Harry Calcutt III v. FDIC ( 2022 )


Menu:
  •                                RECOMMENDED FOR PUBLICATION
    Pursuant to Sixth Circuit I.O.P. 32.1(b)
    File Name: 22a0122p.06
    UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
    FOR THE SIXTH CIRCUIT
    ┐
    HARRY C. CALCUTT III,
    │
    Petitioner,     │
    >        No. 20-4303
    │
    v.                                                  │
    │
    FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION,                     │
    Respondent.            │
    ┘
    On Petition for Review of an Order of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation;
    Nos. FDIC-12-568e; FDIC-13-115k.
    Argued: October 20, 2021
    Decided and Filed: June 10, 2022
    Before: BOGGS, GRIFFIN, and MURPHY, Circuit Judges.
    _________________
    COUNSEL
    ARGUED: Sarah M. Harris, WILLIAMS & CONNOLLY LLP, Washington, D.C., for
    Petitioner.  Michelle Ognibene, FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION,
    Arlington, Virginia, for Respondent. ON BRIEF: Sarah M. Harris, Ryan T. Scarborough,
    William B. Snyderwine, Helen E. White, WILLIAMS & CONNOLLY LLP, Washington, D.C.,
    Barry D. Hovis, MUSICK, PEELER & GARRETT LLP, San Francisco, California, for
    Petitioner.   Michelle Ognibene, John Guarisco, FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE
    CORPORATION, Arlington, Virginia, for Respondent. John M. Masslon II, WASHINGTON
    LEGAL FOUNDATION, Washington, D.C., Ilya Shapiro, CATO INSTITUTE, Washington,
    D.C., Michael Pepson, AMERICANS FOR PROSPERITY FOUNDATION, Arlington, Virginia,
    Andrew J. Pincus, MAYER BROWN LLP, Washington, D.C., Robert D. Nachman, BARACK
    FERRAZZANO KIRSCHBAUM & NAGELBERG LLP, Chicago, Illinois, for Amici Curiae.
    BOGGS, J., delivered the opinion of the court in which GRIFFIN, J., joined. MURPHY,
    J. (pp. 54–91), delivered a separate dissenting opinion.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 2
    _________________
    OPINION
    _________________
    BOGGS, Circuit Judge. Harry C. Calcutt III, a bank executive and director, petitions for
    review of an order issued by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (“FDIC”) that removes
    him from his position, prohibits him from participating in the conduct of the affairs of any
    insured depository institution, and imposes civil money penalties. In addition to attacking the
    conduct and findings in his individual proceedings, he also brings several constitutional
    challenges to the appointments and removal restrictions of FDIC officials.
    His first hearing in these proceedings occurred before an FDIC administrative law judge
    (“ALJ”) in 2015. Before the ALJ released his recommended decision, the Supreme Court
    decided Lucia v. SEC, 
    138 S. Ct. 2044
     (2018), which invalidated the appointments of similar
    ALJs in the Securities and Exchange Commission (“SEC”). The FDIC Board of Directors then
    appointed its ALJs anew, and in 2019 a different FDIC ALJ held another hearing in Calcutt’s
    matter and ultimately recommended penalties.
    Broadly, Calcutt’s claims fall into two categories.        First, he brings structural
    constitutional challenges, contending that: The FDIC Board of Directors is unconstitutionally
    shielded from removal by the President; the FDIC ALJs who oversee enforcement proceedings
    are also unconstitutionally insulated from removal; and the second hearing before a different ALJ
    failed to afford him a “new hearing,” as mandated by Lucia. In his second group of challenges,
    Calcutt attacks the procedure used and results reached in his post-Lucia adjudication. He begins
    by contending that the ALJ abused his discretion by curtailing cross-examination about bias of
    the witnesses.    He then argues that the FDIC Board failed to find that he had committed
    misconduct that caused “effects” for Northwestern Bank, as the governing statute, 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1), requires. See Dodge v. Comptroller of Currency, 
    744 F.3d 148
    , 152 (D.C. Cir.
    2014).
    We deny his petition. Calcutt’s challenges to the removal restrictions at the FDIC are
    unavailing, because even if he were to establish a constitutional violation, he has not shown that
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                     Page 3
    he is entitled to relief. See Collins v. Yellen, 
    141 S. Ct. 1761
    , 1789 (2021). We also conclude that
    his 2019 hearing satisfied Lucia’s mandate. As for the limits on cross-examination at that
    hearing, any error committed by the ALJ was harmless. Finally, there is substantial evidence in
    the record to support the FDIC Board’s findings regarding the elements of § 1818(e)(1).
    I. BACKGROUND
    A. Overview of FDIC Enforcement Proceedings
    Among other functions, the FDIC conducts examinations and investigations to ensure
    banks’ safety, soundness, and compliance with statutes and regulations. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1811
    .
    It has the authority to impose a range of enforcement remedies. 
    Id.
     § 1818. These include
    removal and prohibition orders, in which the FDIC orders “an institution-affiliated party” to be
    removed from office or “prohibit[s] any further participation by such party, in any manner, in the
    conduct of the affairs of any insured depository institution.” Id. § 1818(e)(1). An institution-
    affiliated party includes “any director, officer, employee, or controlling stockholder (other than a
    bank holding company or savings and loan holding company) of, or agent for, an insured
    depository institution.” Id. § 1813(u)(1).
    Section 8(e) of the Federal Deposit Insurance Act (“FDI Act”), 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e), as
    amended by the Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement Act (“FIRREA”),
    P.L. No. 101-73, § 903, 
    103 Stat. 183
    , 453–54 (1989), provides that FDIC may remove an
    institution-affiliated party from office or prohibit the party from participating in conducting the
    affairs of any insured institution upon establishing three elements: “(1) the banker committed an
    improper act; (2) the act had an impermissible effect, either an adverse effect on the bank or a
    benefit to the actor; and (3) the act was accompanied by a culpable state of mind.” De la Fuente
    v. FDIC, 
    332 F.3d 1208
    , 1222 (9th Cir. 2003). First, the Board of Directors of the FDIC (“FDIC
    Board” or “Board”) must find that the party has committed misconduct, including engaging in
    “any unsafe or unsound practice in connection with any insured depository institution” or
    committing “any act, omission, or practice which constitutes a breach of such party’s fiduciary
    duty.” 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)(ii)–(iii).     Second, the Board must find that at least one
    requisite effect has occurred, i.e., that “by reason of” the party’s action, the insured depository
    No. 20-4303                              Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 4
    institution “has suffered or will probably suffer financial loss or other damage,” its depositors
    have been or could be prejudiced, or the party has received financial gain or other benefit. 
    Id.
    § 1818(e)(1)(B). Finally, the party must have had a culpable state of mind: The violation must
    be one that “involves personal dishonesty” or “demonstrates willful or continuing
    disregard by such party for the safety or soundness of such insured depository institution.” Id.
    § 1818(e)(1)(C).
    The FDIC may also issue civil money penalties (“CMPs”) under a similar test. See
    
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (i)(2). As relevant here, the agency may impose a “second tier” penalty of
    $25,000 per day of violation when a party “recklessly engages in an unsafe or unsound practice
    in conducting the affairs of [an] insured depository institution” or “breaches any fiduciary duty,”
    and that action “is part of a pattern of misconduct,” causes more than minimal loss to the
    institution, or benefits the institution-affiliated party. 
    Id.
     § 1818(i)(2)(B).
    To commence these enforcement proceedings, the FDIC first serves the party with a
    notice of intention to remove the party from office and/or prohibit that party from participating in
    other insured depository institutions.      See id. § 1818(e)(1); see also id. § 1818(i)(2)(E)(i)
    (requiring notice for civil money penalty).         The notice must contain a statement of facts
    establishing grounds for the removal and indicate a time and place for a hearing.                Id.
    § 1818(e)(4). The institution-affiliated party may then appear at the hearing to contest the notice;
    failure to appear constitutes consent to the order. Ibid.
    An ALJ conducts the adversarial hearing in accordance with the Administrative
    Procedure Act (“APA”), 
    5 U.S.C. §§ 551
    –559. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (h)(1) (requiring hearings
    to be “conducted in accordance with the provisions of chapter 5 of Title 5”).            Under the
    applicable regulations, an ALJ presiding over a removal proceeding has “all powers necessary to
    conduct a proceeding in a fair and impartial manner and to avoid unnecessary delay,” 
    12 C.F.R. § 308.5
    (a), including the power to “receive relevant evidence and to rule upon the admission of
    evidence and offers of proof,” 
    id.
     § 308.5(b)(3); “[t]o consider and rule upon all procedural and
    other motions appropriate in an adjudicatory proceeding . . . ,” id. § 308.5(b)(7); and “[t]o
    prepare and present to the Board of Directors a recommended decision,” id. § 308.5(b)(8).
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 5
    The regulations also provide that evidence that would be admissible under the Federal
    Rules of Evidence is admissible in adjudicatory proceedings, id. § 308.36(a)(2), and that except
    as otherwise provided, “relevant, material, and reliable evidence that is not unduly repetitive is
    admissible to the fullest extent authorized by the Administrative Procedure Act and other
    applicable law,” id. § 308.36(a)(1).      If evidence meets this latter standard but would be
    inadmissible under the Federal Rules of Evidence, the ALJ may not deem the evidence
    inadmissible. Id. § 308.36(a)(3).
    After the hearing, the ALJ must file and certify a record of the proceeding, including a
    recommended decision, recommended findings of fact, recommended conclusions of law, and a
    proposed order. Id. § 308.38(a). A party then has thirty days to file written exceptions for the
    FDIC Board’s review objecting to particular matters or omissions in the ALJ’s
    recommendations, but a failure to file an exception on a particular matter is treated as a waiver of
    that objection, and the Board need not consider any such objections that were not initially raised
    before the ALJ. Id. § 303.39.
    The Board then reviews the ALJ’s recommendations and issues a final decision. Id.
    § 308.40. Its review is “based upon review of the entire record of the proceedings,” although it
    may limit its review to those arguments and exceptions that were raised by the parties. Id.
    § 308.40(c)(1). After the Board’s final decision, a party may petition for review in the United
    States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit or the circuit in which the
    institution’s home office is located. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (h)(2).
    B. FDIC Composition and Structure
    The FDIC Board consists of five members: the Comptroller of the Currency, the Director
    of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (“CFPB”), and three additional directors who are
    appointed by the President with the advice and consent of the Senate. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1812
    (a)(1).
    The Comptroller of the Currency and the CFPB Director are also appointed by the President with
    Senate advice and consent. 
    Id.
     § 2 (Comptroller of the Currency); id. § 5491(b)(2) (CFPB
    Director). The Board also incorporates a measure of partisan balancing, with a maximum of
    three directors permitted to be members of the same political party. Id. § 1812(a)(2).
    No. 20-4303                                Calcutt v. FDIC                                         Page 6
    The three members of the Board not appointed by virtue of another office serve fixed
    terms, and the parties agree that they are not removable at will. During the proceedings before
    the ALJs in this case, the CFPB Director also enjoyed for-cause protection from removal under
    
    12 U.S.C. § 5491
    (c)(3); however, before the Board issued its final order, the Supreme Court held
    this removal restriction to be unconstitutional. Seila Law LLC v. Consumer Fin. Prot. Bureau,
    
