The plaintiff offered, as a
    theory of antitrust injury, that it faced a threat of lost profits
    stemming from the possibility that the defendant, after the
    32
    merger, would lower its prices to a level at or above-cost. 
    Id. at 114-15
    . The plaintiff claimed that it would have to respond
    by lowering its prices, which would cause it to suffer a loss in
    profitability. 
    Id. at 115
    . The Supreme Court held that such a
    theory did not present a cognizable antitrust injury, reasoning
    that ―the antitrust laws do not require the courts to protect
    small businesses from the loss of profits due to continued
    [above-cost] competition.‖ 
    Id. at 116
    .
    Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co. involved
    an allegation that a vertical price-fixing agreement was
    unlawful under Section 1 of the Sherman Act. 
    495 U.S. at 331
    . In that case, the plaintiff was an independent retail
    marketer of gasoline, which bought gasoline from major
    petroleum companies for resale under its own name. 
    Id.
     The
    defendant was an integrated oil company, which sold directly
    to consumers through its own stations, and sold indirectly
    through brand dealers. 
    Id.
     Facing competition from
    independent marketers like the plaintiff, the defendant
    adopted a new marketing strategy, under which it encouraged
    its dealers to match the retail prices offered by independents
    by offering discounts and reducing the dealers‘ costs. 
    Id. at 331-32
    . The plaintiff brought suit under the Sherman Act,
    alleging that the defendant conspired with its dealers to sell
    gasoline at below-market levels. 
    Id. at 332
    . The district court
    granted summary judgment for the defendant on the basis that
    the plaintiff had not shown that the defendant engaged in
    predatory pricing, and thus had not shown any antitrust
    injury. 
    Id. at 333
    . The U.S. Court of Appeals for the Ninth
    Circuit reversed, USA Petroleum Co. v. Atl. Richfield Co.,
    
    859 F.2d 687
    , 693 (9th Cir. 1988), reasoning that a showing
    33
    of predatory pricing was not necessary to establish antitrust
    injury; rather, the antitrust laws were designed to ensure that
    market forces alone determine what goods and services are
    offered, and at what price they are sold, and thus, an antitrust
    injury could result from a disruption in the market. The
    Supreme Court disagreed, explaining that where a firm (or a
    group of firms) lowers prices pursuant to a vertical
    agreement, but maintains those prices above predatory levels,
    any business lost by rivals cannot be viewed as an
    anticompetitive consequence of the agreement. Atl. Richfield,
    
    495 U.S. at 337
    . ―A firm complaining about the harm it
    suffers from nonpredatory price competition is really
    claiming that it is unable to raise prices.‖ 
    Id. at 337-38
    .
    In Brooke Group, the plaintiff and the defendant were
    competitors in the cigarette market in the early 1980s. 509
    U.S. at 212. At that time, demand for cigarettes in the United
    States was declining and the plaintiff, once a major force in
    the industry, had seen its market share drop to 2%. Id. at 214.
    In response, the plaintiff developed a line of generic
    cigarettes, which were significantly cheaper than branded
    cigarettes. Id. The plaintiff promoted the generic cigarettes
    at the wholesale level by offering rebates that increased with
    the volume of cigarettes ordered. Id. Losing volume and
    profits on its branded products, the defendant entered the
    generic cigarette market. Id. at 215. At the retail level, the
    suggested price of the defendant‘s generic cigarettes was the
    same as that of the plaintiff‘s cigarettes, but the defendant‘s
    volume discounts to wholesalers were larger. Id. The
    plaintiff responded by increasing its wholesale rebates, and a
    price war ensued. Id. at 216. Subsequently, the plaintiff filed
    34
    a complaint against the defendant under the Robinson-Patman
    Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 13
    (a), alleging that the defendant‘s volume
    rebates amounted to unlawful price discrimination. 
    Id.
     The
    plaintiff explained that it would have been unable to reduce
    its wholesale rebates without losing substantial market share.
    
    Id.
     Accordingly, because the ―essence‖ of the plaintiff‘s
    claim was that its ―rival ha[d] priced its products in an unfair
    manner with an object to eliminate or retard competition and
    thereby gain and exercise control over prices in the relevant
    market,‖ the plaintiff had an obligation to show that the
    defendant‘s prices were below its costs. 
    Id. at 222
    .
    Here, in contrast to Cargill, Atlantic Richfield, and
    Brooke Group, Plaintiffs did not rely solely on the
    exclusionary effect of Eaton‘s prices, and instead highlighted
    a number of anticompetitive provisions in the LTAs.
    Plaintiffs alleged that Eaton used its position as a supplier of
    necessary products to persuade OEMs to enter into
    agreements imposing de facto purchase requirements of
    roughly 90% for at least five years, and that Eaton worked in
    concert with the OEMs to block customer access to Plaintiffs‘
    products, thereby ensuring that Plaintiffs would be unable to
    build enough market share to pose any threat to Eaton‘s
    monopoly. Therefore, because price itself was not the clearly
    predominant mechanism of exclusion, the price-cost test
    cases are inapposite, and the rule of reason is the proper
    framework within which to evaluate Plaintiffs‘ claims.
    We recognize that Eaton‘s rebates were part of
    Plaintiffs‘ case. DeRamus testified about the exclusionary
    effect of the rebates, OEM officials testified that Eaton
    offered lower prices, and Plaintiffs‘ counsel stated in oral
    35
    argument that part of the reason ZF Meritor could not
    increase sales above a certain level was that ―the OEMs were
    trying to hit those [share-penetration] targets to get their
    money from Eaton.‖           Eaton‘s post-rebate prices were
    attractive to the OEMs, and Eaton‘s low prices may, in fact,
    have been an inducement for the OEMs to enter into the
    LTAs. That fact is not irrelevant, as it may help explain why
    the OEMs agreed to otherwise unfavorable terms and it may
    help to rebut an argument that the agreements were
    inefficient. Hovenkamp ¶ 1807b, at 134. However, contrary
    to Eaton‘s assertions, that fact is not dispositive.
    Plaintiffs presented considerable evidence that Eaton
    was a monopolist in the industry and that it wielded its
    monopoly power to effectively force every direct purchaser of
    HD transmissions to enter into restrictive long-term
    agreements, despite the inclusion in such agreements of terms
    unfavorable to the OEMs and their customers. Significantly,
    there was considerable testimony that the OEMs did not want
    to remove ZF Meritor‘s transmissions from their data books,
    but that they were essentially forced to do so or risk financial
    penalties or supply shortages. Several OEM officials testified
    that exclusive data book listing was not a common practice in
    the industry and, in fact, it was probably detrimental to
    customers. An email between Freightliner employees stated:
    ―From a customer perspective, publishing [ZF Meritor‘s]
    product is probably the right thing to do and [it] should never
    have been taken out of the book. It is a good product with
    considerable demand in the marketplace.‖ The email went on
    to conclude, however, that including ZF Meritor‘s products
    would not be ―prudent‖ because it would jeopardize
    36
    Freightliner‘s relationship with Eaton. Eaton itself even
    acknowledged that the OEMs were dissatisfied. Internal
    Eaton correspondence reveals that PACCAR complained that
    the LTAs were preventing it from promoting a competitive
    product (FreedomLine), which was being demanded by truck
    buyers. In fact, PACCAR felt that Eaton was holding it
    ―hostage.‖
    Plaintiffs also introduced evidence that not only were
    the rebates conditioned on the OEMs meeting the market
    penetration targets, but so too was Eaton‘s continued
    compliance with the agreements. As one OEM executive
    testified, if the market penetration targets were not met, the
    OEMs ―would have a big risk of cancellation of the contract,
    price increases, and shortages if the market [was] difficult.‖
    Eaton was a monopolist in the HD transmissions market, and
    even if an OEM decided to forgo the rebates and purchase a
    significant portion of its requirements from another supplier,
    there would still have been a significant demand from truck
    buyers for Eaton products. Therefore, losing Eaton as a
    supplier was not an option.
    Accordingly, this is not a case in which the
    defendant‘s low price was the clear driving force behind the
    customer‘s compliance with purchase targets, and the
    customers were free to walk away if a competitor offered a
    better price. Compare Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1063
     (in
    deciding to apply price-cost test, noting that customers were
    free to walk away at any time and did so when the
    defendant‘s competitors offered better discounts), with
    Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 189-96
     (applying exclusive dealing
    analysis where the defendant threatened to refuse to continue
    37
    dealing with customers if customers purchased rival‘s
    products, and no customer could stay in business without the
    defendant‘s products). Rather, Plaintiffs introduced evidence
    that compliance with the market penetration targets was
    mandatory because failing to meet such targets would
    jeopardize the OEMs‘ relationships with the dominant
    manufacturer of transmissions in the market. See Dentsply,
    
    399 F.3d at 194
     (noting that ―[t]he paltry penetration in the
    market by competitors over the years has been a refutation
    of‖ the theory that a competitor could steal the defendant‘s
    customers by offering a better deal or a lower price ―by
    tangible and measurable results in the real world‖); 
    id. at 195
    (explaining that an exclusivity policy imposed by a dominant
    firm is especially troubling where it presents customers with
    an ―all-or-nothing‖ choice).
    Although the Supreme Court has created a safe harbor
    for above-cost discounting, it has not established a per se rule
    of non-liability under the antitrust laws for all contractual
    practices that involve above-cost pricing. See Cascade
    Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth, 
    515 F.3d 883
    , 901 (9th Cir.
    2007) (stating that the Supreme Court‘s predatory pricing
    decisions have not ―go[ne] so far as to hold that in every case
    in which a plaintiff challenges low prices as exclusionary
    conduct[,] the plaintiff must prove that those prices were
    below cost‖). Nothing in the case law suggests, nor would it
    be sound policy to hold, that above-cost prices render an
    otherwise unlawful exclusive dealing agreement lawful. We
    decline to impose such an unduly simplistic and mechanical
    rule because to do so would place a significant portion of
    38
    anticompetitive conduct outside the reach of the antitrust laws
    without adequate justification.
    ―[T]he means of illicit exclusion, like the means of
    legitimate competition, are myriad.‖ Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 58
    ; LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 152
     (―‗Anticompetitive conduct‘
    can come in too many different forms, and is too dependent
    on context, for any court or commentator ever to have
    enumerated all the varieties.‖) (quoting Caribbean Broad
    Sys., Ltd. v. Cable & Wireless PLC, 
    148 F.3d 1080
    , 1087
    (D.C. Cir. 1998)). The law has long recognized forms of
    exclusionary conduct that do not involve below-cost pricing,
    including unlawful tying, Jefferson Parish, 446 U.S. at 21;
    Standard Oil, 
    337 U.S. at 305-06
    , enforcement of a legal
    monopoly provided by a patent procured through fraud,
    LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at
    152 (citing Walker Process Equip., Inc.
    v. Food Mach. & Chem. Corp., 
    382 U.S. 172
    , 174 (1965)),
    refusal to deal, Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing
    Corp., 
    472 U.S. 585
    , 601-02 (1985); Otter Tail Power Co. v.
    United States, 
    410 U.S. 366
     (1973), exclusive dealing, Tampa
    Electric, 
    365 U.S. at 327
    ; Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 184
    , and
    other unfair tortious conduct targeting competitors, Conwood
    Co., L.P. v. U.S. Tobacco Co., 
    290 F.3d 768
     (6th Cir. 2002);
    Int’l Travel Arrangers, Inc. v. Western Airlines, Inc., 
    623 F.2d 1255
     (8th Cir. 1980).
    Despite Eaton‘s arguments to the contrary, we find
    nothing in the Supreme Court‘s recent predatory pricing
    decisions to indicate that the Court intended to overturn
    decades of other precedent holding that conduct that does not
    result in below-cost pricing may nevertheless be
    anticompetitive. Rather, as we explained above, Brooke
    39
    Group and the cases preceding it each involved an allegation
    that the defendant‘s pricing itself operated as the exclusionary
    tool. See Brooke Grp., 509 U.S. at 212-22; Atl. Richfield, 
    495 U.S. at 331-38
    ; Cargill, 409 U.S. at 114-16. Eaton places
    particular emphasis on two recent cases, arguing that such
    cases demonstrate the Supreme Court‘s willingness to extend
    the price-cost test beyond the traditional predatory pricing
    context. However, neither of these cases suggests that the
    price-cost test applies to the exclusive dealing claims at issue
    in our case.
    In Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood
    Lumber Co., 
    549 U.S. at 315, 320
    , the Supreme Court applied
    the price-cost test to a case involving an allegation of
    predatory bidding by a monopsonist.12 In a predatory bidding
    scheme, a purchaser of inputs bids up the market price of a
    critical input to such high levels that rival buyers cannot
    survive, and as a result acquires or maintains monopsony
    power. 
    Id.
     Then, ―if all goes as planned,‖ once rivals have
    been driven out, the predatory bidder will reap monopsonistic
    profits to offset the losses that it suffered during the high-
    bidding stage. 
    Id. at 321
    . Therefore, the Court explained,
    predatory pricing and predatory bidding claims are
    ―analytically similar.‖     
    Id.
       ―Both claims involve the
    12
    Monopsony power is market power on the buy (or
    input) side of the market. Weyerhaeuser, 
    549 U.S. at 320
    .
    ―As such, a monopsony is to the buy side of the market what
    a monopoly is to the sell side[.]‖ 
    Id.
     (citing Roger Blair &
    Jeffrey Harrison, Antitrust Policy and Monopsony, 
    76 Cornell L. Rev. 297
    , 301, 320 (1991)).
    40
    deliberate use of unilateral pricing measures for
    anticompetitive purposes.‖ 
    Id. at 322
    . Moreover, the Court
    noted, bidding up input prices, like lowering costs, is often
    ―the very essence of competition.‖ 
    Id.
     at 323 (citing Brooke
    Grp., 509 U.S. at 226). ―Just as sellers use output prices to
    compete for purchasers, buyers use bid prices to compete for
    scarce inputs. There are myriad legitimate reasons—ranging
    from benign to affirmatively procompetitive—why a buyer
    might bid up input prices.‖ Id. Furthermore, high bidding
    will often benefit consumers because it will likely lead to the
    firm‘s acquisition of more inputs, which will generally lead to
    the manufacture of more outputs, and an increase in outputs
    generally results in lower prices for consumers. Id. at 324.
    Accordingly, the Supreme Court adopted a variation of the
    price-cost test for allegations of predatory bidding: ―[a]
    plaintiff must prove that the alleged predatory bidding led to
    below-cost pricing of the predator‘s outputs.‖ Id. at 325. In
    other words, the firm‘s predatory bidding must have caused
    the cost of the relevant output to increase above the revenues
    generated by the sale of such output. Id.
    In Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. linkLine
    Communications, Inc., the Supreme Court relied, in part, on
    the price-cost test to hold that the plaintiffs‘ price-squeezing
    claim was not cognizable under the Sherman Act. 
    555 U.S. at 457
    . In that case, the plaintiffs alleged that the defendant, an
    integrated firm that sold inputs at wholesale and sold finished
    goods at retail, drove its competitors out of the market by
    raising the wholesale price while simultaneously lowering the
    retail price. 
    Id. at 442
    . The Court held that, pursuant to
    Verizon Communications Inc. v. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. at
    41
    409-10, the wholesale claim was not cognizable because the
    defendant had no antitrust duty to deal with its competitors at
    the wholesale level, and pursuant to Brooke Group, the retail
    claim was not cognizable because the defendant‘s retail prices
    were above cost. linkLine, 
    555 U.S. at 457
    . As to the retail
    claim, the Court explained that ―recognizing a price-squeeze
    claim where the defendant‘s retail price remains above cost
    would invite the precise harm‖ the price-cost test was
    designed to avoid: a firm might refrain from aggressive price
    competition to avoid potential antitrust liability. 
    Id.
     at 451-
    52. Recognizing that the plaintiffs were trying to combine
    two non-cognizable claims into a new form of antitrust
    liability, the Court explained that ―[t]wo wrong claims do not
    make one that is right.‖ 
    Id. at 457
    .
    Contrary to Eaton‘s argument, neither Weyerhaeuser
    nor linkLine stands for the proposition that the price-cost test
    applies here. Weyerhaeuser established the straightforward
    principle that the exercise of market power on prices for the
    purpose of driving out competitors should be judged by the
    same standard, whether such power is exercised on the input
    or output side of the market. See 
    549 U.S. at 321, 325
    . And
    linkLine did no more than hold that two antitrust theories
    cannot be combined to form a new theory of antitrust liability.
    See 
    555 U.S. at 457
    . The plaintiffs‘ retail-level claim in
    linkLine was a traditional pricing practices claim, and
    therefore indistinguishable from the pricing practices claims
    42
    in Brooke Group, Atlantic Richfield, and Cargill. 
    555 U.S. at 451-52, 457
    .13
    13
    Eaton also relies heavily on the Supreme Court‘s
    statement in Atlantic Richfield v. USA Petroleum Co. that
    price-cost principles apply ―regardless of the type of antitrust
    claim involved.‖ 
    495 U.S. at 340
    . When read in context,
    however, it is clear that this statement means that the price-
    cost test applies regardless of the statute under which a
    pricing practices claim is brought, not that the price-cost
    applies regardless of the type of anticompetitive conduct.
    In Atlantic Richfield, the plaintiffs argued that no
    showing of below-cost pricing was required to establish
    antitrust injury for a claim of illegal price-fixing under
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act because the price agreement
    itself was illegal, and any losses that stem from such an
    agreement, by definition, flow from that which makes the
    defendant‘s conduct unlawful. 
    Id. at 338
    . The Supreme
    Court rejected that argument, reasoning that although price-
    fixing is unlawful under Section 1, a plaintiff does not suffer
    antitrust injury unless it is adversely affected by an
    anticompetitive aspect of the defendant‘s conduct, and ―in the
    context of pricing practices, only predatory pricing has the
    requisite anticompetitive effect.‖ 
    Id.
     at 339 (citing Brunswick
    Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    , 487 (1977))
    (additional citations omitted). It was in this in context, in
    rejecting an argument that Section 1 was somehow exempt
    from the price-cost test, that the Supreme Court made the
    broad statement that it has ―adhered to . . . [price-cost]
    43
    In contrast to the price-cost test line of cases, here,
    Plaintiffs do not allege that price itself functioned as the
    exclusionary tool. As such, we conclude that the price-cost
    test is not adequate to judge the legality of Eaton‘s conduct.
    Although prices are unlikely to exclude equally efficient
    rivals unless they are below-cost, exclusive dealing
    arrangements can exclude equally efficient (or potentially
    equally efficient) rivals, and thereby harm competition,
    irrespective of below-cost pricing. See Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 191
    . Where, as here, a dominant supplier enters into de facto
    exclusive dealing arrangements with every customer in the
    principle[s] regardless of the type of antitrust claim
    involved.‖ See id. at 340.
    The Court‘s discussion following this statement
    supports our interpretation. The Court went on to explain
    that, for purposes of determining whether a plaintiff has
    suffered antitrust injury in a pricing practices case, Section 1
    is no different than, for example, the plaintiff‘s allegation in
    Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc. that the defendants‘
    unlawful merger under Section 7 of the Clayton Act caused
    antitrust injury. Id. at 340 (citing Cargill, 
    479 U.S. at 116
    )
    (―To be sure, the source of the price competition in the instant
    case was an agreement allegedly unlawful under § 1 of the
    Sherman Act rather than a merger in violation of § 7 of the
    Clayton Act. But that difference is not salient.‖). Moreover,
    Atlantic Richfield was decided before LePage’s and we did
    not interpret the ―regardless of the type of antitrust claim
    involved‖ language as mandating the application of the price-
    cost test to 3M‘s bundled rebates.
    44
    market, other firms may be driven out not because they
    cannot compete on a price basis, but because they are never
    given an opportunity to compete, despite their ability to offer
    products with significant customer demand. See id. at 191,
    194. Therefore, Eaton‘s attempt to characterize this case as a
    pricing practices case, subject to the price-cost test, is
    unavailing. We hold that, instead, the rule of reason from
    Tampa Electric and its progeny must be applied to evaluate
    Plaintiffs‘ claims.
    B. Proof of Anticompetitive
    Conduct and Antitrust Injury
    We turn now to Eaton‘s contention that even leaving
    aside the price-cost test, Plaintiffs failed to prove that Eaton‘s
    LTAs were anticompetitive or that they caused antitrust
    injury to Plaintiffs. The rule of reason governs Plaintiffs‘
    claims under Section 1 and Section 2 of the Sherman Act, and
    Section 3 of the Clayton Act. See LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at
    157
    & n.10 (explaining that exclusive dealing claims are
    cognizable under Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act and
    Section 3 of the Clayton Act, and evaluated under the same
    rule of reason); see also Section III.A, supra, at n.9. Under
    the rule of reason, an exclusive dealing arrangement is
    anticompetitive only if its ―probable effect‖ is to substantially
    lessen competition in the relevant market, rather than merely
    disadvantage rivals. Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 328-29
    .
    In addition to establishing a statutory violation, a
    plaintiff must demonstrate that it suffered antitrust injury.
    Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 75
    . To establish antitrust injury, the
    plaintiff must demonstrate: ―(1) harm of the type the antitrust
    45
    laws were intended to prevent; and (2) an injury to the
    plaintiff which flows from that which makes defendant‘s acts
    unlawful.‖ 
    Id. at 76
     (quoting Gulfstream III Assocs. Inc. v.
    Gulfstream Aerospace Corp., 
    995 F.2d 425
    , 429 (3d Cir.
    1993)) (additional citation omitted).
    Our inquiry on appeal has several components. First,
    we examine whether the LTAs could reasonably be viewed as
    exclusive dealing arrangements, despite the fact that the
    LTAs covered less than 100% of the OEMs‘ purchase
    requirements and contained no express exclusivity provisions.
    Second, because the unique characteristics of the HD
    transmissions market bear heavily on our inquiry, we review
    Eaton‘s monopoly power, the concentrated nature of the
    market, and the ability of a monopolist in Eaton‘s position to
    engage in coercive conduct.          Third, we discuss the
    anticompetitive effects of the various provisions in the LTAs,
    and consider Eaton‘s procompetitive justifications for the
    agreements.      Finally, we consider whether Plaintiffs
    established that they suffered antitrust injury as a result of
    Eaton‘s conduct.
    1. De Facto Partial Exclusive Dealing
    A threshold requirement for any exclusive dealing
    claim is necessarily the presence of exclusive dealing. Eaton
    argues that Plaintiffs‘ claims must fail because the LTAs were
    not ―true‖ exclusive dealing arrangements in that they did not
    contain express exclusivity requirements, nor did they cover
    100% of the OEMs‘ purchases. Neither contention is
    persuasive because de facto partial exclusive dealing
    46
    arrangements may, under certain circumstances, be actionable
    under the antitrust laws.14
    First, the law is clear that an express exclusivity
    requirement is not necessary because de facto exclusive
    dealing may be unlawful. Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 326
    ;
    Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 193
    ; LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 157
    . For
    example, in United States v. Dentsply International, Inc., we
    held that transactions which were ―technically only a series of
    independent sales‖ could form the basis for an exclusive
    dealing claim because the large share of the market held by
    the defendant and its conduct in excluding competitors,
    ―realistically made the arrangements . . . as effective as those
    in written contracts.‖ 399 F.3d at 193 (citing Monsanto Co. v.
    Spray-Rite Serv. Corp., 
    465 U.S. 752
    , 764 n.9 (1984)).
    Likewise, in LePage’s, we held that bundled rebates and
    discounts offered to major suppliers were designed to and did
    14
    Our dissenting colleague objects to the phrase ―de
    facto partial exclusive dealing‖ as constituting a creative
    neologism that ―distorts the English language‖ and
    infrequently appears in a search of an online legal database.
    Dissenting Op., Part II. ―De facto partial exclusive dealing‖
    is certainly a neologism, but it also accurately represents that
    an exclusive dealing claim does not require a contract that
    imposes an express exclusivity obligation, Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 326
    ; Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 193
    ; LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 157
    , nor a contract that covers 100% of the buyer‘s needs,
    Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 328
     (―[T]he competition foreclosed
    by the contract must be found to constitute a substantial share
    of the relevant market.‖) (emphasis added).
    47
    operate as exclusive dealing arrangements, despite the lack of
    any express exclusivity requirements. 
    324 F.3d at 157-58
    .
    Here, there was sufficient evidence from which a jury
    could infer that, although the LTAs did not expressly require
    the OEMs to meet the market penetration targets, the targets
    were as effective as mandatory purchase requirements. See
    Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 326
     (noting that ―even though a
    contract does ‗not contain specific agreements not to use the
    (goods) of a competitor,‘ if ‗the practical effect is to prevent
    such use,‘ it comes within the condition of [Section 3] as to
    exclusivity‖) (citing United Shoe Mach. Corp. v. United
    States, 
    258 U.S. 451
    , 457 (1922)); Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at
    193-
    94. Evidence presented at trial indicated that not only were
    lower prices (rebates) conditioned on the OEMs meeting the
    market-share targets, but so too was Eaton‘s continued
    compliance with the LTAs. For example, Eaton‘s LTAs with
    Freightliner, the largest OEM, and Volvo explicitly gave
    Eaton the right to terminate the agreements if the market-
    share targets were not met. And despite the fact that Eaton
    did not actually terminate the agreements on the rare occasion
    when an OEM failed to meet its target, the OEMs believed
    that it might.15 Critically, due to Eaton‘s position as the
    dominant supplier, no OEM could satisfy customer demand
    without at least some Eaton products, and therefore no OEM
    could afford to lose Eaton as a supplier. Accordingly, we
    agree with the District Court that a jury could have concluded
    15
    In 2003, for example, PACCAR failed to meet its
    market penetration target, and although Eaton withdrew all
    contractual savings, it did not terminate the agreement.
    48
    that, under the circumstances, the market penetration targets
    were as effective as express purchase requirements ―because
    no risk averse business would jeopardize its relationship with
    the largest manufacturer of transmissions in the market.‖ ZF
    Meritor, 
    769 F. Supp. 2d at 692
    .
    Second, an agreement does not need to be 100%
    exclusive in order to meet the legal requirements of exclusive
    dealing. We acknowledge that ―partial‖ exclusive dealing is
    rarely a valid antitrust theory. See Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at
    110 n.24 (―An agreement affecting less than all purchases
    does not amount to true exclusive dealing.‖) (citation
    omitted); Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1044, 1062-63
     (noting
    that the defendant‘s discount program, which conditioned
    incremental discounts on customers purchasing 60-80% of
    their needs from the defendant, did not constitute exclusive
    dealing because customers were not required to purchase all
    of their requirements from the defendant, and in fact, could
    purchase up to 40% of their requirements from other sellers
    without foregoing the discounts); Magnus Petroleum Co. v.
    Skelly Oil Co., 
    599 F.2d 196
    , 200-01 (7th Cir. 1979) (holding
    that contract requiring buyer to purchase a fixed quantity of
    goods that amounted to roughly 60-80% of its needs was not
    unlawful ―[b]ecause the agreements contained no exclusive
    dealing clause and did not require [the buyer] to purchase any
    amounts of [the defendant‘s product] that even approached
    [its] requirements‖) (citations omitted). Partial exclusive
    dealing agreements such as partial requirements contracts and
    contracts stipulating a fixed dollar or quantity amount are
    generally lawful because market foreclosure is only partial,
    and competing sellers are not prevented from selling to the
    49
    buyer. See Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1062-63
    ; Magnus
    Petroleum, 
    599 F.2d at 200-01
    .
    However, we decline to adopt Eaton‘s view that a
    requirements contract covering less than 100% of the buyer‘s
    needs can never be an unlawful exclusive dealing
    arrangement. See Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 466-67
    (―Legal presumptions that rest on formalistic distinctions
    rather than actual market realities are generally disfavored in
    antitrust law.‖). ―Antitrust analysis must always be attuned to
    the particular structure and circumstances of the industry at
    issue.‖ Verizon Commc’ns, 540 U.S. at 411. Therefore, just
    as ―total foreclosure‖ is not required for an exclusive dealing
    arrangement to be unlawful, nor is complete exclusivity
    required with each customer. See Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 191
    .
    The legality of such an arrangement ultimately depends on
    whether the agreement foreclosed a substantial share of the
    relevant market such that competition was harmed. Tampa
    Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 326-28
    .
    In our case, although the market-share targets covered
    less than 100% of the OEMs‘ needs, a jury could nevertheless
    find that the LTAs unlawfully foreclosed competition in a
    substantial share of the HD transmissions market. See 
    id.
    There are only four direct purchasers of HD transmissions in
    North America, and Eaton, long the dominant supplier in the
    industry, entered into long-term agreements with each of
    them. Compare Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1044
     (noting the
    defendant was the market leader, but there were at least ten
    other competing manufacturers). Each LTA imposed a
    market-penetration target of roughly 90% (with the exception
    of Volvo, which manufactured some of its own transmissions
    50
    for use in its own trucks), which we explained above, could
    be viewed as a requirement that the OEM purchase that
    percentage of its requirements from Eaton. Although no
    agreement was completely exclusive, the foreclosure that
    resulted was no different than it would be in a market with
    many customers where a dominant supplier enters into
    complete exclusive dealing arrangements with 90% of the
    customer base. Under such circumstances, the lack of
    complete exclusivity in each contract does not preclude
    Plaintiffs‘ de facto exclusive dealing claim.16
    2. Market Conditions in HD Transmissions Market
    Exclusive dealing will generally only be unlawful
    where the market is highly concentrated, the defendant
    possesses significant market power, and there is some
    element of coercion present. See Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 329
    ; Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 77-78
    ; LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 159
    . For example, if the defendant occupies a dominant
    position in the market, its exclusive dealing arrangements
    invariably have the power to exclude rivals. Tampa Elec.,
    
    365 U.S. at 329
    ; Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 187
    . Here, the jury
    16
    Additionally, the District Court instructed the jury
    that Plaintiffs did not allege ―actual‖ exclusive dealing, but
    instead alleged that ―the long-term supply contracts with
    defendant, in effect, committed the OEMs to purchase at least
    a substantial share of their transmissions from defendant.‖
    The District Court defined such an arrangement as a ―‗de
    facto‘ exclusive dealing contract.‖ Eaton does not challenge
    this instruction on appeal.
    51
    found that Eaton possessed monopoly power in the HD
    transmissions market, and Eaton does not contest that finding
    on appeal.
    A hard look at the nature of the market in which the
    parties compete is equally important. Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 329
    . An exclusive dealing arrangement is most likely to
    present a threat to competition in a situation in which the
    market is highly concentrated, such that long-term contracts
    operate to ―foreclose so large a percentage of the available
    supply or outlets that entry‖ or continued operation in ―the
    concentrated market is unreasonably constricted.‖ Race
    Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 76
     (quoting E. Food Servs., 
    357 F.3d at 8
    );
    see Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 184
     (noting that the relevant market
    was ―marked by a low or no-growth potential‖ and the
    defendant had long dominated the industry with a 75-80%
    market share). Here, the HD transmissions market had long
    been dominated by Eaton. Except for Meritor‘s production of
    manual transmissions in the 1990s and the ZF Meritor joint
    venture, no significant external supplier has entered the
    market for the last twenty years. A jury could certainly infer
    that Eaton‘s dominance over the OEMs created a barrier to
    entry that any potential rival manufacturer would have to
    confront. See Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1059
     (―If entry
    barriers to new firms are not significant, it may be difficult
    for even a monopoly company to control prices through some
    type of exclusive dealing arrangement because a new firm or
    firms easily can enter the market to challenge it [but] [i]f
    there are significant entry barriers . . . , a potential competitor
    would have difficulty entering.‖) (citations omitted). The
    record shows that the barriers to entry in the North American
    52
    HD transmission market are especially high:                 HD
    transmissions are expensive to produce; transmissions
    developed for other geographic markets must be substantially
    modified for the North American market; and all HD
    transmission sales must pass through the highly concentrated
    intermediate market in which the OEMs operate. Eaton‘s
    theory that ZF Meritor or any new HD transmissions
    manufacturer would be able to ―steal‖ an Eaton customer by
    offering a superior product at a lower price ―simply has not
    proved to be realistic.‖ Dentsply, 399 F.3d at 194 (citation
    omitted); compare NicSand, 
    507 F.3d at 454
     (in finding
    exclusive dealing arrangements lawful, noting that the
    plaintiff was the market leader, and lost business due to a new
    entrant‘s competition). ―The paltry penetration in the market
    by competitors over the years has been a refutation of
    [Eaton‘s] theory by tangible and measurable results in the real
    world.‖ Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 194
    ; see Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 55
     (noting importance of significant barriers to entry in
    maintaining monopoly power, in spite of the plaintiffs‘ self-
    imposed problems).
    Although we generally ―assume that a customer will
    make [its] decision only on the merits,‖ Santana Prods., Inc.
    v. Bobrick Washroom Equip., Inc., 
    401 F.3d 123
    , 133 (3d Cir.
    2005) (quoting Stearns Airport Equip. Co. v. FMC Corp., 
    170 F.3d 518
    , 524-25 (5th Cir. 1999)), a monopolist may use its
    power to break the competitive mechanism and deprive
    customers of the ability to make a meaningful choice. See
    Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 77
     (noting that coercion ―has played a
    key, if sometimes unexplored, role‖ in antitrust law);
    Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 184
     (observing that the defendant
    53
    ―imposed‖ an exclusivity policy on its customers); LePage’s,
    