    140 S. Ct. 2183
     (2020). The Comptroller of the Currency’s term lasts for five years “unless
    sooner removed by the President, upon reasons to be communicated by him to the Senate,” and
    Calcutt concedes that this provision provides for at-will removal. 
    12 U.S.C. § 2
    . In practice,
    however, the FDIC Board has had several vacancies during the proceedings in Calcutt’s case;
    additionally, at least one board member continued to serve after his term expired until a
    successor was appointed. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1812
    (c)(3) (providing for continuation of service of
    appointed members after expiration of term before a successor is appointed).
    The ALJs who hear FDIC removal and prohibition proceedings are part of a pool housed
    in the Office of Financial Institution Adjudication (“OFIA”), an interagency body established by
    FIRREA that presides over enforcement proceedings brought by the FDIC, the Office of the
    Comptroller of the Currency (“OCC”), the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
    (“FRB”), and the National Credit Union Administration (“NCUA”). See FIRREA § 916, 
    103 Stat. 183
    , 486–87 (codified at 
    12 U.S.C. §1818
     note); 
    12 C.F.R. § 308.3
     (defining OFIA as “the
    executive body charged with overseeing the administration of administrative enforcement
    proceedings” of OCC, FRB, FDIC, and NCUA).1 These agencies signed an agreement that
    provides for cost-sharing and specifies that the FDIC is the “Host Agency,” responsible for the
    employment of an office staff consisting of ALJs and administrative employees. See Ex. L to
    Emergency Motion for Stay Pending Review, at 1–6. The agreement also states: “Any change to
    the Office Staff personnel shall be subject to the prior written approval of all Agencies.” 
    Id. at 3
    .
    Two ALJs currently make up the pool in OFIA. See Our Judges, Office of Financial Institution
    Adjudication, https://www.ofia.gov/who-we-are/our-judges.html (last visited May 24, 2022).
    1Initially, the Office of Thrift Supervision served as “host agency” for OFIA, but that agency’s
    responsibilities were transferred to FRB, OCC, and FDIC in Title III of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and
    Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No 111-203, 
    124 Stat. 1376
     (2010).
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 7
    Until Lucia, these ALJs were not appointed by the FDIC. After the Supreme Court held
    in Lucia that SEC ALJs were officers who must be appointed by the President, a court of law, or
    a head of department, see 
    138 S. Ct. at
    2051–54, the FDIC Board then newly appointed the same
    ALJs without conceding that their previous appointments had been unconstitutional. The FDIC
    ALJs may only be removed “for good cause” determined by the Merit Systems Protection Board
    (“MSPB”) on the record after an opportunity for a hearing. 
    5 U.S.C. § 7521
    (a). Members of the
    MSPB, in turn, may be removed by the President “only for inefficiency, neglect of duty, or
    malfeasance in office.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 1202
    (d).
    C. Calcutt’s Actions at Northwestern Bank
    With this background, we turn to the facts of the present case. Calcutt was the President,
    CEO, and Chairman of the Board of Directors of Northwestern Bank (the “Bank”), which had its
    principal place of business in Traverse City, Michigan. He also served as a member of the
    Bank’s senior loan committee and as CEO of the Bank’s holding company, Northwestern
    Bancorp. The Bank was an insured state nonmember bank subject to the FDI Act, as well as
    associated regulations and Michigan state laws. Calcutt retired from his positions at the Bank in
    2013 and now serves as the Chairman of State Savings Bank in Michigan and its holding
    company. Northwestern Bank was purchased by a competitor in 2014.
    Under the Bank’s management structure, twenty employees reported directly to Calcutt,
    including Richard Jackson, an Executive Vice President and board member. A commercial-loan
    officer named William Green also worked for the Bank.
    By 2009, the Bank’s largest loan relationship was with a group of nineteen limited
    liability companies controlled by the Nielson family (the “Nielson Entities”). These businesses’
    activities involved development of real estate, holding vacant and developed real estate, and
    holding oil and gas interests. At that time, the Bank’s loans to the Nielson Entities (the “Nielson
    Loans”) amounted to approximately $38 million. The value of the Nielson Entities’ holdings
    during this time was approximately $112 million, with $7–9 million in cash or cash equivalents,
    and $80 million available in real estate or oil and gas assets that could be used for collateral or
    loan-payment purposes.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 8
    As early as 2008, FDIC examiners identified several of the Nielson Entities as a single
    borrower and identified the Bank’s loans to these businesses as a “concentration of credit”—
    defined as a lending relationship that exceeds twenty-five percent of a bank’s Tier 1 capital.
    Although in practice the Nielsons could use cash derived from one entity to pay the loans of
    another entity, the loans were not cross-collateralized, meaning that the collateral in one Nielson
    Entity did not secure loans to other Nielson Entities, despite the common control. Neither were
    the loans supported by personal guarantees: If a Nielson Entity failed, the Bank could not
    compel the Nielsons to personally satisfy the obligation. Loans lacking personal guarantees were
    considered to be an exception to the Bank’s commercial-loan policy.
    In April 2008, Calcutt and Green met Cori Nielson, one of the managers of the limited-
    liability company that managed the Nielson Entities, and Autumn Berden, the chief financial
    officer of that company. Calcutt and Green requested that the Nielsons stop reporting transfers
    between Nielson Entities as intercompany loans on their balance sheets; instead, the bankers
    recommended that when an entity needed funds, another entity should distribute funds to its
    members, who could then loan or give the funds to the cash-strapped entity. Such a payment
    mechanism would not be reported to regulators as an intercompany transfer and would conceal
    the Nielson Entities’ “common use of funds.” According to the FDIC, over the following
    months this strategy also masked the interrelationship of the Nielson Entities and hid loans to
    Entities that had no positive cash flow by routing funds through other actors in the Nielson
    group.
    The relationship between the Bank and the Nielsons began to deteriorate during the Great
    Recession. Although in May 2009 several of the Nielson Entities wrote to Calcutt stating that
    they had sufficient cash flow for debt service, by August multiple loans were past due. More
    were scheduled to mature on September 1. On August 10, Berden told the Bank that the Nielson
    Entities would need to restructure their loans, and on August 21, Cori Nielson made a similar
    communication. The Bank did not oblige, and the Nielson Entities stopped paying their loans on
    September 1.
    Over the following months, the Nielsons and the Bank continued to negotiate, but their
    efforts were fruitless. The Nielsons sought measures such as debt forbearance, reduction of loan
    No. 20-4303                                     Calcutt v. FDIC                                               Page 9
    payments, or deeds in lieu of foreclosure,2 because ongoing problems in the real-estate market
    had diminished their ability to repay existing debts. Calcutt, on the other hand, later testified that
    he thought that the Nielsons were “posturing” and possessed sufficient funds to pay their loans.
    The Bank attempted to convince the Nielsons to refinance and provide greater payments on their
    loans. Cori Nielson later testified that in response to her communications, Calcutt expressed
    concerns about raising “red flags” to regulators about the Bank’s relationship with the Nielson
    Entities. By November 30, 2009, several of the loans to the Nielson entities were automatically
    placed on nonaccrual status by the Bank, meaning that they were ninety days past due.
    Also on November 30, the Bank and the Nielson Entities finally reached an agreement
    that would bring all the loans current. First, the Bank extended a loan of $760,000 to Bedrock
    Holdings LLC, one of the Nielson Entities (the “Bedrock Loan”), which would be used for the
    companies’ future required loan payments until April 2010. After receipt of the loan, Bedrock
    Holdings transferred the funds into accounts at the Bank for other Nielson Entities. Second, the
    Bank agreed to release $600,000 worth of collateral in investment-trading funds that had been
    granted to it by another Nielson Entity, Pillay Trading LLC (the “Pillay Collateral”).3 This
    collateral release allowed the Nielson Entities to bring their past-due loans current. Finally, the
    Bank renewed the Nielson Entities’ matured loans, including a loan of $4,500,000 to Bedrock
    Holdings. The parties refer to this agreement, which took effect in December 2009, as the
    “Bedrock Transaction.”           Consequently, the Nielson Entities’ loans were removed from the
    Bank’s nonaccrual list on December 1.
    The FDIC Board would later find that the actions surrounding the Bedrock Transaction
    violated the Bank’s commercial-loan policy. That policy required that “all commercial loans are
    to be supported by a written analysis of the net income available to service the debt and by
    written evidence from the third parties supporting the collateral value of the security,” yet the
    Bank did not conduct these analyses or collateral appraisals prior to providing the Bedrock Loan
    2Through    a deed in lieu of foreclosure, “a mortgagee . . . take[s] a conveyance from the mortgagor in full or
    partial satisfaction and as a substitute for foreclosure.” Restatement (Third) of Property (Mortgages) § 8.5 cmt. b
    (Am. Law Inst. 1997).
    3Asdiscussed below, a year later Northwestern Bank also released $690,000 in collateral from Pillay
    Trading LLC. We refer to the $600,000 and $690,000 disbursements together as the “Pillay Collateral.”
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 10
    and releasing the Pillay Collateral. At the 2019 hearing, however, Calcutt testified that he
    thought that the Bedrock Transaction was in the Bank’s best interest, because it provided time
    for the Nielson Entities to pay off their debt and because he believed they had the resources to do
    so.
    Moreover, the commercial-loan policy required approval by two-thirds of the board of
    directors for loans “where the total aggregate exposure is between 15 and 25 percent of the
    Bank’s Regulatory Capital.” Ibid. The loans to the Nielson Entities were approximately half of
    the Bank’s Tier 1 capital, thereby qualifying for the voting requirement. According to the FDIC,
    however, the board did not approve the Bedrock Transaction until March 2010—approximately
    four months after the disbursements. The loan write-up for the Bedrock Transaction that was
    presented to the board in March 2010 also contained inaccurate information, including misstating
    the purpose of the Bedrock Loan as “working capital requirements” and omitting that the
    Bedrock Transaction had already occurred.
    That loan write-up was prepared by a credit analyst based on information provided by
    Green, and Calcutt and Jackson both initialed the document. Before the FDIC, Calcutt argued
    that: (a) the write-up’s errors and mischaracterization could not be attributed to him; (b) the
    board of directors was aware of the difficulties with the Nielson Entities in November 2009
    because of materials it had received; and (c) the board of directors verbally approved the
    Bedrock Transaction in November and December 2009. The ALJ and FDIC Board, however,
    found against him on these points.
    Calcutt’s actions surrounding the FDIC’s June 2010 examination of the Bank also
    attracted scrutiny. In May 2010, Calcutt signed an Officer’s Questionnaire required by the
    agency. The first question required him to list the loans that the Bank had renewed or extended
    since the previous year’s examination by accepting separate notes for the payment of interest or
    without fully collecting interest, as well as any loans made for the direct benefit of anyone other
    than the named recipients of the loans. On the questionnaire, Calcutt answered that he was not
    aware of any such loans. He later testified that these answers were incorrect in light of the
    Bank’s activities with the Nielson Entities, but argued that the misstatements were “inadvertent
    and unintentional.” (Brackets omitted.)
    No. 20-4303                                 Calcutt v. FDIC                                          Page 11
    Additionally, Calcutt participated in a decision to sell several Nielson Entity loans to two
    of Northwestern Bank’s affiliates in May 2010, shortly before the FDIC examiners were due to
    arrive. Green told Berden that he and Calcutt would continue to serve as the points of contact on
    those loans. In late September 2010, the Bank repurchased the loans, at which point the loans
    were delinquent and past maturity.
    Despite these actions, by September 2010 the Nielson Entities’ position remained
    precarious. Beginning on September 1, they again stopped making payments on their loans.
    Several additional months of negotiations ensued, and in December 2010 the parties agreed to an
    additional release of $690,000 of collateral from Pillay Trading LLC to fund the Nielson
    Entities’ debt service from September 2010 to January 2011. The Bank’s board of directors
    agreed to this arrangement. At the end of that period, however, the Nielson Entities yet again
    stopped making payments, and they have been in default since then.
    D. The 2011 Examination
    Shortly before the FDIC’s 2011 regular examination of the Bank was set to begin on
    August 1, 2011, Cori Nielson sent the agency a binder with approximately 267 pages of
    correspondence between herself, Berden, Green, and Calcutt.                   The binder’s contents went
    beyond the correspondence that FDIC examiners had found in the Bank’s loan file. According to
    Calcutt, Nielson’s move also began a series of actions in which she and Berden improperly
    influenced the FDIC’s Case Manager, Anne Miessner, and Miessner became biased against
    Calcutt while participating in the examination.
    During his September 14, 2011 meeting with examiners from the FDIC and the Michigan
    Office of Financial and Insurance Regulation,4 Calcutt made several false statements about the
    Bedrock Transaction. First, in response to a question about his understanding as to the purpose
    of the Bedrock Loan, Calcutt said that the funds were meant to provide “working capital” in
    connection with an acquisition of another business, although their true purpose was to help pay
    off the loans to Nielson Entities. Second, when examiners asked him about the release of the
    Pillay Collateral, he responded, “I thought we still had them,” although he had authorized
    4This   agency has been renamed the Michigan Department of Insurance and Financial Services.
    No. 20-4303                                   Calcutt v. FDIC                                                Page 12
    releases of the collateral in 2009 and 2010. Third, when queried about how the Nielson Entities
    managed to bring their loans current in December 2010, he answered that they used their “vast
    resources between oil, gas, and rentals,” although the December 2010 release of Pillay Collateral
    was in fact used to satisfy these obligations.
    In its 2011 examination, the FDIC also noted that the Nielson relationship “should have
    been reported as nonaccrual on quarterly Call Reports beginning no later than December 2009,”
    and that its omission “has resulted in a material overstatement in earnings both in the form of
    falsely inflated interest income and of grossly understated provision expense.” Calcutt signed
    the Call Reports, yet he later testified that he was not involved in their preparation.
    Ultimately, the FDIC’s 2011 examination report identified the Bank’s failures in securing
    and analyzing the Bedrock Transaction, its reporting inaccuracies, and its misstatements during
    the examination. It ordered the Bank to charge off $6.443 million on the loans to Nielson
    Entities, which represented the amount that the Bank would be unlikely to collect. 5 On July 31,
    2012, the Bank charged off an additional $30,000 specifically on the Bedrock Loan.
    E. Administrative Proceedings
    1.     The 2015 Hearing
    On April 13, 2012, the FDIC formally opened an investigation into the Bank’s officers.
    Its investigation ended on August 20, 2013, and the agency issued a Notice of Intention to
    Remove from Office and Prohibit from Further Participation against Calcutt, Jackson, and
    Green, as well as a notice of assessment of civil money penalties (the “Notice”). In 2015, both
    Jackson and Green stipulated to orders prohibiting them from banking activity, and Jackson
    agreed to a $75,000 CMP.                Calcutt proceeded to discovery and further administrative
    proceedings.
    In September 2015, ALJ C. Richard Miserendino held an eight-day hearing on Calcutt’s
    charges. Among the several witnesses who testified were Calcutt, Jackson, Nielson, Berden,
    Miessner, and Dennis O’Neill (one of the FDIC examiners).                         ALJ Miserendino released a
    5The   parties disagree about whether a charge-off necessarily qualifies as a loss. See infra at 45.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                 Page 13
    recommended decision on June 6, 2017. However, before the Board issued its final decision, it
    stayed the case pending the Supreme Court’s decision in Lucia, because ALJ Miserendino had
    not been appointed by an agency head.
    2.     The 2019 Hearing
    Following Lucia, the FDIC Board formally appointed Miserendino and its other ALJ,
    Christopher B. McNeil, then remanded and reassigned each ALJ’s pending cases to the other
    ALJ “for a new hearing and a fresh reconsideration of all prior actions, including summary
    dispositions, taken before the hearing.” See FDIC Resolution Seal No. 085172, Order in Pending
    Cases (July 19, 2018). The Board permitted each new ALJ to conduct a paper hearing on
    remand, but if a party objected to the paper hearing, the Board ordered that the ALJ “must
    conduct a new oral hearing in accordance with 
    12 C.F.R. § 308.35
    , except that the ALJ may
    accept the written transcript of prior testimony of any witnesses for which the parties agreed to
    accept such testimony.”
    Calcutt’s case was reassigned to ALJ McNeil, who stated that he would conduct an oral
    hearing and requested that the parties submit objections to ALJ Miserendino’s prehearing
    rulings. In response, Calcutt asserted that the prior proceedings were entirely void under Lucia
    because the prior ALJ had not been appointed by an agency head. ALJ McNeil rejected this
    argument, and proceeded to request that the parties submit specific examples where the prior
    proceeding’s outcome turned on evidence that should have been included or excluded, or
    “elements, such as witness demeanor, that are not readily determined from a review of the
    written record.”
    Calcutt then reasserted his argument that “the original proceeding was void ab initio” and
    objected to the inclusion of the record from the 2015 proceedings because the case “turn[ed]
    entirely on credibility assessments.” In an order dated March 19, 2019, ALJ McNeil rejected
    these arguments, concluding that the second hearing would not be de novo, and that “[t]he prior
    proceedings have not been deemed void ab initio, but instead serve as the primary source of the
    evidentiary record, subject to review and reconsideration by the new ALJ.” ALJ McNeil went
    on to observe that although credibility assessments were material to the decision of the case,
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                 Page 14
    Calcutt had not established that a review of the 2015 hearing transcript would be hindered by an
    inability to view witnesses’ demeanor. Finally, he rejected Calcutt’s objections to the admission
    of several exhibits from the 2015 proceedings.
    On March 20, 2019, ALJ McNeil released an additional prehearing order, which among
    other things specified that the parties should identify witnesses by May 15, 2019 and indicate
    each witness’s expected testimony. The order specified that “during the evidentiary hearing,
    witness testimony will be limited to the descriptions provided in this summary.” Calcutt sought
    an interlocutory appeal before the FDIC Board on ALJ McNeil’s limitations on the oral hearing.
    The Board granted his request for a new oral hearing on all issues considered at the prior hearing,
    including live witness testimony, but it denied his request for an entirely new proceeding as
    untimely.
    In the next prehearing order, ALJ McNeil granted enforcement counsel’s motions to
    strike Calcutt’s affirmative defenses of laches, entrapment, and examiners’ violation of the
    agency’s own procedural rules. Then, in response to the parties’ motions in limine, he permitted
    introduction of Green and Jackson’s testimony and the parties’ stipulations at the 2015 hearing,
    among other evidentiary rulings.
    The hearing lasted from October 29 to November 6, 2019. Calcutt was among twelve
    witnesses who testified. During the proceedings, Calcutt’s counsel unsuccessfully attempted to
    cross-examine witnesses, including Berden, Miessner, and Nielson, about the theory that
    Miessner and the FDIC were biased against Calcutt due to their relationship with the Nielsons.
    In sustaining enforcement counsel’s objections to this testimony, ALJ McNeil reasoned that
    these questions were outside the scope of direct examination, and that in accordance with his
    March 20, 2019 order, Calcutt could have identified these witnesses in a prehearing submission
    as subject to questioning about bias but failed to do so.
    On April 3, 2020, ALJ McNeil issued the Findings of Fact, Conclusions of Law, and
    Recommended Decision on Remand (the “Recommended Decision”), finding that Calcutt’s
    actions surrounding the Bedrock Transaction amounted to unsafe or unsound practices and
    breached his fiduciary duties of care and candor; that these actions caused the Bank to suffer
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 15
    damages and financially benefitted Calcutt; and that the actions involved personal dishonesty and
    willful and continuing disregard for the Bank’s safety and soundness.             See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1).   Finding that Calcutt’s actions satisfied the requirements for a removal and
    prohibition order and civil money penalties, ALJ McNeil recommended that Calcutt be
    prohibited from banking and assessed a $125,000 CMP.
    Calcutt filed exceptions to the FDIC Board, challenging many of these findings and
    conclusions. He also argued that the proceedings were invalid because the restrictions on ALJ
    McNeil’s removal were unconstitutional, and because the new hearing granted after Lucia did
    not remedy the Appointments Clause violation in the previous proceedings before ALJ
    Miserendino. He did not argue that the Board was also improperly shielded from removal.
    Upon review, the FDIC Board accepted ALJ McNeil’s findings and conclusions, and on
    December 15, 2020, it issued a final Decision and Order to Remove and Prohibit from Further
    Participation and Assessment of Civil Money Penalties (the “Removal and Prohibition Order”).
    The Board concluded that Calcutt’s involvement with the Bank’s loans to the Nielson Entities, as
    well as his misrepresentations to regulators and the board of directors, were both unsafe and
    unsound practices and breaches of his fiduciary duties. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A). It also
    found that sufficient effects had occurred by reason of Calcutt’s malfeasance: loan charge-offs;
    the Bank’s increased investigative, legal, and auditing expenses; and Calcutt’s receipt of
    dividends from the Bank’s holding company that reflected the Nielson portfolio’s inflated value.
    See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B).        And it concluded that Calcutt acted with the requisite
    culpability. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(C).       The Board similarly upheld ALJ McNeil’s
    conclusions regarding the appropriateness of the civil money penalty. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (i).
    Finally, it rejected Calcutt’s exceptions regarding the ALJ’s insulation from removal, the
    adequacy of the new hearing after Lucia, the ALJ’s evidentiary rulings, the statute of limitations,
    and the ALJ’s bias.
    Calcutt petitioned this court for review the following day. On December 21, 2020, he
    moved for an emergency stay. A panel of this court granted the stay on January 5, 2021. We
    have jurisdiction over Calcutt’s petition for review of the FDIC’s order under 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (h)(2).
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 16
    II. STANDARD OF REVIEW
    The judicial-review provisions of the APA apply to FDIC removal and prohibition orders
    and orders assessing CMPs. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (h)(2). Accordingly, we must hold unlawful and
    set aside agency actions, findings, or conclusions that are “arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of
    discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with law”; “contrary to constitutional right, power,
    privilege, or immunity”; “in excess of statutory jurisdiction, authority, or limitations”;
    “without observance of procedure required by law”; or “unsupported by substantial evidence.”
    
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2). Furthermore, “due account shall be taken of the rule of prejudicial error.”
    Ibid.; see Nat’l Ass’n of Home Builders v. Defs. of Wildlife, 
    551 U.S. 664
    , 659–60 (2007)
    (explaining that this statutory language refers to a harmless-error rule). Though a court does not
    “substitute its judgment for that of the agency” over decisions within the agency’s delegated
    authority in applying the APA’s arbitrary-and-capricious standard, the agency’s conclusions must
    still be based on “reasoned decision making.” Wollschlager v. FDIC, 
    992 F.3d 574
    , 581–82 (6th
    Cir. 2021).
    We review other agency determinations differently.         Questions of law are reviewed
    de novo, but we defer to an agency’s interpretation of a provision in a statute that it is entrusted
    with administering, if (1) Congress has not “directly spoken to the precise question at issue,” and
    (2) “the agency’s answer is based on a permissible construction of the statute.” N. Fork Coal
    Corp. v. Fed. Mine Safety & Health Rev. Comm’n, 
    691 F.3d 735
    , 739 (6th Cir. 2012) (quoting
    Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    , 842–43 (1984)). And an
    agency’s factual findings are reviewed for substantial evidence, which is “more than a scintilla of
    evidence but less than a preponderance; it is such relevant evidence as a reasonable mind might
    accept as adequate to support a conclusion.” Gen. Med., P.C. v. Azar, 
    963 F.3d 516
    , 520 (6th Cir.
    2020) (quoting Cutlip v. Sec’y of Health & Hum. Servs., 
    25 F.3d 284
    , 286 (6th Cir. 1994)).
    “The substantiality of evidence must take into account whatever in the record fairly detracts from
    its weight.” Universal Camera Corp. v. NLRB, 
    340 U.S. 474
    , 488 (1951).
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                 Page 17
    III. REMOVAL PROTECTIONS
    Calcutt maintains that two features of the structure of the FDIC violate Article II and the
    separation of powers and thus compel invalidation of the agency’s proceedings against him.
    First, relying principally on Seila Law, he argues that the members of the FDIC Board are
    unconstitutionally insulated from removal by the President. Second, he contends that the FDIC’s
    ALJs are insulated by multiple levels of for-cause protection in contravention of the Supreme
    Court’s holding in Free Enterprise Fund v. Public Company Accounting Oversight Board,
    
    561 U.S. 477
     (2010).
    Neither alleged infirmity, however, compels invalidation of the FDIC proceedings against
    Calcutt. As the Court recently explained in Collins v. Yellen, even if an agency’s structure
    unconstitutionally shields officers from removal, a party challenging the agency’s action is not
    entitled to relief unless that unconstitutional provision “inflict[s] compensable harm.” 141 S. Ct.
    at 1789. Calcutt has not demonstrated that the removal protections of the FDIC Board or the
    FDIC ALJs caused such harm to him.
    A. FDIC Board Structure
    We first address Calcutt’s challenge to the FDIC Board’s structure. To start, we conclude
    that Calcutt has not forfeited this claim.      However, Calcutt has not demonstrated that the
    purported constitutional infirmity inflicted harm. See Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1789. Thus, he is not
    entitled to invalidation of the proceedings on this basis.
    1.     Issue Exhaustion
    At the outset, we disagree with the argument by the FDIC that Calcutt has forfeited his
    challenge to the Board’s removal protections by not raising it in his exceptions to the
    recommended decision of ALJ McNeil. This is a question of “issue exhaustion,” a rule in many
    administrative contexts that requires a party to present an issue to an agency before pursuing
    judicial review on that issue. Carr v. Saul, 
    141 S. Ct. 1352
    , 1358 (2021).
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 18
    We have recognized three types of issue-exhaustion requirements.                First, many
    “requirements of administrative issue exhaustion are largely creatures of statute.” Sims v. Apfel,
    
    530 U.S. 103
    , 107 (2000). Second, an agency’s regulations may require exhaustion, 
    id. at 108
    ,
    so long as the regulations “comport with the statute” and are not applied arbitrarily, Island Creek
    Coal Co. v. Bryan, 
    937 F.3d 738
    , 747 (6th Cir. 2019). Third, a court may impose an issue-
    exhaustion requirement without either a statute or regulation. Sims, 
    530 U.S. at 108
    ; see Bryan,
    937 F.3d at 747–48 (describing “prudential exhaustion” and its unclear doctrinal source). In this
    last context, “[t]he desirability of a court imposing a requirement of issue exhaustion depends on
    the degree to which the analogy to normal adversarial litigation applies in a particular
    administrative proceeding.” Carr, 141 S. Ct. at 1358 (quoting Sims, 
    530 U.S. at 109
    ). This
    resemblance to an adversarial litigation in turn depends on “whether claimants bear the
    responsibility to develop issues for adjudicators’ consideration.” 
    Ibid.
    The FDIC argues that its regulations (namely 
    12 C.F.R. § 308.39
    (b)) compelled Calcutt
    to raise any Appointments Clause challenge to the Board’s structure in his exceptions to the
    Recommended Decision before raising them before this court. Moreover, the agency adds,
    Carr’s limitation on imposing issue-exhaustion requirements in non-adversarial proceedings do
    not apply here, because Calcutt’s adjudication was adversarial.
    Calcutt responds that § 308.39(b) requires exhaustion only of issues over which the
    agency has jurisdiction, and that because agencies lack “authority to entertain a facial
    constitutional challenge to the validity of a law,” he did not need to exhaust the removal issue
    before the ALJ or the Board. Reply Br. 2 (quoting Jones Bros., 898 F.3d at 673); see 
    12 C.F.R. § 308.39
    (c)(1) (stating that exceptions “must be confined to the particular matters in, or
    omissions from, the administrative law judge’s recommendations”). Relatedly, he argues that an
    agency proceeding is an inappropriate forum to consider a structural constitutional claim such as
    the Board’s removability, because the Board has no special expertise in Appointments Clause
    jurisprudence and has previously disclaimed authority to entertain constitutional challenges to
    statutes, meaning that raising this issue before the Board would have been futile.
    We think Calcutt has the better of the argument, and that in the “particular administrative
    scheme at issue” in this case, no statute, regulation, or prudential principle required him to raise
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 19
    his challenge to the FDIC Board during the administrative proceedings.          Joseph Forrester
    Trucking v. Dir., Off. of Workers’ Comp. Programs, 
    987 F.3d 581
    , 590 (6th Cir. 2021) (quoting
    Weinberger v. Salfi, 
    422 U.S. 749
    , 765 (1975)). To begin with, the judicial review provision of
    the FDI Act, 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (h), says nothing bearing on exhaustion. We have explained that a
    statute must contain language “directing parties to raise issues” before the agency in order to
    create a statutory issue-exhaustion requirement. See Bryan, 937 F.3d at 749; Jones Bros., Inc. v.
    Sec’y of Lab., 
    898 F.3d 669
    , 673–74 (6th Cir. 2018).
    The applicable FDIC regulations hit closer to the mark. They provide that the “[f]ailure
    of a party to file exceptions . . . is deemed a waiver of objection thereto.”           
    12 C.F.R. § 308.39
    (b)(1). This text might be read to create an issue-exhaustion requirement in light of our
    decision in Bryan, where we detected an issue-exhaustion requirement in a regulation requiring
    that a petition for review list “specific issues to be considered” for appeals from Black Lung
    Benefits Act adjudications to the Benefits Review Board. 937 F.3d at 749 (quoting 
    20 C.F.R. § 802.211
    (a)). However, there is an important difference between Bryan and this case. Calcutt
    raises a facial constitutional challenge to the FDI Act, and the FDIC has no power to invalidate
    its own organic statute; thus, it could never entertain Calcutt’s separation-of-powers challenge to
    the FDIC Board in the first place. See Jones Bros., 898 F.3d at 673–74 (reading statute not to
    impose issue-exhaustion requirement on facial constitutional challenges where agency could not
    “invalidate the statute from which it derives its existence and that it is charged with
    implementing”).     True, we have explained that an agency may entertain certain facial
    constitutional challenges and therefore impose issue-exhaustion requirements where it has long
    asserted that authority. See Joseph Forrester Trucking, 987 F.3d at 588–89; Bryan, 937 F.3d at
    753.   But the FDIC Board has previously disclaimed the authority to determine the
    constitutionality of statutes. See Matter of the Bank of Hartford, No. FDIC-92-212kk, at A-2525
    (FDIC Apr. 11, 1995), https://www.fdic.gov/bank/individual/enforcement/5223.html (last visited
    June 8, 2022)). Though the FDIC now offers a list of examples in which it has considered
    constitutional claims in adjudications, almost none of those decisions considered a constitutional
    challenge to the authority or structure of the FDIC, and the decision that did so—Matter of ***,
    No. 20-4303                                   Calcutt v. FDIC                                            Page 20
    No. FDIC-85-363e, 
    1986 WL 379631
     (FDIC Apr. 21, 1986)—predates Bank of Hartford.6 And
    even if we recognize that the FDIC has asserted authority to decide some constitutional issues,
    we cannot say that this constitutes an established practice for the type of separation-of-powers
    claim at issue here.
    A further consideration counsels against imposing an issue-exhaustion requirement here:
    Calcutt’s challenge to the removal protections of the FDIC Board is a structural constitutional
    challenge over which the FDIC Board has no special expertise. See Carr, 141 S. Ct. at 1360.
    And had Calcutt raised this challenge before the Board, his efforts would have been futile.
    See id. at 1361 (“[T]his Court has consistently recognized a futility exception to exhaustion
    requirements.”).7 To illustrate, consider what remedy the Board could have offered if Calcutt
    had raised the issue and the Board had agreed that it was unconstitutionally shielded from
    removal. The remedies granted by Article III courts, such as severing and striking the Board’s
    for-cause protections from the FDIC’s organic statute, would have been unavailable, because the
    Board, an agency of the Executive Branch, cannot edit its own organic statute. Cf. Seila Law,
    140 S. Ct. at 2207–09. Similarly, the Board could hardly have told the President to treat it as if it
    had no protections from removal, since an agency cannot compel the President to act (let alone
    violate a statute). Another possibility would be for it to vacate Calcutt’s penalty, but that would
    not resolve the constitutional issue, because the removal restrictions would persist. Requiring
    issue exhaustion in this situation would have been a pointless exercise.
    In sum, Calcutt has not forfeited his claim that the FDIC Board is unconstitutionally
    insulated from removal.
    6This    is not to say that the FDIC has disavowed authority to address any constitutional claim. As the FDIC
    notes, it has previously addressed Appointments Clause and separation-of-powers challenges to ALJs. See Matter of
    Sapp, Nos. FDIC-13-477(e), FDIC-13-478(k), 
    2019 WL 5823871
    , at *18–19 (FDIC Sept. 17, 2019); Matter of
    Landry, No. FDIC-95-65e, 
    1999 WL 440608
    , at *27–29 (FDIC May 25, 1999); Matter of Leuthe, Nos. FDIC-95-
    15Ee, FDIC-95-16k,
    1998 WL 438323
    , *10–11 (FDIC June 26, 1998). Those decisions, however, did not concern a
    separation-of-powers challenge to the FDIC Board.
    7While  the Supreme Court has cautioned that courts should hesitate to apply exceptions to mandatory
    exhaustion requirements in a statute, see Ross v. Blake, 
    136 S. Ct. 1850
    , 1857–58 (2016), that concern does not
    apply here because, as we have explained, the FDI Act does not clearly mandate an issue-exhaustion requirement.
    No. 20-4303                                 Calcutt v. FDIC                                          Page 21
    2.      FDIC Board Structure
    Calcutt would have us hold that the FDIC Board is unconstitutionally shielded from
    removal and therefore asks us to invalidate his entire proceeding. Under the framework set out
    by the Supreme Court’s recent separation-of-powers decisions, however, he is not entitled to
    invalidation of his proceedings. See Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1783–89; Seila Law, 140 S. Ct. at
    2198–2204. In particular, Collins indicates that Calcutt is not entitled to the relief he seeks,
    because he has not specified the harm that occurred as a result of the allegedly unconstitutional
    removal restrictions. See 141 S. Ct. at 1788–89.
    Article II of the Constitution states that “[t]he executive Power shall be vested in a
    President,” U.S. Const. art. II, § 1, cl. 1, and requires the President to “take Care that the Laws be
    faithfully executed,” id. art. II, § 3. This language establishes a core principle of constitutional
    separation of powers: “[T]he President’s removal power is the rule, not the exception.” Seila
    Law, 140 S. Ct. at 2206; see also Myers v. United States, 
    272 U.S. 52
    , 163–64 (1926).
    In Seila Law, the Court provided the framework for analyzing the constitutionality of a
    restriction on the President’s removal authority. 140 S. Ct. at 2198. At the first step, we ask
    whether an officer’s tenure protection falls within an established exception to the general
    removal authority. Id. at 2198. As relevant here, one such exception, identified in Humphrey’s
    Executor v. United States, 
    295 U.S. 602
     (1935), permits for-cause removal protections for
    “multimember expert agencies that do not wield substantial executive power.”                        Seila Law,
    140 S. Ct. at 2199–2200.8 To determine whether an agency falls within this category, we
    consider whether (a) the agency is a “body of experts,” id. at 2200 (quoting Humphrey’s Ex’r,
    
    295 U.S. at 624
    ); (b) the agency is nonpartisan or balanced along partisan lines, ibid.; and (c) the
    agency is closer to “a mere legislative or judicial aid” that “was said not to exercise any
    enforcement power,” 
    id.
     at 2199–2200, or rather an enforcement body that may “promulgate
    binding rules,” “unilaterally issue final decisions awarding legal and equitable relief in
    8The   Seila Law Court also recognized an exception for “inferior officers with limited duties and no
    policymaking or administrative authority” under Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. 654
     (1988). See Seila Law, 140 S. Ct.
    at 2199–2200. However, this exception does not apply to the FDIC Board, which qualifies as the head of a
    department. See Free Enter. Fund, 
    561 U.S. at
    512–13 (explaining that multimember commissions can qualify as
    head of a department).
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                     Page 22
    administrative adjudications,” and “seek daunting monetary penalties against private parties on
    behalf of the United States in federal court,” id. at 2200.
    At the second step, if an agency structure does not fall within an established exception,
    we must determine “whether to extend those precedents to the ‘new situation.’” Seila Law,
    140 S. Ct. at 2201 (quoting Free Enter. Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 483
    ). In concluding that the CFPB
    Director was unconstitutionally shielded from removal, the Seila Law Court emphasized two key
    features: the historical novelty of an agency headed by a single director removable only for
    cause, and the inconsistency of this design with constitutional structure. 
    Id.
     at 2201–04.
    As for the historical inquiry, the Court canvassed American history and found only
    “modern and contested” examples of agencies headed by a single director who enjoyed good-
    cause tenure, such as the Federal Housing Finance Agency (“FHFA”) Director, and a “one-year
    blip” during the Civil War in which the Comptroller of the Currency received for-cause
    protections. Id. at 2202; see also Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1783 (holding that removal restriction for
    FHFA Director was unconstitutional, and that Seila Law was “all but dispositive” on the
    question).
    As for the structural inquiry, the Court underscored that the constitutional scheme’s
    combination of the separation of powers and democratic accountability foreclosed
    executive officers from exercising significant authority without direct presidential supervision.
    The Constitution emphasizes the division of power, but it also recognized the need for an
    “energetic executive” to respond quickly and flexibly to challenges. Seila Law, 140 S. Ct. at
    2203 (discussing The Federalist No. 51 (James Madison) and The Federalist No. 70 (Alexander
    Hamilton)). To resolve these dueling priorities, the Constitution makes the President directly
    accountable to the American people through elections, allowing him to delegate authority to
    subordinate officials to complete the tasks of governance so long as that delegated authority
    “remains subject to the ongoing supervision and control of the elected President.” Ibid. The
    CFPB Director’s for-cause protections violated this structure because, by eliminating the
    President’s ability to remove the CFPB Director at will, the CFPB concentrated power in a
    single officer while insulating him from presidential control. Id. at 2204. This infirmity was
    exacerbated by the CFPB Director’s five-year term, which meant that “some Presidents may not
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 23
    have any opportunity to shape its leadership,” and the agency’s independence from the normal
    appropriations process. Ibid.
    We need not delve deeply into the Seila Law inquiry in this case, however, because
    Collins instructs that relief from agency proceedings is predicated on a showing of harm, a
    requirement that forecloses Calcutt from receiving the relief he seeks. See 141 S. Ct. at 1788–89.
    Collins concerned the Director of the Federal Housing Finance Agency, an agency with authority
    to regulate and act as the conservator or receiver of the Federal National Mortgage Association
    (Fannie Mae) and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac).                 Collins,
    141 S. Ct. at 1770. Acting as the companies’ conservator, the FHFA amended stock purchasing
    agreements with the Treasury Department, which altered the dividends that Fannie Mae and
    Freddie Mac were required to pay to Treasury in exchange for capital. See id. at 1772–75.
    Shareholders of the companies brought suit against the FHFA and the FHFA Director as a result.
    See id. at 1775. As relevant here, the shareholders argued that the statutory for-cause removal
    protection of the FHFA Director violated the separation of powers, see id. at 1778, and that
    therefore the amendment to the FHFA-Treasury agreement “must be completely undone,” id. at
    1787.
    The Supreme Court agreed that the for-cause removal provision was unconstitutional, as
    its decision in Seila Law was “all but dispositive.” Id. at 1783. Just as the CFPB in that decision
    presented a “novel context of an independent agency led by a single Director” whose for-cause
    removal protections “lack[ed] a foundation in historical practice and clashe[d] with constitutional
    structure by concentrating power in a unilateral actor insulated from Presidential control,” so too
    did the single-director structure and removal protections in the FHFA unconstitutionally limit the
    President’s removal power. Id. at 1783–84 (quoting Seila Law, 140 S. Ct. at 2192).
    Yet although the removal restriction was unconstitutional, the Court held that the
    shareholders were not entitled to relief absent further findings by the lower courts.          The
    shareholders were not entitled to a prospective remedy, because a subsequent agreement between
    the FHFA and Treasury had deleted the dividend formula that caused the alleged injury. Id. at
    1779–80. As to retrospective relief for the claimed injury during the years that the dividend
    formula was in effect, the Court observed that “[a]lthough the statute unconstitutionally limited
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 24
    the President’s authority to remove the confirmed Directors, there was no constitutional defect in
    the statutorily prescribed method of appointment to that office.” Id. at 1787. Thus, the Director
    “lawfully possess[ed]” the power to implement the provision. Id. at 1788.
    The Court explained that the shareholders would be entitled to relief if the
    unconstitutional removal restriction “inflict[ed] compensable harm,” and it remanded the case to
    the Court of Appeals to conduct this inquiry.        Id. at 1789.     To establish such harm, the
    shareholders would need to show that the removal restriction specifically impacted the agency
    actions of which they complained:
    Suppose, for example, that the President had attempted to remove a Director but
    was prevented from doing so by a lower court decision holding that he did not
    have “cause” for removal. Or suppose that the President had made a public
    statement expressing displeasure with actions taken by a Director and had
    asserted that he would remove the Director if the statute did not stand in the way.
    In those situations, the statutory provision would clearly cause harm.
    Ibid. Several concurring Justices confirmed that a petitioner would have to establish that an
    unconstitutional removal protection specifically caused an agency action in order to be entitled to
    judicial invalidation of that action. See id. at 1789 (Thomas, J., concurring) (agreeing with
    majority’s remedial analysis “that, to the extent a Government action violates the Constitution,
    the remedy should fit the injury”); id. at 1801 (Kagan, J., concurring in part and concurring in the
    judgment) (“I also agree that plaintiffs alleging a removal violation are entitled to injunctive
    relief—a rewinding of agency action—only when the President’s inability to fire an agency head
    affected the complained-of decision.”); id. at 1803 n.1 (Sotomayor, J., concurring in part and
    dissenting in part) (agreeing with majority’s remedial discussion).
    Calcutt attempts to distinguish Collins by observing that the decision concerned only
    retrospective relief, because the FHFA had already ended the challenged action, whereas
    Calcutt’s Removal and Prohibition Order remains in effect and operates prospectively. That
    distinction does not matter here. The Collins inquiry focuses on whether a “harm” occurred that
    would create an entitlement to a remedy, rather than the nature of the remedy, and our
    determination as to whether an unconstitutional removal protection “inflicted harm” remains the
    same whether the petitioner seeks retrospective or prospective relief (particularly when we
    No. 20-4303                                    Calcutt v. FDIC                                            Page 25
    review an adjudication that has already ended). Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1789. In other words,
    Collins instructs that we must ask whether the FDIC Board’s for-cause protections “inflicted
    harm,” such as by preventing superior officers from removing Board members when they
    attempted to do so, or possibly by altering the Board’s behavior. Ibid. The Removal and
    Prohibition Order’s prospective effect does not change a court’s ability to conduct that inquiry.
    Collins thus provides a clear instruction: To invalidate an agency action due to a removal
    violation, that constitutional infirmity must “cause harm” to the challenging party. Ibid. Our
    sister circuits that have considered the question agree that this is the key inquiry. See Kaufmann
    v. Kijakazi, 
    32 F.4th 843
    , 849 (9th Cir. 2022) (explaining that “[a] party challenging an agency’s
    past actions must . . . show how the unconstitutional removal provision actually harmed the
    party”); Bhatti v. Fed. Housing Fin. Agency, 
    15 F.4th 848
    , 854 (8th Cir. 2021) (identifying issue
    under Collins as whether unconstitutional removal restriction “caused compensable harm”);9
    Decker Coal Co. v. Pehringer, 
    8 F.4th 1123
    , 1137 (9th Cir. 2021) (stating that, under the
    “controlling” authority of Collins, “[a]bsent a showing of harm, we refuse to unwind the
    [agency] decisions below”).
    Calcutt has not demonstrated that the structure of the FDIC Board caused him harm.
    He first states that the FDIC Board’s Removal and Prohibition Order “inflicts ongoing harm” by
    preventing him from participating in banking activities. Reply Br. 10. However, Collins does
    not say that any administrative penalty imposed by an unconstitutionally-structured agency must
    be vacated. Instead, the constitutional violation must have caused the harm. See Collins,
    
    141 S. Ct. 1789
     (identifying inquiry as whether “an unconstitutional provision . . . inflict[ed]
    compensable harm”).
    Calcutt also argues that the possibility that the FDIC would have taken different actions in
    his case, if the Board not been unconstitutionally shielded from removal, means that we should
    9In Bhatti, the Eighth Circuit also remanded to the district court “to determine if the shareholders suffered
    ‘compensable harm’ and are entitled to ‘retrospective relief.’” Bhatti, 15 F.4th at 854 (quoting Collins, 141 S. Ct. at
    1789). This language does not conflict with our conclusion that Collins does not rest on whether relief is
    prospective or retrospective, because Bhatti concerned the same agency actions as Collins did. See id. at 852.
    Because the Collins Court recognized that only retrospective relief was available to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac
    shareholders, the Bhatti court followed that precedent. See ibid.
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 26
    vacate and remand. Taken in isolation, some language in Collins might be read to support this
    view. See, e.g., ibid. (“[T]he possibility that the unconstitutional restriction on the President’s
    power to remove a Director of the FHFA could have such an effect [of inflicting compensable
    harm] cannot be ruled out.”). But such a broad reading would effectively eliminate any need to
    show that unconstitutional removal protections caused harm, because a petitioner could always
    assert a possibility that an agency with different personnel might have acted differently. The
    Collins Court was not deterred from its holding by the very possibility that harm might occur;
    rather, it indicated that a more concrete showing was needed.
    Calcutt also posits that if the FDIC Board had not been unconstitutionally insulated from
    removal, after Lucia it might have “altered [its] behavior,” ibid., and provided new proceedings
    as recommended by the Solicitor General, see Mem. from the Solicitor General to Agency
    General Counsels, Guidance on Administrative Law Judges after Lucia v. SEC (S. Ct.) 8–9,
    https://static.reuters.com/resources/media/editorial/20180723/ALJ--SGMEMO.pdf (last visited
    May 24, 2022). While failure to follow executive-branch policy could certainly help indicate
    that a removal restriction inflicted harm, that is not what happened here. As we explain further
    below, the FDIC provided a new hearing to Calcutt consistent with Lucia. See infra at 30–35.
    We also fail to see how the FDIC disregarded the Solicitor General’s guidance. The Solicitor
    General told agencies that while “a full soup-to-nuts redo of the administrative proceeding” was
    “the safest course” after Lucia, it was not the only course available:
    While litigants may be expected to argue otherwise, however, we do not believe a
    complete do-over is constitutionally required. We believe that a ‘new hearing’
    will be constitutionally adequate as long as the new ALJ is careful to avoid any
    taint from the prior ALJ’s decision. Thus, we do not think it is necessarily fatal if
    the new ALJ starts with the existing record in the proceeding (including hearing
    transcripts), much of which there would be little purpose in generating anew.
    Mem. from the Solicitor General to Agency General Counsels 8–9. Thus, we disagree with
    Calcutt’s suggestion that the FDIC Board failed to follow executive-branch policy—let alone that
    it did so because of its removal protections.
    Finally, Calcutt asks this court to remand to the FDIC to determine whether the removal
    restriction “inflicted harm” in his case, as the Collins court also remanded for further findings.
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 27
    We do not think this step is necessary.        The record is sufficiently clear that the removal
    protections did not cause harm, and Calcutt provides only vague, generalized allegations in
    response. See Decker Coal Co., 8 F.4th at 1137 (declining to remand where “the record is
    clear”). We also note that, unlike the Collins Court or the Eighth Circuit in Bhatti, we would be
    remanding to an agency rather than another court. See Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1789 (remanding to
    court of appeals); Bhatti, 15 F.4th at 854 (remanding to district court to determine whether
    Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac shareholders suffered compensable harm entitling them to relief
    under Collins). We do not see how yet another proceeding before the FDIC would aid in
    developing the record on this point.
    B. FDIC ALJ Structure
    Calcutt’s separation-of-powers challenge to the removal protections of FDIC ALJs is
    unsuccessful for similar reasons as his challenge to the structure of the FDIC Board. First and
    foremost, even if we were to accept that the removal protections for the FDIC ALJs posed a
    constitutional problem, Calcutt is not entitled to relief unless he establishes that those protections
    “inflict[ed] compensable harm,” and he has not made this showing. Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1789.
    Second, even if he established that the removal protections caused him harm, Free Enterprise
    Fund explicitly excludes ALJs from its prohibition on multiple levels of for-cause removal
    protection, and thus, like Seila Law, it only provides weak support for his position. See Free
    Enter. Fund, 
    561 U.S. at
    507 n.10.
    To recall, FDIC ALJs can only be removed if the MSPB finds that there is “good cause”
    for removal on the record after an opportunity for a hearing. 
    5 U.S.C. § 7521
    (a). The President
    may remove MSPB members “only for inefficiency, neglect of duty, or malfeasance in office.”
    
    5 U.S.C. § 1202
    (d). Additionally, the FDIC ALJs are housed in an interagency body—the Office
    of Financial Institution Adjudication, or OFIA—composed of the FDIC, OCC, FRB, and NCUA.
    The memorandum of understanding for OFIA states: “Any change to the Office Staff personnel
    shall be subject to the prior written approval of all Agencies.” See Ex. L to Emergency Motion
    for Stay Pending Review, at 3.         According to Calcutt, OFIA’s structure “magnifies the
    constitutional problem” by requiring all four member agencies to consent before “initiat[ing]
    ALJ removal proceedings.” Br. of Petitioner 30.
    No. 20-4303                                  Calcutt v. FDIC                                           Page 28
    We begin with the Collins issue. As previously discussed, that decision requires a
    showing that an unconstitutional removal restriction “cause[d] harm” to invalidate an agency
    action. 141 S. Ct. at 1789.10 Here, again, Calcutt offers vague assertions that it “cannot be ruled
    out” that the multiple levels of for-cause removal protections insulating ALJ McNeil caused him
    harm, but a generalized allegation is insufficient for affording relief. Reply Br. 18 (quoting
    Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1789). He also argues that had these removal restrictions not been in place,
    ALJ McNeil would have been more responsive to executive-branch policy, would have properly
    offered a new hearing after Lucia, and would not have issued a recommended decision
    that conflicted with the FDI Act. But those arguments are premised on the success of Calcutt’s
    other claims of constitutional and statutory violations, and as we explain below, none of those
    claims succeed. See infra at 30–35, 37–53. Thus, he cannot rely on those allegations of harm,
    either.
    An additional feature in this case further suggests that no harm was caused by the
    removal restrictions. Before Lucia, FDIC adjudications were performed by two ALJs who were
    not appointed by the FDIC Board: ALJ Miserendino and ALJ McNeil. After Lucia held that
    similar ALJs in the SEC were inferior officers who must be appointed by the President, a court of
    law, or a head of department, see 
    138 S. Ct. at
    2051 (citing U.S. Const. art. II, § 2, cl. 2), the
    FDIC could have appointed new ALJs. However, it simply appointed the officials who had
    previously been acting as ALJs—including ALJ McNeil. In the specific circumstances of this
    case, where the FDIC newly appointed an ALJ when it had the option not to do so, it is unlikely
    that the restriction on the removal of the ALJ prevented the agency from pursuing a different
    path respecting Calcutt.
    Even if relief were available, we doubt Calcutt could establish a constitutional violation
    from the ALJ removal restrictions. Though Free Enterprise Fund concluded that the two layers
    of for-cause protections enjoyed by the members of the Public Company Accounting Oversight
    Board were “incompatible with the Constitution’s separation of powers,” Free Enter. Fund,
    10Even   if the restrictions on the removal of FDIC ALJs were invalid, both parties agree that ALJ McNeil
    was validly appointed. Therefore, we need not address whether Calcutt would be entitled to relief on grounds
    specifically relating to McNeil’s appointment. See Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1787–88.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                 Page 29
    
    561 U.S. at 498
    , the Court took care to omit ALJs from the scope of its holding, 
    id.
     at 507 n.10
    (“[O]ur holding also does not address that subset of independent agency employees who serve as
    administrative law judges.”). The Court explained that its decision did not apply to ALJs for
    several reasons: “Whether administrative law judges are necessarily ‘Officers of the United
    States’ is disputed,” and many ALJs “perform adjudicative rather than enforcement or
    policymaking functions, . . . or possess purely recommendatory powers.” 
    Ibid.
     (citing Landry v.
    FDIC, 
    204 F.3d 1125
     (D.C. Cir. 2000) (statutory citations omitted)). Similarly, as then-Judge
    Kavanaugh explained in dissent in the District of Columbia Circuit proceedings, the for-cause
    protections of ALJs are distinguishable because agencies can choose not to use ALJs in
    adjudications; ALJs may not be officers (as the law stood at that time); and many ALJs perform
    adjudicatory functions that are subject to review by higher agency officials, which “arguably
    would not be considered ‘central to the functioning of the executive Branch’ for purposes of the
    Article II removal precedents.” Free Enter. Fund v. Pub. Co. Acct. Oversight Bd., 
    537 F.3d 667
    ,
    699 n.8 (D.C. Cir. 2008) (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting) (quoting Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. 654
    ,
    691–92 (1988)).
    Other than the argument that ALJs are not officers, which Lucia forecloses, see 
    138 S. Ct. at
    2053–54, these rationales still apply to the FDIC ALJs. First, the FDIC ALJs perform
    adjudicatory functions, and they file a recommended decision that is subject to review by the
    FDIC Board. See Free Enter. Fund, 
    561 U.S. at
    496 n.10; Free Enter. Fund, 
    537 F.3d at
    699 n.8
    (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting); 
    12 C.F.R. § 308.38
    (a).        Second, “Congress has not tied the
    President’s hands and hindered his control over his subordinates here.” Decker Coal Co., 8 F.4th
    at 1133. Rather, the FDIC must conduct hearings “in accordance with the provisions of [the
    APA],” 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (h)(1), and the APA permits an agency to choose whether to preside
    over an adjudication itself, allow one or more members to be presiding officers, or use an ALJ,
    