    324 F.3d at 159
     (explaining that because 3M occupied a
    dominant position in several different product markets, it was
    able to effectively force customers in the ―private label‖ tape
    market to deal with 3M exclusively, despite the plaintiff‘s
    competitiveness in that market). A highly concentrated
    market, in which there is one (or a few) dominant supplier(s),
    creates the possibility for such coercion. And here, there was
    evidence that Eaton leveraged its position as a supplier of
    necessary products to coerce the OEMs into entering into the
    LTAs. Plaintiffs presented testimony from OEM officials
    that many of the terms of the LTAs were unfavorable to the
    OEMs and their customers, but that the OEMs agreed to such
    terms because without Eaton‘s transmissions, the OEMs
    would be unable to satisfy customer demand.17
    17
    Eaton emphasizes that the OEMs are multi-billion
    dollar companies (or at least owned by multi-billion dollar
    parent companies), and therefore claims that the OEMs
    dictated terms to Eaton – not the other way around.
    Significantly, in United States v. Dentsply International, Inc.,
    we found coercion even though the relationship between the
    customers and the defendant was not totally one-sided. 
    399 F.3d 181
    , 185 (3d Cir. 2005) (noting that the defendant
    considered bypassing dealers and selling directly to customers
    but abandoned that strategy out of fear that dealers might
    retaliate by refusing to buy other products manufactured by
    the defendant). Moreover, even assuming that the evidence
    could support a conclusion that the OEMs had more power in
    the relationship, the fact that two reasonable conclusions
    54
    Accordingly, this case involves precisely the
    combination of factors that we explained would be present in
    the rare case in which exclusive dealing would pose a threat
    to competition. See Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 76
    .
    3. Sufficiency of the Evidence: Anticompetitive Conduct
    We turn now to a discussion of whether there was
    sufficient evidence for a jury to conclude that Eaton engaged
    in anticompetitive conduct. Our inquiry in a sufficiency of
    the evidence challenge is limited to determining whether,
    ―viewing the evidence in the light most favorable to the
    [winner at trial] and giving it the advantage of every fair and
    reasonable inference, there is insufficient evidence from
    which a jury reasonably could find liability.‖ Lightning Lube,
    Inc. v. Witco Corp., 
    4 F.3d 1153
    , 1166 (3d Cir. 1993)
    (citation omitted).      Eaton argues that even under the
    extraordinarily deferential standard, there was insufficient
    evidence for a reasonable jury to conclude that Eaton engaged
    in conduct that harmed competition. Guided by the principles
    set forth in Section III.A.1, supra, we disagree.
    i. Extent of Foreclosure
    First, the extent of the market foreclosure in this case
    was significant. ―The share of the market foreclosed is
    important because, for the contract to have an adverse effect
    upon competition, ‗the opportunities for other[s] . . . to enter
    could be drawn from the evidence does not make the jury‘s
    adoption of Plaintiffs‘ view unreasonable.
    55
    into or remain in that market must be significantly limited.‘‖
    Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at
    69 (citing Tampa Elec., 
    365 U.S. at 328
    ). Substantial foreclosure allows the dominant firm to
    prevent potential rivals from ever reaching ―the critical level
    necessary‖ to pose a real threat to the defendant‘s business.
    Dentsply, 339 F.3d at 191. Here, Eaton entered into long-
    term agreements with every direct purchaser in the market,
    and under each agreement, imposed what could be viewed as
    mandatory purchase requirements of at least 80%, and up to
    97.5%. The OEMs generally met these targets, which, as
    Plaintiffs‘ expert testified, resulted in approximately 15% of
    the market remaining open to Eaton‘s competitors by 2003.18
    See LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 159
     (noting that foreclosure of
    40% to 50% is usually required to establish an exclusive
    18
    ZF Meritor‘s expert, Dr. David DeRamus, testified
    at trial that Eaton‘s market share was consistently above 80%
    from 2000 through 2007. Later in his testimony, DeRamus
    concluded that Eaton‘s increased market share from 2000 to
    2007 was the result of the LTAs. Furthermore, DeRamus
    showed that ZF Meritor‘s market share percentages in the
    linehaul transmissions market (i.e., the only portion of the
    overall HD transmissions market in which ZF Meritor
    competed), dropped from 32% to 24% between 2000 and
    2002, and dropped even further from 24% to 12% between
    2002 and 2003, before ultimately falling to 0% in 2007.
    DeRamus concluded that the loss of ZF Meritor‘s linehaul
    transmissions market share and its eventual exit from the
    market were due to Eaton‘s conduct and, specifically, the
    LTAs.
    56
    dealing violation under Section 1 of the Sherman Act (citing
    Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 70
    )). From 2000 through 2003,
    Plaintiffs‘ overall market share ranged from 8-14%, and by
    2005, Plaintiffs‘ market share had dropped to 4%.
    ii. Duration of LTAs
    Second, the LTAs were not short-term agreements,
    which would present little threat to competition. See, e.g.,
    Christofferson Dairy, Inc. v. MMM Sales, Inc., 
    849 F.2d 1168
    , 1173 (9th Cir. 1988) (upholding exclusive dealing
    arrangement of ―short duration‖); Roland Mach. Co. v.
    Dresser Indus., Inc., 
    749 F.2d 380
    , 395 (7th Cir. 1984)
    (noting that exclusive dealing contracts of less than one year
    are presumptively lawful); Barry Wright, 
    724 F.2d at
    237
    (citing two-year term in upholding requirements contract).
    Rather, each LTA was for a term of at least five years, and the
    PACCAR LTA was for a seven-year term.19 See FTC v.
    Motion Picture Adver. Serv. Co., 
    344 U.S. 392
    , 393-96
    (1953) (upholding contracts of one year or less, but
    condemning contract terms ranging from two to five years).
    Although long exclusive dealing contracts are not per se
    unlawful, ―[t]he significance of any particular contract
    duration is a function of both the number of such contracts
    and market share covered by the exclusive-dealing contracts.‖
    Hovenkamp ¶ 1802g, at 98. Here, Eaton entered into long-
    term contracts with every direct purchaser in the market,
    which locked up over 85% of the market for at least five
    19
    Eaton and Freightliner revised their original LTA to
    increase the duration to ten years.
    57
    years. Although long-term agreements had previously been
    used in the HD transmissions industry, it was unprecedented
    for a supplier to enter into contracts of such duration with the
    entire customer base.
    Eaton acknowledges, as it must, the unprecedented
    length of the LTAs, but maintains that the LTAs were not
    anticompetitive because they were easily terminable. See,
    e.g., PepsiCo, Inc. v. Coca-Cola Co., 
    315 F.3d 101
    , 111 (2d
    Cir. 2002) (finding challenged contracts lawful, in part,
    because they were terminable at will); Omega Envtl., 
    127 F.3d at 1164
     (noting easy terminability of agreements). Each
    LTA included a ―competitiveness‖ clause, which permitted
    the OEM to purchase from another supplier or terminate the
    agreement if another supplier offered a better product or a
    lower price. However, Plaintiffs presented evidence that any
    language giving OEMs the right to terminate the agreements
    was essentially meaningless because Eaton had assured that
    there would be no other supplier that could fulfill the OEMs‘
    needs or offer a lower price. Thus, a jury could very well
    conclude that ―in spite of the legal ease with which the
    relationship c[ould] be terminated,‖ the OEMs had a strong
    economic incentive to adhere to the terms of the LTAs, and
    therefore were not free to walk away from the agreements and
    purchase products from the supplier of their choice.
    Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 194
    .
    iii. Additional Anticompetitive Provisions in LTAs
    Third, the LTAs were replete with provisions that a
    reasonable jury could find anticompetitive. To begin, a jury
    could have found that the data book provisions were
    58
    anticompetitive in that they limited the ability of ZF Meritor
    to effectively market its products, and limited the ability of
    truck buyers to choose from a full menu of available
    transmissions. See 
    id.
     (discussing anticompetitive effect of
    limitations on customer choice). Eaton downplays the
    significance of the data book provisions, arguing that truck
    buyers always remained free to request unlisted
    transmissions, and ZF Meritor remained free to market
    directly to truck buyers. However, the mere existence of
    potential alternative avenues of distribution, without ―an
    assessment of their overall significance to the market,‖ is
    insufficient to demonstrate that Plaintiffs‘ opportunities to
    compete were not foreclosed. 
    Id. at 196
    . An OEM‘s data
    book was the ―most important tool‖ that any buyer selecting
    component parts for a truck would use. If a product was not
    listed in a data book, it was ―a disaster for the supplier.‖
    Although truck buyers could request unpublished
    components, doing so involved additional transaction costs,
    and in practice, meant that truck buyers were far more likely
    to select a product listed in the data book. See 
    id. at 193
    (explaining that the key question was not whether alternative
    distribution methods allowed a competitor to ―survive‖ but
    whether the alternative methods would ―pose[] a real threat‖
    to the defendant‘s monopoly) (citing Microsoft, 
    253 F.3d at 71
    ). Additionally, prior to the LTAs, it was not common
    practice for one supplier to be given exclusive data book
    listing. Historically, data books had included all product
    offerings, including Meritor transmissions, and the OEMs
    acknowledged that removing ZF Meritor products, especially
    FreedomLine, from the data books was ―from a customer
    perspective,‖ the wrong thing to do so because they were
    59
    ―good product[s]      with   considerable    demand     in   the
    marketplace.‖
    A jury could also have found that the ―preferential
    pricing‖ provisions in the LTAs were anticompetitive.
    Although it was ―common‖ for price savings to be passed
    down to truck buyers in the form of lower prices, and there
    are indications that at least some of the savings from Eaton
    transmissions were indeed passed down, there is also
    evidence that the preferential prices were achieved by
    artificially increasing the prices of Plaintiffs‘ products.
    Additionally, the jury could have determined that the
    ―competitiveness‖ clauses were of little practical import
    because Eaton‘s conduct ensured that no rival would be able
    to offer a comparable deal. There was also evidence that the
    competitiveness clauses were met with stiff resistance by
    Eaton.
    iv. Anticompetitive Effects vs. Procompetitive Effects
    Finally, the only procompetitive justification offered
    by Eaton on appeal is that the LTAs were crafted to meet
    customer demand to reduce prices, as well as engineering and
    support costs. See Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at 111
     (explaining
    that courts must ―evaluate the restrictiveness and the
    economic usefulness of the challenged practice in relation to
    the business factors extant in the market‖) (citations omitted).
    In response to the economic downturn in the heavy-duty
    trucking industry in the late 1990s and early 2000s, each
    OEM sought to negotiate lower prices, and some sought to
    reduce the number of suppliers. During this time, oversupply
    60
    was a problem, as were low truck prices, and an
    unavailability of drivers. It appears that Eaton responded
    well to the downturn; despite persistent quality control
    problems and a relatively late introduction of two-pedal
    automated mechanical transmissions, the company cut costs
    and increased market share.
    However, no OEM ever asked Eaton to be a sole
    supplier, and there was considerable testimony from OEM
    officials that it was in an OEM‘s interest to have multiple
    suppliers. Although long-term agreements offering market-
    share or volume discounts had been used in the industry in the
    past (for transmissions and for other truck components), OEM
    executives consistently testified that Eaton‘s new LTAs
    represented a substantial departure from past practice. For
    example, the longest supply agreements Freightliner and
    Volvo had ever signed previously were for two-year terms.
    Likewise, OEM officials testified that the provisions in the
    LTAs requiring exclusive data book listing and ―preferential
    pricing‖ were not common. Critically, there was considerable
    evidence from which a jury could infer that the primary
    purpose of the LTAs was not to meet customer demand, but
    to take preemptive steps to block potential competition from
    the new ZF Meritor joint venture. Eaton devised the
    unprecedented LTAs only after Meritor formed the joint
    venture with ZF AG, which Eaton viewed as a ―serious
    competitor.‖ Eaton feared that the ZF Meritor joint venture
    would put Eaton‘s ―[North American] position at risk‖ by
    introducing a new product (FreedomLine) for which there
    was significant customer demand, but for which Eaton did not
    produce a comparable alternative.
    61
    In sum, the LTAs included numerous provisions
    raising anticompetitive concerns and there was evidence that
    Eaton sought to aggressively enforce the agreements, even
    when OEMs voiced objections.20 Accordingly, we hold that
    there was more than sufficient evidence for a jury to conclude
    that the cumulative effect of Eaton‘s conduct was to adversely
    affect competition.21
    20
    Judge Greenberg, in dissent, objects that our rule of
    reason analysis fails to consider that Eaton‘s prices were
    above cost. Dissenting Op., Part II. However, contrary to
    this objection, and even though ZF Meritor does not contend
    that Eaton‘s prices operated as an exclusionary tool, we do
    not view Eaton‘s prices as irrelevant to the rule of reason
    analysis. Rather than analyzing the alleged exclusionary
    provisions in a vacuum, we analyze these provisions in the
    larger context of the LTAs as a whole, and we recognize that
    Eaton maintained above-cost prices. We conclude that ZF
    Meritor presented sufficient evidence for the jury to find that,
    even though not every provision was exclusionary, the LTAs
    as a whole functioned as exclusive dealing agreements that
    adversely affected competition.
    21
    It is worth noting that despite Eaton‘s contention
    that Plaintiffs‘ higher prices and quality problems led to their
    decline in market share, the OEMs felt differently. In 2002, a
    Freightliner executive wrote: ―[t]his is a dangerous situation.
    We have already killed Meritor‘s transmission business. It is
    just a matter of time before they close their doors.‖ Likewise,
    a 2006 Volvo presentation states: ―With all its OEM
    customers, Eaton has established long term supply contracts
    62
    4. Sufficiency of the Evidence: Antitrust Injury
    Having concluded that there was sufficient evidence
    from which a jury could determine that the LTAs functioned
    as unlawful exclusive dealing agreements, we have no
    difficulty concluding that there was likewise sufficient
    evidence that Plaintiffs suffered antitrust injury. See Atl.
    Richfield, 
    495 U.S. at 344
     (explaining that a plaintiff suffers
    antitrust injury if its injury ―stems from a competition-
    reducing aspect or effect of the defendant‘s behavior‖).
    Eaton‘s conduct unlawfully foreclosed a substantial share of
    the HD transmissions market, which would otherwise have
    been available for rivals, including Plaintiffs. ZF Meritor
    exited the market in 2003, followed by Meritor in 2006,
    because they could not maintain high enough market shares to
    remain viable. A jury could certainly conclude that Plaintiffs‘
    inability to grow was a direct result of Eaton‘s exclusionary
    conduct.
    C. Expert Testimony
    1. Expert Testimony on Liability
    Eaton raises two challenges to the District Court‘s
    decision to admit DeRamus‘s testimony on liability. First,
    Eaton argues that DeRamus failed to employ any recognized
    or reliable economic test for determining whether Eaton‘s
    . . . [which] ha[ve] led to . . . Eaton‘s only North American
    competitor, Meritor, [being] gradually marginalized to its
    current market position with a 10% market share.‖
    63
    conduct harmed competition and caused antitrust injury.
    Second, Eaton contends that DeRamus‘s opinion was
    contradicted by the facts.   We disagree with both
    22
    contentions.
    Federal Rule of Evidence 702 provides:
    A witness who is qualified as an expert by
    knowledge, skill, experience, training, or
    education may testify in the form of an opinion
    or otherwise if: (a) the expert‘s scientific,
    technical, or other specialized knowledge will
    help the trier of fact to understand the evidence
    or to determine a fact in issue; (b) the testimony
    is based on sufficient facts or data; (c) the
    testimony is the product of reliable principles
    and methods; and (d) the expert has reliably
    applied the principles and methods to the facts
    of the case.
    Under Rule 702, the district court acts as a ―gatekeeper‖ to
    ensure that ―the expert‘s opinion [is] based on the methods
    and procedures of science rather than on subjective belief or
    unsupported speculation.‖ Calhoun v. Yamaha Motor Corp.,
    U.S.A., 
    350 F.3d 316
    , 321 (3d Cir. 2003) (quoting In re Paoli
    R.R. Yard PCB Litig. (Paoli II), 
    35 F.3d 717
    , 741 (3d Cir.
    22
    Eaton also argues that DeRamus‘s testimony was
    contrary to law because he did not employ a price-cost test.
    However, as we explained above, no price-cost test was
    required in this case.
    64
    1994)). Here, as the District Court noted, DeRamus relied on
    the exclusionary nature of the LTAs to form his opinion. He
    defined the relevant market, determined whether Eaton has
    monopoly power, and engaged in an analysis of Eaton‘s
    conduct, taking into account market conditions and the extent
    of the exclusive dealing. He examined the effect of the LTAs
    on prices and consumer choice, and considered whether
    foreclosure of the market could be attributed to factors other
    than the LTAs, such as market conditions or quality issues
    with Plaintiffs‘ products. We find no error in the District
    Court‘s acceptance of DeRamus‘s methodologies as reliable
    under Rule 702. See LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 154-64
     (analyzing
    exclusive dealing by looking to many of the same factors
    considered by DeRamus).
    Eaton also argues that DeRamus‘s opinion was
    contradicted by the facts. ―When an expert opinion is not
    supported by sufficient facts to validate it in the eyes of the
    law, or when indisputable record facts contradict or otherwise
    render the opinion unreasonable, it cannot support a jury‘s
    verdict.‖ Brooke Grp., 509 U.S. at 242; Phila. Newspapers,
    
    51 F.3d at 1198
    . In an antitrust case, an expert opinion
    generally must ―incorporate all aspects of the economic
    reality‖ of the relevant market. Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1057
    . Here, the District Court properly rejected Eaton‘s
    argument that DeRamus‘s testimony should have been
    excluded on the basis that it was contradicted by other facts.
    Eaton‘s argument on this point really amounts to nothing
    more than a complaint that DeRamus did not adopt Eaton‘s
    view of the case. The District Court correctly noted that,
    although some of DeRamus‘s testimony may have been
    65
    contradicted by other evidence, including the testimony of
    Eaton‘s expert, the existence of conflicting evidence was not
    a basis on which to exclude DeRamus‘s testimony. The
    respective credibility of Plaintiffs‘ and Eaton‘s experts was a
    question for the jury to decide. LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 165
    .
    DeRamus was extensively cross-examined and Eaton
    presented testimony from its own expert, who opined that the
    LTAs had no anticompetitive effect. In the end, the jury
    apparently found DeRamus to be more credible. ―[Eaton]‘s
    disappointment as to the jury‘s finding of credibility does not
    constitute an abuse of discretion by the District Court in
    allowing [DeRamus‘s] testimony.‖ 
    Id. at 166
    .
    2. Expert Testimony on Damages
    In their cross-appeal, Plaintiffs argue that the District
    Court erred in excluding DeRamus‘s testimony on the issue
    of damages. The core of DeRamus‘s damages analysis was
    one page (titled ―Five Year Product Line Profit and Loss‖) of
    ZF Meritor‘s Revised Strategic Business Plan (―SBP‖) for
    fiscal years 2002 through 2005, which was presented to ZF
    Meritor‘s Board of Directors in November 2000.23 The
    District Court determined that, although DeRamus used
    methodologies regularly employed by economists, his opinion
    nevertheless failed the reliability requirements of Daubert and
    the Federal Rules of Evidence because the underlying data
    23
    The SBP contained a five-year forecast of profit and
    loss estimates based on estimated unit sales, unit prices,
    manufacturing costs, operating expenses, and other
    considerations.
    66
    was not sufficiently reliable.             The District Court
    acknowledged that experts often rely on business plans in
    forming damages estimates, but concluded that DeRamus‘s
    reliance on the SBP in this case was improper because he did
    not know either the qualifications of the individuals who
    prepared the SBP estimates or the assumptions upon which
    the estimates were based. Plaintiffs filed a motion for
    clarification, which asked the District Court to allow
    DeRamus to testify based on his existing expert report to
    damages estimates independent of the SBP, or, in the
    alternative, to allow him to amend his report to include the
    alternate damages estimates. The District Court did not
    resolve the damages issue at that time, and bifurcated the
    case. After the trial on liability, Plaintiffs supplemented their
    pre-trial motion for clarification, adding several new
    arguments based on developments at trial, and renewing their
    request that DeRamus be allowed to testify based on alternate
    calculations. The District Court denied Plaintiffs‘ motion and
    awarded $0 in damages.
    Our inquiry on appeal is two-fold. Initially, we must
    determine whether the District Court erred in excluding the
    expert opinion of DeRamus on the basis that it was not
    sufficiently reliable. Then, we must consider whether the
    District Court abused its discretion in denying Plaintiffs‘
    request to allow DeRamus to testify to alternative damages
    calculations. We will address these issues in turn.
    i. DeRamus‘s original damages calculations
    First, we will consider Plaintiffs‘ contention that the
    District Court erred in determining that DeRamus‘s damages
    67
    opinion was not sufficiently reliable. Federal Rule of
    Evidence 702, as amended in 2000 to incorporate the
    standards set forth in Daubert, imposes an obligation upon a
    district court to ensure that expert testimony is not only
    relevant, but reliable. Fed. R. Evid. 702; Paoli II, 
    35 F.3d at 744
    . As we have made clear, ―the reliability analysis
    [required by Daubert] applies to all aspects of an expert‘s
    testimony: the methodology, the facts underlying the expert‘s
    opinion, [and] the link between the facts and the conclusion.‖
    Heller v. Shaw Indus., Inc., 
    167 F.3d 146
    , 155 (3d Cir. 1999);
    see also 
    id.
     (―Not only must each stage of the expert‘s
    testimony be reliable, but each stage must be evaluated
    practically and flexibly without bright-line exclusionary (or
    inclusionary) rules.‖). As we explain below, the District
    Court did not abuse its discretion by finding that DeRamus‘s
    damages estimate, which was based heavily on the SPB
    projections, bore insufficient indicia of reliability to be
    submitted to a jury.
    To determine the damages suffered by Plaintiffs as a
    result of Eaton‘s anticompetitive conduct, DeRamus
    conducted a two-part analysis. He computed Plaintiffs‘ lost
    profits for the period between 2000 and 2009, as well as the
    lost enterprise value of Plaintiffs‘ HD transmissions business.
    To calculate Plaintiffs‘ lost profits, DeRamus first estimated
    the incremental revenues that Plaintiffs would have earned
    ―but for‖ Eaton‘s anticompetitive conduct, and then
    subtracted from that figure the incremental cost that Plaintiffs
    would have had to incur to achieve such incremental sales.
    Ordinarily, such an approach would be appropriate
    because ―an expert may construct a reasonable offense-free
    68
    world as a yardstick for measuring what, hypothetically,
    would have happened ‗but for‘ the defendant‘s unlawful
    activities.‖ LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 165
     (citations omitted).
    However, the District Court‘s primary criticism of
    DeRamus‘s report was that he did not construct an offense-
    free world based on actual financial data, but instead relied on
    a one-page set of profit and volume projections without
    knowing the circumstances under which such projections
    were created or the assumptions on which they were based.
    In some circumstances, an expert might be able to rely on the
    estimates of others in constructing a hypothetical reality, but
    to do so, the expert must explain why he relied on such
    estimates and must demonstrate why he believed the
    estimates were reliable. See Fed. R. Evid. 702; Daubert, 
    509 U.S. at 592-95
    ; Paoli II, 
    35 F.3d at
    748 n.18 (―Arguably,
    [third-party estimates] that an expert relies on are not his
    underlying data, but rather the data that went into the [third-
    party estimates] in the first place are his underlying data.‖).
    Plaintiffs contend that DeRamus‘s reliance on the SBP
    estimates was appropriate because a company‘s internal
    financial projections, like those in the SBP, are regularly and
    reasonably relied upon by economists in formulating opinions
    regarding a company‘s performance in an offense-free world.
    Plaintiffs are certainly correct that ―internal projections for
    future growth‖ often serve as legitimate bases for expert
    opinions. See LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 165
    ; Autowest, Inc. v.
    Peugeot, Inc., 
    434 F.2d 556
    , 566 (2d Cir. 1970) (holding that
    damages testimony was admissible because the financial
    projections on which the testimony was based ―were the
    product of deliberation by experienced businessmen charting
    69
    their future course‖). Businesses are generally well-informed
    about the industries in which they operate, and have
    incentives to develop accurate projections. As such, experts
    frequently use a plaintiff‘s business plan to estimate the
    plaintiff‘s expected profits in the absence of the defendant‘s
    misconduct. See Litigation Services Handbook: The Role of
    the Financial Expert 24:13 (4th ed. 2007). However, there is
    no per se rule of inclusion where an expert relies on a
    business plan; district courts must perform a case-by-case
    inquiry to determine whether the expert‘s reliance on the
    business plan in a given case is reasonable. See Heller, 
    167 F.3d at 155
    .
    Here, the District Court concluded that the SBP could
    not serve as a reliable basis for DeRamus‘s opinion because
    he was unaware of the qualifications of the individuals who
    prepared the document, or the assumptions on which the
    estimates were based. Plaintiffs argue that these factual
    findings are contradicted by the record. Admittedly, the
    record indicates that DeRamus did not, as the District Court
    suggested, blindly accept the SBP estimates without question.
    DeRamus was aware that the SBP had been presented to ZF
    Meritor‘s Board of Directors, and that it was revised several
    times to ―address and resolve queries management had about
    the reasonableness of the assumptions, projections, [and]
    forecasts.‖ He also knew that the Board had relied on the
    SBP in making business decisions. Moreover, ZF Meritor‘s
    former president testified that he ―did not submit SBPs to
    management for review unless [he] believed the projections,
    forecasts, and assumptions therein to be reliable.‖
    70
    However, contrary to Plaintiffs‘ assertions, these
    excerpts from the record do not contradict the District Court‘s
    ultimate findings. The record amply supports the District
    Court‘s concern that, although DeRamus was generally aware
    of the circumstances under which the SBP was created and
    the purposes for which it was used, he lacked critical
    information that would be necessary for Eaton to effectively
    cross-examine him. An expert‘s ―lack of familiarity with the
    methods and the reasons underlying [someone else‘s]
    projections virtually preclude[s] any assessment of the
    validity of the projections through cross-examination.‖ TK-7
    Corp. v. Estate of Barbouti, 
    993 F.2d 722
    , 732 (10th Cir.
    1993); compare Autowest, 
    434 F.2d at 566
     (holding that
    projections of company officials were admissible where such
    officials ―set out at length the bases from which they derived
    their figures, and consequently, [the opposing party] was able
    to cross-examine them vigorously‖). Here, DeRamus knew
    that the SBP was presented to the Board by experienced
    management professionals, but he did not know who initially
    calculated the SBP figures. He did not know whether the
    SBP projections were calculated by ZF Meritor management,
    lower level employees at ZF Meritor, or came from some
    outside source. Nor did DeRamus know the methodology
    used to create the SBP or the assumptions on which the SBP‘s
    price and volume estimates were based.24
    24
    As the District Court noted, it is especially important
    for an expert to identify and justify the assumptions
    underlying financial projections when dealing with a new
    company. Here, although Meritor had been in the HD
    71
    Under the deferential abuse of discretion standard, we
    will not disturb a district court‘s decision to exclude
    testimony unless we are left with ―a definite and firm
    conviction that the court below committed a clear error of
    judgment.‖ In re TMI Litig., 
    193 F.3d 613
    , 666 (3d Cir.
    1999) (citation omitted). Plaintiffs cannot clear that high
    hurdle. Accordingly, we conclude that the District Court
    acted within its discretion in determining that one page of
    financial projections for a nascent company, the assumptions
    underlying which were relatively unknown, did not provide
    ―good grounds,‖ Paoli II, 
    35 F.3d at 742
     (quoting Daubert,
    
    509 U.S. at 590
    ), for DeRamus to generate his damages
    estimate. Compare LePage’s, 
    324 F.3d at 165
     (noting that
    plaintiff‘s expert considered the defendant‘s internal
    projections for growth, but also closely examined the market
    conditions, including the past performance of competitors).
    Plaintiffs raise two additional challenges to the District
    Court‘s exclusion of DeRamus‘s testimony. First, Plaintiffs
    contend that because the SBP was admitted into evidence at
    trial, Rule 703 does not provide a basis for exclusion.
    However, this argument is based on the flawed assumption
    that the District Court excluded DeRamus‘s testimony under
    Rule 703, rather than Rule 702. Plaintiffs assume that
    because the District Court stated that ―DeRamus manipulated
    the SBP using methodologies employed by economists,‖ ZF
    Meritor, 
    646 F. Supp. 2d at 667
    , the District Court necessarily
    transmissions industry for over a decade, ZF Meritor was
    offering a brand new line of transmissions that had never
    before been sold in the North American market.
    72
    concluded that Rule 702, which focuses on methodologies,
    was satisfied. However, the District Court explicitly stated
    that ―the fundamental query‖ was ―whether the [SBP]
    estimates pass[ed] the reliability requirements of Rules 104,
    702, and 703.‖ 
    Id.
     Although it is not entirely clear from the
    District Court‘s opinion which rule the District Court relied
    upon in finding DeRamus‘s testimony inadmissible, we may
    affirm evidentiary rulings on any ground supported by the
    record, Hughes v. Long, 
    242 F.3d 121
    , 122 n.1 (3d Cir. 2001),
    and we conclude that DeRamus‘s opinion was properly
    excluded because it failed the reliability requirements of Rule
    702.25
    Plaintiffs‘ suggestion that the reasonableness of an
    expert‘s reliance on facts or data to form his opinion is
    somehow an inappropriate inquiry under Rule 702 results
    25
    We base our affirmance of the District Court‘s
    decision entirely on the fact that DeRamus‘s opinion failed
    Rule 702, and do not decide whether Rule 703 provides an
    additional basis for exclusion. We note, however, that
    Plaintiffs‘ argument that Rule 703 somehow constrains a
    district court‘s ability to conduct an assessment of reliability
    under Rule 702 is misplaced. After all, a piece of evidence
    may be relevant for one purpose, and thus admissible at trial,
    but not be the type of information that can form the basis of a
    reliable expert opinion. As the District Court stated, ―the fact
    that [a piece of evidence] [i]s part of [the] plaintiffs‘ ‗story‘
    does not mean, ipso facto,‖ that an expert opinion relying on
    such evidence is admissible. ZF Meritor LLC v. Eaton Corp.,
    