    5 U.S.C. § 556
    (b). In short, though Calcutt is correct that Free Enterprise Fund left open
    whether it applied to ALJs, that decision’s reasoning for exempting ALJs still extends to this
    case.
    Calcutt and amicus Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America also argue
    that the structure of OFIA provides particularly egregious removal protections for FDIC ALJs
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 30
    that violate the separation of powers. Under OFIA’s governing memorandum of understanding,
    all the constituent agencies of OFIA—the FDIC, OCC, FRB, and NCUA—must approve
    “[a]ny change to the Office Staff personnel.” Ex. L to Emergency Motion for Stay Pending
    Review, at 3. According to Calcutt, this provision means that each agency has veto power over
    any other agency’s attempt to remove an ALJ. Exacerbating this problem, he adds, several of the
    agencies who must agree to removal also enjoy for-cause protection. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 242
    (FRB); 12 U.S.C. § 1752a(c) (NCUA Board members serve fixed terms); supra at 6 (FDIC for-
    cause protections).
    Although OFIA may present a “novel structure,” Free Enter. Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 495
    , the
    Free Enterprise Fund exception for ALJs centers on their status as adjudicatory officials that
    issue non-final recommendations to an agency, and not on how many levels of removal
    protections they enjoy, see 
    id.
     at 496 n.10. Consequently, OFIA does not present a reason for us
    to hold that the removal restrictions for FDIC ALJs violates constitutional separation of powers.
    More importantly, even if we were to find such a violation, Collins decisively precludes relief for
    Calcutt.
    C. Appointments Clause
    The Appointments Clause requires that “Officers of the United States” be appointed by
    the President with the advice and consent of the Senate, but Congress may allow “inferior
    Officers” to be appointed by the President alone, by courts, or by heads of departments.
    U.S. Const. art. II, § 2, cl. 2. “[T]he ‘appropriate’ remedy for an adjudication tainted with an
    appointments violation is a new ‘hearing before a properly appointed official.’”             Lucia,
    
    138 S. Ct. at 2055
     (quoting Ryder v. United States, 
    515 U.S. 177
    , 188 (1995)). Calcutt argues
    that he did not receive this “new hearing,” but he is wrong.
    Calcutt states that the FDIC ALJs are “inferior Officers,” and the FDIC does not contest
    this point.   We agree that FDIC ALJs are inferior officers and that they were improperly
    appointed before Lucia.      Cf. Burgess v. FDIC, 
    871 F.3d 297
    , 302–03 (5th Cir. 2017)
    (reasoning that FDIC ALJs are officers). Because they are inferior officers, the FDIC ALJs must
    be appointed by the President, a court, or the FDIC Board. U.S. Const. art. II, § 2, cl. 2. Prior to
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                 Page 31
    2018, the FDIC Board did not appoint the ALJs, so their appointments were invalid. See Jones
    Bros., 898 F.3d at 679.
    Calcutt and the FDIC also agree up to a point that the remedy for the prior Appointments
    Clause violation is “a new ‘hearing before a properly appointed’ official” distinct from the
    previous ALJ. Lucia, 
    138 S. Ct. at 2055
     (quoting Ryder, 
    515 U.S. at 188
    ). However, Calcutt
    argues that a new hearing must consist of an entirely new proceeding, where the new adjudicator
    starts from scratch and ignores the record from the prior proceeding. He specifically objects to
    ALJ McNeil’s admission of stipulations and transcripts from the 2015 proceedings, and he
    contends that ALJ Miserendino’s procedural rulings in 2015 narrowed the scope of discovery in a
    manner that impacted the 2019 proceedings. The FDIC, in contrast, contends that the “new
    hearing” requires only a new, independent evaluation of the merits of a case without limiting
    consideration of the prior record, and that therefore ALJ McNeil’s use of the 2015 record was
    proper.
    Lucia does not specify what features a “new hearing” must contain, other than a new
    adjudicator. 
    138 S. Ct. at 2055
    . Other decisions addressing the remedies for Appointments
    Clause violations are similarly vague. See Ryder, 
    515 U.S. at 188
     (holding that petitioner “is
    entitled to a hearing before a properly appointed panel” of military court); Jones Bros., 898 F.3d
    at 679 (holding that petitioner “is entitled to a new hearing before a constitutionally appointed
    administrative law judge” and remanding for “fresh proceedings”).
    Other decisions indicate that courts afford agencies more leeway on remand after
    Appointments Clause violations than Calcutt’s all-or-nothing position suggests. In Lucia, for
    example, the Supreme Court recognized that in situations where “there is no substitute
    decisionmaker” after an Appointments Clause violation, a new hearing before the original
    decisionmaker could be proper. Lucia, 
    138 S. Ct. at
    2055 n.5 (citing FTC v. Cement Inst.,
    
    333 U.S. 683
    , 700–03 (1948)). The Federal Circuit, after finding that administrative patent
    judges were invalidly appointed, also explained that it required a “new hearing” before a “new
    panel” of judges, but that it saw “no error in the new panel proceeding on the existing record”
    and left to the agency’s “sound discretion” whether to “allow additional briefing or reopen the
    record in any individual case.” Arthrex, Inc. v. Smith & Nephew, Inc., 
    941 F.3d 1320
    , 1340
    No. 20-4303                                    Calcutt v. FDIC                                            Page 32
    (Fed. Cir. 2019), vacated on alternate grounds and remanded sub nom. United States v. Arthrex,
    Inc., 
    141 S. Ct. 1970
     (2021).11 For its part, the Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia
    Circuit rejected a petitioner’s claim that a new proceeding by a properly appointed official must
    involve entirely new proceedings that ignore the prior record. Intercollegiate Broad. Sys., Inc. v.
    Copyright Royalty Bd., 
    796 F.3d. 111
    , 117–19 (D.C. Cir. 2015). Instead, that court concluded
    that a subsequent proceeding is valid when “a properly appointed official has the power to
    conduct an independent evaluation of the merits and does so,” 
    id. at 117
    , and that as a
    constitutional matter this “independent evaluation” could include a review of prior records and
    transcripts, see 
    id. at 122
    .
    This reluctance to adopt a bright-light rule makes sense. To hold that all adjudications
    must start from zero after a judicial decision invalidating ALJ appointments would result in
    cumbersome, repetitive processes throughout the executive branch simply to produce findings
    and orders that would often be identical the second time around. Moreover, as the District of
    Columbia Circuit observed, an “independent evaluation of the merits” does not require an ALJ to
    ignore all past proceedings: Independence is not a synonym for ignorance. See 
    id.
     at 121–23.12
    Thus, our inquiry focuses on whether ALJ McNeil’s consideration of the 2015
    stipulations and testimony showed “sufficient continuing taint arising from the first
    [proceeding]” to demonstrate that the second proceeding was not “an independent, de novo
    11We   note that although the Supreme Court stated that a new hearing was unnecessary in Arthrex, it
    explained that Arthrex was not entitled to a new hearing before a new panel “[b]ecause the source of the
    constitutional violation is the restraint on the review authority of the Director [of the Patent and Trademark Office],
    rather than the appointment of [administrative patent judges] by the Secretary [of Commerce].” Arthrex, 141 S. Ct.
    at 1988 (emphases added). This decision thus did not reject the Federal Circuit’s conclusion that, if the
    administrative patent judges’ appointments had been invalid, a new hearing would be appropriate, including some
    consideration of the original record.
    12Our  dissenting colleague characterizes our approach as a cost-benefit balancing exercise. See Dissent at
    74. But determining whether a new ALJ can conduct an “independent evaluation of the merits,” see Intercollegiate
    Broad. Sys., 796 F.3d at 117, involves analyzing the impact of those past proceedings on a current adjudication—an
    inquiry that bears little resemblance to a weighing of the relative costs and benefits of a new administrative
    proceeding. Though we mention prudential considerations that favor our approach, we do not rely on them.
    Instead, our conclusion rests on the principle illustrated in Intercollegiate Broadcasting System and other decisions
    that, following an Appointments Clause violation, a new proceeding affords adequate remedy when a new
    decisionmaker can independently consider the merits. See id. at 117–20; Arthrex, 941 F.3d at 1340.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 33
    decision.” Id. at 124 (citing Fed. Election Comm’n v. Legi-Tech, Inc., 
    75 F.3d 704
    , 708 n.5 (D.C.
    Cir. 1996)). No such ongoing impact occurred here.
    First, ALJ Miserendino’s general ability to shape the record at the 2015 hearing does not
    demonstrate that ALJ McNeil lacked independence. Calcutt implies that any decision at a prior
    proceeding that shapes the record of a later proceeding invalidates the latter’s outcome. That
    goes too far. See Intercollegiate Broad. Sys., 796 F.3d at 124 (explaining that “not every possible
    kind of taint is fatal because, if it were, there would be no way to remedy an Appointments
    Clause violation”); Legi-Tech, 
    75 F.3d at
    708–09 (accepting that past Appointments Clause
    violation will have some impact on later proceedings, but refusing to restart administrative
    process). And where a party receives an opportunity to submit additional evidence and to specify
    alleged defects in the first proceeding, as the FDIC’s order after Lucia provided here, the
    subsequent proceeding is even more likely to be independent.
    Second, ALJ McNeil’s reliance on stipulations that the FDIC, Calcutt, Green, and
    Jackson made during the 2015 proceedings before Green and Jackson settled did not taint the
    proceedings. Calcutt and amicus Washington Legal Foundation argue that the settlement altered
    the facts that Calcutt would have conceded. At most, however, the cases cited by the parties
    show that courts sometimes accept stipulations made in prior proceedings and sometimes do not,
    and that these decisions are reviewed for abuse of discretion.         See United States v. Kanu,
    
    695 F.3d 74
    , 78 (D.C. Cir. 2012); Waldorf v. Shuta, 
    142 F.3d 601
    , 616 (3d Cir. 1998); Hunt v.
    Marchetti, 
    824 F.2d 916
    , 918 (11th Cir. 1987). To the extent that these decisions about judicial
    proceedings apply to administrative adjudications, ALJ McNeil did not abuse his discretion. In
    Waldorf, the court specified that “a stipulation does not continue to bind the parties if they
    expressly limited it to the first proceeding or if the parties intended the stipulation to apply only
    at the first trial,” 
    142 F.3d at 616
    , and in this case the parties had agreed to stipulations at the
    2015 proceedings without expressly limiting the stipulations to those proceedings. Moreover,
    while stipulations from prior proceedings may be excluded if their admission would create a
    “manifest injustice,” Kanu, 695 F.3d at 78, Calcutt did not deny that the stipulations were
    accurate, but rather argued that they were irrelevant or inappropriate to the new proceeding now
    that that his co-respondents had settled. The ALJ did not abuse his discretion by admitting the
    No. 20-4303                                Calcutt v. FDIC                                        Page 34
    stipulations when Calcutt had failed to show that their admission would produce manifest
    injustice and had failed to expressly limit their use to the prior proceedings.
    Finally, Calcutt contends that ALJ McNeil and the FDIC Board’s use of the record of the
    2015 hearing hampered their ability to make an independent judgment. At the 2019 hearing,
    Calcutt objected to using that record for all but two witnesses,13 except for impeachment
    purposes. ALJ McNeil indicated that he was willing to use the entire 2015 record for substantive
    as well as impeachment purposes, and he ultimately used that record at several points throughout
    the hearing and his recommended decision. The FDIC Board then referred to the 2015 record in
    its final decision at several points, including instances when the 2015 record was the only cited
    evidence. It also concluded that it could consider Calcutt’s testimony during 2015 as either
    impeachment or substantive evidence.
    This inclusion of the 2015 record also did not prevent ALJ McNeil and the Board from
    conducting an “independent evaluation of the merits.” Intercollegiate Broad. Sys., 796 F.3d at
    122. To begin with, Calcutt’s prior testimony likely qualifies as an opposing party’s statement,
    despite his objection. See 
    12 C.F.R. § 308.36
    (a)(2) (permitting admission of evidence that would
    be admissible under Federal Rules of Evidence); United States v. Cunningham, 
    679 F.3d 355
    ,
    383 (6th Cir. 2012) (explaining that Federal Rule of Evidence 801(d)(2)(A) allows “a party’s
    own statement to be offered as evidence against that party even where the statement would
    otherwise be inadmissible as hearsay”). Additional testimony from 2015 was corroborated by
    other evidence. The remaining isolated instances in which either ALJ McNeil or the Board relied
    on the 2015 record for substantive conclusions do not convince us that the agency was unable to
    independently consider the merits of Calcutt’s case. And, if there was error at these points in its
    analysis, it was likely harmless due to the abundance of evidence in the record supporting the
    agency’s decision. See 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2); see also infra at 37–53.
    In sum, Lucia required that Calcutt receive a new hearing, and that is what he got. A new
    hearing need not be from scratch; rather, the impact of the prior proceeding must be sufficiently
    muted that the new adjudicator can independently consider the merits. ALJ McNeil and the
    13The parties agreed by stipulation to introduce the 2015 testimony of Dennis O’Neill and Charles Bird,
    two FDIC examiners.
    No. 20-4303                           Calcutt v. FDIC                                 Page 35
    FDIC Board did not abuse their discretion by admitting the 2015 materials when they remained
    capable of drawing their own conclusions about Calcutt’s case.
    IV. HEARING CHALLENGES
    We now turn from Calcutt’s structural constitutional challenges to his claims regarding
    the specifics of his 2019 hearing. These fall into three categories: a challenge relating to the
    decision of the ALJ to limit cross-examination on bias at the hearing, a challenge to the
    substance of the FDIC Board’s findings and conclusions, and an abuse-of-discretion challenge to
    the FDIC Board’s choice of sanction.
    A. Cross-Examination
    Under the FDI Act and the APA, parties are entitled “to conduct such cross-examination
    as may be required for a full and true disclosure of the facts.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 556
    (d); see 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (h)(1) (requiring FDIC hearings to be conducted in accordance with APA adjudication
    procedures). The FDIC’s regulations provide that evidence which would be admissible under the
    Federal Rules of Evidence is also admissible in an enforcement hearing, 
    12 C.F.R. § 308.36
    (a)(2), and that evidence that would be inadmissible under the Federal Rules of
    Evidence is admissible in the hearing if it is “relevant, material, reliable, and not unduly
    repetitive,” 
    id.
     § 308.36(a)(3); see id. § 308.36(a)(1). Calcutt argues that ALJ McNeil erred
    under these provisions by limiting cross-examination of Autumn Berden, Cori Nielson, and Anne
    Miessner regarding their purported bias against Calcutt, and that the Board erred by accepting
    these limitations. The parties agree that neither Berden, Nielson, nor Miessner testified about
    bias at the hearing.
    We review an ALJ’s exclusion of evidence under an abuse-of-discretion standard. NLRB
    v. Jackson Hosp. Corp., 
    557 F.3d 301
    , 305–06 (6th Cir. 2009). An abuse of discretion occurs
    when the ALJ “applies the wrong legal standard, misapplies the correct legal standard, or relies
    on clearly erroneous findings of fact.” B & G Mining, Inc. v. Dir., Off. of Workers’ Comp.
    Programs, 
    522 F.3d 657
    , 661 (6th Cir. 2008) (quotation marks omitted).
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 36
    Yet, “due account must be taken of the rule of prejudicial error.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2); see
    
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (h)(2) (providing that the APA governs review of FDIC enforcement
    proceedings). This language applies the federal harmless-error standard from civil cases. See
    Shinseki v. Sanders, 
    556 U.S. 396
    , 406–07 (2009). We employ a “case-specific application of
    judgment, based upon examination of the record,” 
    id. at 407
    , to determine whether the error
    “affect[ed] the substantial rights of the parties,” 
    28 U.S.C. § 2111
    . An error is not harmless
    when, for example, an agency violates its own procedural rules and the petitioner shows that he
    “has been prejudiced on the merits or deprived of substantial rights because of the agency’s
    procedural lapses.” Wilson v. Comm’r of Soc. Sec., 
    378 F.3d 541
    , 547 (6th Cir. 2004) (quotation
    marks and emphasis omitted).
    We need not reach whether ALJ McNeil abused his discretion in limiting cross-
    examination on the bias of Berden, Nielson, and Miessner, because even if he did, that error was
    harmless. As we have explained in the civil context, an adjudicator’s erroneous exclusion of
    evidence is not prejudicial, and therefore is harmless, “if other substantially equivalent evidence
    of the same facts [was] admitted into evidence.” In re Air Crash Disaster, 
    86 F.3d 498
    , 526 (6th
    Cir. 1996) (quoting Leonard v. Uniroyal, Inc., 
    765 F.3d 560
    , 567 (6th Cir. 1985) (alteration in
    original)). Thus, we recently observed that where a court excluded evidence of police interview
    transcripts but the record contained depositions of “most of the same witnesses” quoted in the
    transcripts, any error was harmless. M.J. v. Akron City Sch. Dist. Bd. of Educ., 
    1 F.4th 436
    , 447
    (6th Cir. 2021); see also Smith v. Woolace Elec. Corp., 822 F. App’x 409, 417 (6th Cir. 2020)
    (potential error over excluding witness’s testimony was harmless where plaintiff “introduced
    substantially equivalent evidence” through another witness’s testimony).
    ALJ McNeil and the FDIC Board had access to the 2015 record, which contained
    substantially equivalent evidence regarding Berden, Nielson, and Miessner’s bias. See supra at
    31–35. During those earlier proceedings, Calcutt’s counsel examined Berden, Nielson, and
    Miessner about their bias and alleged collaboration. Other documents in the record were also
    relevant to bias, including an email where Nielson told Miessner about difficulties with
    Northwestern Bank, requested that the FDIC contact Michigan regulators, and stated, “I just wish
    there was a fresh face to talk to at the bank—all this collateral damage is meaningless”; an email
    No. 20-4303                                    Calcutt v. FDIC                                            Page 37
    in which Miessner communicated with Michigan regulators regarding Nielson’s request;
    Berden’s handwritten notes from meetings with FDIC officials; and an email correspondence
    between Miessner, Nielson, and Berden about FDIC charges against Calcutt, titled “A little news
    to brighten your weekend.” Although further cross-examination would have allowed Calcutt to
    further develop his bias argument, the availability of these other materials indicates that the
    agency’s factfinders possessed sufficient information regarding the possible bias of Berden,
    Nielson, and Miessner to render any error harmless. Thus, the limits on cross-examination do
    not necessitate a new proceeding.
    B. Substantive Challenges
    As previously discussed, Section 8(e) of the FDI Act permits the FDIC to enter a removal
    and prohibition order against an institution-affiliated party after finding that three elements have
    been met: misconduct, effects, and culpability. See Dodge, 744 F.3d at 152. Misconduct occurs
    when a party has “directly or indirectly” violated a law or regulation, “engaged or participated in
    any unsafe or unsound practice” connected with an insured institution, or breached a fiduciary
    duty. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A). The requisite effects take place when, “by reason of” the
    misconduct, the insured institution “has suffered or will probably suffer financial loss or other
    damage,” its depositors’ interests are prejudiced, or the party “has received financial gain or
    other benefit by reason of” the misconduct. 
    Id.
     § 1818(e)(1)(B). And the culpability element is
    met when the party’s action “involves personal dishonesty” or “demonstrates willful or
    continuing disregard . . . for the safety or soundness” of the insured institution.                                Id.
    § 1818(e)(1)(C). We review the FDIC Board’s factual findings for substantial evidence and set
    aside the agency’s legal conclusions if they are “arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or
    otherwise not in accordance with law.” Pharaon v. Bd. of Governors of Fed. Rsrv. Sys., 
    135 F.3d 148
    , 152 (D.C. Cir. 1998) (quoting 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(A)).14
    Calcutt argues that the FDIC exceeded its statutory authority by finding misconduct when
    none of his actions qualified under the statutory definitions, failing to demonstrate that any
    14Though    the FDIC Board’s interpretation of Section 8(e) of the FDI Act may receive persuasive weight, at
    least one of our sister circuits has explained that the FDIC receives no Chevron deference to its interpretation of the
    Act, because several agencies administer that statute. Dodge, 744 F.3d at 155.
    No. 20-4303                                   Calcutt v. FDIC                                            Page 38
    effects resulted “by reason of” of the misconduct, and failing to identify qualifying effects.
    He therefore does not challenge the Board’s finding as to his culpability, so we do not address
    that part of the Removal and Prohibition Order. He also challenges his civil money penalty only
    to the extent that the Board’s reasoning for the penalty overlaps with its analysis supporting the
    Removal and Prohibition Order.
    1.       Misconduct
    As to misconduct, Calcutt maintains that the FDIC Board erred by determining that his
    actions constituted an “unsafe or unsound practice” or a breach of fiduciary duties under the
    statute.15 We disagree.
    a. Unsafe or Unsound Practice
    The FDI Act does not define an “unsafe or unsound practice,” and the term is interpreted
    flexibly. See Seidman v. Off. of Thrift Supervision (Matter of Seidman), 
    37 F.3d 911
    , 926–27
    (3d Cir. 1994).       However, courts have generally treated the phrase as referring to two
    components: “(1) an imprudent act (2) that places an abnormal risk of financial loss or damage
    on a banking institution.” 
    Id. at 932
    ; see also Michael v. FDIC, 
    687 F.3d 337
    , 352 (7th Cir.
    2012) (same); Landry, 
    204 F.3d at 1138
     (identifying imprudent-act and abnormal-financial-risk
    components).
    Calcutt emphasizes the financial-risk component and argues that the Bedrock Transaction
    did not pose an abnormal financial risk to Northwestern Bank. Along with amicus American
    Association of Bank Directors, he characterizes the Bedrock Transaction as a good-faith attempt
    to shore up one of the Bank’s largest lending relationships during the tumult of the Great
    Recession by releasing collateral and extending a loan that amounted to only a fraction of the
    Nielson Entities’ total debt. And even if the $760,000 loan and $600,000 in collateral were
    ultimately not collected, he says, that loss would have been insignificant, considering that the
    Bank’s Tier 1 capital totaled more than $70 million.
    15The FDIC does not argue that Calcutt’s actions violated any explicit statute, regulation, cease-and-desist
    order, or other similar requirement. Cf. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)(i).
    No. 20-4303                           Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 39
    The FDIC responds that the statute does not require a finding of a threat to bank stability
    in order to find “unsafe or unsound” practice, and that “[c]ourts have affirmed prohibition orders
    based on unsafe and unsound practices with a much more limited effect.” Br. of Respondent 46.
    That reading contradicts the analyses of our sister circuits in Seidman, Michael, and Landry, and
    the decisions that the agency cites in support of its interpretation are not convincing. Ulrich v.
    U.S. Department of Treasury is a Ninth Circuit memorandum in which the court concluded that a
    loan “fraught” with financial risk, not just a limited effect, was an unsafe or unsound practice.
    129 F. App’x 386, 390 (9th Cir. 2005). Other decisions that the FDIC cites—Gully v. National
    Credit Union Administration Board, 
    341 F.3d 155
     (2d Cir. 2003), First State Bank of Wayne
    County v. FDIC, 
    770 F.2d 81
     (6th Cir. 1985), and Jameson v. FDIC, 
    931 F.2d 290
     (5th Cir.
    1991)—did not engage with the question of whether financial risk to the institution was
    necessary to demonstrate an unsafe or unsound practice. Still other cited decisions linked a
    finding of unsafe or unsound practices to abnormal financial risks, again controverting the FDIC.
    See Gulf Fed. Sav. & Loan Ass’n of Jefferson Parish v. Fed. Home Loan Bank Bd., 
    651 F.2d 259
    ,
    264 (5th Cir. 1981); Matter of ***, FDIC-83-252b&c, FDIC-84-49b, FDIC-84-50e
    (Consolidated Action), 
    1985 WL 303871
    , at *9 (FDIC Aug. 19, 1985).
    Whether or not we interpret the statute to require a finding of abnormal financial risk,
    however, the FDIC’s finding that Calcutt committed an “unsafe or unsound practice” is
    supported by substantial evidence. First, Calcutt does not address the Board’s finding that he
    “repeatedly concealed material information about the Nielson Loans” from regulators, and that
    such misrepresentations “constitute unsafe or unsound practices.” See De la Fuente, 
    332 F.3d at 1224
     (“Failure to disclose relevant information to a government investigator can constitute an
    unsound banking practice.”); Seidman, 
    37 F.3d at 937
     (stating that “hindering [a financial
    regulatory agency] investigation is an unsafe or unsound practice”).
    Second, the record supports the FDIC Board’s conclusion that Calcutt committed
    additional imprudent acts that posed an abnormal financial risk.        In particular, the Board
    underscored that when the Nielson Entities indicated to the Bank that they would not be able to
    pay off their loans in 2009, Calcutt declined to seek additional financial information and instead
    approved the Bedrock Transaction, which extended further credit to the Entities and renewed the
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 40
    outstanding $4.5 million in loans to Bedrock Holdings. The Board also found that Calcutt’s
    actions violated the Bank’s commercial-loan policy because he approved the Bedrock
    Transaction without either determining that the Nielson Entities had sufficient income to service
    their debt, obtaining personal guarantees on the loans, or receiving approval by a two-thirds
    majority of the board of directors.
    Calcutt responds that such actions do not constitute “unsafe or unsound” practices absent
    abnormal financial risk to the Bank, and that his actions did not present such a risk. His first
    proposition may be correct. See Seidman, 
    37 F.3d at 932
    . However, Calcutt’s actions concerned
    the Bank’s largest lending relationship—the Nielson Entities—which represented approximately
    $38 million in loans and half of the Bank’s Tier 1 capital. The FDIC Board had substantial
    evidence to find that his actions presented a risk in this context, even if it did not explicitly draw
    that connection. See Allentown Mack Sales & Serv., Inc. v. NLRB, 
    522 U.S. 359
    , 377 (1998)
    (explaining that substantial-evidence test “gives the agency the benefit of the doubt, since it
    requires not the degree of evidence which satisfies the court that the requisite fact exists, but
    merely the degree which could satisfy a reasonable factfinder” (emphasis omitted)).               We
    therefore hold that the FDIC Board did not err in determining that Calcutt engaged in unsafe or
    unsound practices.
    b. Breach of Fiduciary Duties
    The FDIC Board also concluded that the misconduct element was satisfied because
    Calcutt breached his fiduciary duties of care and candor. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)(iii).
    These duties are determined by state law rather than federal common law. See Atherton v. FDIC,
    