    800 F. Supp. 2d 633
    , 637 (D. Del. 2011).
    73
    from an unduly myopic interpretation of Rule 702 and ignores
    the mandate of Daubert that the district court must act as a
    gatekeeper. See Daubert, 
    509 U.S. at 589
    ; Heller, 
    167 F.3d at 153
     (―While ‗the focus, of course, must be solely on
    principles and methodology, not on the conclusions that they
    generate,‘ a district court must examine the expert‘s
    conclusions in order to determine whether they could reliably
    flow from the facts known to the expert and the methodology
    used.‖) (emphasis added) (quoting Daubert, 509 U.S. at 595).
    Where proffered expert testimony‘s ―factual basis, data,
    principles, methods, or their application are called sufficiently
    into question, . . . the trial judge must determine whether the
    testimony has ‗a reliable basis in the knowledge and
    experience of the relevant discipline.‘‖ Kumho Tire Co. v.
    Carmichael, 
    526 U.S. 137
    , 149 (1999) (quoting Daubert, 
    509 U.S. at 592
    ). A district court‘s inquiry under Rule 702 is ―a
    flexible one‖ and must be guided by the facts of the case.
    Daubert, 
    509 U.S. at 591, 594
    . Here, the District Court‘s
    analysis fell squarely within its flexible gatekeeping function
    under Daubert and Rule 702. See Kumho Tire Co. 
    526 U.S. at 149
    ; Paoli II, 
    35 F.3d at
    748 n.18; see also Elcock, 
    233 F.3d at 754
     (explaining that an expert‘s testimony regarding
    damages must be based on a sufficient factual foundation);
    Tyger Constr. Co. v. Pensacola Constr. Co., 
    29 F.3d 137
    , 142
    (4th Cir. 1994) (―An expert‘s opinion should be excluded
    when it is based on assumptions which are speculative and
    not supported by the record.‖).
    Second, Plaintiffs argue that the District Court did not
    provide fair notice that it intended to exclude DeRamus‘s
    testimony under Federal Rule of Evidence 703. Again, this
    74
    argument rests on the flawed assumption that the District
    Court relied solely on Rule 703. However, even assuming the
    District Court mistakenly believed that its Rule 702 reliability
    analysis actually fell under Rule 703, Plaintiffs‘ notice
    argument would still be meritless. A district court must give
    the parties ―an adequate opportunity to be heard on
    evidentiary issues.‖ In re Paoli R.R. Yard PCB Litig. (Paoli
    I), 
    916 F.2d 829
    , 854 (3d Cir. 1990). Here, there was
    extensive briefing regarding DeRamus‘s damages opinion,
    much of which focused on Eaton‘s argument that DeRamus‘s
    reliance on the SBP was improper. The District Court held
    not one, but two in limine hearings, in which DeRamus
    testified for several hours. Compare 
    id. at 854-55
     (holding
    that the district court did not give the plaintiffs an adequate
    opportunity to be heard where it failed to conduct an in limine
    hearing and denied oral argument on the evidentiary issues).
    As such, Plaintiffs were well aware of, and had ample
    opportunity to be heard on, the question of whether
    DeRamus‘s reliance on the SBP rendered his testimony
    inadmissible.
    ii. Alternate damages calculations
    The District Court‘s opinion excluding DeRamus‘s
    damages testimony focused exclusively on DeRamus‘s
    damages estimates based on the SBP projections regarding
    ZF Meritor‘s market share and profit margin. However, his
    expert report also set forth market-share estimates based on
    an econometric model. The econometric model did not
    consider the SBP, but instead used economic variables, such
    as the number of heavy-duty trucks built and sold in the North
    American market, an index of consumer confidence in the
    75
    United States, the average wholesale price of oil in the United
    States, and interest rates. The model also considered ZF
    Meritor‘s market share from the previous month ―in order to
    capture market dynamics.‖
    To reach his ultimate damages estimate, DeRamus
    averaged several damages calculations, each of which used a
    different combination of inputs for market share and profit
    margin. Following the District Court‘s order excluding
    DeRamus‘s testimony due to his reliance on the SBP,
    Plaintiffs filed a motion for clarification, asking the District
    Court to allow DeRamus to calculate damages using the same
    methodologies from his expert report, but using data
    independent of the SBP. Specifically, Plaintiffs proposed
    several revisions to DeRamus‘s damages estimate. First,
    Plaintiffs indicated that DeRamus could revise his ―Eaton
    Operating Profit Method,‖ which used as principal inputs the
    SBP estimates for market share and Eaton‘s actual operating
    profits for profit margin. Plaintiffs stated that DeRamus had
    recalculated lost profits using the same methodology, but
    replacing the market-share data from the SBP with market-
    share data from his econometric model. Second, Plaintiffs
    explained that DeRamus could similarly revise his
    ―Econometric Method‖ of calculating lost profits, which used
    the econometric model for market share, and data from the
    SBP for profit margin. He could use the same methodology
    and replace the profit margin data from the SBP with profit
    76
    margin data from Plaintiffs‘ actual sales data from 1996
    through 2000.26
    Noting that all of the data necessary for DeRamus‘s
    recalculations were already in the expert report, Plaintiffs
    requested that DeRamus be able to testify to the alternate
    calculations using the existing expert report. Allowing
    DeRamus to testify to alternate damages numbers without
    amending his expert report would have left Eaton without
    advance notice of the new calculations, and thus would have
    been improper. As such, the District Court did not err in
    ruling that DeRamus could not testify to new calculations
    based on the existing expert report. However, the District
    Court‘s refusal to allow DeRamus to amend his expert report
    presents a much more difficult question, one that we will
    explore in depth.
    Before beginning our analysis, it is necessary to
    provide some context regarding the procedural history
    because the way in which the damages issue was handled by
    the District Court is significant to our determination that the
    District Court abused its discretion. After the District Court
    granted Eaton‘s motion to exclude DeRamus‘s damages
    testimony, it granted leave for Plaintiffs to file a motion for
    clarification to identify damages calculations in DeRamus‘s
    expert report that were not based on the SBP. On September
    26
    Although the District Court did not address
    DeRamus‘s lost enterprise value calculations, Plaintiffs
    indicated in their motion for clarification that DeRamus could
    make similar revisions to those calculations.
    77
    9, 2009, ten days before trial was set to begin, Plaintiffs filed
    the motion, acknowledging that new calculations would be
    required, but submitting that all of the necessary data was
    already in the report. The next day, the District Court held a
    pretrial conference, in which it considered Plaintiffs‘ motion,
    and determined that it had two options: to ―basically punt‖ on
    the damages issue and bifurcate the case, or to allow
    Plaintiffs‘ new damages theory to go forward and allow Eaton
    to depose DeRamus to examine his new theories. The
    District Court concluded that the ―cleanest‖ option was to
    defer the damages issue, bifurcate, and proceed to trial on
    liability. That way, the District Court stated, the damages
    issue would only need to be resolved if ―the jury c[ame] back
    with a plaintiffs‘ verdict, which [was] [up]held on appeal.‖ In
    opting to defer a decision on damages, the District Court
    noted that it ―did not . . . at the moment, have the time to
    parse [DeRamus‘s report] as carefully‖ as would be necessary
    to satisfactorily address the parties‘ arguments regarding
    damages.
    The jury delivered its verdict on liability on October 8,
    2009, and the District Court entered judgment in favor of
    Plaintiffs on October 14. Two days later, Plaintiffs requested
    that the District Court set a trial on damages. Eaton opposed
    Plaintiffs‘ request, asserting that the judgment on liability was
    a final appealable decision. Although the District Court
    apparently agreed with Eaton initially, stating that it ―d[id]
    not intend to address damages until liability has been finally
    resolved by the Third Circuit,‖ the District Court
    subsequently issued an amended judgment, which stated that
    because damages had not been resolved, there was no final
    78
    appealable order under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 54(b).
    On November 3, 2009, Eaton filed its renewed motion for
    judgment as a matter of law or a new trial. The District Court
    did not rule on the motion until March 2011.27
    Following the District Court‘s denial of Eaton‘s
    motion, Plaintiffs renewed their request for a damages trial.
    On July 25, 2011, the District Court held a status conference,
    in which it heard arguments on whether the liability issue was
    appealable as a judgment on fewer than all claims under Rule
    54(b). Although the District Court initially indicated that it
    would proceed under Rule 54(b), and once again defer
    resolution of the damages issue, after both parties agreed that
    the judgment on liability was not appealable under Rule 54(b)
    (and that it was unlikely that this Court would grant an
    interlocutory appeal), the District Court acknowledged that it
    would ―need to go back to the papers and see how I extract
    myself from the procedural morass that I put myself in.‖ The
    District Court then signaled the way in which it would extract
    itself, stating ―so let‘s assume that I am going to resurrect a
    motion that is two years old [Plaintiffs‘ September 3, 2009
    motion for clarification], and let‘s assume that I deny it, and
    we‘re left with the situation we have now. At that point,
    would it make sense to have a cross-appeal on liability, on the
    Daubert decision, and get it up to the Third Circuit?‖
    27
    It is unclear from the record why sixteen months
    passed between Eaton‘s motion and the District Court‘s
    decision on the motion.
    79
    Several days later, on August 4, 2011, the District
    Court issued a memorandum opinion and order denying
    Plaintiffs‘ motion for clarification, and awarding $0 in
    damages. The District Court‘s entire analysis of Plaintiffs‘
    request to modify DeRamus‘s report consisted of one
    paragraph. The District Court concluded that allowing
    Plaintiffs to amend DeRamus‘s expert report ―would be
    tantamount to reopening expert discovery‖ because DeRamus
    would need to be deposed again and Eaton would have to
    prepare another rebuttal expert report. The District Court also
    noted that, when it granted leave for Plaintiffs to move for
    clarification, leave was granted only for Plaintiffs to show
    that DeRamus‘s report already contained an alternate
    damages calculation, and that Plaintiffs‘ motion requested
    permission to submit additional damages calculations.
    Therefore, the District Court concluded, ―[a]t this stage of the
    litigation,‖ it would not give Plaintiffs an opportunity to
    modify their damages estimate.
    We provide this extensive review of the procedural
    history to make a basic point: while we appreciate the District
    Court‘s attempt to conserve judicial resources and refrain
    from addressing the damages issue unless absolutely
    necessary, it is apparent from the record that Plaintiffs‘
    request for permission to submit alternative damages
    calculations was given little more than nominal consideration.
    We are mindful that the District Court has considerable
    discretion in matters regarding expert discovery and case
    management, and a party challenging the district court‘s
    conduct of discovery procedures bears a ―heavy burden.‖ In
    re Fine Paper, 
    685 F.2d at 817-18
     (―We will not interfere
    80
    with a trial court‘s control of its docket ‗except upon the
    clearest showing that the procedures have resulted in actual
    and substantial prejudice to the complaining litigant.‘‖)
    (citation omitted); see Schiff, 
    602 F.3d at 176
    . Under Federal
    Rule of Civil Procedure 26(a)(2), a party is required to
    disclose an expert report containing ―a complete statement of
    all opinions the witness will express and the basis and reasons
    for them.‖ Fed. R. Civ. P. 26(a)(2)(B)(i) (emphasis added).
    Any additions or changes to the information in the expert
    report must be disclosed by the time the party‘s pretrial
    disclosures are due. Fed. R. Civ. P. 26(e)(2). Here, Plaintiffs
    were required to make all mandatory disclosures six months
    before trial, including all damages calculations. The damages
    estimates in DeRamus‘s report were found to be unreliable,
    and Plaintiffs sought, after the date by which discovery
    disclosures were due, to modify the estimates to reflect
    reliance on different data. Ordinarily, we will not disrupt a
    district court‘s decision to deny a party‘s motion to add
    information to an expert report under such circumstances.
    Schiff, 
    602 F.3d at 176
    ; In re Fine Paper, 685 F.3d at 817. A
    plaintiff omits evidence necessary to sustain a damages award
    at its own risk. See Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc. v. Texaco
    Ref. & Mktg., Inc., 
    2 F.3d 493
    , 504 (3d Cir. 1993).
    However, exclusion of critical evidence is an
    ―extreme‖ sanction, and thus, a district court‘s discretion is
    not unlimited. Konstantopoulos v. Westvaco Corp., 
    112 F.3d 710
    , 719 (3d Cir. 1997); see also E.E.O.C. v. Gen. Dynamics
    Corp., 
    999 F.2d 113
    , 116 (5th Cir. 1993) (explaining that a
    continuance, as opposed to exclusion, is the ―preferred
    means‖ of dealing with a party‘s attempt to offer new
    81
    evidence after the time for discovery has closed). There are
    indeed times, even when control of discovery is at issue, that
    a district court will ―exceed[] the permissible bounds of its
    broad discretion.‖ Drippe v. Tobelinski, 
    604 F.3d 778
    , 783
    (3d Cir. 2010). In Meyers v. Pennypack Woods Home
    Ownership Ass’n, 
    559 F.2d 894
    , 905 (3d Cir. 1977),
    overruled on other grounds by Goodman v. Lukens Steel Co.,
    
    777 F.2d 113
     (3d Cir. 1985), we set forth five factors that
    should be considered in deciding whether a district court‘s
    exclusion of evidence as a discovery sanction constitutes an
    abuse of discretion. Here, although the District Court‘s
    decision was not a discovery sanction nor an exclusion of
    proffered evidence, but rather an exercise of discretion to
    control the discovery process and a refusal to allow
    submission of additional evidence, we find the Pennypack
    factors instructive, and thus they will guide our inquiry. See
    Trilogy Commc’ns, Inc. v. Times Fiber Commc’ns, Inc., 
    109 F.3d 739
    , 744-45 (Fed. Cir. 1997) (applying factors similar to
    those set forth in Pennypack to evaluate whether a district
    court erred in denying the plaintiff‘s motion to supplement its
    expert report with additional data); see also Hunt v. Cnty. of
    Orange, 
    672 F.3d 606
    , 616 (9th Cir. 2012) (applying similar
    factors to determine whether the district court abused its
    discretion in denying a motion to amend a pretrial order).
    In considering whether the District Court abused its
    discretion in denying Plaintiffs‘ request to submit alternate
    damages calculations, we will consider: (1) ―the prejudice or
    surprise in fact of the party against whom the excluded
    witnesses would have testified‖ or the excluded evidence
    would have been offered; (2) ―the ability of that party to cure
    82
    the prejudice‖; (3) the extent to which allowing such
    witnesses or evidence would ―disrupt the orderly and efficient
    trial of the case or of other cases in the court‖; (4) any ―bad
    faith or willfulness in failing to comply with the court‘s
    order‖; and (5) the importance of the excluded evidence.
    Pennypack, 
    559 F.2d at 904-05
    . The importance of the
    evidence is often the most significant factor. See Sowell v.
    Butcher & Singer, Inc., 
    926 F.2d 289
    , 302 (3d Cir. 1991);
    Pennypack, 
    559 F.2d at 904
     (observing ―how important [the
    excluded] testimony might have been and how critical [wa]s
    its absence‖).
    Applying the Pennypack factors to this case, we
    conclude that the District Court abused its discretion in
    denying Plaintiffs‘ request to allow DeRamus to submit his
    alternate damages estimates. As to the first and second
    factors, Eaton would not have suffered substantial prejudice if
    DeRamus were allowed to amend his expert report.
    DeRamus‘s new calculations will be based on data from the
    initial report, which Eaton has been aware of for nearly three
    years, and DeRamus will employ methodologies that the
    District Court has already recognized as being regularly and
    reliably applied by economists. As Plaintiffs noted in their
    motion for clarification, it would be ―a straightforward matter
    of arithmetic‖ to substitute data from the econometric model
    and actual sales data for the SBP projections. For this reason,
    the District Court‘s concern that granting Plaintiffs‘ request
    would be ―tantamount to reopening discovery‖ seems
    unfounded. Although Eaton will have to respond to new
    calculations, it will not have to analyze any new data, or
    challenge any new methodologies. Moreover, Plaintiffs
    83
    specifically set forth in their motion for clarification the
    changes that DeRamus would make, and because the changes
    only involved the substitution of inputs, Eaton would not be
    unfairly surprised by the new damages estimates.
    As to the third Pennypack factor, allowing DeRamus
    to submit additional damages calculations will not disrupt the
    orderly and efficient flow of the case. In fact, our ruling on
    the liability issues and remand to the District Court to resolve
    damages is precisely what the District Court and the parties
    envisioned all along. Eaton, well aware of the District
    Court‘s desire to have this Court determine the liability issues
    before setting a damages trial, suggested that the best way to
    accomplish the District Court‘s objective was to amend the
    JMOL order to include ―zero damages and no injunctive
    relief.‖ As the District Court stated at the July 25, 2011 status
    conference, ―[t]he way I handle complex litigation generally,
    when I bifurcate, is that I enter a final judgment pursuant to
    Rule 54(b) . . . and once the Circuit Court determines liability,
    if there is a reason to have a damages trial, we have a
    damages trial.‖ Thus, it cannot seriously be a surprise to any
    of the parties that they will once again be required to address
    damages in this case. Additionally, Eaton repeatedly states in
    its brief that Plaintiffs seek to reopen discovery ―on the eve of
    trial.‖ Although that may have been true when Plaintiffs‘
    original motion for clarification was filed, it is no longer true.
    Trial ended in October 2009 and thus, when the District Court
    finally ruled on Plaintiffs‘ motion, there was no longer any
    time-crunch problem. Any concern that granting Plaintiffs‘
    motion would prevent Eaton from being able to effectively
    prepare to address DeRamus‘s new damages estimates at trial
    84
    is no longer relevant, nor is there any risk that granting
    Plaintiffs‘ motion would excessively delay a trial on liability.
    As to the fourth factor, there is no evidence of any bad
    faith on the part of Plaintiffs. However, under this fourth
    factor, we may also consider the Plaintiffs‘ justifications for
    failing to include alternative damages calculations in the
    event calculations based on the SBP were found to be
    insufficient. See Pennypack, 
    559 F.2d at 905
    ; Gen. Dynamics
    Corp., 
    999 F.2d at 115-16
    . Given that DeRamus‘s report
    already included the data necessary to develop alternate
    damages estimates, he could very easily have provided such
    estimates. Plaintiffs have provided no persuasive explanation
    for his failure to do so, other than that he believed his existing
    estimates were sufficiently reliable. It is not the district
    court‘s responsibility to help a party correct an error or a poor
    exercise of judgment, and thus, Plaintiffs‘ conscious choice to
    rely so heavily on data that was ultimately found to be
    unreliable weighs against a finding of abuse of discretion.
    This is especially true in a case such as this, where the party
    submitting the flawed expert report is a large corporation with
    significant resources represented by highly competent
    counsel.
    However, perhaps the most important factor in this
    case is the critical nature of the evidence, and the
    consequences if permission to amend is denied. Expert
    testimony is necessary to establish damages in an antitrust
    case. As such, without additional damages calculations, it is
    clear that Plaintiffs will be unable to pursue damages, despite
    the fact that they won at the liability stage. Compare Gen.
    Dynamics Corp., 
    999 F.2d at 116-17
     (finding an abuse of
    85
    discretion in the district court‘s exclusion of expert testimony,
    in part, because the total exclusion of such testimony ―was
    tantamount to a dismissal of the [plaintiff‘s] . . . claim‖), with
    Sowell, 
    926 F.2d at 302
     (finding no abuse of discretion in
    district court‘s exclusion of proffered expert testimony, in
    large part, because ―the record [was] totally devoid of any
    indication of . . . how th[e] testimony might have bolstered
    [the plaintiff‘s] case,‖ and thus, there was ―no basis whatever
    for believing that the admission of expert testimony would
    have influenced the outcome of th[e] case‖). The District
    Court‘s decision therefore would clearly influence the
    outcome of the case. See Sowell, 
    926 F.2d at 302
    .
    Significantly, in the antitrust context, a damages award
    not only benefits the plaintiff, it also fosters competition and
    furthers the interests of the public by imposing a severe
    penalty (treble damages) for violation of the antitrust laws.
    See Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co. of Cal., 
    405 U.S. 251
    , 262
    (1972) (―Every violation of the antitrust laws is a blow to the
    free-enterprise system envisaged by Congress. . . . In
    enacting these laws, Congress had many means at its disposal
    to penalize violators. It could have, for example, required
    violators to compensate federal, state, and local governments
    for the estimated damage to their respective economies
    caused by the violations. But, this remedy was not selected.
    Instead, Congress chose to permit all persons to sue to
    recover three times their actual damages . . . . By [so doing],
    Congress encouraged these persons to serve as ‗private
    attorneys general.‘‖) (citations omitted); Mitsubishi Motors
    Corp. v. Soler Chrysler-Plymouth, Inc., 
    473 U.S. 614
    , 655
    (1985) (―A claim under the antitrust laws is not merely a
    86
    private matter. The Sherman Act is designed to promote the
    national interest in a competitive economy . . . .‖) (quotation
    omitted). Thus, if Plaintiffs are not able to pursue damages,
    not only will they be unable to recover for the antitrust injury
    Eaton caused, the policy of deterring antitrust violations
    through the treble damages remedy will also be frustrated.
    See Paoli II, 
    35 F.3d at 750
     (―[T]he likelihood of finding an
    abuse of discretion is affected by the importance of the
    district court‘s decision to the outcome of the case and the
    effect it will have on important rights.‖).
    In sum, after weighing the Pennypack factors and
    taking into account the circumstances under which Plaintiffs‘
    motion for clarification was ultimately denied, we conclude
    that the District Court abused its discretion in not permitting
    Plaintiffs to submit alternate damages calculations.28
    28
    We express no opinion as to the reliability or
    admissibility of DeRamus‘s alternate damages calculations.
    That is a matter left to the District Court on remand.
    However, we note that Plaintiffs‘ motion for clarification only
    sought to include damages calculations based on data already
    in the expert report, and that fact is crucial to our holding that
    prejudice to Eaton can be easily cured. Nothing in our
    opinion should be read as requiring the District Court to allow
    Plaintiffs to bring in entirely new data for the revised
    damages estimates.
    87
    D. Article III Standing to Seek Injunctive Relief
    Finally, we turn to Eaton‘s contention that Plaintiffs
    lack standing to seek injunctive relief. Eaton argues that
    Plaintiffs‘ complete withdrawal from the HD transmissions
    market in 2006 and their failure to present evidence showing
    anything more than a mere possibility that they will reenter
    the market precludes a finding of Article III standing as to
    injunctive relief. Although the District Court did not directly
    address standing, it noted in a footnote that, ―[w]hile
    [P]laintiffs are no longer in business and are unable to
    directly benefit from an injunction, here, an injunction is
    appropriate because of the public‘s interest in robust
    competition and the possibility that [P]laintiffs may one day
    reenter the market.‖ ZF Meritor LLC v. Eaton Corp., 
    800 F. Supp. 2d 633
    , 639 (D. Del. 2011). We agree with Eaton that
    this determination was improper, and we will therefore vacate
    the injunction issued by the District Court.29
    29
    Even though Meritor was still technically in the HD
    transmissions business at the time the complaint in this case
    was filed, it is still appropriate to frame this issue as one of
    standing, rather than one of mootness. Plaintiffs‘ complaint,
    which was filed on October 5, 2006, stated that Meritor
    intended to exit the HD transmissions business in January
    2007, and did not indicate any intent to reenter. Thus, even at
    the time the complaint was filed, Plaintiffs could not
    demonstrate the requisite likelihood of future injury sufficient
    to confer standing. See Davis v. F.E.C., 
    554 U.S. 724
    , 734
    (2008) (―[T]he standing inquiry [is] focused on whether the
    party invoking jurisdiction had the requisite stake in the
    88
    A plaintiff bears the burden of establishing that he has
    Article III standing for each type of relief sought. Summers v.
    Earth Island Inst., 
    555 U.S. 488
    , 493 (2009). In order to have
    standing to seek injunctive relief, a plaintiff must show:
    (1) that he is under a threat of suffering ―‗injury in fact‘ that is
    concrete and particularized; the threat must be actual and
    imminent, not conjectural or hypothetical‖; (2) a causal
    connection between the injury and the conduct complained
    of; and (3) a likelihood that a favorable judicial decision will
    prevent or redress the injury. 
    Id.
     (citing Friends of Earth, Inc.
    v. Laidlaw Envtl. Servs., Inc., 
    528 U.S. 167
    , 180-81 (2000)).
    Even if the plaintiff has suffered a previous injury due to the
    defendant‘s conduct, the equitable remedy of an injunction is
    ―unavailable absent a showing of irreparable injury, a
    requirement that cannot be met where there is no showing of
    any real or immediate threat that the plaintiff will be wronged
    again[.]‖ City of Los Angeles v. Lyons, 
    461 U.S. 95
    , 111
    (1983); see O’Shea v. Littleton, 
    414 U.S. 488
    , 495-96 (1974)
    (―Past exposure to illegal conduct does not in itself show a
    present case or controversy regarding injunctive relief . . . if
    unaccompanied by any continuing, present adverse effects.‖).
    Accordingly, a plaintiff may have standing to pursue
    outcome when the suit was filed.‖) (citations omitted); U.S.
    Parole Comm’n v. Geraghty, 
    445 U.S. 388
    , 397 (1980) (―The
    requisite personal interest that must exist at the
    commencement of the litigation (standing) must continue
    throughout its existence (mootness).‖) (citation omitted).
    Moreover, even if we treated this as a mootness question, our
    conclusion would remain the same.
    89
    damages, but lack standing to seek injunctive relief. Lyons,
    
    461 U.S. at 105
    .
    For example, in City of Los Angeles v. Lyons, the
    plaintiff sued the city, seeking damages, injunctive relief, and
    declaratory relief, for an incident in which he was allegedly
    choked by police officers. 
    Id. at 97
    . The Supreme Court held
    that, although the plaintiff clearly had standing to seek
    damages, he lacked standing to seek injunctive relief because
    he failed to establish a ―real and immediate threat‖ that he
    would again be stopped by the police and choked. 
    Id. at 105
    .
    ―Absent a sufficient likelihood that he [would] again be
    wronged in a similar way, [the plaintiff] [was] no more
    entitled to an injunction than any other citizen of Los
    Angeles.‖ 
    Id. at 111
    . Likewise, in Summers v. Earth Island
    Institute, the Court held that an organization lacked standing
    to enjoin the application of Forest Service regulations in
    national parks where its members expressed only a ―vague
    desire‖ to return to the affected parks. 555 U.S. at 496.
    ―Such some-day intentions—without any description of
    concrete plans, or indeed any specification of when the some
    day will be—do not support a finding of . . . actual or
    imminent injury.‖ Id. (quoting Lujan v. Defenders of
    Wildlife, 
    504 U.S. 555
    , 564 (1992)) (internal marks omitted);
    see also Wal-Mart Stores, Inc. v. Dukes, 
    131 S. Ct. 2541
    ,
    2559-60 (2011) (noting that employees who no longer
    worked for Wal-Mart lacked standing to seek injunctive or
    declaratory relief against Wal-Mart‘s employment practices).
    Applying those principles to our case, we hold that
    Plaintiffs lack standing to seek an injunction. They clearly
    have standing to seek damages based on Eaton‘s violation of
    90
    the antitrust laws while ZF Meritor and Meritor were
    competitors.     However, the ZF Meritor joint venture
    operationally dissolved in 2003, Meritor stopped
    manufacturing HD transmissions in 2006, and Meritor has
    expressed no concrete desire to revive the joint venture or
    otherwise reenter the market. The sole evidence in the record
    of Meritor‘s future intentions is found in one page of trial
    testimony, in which a Meritor official stated that there had
    been internal discussions at the company about the possibility
    of reentry, but that no decision had been made. The official
    testified that Meritor ―continue[d] to monitor the performance
    of the products that are in the marketplace[,] . . . ha[d] a very
    thorough understanding of how the products [we]re
    working[,] . . . and [was] actively considering what [its]
    alternatives might be.‖ He explained, however, that upon any
    attempt to reenter, Meritor would be confronted with the
    ―same obstacle that caused the dissolution of the joint
    venture.‖30
    As the District Court acknowledged, this evidence
    establishes no more than a ―possibility‖ that Meritor might
    one day reenter the market. Where the District Court went
    30
    In a post-trial status conference, the District Court
    asked Plaintiffs‘ counsel why an injunction would be
    appropriate given that Plaintiffs were no longer in the
    business. Plaintiffs‘ counsel could give no more concrete
    information about Plaintiffs‘ plans than the witness, stating
    simply that, if Eaton‘s conduct was enjoined, ―a different set
    of calculations‖ would apply to Plaintiffs‘ discussions
    regarding reentry into the market.
    91
    wrong, however, was in concluding that such a possibility is
    sufficient to confer Article III standing for injunctive relief.
    See McCray v. Fidelity Nat’l Ins. Co., 
    682 F.3d 229
    , 242-43
    (3d Cir. 2012) (―Allegations of possible future injury are not
    sufficient to satisfy Article III.‖) (internal marks and citation
    omitted). Plaintiffs were required to set forth sufficient facts
    to show that they were entitled to prospective relief, including
    that they were ―likely to suffer future injury.‖ McNair v.
    Synapse Grp. Inc., 
    672 F.3d 213
    , 223 (3d Cir. 2012) (citation
    omitted) (emphasis added); see McCray, 682 F.3d at 243
    (explaining that ―a threatened injury must be certainly
    impending and proceed with a high degree of certainty‖)
    (internal marks and citation omitted). Absent a showing that
    they are likely to reenter the market and again be confronted
    with Eaton‘s exclusionary practices, Plaintiffs were ―no more
    entitled to an injunction‖ than any other entity that has
    considered the possibility of entering the HD transmissions
    market. Lyons, 
    461 U.S. at 111
    . ―Vague‖ assertions of
    desire, ―without any descriptions of concrete plans,‖ are
    insufficient to support a finding of actual or imminent injury.
    See Summers, 
    555 U.S. at 496
    . Although Plaintiffs claim that
    they might again enter the market, such a decision ―w[ould]
    be their choice, and what that choice may be is a matter of
    pure speculation at this point.‖ McNair, 672 F.3d at 225.
    Plaintiffs seem to suggest that there is a lower
    threshold for standing in antitrust cases.31   However,
    31
    Specifically, Plaintiffs argue that the appropriate
    standard is found in Section 16 of the Clayton Act, which
    provides that any person ―shall be entitled to sue for and have
    92
    Plaintiffs confuse the doctrines of constitutional standing and
    antitrust standing. Although the doctrines often overlap in
    practice, they are, in fact, distinct. Sullivan v. D.B. Invs., Inc.,
    
    667 F.3d 273
    , 307 (3d Cir. 2011). Regardless of any
    additional requirements applicable to a particular type of
    action, a plaintiff must always demonstrate that a justiciable
    case or controversy exists sufficient to invoke the jurisdiction
    of the federal courts. 
    Id.
     Plaintiffs‘ failure to do so here
    renders any inquiry into antitrust (statutory) standing
    unnecessary. See Conte Bros. Auto., Inc. v. Quaker State-
    Slick 50, Inc., 
    165 F.3d 221
    , 225 (3d Cir. 1998).
    We agree with the District Court that there are strong
    public policy reasons for issuing an injunction in this case.
    However, the fact that there may be strong public policy
    reasons for enjoining Eaton‘s behavior does not mean that
    Plaintiffs are the appropriate party to seek such an injunction.
    Standing is a constitutional mandate, Doe v. Nat’l Bd. of Med.
    Exam’rs, 
    199 F.3d 146
    , 152 (3d Cir. 1999), and the
    consequences that flow from a finding of lack of standing
    here, although concerning, cannot affect our analysis.32
    injunctive relief . . . against threatened loss or damage by a
    violation of the antitrust laws . . . when and under the same
    conditions and principles as injunctive relief . . . is granted by
    courts of equity.‖ 
    15 U.S.C. § 26
    .
    32
    Because we conclude that Plaintiffs lack standing to
    pursue injunctive relief, we need not address Plaintiffs‘
    argument that the District Court erred by refusing to allow
    them to address the scope of injunctive relief.
    93
    IV. CONCLUSION
    First, we hold that Plaintiffs‘ claims are not subject to
    the price-cost test, and instead must be analyzed as de facto
    exclusive dealing claims under the rule of reason. Second,
    we conclude that Plaintiffs presented sufficient evidence to
    support the jury‘s finding that Eaton engaged in
    anticompetitive conduct and that Plaintiffs suffered antitrust
    injury as a result. Third, we find no error in the District
    Court‘s decision to admit DeRamus‘s testimony on the issue
    of liability. Fourth, we hold that the District Court properly
    exercised its discretion in excluding DeRamus‘s damages
    testimony based on his expert report, but we conclude that the
    District Court abused its discretion by preventing DeRamus
    from submitting alternate damages calculations based on data
    already included in his initial report. Finally, we hold that
    Plaintiffs lack standing to pursue injunctive relief, and
    therefore, we will vacate the injunction issued by the District
    Court. We will remand to the District Court for further
    proceedings consistent with this opinion.
    94
    Greenberg, Circuit Judge, dissenting
    Notwithstanding the majority‟s thoughtful and well-
    crafted opinion, I respectfully dissent as I would reverse the
    District Court‟s order that it entered following its opinion
    reported at ZF Meritor LLC v. Eaton Corp., 
    769 F. Supp. 2d 684
    (D. Del 2011), denying Eaton‟s motion for judgment as a matter
    of law. Although the majority opinion recites in detail the
    factual background of this case, I nevertheless also set forth its
    factual predicate as I believe the inclusion of certain additional
    facts demonstrates even more clearly than the facts the majority
    sets forth why Eaton was entitled to judgment as a matter of
    law.1
    I. FACTS
    A. The HD Transmission Market
    The parties stipulated before the District Court and do not
    now dispute that the relevant product market in this case is
    heavy-duty (“HD”) truck transmissions and that the relevant
    geographic market is the United States, Canada, and Mexico, the
    so-called “NAFTA market.” On appeal, Eaton does not dispute
    1
    Throughout this dissent I use the same standard of review that
    the majority sets forth. Thus while I am exercising plenary
    review of the order denying the motion for a judgment as a
    matter of law within that review I am being deferential to the
    jury verdict.
    1
    that it possessed monopoly power in that market during the
    events relevant to this case.
    HD trucks include linehaul trucks, the familiar 18-
    wheelers used to travel long distances on highways, and
    performance trucks used on unfinished terrain or to carry heavy
    loads, such as cement mixers, garbage trucks, and dump trucks.
    There are three types of HD truck transmissions: manual,
    automatic, and automated mechanical.
    As the majority indicates, the NAFTA HD truck
    transmission market functions in the following way. Original
    Equipment Manufacturers (“OEMs”) construct HD trucks.
    There were four OEMs during the period relevant to this
    dispute: Freightliner Trucks (“Freightliner”); International Truck
    and Engine Corporation (“International”); PACCAR; and Volvo
    Group (“Volvo”). OEMs provide the purchasers of HD trucks
    with “data books” that list HD truck component part options,
    including transmissions, and thereby allow the customer to
    select from various options for certain parts of the HD trucks.
    The data books list one option as the “standard” offering
    with which OEMs will fit the truck unless the customer selects
    otherwise. Additionally, the component part listed in the data
    book as the lowest-priced option is referred to as the so-called
    “preferred” or “preferentially-priced” option.2 For obvious
    2
    “Standard” and “preferred” positioning are not the same thing.
    See J.A. at 2546 (PACCAR and Eaton‟s LTA) (stating that
    PACCAR will list Eaton‟s product “as Standard Equipment and
    the Preferred Option,” whereas “„Standard Equipment‟ means
    2
    reasons, positioning as the standard or preferred component part
    option in a data book can be beneficial and a form of promotion
    of the parts that the component part manufacturers supply.
    Evidence adduced at trial, which I explore further below, shows
    that OEMs decide which component parts to list as standard or
    preferred based, at least in part, on their determination of which
    component part is the most advantageous option for them to
    supply in terms of such factors as cost of supply pricing as to the
    OEMs and the availability and performance of the product.
    Consequently, the OEMs and component part manufacturers
    negotiate with respect to data book positioning.
    Data books, however, are not the exclusive means of
    advertising HD truck transmissions or other parts nor do they
    restrict the truck purchasers‟ choices. Component suppliers,
    such as appellees3 and Eaton, market directly to purchasers, and
    purchasers of HD trucks can and do request unpublished options
    that are not listed in the data books.
    B. The Parties and Market Conditions
    During the 1950s, Eaton began manufacturing
    transmissions for HD trucks, and eventually it developed a full
    the equipment that is provided to a customer unless the customer
    expressly designates another supplier‟s product” and “„Preferred
    Option‟ means the lowest priced option in the Data Book for
    comparable products”).
    3
    I refer to the plaintiffs as appellees even though they are also
    appellants in these consolidated appeals.
    3
    product line of transmissions in a range of speeds and styles.
    Prior to 1989, Eaton was the only domestic manufacturer of HD
    truck transmissions. In 1989, however, Meritor entered the
    market with 9- and 10-speed HD manual transmissions for
    linehaul trucks. But, unlike Eaton, Meritor did not offer nor did
    it develop at any point a full product line of HD truck
    transmissions. Nevertheless, by 1999 Meritor had obtained
    approximately 18% of the market for sales of HD truck
    transmissions in North America.
    In 1999, Meritor entered into a joint venture with ZF
    Freidrichshafen (“ZF AG”), a large German company that
    previously had not sold HD truck transmissions in North
    America. The joint venture, called ZF Meritor (“ZFM”), sought
    to adapt for the NAFTA market ZF AG‟s “ASTronic”
    transmission, a linehaul 12-speed, 2-pedal, automated
    mechanical transmission. Meritor transferred its transmission
    business to ZFM, and ZFM introduced the ASTronic (renamed
    the “FreedomLine” for the NAFTA market) to these new
    markets around February 2001. At that time, Eaton did not have
    a two-pedal automated mechanical transmission and did not
    intend to release one until 2004. Appellees believe that the
    FreedomLine was technically superior to other HD truck
    transmissions available.
    In late 1999, during the same time period that appellees
    formed ZFM, there was a severe economic downturn in the
    NAFTA market area that caused a sharp decline of HD truck
    orders. By 2001, around the time ZFM introduced the
    FreedomLine, HD truck orders had fallen by approximately
    50%, with demand plummeting from more than 300,000 new
    4
    HD truck orders per year to roughly 150,000 orders.
    C. The Long-Term Agreements
    In the 1980s and 1990s, Eaton entered into supply
    agreements with each of the four OEMs. These agreements set
    the prices for Eaton‟s transmissions and offered volume
    discounts to the OEMs, i.e., discounted prices based on the
    OEMs‟ purchase of a certain quantity of transmissions.
    Appellees do not allege that these agreements violated the
    antitrust laws. Beginning in late 2000, however, Eaton entered
    into new supply agreements with all four of the OEMs. Those
    agreements, to which the parties refer as long-term agreements
    (“LTAs”), are at the core of the present dispute.
    Eaton‟s LTAs offered the OEMs rebates based on
    market-share targets. The discounts thus provided the OEMs
    with lower prices on Eaton‟s transmissions conditioned on their
    purchase of a certain percentage of their transmission needs
    from Eaton. Although the LTAs‟ terms varied, all of the LTAs
    at issue were consistent in two respects.
    First, the LTAs were not explicitly exclusive-dealing
    contracts: each OEM remained free to buy parts from any other
    HD transmission manufacturer, including ZFM, and none of the
    LTAs conditioned Eaton‟s payment of rebates on an OEM‟s
    purchase of 100% of its transmission needs from it. Second,
    each LTA contained a so-called “competitiveness clause” that
    permitted the OEM to exclude an Eaton product from the share
    target and to terminate its LTA altogether if another
    manufacturer offered transmissions of better quality or lower
    5
    price. Because the LTAs are at the crux of ZFM‟s claims, I
    review those four contracts and the circumstances of their
    formation in some detail.
    1. Freightliner
    As of 1998, both Eaton and Meritor had respective three-
    year supply agreements with Freightliner, the largest of the
    OEMs. Meritor‟s agreement provided that it would reduce the
    price of its component parts if Freightliner listed Meritor‟s parts
    as standard in its data book, while, as I have mentioned, Eaton‟s
    agreement provided volume-discount rebates to Freightliner.
    In October 2000, Freightliner notified Meritor, which by
    then had evolved into ZFM with respect to its transmission
    business, that Eaton had offered it 10-speed transmissions at a
    price significantly lower than Meritor‟s price, Eaton was
    offering certain transmissions that Meritor did not have
    available, and Eaton‟s transmissions were superior to Meritor‟s
    in price and technology. Pursuant to a provision in Meritor‟s
    supply agreement that required Meritor to remain competitive
    with respect to its products in terms of quality and technology,
    Freightliner notified Meritor that it had 90 days within which to
    match Eaton‟s inventory or Freightliner would delete Meritor‟s
    noncompetitive products from the agreement. Though Meritor
    disputed Freightliner‟s contention it did not make a counteroffer
    or offer to match Eaton‟s inventory.
    Soon thereafter, in November 2000, Eaton entered into a
    five-year LTA with Freightliner, one of the four contracts that
    appellees challenge. The LTA provided rebates ranging from
    6
    $200 to $700, contingent on a 92% share target for Eaton‟s
    transmissions and clutches, an additional truck component that
    Eaton manufactured. In 2003, Eaton and Freightliner amended
    the LTA by adopting a sliding scale that entitled Freightliner to
    varying lower rebates if it met lower market-share targets
    beginning at 86.5% and going up to 90.5%.
    In exchange for the discounted prices, the LTA required
    Freightliner to list Eaton‟s transmissions as the “preferred”
    option in its data book. Significantly, however, Freightliner
    “reserve[d] the right to publish” the FreedomLine transmission
    “through the life of the agreement at normal retail price levels.”
    J.A. at 1948. The LTA also provided that in 2002 Freightliner
    would publish Eaton‟s transmissions and clutches in its data
    book exclusively, but the parties amended that provision in 2001
    to allow Freightliner to continue to publish Eaton‟s competitors‟
    products. From 2002 onwards, Freightliner did not list ZFM‟s
    manual transmissions but it continued to list ZFM‟s other
    transmissions from 2000 to 2004. In 2004, however,
    Freightliner removed the FreedomLine from its data books
    because Meritor4 had refused to pay a $1,250 rebate it had
    promised to Freightliner on that product and because
    Freightliner had experienced reliability issues with ZFM‟s
    products. See id. at 3725 (letter from Freightliner representative
    to Meritor representative (Feb. 10, 2004)) (“Freightliner is
    outraged at ArvinMeritor in the handling of the FreedomLine
    transmissions price changes. It is totally unacceptable that
    4
    As explained below, ZFM dissolved in December of 2003, and
    thus Meritor was handling sales of the FreedomLine
    transmission in the NAFTA market as of 2004.
    7
    ArvinMeritor would commit to price protection, and then seek
    to renege on that commitment.”).
    Under the LTA, Eaton had the right to terminate the
    agreement if Freightliner did not meet its share targets. In 2002,
    however, even though Freightliner did not meet the 92% share
    target, Eaton did not terminate the agreement. In 2003, the
    parties amended the LTA so that it would last for a total of ten
    years, extending the agreement to 2010.
    2. International
    Eaton entered into a five-year LTA with International in
    July 2000. A representative from International stated that
    International entered into the LTA because it made “good
    business sense,” id. at 1532, inasmuch as the LTA provided the
    lowest purchase price for International and there was “greater
    customer preference and brand recognition for the Eaton
    product,” id. at 1528.
    In return, Eaton provided a $2.5 million payment to
    International, $1 million of which was payable in cash or in
    cost-savings initiatives. The LTA provided sliding scale rebates
    of 0.35% to 2% beginning at a market share of 80% and up to
    97.5% and above. It also provided for sliding rebates based on a
    market share of Eaton‟s clutches. For current truck models,
    International agreed to list Eaton‟s transmission as the preferred
    option, and for future models, it agreed to publish Eaton‟s
    transmissions exclusively.5        Notwithstanding the latter
    5
    International already had listed Eaton as the standard option as
    8
    provision, International continued to list ZFM‟s manual
    transmissions in its printed data book.
    3. PACCAR
    In July 2000, Eaton entered into a seven-year LTA with
    PACCAR. A PACCAR representative stated that PACCAR
    agreed to the market-share rebates because it “ma[d]e long term
    economic sense and it ha[d] a total value as to PACCAR.” Id. at
    1555. The PACCAR representative indicated that the “total
    value” concept incorporated such considerations as the “lower
    cost” provided by the LTAs, “providing a full product line of . . .
    transmissions,” “providing product during periods of peak
    demand and ensuring the product is available,” “warranty
    provisions,” and “aftermarket supply.” Id. at 1555-56.
    The representative indicated that PACCAR was in
    discussions with ZFM regarding a supply agreement but
    ultimately it declined to enter into an agreement with ZFM
    because, apart from Eaton‟s more appealing offer, ZFM suffered
    from negative considerations such as ZFM‟s restricted output of
    its products, “massive transmission failure in the marketplace
    that caused market unacceptance of their transmissions earlier,”
    and ZFM‟s lack of a full product line. Id. at 1557, 1562.
    Additionally, PACCAR “always [paid] . . . a higher cost [for a
    ZFM product] than a comparable Eaton product, independent of
    the rebate,” particularly for the FreedomLine, which, according
    of 1996 because, according to an International representative,
    Eaton provided the greatest value to International. See J.A. at
    1533.
    9
    to the PACCAR representative, was “by design, a more
    expensive product” because of its European origins. Id. at 1558-
    59. In this regard, the representative stated that Eaton‟s rebates
    were not “the only thing that made them competitive.” Id. at
    1562.
    Under the LTA, Eaton provided price reductions, a $1
    million payment, firm pricing for seven years, and engineering
    and marketing support. PACCAR also could obtain rebates
    ranging from 2% to 3% in exchange for meeting 90% to 95%
    market share targets in both transmissions and clutches. In
    exchange, PACCAR was required to list Eaton as the standard
    and preferred option in its data book. At all times PACCAR
    continued to list ZFM‟s transmissions in its data book.
    4. Volvo
    Eaton entered into a five-year LTA with Volvo in
    October 2002. A Volvo representative stated that Volvo entered
    into the LTA because it represented “the best overall value for
    Volvo” in terms of “price, delivery, quality manufacturing, and
    logistics.” Id. at 1430. Indeed, another Volvo representative
    stated that “[p]ricing was significantly better with Eaton [even]
    excluding rebates.” Id. at 1295; see id. at 1293, 1296 (the same
    representative estimating the savings to Volvo from the LTA
    with Eaton to be about 12% to 15% excluding the rebates and
    stating that Volvo‟s motivation in entering the LTA was “purely
    dollars, dollars and cents”). Volvo was in discussions with ZFM
    to sign a supply agreement, but ultimately it did not do so in
    large part because of ZFM‟s “inability to have a complete
    product offering of all transmissions.” Id. at 1431.
    10
    The LTA provided sliding scale rebates of 0.5% to 1.5%
    originally set at 65% market share, and, as of 2004, a 70% to
    78% market share. Eaton had the option of terminating the LTA
    if its market share at Volvo fell below 68%. In turn, Volvo
    agreed to position Eaton‟s transmissions and clutches as the
    standard and preferred offering. Volvo continued to list in its
    data books both ZFM‟s and Volvo‟s own transmissions that it
    manufactured only for installation in its own trucks.6
    D. ZFM‟s Business and Exit from the Market
    As of July 2000, before Eaton signed any of the
    challenged LTAs, ZFM had lost nearly 20% of its market share
    in transmissions, its share declining from 16.1% to 13%.
    Minutes from a ZFM Board of Directors meeting held in July
    2000 reveal that ZFM‟s President, Richard Martello, identified a
    number of factors that caused ZFM‟s falling market position,
    including:
    (i) poor product quality image, (ii) a decrease in
    Ryder business, (iii) turnover in the [c]ompany‟s
    sales organization, (iv) an increase in sales of
    Eaton Autoshift, (v) the push towards 13-speed
    transmissions, especially by Freightliner, (vi) the
    multi-year fleet business lost due to competitive
    6
    Eaton also entered into an LTA with the OEM Mack Trucks
    that same month. Volvo had acquired Mack Trucks in 2001,
    and it appears that the LTAs are substantively the same.
    Accordingly, I refer only to the Volvo LTA.
    11
    equalization cutbacks in early 1999 and (vii)
    controlled distribution.
    J.A. at 3235.
    Some explanation will illuminate Mr. Martello‟s
    observations.      “Competitive equalization” payments are
    incentives a component manufacturer provides directly to truck
    purchasers for them to select its products from a data book.
    ZFM‟s internal documents, included in the trial record,
    demonstrate that “[d]uring the peak periods of production
    between March 1999 and September 1999, Meritor reduced
    [competitive equalization] payment[s] on deals trying to reduce
    the incentive [to] „war‟ with Eaton” but Eaton “continued . . . to
    buy business when Meritor declined deals.” Id. at 3028.
    “Controlled distribution” refers to the practice of purposefully
    limiting the quantity of a product available to the market — a
    practice that ZFM identified as the cause of it losing “various
    deals” due to ZFM‟s “lack of product” availability. Id. at 3030.
    The reference to ZFM‟s decrease in “Ryder business” appears
    to refer to the fact that ZFM lost the business of the OEM
    previously known as Mack-Ryder due to ZFM‟s controlled
    distribution practices. See id.
    In that same meeting, Mr. Martello also observed that
    there were “significant forces in favor of direct drive, fully
    automated transmissions,” including:
    (i) major engine changes in October 2002 due to
    emissions standards changes, (ii) continued driver
    shortages, (iii) continued upward pressure on fuel
    12
    prices, (iv) market pressure on „guaranteed cost of
    operation‟ sales incentives and (v) continued
    technician shortages.
    Id. at 3236. Significantly, as I already have noted, the
    FreedomLine was an automated mechanical transmission, not a
    fully automated transmission.
    Mr. Martello also noted that the industry was turning
    away from the component part manufacturers‟ traditional focus
    on advertising directly to truck purchasers as an incentive for
    them to select their component part, so-called “pull” advertising,
    to focus instead on “the creation of closer relationships with the
    OEMs.” Id. Along this line, Mr. Martello observed that the
    OEMs desired to have “single source, full product line
    suppliers” in an effort to reduce costs. See id. Additionally, Mr.
    Martello noted that OEMs were resistant to the prospect of
    engineering new products, such as the FreedomLine, into their
    trucks, and that, as sales of HD trucks declined, component part
    manufacturers provided rapidly increasing sales incentives to the
    OEMs. See id. To overcome these obstacles and increase
    ZFM‟s market share, Mr. Martello “recommended that a full
    line of automated products be released at every OEM and that
    [ZFM] develop a full [HD] product line.” Id. at 3237.
    Notwithstanding ZFM‟s awareness of the declining HD
    truck market, after the 2000 meeting ZFM refused to lower its
    prices despite certain OEMs‟ repeated requests that it do so.
    See, e.g., id. at 3596 (letter from Chris Benner, ZFM, to Paul D.
    Barkus, International (Sept. 19, 2002)) (stating ZFM‟s refusal to
    lower prices despite International‟s June 2002 request that it do
    13
    so); id. at 1537-38 (deposition testimony of Paul D. Barkus,
    International) (indicating that ZFM refused International‟s
    request that ZFM lower its prices in December 2001); id. at
    3953 (ZFM Board minutes) (“Board did not agree with
    providing any price decreases to Volvo/Mack.”). To the
    contrary, at the end of 2003, ZFM raised the price of the
    FreedomLine by roughly 25%, an increase that caused
    significant consternation among the OEMs. Moreover, ZFM did
    not develop a full HD truck transmission product line as Mr.
    Martello had recommended. Furthermore, as the majority notes,
    at least two of ZFM‟s transmissions, including its flagship
    transmission, the FreedomLine, experienced significant
    performance problems resulting in frequent repairs, and, in 2002
    and 2003, ZFM faced significant warranty claims on its products
    amounting to millions of dollars in potential liability.
    Notwithstanding the trouble it experienced in 2000, ZFM
    experienced growth in some areas. From 2001 to 2003, the
    FreedomLine transmission went from comprising 0% of the
    linehaul market to 6% of the linehaul market, and between 2000
    and 2003, ZFM‟s market share of linehaul HD truck
    transmissions increased at three of the four OEMs. From July
    2000 to October 2003, ZFM‟s share of the total HD transmission
    market ranged between 8% and 14%.
    In spite of its gains, ZFM believed that Eaton‟s LTAs
    limited ZFM‟s potential market share to approximately 8% of
    the transmission market, not the 30% that it had expected to gain
    as a result of the joint venture and which it needed to achieve for
    the venture to be a viable business. In December 2003, on the
    basis of that calculation, ZFM was dissolved. Following ZFM‟s
    14
    dissolution, Meritor returned to the transmission business it had
    conducted before entering into the joint venture. In 2006,
    however, Meritor exited the HD truck transmission business
    entirely.
    E. Eaton‟s Pricing
    At trial, appellees did not allege or introduce any
    evidence that Eaton priced its transmissions below any measure
    of cost during the relevant time period, and, on appeal, appellees
    do not contend that Eaton‟s prices were below cost.
    Furthermore, at all times relevant to the present dispute, Eaton‟s
    average transmission prices to the OEMs were lower than
    ZFM‟s average prices to the OEMs. In other words, the OEMs
    paid more to purchase and supply ZFM‟s transmissions to the
    truck purchasers than they paid for Eaton‟s transmissions. In
    particular, ZFM priced its FreedomLine significantly above the
    price of Eaton‟s transmissions.
    II. ANALYSIS
    Although it frames the question differently, as the
    majority recognizes the central question that emerges in this
    appeal is what effect, if any, does appellees‟ failure to allege,
    much less prove, that Eaton engaged in below-cost pricing have
    on its claims? Eaton, of course, contends that the effect is
    dispositive, arguing that Supreme Court precedent requires that
    courts apply the price-cost test of Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown
    & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 
    509 U.S. 209
    , 
    113 S.Ct. 2578
    15
    (1993), in any case in which a plaintiff challenges a defendant‟s
    pricing practices.7 Appellees challenged Eaton‟s pricing
    practices, namely, its market-share discounts, but because
    appellees did not introduce evidence that Eaton engaged in
    below-cost pricing, Eaton contends that appellees did not
    establish that they suffered antirust injury nor did they show that
    by adopting the LTAs Eaton violated the antitrust laws.8
    7
    Under the Brooke Group price-cost test, a firm must first
    establish that the defendant‟s prices “are below an appropriate
    measure of its . . . costs,” and second, it must show that the
    defendant “had a reasonable prospect [under § 1 of the Sherman
    Act], or, under § 2 of the Sherman Act, a dangerous probability,
    of recouping its investment in below-cost prices.” 509 U.S. at
    223-24, 113 S.Ct. at 2587-88.
    8
    Apart from meeting the requirements of Article III standing, an
    antitrust plaintiff seeking monetary or injunctive relief must
    show that it has suffered antitrust injury, i.e., an “injury of the
    type that the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that
    flows from that which makes [the] defendant[‟s] acts unlawful.”
    Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 
    429 U.S. 477
    ,
    489, 
    97 S.Ct. 690
    , 697 (1977). Although courts often conflate
    the antitrust injury requirement with the determination of
    whether the defendant‟s conduct violated the antitrust laws, this
    approach is erroneous as the antitrust injury requirement
    assumes the defendant‟s conduct was unlawful (and thus
    anticompetitive) and asks whether the anticompetitive aspect of
    the unlawful conduct is the cause of plaintiff‟s injury. See
    Angelico v. Lehigh Valley Hosp., Inc., 
    184 F.3d 268
    , 275 n.2
    16
    Appellees, of course, contend that their failure to show
    that Eaton engaged in below-cost pricing is entirely irrelevant to
    the success or failure of their claims. Appellees claim that the
    obligation to show below-cost pricing applies only where a
    (3d Cir. 1999) (“The District Court erred by incorporating the
    issue of anticompetitive market effect into its standing analysis,
    confusing antitrust injury with an element of a claim under
    section 1 of the Sherman Act . . . .”); see also Daniel v. Am. Bd.
    of Emergency Med., 
    428 F.3d 408
    , 447-48 (2d Cir. 2005)
    (explaining that anticompetitive effects of defendant‟s behavior
    “are classic „rule of reason‟ questions, distinct from the antitrust
    standing question”) (citations omitted). Because I conclude that
    Eaton was entitled to judgment as a matter of law as there was
    insufficient evidence for the jury‟s conclusion that Eaton
    violated Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act and Section 3 of
    the Clayton Act, I do not address whether appellees satisfied the
    antitrust injury requirement. Accord L.A.P.D., Inc. v. Gen. Elec.
    Corp., 
    132 F.3d 402
    , 404 (7th Cir. 1997) (“Because LAPD
    adequately alleges injury in fact and thus has standing under
    Article III, however, we may bypass the antitrust-injury issue to
    go straight to the merits.”); Hairston v. Pac. 10 Conference, 
    101 F.3d 1315
    , 1318 (9th Cir. 1996) (“[W]e need not decide whether
    appellants have met the requirements for antitrust standing,
    because they have failed to establish any violation of the
    antitrust laws.”); Levine v. Cent. Fl. Med. Affiliates, Inc., 
    72 F.3d 1538
    , 1545 (11th Cir. 1996) (“We need not decide whether
    Dr. Levine has met the requirements for standing as to any of his
    antitrust claims, because as to each one he has failed to establish
    any violation of the antitrust laws.”).
    17
    plaintiff brings a so-called “predatory pricing” claim.9 In this
    regard, appellees contend that they were not required to show
    that Eaton engaged in below-cost pricing because they did not
    bring a “predatory pricing” claim. In fact, appellees explicitly
    disavow any allegation that Eaton engaged in below-cost pricing
    and instead contend that the LTAs, including the market-share
    rebates they contained, amounted to unlawful de facto exclusive
    dealing agreements.10
    The majority appears to split the difference between the
    parties‟ two positions. The majority concludes that the Brooke
    9
    A firm engages in “predatory pricing” when it cuts its prices
    below an appropriate measure of cost to force competitors out of
    the market or to deter potential entrants from entering the
    market. See Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp.,
    
    475 U.S. 574
    , 584 n.8, 
    106 S.Ct. 1348
    , 1355 n.8 (1986). “The
    success of any predatory scheme depends on maintaining
    monopoly power for long enough both to recoup the predator‟s
    losses and to harvest some additional gain.” 
    Id. at 589
    , 
    106 S.Ct. at 1357
     (emphasis in original). Due to the inherently
    speculative nature of such an undertaking, “predatory pricing
    schemes are rarely tried, and even more rarely successful.” 
    Id.
    10
    As the leading antitrust treatise points out, “to be challenged as
    unlawful exclusive dealing, . . . [a] quantity discount program
    would necessarily involve prices above cost, else the program
    would not be sustainable.” Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert
    Hovenkamp, Fundamentals of Antitrust Law § 18.03b, at 18-70
    (4th ed. 2011).
    18
    Group price-cost test may be dispositive in a case where a
    plaintiff brings a claim challenging a defendant‟s pricing
    practices11 and alleges that price itself functioned as the
    exclusionary tool. I agree completely with the majority‟s
    conclusion in this regard. Thereafter, however, our paths
    diverge because the majority appears to conclude that where a
    plaintiff brings a claim of unlawful exclusive dealing against a
    defendant‟s pricing practices but does not contend that the
    defendant‟s prices operated as the exclusionary tool, the price-
    cost test is irrelevant and has neither dispositive nor persuasive
    effect.12
    As I explain further below, while I do not believe that the
    Supreme Court has held that the inferior courts must impose and
    give dispositive effect to the Brooke Group price-cost test in
    every claim challenging a defendant‟s pricing practices, the
    11
    Throughout this opinion I use the term “pricing practices” to
    encompass the variety of ways in which a firm may set its
    prices, including but not limited to, straightforward price cuts
    and conditional rebates or discounts.
    12
    I recognize that the majority states that Eaton‟s low prices are
    not irrelevant to the extent they may help explain why the OEMs
    entered the LTAs even though the LTAs allegedly included
    terms that were unfavorable to the OEMs and to rebut an
    argument that the agreements were inefficient but the majority
    does not factor the circumstance that Eaton‟s prices were above
    cost into its analysis of whether the LTAs were exclusionary and
    anticompetitive, and I believe its failure to do so is error.
    19
    Court‟s unwavering adherence to the general principle that
    above-cost pricing practices are not anticompetitive and its
    justifications for that position lead me to conclude that this
    principle is a cornerstone of antitrust jurisprudence that applies
    regardless of whether the plaintiff focuses its claim on the price
    or non-price aspects of the defendant‟s pricing program. Thus,
    although the price-cost test may not bar a claim of exclusive
    dealing challenging a defendant‟s above-cost pricing practices,
    regardless of how a plaintiff casts its claim or the non-price
    elements of the pricing practices that the plaintiff identifies as
    the exclusionary conduct, where a plaintiff attacks a defendant‟s
    pricing practices — and to be clear that is what the market-share
    rebate programs at issue here are — the fact that defendant‟s
    prices were above-cost must be a high barrier to the plaintiff‟s
    success. Accordingly, I believe that we must apply the Brooke
    Group price-cost test to the present case and give that test
    persuasive effect in the context of our broader analysis under the
    antitrust laws at issue.
    Allowing appellees that opportunity, the majority
    concludes that the plaintiffs adduced sufficient evidence at trial
    from which a jury reasonably could infer that the LTAs
    represented unlawful “de facto partial exclusive dealing.”13 In
    13
    I cannot utilize this phrase without making the point that where
    a court permits a non-exclusive, non-mandatory supply
    agreement to morph into a mandatory exclusive-dealing contract
    to legitimize a plaintiff‟s claim of unlawful “de facto partial
    exclusive dealing” the court follows antitrust plaintiffs down the
    rabbit hole a bit too far. While “de facto partial exclusive
    dealing” is a creative neologism, the phrase not only distorts the
    20
    doing so, the majority concludes that despite the fact that the
    LTAs by their terms were not exclusive nor mandatory and
    despite the fact that the prices offered under them were at all
    times above-cost such that an equally-efficient competitor could
    have matched them, they were de facto partial exclusive dealing
    contracts because Eaton was a dominant supplier, the OEMs
    could not have afforded to lose Eaton as a supplier, and thus, the
    majority reasons, the OEMs were compelled to enter the LTAs
    and meet their market-share targets. The majority reaches its
    English language (in what other realm would one refer to a
    contract as “partially exclusive”?), it takes us so far from the
    text of Section 3 of the Clayton Act and the actual concept of
    exclusive dealing that I shudder to think what will be labeled as
    exclusive dealing next.
    The majority concedes that “partial exclusive dealing is
    rarely a valid antitrust theory.” Typescript at 43 (internal
    quotation marks omitted). Indeed, the only thing rarer may be
    what appellees actually allege here: “de facto partial exclusive
    dealing.” I am not aware of any Supreme Court or court of
    appeals precedent recognizing such a claim, and a Westlaw
    search of the phrase reveals only one other case recognizing the
    concept as a viable antitrust claim. In a sign that we truly have
    come full circle, that case is a class action pending in the United
    States District Court for the District of Delaware brought by
    truck purchasers against Eaton, the four OEMs, and a handful of
    other entities, alleging that the same LTAs at issue here violated
    Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act and Section 3 of the
    Clayton Act. See Wallach v. Eaton Corp., 
    814 F. Supp. 2d 428
    ,
    442-43 (D. Del. 2011).
    21
    conclusion despite the absence of evidence in the record
    suggesting that Eaton would have refused to supply
    transmissions to the OEMs had the OEMs failed to meet the
    LTAs‟ market-share targets or that Eaton at any point coerced
    the OEMs into entering the LTAs or meeting the targets. For
    reasons I set forth more fully below, I cannot join my colleagues
    in this judicial reworking of the LTAs and the unbridled
    speculation the majority‟s reasoning requires to convert the
    LTAs into exclusive dealing contracts. Even analyzing
    appellees‟ claims under the rule of reason and the principles
    used to ascertain whether an exclusive-dealing arrangement is
    lawful and employing the deferential standard of review to
    which we subject jury verdicts, it is plain that the agreements
    could not have been and in fact were not anticompetitive.
    A. The Supreme Court‟s Treatment of Antitrust Challenges to
    Pricing Practices
    Beginning with Cargill, Inc. v. Monfort of Colorado, Inc.,
    
    479 U.S. 104
    , 
    107 S.Ct. 484
     (1986), the Supreme Court in a
    series of cases considering antitrust challenges to pricing
    practices has made clear that as a general matter above-cost
    pricing practices do not threaten competition. In Cargill, the
    Court considered whether Monfort, a beef-packing business, had
    shown antitrust injury to the end that it had standing to challenge
    the merger of two of its competitors that allegedly violated
    Section 7 of the Clayton Act. See 
    id. at 106-09
    , 
    107 S.Ct. at 487-88
    . Monfort presented two theories of antitrust injury: “(1)
    a threat of a loss of profits stemming from the possibility that . .
    . [defendant], after the merger, would lower its prices to a level
    at or only slightly above its costs” and “(2) a threat of being
    22
    driven out of business by the possibility that . . . [defendant],
    after the merger, would lower its prices to a level below its
    costs.” 
    Id. at 114
    , 
    107 S.Ct. at 491
    .
    The Court rejected Monfort‟s first theory of injury,
    stating “the antitrust laws do not require the courts to protect
    small businesses from the loss of profits due to continued
    competition, but only against the loss of profits from practices
    forbidden by the antitrust laws.” 
    Id. at 116
    , 
    107 S.Ct. at 492
    .
    Because the defendant‟s above-cost “competition for increased
    market share” was not “activity forbidden by the antitrust laws”
    but rather constituted “vigorous competition,” Monfort could
    not demonstrate antitrust injury under its first theory. 
    Id.
     In this
    regard, the Court noted that “[t]o hold that the antitrust laws
    protect competitors from the loss of profits due to such price
    competition would, in effect, render illegal any decision by a
    firm to cut prices in order to increase market share.” 
    Id.
     The
    antitrust laws, the Court noted, “require no such perverse result”
    because “[i]t is in the interest of competition to permit dominant
    firms to engage in vigorous competition, including price
    competition.” 
    Id.
     (internal quotation marks and citation
    omitted). The Court rejected Monfort‟s second claim that the
    defendant would engage in below-cost, i.e. predatory pricing,
    following the merger because Monfort had failed to raise and
    failed to adduce adequate proof of that claim before the district
    court. See 
    id. at 118-19
    , 
    107 S.Ct. at 494
    .
    Four years later, in Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA
    Petroleum Co., 
    495 U.S. 328
    , 
    110 S.Ct. 1884
     (1990), the Court
    reiterated that above-cost pricing practices generally are not
    anticompetitive, this time in the context of Section 1 of the
    23
    Sherman Act. In Atlantic Richfield, USA Petroleum Company
    (“USA”), an independent retail marketer of gasoline, alleged
    that its competitor, Atlantic Richfield Company (“ARCO”),
    which sold gasoline through its own stations and indirectly
    through dealers, violated Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act
    through a price-fixing scheme that set gasoline prices at below-
    market but above-cost levels through its offer of short-term
    discounts, such as volume discounts, and the elimination of
    credit-card sales to its dealers. See 
    id. at 331-32
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1887-88
    . Only USA‟s Section 1 claim was before the Court, see
    
    id.
     at 333 n.3, 
    110 S.Ct. at
    1888 n.3, and the question presented
    was whether USA had suffered an antitrust injury by virtue of
    ARCO‟s Section 1 violation, see 
    id. at 335
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1889
    .
    At the time, ARCO‟s conduct was regarded as a per se violation
    of Section 1. See 
    id.
     (citing Albrecht v. Herald Co., 
    390 U.S. 145
    , 
    88 S.Ct. 869
     (1968), overruled by State Oil Co. v. Khan,
    
    522 U.S. 3
    , 
    118 S.Ct. 275
     (1997)).
    First, the Court rejected USA‟s claim that it automatically
    satisfied the antitrust injury requirement because ARCO‟s
    conduct constituted a per se violation of Section 1. 
    495 U.S. at 336-37
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1890-91
    . The Court then turned to USA‟s
    alternative claim that even if it was not entitled to a presumption
    of injury, it had suffered injury “because of the low prices
    produced by the vertical restraint.” 
    Id. at 337
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1891
    .
    Rejecting this contention, the Court reasoned that “[w]hen a
    firm, or even a group of firms adhering to a vertical agreement,
    lowers prices but maintains them above predatory levels, the
    business lost by rivals cannot be viewed as an „anticompetitive‟
    consequence of the claimed violation.” 
    Id.
     Such injury, the
    Court concluded, “is not antitrust injury; indeed, „cutting prices
    24
    in order to increase business often is the very essence of
    competition.‟” 
    Id. at 338
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1891
     (emphasis in
    original) (quoting Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co., Ltd. v. Zenith
    Radio Corp., 
    475 U.S. 574
    , 594, 
    106 S.Ct. 1348
    , 1359 (1986)).
    USA argued alternatively that it was “inappropriate to
    require a showing of predatory pricing before antitrust injury
    can be established when the asserted antitrust violation is an
    agreement in restraint of trade illegal under § 1 of the Sherman
    Act, rather than an attempt to monopolize prohibited by § 2.”
    Id. at 338, 
    110 S.Ct. at 1891
    . As the Court noted, “[p]rice fixing
    violates § 1, for example, even if a single firm‟s decision to
    price at the same level would not create § 2 liability” because
    “the price agreement itself is illegal.” Id. at 338, 
    110 S.Ct. at 1891
    . USA contended that therefore it had “suffered antitrust
    injury even if [ARCO‟s] pricing was not predatory under § 2 of
    the Sherman Act.” Id. at 339, 
    110 S.Ct. at 1891
    .
    In a passage that is significant in the context of the
    present case, the Court also rejected that contention. It
    explained:
    Although a vertical, maximum-price-fixing
    agreement is unlawful under § 1 of the Sherman
    Act, it does not cause a competitor antitrust injury
    unless it results in predatory pricing. Antitrust
    injury does not arise for purposes of § 4 of the
    Clayton Act, until a private party is adversely
    affected by an anticompetitive aspect of the
    defendant‟s conduct; in the context of pricing
    practices only predatory pricing has the requisite
    25
    anticompetitive effect. Low prices benefit
    consumers regardless of how those prices are set,
    and so long as they are above predatory levels,
    they do not threaten competition. Hence, they
    cannot give rise to antitrust injury.
    Id. at 339-40, 
    110 S.Ct. at 1891-92
     (citations omitted and some
    emphasis added).
    The Court observed that it had “adhered to this principle
    regardless of the type of antitrust claim involved.” 
    Id. at 340
    ,
    