    519 U.S. 213
    , 226 (1997) (holding that state law rather than federal common law defines
    standard of care for corporate governance); Mickowski v. Visi-Trak Worldwide, LLC, 
    415 F.3d 501
    , 511–12 (6th Cir. 2005). Under Michigan law, bank directors and officers have a fiduciary
    duty to act with the degree of care “that an ordinarily prudent person would exercise under
    similar circumstances in a like position.” 
    Mich. Comp. Laws Ann. § 487.13504
    (1) (2021).
    And in other contexts, Michigan courts have recognized that “[a] fiduciary has an affirmative
    duty to disclose” material facts relating to the fiduciary relationship to a principal. Silberstein v.
    Pro-Golf of Am., Inc., 
    750 N.W.2d 615
    , 624 (Mich. Ct. App. 2008); see also Lumber Vill., Inc. v.
    No. 20-4303                                  Calcutt v. FDIC                                          Page 41
    Siegler, 
    355 N.W.2d 654
    , 694–95 (Mich. Ct. App. 1984) (recognizing that courts may toll the
    statute of limitations for fraudulent concealment actions when a fiduciary fails to inform a
    principal of material facts relating to the claim, because “there is an affirmative duty to disclose
    where the parties are in a fiduciary relationship”).
    On appeal, Calcutt presents three arguments, none availing. First, he contends that he
    cannot have violated his duty of care, because his actions did not create an “undue risk” to the
    Bank. Br. of Petitioner 51 (quoting Kaplan v. Off. of Thrift Supervision, 
    104 F.3d 417
    , 421 (D.C.
    Cir. 1997)). This argument echoes his position that he did not commit an “unsafe or unsound”
    practice with regard to the Bedrock Transaction.16 See Landry, 
    204 F.3d at 1138
     (noting overlap
    in analyses of breach of fiduciary duties and unsafe or unsound practices). And it fails for the
    same reason as his unsafe-or-unsound claim: The record presents substantial evidence to support
    a finding of financial risk.
    Second, Calcutt argues that the Board’s finding that he failed to supervise his
    subordinates (namely Green, Jackson, and other Bank employees) does not indicate that he
    breached his duty of care. It is true that an officer does not necessarily violate a duty of care
    merely because subordinates failed to follow orders. See Doolittle v. Nat’l Credit Union Admin.,
    
    992 F.2d 1531
    , 1537 (11th Cir. 1993); see also Kaplan, 
    104 F.3d at 422
     (explaining that
    director’s approval of plan that ultimately led other officers and directors to “dishonestly short
    circuit the required procedures” was not “remotely foreseeable” and did not “contribut[e] to any
    increased risk” to institution).
    But even if Green, Jackson, and other employees committed many of the actions related
    to the Nielson Entities, Calcutt remains responsible if he knew about their actions and permitted
    them to occur. Failure to supervise subordinates breaches an officer’s duty of care when the
    officer knows about subordinates’ activities or buries his head in the sand. See Hoye v. Meek,
    
    795 F.2d 893
    , 896 (10th Cir. 1986) (holding that bank director and president inadequately
    supervised subordinate, because “[w]here suspicions are aroused, or should be aroused, it is the
    16We   note that the Board also concluded that the December 2010 release of Pillay Collateral violated the
    duty of care, but it did not conclude that the collateral release constituted an unsafe or unsound practice. This
    difference between the two types of misconduct findings does not affect our analysis.
    No. 20-4303                                    Calcutt v. FDIC                                             Page 42
    directors’ duty to make necessary inquiries”). In Doolittle, for instance, the Eleventh Circuit
    clarified that an officer was not responsible for his subordinates’ actions when he gave proper
    orders to them, they failed to follow those orders, and he attempted to take remedial measures,
    but that those circumstances did not present “a case where a fiduciary engaged in imprudent
    lending activities or stood idle and allowed damage to increase.” 
    992 F.2d at 1537
    .17
    The record provides substantial evidence that Calcutt knew about his subordinates’
    activities and permitted them to continue. For instance, in 2008, he was involved in discussions
    with Green and the Nielsons involving the suggestion that they change their methods of
    intercompany loans. Calcutt was aware of the Nielson Entities’ difficulty in paying their loans,
    although he testified that he thought that they were “posturing.” He received correspondence
    directly from the Nielsons. Berden testified that though Calcutt would not attend all meetings,
    Green often sought his approval before proceeding in negotiations. Calcutt had received a memo
    from Green in November 2009 describing the loan to Bedrock Holdings. He was aware of (and
    possibly participated in approving) the sale of Nielson Entity loans to affiliated banks. And
    Green reported directly to Calcutt. There was ample evidence for the FDIC Board to find that he
    had breached his duty of care by failing to supervise subordinates.
    Finally, Calcutt resists the Board’s conclusion that he breached his duty of candor to the
    Bank’s board of directors by failing to timely disclose the information about the status of the
    Nielson Loans and the Bedrock Transaction.                    He asserts that the duty of candor requires
    corporate fiduciaries to “disclose only ‘material information relevant to corporate decisions from
    which [the fiduciary] may derive a personal benefit,’” and that he did not have a personal interest
    in the Bedrock Transaction. Br. of Petitioner 53 (quoting De la Fuente, 
    332 F.3d at 1222
    (alteration in original)).       Even if we accept this framing of the duty, however, the FDIC
    concluded that Calcutt derived a personal benefit from misrepresenting the status of the Nielson
    17Calcutt  and amicus American Association of Bank Directors refer to the business-judgment rule and urge
    us not to fault Calcutt for taking what they characterize as reasonable, good-faith, but ultimately mistaken decisions
    in managing the Bank. Michigan courts have recognized that “[i]nterference with the business judgment of
    corporate directors is not justified by allegations that a different policy could have been followed.” Matter of Est. of
    Butterfield, 
    341 N.W.2d 453
    , 462 (Mich. 1983). However, they also recognize that a breach of fiduciary duty merits
    judicial intervention. 
    Ibid.
     The business-judgment rule thus does not prevent us from considering whether Calcutt
    breached fiduciary duties.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 43
    Loans to regulators, because he received dividends through the Bank’s holding company that
    reflected the Bank’s artificially inflated income. To the extent that substantial evidence supports
    the personal-benefit determination, the finding that Calcutt breached his duty of candor would
    also be sufficiently supported. In addition, even if Calcutt did not receive a personal benefit, the
    support for the Board’s finding that he committed unsafe and unsound practices and violated the
    duty of care means that this error would be harmless. See Sanders, 
    556 U.S. at 407
    .
    In sum, we decline to set aside the Board’s conclusions that Calcutt met the misconduct
    element of the statute.
    2. Effects
    Under the FDI Act, the FDIC must find that “by reason of” Calcutt’s misconduct, one or
    more of the following effects resulted: The Bank “has suffered or will probably suffer financial
    loss or other damage,” its “depositors have been or could be prejudiced,” or Calcutt “has
    received financial gain or other benefit.” 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B). The FDIC Board found
    that three types of harms qualified under this provision: (1) a $30,000 charge-off to the $760,000
    Bedrock Loan that the Bank recorded; (2) $6.443 million in other charge-offs that the Bank
    recorded on other Nielson Loans; and (3) investigative, legal, and auditing expenses that the
    Bank incurred. It also found that Calcutt received a financial benefit, because he received
    dividends from the Bank’s holding company that would have been smaller had he reported the
    condition of the Nielson Loans and not approved the Bedrock Transaction or 2010 release of
    Pillay Collateral.
    Calcutt commences by arguing that the Board erred by failing to read the statute’s “by
    reason of” language to require proximate causation.         In its final decision, the FDIC was
    unwilling to apply a proximate-causation standard, instead stating that “an individual respondent
    need not be the proximate cause of the harm to be held liable under section 8(e).”
    Because Section 8(e) requires that a bank’s loss or potential loss, or a party’s benefit,
    occur “by reason of” the misconduct, it mandates proximate causation.                   
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B). Recently, we observed that “[t]he Supreme Court has repeatedly and explicitly
    held that when Congress uses the phrase ‘by reason of’ in a statute, it intends to require a
    No. 20-4303                           Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 44
    showing of proximate cause.” Crosby v. Twitter, Inc., 
    921 F.3d 617
    , 623 (6th Cir. 2019)
    (quoting Kemper v. Deutsche Bank AG, 
    911 F.3d 383
    , 391 (7th Cir. 2018)). This interpretation
    has occurred in the context of other statutory schemes. See Hemi Grp., LLC v. City of New York,
    
    559 U.S. 1
    , 9 (2010) (civil RICO statute, 
    18 U.S.C. § 1964
    (c)); Holmes v. Sec. Inv. Prot. Corp.,
    
    503 U.S. 258
    , 268 (1992) (same); Crosby, 921 F.3d at 623 (Anti-Terrorism Act, 
    18 U.S.C. § 2333
    ). The FDIC has not offered a reason why the phrase should not have the same meaning
    in Section 8(e), and “[i]n the absence of any statutory definition to the contrary, courts assume
    that Congress adopts the customary meaning of the terms it uses.” United States v. Detroit Med.
    Ctr., 
    833 F.3d 671
    , 674 (6th Cir. 2016) (citing Morissette v. United States, 
    342 U.S. 246
    , 263
    (1952)).
    The FDIC alternatively argues that its formulation—that “by reason of” requires only “a
    causal ‘nexus’ between the misconduct and harm, or that harm was reasonably foreseeable”—is
    consistent with proximate causation. Br. of Respondent 50. This has some appeal; after all, it is
    notoriously difficult for judges to define proximate cause. See Associated Gen. Contractors of
    Cal., Inc. v. Cal. State Council of Carpenters, 
    459 U.S. 519
    , 535–36, 535 n.32 (1983); Crosby,
    921 F.3d at 623–24. We also recognize that in prior adjudications, the FDIC has concluded
    that a reasonably foreseeable loss “satisfies the ‘effects’ requirement.”    Matter of Conover,
    Nos. FDIC-13-214e, FDIC-13-217k, 
    2016 WL 10822038
    , at *22 (FDIC Dec. 14, 2016); see also
    Matter of ***, 
    1985 WL 303871
    , at *114 (declining to characterize the causation standard as
    proximate cause). However, while reasonable foreseeability may be a necessary component of
    proximate causation, it is not sufficient: “substantiality, directness, and foreseeability are all
    relevant in a proximate cause determination,” though these concepts may overlap. Crosby,
    921 F.3d at 624.
    The decisions cited by the FDIC as support for its view are consistent with a proximate-
    causation definition of “by reason of” that incorporates substantiality, directness, and
    foreseeability. In De la Fuente, for example, the Ninth Circuit held that a risk of loss must be
    “reasonably foreseeable,” but did not conclude that reasonable foreseeability alone was enough
    for liability. 
    332 F.3d at 1223
    ; see also United States v. Gamble, 
    709 F.3d 541
    , 549 (6th Cir.
    2013) (holding that harms must be reasonably foreseeable to be proximately caused, but not
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 45
    stating that reasonable foreseeability is sufficient). Haynes v. FDIC, a memorandum, seemingly
    treated “reasonably foreseeable” as interchangeable with “by reason of,” but did so in a summary
    fashion that we do not consider persuasive.        See 664 F. App’x 635, 637 (9th Cir. 2016).
    Although in Landry, the Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit recognized that an
    individual could be liable for the effects of misconduct even if he acted “only indirectly,” the
    court was construing the misconduct element of Section 8(e). 
    204 F.3d at 1139
    ; see 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A) (identifying relevant finding as whether a party has “directly or indirectly”
    committed misconduct). We do not read that decision to say that when it comes to the effects
    inquiry, reasonable foreseeability alone suffices to show causation.
    With the causation standard established, we consider the statutory effects identified by
    the FDIC Board. We conclude that substantial evidence supports the conclusion that some—but
    not all—of the impacts to the Bank are “effects” under Section 8(e) and were proximately caused
    by Calcutt’s misconduct.
    a. The $30,000 Charge-Off on the $760,000 Bedrock Loan
    The charge-off on the loan to Bedrock Holdings, which was part of the Bedrock
    Transaction, is an effect under the statute. Calcutt argues that a charge-off does not reflect actual
    losses but rather estimates possible future loss, but the FDI Act is clear that a loss that a bank
    will “probably suffer” qualifies as an effect, 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B)(i).          Similarly, an
    estimated loss is sufficient. See Dodge, 744 F.3d at 158 (explaining that effects requirement “is
    satisfied by evidence of either potential or actual loss to the financial institution, and the exact
    amount of harm need not be proven”); Pharaon, 
    135 F.3d at 157
     (holding that FDIC Board need
    not “demonstrate the exact amount of harm”). Though Calcutt argues that some charge-offs are
    too small to constitute effects, we need not address this issue, because the FDIC supplemented its
    finding with respect to the $30,000 effect with several other findings of effects. And the record
    indicates that, because Calcutt participated extensively in negotiating and approving the Bedrock
    Transaction, his actions proximately caused the Bedrock Loan charge-off.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 46
    b. Investigative, Auditing, and Legal Expenses
    The FDIC Board also agreed with ALJ McNeil that Calcutt’s misconduct caused the
    Bank to incur expenses by retaining a CPA firm and a legal firm to conduct work relating to the
    regulatory problems with the Nielson Entities relationship. We conclude, however, that such
    professional fees are not “effects” under Section 8(e). Banks regularly engage accounting and
    legal firms as part of their normal business, and we do not see how employing such businesses
    for additional services related to imprudent loans is meaningfully different from their run-of-the-
    mill engagements.
    The FDIC Board reasoned that though legal fees “presumptively are a normal cost of
    doing business,” they can constitute an effect when they “are coupled with other ‘non-neutral
    indicia of loss,’” and that the Bank’s payments to a CPA firm and loan charge-offs constituted
    such other non-neutral indicia. See Matter of Proffitt, FDIC-96-105e, 
    1998 WL 850087
    , at *9
    n.11 (FDIC Oct. 6, 1998) (considering “a [court] judgment of improper and illegal behavior” in a
    related lawsuit to be a non-neutral indicium).       We are unpersuaded by this rationale: If
    professional fees are not a loss unless they are coupled with other “non-neutral indicia of loss,”
    then it may be that the fees do not have any independent significance. The two FDIC decisions
    cited by the Board exemplify this problem, since in both instances banks suffered losses in
    addition to their payment of professional fees. In Matter of Proffitt, the Board explained that “a
    judgment of improper and illegal behavior”—in that context, a court judgment awarding a bank
    to pay damages—plus legal fees could establish a qualifying loss. 
    Id. at *3
    , *9 & n.11. And in
    Matter of Shollenburg, the bank suffered additional losses besides professional fees in order to
    satisfy tax laws that the respondents had violated. See FDIC-00-88e, 
    2003 WL 1986896
    , at *12–
    13 (FDIC Mar. 11, 2003).
    c. $6.443 Million in Other Losses
    Next, the Board found that Calcutt’s actions cost the Bank $6.443 million in losses from
    other loans to the Nielson Entities, and that his approval of the release of approximately
    $1.2 million in Pillay Collateral prevented the Bank from using those funds to recoup part of
    those losses. Apart from asserting that the Board failed to apply a proximate-causation standard,
    No. 20-4303                                   Calcutt v. FDIC                                            Page 47
    Calcutt argues that under that standard, the $6.443 million loss does not count as an effect,
    because it represents a probable future loss from the entire Nielson Entity loan portfolio that
    would have occurred regardless of his actions, and because the $1.2 million in released collateral
    was used to pay off the Nielson Entities’ debts, thereby benefitting the Bank.18
    Only part of the $6.443 million in charge-offs can be described as an effect proximately
    caused by Calcutt’s misconduct. Recall that the Nielson Entities indicated that they were unable
    to pay off debts as early as 2009. The Bank probably would have incurred some loss no matter
    what Calcutt did: Although multiple parties’ actions can proximately cause the same outcome,
    the state of the Bank’s relationship with the Nielson Entities suggests that Calcutt’s actions did
    not substantially or directly contribute to all of its ultimate losses.
    Additionally, the FDIC’s explanation for considering the $1.2 million of released
    collateral in its loss calculation is unconvincing. In its decision, the FDIC Board reasoned that
    had Calcutt not participated in the release of the Pillay Collateral in 2009 and 2010, those funds
    would have been available to pay off debts owed by certain Nielson Entities that were secured by
    that collateral. But that view ignores that the release of Pillay Collateral was used to satisfy
    other Nielson Entity debts, and that the FDIC, in calculating the $6.443 million in losses,
    considered all of the Bank’s loans to the companies together. We fail to see how the agency
    could reasonably consider the interrelatedness of the Nielson Entities in one part of its loss
    calculation and ignore those connections in another. Thus, the mere release of the $1.2 million
    in collateral does not qualify as an effect.
    Nevertheless, there is substantial evidence that part of the $6.443 million in losses was an
    effect of Calcutt’s actions. The record indicates that Calcutt, knowing that the Nielson Entities
    were near default and that they were a large lending relationship, extended credit and renewed
    loans to them while concealing these transactions and the scale of the problem from the Bank’s
    board and from regulators. ALJ McNeil also found that, in 2009, the Nielson Entities had
    proposed loan renewals, forbearance, deeds in lieu of foreclosure, and other mechanisms to
    relieve their obligations. Though Calcutt may have thought that these options would have
    18Calcutt also suggests that because the $6.443 million was recorded in charge-offs, it does not qualify as a
    loss. For the reasons previously discussed, this view fails. See supra at 45.
    No. 20-4303                               Calcutt v. FDIC                                       Page 48
    resulted in “sure losses” to the Bank, the FDIC could have concluded from the record that his
    decision to extend additional loans ultimately exacerbated the problem.
    Additionally, there is substantial evidence that Calcutt’s actions resulted in probable
    future losses to the Bank. Cf. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B)(i) (permitting effects finding where
    bank “will probably suffer financial loss or other damage”); Proffitt v. FDIC, 
    200 F.3d 855
    , 863
    (D.C. Cir. 2000) (noting that “the effect prong can be met by either potential or actual ‘financial
    loss or other damage’”).        Even if there were insufficient evidence that Calcutt’s actions
    surrounding the Bedrock Transaction and 2010 release of Pillay Collateral caused an actual loss,
    his negotiation with the Nielson Entities and approval of loans despite indications that they
    would not be able to repay their debts was a direct, substantial, and foreseeable cause of a
    situation in which the Bank could suffer a potential loss. The record also shows that Calcutt’s
    actions prevented the board and regulators from discovering and mitigating the probable losses
    from these activities. Cf. Seidman, 
    37 F.3d at 937
     (noting, in the context of identifying an unsafe
    or unsound practice, that a chairman of a board of director’s “attempt to obstruct the
    investigation, if continued, would pose an abnormal risk of damage” to the agency). Relying on
    board members’ testimony and contemporaneous board minutes,19 ALJ McNeil found that the
    board did not approve the loan to Bedrock Holdings until several months after the loan had
    already been made. And Miessner testified (despite Calcutt’s theory that she was biased) that, in
    her opinion, misrepresenting the condition of the Bank’s loans with the Nielson Entities exposed
    the Bank to additional risk. In these circumstances, we conclude from the record as a whole that
    Calcutt’s actions proximately caused an actual and potential loss to the Bank—even if the loss
    did not amount to the total of $6.443 million.
    d. Holding Company Dividends
    Finally, the Board concluded that the dividends Calcutt received from the Bank’s holding
    company qualified as a financial benefit that satisfied the “effects” element. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B)(iii) (providing that an effect is present when a party “has received financial gain
    or other benefit by reason of such violation, practice, or breach”). The holding company,
    19ALJ McNeil also found that Calcutt’s testimony regarding the timing of the board’s approval of the
    Bedrock Transaction was not credible.
    No. 20-4303                                  Calcutt v. FDIC                                           Page 49
    Northwestern Bancorp, wholly owned the Bank, and Calcutt held approximately ten percent of
    the shares in the holding company. In 2010 and 2011, the Bank paid dividends to Northwestern
    Bancorp. The holding company, in turn, paid a dividend to its shareholders. Calcutt argues that
    his alleged misconduct cannot have proximately caused a financial benefit, because
    Northwestern Bancorp operated independently from the Bank and had alternative sources of
    income; thus, even if the Bank’s income appeared inflated due to the improper reporting of the
    Nielson Loans, it did not substantially affect the holding company’s payout to shareholders.
    As in the circumstance of the FDIC’s categorization of the $6.443 million in losses, the
    record compels an answer somewhere in between the two parties’ positions. On one hand, the
    FDIC did not point to specific evidence in the record showing that Northwestern Bancorp’s
    dividends with certainty reflected the inflated earnings from the Nielson Entities. It simply
    assumed (and reasonably so) that the dividends paid by the holding company reflected the value
    of the dividends paid by the Bank. On the other hand, Calcutt does not really challenge the
    findings that the Bank paid a dividend to the holding company, nor that the Bank’s dividend
    reflected its inflated representation of the Nielson Loans’ performance. Rather, his position is
    that the holding company still might have paid out dividends from its other sources of income.
    He does not provide evidence (other than his own testimony, which is stated in general terms) 20
    that the holding company had ever paid dividends over and above a reflection of the Bank’s
    perceived performance. Absent such evidence, we are skeptical that the Bank’s earnings did not
    impact its holding company’s dividend payments. On balance, the evidence and common sense
    support the agency’s position as to this effects finding.
    e. Cumulative Effects
    In sum, the support for the effects findings made by the FDIC Board are mixed. Taken
    together, the $30,000 charge-off on the Bedrock Loan, some of the $6.443 million in other losses
    related to the Nielson Entities, and some of the dividend payments that Calcutt received from
    20“Q.  Did the holding company have sufficient capacity to make payments to shareholders regardless of
    whether there were dividends being paid by the Bank to the holding company?
    A. [Calcutt:] Yes, for some years the holding company not only had its own assets that generated some
    income but it had a line of credit so it had capacity to make dividend payments to shareholders. Again, we were, we
    were laughed at a bit in the industry because we had one of the lowest dividend payout ratios that was recorded.”
    No. 20-4303                              Calcutt v. FDIC                                      Page 50
    Northwestern Bancorp occurred “by reason of” his misconduct surrounding loan activities and
    misrepresentations to the Bank’s board of directors and regulators. But the Bank’s auditing and
    legal fees do not qualify as an effect, and Calcutt’s actions may not have proximately caused
    some of the losses and dividend payments.
    These conclusions lead to a further question: If some, but not all, of the FDIC’s effects
    findings are supported, should the Removal and Prohibition Order be remanded? One might
    argue that had the FDIC only considered those effects for which the record presented substantial
    evidence, it would not have thought it appropriate to remove Calcutt from his banking positions
    and prohibit him from participation in the industry. Or, perhaps one might say that the whittled-
    down effects findings are sufficiently minimal to compel us to send the matter back to the agency
    for further findings and proceedings.
    A remand is not necessary, for several reasons. To start, the text of the statute indicates
    that if substantial evidence supports the FDIC’s finding as to one effect out of multiple
    possibilities, the fact that it fails to adequately support its other effects findings does not limit its
    power to issue a removal and prohibition order. Section 8(e)(1)(B) separates the categories of
    permissible effects by the disjunctive term “or”: The agency must find that “by reason of” the
    misconduct,
    (i) such insured depository institution . . . has suffered or will probably suffer
    financial loss or other damage;
    (ii) the interests of the insured depository institution’s depositors have been or
    could be prejudiced; or
    (iii) such party has received financial gain or other benefit . . . .
    
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B) (emphases added). Generally, “terms connected by a disjunctive [are]
    given separate meanings, unless the context dictates otherwise.” Reiter v. Sonotone Corp.,
    
    442 U.S. 330
    , 339 (1979). For example, when a statute lists two activities connected by “or,” the
    natural reading is usually that it applies to either activity. See Encino Motorcars, LLC v.
    Navarro, 
    138 S. Ct. 1134
    , 1141 (2018). Thus, the text of the FDI Act permits the FDIC to
    remove and prohibit a party (assuming that the misconduct and culpability elements are met) as
    long as the evidence supports a finding of one out of any of the options provided by Section
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 51
    8(e)(1)(B). Because we conclude here that substantial evidence supports several of the FDIC’s
    effects findings, the statutory text indicates that the Removal and Prohibition Order should stand.
    Additionally, other circuits have also suggested that when such a finding can be
    supported by one of several alternative bases, courts should deny petitions challenging the
    agency’s order. In Dodge, for example, the District of Columbia Circuit upheld an effects
    finding when substantial evidence supported the Comptroller of the Currency’s conclusions that
    a bank’s depositors could be prejudiced under Section 8(e)(1)(B)(ii) and that the petitioner
    received a financial benefit under Section 8(e)(1)(B)(iii)—even when the court declined to rely
    on the Comptroller’s finding of potential harm to the bank under Section 8(e)(1)(B)(i). 744 F.3d
    at 158. And in De la Fuente, the Ninth Circuit held that the FDIC Board “correctly concluded
    that De La Fuente’s [sic] actions had an impermissible effect because he received financial
    benefit from the transaction and/or because the interests of [the bank’s] depositors were
    prejudiced thereby.” 
    332 F.3d at 1223
     (emphasis added). That is, the court suggested that even
    if the Board had incorrectly concluded that the petitioner received financial benefit, its separate
    finding of prejudice to depositors was sufficient to satisfy the effects element.
    Finally, a remand would be in tension with the substantial-evidence standard of review
    for factual findings. In conducting this review, we consider the whole record, 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2),
    but we must uphold an agency’s decision even if we “would decide the matter differently . . . and
    even if substantial evidence also supports the opposite conclusion.” Gen. Med., P.C., 963 F.3d at
    520 (quoting Cutlip, 
    25 F.3d at 286
    ). As we have explained, the record in this case provides
    substantial evidence to conclude that Calcutt’s actions produced sufficient effects to merit the
    FDIC’s sanction, even if some findings as to other effects were incorrect. We cannot nitpick the
    agency’s factfinding more than that.
    Our dissenting colleague would nonetheless remand the petition to the FDIC, reasoning
    that only that remedy is consistent with the principle that courts may not uphold an agency’s
    order “unless the grounds upon which the agency acted in exercising its powers were those upon
    which its action can be sustained.” SEC v. Chenery Corp., 
    318 U.S. 80
    , 95 (1943). While we do
    not question Chenery, that decision does not mean that a court must remand where the agency
    makes any legal error, especially where substantial evidence amply supports an agency’s
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 52
    findings. Remand is unnecessary where an agency’s “incorrect reasoning was confined to that
    discrete question of law and played no part in its discretionary determination,” and it reaches a
    conclusion that it was bound to reach. United Video, Inc. v. FCC, 
    890 F.2d 1173
    , 1190 (D.C. Cir.
    1989); see also Morgan Stanley Cap. Grp. Inc. v. Pub. Util. Dist. No. 1., 
    554 U.S. 527
    , 545
    (2008) (“That [the agency] provided a different rationale for the necessary result is no cause for
    upsetting its ruling.”). Reading Chenery so broadly as to compel remand in such circumstances
    would result in yet another agency proceeding that amounts to “an idle and useless formality.”
    NLRB v. Wyman-Gordon Co., 
    394 U.S. 759
    , 766 n.6 (1969) (plurality op.). And it would risk
    contradicting the harmless-error rule in courts’ review of agency action. See Sanders, 
    556 U.S. at
    406–07.
    Thus, we do not uphold the FDIC’s order in this case simply by substituting our
    reasoning for the agency’s discretionary determinations. Rather, our inquiry focuses on whether
    substantial evidence supports the FDIC’s factual findings that the charge-offs, dividends, and
    other expenses were “effects” under the statute.          Notwithstanding the agency’s error in
    identifying the appropriate causation standard, and our conclusion that legal expenses do not
    qualify as “effects,” the agency’s findings clear this hurdle. We decline to remand the petition to
    the FDIC.
    3. Sanction
    Finally, Calcutt claims that the FDIC’s order removing him from his position and
    prohibiting him from future banking activities is an abuse of discretion. Courts review a removal
    sanction for abuse of discretion. Grubb v. FDIC, 
    34 F.3d 956
    , 963 (10th Cir. 1994). A sanction
    constitutes an abuse of discretion when it “is unwarranted in law or without justification in fact.”
    
    Ibid.
     (quoting Butz v. Glover Livestock Comm’n Co., 
    411 U.S. 182
    , 185–86 (1973)) (quotation
    marks omitted).    According to Calcutt, his penalty is “plainly excessive” in light of his
    subsequent, misconduct-free work for State Savings Bank, his age, and the harshness of the
    penalty. Br. of Petitioner 63. True, removal and prohibition are “extraordinary sanction[s].”
    De la Fuente, 
    332 F.3d at 1227
    . And, as Calcutt notes, the FDIC could have opted to proceed
    with only a cease-and-desist order or civil monetary penalty. But for the reasons we have
    explained, Section 8(e) clearly permits removal and prohibition for the actions that the FDIC
    No. 20-4303                           Calcutt v. FDIC                               Page 53
    alleges in this case, and the FDIC’s conclusions are well supported. The agency’s sanction
    choice is not an abuse of discretion under these circumstances.
    V. CONCLUSION
    For the reasons above, we deny Calcutt’s petition for review and vacate our stay of the
    FDIC’s Removal and Prohibition Order.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 54
    _________________
    DISSENT
    _________________
    MURPHY, Circuit Judge, dissenting.          After adjudging Harry Calcutt guilty of
    misconduct in the management of a bank, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)
    issued an order that would bar him from working in his profession and fine him $125,000.
    Calcutt challenges this order on constitutional and statutory grounds. My colleagues reject all of
    his claims. I agree with them on his constitutional claims but must part ways on his statutory
    ones.
    Calcutt’s three constitutional claims do not entitle him to relief. He first alleges that
    Congress has unconstitutionally restricted the President’s right to terminate (and so to control)
    the FDIC’s Board of Directors. But his argument rests on a misreading of the Board’s enabling
    statute. It gives the President complete authority to fire most of the Board’s members. Calcutt
    next argues that Congress at least gave one Board member and the FDIC’s administrative law
    judges unconstitutional protections from removal. Even assuming that this claim has merit,
    however, he fails to show why these unconstitutional statutes would entitle him to the relief that
    he seeks—vacatur of the FDIC’s actions in his case as “void.” The Constitution itself requires
    no remedy. And I would read recent Supreme Court precedent to bar his preferred remedy
    because that reading best comports with the historical practices that we should follow until
    Congress says otherwise. Calcutt lastly notes that the first administrative law judge who heard
    his case had not been appointed in a manner that comported with the Constitution’s
    Appointments Clause. The Board agreed and gave him a new hearing before a new judge.
    Calcutt now claims that the Appointments Clause barred this new judge from relying on any
    evidence developed at the initial hearing. But again, nothing in the Constitution required any
    remedy, let alone Calcutt’s expansive one.
    Calcutt’s statutory claims are another matter. The FDIC misread the statute on which it
    relied to sanction him. Of most note, the FDIC cannot bar Calcutt from banking unless it proves
    that his bank will suffer a loss (or that he will receive a benefit) “by reason of” his misconduct.
    
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B). As the Supreme Court has long made clear, the phrase “by reason
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 55
    of” incorporates common-law principles of but-for and proximate cause. Yet the FDIC’s order
    ignored but-for cause and disavowed proximate cause. In fact, the agency held Calcutt liable for
    his bank’s entire loss from underwater loans even though the Great Recession likely would have
    caused the bank to suffer much (if not all) of this loss no matter what he did. Congress has given
    the FDIC “extraordinary power” to regulate private parties with only limited judicial oversight.
    In re Seidman, 
    37 F.3d 911
    , 929 (3d Cir. 1994). After Stern v. Marshall, 
    564 U.S. 462
     (2011),
    one might wonder whether the agency exercises judicial power by adjudicating cases that
    deprive individuals of private rights. At the least, its significant authority should make us
    diligent to ensure that the agency has “turn[ed] square corners when” dealing with the regulated
    community. Niz-Chavez v. Garland, 
    141 S. Ct. 1474
    , 1486 (2021). Because the FDIC did not
    do so in this case, I would remand for it to apply the proper law. I thus respectfully dissent.
    I. Background
    Calcutt served for years as the President and Chairman of Northwestern Bank in Traverse
    City, Michigan. During his tenure, entities controlled by the Nielson family (the “Nielson
    Entities”) became the Bank’s largest borrowers with $38 million in loans. The Nielson Entities
    ran real-estate businesses that struggled during the Great Recession.           They defaulted in
    September 2009. Two months later, the Bank entered into the “Bedrock Transaction” with the
    entities. It issued them another $760,000 loan and released to them $600,000 of funds held as a
    security interest. Yet things did not improve. The Nielson Entities again defaulted in September
    2010. After the Bank released to them another $690,000 in secured funds, the entities defaulted
    a final time in January 2011. The Bank incurred $6.443 million in “charge-offs” (amounts
    unlikely to be collected) from the loans and $30,000 in charge-offs from the Bedrock
    Transaction.
    These events led the FDIC to seek to “remove” Calcutt “from office” and to impose a
    “civil penalty” on him. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1), (i)(2)(B). The first administrative law judge
    who heard his case had been unlawfully appointed, so the FDIC assigned him a new judge. This
    judge found that Calcutt had committed many statutory violations and that the FDIC should bar
    him from banking and fine him $125,000. The FDIC agreed. It held that Calcutt had engaged in
    “unsafe or unsound practice[s]” and committed “breach[es]” of his “fiduciary dut[ies]” mainly in
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 56
    connection with the Bedrock Transaction.          
    Id.
     § 1818(e)(1)(A)(ii)–(iii).    Among other
    misconduct, it found that he had violated the Bank’s lending standards by agreeing to that
    transaction, had hid the transaction’s true nature from the Bank’s board of directors, and, perhaps
    most seriously, had lied to regulators about it. The FDIC also found that the Bank would likely
    suffer “financial loss” and that Calcutt had “received financial gain” “by reason of” this
    misconduct. Id. § 1818(e)(1)(B).
    II. Constitutional Claims
    I agree with my colleagues that Calcutt’s constitutional arguments all fall short. But my
    reasoning rests largely on different grounds.
    A. Restrictions on the President’s Ability to Control the FDIC
    Calcutt first argues that the FDIC’s statutory scheme gives the President constitutionally
    insufficient control over the agency’s exercise of executive power. Why? He assumes that the
    statute creating the FDIC’s five-member Board of Directors bars the President from removing
    most of its members except “for cause.” See 
    12 U.S.C. § 1812
    . This limit, Calcutt reasons,
    impairs the President’s ability to command the “executive Power” and to “take Care that the
    Laws be faithfully executed.” U.S. Const. art. II, § 1, cl. 1; id. § 3. He has a point. The
    Supreme Court recently found unconstitutional similar “for cause” limits on the President’s
    ability to remove the Director of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB). Seila Law
    LLC v. CFPB, 
    140 S. Ct. 2183
    , 2197–2207 (2020). In response, the FDIC “does not dispute
    Calcutt’s assumption” that § 1812 gives the Board these removal protections. Resp. Br. 17 n.7.
    But it argues that they pass muster under Humphrey’s Executor v. United States, 
    295 U.S. 602
    (1935), which upheld similar protections for the Federal Trade Commission (FTC). 
    Id.
     at 626–
    30.
    As an intermediate judge, I find this constitutional question difficult. On the one hand,
    Humphrey’s Executor relied on the FTC’s nonpartisan, multimember structure to uphold the
    provision limiting the President’s ability to fire its commissioners. 
    Id.
     at 624–25. The FDIC
    shares the same structure. Compare 
    12 U.S.C. § 1812
    (a)(1)–(2), with 
    15 U.S.C. § 41
    . And while
    Seila Law may well call Humphrey’s Executor into doubt, lower courts must follow a case that is
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 57
    directly on point even if another decision has undercut it. See Agostini v. Felton, 
    521 U.S. 203
    ,
    237 (1997).
    On the other hand, Humphrey’s Executor may not be directly on point. It also upheld the
    FTC’s removal protections because, as the Court understood the FTC’s duties in 1935, the
    agency undertook “no part of the executive power[.]” 
    295 U.S. at 628
    . The FDIC, by contrast,
    performs core executive functions. Here, it has essentially brought a civil-enforcement suit
    against Calcutt to ban him from banking and impose a hefty fine on him. It thus is executing
    (i.e., carrying into effect) the law barring “unsafe or unsound” banking practices. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)(ii); see Saikrishna Prakash, The Chief Prosecutor, 
    73 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 521
    ,
    537–40 (2005). For executive officers of this kind, “the President’s removal power [has been]
    the rule, not the exception.” Seila Law, 140 S. Ct. at 2206; see Myers v. United States, 
    272 U.S. 52
    , 111–75 (1926); Michael W. McConnell, The President Who Would Not Be King 161–69,
    335–41 (2020).
    But I see no reason to resolve the parties’ constitutional debate because I do not read the
    FDIC’s statutory scheme to implicate it. Rather, I read the statute that creates the FDIC’s Board
    (
    12 U.S.C. § 1812
    ) as giving the President full power to remove all but one of the Board’s five
    members. Since the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, the Board
    has consisted of the Comptroller of the Currency, the CFPB’s Director, and three other
    presidentially appointed members. Pub. L. No. 111-203, § 336(a), 
    124 Stat. 1376
    , 1540 (2010);
    12 U.S.C. 1812(a)(1). All agree that the President may fire the Comptroller for any reason.
    