    110 S.Ct. at
    1892 (citing Cargill, 
    479 U.S. at 116
    , 
    107 S.Ct. at 492
    ; Brunswick Corp., 
    429 U.S. at 487
    , 
    97 S.Ct. at 696
    ).14 The
    14
    As did Cargill, Brunswick Corp. involved a competitor‟s
    antitrust challenge to an allegedly illegal acquisition under
    Section 7 of the Clayton Act because it would have brought a
    “„deep pocket‟ parent into a market of „pygmies.‟” 
    429 U.S. at 487
    , 
    97 S.Ct. at 697
    . The Court concluded that the plaintiff
    could not show antitrust injury based on the losses it would
    suffer from that acquisition because the aspect of the merger that
    made it unlawful did not cause the plaintiff‟s losses. See 
    id.
    The majority interprets the Supreme Court‟s statement it
    had adhered to the principle that “in the context of pricing
    practices only predatory pricing has the requisite anticompetitive
    effect” “regardless of the type of antitrust claim involved” to
    mean “that the price-cost test applies regardless of the statute
    under which a pricing practice claim is brought, not that the
    price-cost [test] applies regardless of the type of anticompetitive
    conduct.” Typescript at 38 n.13. While the Supreme Court‟s
    26
    Court noted that although “the source of the price competition in
    [Atlantic Richfield] was an agreement allegedly unlawful under
    § 1 of the Sherman Act rather than a merger in violation of § 7
    of the Clayton Act . . . that difference [wa]s not salient . . .
    [because] [w]hen prices are not predatory, any losses flowing
    from them cannot be said to stem from an anticompetitive aspect
    of the defendant‟s conduct.” 
    495 U.S. at 340-41
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1892
     (emphasis in original).
    statement undoubtedly makes clear that the principle that above-
    cost pricing is not anticompetitive applies regardless of which
    provision of the antitrust laws is at issue, I believe that the
    Court‟s rather clear statement that it had adhered to this
    principle “regardless of the type of antitrust claim involved”
    means exactly what it says — that whether the plaintiff
    challenges a defendant‟s pricing practices in the context of a
    challenge to an allegedly unlawful merger or whether it does so
    in the context of a claim that a defendant has entered a price-
    fixing agreement a plaintiff cannot contend that the prices
    resulting from those arrangements are anticompetitive unless
    they are below cost. While I do not believe that the Court‟s
    statement in this regard requires that the price-cost test apply
    with dispositive force in every challenge to a defendant‟s pricing
    practices because there may be other elements of a defendant‟s
    conduct that are anticompetitive notwithstanding its above-cost
    prices, the Court‟s reasoning undoubtedly lends support to my
    conclusion that the price-cost test must factor into a court‟s
    decision when it is asked to judge the lawfulness of such a
    defendant‟s rebate program.
    27
    It is, of course, important to understand the significance
    of Cargill and Atlantic Richfield in the context of this case.
    Cargill and Atlantic Richfield involved the question of whether
    the plaintiffs had suffered antitrust injury, not whether above-
    cost pricing practices ever can violate Sections 1 and 2 of the
    Sherman Act or Section 3 of the Clayton Act. Indeed, at the
    time the Court decided Atlantic Richfield, vertical, maximum-
    price-fixing schemes were regarded as per se illegal under
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act, and the Court assumed in its
    analysis that even the above-cost scheme at issue in Atlantic
    Richfield was illegal under Section 1.
    Nevertheless, though it was writing in the context of the
    antitrust injury requirement for the actions, the Court in Cargill
    and Atlantic Richfield forcefully rejected the notion that the
    above-cost pricing practices at issue threatened competition at
    all. See Atl. Richfield, 
    495 U.S. at 340
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1892
     (“[S]o
    long as [prices] are above predatory levels, they do not threaten
    competition.”); Cargill, 
    479 U.S. at 116
    , 
    107 S.Ct. at 492
    (stating that Cargill‟s above-cost pricing practices aimed at
    increasing its market share was not “activity forbidden by the
    antitrust laws”) (emphasis added). Because the antitrust laws at
    issue in this case require to fix liability on it that Eaton‟s
    behavior present a probable threat to or actually negatively
    impact competition in the relevant marketplace, these
    pronouncements are important here and should bear on our
    consideration of the question of whether the particular pricing
    practices involved in this case are anticompetitive and thus
    violate the antitrust laws.
    Along this same line, other courts of appeals have looked
    28
    to Atlantic Richfield‟s discussion of above-cost pricing practices
    not only in the context of considering whether the plaintiff has
    demonstrated antitrust injury but also in considering whether a
    defendant‟s conduct violates the antitrust laws. See Cascade
    Health Solutions v. PeaceHealth, 
    515 F.3d 883
    , 902-03 (9th Cir.
    2008) (relying on Atlantic Richfield, among other cases, to hold
    that bundled discounts are not exclusionary conduct under
    Section 2 of the Sherman Act unless the discounts result in
    below-cost pricing); Virgin Atl. Airways Ltd. v. British Airways
    PLC, 
    257 F.3d 256
    , 269 (2d Cir. 2001) (stating in the context of
    a challenge to a volume-discount program that “[a]s long as low
    prices remain above predatory levels, they neither threaten
    competition nor give rise to antitrust injury”) (citing Atl.
    Richfield, 
    495 U.S. at 340
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1892
    ) (emphasis added);
    Concord Boat Corp. v. Brunswick Corp., 
    207 F.3d 1039
    , 1060-
    61 (8th Cir. 2000) (relying on Atlantic Richfield in concluding
    that defendant had not violated Section 2 through its above-cost
    market-share discounts). Similarly, the Supreme Court has
    invoked Atlantic Richfield‟s discussion of below-cost pricing
    practices in considering whether pricing practices violate the
    antitrust laws.
    Indeed, three years after it decided Atlantic Richfield, the
    Court reemphasized this principle in concluding that below-cost
    pricing was necessary to establish liability under Section 2 of the
    Clayton Act in an attack on a defendant‟s pricing practices. In
    Brooke Group, Liggett, a generic cigarette manufacturer, alleged
    that Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corporation (“B&W”)
    violated Section 2 of the Clayton Act when it offered below-cost
    price-cuts and volume rebates on “orders of very substantial
    size” to its wholesalers on B&W‟s generic cigarettes in an effort
    29
    to reverse decreasing sales of its branded cigarettes. 509 U.S. at
    216-17, 113 S.Ct. at 2584. The Court stated that “whether the
    claim alleges predatory pricing under § 2 of the Sherman Act or
    primary-line price discrimination under the Robinson-Patman
    Act, . . . , a plaintiff seeking to establish competitive injury
    resulting from a rival‟s low prices must prove that the prices
    complained of are below an appropriate measure of its rival‟s
    costs” and “that the competitor had a reasonable prospect, or
    under § 2 of the Sherman Act, a dangerous probability, of
    recouping its investment in below-cost prices.” Id. at 222-24,
    113 S.Ct. at 2587-88 (emphasis added). Because Liggett had
    failed to provide sufficient evidence that B&W had a reasonable
    prospect of recouping its allegedly predatory losses, the Court
    concluded that B&W was entitled to judgment as a matter of
    law. See id. at 243, 113 S.Ct. at 2598.
    Importantly, in explaining the dual requirements set forth
    above, the Court noted that it had “rejected elsewhere the notion
    that above-cost prices that are below general market levels or
    the costs of a firm‟s competitors inflict injury to competition
    cognizable under the antitrust laws.” Id. at 223, 113 S.Ct. at
    2588 (citing Atl. Richfield, 
    495 U.S. at 340
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1892
    ).
    In this connection, the Court reiterated Atlantic Richfield‟s
    principle that “„[l]ow prices benefit consumers regardless of
    how those prices are set, and so long as they are above predatory
    levels, they do not threaten competition . . . regardless of the
    type of antitrust claim involved.‟” 
    Id.
     (quoting Atl. Richfield,
    
    495 U.S. at 340
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1892
    ). The Court observed:
    As a general rule, the exclusionary effect
    of prices above a relevant measure of cost either
    30
    reflects the lower cost structure of the alleged
    predator, and so represents competition on the
    merits, or is beyond the practical ability of a
    judicial tribunal to control without courting
    intolerable risks of chilling legitimate price-
    cutting.
    509 U.S. at 223, 113 S.Ct. at 2588.
    The Court again rejected an attack on above-cost pricing
    practices with its decision in Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-
    Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 
    549 U.S. 312
    , 320-21, 
    127 S.Ct. 1069
    , 1075 (2007). Weyerhaeuser involved the unusual
    situation in which there was an allegation of “predatory
    bidding,” meaning that a firm with monopoly buying power on
    the supply side drives up the price of that input to levels at
    which a competitor cannot compete. 
    Id. at 320
    , 
    127 S.Ct. at 1075
    . Once the monopolist has caused competing buyers to exit
    the market for the input, “it will seek to restrict its input
    purchases below the competitive level, thus reduc[ing] the unit
    price for the remaining input[s] it purchases[,]” thereby allowing
    the monopolist to reap profits that will offset any losses it
    suffered in bidding up the input prices. 
    Id. at 320-21
    , 
    127 S.Ct. at 1075-76
    . The issue was whether a plaintiff alleging that a
    defendant engaged in such conduct was required to demonstrate
    that the defendant engaged in below-cost pricing through the
    alleged predatory bidding on the supply side. Due to the
    theoretical and practical similarities between a claim of
    predatory pricing and a claim of predatory bidding, the Court
    concluded that its Brooke Group test applies to predatory
    bidding claims under Section 2 just as the test applies to Section
    31
    2 predatory pricing claims. See 
    id. at 325
    , 
    127 S.Ct. at 1078
    .
    In doing so, the Court noted that in Brooke Group it had
    been “particularly wary of allowing recovery for above-cost
    price cutting because allowing such claims could, perversely,
    „chil[l] legitimate price cutting,‟ which directly benefits
    consumers.” 
    Id. at 319
    , 
    127 S.Ct. at 1074
     (quoting Brooke Grp.,
    509 U.S. at 223-24, 113 S.Ct. at 2588). Accordingly, the Court
    had “specifically declined to allow plaintiffs to recover for
    above-cost price cutting, concluding that „discouraging a price
    cut and . . . depriving consumers of the benefits of lower prices .
    . . does not constitute sound antitrust policy.‟” Id., 
    127 S.Ct. at 1074-75
     (quoting Brooke Grp., 509 U.S. at 224, 113 S.Ct. at
    2588).
    Most recently in Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. Linkline
    Communications, Inc., 
    555 U.S. 438
    , 
    129 S.Ct. 1109
     (2009), the
    Court extended this principle to “price squeeze” claims. Price
    squeeze claims allege that a “vertically integrated firm [that]
    sells inputs at wholesale and also sells finished goods or services
    at retail” has “simultaneously raise[d] the wholesale price of
    inputs and cut the retail price of the finished good” thereby
    “squeezing the profit margins of any competitors in the retail
    market,” and forcing the competitors to “pay more for the inputs
    they need . . . [and] cut their retail prices to match the other
    firm‟s prices.” 
    Id. at 442
    , 129 S.Ct. at 1114. The Court noted
    that “[t]o avoid chilling aggressive price competition, [it] ha[d]
    carefully limited the circumstances under which plaintiffs can
    state a Sherman Act claim by alleging that prices are too low.”
    Id. at 451, 129 S.Ct. at 1120. It reiterated the dual requirements
    of Brooke Group for predatory pricing claims, and noted, once
    32
    more, Atlantic Richfield‟s principle that “so long as [prices] . . .
    are above predatory levels, they do not threaten competition.”
    Id. (quoting Atl. Richfield, 
    495 U.S. at 340
    , 
    110 S.Ct. at 1892
    ).15
    The Supreme Court‟s decisions in the above cases require
    that inferior courts recognize that in general above-cost pricing
    practices are not anticompetitive and thus do not violate the
    antitrust laws. Time and time again, the Court has made clear
    that above-cost pricing practices generally do not threaten
    competition in the marketplace. Accord Cascade Health
    Solutions, 515 F.3d at 901 (observing in the context of challenge
    to bundled discount program that Brooke Group and
    Weyerhaeuser “strongly suggest that, in the normal case, above-
    cost pricing will not be considered exclusionary conduct for
    antitrust purposes”); Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1061
     (stating in
    the context of a challenge to a market-share discount program
    that decisions of the Supreme Court “illustrate the general rule
    that above cost discounting is not anticompetitive”); see also
    Khan, 
    522 U.S. at 15
    , 
    118 S.Ct. at 282
     (“Our interpretation of
    the Sherman Act also incorporates the notion that condemnation
    of practices resulting in lower prices to consumers is „especially
    costly‟ because „cutting prices in order to increase business
    often is the very essence of competition.”) (internal quotation
    15
    An equally important facet of the Court‟s decision in Linkline,
    in a context quite apart from that here, was its holding that a
    plaintiff may not bring a Section 2 Sherman Act price-squeeze
    claim “when the defendant is under no antitrust obligation to sell
    the inputs to the plaintiff in the first place.” 555 U.S. at 442,
    129 S.Ct. at 1115.
    33
    marks and citation omitted).
    As the majority notes, it is also clear that the conditional
    nature of the price cuts or the fact that the prices and the
    conditions were memorialized in the LTAs does not render the
    precedent that I summarize above inapplicable.16 As noted, both
    Atlantic Richfield and Brooke Group involved conditional
    discounts of another type, namely volume rebates, and surely
    inasmuch as ARCO and B&W both were sophisticated
    companies that dealt in large-scale transactions, they certainly
    explained these discounts and the conditions they placed on
    them to the purchasers of their products whether or not they did
    so in writing. In any event, the purchasers necessarily knew that
    they were receiving the discounts when they were afforded
    16
    As noted, in the case of PACCAR‟s and International‟s
    respective LTAs, Eaton provided up-front cash payments in
    addition to market rebates. Although these payments were not
    in the form of rebates, they cannot be distinguished from the
    market-share rebates because both practices were an avenue for
    Eaton ultimately to provide discounted prices to the OEMs.
    Accord Race Tires Am., Inc. v. Hoosier Racing Tire Corp., 
    614 F.3d 57
    , 79 (3d Cir. 2010) (noting that tire manufacturer‟s offer
    of up-front payments to race sanctioning bodies to select
    manufacturer‟s tires presented no more a coercive threat than an
    offer of lower prices); NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Co., 
    507 F.3d 442
    ,
    452 (6th Cir. 2007) (en banc) (noting that defendant‟s cash
    payments to induce retailers to carry its product solely were
    “nothing more than price reductions offered to the buyers”)
    (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).
    34
    them. These cases thus make apparent that the Court‟s
    reluctance to condemn above-cost pricing practices extends not
    only to direct price cuts but also to conditional pricing practices
    whether or not they are stated in written agreements. The
    principle that above-cost pricing practices generally do not
    threaten competition in the marketplace remains true whether
    the plaintiff casts its claim in the verbiage of “predatory pricing”
    and alleges explicitly that defendant‟s prices are too low or
    whether it realizes it cannot do so because the prices were above
    cost so it instead couches its challenge in the language of
    exclusive dealing and attacks the agreements that offer the low
    prices.
    In practice, however, a defendant‟s pricing practices may
    include both price and non-price elements. Further, I concur in
    the majority‟s conclusion that notwithstanding the Court‟s
    strong pronouncements favoring above-cost price cuts, the
    Supreme Court has not held that in every case in which a
    plaintiff challenges a defendant‟s pricing practices the Brooke
    Group test is dispositive and the plaintiff therefore must
    demonstrate that there has been below-cost pricing to succeed.
    See Cascade Health Solutions, 515 F.3d at 901 (noting that “in
    neither Brooke Group nor Weyerhaeuser did the Court go so far
    as to hold that in every case in which a plaintiff challenges low
    prices as exclusionary conduct the plaintiff must prove that
    those prices were below cost”).17 But where a plaintiff contends
    17
    Likewise, I concur fully with the majority‟s point that a firm
    may engage in anticompetitive conduct without engaging in
    below-cost pricing. The antitrust laws proscribe an array of
    conduct that, of course, does not require as an essential element
    35
    that a defendant‟s prices alone were anticompetitive, the Brooke
    Group price-cost test provides the entire legal framework
    necessary to evaluate that claim because the Brooke Group
    price-cost test is designed to measure whether prices are
    anticompetitive or not. Thus, where a plaintiff challenges a
    defendant‟s pricing practices as exclusive dealing or under any
    other theory of antitrust liability but in fact alleges only that the
    defendant‟s prices themselves operate as the exclusionary or
    anticompetitive tool, the Brooke Group test must apply and have
    dispositive effect.18 My conclusions in this regard largely mirror
    below-cost pricing. For example, tying arrangements, unlawful
    mergers, and price-fixing agreements, to name a few, are all
    practices that may violate the antitrust laws regardless of the
    prices resulting from such conduct. The Supreme Court has
    made clear, however, that where an antitrust plaintiff attacks a
    defendant‟s pricing practices, i.e. price cuts, rebates or the like,
    if those practices result in above-cost prices they generally do
    not threaten competition, regardless of the source or type of
    antitrust claim at issue.
    18
    Appellees rely heavily on LePage‟s Inc. v. 3M, 
    324 F.3d 141
    (3d Cir. 2003) (en banc), and contend that our decision in that
    case precludes the possibility that the price-cost test has any
    applicability outside of the predatory-pricing-claim framework.
    For essentially the same reasons the majority sets forth, I, too,
    believe that LePage‟s must be confined to its facts and in any
    event does not bear on the present factually-distinguishable case.
    LePage‟s dealt with bundled rebates, a practice which we
    analogized to tying arrangements in its exclusive potential and
    36
    which we concluded may exclude an equally efficient but less
    diversified rival even if the bundled rebates resulted in above-
    cost prices. See 
    324 F.3d at 155
     (“The principal anticompetitive
    effect of bundled rebates as offered by 3M is that when offered
    by a monopolist they may foreclose portions of the market to a
    potential competitor who does not manufacture an equally
    diverse group of products and who therefore cannot make a
    comparable offer.”). Above-cost single-product market-share
    discounts, however, do not present the same putative danger of
    excluding an equally efficient but less diversified rival by virtue
    of that rival‟s limited production alone. For this exact reason, as
    I explain in further detail below, the same leading antitrust
    treatise upon which LePage‟s relied to analogize bundled
    rebates to tying concludes that single-product market-share
    discounts are more appropriately likened to straightforward
    price cuts and the Brooke Group price-cost test should control
    challenges to such programs. Thus, I concur with the majority
    that our reasoning in that case necessarily is limited to a single-
    product producer‟s claim that it has been excluded through a
    more-diversified competitor‟s bundled rebate program that
    conditioned discounts on the purchase of products that the
    single-product producer did not offer.
    Additionally, while I believe that LePage‟s‟ bases for
    distinguishing Brooke Group stood on questionable grounds
    when we set them forth nine years ago, as the majority notes the
    Supreme Court‟s subsequent decisions have eviscerated those
    bases and counsel that we do not extend LePage‟s beyond its
    original parameters. Furthermore, in concluding that LePage‟s
    must be confined to its facts, I think it appropriate to point out
    37
    those of the majority.
    Where I part from my colleagues, however, is with their
    conclusion that if a plaintiff challenges a defendant‟s pricing
    that there has been considerable academic criticism of our
    opinion in that case. See, e.g., J. Shahar Billbary, Predatory
    Bundling and the Exclusionary Standard, 
    67 Wash. & Lee L. Rev. 1231
    , 1246 (Fall 2010) (“[T]he main problem with the
    LePage‟s test is that it does not investigate whether a bundled
    discount is pro-competitive. . . . [It] may in fact protect a less
    efficient competitor (as LePage‟s admitted to be.”); Richard A.
    Epstein, Monopoly Dominance or Level Playing Field? The
    New Antitrust Paradox, 
    72 U. Chi. L. Rev. 49
    , 49, 61-72
    (Winter 2005) (criticizing LePage‟s‟ reasoning and noting that
    the case “shows the deleterious consequences that flow from the
    aggressive condemnation of unilateral practices”). Moreover,
    another court of appeals specifically has declined to follow
    LePage‟s, see Cascade Health Solutions, 515 F.3d at 903. But
    perhaps most significantly, the Antitrust Modernization
    Commission, a statutorily-created bipartisan group tasked with
    evaluating the state of antitrust law and setting forth
    recommendations to Congress and the President for its
    modernization, criticized LePage‟s as potentially “harm[ing]
    consumer welfare,” and proposed instead that courts adopt a
    three-part test modeled after Brooke Group‟s below-cost pricing
    test to evaluate the lawfulness of bundled discounts. See
    Antitrust      Modernization       Comm‟n,        Report      and
    Recommendations          94-99       (2007)      available      at
    http://govinfo.library.unt.edu/amc/report_recommendation/amc_
    final_report.pdf.
    38
    practices but contends that the non-price aspects of defendant‟s
    conduct, rather than the prices themselves, constituted the
    anticompetitive conduct, the price-cost test is no longer relevant.
    While the Supreme Court has not held that the price-cost test is
    dispositive of all claims that attack a defendant‟s pricing
    practices, it is undeniable that its reasoning in the above cases
    establishes that courts ought to exercise a great deal of caution
    before condemning above-cost pricing practices. As the
    majority notes, in the precedent recited above the plaintiffs
    grounded their claims in the allegation that defendant‟s prices
    would cause or had caused them harm. Yet the purpose of my
    summary and my quotation of that precedent in such detail is to
    bear out the fact that the Court‟s holdings rejecting the
    respective plaintiffs‟ challenges in those cases were grounded in
    the fundamental and broader principle that above-cost pricing
    practices, even those embodied in discount and rebate programs
    memorialized in written agreements, generally are not
    anticompetitive and it is that point that is so critical here.
    I believe that it is evident that the Supreme Court‟s
    reasoning with respect to above-costs pricing applies to a
    plaintiff‟s challenge to a defendant‟s pricing practices even if
    the plaintiff claims that the non-price aspects of the defendant‟s
    practices were the actual exclusionary tactics. Regardless of
    what components of Eaton‟s rebate program that appellees
    identify as the anticompetitive conduct, whether it is the prices
    or the conditions that Eaton attached to those prices, the
    question the jury considered at the trial and that we face on
    appeal is whether Eaton‟s rebate program and conduct as a
    whole was procompetitive or anticompetitive. See LePage‟s
    Inc. v. 3M, 
    324 F.3d 141
    , 162 (3d Cir. 2003) (en banc) (“[T]he
    39
    courts must look to the monopolist‟s conduct taken as a whole
    rather than considering each aspect in isolation.”) (citing Cont‟l
    Ore Co. v. Union Carbide & Carbon Corp., 
    370 U.S. 690
    , 699,
    
    82 S.Ct. 1404
     (1962)). Our inquiry in that regard should be an
    objective one that focuses on the facts of the program and our
    answer to that question should not turn on the circumstance that
    appellees had enough foresight specifically not to protest
    Eaton‟s prices.19
    Eaton‟s prices were, of course, the crux of the rebate
    program and are an inextricable element of the LTAs. Although
    appellees conveniently chose to ignore Eaton‟s prices in
    formulating their claims, in light of that economic reality and the
    Supreme Court‟s mandate that the inferior courts tread lightly
    when asked to condemn above-cost pricing practices, the nature
    of those prices must bear on the question of whether Eaton‟s
    rebate program as a whole was anticompetitive or not.
    Accordingly, I believe that if, as here, a plaintiff attacks both the
    price-based and non-priced-based elements of a defendant‟s
    pricing practices, a court should apply and give persuasive effect
    to the Brooke Group price-cost test such that a firm‟s above-cost
    pricing practices enjoy a presumption of lawfulness regardless
    of how a plaintiff crafts its claim challenging the practices. This
    approach honors the Supreme Court‟s repeated admonition that
    19
    In this regard I note that Eaton‟s rebate program existed in the
    same form, above-cost prices and all, on the day before
    appellees filed their claim as on the day after they filed their
    claim.      The program did not undergo an ontological
    transformation because appellees had enough prudence not to
    challenge the price aspects of the program.
    40
    above-cost pricing practices are generally procompetitive and
    that inferior courts must exercise caution before condemning
    such practices. Furthermore, it has the added virtue of injecting
    a modicum of predictability into this muddled area of antitrust
    jurisprudence. This principle is critical in this case.
    I recognize, however, that as is always true with respect
    to any nonconclusive presumption, there may be an exception to
    the presumption of lawfulness of above-cost pricing if a plaintiff
    challenging a defendant‟s above-cost pricing practices
    establishes that the defendant‟s conduct as a whole was
    anticompetitive notwithstanding the pricing aspect of its
    conduct. In this vein, I acknowledge that, as most contracts
    offering large-scale quantity discounts necessarily do, the LTAs
    had other provisions besides the reduced prices themselves,
    namely, the conditions Eaton attached to those reduced prices,
    i.e., the market-share targets and the data book placement
    provisions which appellees attack as anticompetitive. Applying
    and giving persuasive effect to the Brooke Group price-cost test
    would not preclude appellees from arguing that the non-price
    aspects of Eaton‟s conduct were anticompetitive even in the
    absence of below-cost pricing. In practice then, in a case such
    as this one, the Brooke Group price-cost test would operate only
    as one element, though a significant one, of a court‟s and jury‟s
    inquiry under the rule of reason.
    In at least implicitly recognizing the dubious footing of
    an antitrust mode of analysis that hinges entirely on how a
    plaintiff crafts its claim, the majority states that a plaintiff may
    not escape the Brooke Group price-cost test simply by
    characterizing its claim as one of exclusive dealing but it does
    41
    allow the plaintiff to avoid application of the test as long as the
    plaintiff brings an exclusive dealing claim and contends that the
    non-price aspects of the agreement offering the reduced prices
    operated as the exclusionary tool. The result of the majority‟s
    approach is that the strong procompetitive justifications driving
    the Supreme Court‟s repeated charge that inferior courts
    exercise caution before condemning above-cost pricing practices
    suddenly disappear so long as the plaintiff is clever enough to
    claim that the non-price aspects of the defendant‟s pricing
    practices, not the prices themselves, were anticompetitive. I do
    not believe that this is the result the precedent requires or
    prudence counsels.
    I reject the notion that a plaintiff may engage in such
    legalistic maneuvering in an effort to circumvent the Supreme
    Court‟s charge that a court look with a skeptical eye at attacks
    on above-cost pricing practices. The non-price aspects of the
    LTAs which appellees challenge, namely the market-share
    targets and the data book placement provisions, and indeed the
    LTAs themselves would not exist without the reduced prices
    that Eaton offered as an incentive for the OEMs to enter the
    agreements. Conceptually severing the conditions Eaton
    attached to those prices ignores the economic realities of this
    case and allows a plaintiff essentially to commandeer a court‟s
    analysis through artificial distinctions.20 In concluding that the
    20
    Of course, the majority in effect if not intent encourages an
    antitrust plaintiff challenging a defendant‟s above-cost pricing
    practices simply to avoid any mention of defendant‟s prices. In
    light of the majority‟s approach, it would be the rare case indeed
    in which a sophisticated plaintiff would bring an exclusive
    42
    Brooke Group price-cost test at least must have persuasive
    effect in a plaintiff‟s challenge to a defendant‟s pricing practices
    regardless of how a plaintiff casts its claim, I believe it
    appropriate to note that although I stand alone in this case, I
    nonetheless find myself in good company. The leading antitrust
    treatise, on which the majority also relies,21 concludes that
    single-product market-share discounts that do not require
    exclusivity as a condition of the discount are pro-competitive
    and thus lawful so long as they remain above-cost. Because that
    treatise cogently explains why above-cost market-share
    dealing claim against a defendant‟s above-cost pricing practices
    and allege that price itself functioned as the exclusionary tool
    for such a claim necessarily would be ill-fated under the
    majority‟s approach.
    21
    The majority quotes from Areeda and Hovenkamp to explain
    the treatise‟s perspective that a dominant firm may employ
    exclusive-dealing contracts to preclude a young rival‟s
    expansion. I do not doubt the truth of this statement but as I
    note above the treatise takes the position that market-share
    discount programs that do not condition the discount on
    exclusivity, which precisely describes Eaton‟s program, are, in
    fact, not exclusive dealing contracts and should not be treated as
    such. Areeda and Hovenkamp suggest that where a market-
    share discount program conditions the discount on exclusivity
    the standards applicable to exclusive dealing should apply. See
    Fundamentals of Antitrust Law, § 18.03b, at 18-65 (“A discount
    conditioned on exclusivity should generally be treated as no
    different than an orthodox exclusive-dealing arrangement.”).
    43
    discounts are generally not anticompetitive and do not constitute
    unlawful exclusive dealing, I quote it at length:
    [U]nilaterally imposed quantity discounts
    can foreclose the opportunities of rivals when a
    dealer can obtain its best discount only by dealing
    exclusively with the dominant firm. For example,
    discounts might be cumulated over lengthy
    periods of time, such as a calendar year, when no
    obvious economies result.          The effect of
    continuously increasing discounts varies, but they
    can resemble exclusive dealing in extreme
    circumstances.
    Nevertheless, quantity and market share
    discounts differ from exclusive dealing in
    important respects. First, the buyer need not
    make any ex ante commitment of long duration to
    deal with only one firm; as soon as other
    advantages outweigh the discount, the buyer can
    switch simply by paying the nondiscounted price.
    The buyers can also switch if one or more other
    sellers can match the discount. As long as the
    discounted price is above cost and not predatory,
    it can be matched by any equally efficient rival.
    Second, the similarity to exclusive dealing
    is greatest when the product in question is
    fungible, with buyers indifferent to all
    44
    characteristics except price.[22] If the product is
    differentiated, the buyer may wish to purchase a
    mixture from alternative sellers, notwithstanding
    one seller‟s progressive discount. For example,
    an appliance seller who has customer demand for
    four brands of refrigerators is likely to stock all
    four, even though the seller of one offers
    progressive discounts for larger purchases.
    The effective period over which a firm is
    „locked up‟ by a cumulating discount may bear on
    competitive effects, just as contract duration in
    excluding dealing cases. . . . Discounts that are
    aggregated over a longer period — say, over all
    purchases made in one year — may be more
    problematic. First, however, they cannot have an
    anticompetitive effect greater than exclusive
    dealing with one year contracts. Where there are
    multiple buyers, numerous selling opportunities
    will come up anew each year. Second, in the
    great majority of cases they exclude much less
    than the one-year exclusive dealing contract
    because an aggressive rival can steal sales by
    matching the cumulated discount, which will be
    22
    Of course, HD truck transmissions are not fungible products.
    Indeed, this fact is an unstated premise of appellees‟ claims
    because they contend essentially that the FreedomLine was far
    superior to Eaton‟s transmissions and that its failure in the
    marketplace can be attributed only to Eaton‟s anticompetitive
    conduct.
    45
    the same as the dominant firm‟s cumulative
    discount obligation. Even in such a case, single-
    item discounts can be matched by an equally
    efficient rival.
    For single-item discounts, no matter how
    measured or aggregated, injury to an equally
    efficient rival seems implausible. It is perhaps
    most plausible where there are a very small
    number of buyers, entry barriers into the buying
    market are very high, and buying requires the
    making of long-term commitments. In that case,
    aggressive discounting by the monopolist could
    deprive a rival of most of its patronage. Even
    here, however, we would hesitate to condemn a
    firm for making an above-cost sale that could
    readily be matched by an equally efficient rival.
    Competitive injury is not plausible when there are
    a large number of buyers, particularly when entry
    barriers into the buying market are low. As the
    First Circuit did in Barry Wright [Barry Wright
    Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 
    724 F.2d 227
    , 232
    (1st Cir. 1983) (Breyer, J.)], we would test
    illegality by the ordinary rules applying to
    predatory pricing and allow all above-cost single
    item discounts.
    Given that above-cost discounts can be
    matched      by     equally     efficient    rivals,
    anticompetitive effects are likely only when the
    large firm can offer a larger variety of products or
    46
    services than the smaller firm does. The most
    common scenario resembles tying.
    IA Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶
    768b, at 148-50 (2d ed. 2000) (emphasis added).
    This discussion is set forth in the treatise‟s treatment of
    market-share discounts in the context of Section 2 of the
    Sherman Act. However, for the same reasons recited above,
    Areeda and Hovenkamp take the identical position in the context
    of Section 1 Sherman Act challenges to market-share discounts:
    One approach to [market-share discounts] .
    . . is to treat them as exclusive dealing contracts,
    with the contract period equal to the period over
    which purchases can be aggregated for purposes
    of measuring the size of the discount.
    ...
    If exclusive dealing under equivalent
    structural conditions and subject to equivalent
    defenses were lawful, the discount arrangement
    should be lawful as well. But the competitive
    impact must in fact be less because any equally
    efficient rival can take the customer by bidding a
    better price and even compensating the customer
    for the loss of the discount from the defendant —
    assuming, as we have, that the defendant‟s
    program results in above-cost prices at all
    discount levels. . . . For these reasons we suggest
    47
    that discounts attached merely to the quantity of
    good purchased, and not to exclusivity itself, be
    treated as lawful, and not be subjected to the laws
    of exclusive dealing.
    The decisions to the contrary involve
    situations where the defendant aggregates the
    discount across two or more related products,
    while the plaintiff produces only one or a subset
    of these products.
    XI Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1807b2, at 132-33
    (citing LePage‟s, 
    324 F.3d 141
    ) (emphasis added).23
    The treatise‟s reasoning as set forth above is clear and
    needs little further elaboration from me. While, as noted, the
    law allows a plaintiff to contend that non-price aspects of a
    defendant‟s pricing practices were anticompetitive under the
    rule of reason notwithstanding the defendant‟s above-cost
    prices, I believe that the treatise‟s extraordinarily detailed
    economic rationale for concluding that the price-cost test is
    appropriate in challenges to single-product market-share
    discounts show that my approach is on firm footing. See also
    Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 
    724 F.2d 227
    , 232
    (1st Cir. 1988) (Breyer, J.) (Above-cost prices do not “have a
    tendency to exclude or eliminate equally efficient competitors.
    Moreover, a price cut that leaves prices above incremental costs
    23
    As I explain below, Areeda and Hovenkamp take the position
    that Section 3 does not encompass non-exclusive market-share
    discount programs.
    48
    was probably moving prices in the „right‟ direction — towards
    the competitive norm.”); Herbert Hovenkamp, Discounts and
    Exclusion, 
    2006 Utah L. Rev. 841
    , 844 (2006) (“One of the
    factors driving the predatory pricing rule is that, as long as
    prices are above the relevant measure of cost, the discounts
    cannot exclude an equally efficient rival. The same is true of
    single-product discounts.”).
    In sum, I reiterate that Supreme Court precedent requires
    that courts exercise considerable caution before condemning
    above-cost pricing practices and that in a challenge to a
    defendant‟s pricing practices the Brooke Group price-cost test
    should apply and be given persuasive effect regardless of
    whether a plaintiff identifies non-price elements of a
    defendant‟s conduct that it alleges were anticompetitive.
    Having discussed this critical point, I now turn to the question of
    whether under the rule of reason analysis and the standards
    applicable to claims of unlawful exclusive dealing appellees
    demonstrated that a jury could hold that Eaton violated the
    antitrust laws notwithstanding its above-cost prices.
    B. Clayton Act Section 3 and Sherman Act Section 1 Claims24
    24
    The majority collapses appellees‟ three claims into one
    analysis, and while that approach is not necessarily incorrect and
    the three provisions at issue overlap substantially, I believe it
    most prudent to address the claims separately as the provisions
    at issue have some distinct elements that require separate
    discussion.
    49
    Appellees contend that the LTAs were anticompetitive
    exclusive dealing arrangements in violation of Section 1 of the
    Sherman Act and Section 3 of the Clayton Act. They claim that
    through the LTAs “Eaton engaged in de facto exclusive dealing
    agreements and other conduct that denied any other supplier the
    ability to compete for even 10% of the market.” Appellees‟ br.
    at 43.
    In considering this argument, I start with the principle
    that even explicit exclusive-dealing arrangements, which
    preclude a buyer from purchasing the goods of another seller,
    are not per se unlawful. See Race Tires Am., Inc. v. Hoosier
    Racing Tire Corp., 
    614 F.3d 57
    , 76 (3d Cir. 2010); United States
    v. Dentsply Int‟l, Inc., 
    399 F.3d 181
    , 187 (3d Cir. 2005).
    Indeed, “it is widely recognized that in many circumstances
    exclusive dealing arrangements may be highly efficient — to
    assure supply, price stability, outlets, investment, best efforts or
    the like — and pose no competitive threat at all.” Races Tires,
    