    12 U.S.C. § 2
    .
    So the President’s ability to control the Board turns on whether he has free rein to fire its
    three appointed members. The statute creating their offices provides: “Each appointed member
    shall be appointed for a term of six years.” 
    Id.
     § 1812(c)(1). This statute says nothing that
    expressly grants for-cause removal protections to these members. Maybe the mere creation of a
    fixed-year term implies that the President may not remove them before their terms end? That
    view raises a host of problems. If read this way, wouldn’t the text create an “absolute” ban on
    removal even if the President has an excellent reason (like fraud)? Parsons v. United States,
    
    167 U.S. 324
    , 343 (1897). How can we read the text to include an implied gloss authorizing
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 58
    some removals (for cause) on top of an implied restriction generally barring them? That is an
    awful lot of implications. And if we were to create this gloss, how do we decide what counts as
    adequate “cause”?     Judicial intuition?    Simply put, we would be legislating rather than
    interpreting if we read § 1812 to bar all but for-cause removals. See Morgan v. Tenn. Valley
    Auth., 
    115 F.2d 990
    , 992–93 (6th Cir. 1940).
    Historical context confirms that § 1812 does not interfere with the President’s ability to
    remove the Board’s appointed members. The provision establishing their six-year term dates to
    the creation of the FDIC in 1933. Banking Act of 1933, Pub. L. No. 73-66, § 8, 
    48 Stat. 162
    ,
    168.    At that time, a “well-approved” “rule of” “statutory construction” directed courts to
    interpret laws that gave the President the power to appoint an executive officer as including the
    power to remove the officer. Myers, 
    272 U.S. at 119
    . So if a law was silent on removal, the
    President could terminate the officer for any reason. See Shurtleff v. United States, 
    189 U.S. 311
    ,
    316 (1903); Parsons, 
    167 U.S. at
    338–39. The Congress that created the FDIC operated against
    this interpretive rule. See Collins v. Yellen, 
    141 S. Ct. 1761
    , 1782 (2021). And while the Court
    has since departed from the rule once, it relied on the “philosophy of Humphrey’s Executor” to
    do so. Wiener v. United States, 
    357 U.S. 349
    , 356 (1958). That philosophy did not exist in
    1933.
    A constitutional concern points the same way.         Before Humphrey’s Executor, the
    Supreme Court had broadly held that Congress could not constitutionally limit the President’s
    power to fire officers who are appointed with the advice and consent of the Senate. See Myers,
    
    272 U.S. at
    109–76. The FDIC was created between Myers and Humphrey’s Executor—when
    the Court treated these removal protections as presumptively invalid. Myers “aroused wide
    interest,” Morgan, 
    115 F.2d at 992
    , so Congress would have known that such protections raised
    “grave” constitutional “doubts,” United States v. Jin Fuey Moy, 
    241 U.S. 394
    , 401 (1916). These
    concerns make it all the more implausible to read a law passed at this time as silently including
    them. See Free Enter. Fund v. Pub. Co. Acct. Oversight Bd., 
    561 U.S. 477
    , 545–46 (2010)
    (Breyer, J., dissenting). In short, the President has unfettered power to fire (and control) most of
    the FDIC’s Board.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 59
    To be sure, both parties seem content to assume that the statute grants the Board
    protections from removal. Cf. United States v. Sineneng-Smith, 
    140 S. Ct. 1575
    , 1579 (2020). In
    a related case, the Supreme Court also assumed that another agency had these protections. Free
    Enter. Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 487
    . Yet parties cannot force courts to accept their stipulations of law.
    See Young v. United States, 
    315 U.S. 257
    , 258–59 (1942). Under basic avoidance principles,
    moreover, our power to address an unraised issue reaches its apex when parties ask us to resolve
    a weighty constitutional question that a statute might not present. Cf. Nw. Austin Mun. Util. Dist.
    No. One v. Holder, 
    557 U.S. 193
    , 205 (2009).           That is especially true here.     Calcutt’s
    constitutional claim, if accepted, would take us right back to a statutory “severability” question:
    Which parts of the statute must we set aside as unconstitutional? See Free Enter. Fund, 
    561 U.S. at
    508–10; John Harrison, Severability, Remedies, and Constitutional Adjudication, 
    83 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 56
    , 88–89 (2014). If the removal protections are imaginary, this question has an
    easy answer. We should disregard those protections. Since we may have to consider this
    statutory issue even if we reach Calcutt’s constitutional claim, we might as well reach it
    immediately.    See William Baude, Severability First Principles, 109 Va. L. Rev. ____
    (forthcoming 2023) (manuscript at 44–45).
    *
    Even so, Calcutt responds, the President and Board believed that § 1812 contained
    removal protections. This belief, Calcutt argues, “shows that the Board enjoyed de facto tenure
    protections while pursuing this enforcement action, causing” him harm. Reply Br. 7 n.1. I agree
    that the executive branch likely read the statute this way. But why would “de facto” protections
    violate the law? Consider a hypothetical: Disagreeing with my reading, the President issues an
    order stating that he will adhere to for-cause removal rules for the Board due to his views of
    § 1812 and the Constitution. If we conclude that this order misreads § 1812 and that the statute
    would be unconstitutional if it imposed such protections, would the order violate the Constitution
    or statute?
    I fail to see why it would violate the Constitution. Like the Supreme Court when
    resolving cases, the President must interpret the Constitution when performing his constitutional
    duties. See Island Creek Coal Co. v. Bryan, 
    937 F.3d 738
    , 753 (6th Cir. 2019) (citing Frank H.
    No. 20-4303                           Calcutt v. FDIC                                 Page 60
    Easterbrook, Presidential Review, 
    40 Case W. Res. L. Rev. 905
     (1990)). Presidents have
    routinely done so. When exercising his pardon power, President Jefferson pardoned those
    convicted under the Sedition Act of 1798 because he believed that the convictions violated the
    First Amendment. See New York Times Co. v. Sullivan, 
    376 U.S. 254
    , 273–76 (1964). When
    exercising his veto power, President Jackson vetoed a bill reauthorizing the national bank
    because he believed that Congress lacked the power to create it. See Easterbrook, supra, at 909–
    10. Like these powers, the removal power belongs to the President. See Seila Law, 140 S. Ct. at
    2197–98. So what constitutional provision would the President offend by self-limiting this
    power? If anything, a court’s intrusion on his authority would raise the concerns. If an injured
    bank customer had sued President Jackson over his national-bank veto, nobody (I hope) would
    claim that a court could enjoin the President’s veto with a citation to McCulloch v. Maryland,
    
    17 U.S. 316
     (1819). See Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1794 (Thomas, J., concurring). We would raise
    identical separation-of-powers problems if we intruded on the President’s lawful exercise of the
    removal power with a citation to Seila Law.
    Nor would this hypothetical executive order violate § 1812.        The statute gives the
    President the power to remove any of the Board’s appointed members for any reason. The
    President thus may retain any member for any reason—whether based on his reading of the
    statute or on the benefits of a civil-service system. In this respect, the statute is not much
    different than a provision that sets the minimum process that an agency must provide. That floor
    does not foreclose the agency from offering additional process. Cf. Vt. Yankee Nuclear Power
    Corp. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc., 
    435 U.S. 519
    , 543–49 (1978); Al-Saka v. Sessions,
    
    904 F.3d 427
    , 432 (6th Cir. 2018); Easterbrook, supra, at 908. So while § 1812 does not impose
    for-cause removal protections on the President, it also does not bar him from imposing those
    protections on himself.
    Now adjust my hypothetical slightly: Before the FDIC acted in Calcutt’s case, “suppose
    that the President had made a public statement expressing displeasure with actions taken by [its
    Board] and had asserted that he would remove [its members] if [§ 1812] did not stand in the
    way.” Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1789. If the President’s (mis)reading of § 1812 does not violate the
    law once he knows that the courts will interpret it differently than he does, why would this
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 61
    reading violate the law before he knows how they will interpret it? I am not sure. Yet I would
    leave open whether courts may vacate agency action as “arbitrary and capricious” under the
    Administrative Procedure Act (APA) if the President’s reading tangibly affected the disputed
    action. 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(A); Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1794 n.7 (Thomas, J., concurring). We need
    not decide this question because the APA tells us to take “due account” “of the rule of prejudicial
    error.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    . Calcutt thus would have needed to show that any mistaken belief about
    the Board’s removal protections harmed him (by, for example, affecting the Board’s makeup).
    See Jicarilla Apache Nation v. U.S. Dep’t of Interior, 
    613 F.3d 1112
    , 1121 (D.C. Cir. 2010).
    He presented no such evidence.
    Calcutt responds that we should remand to the FDIC to allow him to seek discovery over
    whether any de facto protections harmed him. That leads to my final point. An FDIC regulation
    contains an issue-exhaustion rule that requires parties to raise all exceptions to an administrative
    law judge’s decision with the Board. 
    12 C.F.R. § 308.39
    (b). Calcutt concedes that he did not
    raise this facial constitutional challenge with the agency but says that exhaustion mandates
    categorically do not apply to those challenges. I am not so confident. Courts must tread lightly
    before creating implied exceptions to regulatory exhaustion rules (as opposed to judge-made
    ones). Bryan, 937 F.3d at 751–52. Yet I find the FDIC’s specific regulation unclear as to
    whether its text even covers these types of challenges. Cf. id. at 752. I thus would leave this
    question for another day because exhaustion is a nonjurisdictional affirmative defense. See
    Jones v. Bock, 
    549 U.S. 199
    , 211–12 (2007). A rejection of Calcutt’s claim on statutory grounds
    makes the issue unnecessary to decide. Cf. Woodford v. Ngo, 
    548 U.S. 81
    , 101 (2006). Apart
    from exhaustion, however, I see no reason why we should give Calcutt a redo to obtain discovery
    that he did not seek the first time around.
    B. Restrictions on Removal of the CFPB Director and Administrative Law Judge
    Calcutt next challenges two unambiguous removal protections. First, the law that created
    the FDIC’s final Board member—the CFPB Director—gives the Director these protections.
    
    12 U.S.C. § 5491
    (c)(3). As noted, Seila Law found this provision unconstitutional. 140 S. Ct. at
    2201–07. And while the President could control all of the other Board members, Calcutt claims
    that Congress may not create a multimember agency with even one tenure-protected member.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 62
    Second, “dual for-cause limitations” on removal insulated the administrative law judge who
    heard Calcutt’s case from presidential oversight. Free Enter. Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 492
    . The judge
    could be fired only if the Merit System Protection Board found “good cause,” 
    5 U.S.C. § 7521
    (a), and the President could remove that entity’s members only for cause too, 
    id.
    § 1202(d). Calcutt claims that the Constitution bars the judge’s “double insulation” from the
    President. Compare Decker Coal Co. v. Pehringer, 
    8 F.4th 1123
    , 1129–36 (9th Cir. 2021), with
    Fleming v. U.S. Dep’t of Agric., 
    987 F.3d 1093
    , 1113–18 (D.C. Cir. 2021) (Rao, J., concurring in
    part and dissenting in part).
    I see no need to opine on the merits of these claims.            We must distinguish the
    constitutional questions that Calcutt raises (do the removal statutes violate the Constitution?)
    from a separate remedies question (if so, do these defects entitle him to his requested relief?).
    As his proposed remedy, Calcutt asks us to vacate the FDIC’s order as “void.” But he fails to
    identify the source of law that requires (or permits) courts to treat the FDIC’s past actions as
    void because potentially unconstitutional statutes attempted to insulate two of the FDIC’s
    officers from the President’s removal power. And my review of the relevant legal authorities
    leads me to conclude that Calcutt could not obtain this relief even if he successfully established
    the statutes’ unconstitutionality.
    1
    Because Calcutt seeks relief for a constitutional violation, the Constitution provides the
    place to start on this remedies question.         But it says almost nothing about remedies.
    Cf. Hernandez v. Mesa, 
    140 S. Ct. 735
    , 741–43 (2020); Armstrong v. Exceptional Child Ctr.,
    Inc., 
    575 U.S. 320
    , 324–27 (2015). Except for a few provisions like the requirement to pay “just
    compensation” for a taking, see Knick v. Township of Scott, 
    139 S. Ct. 2162
    , 2171 (2019), the
    Constitution sets only limits on government conduct without prescribing specific relief for
    violations, see Alfred Hill, Constitutional Remedies, 69 Colum. L. Rev 1109, 1118 (1969). One
    thus will search Article II in vain for an explicit constitutional remedy that applies to an invalid
    removal provision.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 63
    Where else should we look? The founders enacted the Constitution against the backdrop
    of a preexisting legal system with preexisting causes of action and remedies. See 
    id.
     at 1131–32.
    Before the founding, for example, this system often allowed equity courts to issue injunctions to
    stop “illegal executive action[.]” Armstrong, 575 U.S. at 327; Ex parte Young, 
    209 U.S. 123
    ,
    150–51 (1908). The Supreme Court has held that we may use these preexisting “judge-made”
    remedies to redress constitutional wrongs unless Congress displaces them. Armstrong, 575 U.S.
    at 327–28.
    But courts should not take this allowance too far. The Constitution does not give us
    freewheeling power to adopt federal common-law remedies based on our views of wise policy.
    See Hernandez, 140 S. Ct. at 741–42 (citing Erie R.R. Co. v. Tompkins, 
    304 U.S. 64
    , 78 (1938)).
    And the Court “disfavor[s]” remedies that are rooted in legislative-like choices about the best
    way to deter illegal acts. Ziglar v. Abbasi, 
    137 S. Ct. 1843
    , 1857 (2017) (citation omitted).
    This dichotomy points the way here. We lack an inherent power to treat the FDIC’s
    actions as “void” because we think it would be a good idea. See Hernandez, 140 S. Ct. at 741–
    42. We instead must look to the causes of action and remedies that traditionally applied to
    claims like Calcutt’s—that a statutory provision related to an office was illegal and that this
    defect rendered the officer’s actions void. When courts traditionally chose remedies for this sort
    of claim, they distinguished between two types of officers: a “de facto officer” in a lawful
    office (whose actions were enforceable) and a “mere usurper” in an unlawful one (whose
    actions were void). Albert Constantineau, A Treatise on the De Facto Officer Doctrine §§ 5, 34,
    at 8–10, 52–53 (1910).
    De Facto Officer in Lawful Office. For centuries, parties have alleged that an officer was
    unlawfully holding (and performing the duties of) an office. To give an example at the time of
    the founding, a party claimed that a sheriff could not hold that office because the sheriff had
    not lived in the county as long as the law required. State v. Anderson, 
    1 N.J.L. 318
    , 324–28
    (N.J. 1795).
    English courts channeled these claims into a specific writ (“quo warranto”) with a
    specific remedy (prospectively ousting the officer). See 3 William Blackstone, Commentaries
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 64
    *262–64; 2 Edward Coke, Institutes of the Laws of England 282, 494–99 (1642). American
    courts followed suit. Constantineau, supra, § 451, at 635 n.1; State v. Parkhurst, 
    9 N.J.L. 427
    ,
    437–38 (N.J. 1802). Three aspects of the quo warranto action deserve mention. For one, invalid
    officers caused public harms, so the government itself typically needed to sue them. See Wallace
    v. Anderson, 
    18 U.S. 291
    , 292 (1820). Yet private parties could sue on the government’s behalf
    if they showed a unique interest. See Newman v. United States ex rel. Frizzell, 
    238 U.S. 537
    ,
    549–51 (1915). For a second, the remedy was exclusive. Constantineau, supra, § 451, at 635.
    A party disputing an officer’s authority could not sue for an injunction “to restrain the exercise of
    official functions[.]” Floyd R. Mecham, A Treatise on the Law of Public Offices and Officers
    § 478, at 307 (1890). For a third, the remedy exists today. See 
    D.C. Code § 16-3503
    . Parties
    may ask the Attorney General to seek this relief or request leave of court to seek it themselves—
    a process that may look “cumbersome” to modern eyes. Andrade v. Lauer, 
    729 F.2d 1475
    ,
    1497–98 (D.C. Cir. 1984) (Wright, J.).
    Yet the process has always looked cumbersome. Rather than file a direct quo warranto
    suit to oust invalid officers, parties harmed by the officers’ actions have tried to collaterally
    attack their qualifications in suits involving the actions. 
    Id. at 1496
    . Since 1431, English courts
    have rebuffed these attacks under the “de facto officer doctrine.” Constantineau, supra, § 5, at
    8–10 (citing The Abbé de Fontaine, 1431 Y.B. 9 Hen. VI, fol. 32, pl. 3 (Eng.)); Clifford L.
    Pannam, Unconstitutional Statutes and De Facto Officers, 2 Fed. L. Rev. 37, 39–42 (1966).
    That doctrine treats the past actions of an officer with a colorable claim to office as valid whether
    or not the officer met all conditions to hold the office. Constantineau, supra, § 1, at 3–4.
    English courts introduced it “into the law as a matter of policy and necessity, to protect the
    interests of the public and individuals, where those interests were involved in the official acts of
    persons exercising the duties of an office, without being lawful officers.” State v. Carroll, 
    38 Conn. 449
    , 467 (1871).
    American courts likewise adhered to the de facto officer doctrine as a corollary to the
    exclusive quo warranto remedy. See Cocke v. Halsey, 
    41 U.S. 71
    , 81–88 (1842); Taylor v.
    Skrine, 
    5 S.C.L. 516
    , 516–17 (S.C. 1815); Fowler v. Bebee, 
    9 Mass. 231
    , 234–35 (1812); People
    ex rel. Bush v. Collins, 
    7 Johns. 549
    , 554 (N.Y. 1811) (per curiam). Notably, these courts upheld
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 65
    the actions of invalid officers who did not meet constitutional conditions on their offices.
    An officer might not have taken an oath. Cf. Bucknam v. Ruggles, 
    15 Mass. 180
    , 182–83 (1818)
    (per curiam). Or the officer might have been appointed in an illegal way. Cf. Ex parte Ward,
    
    173 U.S. 452
    , 454 (1899). Or the officer might have flunked an eligibility requirement. Perhaps
    the officer was too young. Cf. Blackburn v. State, 
    40 Tenn. 690
    , 690–91 (1859). Or maybe the
    officer had been in the Congress that increased the office’s salary before taking office. Cf. U.S.
    Const. art. I, § 6, cl. 2; William Baude, The Unconstitutionality of Justice Black, 
    98 Tex. L. Rev. 327
     (2019); In re Griffin, 
    11 F. Cas. 7
    , 27 (C.C.D. Va. 1869) (No. 5,815). The same rules
    applied even if the officer held the office by reason of an unconstitutional statute.            See
    Constantineau, supra, §§ 192–96, at 264–70. An early decision thus upheld the acts of an officer
    who had been appointed by the governor under a statute authorizing this appointment, even
    though the state constitution had required the legislature to elect the officer. See Taylor, 5 S.C.L.
    at 516–17; Carroll, 38 Conn. at 474; see also State v. McMartin, 
    43 N.W. 572
    , 572 (Minn.
    1889); Ex Parte Strang, 
    21 Ohio St. 610
    , 615–18 (1871); cf. Buckley v. Valeo, 
    424 U.S. 1
    , 142
    (1976) (per curiam).
    Usurper in Unlawful Office. Other times, parties have alleged that a generic office could
    not exist because it had been assigned “sovereign functions” that it could not possess. Mecham,
    supra, § 4, at 5. In one case, for example, a party alleged that a legislatively created “court”
    could not perform judicial duties because those duties had been vested in a wrongly abolished
    life-tenured court. Hildreth’s Heirs v. McIntire’s Devisee, 
    24 Ky. 206
    , 207–08 (1829); Jeffrey S.
    Sutton, Who Decides? States as Laboratories of Constitutional Experimentation 76–80 (2022).
    Courts granted much broader relief for this type of claim. Parties affected by an illegal
    office did not need to sue in quo warranto to dispute the officeholder’s power to perform the
    challenged function. Parties instead could dispute the officer’s conduct “in any kind” of suit.
    Walcott v. Wells, 
    24 P. 367
    , 370 (Nev. 1890); Mecham, supra, §§ 324–26, at 216–18. And the
    opposing party could not defend the officer’s past acts using the de facto officer doctrine.
    Constantineau, supra §§ 34–36, at 51–55. The officer instead was “merely a usurper, to whose
    acts no validity can be attached[.]” Norton v. Shelby County, 
    118 U.S. 425
    , 449 (1886).
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                      Page 66
    This rule extended to constitutional defects. The Supreme Court may have followed it as
    early as United States v. Yale Todd (U.S. 1794). United States v. Ferreira, 
    54 U.S. 40
    , 52–53
    (1851) (note by Taney, C.J.). This unreported case addressed a law allowing pensions for
    disabled Revolutionary War veterans. The law ordered circuit courts to determine whether
    applicants were disabled and to send their findings to the Secretary of War. Circuit judges
    (including Supreme Court Justices) found that the law unconstitutionally gave courts executive
    power by making them the Secretary’s administrators. Hayburn’s Case, 
    2 U.S. 408
    , 410 n.*
    (1792). Given the law’s benevolent goals, though, some judges awarded pensions by claiming to
    act as “commissioners.” See Wilfred J. Ritz, United States v. Yale Todd (U.S. 1794), 
    15 Wash. & Lee L. Rev. 220
    , 228–29 (1958). Congress ordered the Attorney General to seek Supreme
    Court review of pensions granted by judges “styling themselves commissioners.” Act of Feb.
    28, 1793, 
    1 Stat. 324
    , 325. In Yale Todd’s case, the Court required him to return the funds. Ritz,
    supra, at 228–30. As others have noted, the Court may well have found the judges’ actions void
    because they unconstitutionally undertook executive functions. Ferreira, 54 U.S. at 53 (note by
    Taney, C.J.); Keith E. Whittington, Judicial Review of Congress before the Civil War, 
    97 Geo. L.J. 1257
    , 1270–74 (2009).
    Many decisions followed this remedial approach for claims that a legislative body had
    granted functions to an office that it could not lawfully possess. See Town of Decorah v. Bullis,
    