    614 F.3d at 76
     (quoting E. Food Servs., Inc. v. Pontifical
    Catholic Univ. Servs. Ass‟n, Inc., 
    357 F.3d 1
    , 8 (1st Cir. 2004))
    In this case, I make many more citations to the record
    than judges of this Court ordinarily would make in an opinion. I
    do so because while deference to the jury‟s verdict requires that
    we not reweigh the evidence and that we view the evidence in
    the light most favorable to appellees, where, as here, the
    evidence supporting that verdict falls so short of the standard
    required to sustain that verdict I believe it appropriate to point
    not only to the absence of evidence supporting the jury verdict
    but also to the considerable undisputed evidence contradicting
    that verdict.
    50
    (internal brackets omitted); see also Standard Oil Co. of Calif. v.
    United States, 
    337 U.S. 293
    , 306-07, 
    69 S.Ct. 1051
    , 1058-59
    (1949) (listing advantages of requirements contracts to both
    buyers and sellers); Omega Envtl., Inc. v. Gilbarco, Inc., 
    127 F.3d 1157
    , 1162 (9th Cir. 1997) (“There are . . . well-recognized
    economic benefits to exclusive dealing arrangements, including
    the enhancement of interbrand competition.”) (citation omitted).
    As we stated in Race Tires, “[i]t is well established that
    competition among businesses to serve as an exclusive supplier
    should actually be encouraged.” 
    614 F.3d at 83
     (citation
    omitted). “[C]ompetition to be an exclusive supplier may
    constitute „a vital form of rivalry, and often the most powerful
    one, which the antitrust laws encourage rather than suppress.‟”
    
    Id. at 76
     (quoting Menasha Corp. v. News Am. Marketing In-
    Store, Inc., 
    354 F.3d 661
    , 663 (7th Cir. 2004)). Of course,
    “exclusive agreements are not exempt from antitrust scrutiny.”
    Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 76
    . “All exclusive dealing agreements
    must comply with section 1 of the Sherman Act.” Barr Labs.,
    Inc. v. Abbott Labs., 
    978 F.2d 98
    , 110 (3d Cir. 1992) (citing
    Am. Motor Inns, Inc. v. Holiday Inns, Inc., 
    521 F.2d 1230
    , 1239
    (3d Cir. 1975)). “Contracts for the sale of goods . . . must also
    comply with the more rigorous standards of section 3 of the
    Clayton Act.” 
    Id.
    While Section 3 requires that a plaintiff demonstrate that
    it is “probable that performance of the contract will foreclose
    competition in a substantial share of the line of commerce
    affected,” Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 
    365 U.S. 320
    , 327, 
    81 S.Ct. 623
    , 628 (1961) (emphasis added), under a
    Section 1 rule-of-reason case such as this case “the plaintiff
    bears the initial burden of showing that the [alleged] agreement
    51
    produced an adverse, anticompetitive effect within the relevant
    geographic market,” Burtch v. Milberg Factors, Inc., 
    662 F.3d 212
    , 222 (3d Cir. 2011) (quotations marks and citation omitted)
    (emphasis added). Accordingly, if an arrangement “do[es] not
    infringe upon the stiffer standards of anti-competitiveness under
    the Clayton Act, . . . [it] will also be lawful under the less
    restrictive provisions of the Sherman Act.” Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at
    110 (citing Am. Motor Inns, 
    521 F.2d at 1250
    ); see also CDC
    Techs., Inc. v. IDEXX Labs., Inc., 
    186 F.3d 74
    , 79 (2d Cir.
    1999) (“The conclusion that a contract does not violate § 3 of
    the Clayton Act ordinarily implies the conclusion that the
    contract does not violate the Sherman Act . . . .”) (citation
    omitted); Twin City Sportservice, Inc. v. Charles O. Finley &
    Co., 
    676 F.2d 1291
    , 1304 n.9 (9th Cir. 1982) (“[A] greater
    showing of anticompetitive effect is required to establish a
    Sherman Act violation than a section 3 Clayton Act violation in
    exclusive-dealing cases.”) (citation omitted).25
    25
    In Tampa Electric, the Court indicated that if an arrangement
    is lawful under Section 3 of the Clayton Act it will be lawful
    under both Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act. See 
    365 U.S. at 335
    , 
    81 S.Ct. at 632
     (“We need not discuss the respondents‟
    further contention that the contract also violates § 1 and § 2 of
    the Sherman Act, for if it does not fall within the broader
    proscription of § 3 of the Clayton Act it follows that it is not
    forbidden by those of the former.”) (citing Times-Picayune
    Publ‟g Co. v. United States, 
    345 U.S. 594
    , 608-09, 
    73 S.Ct. 872
    ,
    880 (1953)). In Barr Laboratories, however, we disposed of the
    plaintiff‟s Section 1 Sherman Act claim with its Section 3
    Clayton Act claim but we addressed the plaintiff‟s Section 2
    52
    To determine whether it is “probable that performance of
    the contract will foreclose competition in a substantial share of
    the line of commerce affected” in violation of Section 3, Tampa
    Electric Co., 
    365 U.S. at 327
    , 
    81 S.Ct. at 628
    , logically a
    plaintiff first must establish the share of the market, expressed in
    a percentage, in which the exclusive dealing arrangement
    forecloses competition. As the Court of Appeals for the District
    of Columbia Circuit stated in one of the more notable antitrust
    cases of the recent past, “[t]hough what is „significant‟ may vary
    depending upon the antitrust provision under which an exclusive
    deal is challenged, it is clear that in all cases the plaintiff must
    both define the relevant market and prove the degree of
    foreclosure.” United States v. Microsoft Corp., 
    253 F.3d 34
    , 69
    (D.C. Cir. 2001); see also Stop & Shop Supermarket Co. v. Blue
    Cross & Blue Shield of R.I., 
    373 F.3d 57
    , 66 (1st Cir. 2004)
    (“For the exclusive dealing contract, the first step would be [for
    plaintiff] to show the extent of foreclosure resulting from the . . .
    contract . . . .”); R.J. Reynolds Tobacco Co. v. Philip Morris
    Inc., 
    199 F. Supp. 2d 362
    , 388 (M.D.N.C. 2002), aff‟d, 67 F.
    App‟x 810 (4th Cir. 2003) (“A plaintiff makes out a prima facie
    case of substantial foreclosure by demonstrating first that a
    Sherman Act claim separately. See 
    978 F.2d at 110-12
    ; see also
    Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 197
     (concluding that the district court
    erred in stating that defendant had not violated Section 2 of the
    Sherman Act solely because it had concluded that defendant had
    not violated Section 3 of the Clayton Act) (citing LePage‟s, 
    324 F.3d at
    157 n.10). For this reason, I subsume appellees‟ Section
    1 Sherman Act claim within its Section 3 claim but I address
    separately appellees‟ Section 2 Sherman Act claim.
    53
    significant percentage of the relevant market is foreclosed by the
    provision challenged.”).
    “The share of the market foreclosed is important because,
    for the contract to have an adverse effect upon competition, „the
    opportunities for other traders to enter into or remain in that
    market must be significantly limited.‟” Microsoft Corp., 
    253 F.3d at 69
     (quoting Tampa Elec. Co., 
    365 U.S. at 328
    , 
    81 S.Ct. at 628-29
    ); see also Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde,
    
    466 U.S. 2
    , 45, 
    104 S.Ct. 1551
    , 1576 (1984) (O‟Connor, J.,
    concurring) (“Exclusive dealing is an unreasonable restraint on
    trade [under Section 1 of the Sherman Act] only when a
    significant fraction of buyers or sellers are frozen out of a
    market by the exclusive deal.”) (citation omitted); Chuck‟s Feed
    & Seed Co. v. Ralston Purina Co., 
    810 F.2d 1289
    , 1294 (4th Cir.
    1987) (“[T]he courts‟ focus in evaluating exclusive dealing
    arrangements should be on their effect in shutting out competing
    manufacturers‟ brands from the relevant market.”); Perington
    Wholesale, Inc. v. Burger King Corp., 
    631 F.2d 1369
    , 1374
    (10th Cir. 1979) (“[A] complaining trader [challenging an
    exclusive-dealing arrangement] must allege and prove that a
    particular arrangement unreasonably restricts the opportunities
    of the seller‟s competitors to market their product.”) (citation
    omitted). Thus, “[f]ollowing Tampa Electric, courts considering
    antitrust challenges to exclusive contracts have taken care to
    identify the share of the market foreclosed.” Microsoft Corp.,
    
    253 F.3d at 69
     (citation omitted); see also E.I. du Pont de
    Nemours and Co. v. Kolon Indus., Inc., 
    637 F.3d 435
    , 451 (4th
    Cir. 2011) (noting that “the requirement of a significant degree
    of foreclosure serves a useful screening function”) (internal
    quotation marks and citation omitted).
    54
    Nevertheless, the antitrust laws tolerate some degree of
    market foreclosure; Section 3 only condemns an agreement
    where the foreclosure represents a substantial share of the
    market. See Standard Fashion Co. v. Magrane Houston Co., 
    258 U.S. 346
    , 357, 
    42 S.Ct. 360
    , 362 (1922) (“That . . . [Section 3]
    was not intended to reach every remote lessening of competition
    is shown in the requirement that such lessening must be
    substantial.”). Thus, once the plaintiff demonstrates the portion
    of the market the exclusive-dealing arrangement forecloses, the
    court must ask whether that level of preemption constitutes a
    “substantial” share of the market. See Tampa Elec. Co., 
    365 U.S. at 328
    , 
    81 S.Ct. at 628
     (In a Section 3 case, the Court must
    consider the degree of market foreclosure and “the competition
    foreclosed by the contract must be found to constitute a
    substantial share of the relevant market.”). There is no fixed
    percentage at which foreclosure becomes “substantial” and
    courts have varied widely in the degree of foreclosure they
    consider unlawful. See R.J. Reynolds Tobacco Co., 
    199 F. Supp. 2d at 388
     (collecting cases and noting that “[c]ourts have
    condemned provisions involving foreclosure as low as 24%
    while provisions involving foreclosure as high as 50% have
    been upheld”) (citations omitted).
    Under Tampa Electric, however, “the degree of market
    foreclosure is only one of the factors involved in determining
    the legality of an exclusive dealing arrangement.” Barr Labs.,
    
    978 F.2d at 111
     (citation omitted). Indeed, while a negligible
    degree of foreclosure “makes dismissal easy,” a high degree of
    market foreclosure does not “automatically condemn” an
    exclusive-dealing arrangement. Stop & Shop Supermarket, 
    373 F.3d at 68
    . Rather, once a plaintiff identifies the degree of
    55
    market foreclosure, to determine whether that preemption is
    “substantial,” a court considers not only the quantitative aspect
    of the foreclosure but also the qualitative conditions of the
    particular market, such as “the relative strength of the parties,
    the proportionate volume of commerce involved in relation to
    the total volume of commerce in the relevant market area,” and
    the effect “preemption of that share of the market might have on
    effective competition therein.” Tampa Elec. Co., 
    365 U.S. at 329
    , 
    81 S.Ct. at 629
    ; see also Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at 111
    .
    Courts employing Tampa Electric‟s market analysis also
    consider the duration of the agreement, the ease of its
    terminability, the height of any entry barriers, alternative outlets
    competitors may employ to sell their product, and the buyer‟s
    and seller‟s business justifications for the arrangement. See
    Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1059
    ; Omega Envtl., 
    127 F.3d at 1163-65
    ; Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at 111
    ; Barry Wright Corp, 
    724 F.2d at 236-37
    ; R.J. Reynolds Tobacco Co., 
    199 F. Supp. 2d at 389
    ; see also XI Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1821d,
    at 183-88.26
    26
    In substance, the Tampa Electric standard for Clayton Act
    Section 3 claims differs very marginally, if at all, from the fact-
    intensive rule-of-reason analysis that applies to this case under
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act. Cf. Deutscher Tennis Bund v.
    ATP Tour, Inc., 
    610 F.3d 820
    , 830 (3d Cir. 2010) (“The rule of
    reason requires the fact-finder to weigh [] all of the
    circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice
    should be prohibited as imposing an unreasonable restraint on
    competition. The inquiry is whether the restraint at issue is one
    that promotes competition or one that suppresses competition.”)
    56
    In considering whether Eaton‟s conduct violated Section
    3, I note first that it is undisputed that the LTAs were not by
    their terms exclusive-dealing contracts. The LTAs did not
    require the OEMs to purchase any amount, much less all, of
    their transmission needs from Eaton, and they did not preclude
    the OEMs from purchasing transmissions from appellees or any
    other manufacturer. Additionally, the LTAs did not condition
    the rebates on the OEMs‟ purchase of 100% of their
    transmission needs from Eaton.
    In the past, we have expressed doubt as to whether an
    agreement involving less than all of a customer‟s purchases even
    falls within the ambit of Section 3. See Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at
    110 n.24 (“An agreement affecting less than all purchases does
    not amount to true exclusive dealing.”) (citation omitted); see
    also W. Parcel Express v. United Parcel Serv. of Am., Inc., 190
    (quotation marks and citations omitted). Indeed, it appears more
    often than not that in a Section 1 case courts explicitly employ
    the Tampa Electric standard as the guiding framework for the
    rule-of-reason analysis. See, e.g. Allied Orthopedic Appliances
    Inc. v. Tyco Health Care Grp., 
    592 F.3d 991
    , 996 (9th Cir. 2010)
    (“Under the antitrust rule of reason, an exclusive dealing
    arrangement violates Section 1 only if its effect is to „foreclose
    competition in a substantial share of the line of commerce
    affected.‟”) (quoting Omega Envtl., 
    127 F.3d at 1162
    ); see also
    Jefferson Parish, 
    466 U.S. at 45
    , 104 S.Ct. at 1575 (O‟Connor,
    J., concurring) (“Exclusive dealing arrangements are
    independently subject to scrutiny under § 1 of the Sherman Act,
    and are also analyzed under the Rule of Reason.”) (citing Tampa
    Elec. Co., 
    365 U.S. at 333-35
    , 
    81 S.Ct. at 631-32
    ).
    
    57 F.3d 974
    , 976 (9th Cir. 1999) (concluding that because volume
    discount contracts did “not preclude consumers from using other
    delivery services, they [we]re not exclusive dealing contracts
    that preclude[d] competition”); Magnus Petroleum Co., v. Skelly
    Oil Co., 
    599 F.2d 196
    , 200 (7th Cir. 1979) (“Because the
    agreements contained no exclusive dealing clause and did not
    require plaintiffs to purchase any amounts of gasoline that even
    approached their requirements, they did not violate Section 3 of
    the Clayton Act.”) (citations omitted).
    Indeed, Section 3 explicitly applies only to those
    agreements entered into “on the condition, agreement, or
    understanding that the lessee or purchaser . . . shall not use or
    deal in the goods . . . of a competitor.” 
    15 U.S.C. § 14
    ; see also
    Standard Fashion Co., 258 U.S. at 356, 42 S.Ct. at 362 (Section
    3 “deals with consequences to follow the making of the
    restrictive covenant limiting the right of the purchaser to deal in
    the goods of the seller only.”).27 I doubt whether a market-share
    27
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act, which proscribes “[e]very
    contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or
    conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce,” 
    15 U.S.C. § 1
    and Section 2 of the Sherman Act, which proscribes the
    monopolization or attempted monopolization of trade or
    commerce, 
    15 U.S.C. § 2
    , do not contain Section 3‟s “on the
    condition” language. Accordingly, the LTAs fall within the
    theoretical reach of those provisions. Nevertheless, appellees‟
    Section 1 and 2 claims fail because appellees did not introduce
    sufficient evidence from which a jury could infer that the LTAs
    were exclusive dealing contracts that foreclosed competition in
    the marketplace.
    58
    discount program of the type here, which does not preclude the
    buyer from dealing in the goods of others and does not even
    condition the rebate on exclusivity, falls within the statutory
    reach of that provision. See IIIA Areeda & Hovenkamp,
    Antitrust Law ¶ 768, at 148 n.26 (noting that “only the Sherman
    Act applies” to a claim that a market-share discount amounts to
    exclusive dealing because “[w]hile § 3 of the Clayton Act, 
    15 U.S.C. § 14
    , expressly covers the seller who offers a „discount
    from, or rebate upon‟ a sale in exchange for a promise not to
    deal with others, that is not the same thing as a quantity or
    market share discount, in which the buyer makes no promise not
    to deal with others”).28
    The majority bypasses this obstacle to appellees‟ success
    by stating that a plaintiff‟s allegation that a contract lacking an
    express exclusivity requirement nonetheless establishes an
    unlawful de facto exclusive dealing program sets forth a
    28
    In fact, even if the LTAs had required the OEMs to purchase a
    certain share but not all of their transmissions needs from Eaton,
    as the majority interprets them to do, it is still unclear whether
    Section 3 would have reached that agreement. See Areeda &
    Hovenkamp, Fundamentals of Antitrust Law § 18.01c, at 18-17
    (“Literally, a „partial‟ exclusive dealing requirement appears not
    to be covered by § 3 of the Clayton Act at all. For example, if A
    requires B to purchase „at least 60 percent‟ of its gasoline needs
    from A, B is still free to purchase the remaining 40 percent
    elsewhere. As a result, there is no condition that B not deal in
    the goods of a competitor, as the statute requires. Most of the
    courts take this position.”) (citations omitted).
    59
    cognizable antitrust claim. In doing so, the majority also
    concludes that Section 3 encompasses contracts that require
    partial exclusivity.
    The notion of de facto exclusive dealing has its roots in
    United Shoe Machinery Corp. v. United States, 
    258 U.S. 451
    ,
    457, 
    42 S.Ct. 363
    , 365 (1922), in which the Court held that a
    contract lacking an express agreement not to use the goods of a
    competitor falls within the ambit of Section 3 if “the practical
    effect is to prevent such use.” As noted, the majority appears to
    interpret this statement as meaning that a contract that has the
    effect of causing the purchaser to buy most of its needs from one
    seller falls within Section 3 because it induces near-exclusivity.
    I disagree with this interpretation and believe instead that United
    Shoe and its “practical effect” standard stands for the
    proposition that a contract that is not facially exclusive may
    nonetheless fall within the ambit of Section 3 if, in the
    implementation of its terms, it induces actual exclusivity.
    In United Shoe, the Court condemned as unlawful
    exclusive dealing a lease that included, among other things, a
    forfeiture provision to the effect that if the lessee failed to use
    exclusively machinery of certain kinds made by the lessor, the
    lessor had the right to cancel the lessee‟s right to use all such
    machinery, a provision that the lessee would not use the
    machinery on products that had not received particular
    operations upon certain of other lessor‟s machines, and a clause
    that required the lessee to purchase its supplies exclusively from
    the lessor. See 
    id. at 456-57
    , 42 S.Ct. at 365. Lessees who used
    the lessor‟s competitors‟ machines in violation of the terms of
    the leases “had their attention called to the forfeiture provisions
    60
    in the leases, which was understood, by many of the lessees, as
    warnings, in the nature of threats, that unless discontinued these
    covenants of the leases would be enforced.” United States v.
    United Shoe Mach. Co., 
    264 F. 138
    , 145 (D.C. Mo. 1920).
    These provisions, which the Court noted amounted in reality to
    “tying agreements,” fell within the scope of Section 3 because
    they “effectually prevent[ed] the lessee from acquiring the
    machinery of a competitor of the lessor, except at the risk of
    forfeiting the right to use the machines furnished by the
    [lessor].” 258 U.S. at 457-58, 42 S.Ct. at 365. Thus, in practice,
    the lease induced actual, total exclusivity. Subsequent cases
    relying on United Shoe‟s "practical effect” formulation bear the
    point out.
    In International Business Machines Corp. v. United
    States, 
    298 U.S. 131
    , 135, 
    56 S.Ct. 701
    , 703 (1936), the Court,
    relying on United Shoe, concluded that a lease for tabulating
    machines that required the lessee to use only the tabulating cards
    of the lessor on its machines fell within Section 3 because in
    practice it required the exclusive use of the lessor‟s cards. The
    Court explained that while “the condition is not in so many
    words against the use of the cards of a competitor, but is
    affirmative in form, that the lessee shall use only appellant‟s
    cards in the leased machines,” because “the lessee can make no
    use of the cards except with the leased machines, and the
    specified use of appellant‟s cards precludes the use of the cards
    of any competitor, the condition operates [to prohibit the use of
    the cards of a competitor] in the manner forbidden by” Section 3
    of the Clayton Act. 
    Id.
     (citing United Shoe, 
    258 U.S. at 458
    , 42
    S.Ct. at 365); but see FTC v. Sinclair Refining Co., 
    261 U.S. 463
    , 474, 
    43 S.Ct. 450
    , 453 (1923) (distinguishing United Shoe
    61
    and concluding that contract that required lessee of gasoline
    pumps not to use competitor‟s gasoline in lessor‟s pumps did not
    fall within Section 3 because the contract did not contain a
    provision “which obligate[d] the lessee not to sell the goods of
    another,” and “[t]he lessee [wa]s free to buy [pumps] wherever
    he cho[se]”). Similarly, in Standard Oil, the Court assumed that
    Section 3 encompassed “[e]xclusive supply contracts” that the
    defendant had entered with its dealers, in which the dealer
    promised “to purchase from Standard all his requirements of one
    or more products.”29 
    337 U.S. at 295-96
    , 
    69 S.Ct. at 1054
    .
    Accordingly, while Section 3 encompasses agreements
    that do not contain express exclusivity provisions but in reality
    induce actual exclusivity, it does not, as the majority seems to
    believe, encompass agreements that do not contain express
    exclusivity provisions and do not induce actual exclusivity.30
    29
    In Tampa Electric, the case most often cited for the “practical
    effect” standard, the Court considered a challenge to a
    requirements contract and “assume[d], but d[id] not decide, that
    the contract [wa]s an exclusive-dealing arrangement within the
    compass of § 3.” 
    365 U.S. at 330
    , 
    81 S.Ct. at 629
    .
    30
    LePage‟s and Dentsply, cases on which the majority relies, are
    not to the contrary. Those cases dealt not with Section 3 of the
    Clayton Act but rather with Section 2 of the Sherman Act, which
    does not contain the same restrictive “on the condition”
    language as Section 3. Furthermore, in LePage‟s, we concluded
    that 3M‟s bundled rebate agreements constituted unlawful de
    facto exclusive dealing arrangements because LePage‟s
    “introduced powerful evidence” that its prior customers refused
    62
    Here, not only did the LTAs lack any provision imposing a ban
    on the OEMs‟ purchase of Eaton‟s competitors‟ products, they
    did not contain a provision amounting to or having the effect of
    imposing such a ban. Moreover, the evidence adduced at the
    trial demonstrates that the LTAs actually did not induce de facto
    total exclusivity on the part of the OEMs. As noted, from July
    2000 to October 2003, ZFM‟s share of the HD transmission
    market ranged between 8% and 14%. Thus, the majority, in
    interpreting the scope of Section 3 to encompass an agreement
    which neither explicitly forbids nor has the effect of precluding
    the OEMs from purchasing Eaton‟s competitors‟ products, has
    expanded the scope of Section 3 greatly beyond its intent.
    Section 3 only encompasses agreements that explicitly forbid or
    have the practical effect of precluding one party from using the
    goods of another. Nevertheless, despite my serious misgivings
    on this threshold exclusive-dealing issue, which could justify
    terminating this discussion now and thus reversing the District
    Court‟s denial of judgment as a matter of law as to appellees‟
    Section 3 Clayton Act claim, I will assume that the LTAs fall
    to meet with LePage‟s‟ sales representatives, refused to discuss
    purchasing LePage‟s products for “the next three years,” and
    3M offered bonus rebates to its customers upon achieving sole-
    supplier status. 
    324 F.3d at 158
    . And in Dentsply, we
    concluded that a provision that Dentsply imposed on its dealers
    that actually prohibited the dealers from adding its competitors‟
    tooth lines as part of their product offering amounted to
    exclusive dealing. 399 F.3d at 193. Here, as explained below,
    appellees fell woefully short of introducing evidence that the
    LTAs induced anything approaching actual exclusivity.
    63
    within the theoretical reach of Section 3 and proceed to analyze
    the LTAs under that provision. My analysis, however, does not
    get very far before it becomes readily apparent that this
    fundamental flaw in appellees‟ case — that the LTAs were not,
    in fact, exclusive-dealing contracts — is fatal to their claim.
    As noted above, under Tampa Electric a plaintiff first
    must identify the degree of market foreclosure. Despite a
    lengthy trial in the District Court, which has resulted in the
    creation of a nine-volume joint appendix and extensive briefing
    on this appeal, appellees do not identify clearly for us the precise
    degree of market foreclosure attributable to the LTAs. The
    majority, however, attempts to make up for appellees‟
    deficiency in this regard by stating that appellees‟ expert, Dr.
    David DeRamus, testified that the LTAs left only 15% of the
    market remaining to Eaton‟s competitors, or stated another way,
    that the LTAs foreclosed competition in 85% of the market. In
    reality, however, Dr. DeRamus did not testify that the LTAs
    foreclosed competition in 85% of the market. The testimony on
    which the majority apparently relies for that figure deals not
    with Dr. DeRamus‟ opinion as to the extent to which the LTAs
    foreclosed competition in the HD truck transmission market but
    rather with Dr. DeRamus‟ calculation of Eaton‟s market share
    during the relevant time period in the context of his
    determination as to whether Eaton had monopoly power. See
    J.A. at 722 (Dr. DeRamus‟ testimony) (explaining the steps he
    took to ascertain whether “Eaton has monopoly power in the[] . .
    . [NAFTA HD truck transmission market”); see also J.A. at
    4758, 4760 (Dr. DeRamus‟ expert report) (setting forth the data
    reflecting Eaton‟s market share). I think it obvious that the
    inquiry into Eaton‟s market share is a question separate and
    64
    apart from the LTAs‟ alleged foreclosure effect31 and that we
    may not simply borrow Dr. DeRamus‟ testimony as to Eaton‟s
    market share to adduce evidence of the LTAs‟ foreclosure
    effect.
    In point of fact, Dr. DeRamus aimed much higher with
    his estimation of the LTAs‟ alleged foreclosure effect by stating
    explicitly in his expert report that “Eaton‟s exclusionary
    agreements with all four of the heavy-duty truck OEMs — the
    only significant manufacturers of heavy-duty trucks in the
    relevant geographic markets at issue in this case — foreclosed
    nearly 100 percent of the North American market or markets for
    HD [t]ransmissions.” J.A. at 4814 (Dr. DeRamus‟ expert
    report). Dr. DeRamus arrived at this foreclosure percentage on
    the basis of the market-share targets the LTAs required for the
    31
    See, e.g., Barry Wright Corp., 
    724 F.2d at 229, 237
     (observing
    that potential foreclosure effect of volume discount
    requirements contract between manufacturer, who had 83% to
    94% market share, and purchaser of mechanical snubbers was
    50% where purchaser‟s snubber purchases represented 50% of
    snubber market). The distinction between these two inquiries,
    the question of Eaton‟s market share and the question of the
    LTAs‟ alleged foreclosure effect, is particularly critical in a case
    such as this one since prior to 1989 Eaton was the only HD
    transmission manufacturer and thus possessed 100% market
    share at a time before appellees contend that it engaged in any
    alleged anticompetitive conduct.
    65
    OEMs to receive the rebates.32
    In denying Eaton judgment as a matter of law, the
    District Court took a similar view that reliance on the market-
    share targets was an appropriate method to ascertain the LTAs‟
    foreclosure effect, concluding that there was sufficient evidence
    “that the contracts foreclosed a substantial share of the market”
    not because ZFM identified a specific foreclosure percentage
    but because “each OEM was required to order 80% or more of
    its transmissions from” Eaton to receive the rebates. ZF
    Meritor, 
    769 F. Supp. 2d at 692
    .33 While the majority‟s reliance
    on Dr. DeRamus‟ testimony regarding Eaton‟s market share to
    ascertain the LTAs‟ foreclosure effect is mistaken, it is clear that
    the majority likewise ultimately concludes that the market-share
    32
    Although Dr. DeRamus did not set forth explicitly in his
    expert report how he arrived at his foreclosure percentage or his
    arithmetic in that regard — a shocking oversight in a case that
    hinges on this very question — his testimony at trial illuminates
    that he relied on the market-share targets to arrive at his
    estimation of the LTAs‟ foreclosure effect, though notably he
    testified as to a different foreclosure percentage than that which
    he set forth in his report. See J.A. at 858 (Dr. DeRamus‟
    testimony) (explaining that he arrived at his opinion of the
    LTAs‟ foreclosure effect by relying on the market-share targets
    and opining that one could take a “simple average” of the
    market-share targets to yield a 90% foreclosure rate).
    33
    The District Court‟s statement in this regard was inaccurate as
    Volvo‟s LTA granted it rebates beginning at a 65% market-
    share target.
    66
    targets may serve as a measure of the LTAs‟ foreclosure effect.
    For several reasons, however, the market-share targets do not
    reflect the LTAs‟ foreclosure effect, and, on this point, I find
    that the Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit‟s and the Court
    of Appeals for the Eighth Circuit‟s treatment of Sherman Act
    Section 1 challenges to non-exclusive market-share discount
    programs are instructive.
    In Allied Orthopedic Appliances Inc. v. Tyco Health Care
    Group, 
    592 F.3d 991
    , 994-96 (9th Cir. 2010), a group of
    hospitals and health care providers alleged, among other things,
    that Tyco, a monopolist in the U.S. pulse oximetry sensor
    market, unlawfully foreclosed competition in the market in
    contravention of Section 1 of the Sherman Act through its offer
    of market-share discounts.        As here, the market-share
    agreements provided discounts conditioned on the customers‟
    purchase of a certain percentage of the product in issue, i.e.,
    pulse oximetry sensors, from Tyco, the discount increasing with
    Tyco‟s increasing market share. “The agreements did not
    contractually obligate Tyco‟s customers to buy anything from
    Tyco . . . and [t]he only consequence of purchasing less than the
    agreed upon percentage of Tyco‟s products was loss of the
    negotiated discounts.” 
    Id. at 995
    .
    The court of appeals concluded that the agreements did
    not foreclose competition in violation of Section 1 because the
    agreements did not require Tyco‟s customers to purchase
    anything from Tyco and because “[a]ny customer subject to one
    of Tyco‟s market-share discount agreements could choose at
    anytime to forego the discount offered by Tyco and purchase
    67
    from a generic competitor.” 
    Id. at 997
    .34 Thus, Tyco‟s
    competitors “remained able to compete for Tyco‟s customers by
    offering their products at better prices.” 
    Id. at 998
    .
    The Court of Appeals for the Eighth Circuit took a
    similar view of market-share discount agreements in Concord
    Boat. In that case, a group of boat builders that sold boats to
    dealers alleged that Brunswick, the market leader in the
    manufacture of stern drive engines, violated Section 1 through
    its offer of market-share discount agreements with the builders
    and dealers. The agreements offered reduced prices conditioned
    on market-share targets of 60% to 80%. See 
    207 F.3d at 1044
    .35
    As is true here with respect to the product in issue, none of
    Brunswick‟s programs “obligated boat builders and dealers to
    purchase engines from Brunswick, and none of the programs
    restricted the ability of builders and dealers to purchase engines
    from other engine manufacturers.” 
    Id. at 1045
    .
    The court employed the standards of Tampa Electric to
    conclude that the plaintiffs had “failed to produce sufficient
    evidence to demonstrate that Brunswick had foreclosed a
    34
    The court also found significant the plaintiffs‟ expert failure to
    explain why “price-sensitive hospitals would adhere to Tyco‟s
    market-share agreements when they could purchase less
    expensive generic sensors instead.” 
    592 F.3d at 997
    .
    35
    The plaintiffs also alleged that Brunswick had violated Section
    7 of the Clayton Act and Section 2 of the Sherman Act, but the
    court likewise rejected these claims. See 
    207 F.3d at 1043, 1053, 1062
    .
    68
    substantial share of the . . . market through anticompetitive
    conduct” and failed to show that “Brunswick‟s discount
    program was in any way exclusive” in violation of Section 1.
    
    Id. at 1059
    . The court reached that conclusion because the
    builders were “free to walk away from the discounts at any
    time,” and “Brunswick‟s discounts, because they were
    significantly above cost, left ample room for new competitors . .
    . to enter the engine manufacturing market and to lure customers
    away by offering superior discounts.” Id.; see also Se. Mo.
    Hosp. v. C.R. Bard, Inc., 
    642 F.3d 608
    , 612-13 (8th Cir. 2011)
    (rejecting Sherman Sections 1 and 2 and Clayton Section 3
    challenge to market-share discount program on the basis of
    Concord Boat where customers “were not required to purchase
    100 percent of their . . . needs from . . . [defendant] or to refrain
    from purchasing from competitors” or indeed to purchase
    “anything from . . . [defendant]”); Stitt Spark Plug Co. v.
    Champion Spark Plug Co., 
    840 F.2d 1253
    , 1258 (5th Cir. 1988)
    (affirming district court‟s directed verdict in favor of defendant
    on Section 1 and Section 3 claims where plaintiff “proved no
    instance in which a distributor honored an exclusive dealing
    arrangement by refusing to purchase . . . [plaintiff‟s] plugs, . . .
    there was no testimony that any distributor agreed to refrain
    from selling competing plugs for any specific period of time, . . .
    [and] [t]here was no evidence that a distributor who failed to
    abide by the agreement would be subject to any sanction”).
    As was true of the contracts at issue in Allied Orthopedic
    and Concord Boat with respect to what are suggested to be,
    wrongly in my view, mandatory purchase obligations, the LTAs
    did not obligate the OEMs to purchase anything from Eaton,
    much less 100% of their transmission needs, nor did they
    69
    preclude the OEMs from purchasing transmissions from any
    other manufacturer. Rather, the agreements provided for
    increasing rebates and thus lower prices based on the percentage
    of an OEM‟s transmission needs that it purchased from Eaton.
    In such a circumstance, the LTAs did not foreclose competition
    in any share of the market because Eaton‟s competitors were
    able to compete for this business as the OEMs were at liberty to
    walk away from the LTAs at any time.
    Indeed, this point is precisely where the Brooke Group
    price-cost test comes into play. In a situation such as this one,
    where the contract in terms is not exclusive and merely provides
    discounted but above-cost prices conditioned upon a market-
    share target, any equally efficient competitor, including ZFM, if
    it was an equally efficient competitor, had an ongoing
    opportunity to offer competitive discounts to capture the OEMs‟
    business. If Eaton‟s discounts had resulted in prices that were
    below-cost, a charge that appellees do not make, then even an
    equally-efficient competitor might not have the opportunity to
    compete for the business the LTAs covered and thus it could be
    said that competition was foreclosed in that share of the market
    notwithstanding the non-obligatory and non-exclusive nature of
    the LTAs. But we do not need to address that unlikely
    circumstance because Eaton‟s discounts resulted in prices that
    were above-cost and thus the LTAs “left ample room” for ZFM
    or new competitors to enter the market and “to lure customers
    away by offering superior discounts.” Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1059
    . As in Allied Orthopedic, “[t]he market-share discount
    agreements at issue here did not foreclose . . . [Eaton‟s]
    customers from competition because „a competing manufacturer
    need[ed] only offer a better product or a better deal to acquire
    70
    their [business].‟” 
    592 F.3d at 997
     (quoting Omega, 
    127 F.3d at 1164
    ); see also Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 768b, at
    148-50 (concluding that above-cost market-share discounts do
    not exclude equally efficient rivals because “[a]s long as the
    discounted price is above cost and not predatory, it can be
    matched by any equally efficient rival”). Absent evidence that
    notwithstanding the above-cost prices of the LTAs the non-price
    aspects of the LTAs rendered them anticompetitive, we should
    conclude that as a matter of law Eaton‟s LTAs were not
    anticompetitive.
    The majority dismisses as inapplicable the reasoning of
    Allied Orthopedic and Concord Boat by stating that “this is not a
    case in which the defendant‟s low price was the clear driving
    force behind the customer‟s compliance with purchase targets,
    and the customers were free to walk away if a competitor
    offered a better price.” Typescript at 33. But the reality is to the
    contrary as the testimony I have summarized establishes it is
    precisely the case that Eaton‟s low prices led the OEMs to enter
    the LTAs and to strive to meet the market-share targets.
    Likewise, it is clearly the case that the OEMs were free to walk
    away from the market-share rebates the LTAs offered at any
    time. In attempting to overcome this crucial defect in appellees‟
    claim and concluding that notwithstanding the LTAs‟ terms the
    LTAs were in fact mandatory agreements to which the OEMs
    were beholden against their will the majority sets forth two
    justifications.
    First, the majority downplays the possibility that ZFM
    could “steal” Eaton‟s customers by offering a superior product
    or lower price because that possibility did not “prove[] to be
    71
    realistic.” Typescript at 47. In other words, the majority
    appears to assume that because ZFM did not lure away Eaton‟s
    customers through offering superior products or lower prices, it
    could not have done so and the reason for its inability to do so
    was the LTAs. I find the majority‟s treatment of this point to be
    an unpersuasive answer to the logic of Allied Orthopedic and
    Concord Boat.
    I hardly need make the logical point that one cannot
    assume that because an event did not happen it could not have
    happened. It appears that ZFM did not lure away Eaton‟s
    customers. That does not mean, however, that ZFM was
    incapable of doing so. It is beyond dispute and indeed a central
    point to this case that ZFM did not offer lower prices than
    Eaton‟s prices and ZFM did not develop a full product line as it
    knew it had to do in order to compete effectively with Eaton.36
    36
    The majority states, without elaboration, that Eaton assured
    that there would be no other supplier that could fulfill the
    OEMs‟ needs or offer a lower price. I note first that it is an
    undisputed fact that when Meritor entered into the joint venture
    with ZF AG at a time prior to any allegation of anticompetitive
    conduct by Eaton, Meritor did not offer a full product line of
    HD truck transmissions. Thereafter, ZFM explicitly identified
    its lack of a full product line as a barrier to its market success
    and yet it did not develop a full product line. There is no
    evidence that Eaton somehow prevented either Meritor or later
    ZFM from developing a full product line. Furthermore, there is
    no evidence in the record indicating that Eaton prevented ZFM
    from offering more attractive discounts to capture Eaton‟s
    business and there is no evidence that other firms tried to enter
    72
    In other words, ZFM did not even engage in the type of
    competitive conduct that potentially could have lured away
    Eaton‟s customers. Thus, we cannot say that it is not realistic to
    think that if it had engaged in that competition conduct ZFM
    could have been successful.37
    the HD truck transmission market but were thwarted by Eaton.
    37
    I recognize that appellees contend that “[f]ar from offering
    low prices to seek competitive advantages . . . Eaton broke the
    price mechanism, so that ZFM could not compete even by
    offering discounts or other incentives notwithstanding that ZFM
    had a better product.” Appellees‟ br. at 44. But appellees‟
    assessment of their product does not establish that the truck
    purchasers — the entities that actually made the ultimate
    decision as to which transmission to select for their trucks —
    would make the same assessment. Indeed, some of the evidence
    suggests that both OEMs and truck purchasers held the opinion
    that overall Meritor‟s products were inferior to Eaton‟s, and
    Meritor does not point to evidence foreclosing the possibility
    that its relatively unfavorable reputation in that regard persisted
    despite the emergence of ZF Meritor and thereby tainted truck
    purchasers‟ view of the FreedomLine. Moreover, even if the
    truck purchasers had come to the same conclusion as appellees
    regarding the FreedomLine‟s technical superiority, appellees‟
    complaint holds no force as the purchasers‟ were at all times
    free to act on that opinion by selecting the FreedomLine for their
    trucks. Nevertheless, it is clear from the record that other
    factors beyond possible technical superiority, including such
    considerations as price, service, and availability of the product,
    73
    Second, the majority attempts to overcome this absolutely
    fundamental defect in appellees‟ case by concluding that
    notwithstanding the fact that the LTAs were not by their terms
    mandatory and the fact that Eaton‟s prices after consideration of
    the rebates were at all times above-cost such that appellees, were
    they equally efficient competitors, could have matched them,
    there nevertheless was sufficient evidence that the LTAs
    foreclosed competition in a substantial share of the HD truck
    transmission market because “the targets were as effective as
    mandatory purchase requirements.” Typescript at 42. In this
    regard, the majority reasons that “[c]ritically, due to Eaton‟s
    position as the dominant supplier no OEM could satisfy
    customer demand without at least some Eaton products, and
    therefore no OEM could afford to lose Eaton as a supplier.” Id.
    at 43. Therefore, the majority reasons, “a jury could have
    concluded that, under the circumstances, the market penetration
    targets were as effective as express purchase requirements
    because no risk averse business would jeopardize its relationship
    could motivate a purchaser in making its decision as to the most
    advantageous transmission for it to purchase. Lest this fact be
    doubted I merely need to point out that consumers regularly
    purchase inexpensive automobiles even though more highly-
    priced automobiles might be technically better. Overall, the
    point remains that if ZFM was an equally efficient competitor
    the LTAs simply did not preclude it from competing with Eaton
    and did not foreclose competition in any portion of the market,
    and thus a jury verdict based on a contrary conclusion simply
    could not survive Eaton‟s motion for judgment as a matter of
    law.
    74
    with the largest manufacturer of transmissions in the market.”
    Id. (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).
    Undoubtedly, there is evidence in the record that the
    OEMs required Eaton‟s products, to the end that an OEM could
    not have afforded to lose Eaton as a supplier. However, there is
    not a scintilla of evidence that if an OEM did not meet its LTA‟s
    market-share target Eaton would have refused to supply it with
    transmissions. First, as the majority notes, only the Freightliner
    LTA and the Volvo LTA granted Eaton the right to terminate
    the LTA altogether if the OEM did not meet its market-share
    targets. Yet the fact that Eaton had the right to terminate those
    LTAs if those OEMs did not meet their targets — notably, a
    right that it did not exercise when Freightliner failed to achieve
    the market-share target in 2002 — is no more significant than
    the fact that Eaton would not have to pay the rebate if
    Freightliner did not meet the target. Termination of the LTA
    simply made unavailable the rebates to those OEMs; it did not,
    as the majority implies, mean that Eaton no longer would
    provide transmissions to those OEMs. It simply meant that
    those OEMs would not receive Eaton‟s transmissions at the
    discounted prices the LTAs offered.
    I understand that the LTAs are supply agreements that
    ensure that Eaton will meet the OEMs‟ transmission needs and
    do so at a certain price and under certain conditions, and an
    OEM lacking a supply agreement may be in an unfavorable
    position as it would prefer a supply agreement to set the terms of
    its relationship with Eaton. Nevertheless, although an OEM
    with a cancelled LTA would have lacked a supply agreement
    with Eaton, at least temporarily, one cannot infer from that fact
    75
    that Eaton would not have supplied the OEM with its
    transmissions. Furthermore, the majority glosses over the fact
    that PACCAR‟s and International‟s LTAs did not include a
    provision granting Eaton the right to terminate the LTAs if those
    OEMs did not meet their respective market-share targets.
    Nevertheless, regardless of whether the LTAs granted
    Eaton a right of termination, the majority‟s suggestion that the
    OEMs faced losing Eaton as a supplier if they failed to meet the
    market-share targets is contradicted by the market reality that
    while Eaton was the largest manufacturer of transmissions in the
    market there were only four OEMs that bought Eaton‟s
    transmissions. Accordingly, the idea that Eaton could or would
    have refused to deal with one of the OEMs in addition to being
    unsupported by the record is irrational from an economic
    viewpoint for if Eaton had done so it would have turned its back
    on a significant purchaser of its products measured in sales
    volume. The notion is completely unjustified.
    Perhaps if appellees had produced evidence at the trial
    that Eaton had threatened to refuse to supply transmissions to an
    OEM that did not meet its market-share targets the non-
    mandatory market-share targets would have taken on an air of
    the mandatory threats that the majority insists they actually
    were. Literally the only evidence that I can identify relating to
    this contention is deposition testimony by a Volvo representative
    relaying an email he had received from one of his colleagues in
    which the colleague stated that Volvo needed to meet its market
    share target because if it was not successful it faced “a big risk
    of cancellation of the contract, price increases and shortages if
    the market is difficult,” J.A. at 688, and a sentence from an
    76
    internal Volvo presentation in which it speculated that if Eaton
    terminated its LTA it would have “[n]o delivery performance
    commitment (possibly disastrous),” id. at 2101. While I
    understand that we view a jury‟s verdict through a deferential
    lens, even under that standard I cannot conclude that one
    sentence of second-hand speculation from a contracting party
    but not from Eaton as to whether Eaton might provide an OEM
    with an insufficient volume of transmissions in the event of a
    market shortage and an unidentified Volvo representative‟s
    statement that if it did not have a delivery performance
    commitment from Eaton it could be potentially disastrous is
    sufficient to sustain the inference that facially voluntary market-
    share targets were in reality the mandatory, almost extortionary,
    provisions the majority makes them out to be.38
    I must address also an aspect of the majority‟s reasoning
    on this point that I find to suffer from a serious flaw with
    dangerous implications for antitrust jurisprudence. Perhaps the
    majority does not believe that any evidence was required to
    rebut the reality that even though the market-share targets were
    38
    The majority appears to hang its hat to some extent on the
    notion that even if the OEMs did not actually face the threat of
    losing Eaton as a supplier they believed they might and that
    belief drove their compliance with the LTAs. While, as noted,
    there is scant evidence, indeed, for the proposition that the
    OEMs‟ efforts to meet the market-share targets was driven by
    such a belief, that belief, if unfounded as it was here, does not
    support the majority‟s repeated statements to the effect that
    Eaton actually coerced the OEMs into entering the LTAs and
    meeting the targets.
    77
    facially voluntary, the mere circumstances that Eaton was the
    dominant supplier in the market and that no OEM could afford
    to lose it as a supplier sufficed to render the LTAs mandatory.
    The majority‟s reasoning in this regard literally would mean that
    had Eaton not been the dominant supplier of HD truck
    transmissions in the NAFTA market, there would not have been
    sufficient evidence for the jury to conclude that the LTAs were
    de facto exclusive. While I realize that monopolists may face
    more constraints on their conduct under the antitrust laws than
    less dominant firms, see LePage‟s, 
    324 F.3d at 151-52
    , it is an
    unfair and unwarranted leap to create the specter of coercion out
    of reference to Eaton‟s market dominance, cf. R.J. Reynolds,
    
    199 F. Supp. 2d at 392
     (“The strong position of Marlboro,
    however, does not, standing alone „coerce‟ retailers into signing
    . . . [market-share] agreements.”). In sum, I cannot ascribe to
    the view that a non-mandatory, non-exclusive contract is
    transformed magically into a mandatory, exclusive contract by
    virtue of reference to the firm‟s market position alone such that
    dominant firms must be wary when they enter voluntary
    contracts that offer rebates or discounts lest a court later permit
    a jury to interpret those contracts as mandatory simply due to
    that firm‟s dominant position.
    Apart from insinuating that Eaton‟s dominant market
    position coerced the OEMs into meeting the market-share
    targets, the majority adds to the picture of coercion it attempts to
    paint by stating that “there was evidence that Eaton leveraged its
    position as a supplier of necessary products to coerce the OEMs
    into entering into the LTAs.” Typescript at 48. Relatedly, the
    majority states that appellees “presented testimony from OEM
    officials that many of the terms of the LTAs were unfavorable to
    78
    the OEMs and their customers, but that the OEMs agreed to
    such terms because without Eaton‟s transmissions, the OEMs
    would be unable to satisfy customer demand.” 
    Id.
    In point of fact, there is not a trace of evidence beyond
    appellees‟ own baseless accusations and the majority does not
    bring our attention to any such evidence supporting its rather
    serious accusation that Eaton leveraged its position as a
    monopolist to force the OEMs to enter into agreements that the
    OEMs did not want to enter.39 Eaton‟s offer of lower prices to
    39
    Appellees contend that the OEMs did not want to enter the
    LTAs and did so only in response to Eaton‟s coercion by citing
    to testimony that in fact weakens their case. In this regard,
    appellees rely on a Volvo representative‟s testimony that it
    entered into the LTA with Eaton because ZFM did not have a
    full product line and thus Volvo would require Eaton‟s products
    even if it entered into an LTA with ZFM but if Eaton was not its
    standard partner it would not provide favorable pricing to
    Volvo. See J.A. at 522; see also J.A. 2098 (noting that Eaton
    would not provide favorable pricing to Volvo if it selected ZFM
    as its partner). In part for this reason, it elected to enter the LTA
    with Eaton.
    In business as in life we rarely are presented with a
    perfect option. The fact that long-term supply agreements with
    ZFM and Eaton each had their respective advantages and
    disadvantages is hardly surprising and that Eaton would not
    have granted an OEM the generous discounts its LTA provided
    if it selected ZFM as its primary supplier is likewise not exactly
    an astonishing revelation. That the OEMs had to weigh these
    79
    the OEMs in the form of rebates and direct payments in an effort
    to gain their business is hardly coercion. Rather, it is nothing
    more than legitimate good business practice. See Race Tires,
    
    614 F.3d at 79
     (“[I]t is no more an act of coercion, collusion, or
    improper interference for [suppliers] . . . to offer more money to
    [customers] . . . than it is for such suppliers to offer the lowest . .
    . prices.”).
    Likewise, there is no evidence that the LTAs represented
    unfavorable arrangements for the OEMs such that the OEMs
    only agreed to enter the contracts out of fear of losing Eaton as a
    supplier.40 Indeed, to the extent one may be tempted to infer
    factors in deciding whether to enter into an LTA with Eaton
    hardly amounts to coercion.
    40
    In their brief, appellees point to the testimony of two OEM
    representatives who testified to the hardly surprising fact that
    they would have preferred upfront price cuts with no strings
    attached as opposed to conditional market-share targets but that
    the OEMs entered the agreements because they nonetheless
    offered the best prices. See J.A. at 415-16 (deposition testimony
    of International representative) (stating that International
    preferred to have upfront discounts “in price” but “if a supplier
    is willing to offer [it] rebates” it would take that option if it
    believed it could meet the conditions for those rebates); see id.
    at 525 (deposition testimony of Volvo representative) (stating
    that during LTA negotiations Volvo “wanted no” market-share
    targets but it agreed to the 68% target because it believed it
    could achieve that target and it “wanted the savings and the
    equalization, and the rebates”). That the OEMs would have
    80
    that the market-share targets were so high as to be unfavorable
    to the OEMs I note that the targets were actually very close to or
    in fact below Eaton‟s preexisting market share at three out of the
    four OEMs measured at a time before the adoption of the LTAs
    during which appellees do not claim that Eaton was violating
    any law. See J.A. at 4779 (Dr. DeRamus‟ expert report)
    (Eaton‟s LTA with International began providing rebates at 80%
    market share but Eaton‟s market share of International‟s
    transmission needs prior to the LTA already was 79%); id. at
    4785 (Eaton‟s LTA with PACCAR provided rebates beginning
    at 90% but Eaton‟s market share “consistently hover[ed] around
    90% or higher for HD transmissions” with PACCAR prior to the
    LTA); id. at 4793 (Eaton‟s LTA with Volvo provided a rebate
    starting at 65% market share but Eaton‟s market share of
    Volvo‟s transmissions was 85% when they entered the LTA in
    2002.). The reality that the market share levels that Eaton
    reached prior to the adoption of the LTAs makes it, in a word I
    do not like using but fits perfectly here, ridiculous to conclude
    that the LTAs had a coercive effect on the OEMs.
    preferred that Eaton simply cut its prices is hardly surprising.
    Customers faced with a buy one at full price and get one for
    50% off deal likely would prefer to have the option of buying
    one item for 50% off. Yet, in the same way that the customer
    who purchases the two items to receive the discount on one
    cannot be said to have been “coerced” into that transaction, the
    OEMs‟ preference for unconditional price cuts hardly can be
    used as evidence that the terms of the LTAs were “unfavorable”
    to them, much less so “unfavorable” as to warrant the inference
    that the OEMs must have entered them as a product of coercion.
    81
    After studying the majority‟s treatment of the LTAs I am
    left with the impression that it pictures Eaton representatives as
    using coercion when they handed the OEM representatives the
    LTAs. Yet the reality is that there is absolutely no evidence in
    the record suggesting that Eaton compelled the OEMs by the
    threat of punishment to agree to the LTAs or compelled them to
    meet the share targets.41 Quite to the contrary, the record is
    replete with evidence, as I have summarized above, that shows
    that far from cowering under Eaton‟s “threats,” the OEMs
    entered into the LTAs in furtherance of their own economic self-
    interests and because those agreements provided the best
    possible prices and assurance of a full product line supply. They
    worked to meet the market-share targets because by achieving
    those targets they received discounted prices.
    Tellingly, the evidence also shows that the OEMs used
    those arrangements to their advantage. An illuminating example
    of this market reality is found in a letter an International
    representative wrote to ZFM in June 2002, in which the
    representative recounted the HD truck market‟s dramatic slump
    and stated to ZFM that:
    In the last 12 months, your competition has
    supported our need for cost control with price
    41
    Of course, the lack of coercion associated with the LTAs is
    significant. While coercion is not “an essential element of every
    antitrust claim,” it is an important consideration where the
    relevant market players adopt their own business practices and
    the parties “freely entered into exclusive contracts.” Race Tires,
    
    614 F.3d at 78
    .
    82
    reductions consistent with the trend in new truck
    pricing. In addition, one of your competitors [i.e.,
    Eaton] has offered International a compelling
    incentive to increase their sales at your expense.
    As a result, International is seriously considering
    shifting your portion of our buy to alternative
    suppliers.
    International values the relationship our
    companies have created over the years. However,
    the relationship is in jeopardy if your lack of cost
    competitiveness cannot be overcome.              We
    therefore require a 5% across the board price
    reduction effective August 1, 2002.
    J.A. at 4596 (letter from Paul D. Barkus, International, to Robert
    S. Harrison, ZFM (June 18, 2002)). In fact, the record shows
    that six months prior to this correspondence, International had
    attempted to use its relationship with Eaton as leverage to gain
    further cost reductions from ZFM. See id. at 3727 (electronic
    mail from Paul D. Barkus, International, to Galynn Skelnik,
    International (Jan. 11, 2002)) (“I got a phone message from
    [ZFM] . . . stating that after much internal discussion they have
    decided not to offer any transmission reductions even though
    their list prices could be increased. . . . Our strategy was to give
    Meritor the impression that our Partnership with Eaton provided
    us with HD reductions that would increase Meritor‟s list price if
    they didn‟t offset the widened price gap. That started out as a
    bluff, but when we look at our option prices between the two
    supplier[s] there appears to be some cost/price inconsistency.”).
    In sum, because appellees failed to produce evidence to show
    83
    that the LTAs and their voluntary, above-cost market-share
    target rebates could have or did foreclose competition in any,
    much less a substantial, share of the market, notwithstanding the
    jury‟s verdict it is obvious that appellees‟ claims must fail under
    Tampa Electric.
    Before moving on, I think it appropriate to make a final
    point on the importance of the Tampa Electric standard and to
    illuminate fully why I depart from the majority‟s application of
    that case. As I already have noted, exclusive-dealing contracts
    are not per se unlawful and, indeed, may lead to more
    competition in the marketplace as firms compete for such
    potentially lucrative arrangements. Accordingly, one must ask
    why antitrust law ever would forbid such contracts. The reason,
    as the Supreme Court‟s Tampa Electric standard makes clear, is
    that where there is such an agreement, the seller‟s competitors
    cannot compete for the percentage of the market that a purchaser
    needs because the purchaser has signed a contract to deal only in
    the goods of that particular seller (or has signed a contract that
    has that practical effect). Even if the seller‟s competitors can
    offer a better deal to the purchaser, the purchaser is precluded
    from accepting competing offers because they have entered the
    exclusive-dealing arrangement. Cf. Standard Oil, 
    337 U.S. at 314
    , 
    69 S.Ct. at 1062
     (requirements contract violated Section 3
    because “observance by a dealer of his requirements contract
    with Standard does effectively foreclose whatever opportunity
    there might be for competing suppliers to attract his patronage,
    and . . . the affected proportion of retail sales of petroleum
    products is substantial”). Therefore, competition is foreclosed
    in that percentage of the marketplace and under Tampa Electric
    the question is simply whether that foreclosure is substantial,
    84
    considering the quantity of the foreclosure and the qualitative
    aspects of the marketplace and the agreement itself.
    It is that foreclosure of competition, the elimination of
    the possibility that the seller‟s competitors can capture that
    portion of the market through vigorous competition, with which
    Section 3 (and Section 1 of the Sherman Act in exclusive-
    dealing cases) is concerned. See Tampa Elec. Co., 
    365 U.S. at 328
    , 
    81 S.Ct. at 629
     (emphasis added) (observing that “the
    ultimate question” is “whether the contract forecloses
    competition in a substantial share of the line of commerce
    involved”). The Tampa Electric market-foreclosure analysis
    thus assumes that a circumstance existed which appellees seek
    and fail to prove existed here: that there was an exclusive-
    dealing arrangement between a market seller and purchaser.
    Now consider the case at hand. The parties do not
    dispute that the LTAs did not require the OEMs to purchase
    anything, much less 100% of their needs, from Eaton and
    appellees do not contend that Eaton‟s prices were below cost.
    Accordingly, appellees remained free at all times to compete for
    the OEMs‟ (and the truck purchasers‟) business. Appellees, if
    they were equally efficient competitors, were at liberty to offer
    lower prices, better products, more logistical and technical
    support, or any other myriad considerations to make their
    products more attractive to the OEMs, and the OEMs and the
    truck purchasers were at all times free to accept appellees‟
    products and services. Accordingly, the LTAs did not foreclose
    competition in any portion of the market. This basic point —
    that the LTAs were not in fact exclusive-dealing arrangements
    that foreclosed competition in any portion of the market —
    85
    explains appellees‟ failure to identify before us any credible,
    precise percentage of market foreclosure. Appellees‟ failure to
    meet their burden under Tampa Electric to prove any
    quantitative degree of market foreclosure should spell the end of
    their Section 3 and Section 1 claims.
    Although I believe that appellees‟ failure in this regard
    renders unnecessary discussion of the qualitative analysis under
    Tampa Electric, I note briefly that contrary to the majority‟s
    discussion, the qualitative inquiry elucidates further why the
    LTAs did not violate Section 3. Contrary to the majority‟s
    statement that the long duration of the contracts added to their
    alleged anticompetitiveness, the duration of the LTAs is of little
    to no significance because they did not actually preclude the
    OEMs from purchasing competitors‟ products at any time during
    the life of the LTA. Because the OEMs were free to walk away
    from the discounts at any time it does not matter how long Eaton
    promised to offer those discounts to the OEMs.
    Moreover, a claim of lack of ease of terminability is
    likewise a non-starter given the LTAs were terminable at will;
    the agreements simply would have lost their force once the
    OEMs decided to seek Eaton‟s competitors‟ products and forego
    the market-share rebate.42 The majority denies that the LTAs
    42
    Although I conclude that the LTAs did not foreclose
    competition in any portion of the market, if as the majority
    concludes, the LTAs did foreclose competition in the market,
    that alleged foreclosure effect necessarily was diminished by the
    fact that the LTAs at most blocked only one avenue of reaching
    the end-users, i.e., the truck purchasers. Component part
    86
    were easily terminable by reasoning that “the OEMs had a
    strong economic incentive to adhere to the terms of the LTAs,
    and therefore were not free to walk away from the agreements.”
    Typescript at 52. I reject the majority‟s ipse dixit reasoning on
    this point. While Eaton offered through the LTAs financial
    incentives that undoubtedly served as the OEMs‟ motivation to
    meet the market-share targets, the LTAs‟ promise of financial
    reward does not mean that the OEMs were not at liberty to leave
    the LTAs behind to take up a more attractive offer. Economic
    incentives are by their nature fluid and the OEMs‟ incentives
    might have shifted in the face of a more financially appealing
    option.
    Additionally, “[t]he existence of legitimate business
    justifications for the contracts also supports the legality of the . .
    . contracts.” Barr Labs., 
    978 F.2d at 111
    . In this regard,
    evidence that the defendant‟s actions were motivated by an
    ordinary business motive is significant. See Aspen Skiing Co. v.
    Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 
    472 U.S. 585
    , 608, 
    105 S.Ct. 2847
    , 2860 (1985) (noting that “[p]erhaps most significant . . . is
    the evidence related to [defendant] itself, for [defendant] did not
    persuade the jury that its conduct was justified by any normal
    business purpose”). Eaton contends that the LTAs were
    designed to meet the OEMs‟ demands to lower prices by
    consolidating their component part suppliers and that the OEMs
    manufacturers, including ZFM, can and do advertise directly to
    truck purchasers and are able to offer discounts directly to those
    consumers as an incentive for them to select their parts from
    their data books, and truck purchasers were at all times free to
    select appellees‟ products.
    87
    entered the contracts because they afforded the best possible
    prices. As I noted above, the record supports this assertion as
    representatives from each of the OEMs testified that the OEMs
    entered into the LTAs because those agreements were
    financially attractive, and ZFM itself noted in 2001 that the
    OEMs sought a single-source supplier.43 Additionally, an Eaton
    representative testified that when the OEMs increase their
    purchases of Eaton‟s products, Eaton is able to “translate that
    volume into [a] lower cost base, [and] come up with the funds
    and the revenue to give them [the OEMs] more competitive
    pricing, which is what they were asking for.” J.A. at 1398.
    In a similar circumstance, we concluded that a defendant
    drug manufacturer offered valid business justifications to defeat
    its competitor‟s Section 1 and Section 3 claims, which attacked
    the defendant‟s offer of contracts that provided volume-based
    discounts to warehouse chain drug stores. See Barr Labs., 978
    F.3d at 104-05. We found that there were “legitimate business
    justifications for the contracts” because “the evidence
    established that the warehouse chains [that carried defendant‟s
    products] entered the contracts because of the inherent
    advantages they saw in them in price, convenience, and service”
    and “[t]he contracts also proved advantageous from Abbott‟s
    perspective in terms of reaping business goodwill, and as
    providing high volume, low transaction cost outlets for Abbott‟s
    43
    The majority states that the procompetitive justifications of the
    LTAs are diminished by the fact that no OEM asked Eaton to be
    a sole supplier. My response to that assertion is as simple as
    remarking once more that the LTAs did not by their terms or by
    their effect make Eaton a sole supplier for any of the OEMs.
    88
    manufacturing capacity.” Id. at 111; see also Virgin Atl.
    Airways, 
    257 F.3d at 265
     (finding that defendant proffered pro-
    competitive justification for market-share incentive agreement
    because such agreements “allow firms to reward their most loyal
    customers” and “[r]ewarding customer loyalty promotes
    competition on the merits”); Barry Wright, 
    724 F.2d at 237
    (finding legitimate business justification for requirements
    contracts because for the purchaser “the contracts guaranteed a
    stable source of supply, and, perhaps, more importantly, they
    assured [the purchaser] a stable, favorable price” and for the
    seller “they allowed use of considerable excess . . . [product]
    capacity and they allowed production planning that was likely to
    lower costs”).
    Undoubtedly, Eaton was motivated to tender the LTAs
    because of its desire to increase sales of its product. Although
    such a motivation could not excuse otherwise anticompetitive
    conduct, the desire to sell more product is an ordinary business
    purpose, and the antitrust laws do not prohibit such motivation.
    As the Supreme Court stated in Cargill, “competition for
    increased market share[] is not activity forbidden by the antitrust
    laws. It is simply . . . vigorous competition.” 
    479 U.S. at 116
    ,
    
    107 S.Ct. at 492
     (emphasis added); see also Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1062
     (noting that defendant‟s proffered reason that it
    was “trying to sell its product” through market-share discounts
    constituted valid, pro-competitive business justification for
    program); Stearns Airport Equip. Co. v. FMC Corp., 
    170 F.3d 518
    , 524 (5th Cir. 1999) (observing that defendant‟s explanation
    that “it was trying to sell its product” was valid business
    justification).
    89
    Tampa Electric makes clear that “it is the preservation of
    competition which is at stake” under Section 3. 
    365 U.S. at 328
    ,
    
    81 S.Ct. at 628
     (emphasis added and internal quotations marks
    and citation omitted). Here, appellees remained free at all times
    to compete for the OEMs‟ business and directly for customers‟
    business and yet the majority permits a jury to condemn the
    LTAs. I cannot join in that conclusion. Appellees failed to
    supply an evidentiary basis to establish that the LTAs had the
    probable effect of foreclosing competition in a substantial share
    of the market and thus they failed to produce evidence that could
    demonstrate that Eaton violated Section 3 of the Clayton Act.
    Because Section 3 of the Clayton Act sweeps more broadly than
    Section 1 of the Sherman Act, appellees likewise failed to show
    that Eaton violated Section 1.
    C. Sherman Act Section 2 Claim
    Appellees presented the same evidence and same de facto
    exclusive dealing theory on which they based their Section 2
    claim as they did to support their Clayton Act Section 3 and
    Sherman Act Section 1 claims. In light of my lengthy analysis
    of appellees‟ other claims, I will abbreviate my discussion of
    their Section 2 claim.
    Section 2 targets defendants who “monopolize or attempt
    to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or
    persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce
    among the several States, or with foreign nations.” 
    15 U.S.C. § 2
    . To establish a Section 2 violation, a plaintiff must show that:
    (1) the defendant possessed monopoly power in the relevant
    market and (2) the defendant willfully acquired or maintained
    90
    that power “as distinguished from growth or development as a
    consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic
    accident.” Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 
    504 U.S. 451
    , 481, 
    112 S.Ct. 2072
    , 2089 (1992) (quoting United
    States v. Grinnell Corp., 
    384 U.S. 563
    , 570-71, 
    86 S.Ct. 1698
    ,
    1704 (1966)). Eaton acknowledges that it has monopoly power
    in the NAFTA HD truck transmission market, and thus I focus
    my discussion on whether it has maintained that monopoly
    through unlawful means.
    A monopolist willfully acquires or maintains monopoly
    power in contravention of Section 2 if it “attempt[s] to exclude
    rivals on some basis other than efficiency.” Aspen Skiing Co.,
    
    472 U.S. at 605
    , 105 S.Ct. at 2859. “Anticompetitive conduct
    may take a variety of forms, but it is generally defined as
    conduct to obtain or maintain monopoly power as a result of
    competition on some basis other than the merits.” Broadcom
    Corp. v. Qualcomm Inc., 
    501 F.3d 297
    , 308 (3d Cir. 2007)
    (citation omitted). “[E]xclusive dealing arrangements can be an
    improper means of maintaining a monopoly.” Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at
    187 (citing Grinnell Corp., 
    384 U.S. 563
    , 
    86 S.Ct. 1698
    ;
    LePage‟s, 
    324 F.3d at 157
    ).
    The District Court denied Eaton‟s motion seeking a
    judgment as a matter of law on appellees‟ Section 2 claim as it
    concluded that “[t]he jury found that [Eaton] had willfully
    acquired or maintained its monopoly power through LTAs that
    amounted to de facto exclusive dealing contracts having the
    power to foreclose competition from the marketplace.” ZFM,
    
    769 F. Supp. 2d at 697
     (emphasis added). In this regard, the
    Court concluded that “„neither proof of exertion of the power to
    91
    exclude nor proof of actual exclusion of existing or potential
    competitors is essential to sustain a charge of monopolization
    under the Sherman Act.‟” 
    Id.
     (quoting LePage‟s, 
    324 F.3d at 148
    ).
    The District Court‟s finding on this point reflected its
    misunderstanding of the requirements of Section 2. As we
    recently stated in Dentsply:
    Unlawful maintenance of a monopoly is
    demonstrated by proof that a defendant has
    engaged in anti-competitive conduct that
    reasonably appears to be a significant contribution
    to maintaining monopoly power. Predatory or
    exclusionary practices in themselves are not
    sufficient. There must be proof that competition,
    not merely competitors, has been harmed.
    399 F.3d at 187 (citing LePage‟s, 
    324 F.3d at 162
    ) (emphasis
    added) (citations omitted); see also Broadcom, 
    501 F.3d at 308
    (“[T]he acquisition or possession of monopoly power must be
    accompanied by some anticompetitive conduct on the part of the
    possessor.”) (citing Verizon Commc‟ns Inc. v. Law Offices of
    Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 
    540 U.S. 398
    , 407, 
    124 S.Ct. 872
    , 878-
    79 (2004)).
    Indeed, in Dentsply we made clear that a plaintiff‟s
    demonstration that the defendant merely possessed the power to
    exclude is not a sufficient basis on which to build a claim that
    the defendant is culpable under Section 2; a plaintiff must show
    that the defendant used its power to foreclose competition. See
    92
    399 F.3d at 191 (“Having demonstrated that Dentsply possessed
    market power, the Government must also establish the second
    element of a Section 2 claim, that the power was used „to
    foreclose competition.‟”) (quoting United States v. Griffith, 
    334 U.S. 100
    , 107, 
    68 S.Ct. 941
    , 945 (1948)) (emphasis added). As
    the Supreme Court explained in Trinko:
    The mere possession of monopoly power, and the
    concomitant charging of monopoly prices, is not
    only not unlawful; it is an important element of
    the free-market system. The opportunity to
    charge monopoly prices — at least for a short
    period — is what attracts „business acumen‟ in
    the first place; it induces risk taking that produces
    innovation and economic growth. To safeguard
    the incentive to innovate, the possession of
    monopoly power will not be found unlawful
    unless it is accompanied by an element of
    anticompetitive conduct.
    
    540 U.S. at 407
    , 
    124 S.Ct. at 879
     (emphasis in original).
    “Conduct that merely harms competitors . . . while not
    harming the competitive process itself, is not anticompetitive.”
    Broadcom, 
    501 F.3d at 308
    ; see also Spectrum Sports, Inc. v.
    McQuillan, 
    506 U.S. 447
    , 458, 
    113 S.Ct. 884
    , 892 (1993) (The
    Sherman Act “directs itself not against conduct which is
    competitive, even severely so, but against conduct which
    unfairly tends to destroy competition itself.”). To determine
    whether a practice is anticompetitive in violation of Section 2,
    we consider “whether the challenged practices bar a substantial
    93
    number of rivals or severely restrict the market‟s ambit.”
    Dentsply, 399 F.3d at 191 (citations omitted). Thus, the
    standard for ascertaining whether certain conduct is
    anticompetitive under Section 2 is quite similar to the market-
    foreclosure analysis under Section 3 of the Clayton Act.
    “Conduct that impairs the opportunities of rivals and either does
    not further competition on the merits or does so in an
    unnecessarily restrictive way may be deemed anticompetitive.”
    W. Penn Allegheny Health Sys., 627 F.3d at 108 (internal
    quotation marks and citation omitted).
    Accordingly, for largely the same reasons that appellees‟
    Section 3 and Section 1 claims fail, so, too, does their Section 2
    claim. Because the LTAs did not obligate the OEMs to
    purchase anything from Eaton and did not condition the rebates
    on Eaton having a 100% market share and because its prices
    were at all times above-cost, the LTAs allowed any equally
    efficient competitor, including appellees, if they were equally
    efficient competitors, to compete. Thus, the LTAs did not bar
    Eaton‟s competitors from the market nor did the LTAs impair
    their opportunities to compete with Eaton for the business the
    LTAs covered. Cf. NicSand, Inc. v. 3M Co., 
    507 F.3d 442
    , 452
    (6th Cir. 2007) (en banc) (plaintiff failed to demonstrate
    antitrust injury under Sherman Act Section 2 because
    defendant‟s rebates and up-front payments to retailers pursuant
    to exclusive dealing contract were above-cost).
    In this regard, the LTAs stand in stark contrast to the
    contracts at issue in Dentsply, a case on which appellees and the
    majority rely heavily. In Dentsply we considered whether
    Dentsply, a monopolist in the field of the production of artificial
    94
    teeth, violated Section 2 of the Sherman Act through a provision
    called “Dealer Criterion 6” in its contracts with dealers, who, in
    turn, sold the products to dental laboratories. See 399 F.3d at
    184-85. The provision, which Dentsply “imposed . . . on its
    dealers” prohibited the dealers from adding non-Dentsply tooth
    lines to their product offering. See id. Dealers who carried
    competing lines prior to the implementation of Dealer Criterion
    6 were permitted to continue carrying non-Dentsply products,
    but Dentsply enforced Dealer Criterion 6 against all other
    dealers. See id.
    We concluded that Dealer Criterion 6 violated Section 2
    because “[b]y ensuring that the key dealers offer Dentsply teeth
    either as the only or dominant choice, Dealer Criterion 6 ha[d] a
    significant effect in preserving Dentsply‟s monopoly.” Id. at
    191. We noted that “Criterion 6 impose[d] an „all-or-nothing‟
    choice on the dealers” and “[t]he fact that dealers ha[d] chosen
    not to drop Dentsply teeth in favor of a rival‟s brand
    demonstrates that they ha[d] acceded to heavy economic
    pressure.” Id. at 196. Accordingly, we concluded that Dealer
    Criterion 6 harmed competition by “keep[ing] sales of
    competing teeth below the critical level necessary for any rival
    to pose a real threat to Dentsply‟s market share.” Id. at 191.
    Criterion 6 so limited competitors‟ sales because Dentsply‟s
    competitors realistically could not hope to compete solely
    through direct sales to laboratories and because “[a] dealer
    locked into the Dentsply line [wa]s unable to heed a request for
    a different manufacturers‟ product . . . .” Id. at 194.
    Unlike Dealer Criterion 6, the LTAs did not impose an
    “all-or-nothing” choice on the OEMs because they did not
    95
    prohibit the OEMs from purchasing or from offering to its HD
    truck purchasers non-Eaton transmissions. Accordingly, the
    LTAs did not suppress sales of appellees‟ products because the
    OEMs were able to and, in fact, did heed truck purchasers‟
    requests for ZFM‟s products. Critically, at all times, truck
    purchasers retained the freedom to make the ultimate decision
    with respect to the transmissions they would select. Thus, the
    situation here differs from that in Dentsply because the LTAs
    did not have the effect of making Eaton the only choice for truck
    purchasers nor did it impair the purchasers‟ choice in the
    marketplace. See J.A. at 1530 (deposition testimony of Paul D.
    Barkus, International) (indicating that International‟s LTA
    included a clause explicitly stating that International was not
    precluded from dealing in Eaton‟s competitors‟ products
    because International “would never jeopardize a condition of
    sale based on a customer specifying a product that [it] would
    refuse to provide”).
    Adding to the specter of restricted customer choice, the
    majority states that the OEMs worked with Eaton to force feed
    Eaton‟s products to customers and to shift truck fleets from
    using ZFM transmissions to Eaton transmissions. It appears that
    there is some evidence in the record for the unsurprising
    contention that the OEMs sought to meet the market share
    targets and thus obtain the rebates in part by persuading their
    customers to select Eaton‟s products. Indeed, in all walks of life
    if a salesperson has more to gain by selling a customer product
    X as opposed to product Y it is to be expected that the
    salesperson will push the customer to select product X.
    Ultimately, however, the majority does not and cannot dispute
    the fact that the HD truck purchasers at all times were free to
    96
    select any transmission, including ZFM‟s transmissions, for
    their truck orders.
    Though appellees also assert that the LTA provisions that
    required the OEMs to list Eaton‟s products as the preferred and
    standard option in their data books constituted anticompetitive
    conduct, those provisions no more support appellees‟ case than
    the rebates that the LTAs provided. Appellees claim that the
    provisions were anticompetitive because they required the
    OEMs to charge artificially higher prices for ZFM‟s products
    than for Eaton‟s. This is not the case, however, because the
    terms of the LTAs only required that the OEMs ensure that
    Eaton was priced as the lowest-cost option, which, with respect
    to the OEMs, was at all times the case.
    As a PACCAR representative explained, a component
    part manufacturer “is going to get a preferred position in the
    data book as long as . . . [it is] competitive in the marketplace,
    and being competitive in the marketplace means that . . . [it has]
    the lowest total cost to PACCAR, total cost, not just price, total
    cost.” Id. at 1553. A competitor manufacturer‟s product will be
    listed “at a premium . . . because that other transmission . . . is at
    a higher cost to PACCAR.” Id. at 1552. Indeed, that
    representative confirmed that data book positioning was in fact
    “a leverage point for [PACCAR] to negotiate . . . [to] manage
    [its] supply base.” Id. at 1553. Accordingly, Eaton‟s demand
    that the OEMs preferentially price its products reflected the fact
    that those transmissions came at the lowest cost to the OEMs
    and the fact that Eaton had made certain price concessions to the
    OEMs in exchange for that favorable listing, a practice that was
    apparently commonplace in the HD truck transmission market.
    97
    Furthermore, the demand had the added consequence of
    assuring Eaton that it receive the favorable promotion for which
    it had bargained through its price concessions. If the LTAs did
    not include requirements regarding data book placement, an
    OEM would have been able to purchase Eaton‟s transmissions at
    a low cost while listing Eaton‟s products at a higher cost to the
    truck purchasers than ZFM‟s products in its data book, thereby
    reaping a greater profit on Eaton‟s transmissions. It was entirely
    reasonable for Eaton to avoid this scenario by insisting that the
    OEMs‟ data books reflect that Eaton‟s transmissions were the
    lowest-cost, highest-value product.
    As the majority notes, it is unclear from the record
    whether the OEMs arrived at the preferential price by lowering
    the price of the preferred option or by raising the price of the
    non-preferred options until the preferred component part was the
    lowest-cost option. The LTAs simply required that the OEMs
    list Eaton as the preferred option but they did not require that the
    OEMs take either path in doing so, and thus it appears that the
    OEMs had the discretion to decide in which way they would
    make Eaton the preferred option. Of course, from the OEMs‟
    perspective, keeping the price of Eaton‟s products stable and
    raising the price of Eaton‟s competitors‟ products was the more
    financially attractive option than keeping the prices of Eaton‟s
    competitors‟ products stable and dropping the price of Eaton‟s
    products and, as the majority points out it appears there is some
    evidence in the record that the OEMs took the first path.44
    44
    Thus, as the majority notes, in an email exchange between
    Eaton and Freightliner representatives a Freightliner
    98
    Nevertheless, to the extent that the OEMs in some
    instances may have decided to ZFM‟s raise the cost of
    transmissions to arrive at the preferential price for Eaton‟s
    transmissions or to make Eaton‟s transmissions appear more
    favorable to their customers in an effort to achieve the market-
    share targets and receive the rebates, such conduct reasonably
    cannot be attributed to Eaton as neither the LTAs nor Eaton
    elsewhere required that the OEMs do so. Additionally, it is
    clearly telling with respect to data book placement provisions
    that prior to 2001 Meritor had a three-year LTA with
    representative stated that its LTA with Eaton required it to price
    ZFM‟s products at a $200 premium. Yet, Freightliner‟s LTA
    did not require that Freightliner price ZFM‟s products at a
    premium; it simply required that Eaton‟s products be the lowest-
    priced option. In light of the silence of Freightliner‟s LTA as to
    this issue, I can interpret this exchange only to mean that
    Freightliner had elected to price Eaton‟s products preferentially
    by imposing the $200 premium on ZFM‟s products. Likewise, it
    appears that International and PACCAR may have imposed
    charges on customers who selected ZFM‟s products but neither
    their respective LTA nor Eaton itself required them to do so. In
    fact, as noted, at least in regard to International, there is
    evidence in the record that suggests that the data book price
    increases for ZFM‟s transmissions were a product of
    International‟s realization in 2002 that its current price for
    ZFM‟s products did not reflect accurately the cost of that
    product to International. See J.A. at 3727 (e-mail from Paul D.
    Barkus, International, to Galynn Skelnik, International (Jan. 11,
    2002)) (proposing that International increase ZFM‟s list prices
    to bring them “in line with where they should be”).
    99
    Freightliner, under which Meritor reduced the prices of its
    component parts if Freightliner listed those parts as the standard
    option. Furthermore, there is evidence in the record that as of
    June 2002, ZFM itself was attempting to achieve exclusive
    listing in PACCAR‟s data book. See id. at 3394 (electronic
    correspondence from Tom Floyd, PACCAR, to Christian
    Benner, ZFM (June 4, 2002)) (noting that PACCAR was
    “extremely disappointed” with ZFM‟s business proposal in part
    because PACCAR was “very clear that” ZFM‟s proposal
    “should not include requirements regarding exclusive
    position[ing]” and that “it would require some extraordinary
    benefits for PACCAR in order [for ZFM] to receive
    consideration” in that regard).
    While Meritor‟s prior LTA and ZFM‟s own attempts to
    achieve exclusive data book positioning do not, in themselves,
    defeat appellees‟ claim that those tactics are anticompetitive,
    their actions are of some significance. Cf. Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 82
     (noting fact that plaintiff created and championed racing
    sanctioning bodies‟ rule that required the use of a single brand
    of tire during races and later alleged such rule violated the
    antitrust law); NicSand, 
    507 F.3d at 454
     (plaintiff‟s prior use of
    exclusive-dealing contract undermined its attack on defendant‟s
    use of such arrangements). At a minimum, ZFM‟s conduct
    belies its contention that the LTAs were far afield from the
    normal practice of the HD truck transmission market.
    In our consideration of this case we should remember that
    “[a]ntitrust analysis must always be attuned to the particular
    structure and circumstances of the industry at issue.” Trinko,
    
    540 U.S. at 411
    , 
    124 S.Ct. at 881
    . Practices from industry to
    100
    industry do not come on a one-size-fits-all basis. Here, it
    appears that bargaining between the OEMs and their suppliers
    regarding data book positioning is quite typical of the
    marketplace with which we are dealing. See Race Tires, 
    614 F.3d at 79
     (noting as relevant that it was “a common and
    generally accepted practice for a supplier to provide a sports
    sanctioning body . . . financial support in exchange for a supply
    contract”); Concord Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1062
     (observing that
    “Brunswick‟s competitors also cut prices in order to attract
    additional business, confirming that such a practice was a
    normal competitive tool within the . . . industry”); see also Trace
    X Chem., Inc. v. Canadian Indus., Ltd., 
    738 F.2d 261
    , 266 (8th
    Cir. 1984) (“Acts which are ordinary business practices typical
    of those used in a competitive market do not constitute conduct
    violative of Section 2.”).
    But appellees‟ case fails for one more reason than its
    failure to show that Eaton engaged in anticompetitive conduct,
    in that their case also did not include evidence that the LTAs
    harmed competition. See Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 187
     (“There
    must be proof that competition, not merely competitors, has
    been harmed.”). Appellees contend that the LTAs harmed
    competition by depriving truck buyers of access to the
    FreedomLine, which appellees believe was a technologically
    innovative product, and by causing truck buyers to pay higher
    prices.
    With regard to the FreedomLine, it is enough to say once
    more that the OEMs and truck purchasers were at all times free
    to purchase that transmission as well as any other of ZFM‟s
    transmissions, whether or not those transmissions were listed in
    101
    the data books.       Additionally, with the exception of
    International, the LTAs permitted the OEMs to list all of ZFM‟s
    transmissions, including the FreedomLine, in their respective
    data books and the OEMs continued to do just that.45
    Appellees do not point to any evidence in support of their
    contention that truck purchasers paid higher prices as a result of
    45
    I have not overlooked the fact that International‟s LTA
    required it to list Eaton‟s transmissions exclusively. Yet,
    International continued to list ZFM‟s manual transmissions, and
    it is thus not apparent whether its decision not to list ZFM‟s
    automated and automated mechanical transmissions is
    attributable to the LTA. Regardless, International‟s failure to
    list the FreedomLine, standing alone, did not deprive truck
    purchasers of access to the FreedomLine because truck
    purchasers were at all times free to specify the use of the
    FreedomLine transmission. Furthermore, it is important to note
    that HD truck purchasers in many cases were sophisticated
    customers in the HD truck market that were aware that ZFM‟s
    transmissions were available. Though I recognize that some
    purchasers likely were small operators perhaps owning only one
    HD truck who may have had limited knowledge of the
    differences in available transmissions, certainly the large
    purchasers, i.e., big trucking companies, would have been more
    knowledgeable with respect to available transmissions. In any
    event, we are, after all, not dealing with consumers buying
    motor vehicles for their personal use. The transmissions
    involved here were installed in vehicles intended for commercial
    use, and the owners did not acquire the vehicles to go to the
    grocery store.
    102
    the LTAs. The only evidence that I can find in the record
    relevant to appellees‟ allegation in this regard is Dr. DeRamus‟
    statement in his expert report offered by appellees that after the
    LTAs went into effect Eaton reduced its “competitive
    equalization” or incentive payments that historically it had paid
    to truck buyers as an incentive to them to select Eaton‟s
    transmissions. See J.A. at 4830. While Dr. DeRamus put forth
    data demonstrating that Eaton decreased its competitive
    equalization payments on average by about $100 (dropping from
    roughly $500 on average to just below $400 on average) from
    1999 to 2007, see id. at 4831, he did not present a scintilla of
    evidence that truck purchasers ultimately paid a higher price for
    Eaton‟s transmissions during the existence of the LTAs or
    following their expiration. Overall, it is clear that his testimony
    in this regard as an inadequate basis on which to predicate an
    antitrust case. In sum, appellees failed to put forth any — much
    less sufficient — evidence that Eaton engaged in
    anticompetitive conduct or that Eaton‟s conduct actually harmed
    competition, both of which are required elements of a claim
    under Section 2.46
    46
    Even if a plaintiff establishes under Section 2 that “monopoly
    power exists” and that “the exclusionary conduct . . . ha[s] an
    anti-competitive effect,” “the monopolist still retains a defense
    of business justification.” Dentsply, 
    399 F.3d at 187
    ; Concord
    Boat, 
    207 F.3d at 1062
     (“A Section 2 defendant‟s proffered
    business justification is the most important factor in determining
    whether its challenged conduct is not competition on the
    merits.”); Stearns Airport Equip. Co., 
    170 F.3d at 522
     (“The key
    factor courts have analyzed in order to determine whether
    103
    III. CONCLUSION
    I offer a few final thoughts on this important case, which,
    though seemingly complicated, should have an obvious result.
    It is axiomatic that “[t]he antitrust laws . . . were enacted for „the
    protection of competition not competitors.‟” Brunswick, 
    429 U.S. at 488
    , 
    97 S.Ct. at 697
     (quoting Brown Shoe Co. v. United
    States, 
    370 U.S. 294
    , 320, 
    82 S.Ct. 1502
    , 1521 (1962))
    (emphasis in original). Yet as often as this refrain is repeated
    throughout antitrust jurisprudence, it appears increasingly that
    disappointed competitors, on the assumption that their deficient
    performances must be attributable to their competitors‟
    anticompetitive conduct rather than their own errors in judgment
    or shortcomings or their competitors‟ more desirable products or
    business decisions, or on the assumption that they can convince
    a jury of that view, turn to the antitrust laws when they have
    been outperformed in the marketplace. Of course, competitors
    can be and sometimes are harmed by their peers‟ anticompetitive
    conduct and when they show that is what happened they may
    have viable antitrust claims. Yet often it is the case that a
    defeated competitor falls back on the antitrust laws in an attempt
    to achieve in the courts the goal that it could not reach in the
    challenged conduct is or is not competition on the merits is the
    proffered business justification for the act.”). As with appellees‟
    Section 3 and Section 1 claim, Eaton‟s valid business
    justifications for the LTAs undermines the notion that the LTAs
    constituted competition on some basis other than the merits in
    violation of Section 2.
    104
    properly-functioning competitive marketplace. This case is a
    classic demonstration of that process, which so far with respect
    to liability even if not damages has been successful. Indeed, I
    find it remarkable that appellees‟ case that is predicated on
    nothing more than smoke and mirrors has gotten so far.
    But the basic facts are clear. Appellees do not bring a
    predatory pricing claim because they cannot do so as Eaton‟s
    prices were above cost. Instead, they seek refuge in the law of
    exclusive dealing to challenge the LTAs, which based on the
    record could not be found to be either facially or de facto
    exclusive or mandatory. After stripping this case of appellees‟
    baseless insinuations that Eaton engaged in coercive or
    threatening conduct in regards to the LTAs, it becomes apparent
    that the core of appellees‟ claim really is their belief they had a
    superior product in the FreedomLine and the disappointing sales
    of that product relative to their expectations must have been
    attributable to Eaton‟s anticompetitive conduct. See appellees‟
    br. at 32 (“Eaton‟s conduct harmed competition and ZFM. For
    the first time in this market, a better product, even combined
    with offers of discounts, could not elicit additional sales because
    Eaton‟s LTAs and other conduct had broken the competitive
    mechanism.”). Appellees thus “appear[] to be assuming that if
    [Eaton‟s] product was not objectively superior, then its victories
    were not on the merits.” Stearns Airport Equip., 
    170 F.3d at 527
    .
    As the Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit stated in
    Stearns Airport Equipment in confronting a similar type of
    claim, courts are “ill-suited . . . to judge the relative merits of”
    the parties‟ respective products. 
    Id.
     “That decision is left in the
    105
    hands of the consumer, not the courts, and to the extent this
    judgment is „objectively‟ wrong, the inference is not that there
    has been a[n] [antitrust] violation . . . , but rather that the
    winning party displayed superior business acumen in selling its
    product.” 
    Id.
     The truth is that neither judges nor juries have
    expertise in determining the best transmission to buy. Certainly,
    the purchasers of trucks and transmissions should make
    transmission decisions for themselves and so long as appellees
    manufactured their transmissions they had a chance to be their
    supplier.
    I recognize that the record could support a finding that
    the FreedomLine was a technological innovation for which
    Eaton did not offer a technically comparable product, and I
    further recognize that Eaton engaged in vigorous competition
    through aggressive but above-cost methods to compensate for
    the possible deficiency of their transmission offerings in that
    regard. But in the absence of anticompetitive conduct, the
    antitrust laws do not forbid Eaton‟s response. See Ball Mem‟l
    Hosp., Inc. v. Mutual Hosp. Ins., Inc., 
    784 F.2d 1325
    , 1339 (7th
    Cir. 1986) (“Even the largest firms may engage in hard
    competition, knowing that this will enlarge their market
    shares.”) (citations omitted). In reality, however, the record
    compels that the conclusion that Eaton was able to maintain its
    dominant market position in the face of the availability of the
    FreedomLine for myriad reasons, including its capability of
    offering the OEMs a full product line, favorable pricing, its
    long-standing, positive reputation, and various market forces
    that favored an established market player such as Eaton. And it
    is also evident from the record, especially from ZFM‟s internal
    documents, that there were numerous intervening factors, such
    106
    as ZFM‟s precipitously falling market share, which tellingly
    predated the adoption of the LTAs, the market‟s drive towards
    full-product line manufacturers, the OEMs‟ hesitancy to
    purchase new products, and the severe market downturn, that
    disfavored ZFM.47 In the difficult market it faced, Meritor
    entered into a joint venture that needed to achieve an almost
    one-third market share within approximately four years of the
    venture‟s formation to maintain a viable business, an obviously
    ambitious goal indeed even when one overlooks the fact that the
    joint venture offered a limited product line and a flagship
    transmission that cost far more than other transmissions in the
    market.
    I note finally that courts‟ erroneous judgments in cases
    such as this one do not come without a cost to the economy as a
    47
    I recognize that as the majority points out, certain OEM
    representatives speculated that the LTAs damaged significantly
    ZFM‟s business and may have caused its ultimate demise. As I
    have stated above, it is beyond peradventure to say that “[t]he
    antitrust laws . . . were enacted for „the protection of
    competition not competitors.‟” Brunswick, 
    429 U.S. at 488
    , 
    97 S.Ct. at 697
     (internal quotation marks and citation omitted); see
    also Virgin Atl. Airways, 
    257 F.3d at 259
     (“[W]hat the antitrust
    laws are designed to protect is competitive conduct, not
    individual competitors.”). Even if the LTAs negatively affected
    ZFM‟s business, that circumstance is not the salient inquiry in
    an antitrust case. The pivotal question is whether the LTAs
    negatively affected competition — not a particular competitor —
    in the marketplace, and for the reasons I have recited above,
    they could not be found to have done that.
    107
    whole. Discounts of all varieties, whether tied to the purchase
    of multiple products, exclusivity, volume, or market-share, are
    ubiquitous in our society. “Discounts are the age-old way that
    merchants induce customers to purchase from them and not
    from someone else or to purchase more than they otherwise
    would.” Hovenkamp, Discounts and Exclusion, 2006 Utah L.
    Rev. at 843. Indeed, market-share discounts can be particularly
    pro-competitive because they can result in lower prices for a
    broader range of customers as they extend to smaller purchasers
    discounts typically reserved for the largest of purchasers under
    more common volume-discount programs. See IIIA Areeda &
    Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶786b2, at 148. “[L]ower prices
    help consumers. The competitive marketplace that the antitrust
    laws encourage and protect is characterized by firms willing and
    able to cut prices in order to take customers from their rivals.”
    Barry Wright Corp., 
    724 F.2d at 231
    . Accordingly, “mistaken
    inferences in cases such as this one are especially costly,
    because they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are
    designed to protect.” Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co., 
    475 U.S. at 594
    , 
    106 S.Ct. at 1360
    .
    Thus, as the Supreme Court has stressed, courts do not
    issue these decisions in a vacuum: once we file our opinion in
    this case firms that engage in price competition but seek to stay
    within the confines of the antitrust laws must attempt to use the
    precedent that we establish as a guide for their conduct, at least
    if they are subject to the law of this Circuit. This is serious
    business indeed.48 For this reason, the Supreme Court has
    48
    Of course, every decision we make is serious business and I do
    not imply otherwise. However, particularly in light of the
    108
    “repeatedly emphasized the importance of clear rules in antitrust
    law.” Linkline, 555 U.S. at 452, 129 S.Ct. at 1120-21; see also
    Town of Concord v. Bos. Edison Co., 
    915 F.2d 17
    , 22 (1st Cir.
    1990) (Breyer, C.J.) (Antitrust rules “must be administratively
    workable and therefore cannot always take account of every
    complex economic circumstance or qualification.”). I confess I
    can glean no such clear rule from the majority‟s opinion. I do
    not know how corporate counsel presented with a firm‟s
    business plan at least if it is a dominant supplier that seeks to
    expand sales through a discount program that might be
    challenged by competitors as providing for a de facto exclusive
    dealing program and asked if the plan is lawful under the
    Sherman and Clayton Acts will be able to advise the
    management. The sad truth is that the counsel only will be able
    to tell management that it will have to take a chance in the
    courtroom casino at some then uncertain future date to find out.
    If Eaton‟s above-cost market-share rebate program
    memorialized in the LTAs, which were neither explicitly nor de
    facto exclusive or mandatory, can be condemned as unlawful de
    facto partial exclusive dealing on the basis of literally a handful
    of disjointed statements that amount at most to unsupported
    speculation as to the possibility that Eaton may have stopped
    supplying its transmissions if the OEMs did not meet the targets,
    firms face a difficult task indeed in structuring lawful discount
    programs. “Perhaps most troubling, firms that seek to avoid . . .
    liability [for market-share rebate programs] will have no safe
    harbor for their pricing practices.” Linkline, 555 U.S. at 452,
    current economic climax, the reasoning of a precedential
    opinion with such obvious economic repercussions is crucial.
    109
    129 S.Ct. at 1121 (citing Town of Concord, 
    915 F.2d at 22
    )
    (Antitrust rules “must be clear enough for lawyers to explain
    them to clients.”). What I find most troubling is that firms will
    play it safe by not formulating discount programs and that the
    result of this case will be an increase of prices to purchasers and
    the stifling of competition, surely a perverse outcome. It is
    ironical that the very circumstance that the majority‟s opinion is
    so thoughtful and well crafted that the risk that it poses is so
    great. On the other hand, the approach I believe the Supreme
    Court‟s precedent compels — applying and giving persuasive
    effect to the Brooke Group price-cost test and granting a
    presumption of lawfulness to pricing practices that result in
    above-cost prices — provides clear direction to firms engaging
    in price competition but still allows for an antitrust plaintiff to
    allege that a defendant has engaged in attendant anticompetitive
    conduct that renders its practices unlawful.
    In sum, I conclude that Eaton was entitled to judgment as
    a matter of law on liability in all respects. Accordingly, I would
    reverse the judgment of the District Court and remand this case
    for entry of a judgment in favor of Eaton. My view of this facet
    of the case renders it unnecessary for me to consider the
    numerous other issues raised on this appeal, including the
    District Court‟s decision that appellees suffered antitrust injury,
    and its decisions regarding damages and injunctive relief. Thus,
    I do not opine on the proper disposition of those matters.
    110
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 11-3301, 11-3426

Citation Numbers: 696 F.3d 254

Judges: Fisher, Greenberg, Oliver

Filed Date: 9/28/2012

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 8/5/2023

Authorities (117)

Barry Wright Corporation v. Itt Grinnell Corporation , 724 F.2d 227 ( 1983 )

Stop & Shop Supermarket Co. v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of ... , 373 F.3d 57 ( 2004 )

Eastern Food Services, Inc. v. Pontifical Catholic ... , 357 F.3d 1 ( 2004 )

Town of Concord, Massachusetts v. Boston Edison Company , 915 F.2d 17 ( 1990 )

tk-7-corporation-tal-technologies-and-moshe-tal-and-v-the-estate-of , 993 F.2d 722 ( 1993 )

scott-d-levine-md-v-central-florida-medical-affiliates-inc , 72 F.3d 1538 ( 1996 )

No. 98-5136 , 165 F.3d 221 ( 1998 )

Smithkline Corporation v. Eli Lilly and Company , 575 F.2d 1056 ( 1978 )

In Re Insurance Brokerage Antitrust Litigation , 618 F.3d 300 ( 2010 )

Michael Meyers, Individually and as Representative of a ... , 559 F.2d 894 ( 1977 )

Autowest, Inc. v. Peugeot, Inc., and Associete De ... , 434 F.2d 556 ( 1970 )

Virgin Atlantic Airways Limited v. British Airways Plc , 257 F.3d 256 ( 2001 )

CDC Technologies, Inc. A Connecticut Corporation v. Idexx ... , 186 F.3d 74 ( 1999 )

Pepsico, Inc. v. The Coca-Cola Company , 315 F.3d 101 ( 2002 )

Deutscher Tennis Bund v. Atp Tour, Inc. , 610 F.3d 820 ( 2010 )

Advo, Inc. v. Philadelphia Newspapers, Inc., D/B/A ... , 51 F.3d 1191 ( 1995 )

lucien-b-calhoun-robin-l-calhoun-individually-and-as-administrators-of , 350 F.3d 316 ( 2003 )

In Re Paoli Railroad Yard PCB Litigation , 35 F.3d 717 ( 1994 )

In Re Paoli Railroad Yard Pcb Litigation , 916 F.2d 829 ( 1990 )

Carmelita Elcock v. Kmart Corporation , 233 F.3d 734 ( 2000 )

View All Authorities »