    25 Iowa 12
    , 18–19 (1868); Hildreth’s Heirs, 24 Ky. at 207–08; G. L. Monteiro, Annotation, De
    Jure Office as Condition of De Facto Officer, 
    99 A.L.R. 294
     § III(a) (1935), Westlaw (database
    updated 2022). When, for example, a legislature assigned local-government functions to a board
    of commissioners that the state constitution vested in justices of the peace, the Supreme Court
    treated the board’s actions as void. Norton, 
    118 U.S. at
    441–49. It refused to apply the de facto
    officer doctrine because that doctrine required a valid (“de jure”) office. 
    Id.
     at 444–45.
    The Supreme Court’s modern cases also treat an officer’s actions as void if the generic
    office could “not lawfully possess” the power to take them. Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1788. The
    Court thus found invalid a bankruptcy judge’s decision in a suit that an Article III court needed
    to resolve. See Stern v. Marshall, 
    564 U.S. 462
    , 503 (2011). And a plurality rejected the de
    facto officer doctrine when a party claimed that Congress assigned to Article I judges a duty
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 67
    (sitting on circuit courts) that Article III judges must perform. See Glidden Co. v. Zdanok, 
    370 U.S. 530
    , 535–37 (1962) (plurality opinion); cf. Bowsher v. Synar, 
    478 U.S. 714
    , 732 (1986);
    Young v. United States ex rel. Vuitton et Fils S.A., 
    481 U.S. 787
    , 815 (1987) (Scalia, J.,
    concurring in the judgment).
    2
    This “long history of judicial review” has relevance for Calcutt’s request that we vacate
    the FDIC’s order in his case because invalid removal protections shielded two of its officers.
    Armstrong, 575 U.S. at 327. To begin with, the history refutes the theory that the Constitution of
    its own force compels courts to treat as “void” any action taken by officers whose exercise of an
    office does not comport with a constitutional command. That view would treat the de facto
    officer doctrine itself as unconstitutional. Yet it formed part of the legal backdrop against which
    the founders enacted the Constitution. Near the founding, judges described the doctrine as “a
    well settled principle of law,” Bush, 7 Johns. at 554, or “too well established to admit of a
    doubt,” Taylor, 5 S.C.L. at 517. Nothing in the Constitution can be read to do away with it.
    This history also highlights the key inquiry for deciding whether courts may vacate an
    officer’s actions as a “judge-made remedy” when a statute unconstitutionally limits the
    President’s removal authority. Armstrong, 575 U.S. at 327. Does the unconstitutional removal
    provision show that Congress vested “sovereign functions” in an invalid office that cannot
    possess them? Mecham, supra, § 4, at 5; Norton, 
    118 U.S. at 449
    . If so, courts should treat the
    officer’s actions as void wherever they arise. Or is the removal provision “distinct from the
    provisions creating the . . . office” such that the office itself is valid “even assuming that the
    [removal provision] is” not? McMartin, 43 N.W. at 572; Carroll, 38 Conn. at 449. If so, courts
    should enforce the officer’s acts in suits involving third parties (in contrast to suits between the
    government and the officer).
    Unfortunately for Calcutt, his claim falls on the wrong side of this divide. He does not
    even argue that the two executive officers (the CFPB Director and administrative law judge) sat
    in offices that constitutionally “could not exist” (because, for example, the Constitution vested
    their duties in another branch). Ashley v. Bd. of Supervisors of Presque Isle Cnty., 
    60 F. 55
    , 65
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                     Page 68
    (6th Cir. 1893). Indeed, his argument’s very premise—that Congress has illegally insulated the
    officers from the President—assumes that they perform executive functions. Cf. Seila Law,
    140 S. Ct. at 2209. So I would treat the constitutional “condition” in this case (that an officer be
    accountable to the President) like other constitutional conditions the violation of which does not
    void an officer’s acts. The condition is not much different than, say, a condition that an officer
    be of a certain age, see Blackburn, 40 Tenn. at 690–91, or be elected rather than appointed, see
    Constantineau, supra, § 192, at 264–65. If statutes departing from these mandates did not render
    an officer’s actions void, I fail to see why an unconstitutional removal provision would. Under
    traditional remedial principles, then, Calcutt could not obtain the relief that he seeks in this case.
    The “lack of historical precedent” to attack removal provisions in a suit like Calcutt’s
    reinforces the conclusion that the provisions did not traditionally render an officer’s actions void.
    Seila Law, 140 S. Ct. at 2201 (citation omitted). If any private party could collaterally attack
    removal provisions in any suit implicating an officer’s acts, one would expect to see many of
    these suits. After all, Congress began to enact constitutionally dubious removal provisions
    shortly after the Civil War during President Johnson’s administration. See Myers, 
    272 U.S. at
    166–73. Yet Calcutt cites no historical example in which courts evaluated removal provisions in
    this type of litigation. So constitutional questions about the provisions lingered for decades. 
    Id. at 173
    .
    Challenges to the validity of removal provisions instead arose in employment disputes.
    See Humphrey’s Executor, 
    295 U.S. at
    618–19; Myers, 
    272 U.S. at 106
    ; cf. Shurtleff, 
    189 U.S. at
    311–12; Reagan v. United States, 
    182 U.S. 419
    , 424 (1901); Ex parte Hennen, 
    38 U.S. 230
    , 256–
    57 (1839). A discharged officer would sue to recover a salary (or seek reinstatement) on the
    ground that the termination violated a tenure-protection statute. Myers, 
    272 U.S. at 106
    . The
    government would respond that the statute could not restrict the President’s power. 
    Id.
     This
    different kind of suit required courts to resolve the constitutional question. Courts “almost
    universally recognized” that the de facto officer doctrine did not apply because the suit was
    between the government and the officer (not a third party) and because only valid officers could
    receive salaries. Constantineau, supra, § 236, at 331; 2 James Kent, Commentaries on American
    Law 355 n.2 (11th ed. 1867).
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 69
    Modern precedent confirms my conclusion. The Supreme Court’s recent cases have all
    held that unconstitutional removal provisions do not render the office to which they attach
    invalid or require courts to find actions taken by the officers void. See Collins, 141 S. Ct. at
    1787–89; Seila Law, 140 S. Ct. at 2207–11; Free Enter. Fund, 
    561 U.S. at
    508–10. Take Free
    Enterprise Fund. There, accountants under investigation by the Public Company Accounting
    Oversight Board filed an Ex Parte Young suit seeking to enjoin all of the Board’s actions as void
    because of its removal protections. See 
    561 U.S. at 487
    , 491 n.2, 508. The Court agreed that
    various removal provisions unconstitutionally intruded on the President’s authority. 
    Id.
     at 492–
    98. But it refused to treat the Board’s actions as void. 
    Id.
     at 508–10. It held that the Board
    could perform the executive functions assigned to it despite the invalid removal provisions
    because they were “severable from the remainder of the statute.” 
    Id. at 508
    . The Court analyzed
    this issue in terms of “severability.” See 
    id. at 509
    . But it could just as well have reasoned that
    the unconstitutional statutes did not render the Board’s actions void in third-party suits and so
    did not entitle the accountants to their requested remedy. Cf. McMartin, 43 N.W. at 572;
    Harrison, supra, at 73–75.
    Seila Law fits a similar mold. The CFPB in that case issued a civil investigative demand
    seeking documents from a law firm. 140 S. Ct. at 2194. The firm refused to comply, so the
    CFPB filed a petition to enforce its demand. Id. The district court rejected the firm’s request to
    deny the CFPB’s petition on the ground that its Director’s removal protections rendered all
    CFPB actions void. Id. After agreeing that the protections were unconstitutional, the controlling
    Supreme Court opinion again held that the invalid provisions were severable and did not render
    all CFPB actions void. Id. at 2208–11 (opinion of Roberts, C.J.). Admittedly, the opinion did
    not simply reject the law firm’s remedy and affirm the enforcement of the CFPB’s demand.
    Rather, it remanded for the lower courts to decide whether the demand had been “validly
    ratified” by a Director accountable to the President. Id. at 2211. This resolution might have
    implied that all CFPB actions (including the investigative demand) had been void prior to the
    Court’s severance “remedy.” Id. at 2208. But the Court has since clarified that Seila Law did
    not hold that the CFPB’s prior actions were invalid and instead had left all remedy-related issues
    for the lower courts. See Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1788.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 70
    Most recently in Collins, the Court expressly held that unconstitutional removal
    provisions do not render an officer’s past actions void in suits by third parties. Headed by a
    director with removal protections, the agency in Collins served as the conservator to two large
    mortgage-financing companies. 141 S. Ct. at 1771–72. This agency entered into agreements
    with the Department of Treasury requiring the companies to pay large dividends to the Treasury.
    Id. at 1772–74.    The companies’ shareholders sued to compel the Treasury to return the
    dividends on the ground that the director’s removal protections were unconstitutional and that
    they voided the agency’s past acts (including the challenged agreements). Id. at 1775. Although
    the Court agreed that the removal protections were unconstitutional, id. at 1783–87, it rejected
    the broad remedy, id. at 1787–89. The Court found “no reason to regard any of the actions taken
    by the” agency “as void” simply because its head had been protected by invalid removal
    provisions. Id. at 1787.
    All told, under traditional remedial rules, unconstitutional removal provisions do not
    render the offices to which they attach invalid and so do not allow courts to vacate the actions of
    officers as void in suits by third parties. This tradition compels me to reject Calcutt’s proposed
    remedy.
    3
    I end with two disclaimers about things I need not decide. Disclaimer One: Congress
    may generally displace judge-made remedial principles.         Armstrong, 575 U.S. at 327–29.
    Congress, for example, has sometimes restricted a court’s power to grant Ex Parte Young’s
    injunctive relief for violations of federal law. See id. And Bowsher teaches that Congress may
    adjust the relief for structural constitutional claims too. There, the Court followed the statutory
    remedy once it found that Congress had illegally entrusted a legislative officer with executive
    duties. 
    478 U.S. at
    734–35. Congress thus may permit courts to vacate actions taken by officers
    subject to unconstitutional removal protections even if traditional judge-made remedial limits
    would foreclose relief.
    Has Congress done so here? The FDIC’s statute incorporates the APA. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (h)(2). It orders a court to “hold unlawful and set aside agency action” that is “contrary to
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 71
    constitutional right, power, privilege, or immunity[.]” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(B). Perhaps this text
    could be read to allow courts to depart from traditional limits and vacate agency “actions” if a
    law has structured the agency in a way that is “contrary to constitutional right” or “power.” Id.;
    cf. Collins, 141 S. Ct. at 1795 (Gorsuch, J., concurring in part). That the Constitution’s structural
    principles exist to protect individual liberty could reinforce this reading that a structural problem
    is “contrary to constitutional right” within the meaning of the APA. See Bond v. United States,
    
    564 U.S. 211
    , 220–24 (2011).
    In most structural constitutional cases, however, a private party claims that the challenged
    action itself is “contrary to constitutional right.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(B). So parties routinely
    allege that a prosecution violates the Constitution because the relevant law reaches conduct that
    Congress may not proscribe. See, e.g., Bond, 
    564 U.S. at 224
    . Yet, as I have explained, an
    unconstitutional removal statute for an office would not necessarily render the officer’s “actions”
    void and so would not necessarily render those actions “contrary to constitutional right.”
    
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    (2)(B). Perhaps the APA’s text is thus best read to incorporate—not depart
    from—traditional remedial limits. Cf. 
    id.
     § 702; Tom C. Clark, Att’y Gen.’s Manual on the
    Admin. Proc. Act 108 (1947).
    And even if the APA expanded the available relief, recall that it requires courts to take
    “due account” “of the rule of prejudicial error.” 
    5 U.S.C. § 706
    . The Court has read this text to
    adopt the harmless-error principles that “ordinarily apply in civil cases.” Shinseki v. Sanders,
    
    556 U.S. 396
    , 406 (2009). Under those principles, constitutional errors can be harmless. See
    O’Neal v. McAninch, 
    513 U.S. 432
    , 440 (1995). Although Collins did not cite the APA, this
    harmless-error provision might be one way to understand its suggestion that third parties could
    seek relief for unconstitutional removal provisions if they showed that the provisions harmed
    them (that is, if they showed that the error was not harmless). 141 S. Ct. at 1788–89. At day’s
    end, I would leave these statutory questions open. The parties did not address the APA’s scope
    and focused only on whether the removal provisions rendered the FDIC’s order
    unconstitutionally void. They did not.
    Disclaimer Two: The parties assume that the FDIC performs only executive functions.
    Our resolution should not be taken to have impliedly adopted that premise. The FDIC did not
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 72
    just prosecute this action. It also adjudicated the action—finding Calcutt guilty and imposing a
    punishment on him in the form of an end to his career and a $125,000 penalty. Once an Article
    III court finally enters the picture, moreover, it may review the FDIC’s factual findings only
    under a deferential substantial-evidence test—a test that has been called more deferential than
    the one governing our review of a district court’s factual findings. See Dickinson v. Zurko,
    
    527 U.S. 150
    , 153 (1999).
    Yet both Article III and the Due Process Clause generally require the government to
    follow common-law procedure (including, fundamentally, the use of a “court”) when seeking to
    deprive people of their private rights to property or liberty. See Stern, 
    564 U.S. at
    482–84; Caleb
    Nelson, Adjudication in the Political Branches, 
    107 Colum. L. Rev. 559
    , 569–70 (2007). At first
    blush, one might think that the FDIC has sought to deprive Calcutt of his “core private rights” to
    both. B&B Hardware, Inc. v. Hargis Indus., Inc., 
    575 U.S. 138
    , 171 (2015) (Thomas, J.,
    dissenting). According to Blackstone, Calcutt had a “property” interest in the thousands of
    dollars that the government seeks to take. See 1 Blackstone, supra, at *134–35. According to
    Coke, he had a “liberty” interest in continuing in his profession. See 2 Coke, supra, at 47. So
    perhaps the FDIC has undertaken judicial functions here—functions that the Constitution vests in
    courts. See Stern, 
    564 U.S. at
    482–84. If the FDIC needed to file suit, moreover, the filing
    would have triggered the Seventh Amendment’s right to a jury, which Justice Brennan made
    clear applies to suits seeking civil penalties. See Tull v. United States, 
    481 U.S. 412
    , 422–25
    (1987).
    The government traditionally has responded to this call for more “process” with the
    defense that its action seeks to vindicate “public rights,” rights that need not be litigated in a
    court with a jury. See Oil States Energy Servs., LLC v. Greene’s Energy Grp., LLC, 
    138 S. Ct. 1365
    , 1373 (2018); Atlas Roofing Co. v. Occupational Safety & Health Rev. Comm’n, 
    430 U.S. 442
    , 450–51 (1977). And maybe Calcutt did not raise this argument here because a healthy
    amount of caselaw has accepted that defense in the banking context. See Cavallari v. Off. of
    Comptroller of Currency, 
    57 F.3d 137
    , 145 (2d Cir. 1995); Simpson v. Off. of Thrift Supervision,
    
    29 F.3d 1418
    , 1422–24 (9th Cir. 1994).          Yet this precedent predates the Court’s recent
    instructions in cases like Stern, which held that the adjudication of a state tort claim required an
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                 Page 73
    Article III court. See 564 U.S. at 487–501. And while Stern did not involve an agency, the
    Court “recognize[d]” that its cases may not provide “concrete guidance” on the scope of the
    public-rights doctrine in the administrative context. Id. at 494. Several Justices have also
    expressed concern with extending the doctrine too far. See Oil States, 
    138 S. Ct. at
    1381–85
    (Gorsuch, J., joined by Roberts, C.J., dissenting); B & B Hardware, 575 U.S. at 170–74
    (Thomas, J., joined by Scalia, J., dissenting).
    There must be some limit to the government’s ability to dissolve the Constitution’s usual
    separation-of-powers and due-process protections by waving a nebulous “public rights” flag at a
    court. When the government indicts a person for a crime, it also vindicates “public rights” that
    belong to the community. Spokeo v. Robins, 
    578 U.S. 330
    , 345 (2016) (Thomas, J., concurring)
    (citing Ann Woolhandler & Caleb Nelson, Does History Defeat Standing Doctrine?, 
    102 Mich. L. Rev. 689
    , 695–700 (2004)). But the government cannot send people to prison using a hearing
    room rather than a court room or an administrative officer rather than a jury of peers. N. Pipeline
    Constr. Co. v. Marathon Pipe Line Co., 
    458 U.S. 50
    , 70 n.24 (1982) (plurality opinion). Why
    should this case be different simply because Calcutt must pay a civil penalty rather than a
    criminal fine? Cf. Jarkesy v. SEC, __ F.4th __, 
    2022 WL 1563613
    , at *2–7 (5th Cir. May 18,
    2022). The FDIC one day must provide answers to these questions in a case that does not
    assume them.
    C. Remedy for Appointments Clause Violation
    Calcutt lastly challenges the FDIC’s remedy for an undisputed constitutional wrong. The
    Appointments Clause sets the ground rules for the appointment of officers. U.S. Const. art. II,
    § 2, cl. 2. It allows Congress to vest the power to appoint inferior officers in “the President,”
    “Courts of Law,” or “Heads of Departments.” Id. In Lucia v. SEC, 
    138 S. Ct. 2044
     (2018), the
    Court held that the SEC’s administrative law judges are inferior officers who must be appointed
    by the President or the Commission.         
    Id.
     at 2051–55. The parties agree that the FDIC’s
    administrative law judges are likewise inferior officers, but Calcutt litigated his first hearing
    before a judge who had not been appointed by the President or FDIC. The FDIC thus granted
    Calcutt a “new” hearing before a different, lawfully appointed judge—the remedy that Lucia
    ordered. See 
    id. at 2055
    . Calcutt argues that this remedy still fell short because the FDIC
    No. 20-4303                           Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 74
    allowed the second judge to use records, stipulations, and orders from the invalid judge’s first
    hearing. According to him, the Appointments Clause required the second judge to ignore
    everything that occurred before.
    To decide what Lucia meant by its “new hearing” remedy, my colleagues engage in a
    cost-benefit balance that resembles the Supreme Court’s test for whether a court should suppress
    evidence in a criminal trial under the Fourth Amendment’s “exclusionary rule.” Davis v. United
    States, 
    564 U.S. 229
    , 236–38 (2011). They point out that Calcutt’s remedy would impose heavy
    administrative costs (because it would require inefficient, duplicative processes). They add that
    it would offer few private benefits (because it is unnecessary to insulate the valid judge’s
    decision from the first hearing’s “taint”).   Based on this prudential balancing, they reject
    Calcutt’s claim that the second judge had to ignore items from the first hearing. Their balance
    seems reasonable enough. But I would reject Calcutt’s view of Lucia based on structural
    grounds rooted in the best reading of the Appointments Clause and the Court’s current approach
    to judge-made remedies.
    At the outset, I do not mean to critique my colleagues for engaging in a cost-benefit
    inquiry. The Supreme Court’s instructions in Appointments Clause cases may well be read to
    contemplate it. See Lucia, 
    138 S. Ct. at
    2055 & nn.5–6; Ryder v. United States, 
    515 U.S. 177
    ,
    182–83 (1995). In Ryder, a court-martialed member of the Coast Guard had his conviction
    upheld by a panel that included judges whose appointments violated the Appointments Clause.
    
    515 U.S. at
    179–80. The Court of Military Appeals affirmed the panel’s conviction under the de
    facto officer doctrine. 
    Id. at 180
    . The Supreme Court reversed and refused to apply this
    doctrine. It held that “one who makes a timely challenge to the constitutional validity of the
    appointment of an officer who adjudicates his case is entitled to a decision on the merits of the
    question and whatever relief may be appropriate if a violation indeed occurred.” 
    Id.
     at 182–83.
    Did Ryder look to the “original meaning” of the Appointments Clause to adopt this remedy and
    reject the de facto officer doctrine? Fin. Oversight & Mgmt. Bd. for P.R. v. Aurelius Inv., LLC,
    
    140 S. Ct. 1649
    , 1659 (2020). No, the Court rested on a sentence of pure policy: “Any other rule
    would create a disincentive to raise Appointments Clause challenges[.]” Ryder, 
    515 U.S. at 183
    .
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 75
    The Court summarily found the “proper” remedy to be a second appeal before a lawfully
    constituted panel. See 
    id. at 188
    .
    Lucia followed the same reasoning. It noted that Ryder called for a new hearing before a
    properly appointed administrative law judge.       138 S. Ct. at 2055.     It then added a new
    requirement: an agency may not assign the case to the judge who initially heard it even if that
    judge had been properly appointed in the interim. Id. When responding to the claim that this
    “new judge” remedy was not needed to further the Appointments Clause’s purposes, the Court
    reasoned that its remedies in this area have been “designed not only to advance those purposes
    directly, but also to create ‘[]incentive[s] to raise Appointments Clause challenges.’” Id. at 2055
    n.5 (quoting Ryder, 
    515 U.S. at 183
    ). In both cases, therefore, the Court chose a remedy to
    “incentivize” these claims.
    This reasoning should look familiar. The Court once expansively created judge-made
    remedies that would best promote the purposes of constitutional rights. Although, for example,
    Congress has allowed damages claims only against state officers who violate the Constitution,
    
    42 U.S.C. § 1983
    , the Court felt free to create a remedy allowing parties to seek damages from
    federal officers who violate the Fourth Amendment. See Bivens v. Six Unknown Fed. Narcotics
    Agents, 
    403 U.S. 388
    , 395–96 (1971). And although the Fourth Amendment says nothing about
    the rules of evidence in criminal trials, the Court created the exclusionary rule to “remov[e] the
    incentive to disregard” its ban on unreasonable searches. Mapp v. Ohio, 
    367 U.S. 643
    , 656
    (1961) (citation omitted). Ryder bears the hallmarks of Bivens and Mapp. It even discussed the
    exclusionary rule. The Court noted that its cases have rejected that rule when the rule’s costs
    (allowing criminals to go free) exceeded its benefits (incentivizing officers to obey the law). See
    Ryder, 
    515 U.S. at
    185–86 (citing United States v. Leon, 
    468 U.S. 897
     (1984)). Analogizing to
    this approach, Ryder foresaw no ill effects from granting an Appointments Clause remedy on
    direct appeal and suggested that this appellate relief would create “incentives to make such
    challenges.” Id. at 186.
    Although Ryder might mesh well with Mapp, the Court in recent years has treated these
    types of judge-made innovations with a healthy dose of skepticism. See Hernandez, 140 S. Ct. at
    747. The creation of remedies amounts to “lawmaking” that must balance the benefits of any
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 76
    remedy against its costs. Id. at 741–42. Yet the Constitution reserves this task to Congress, not
    the courts. See id. As a result, the Court has all but held that Bivens was wrong and has refused
    to extend it to any other constitutional right for some 40 years. See id. at 742–43 (citing cases);
    Abbasi, 137 S. Ct. at 1856–58. It has also continued to narrow the scope of the exclusionary
    rule, acknowledging that it is a “judicially created remedy” that must be applied cautiously only
    in cases of clear police misconduct. Davis, 
    564 U.S. at 238
     (citation omitted); see, e.g., Utah v.
    Strieff, 
    579 U.S. 232
    , 237–38, 241 (2016); Herring v. United States, 
    555 U.S. 135
    , 140–44
    (2009).
    What do these principles mean for the issue that confronts us? I agree that Ryder and
    Lucia leave open whether a lawful judge at a “new ‘hearing’” may rely on evidence developed at
    the invalid hearing or on orders entered by the invalid judge. Lucia, 
    138 S. Ct. at 2055
     (quoting
    Ryder, 
    515 U.S. at
    182–83). To resolve the ambiguity, I would read the cases in a way that best
    comports with the Constitution’s “original meaning,” Aurelius, 140 S. Ct. at 1659, and with the
    Court’s recent guidance to act cautiously before expanding judge-made remedies, Hernandez,
    140 S. Ct. at 747. When analyzed in that fashion, the FDIC’s remedy more than sufficed.
    The Appointments Clause does not compel Calcutt’s conclusion that a valid judge must
    ignore all prior proceedings before an invalid one. If anything, the clause itself requires no
    remedy. The de facto officer doctrine broadly applied to claims like Calcutt’s that an officer had
    been appointed by the wrong person. See Constantineau, supra, §§ 182–86, at 248–55. An
    English judge who sat on the first case to enforce the doctrine in 1431 “apparently recognized”
    its application in this setting. Id. § 182, at 248. American courts routinely relied on it when an
    officer was unconstitutionally appointed by, say, the governor rather than the legislature, see
    Carroll, 38 Conn. at 474 (discussing Taylor, 5 S.C.L. at 516–17), or the mayor rather than the
    governor, see Strang, 21 Ohio St. at 615–19. And if the Constitution requires some way in
    which to dispute an officer’s right to an office, Congress left open the traditional (if narrow) quo
    warranto remedy. 
    D.C. Code § 16-3503
    ; cf. Henry M. Hart, Jr., The Power of Congress to Limit
    the Jurisdiction of Federal Courts: An Exercise in Dialectic, 
    66 Harv. L. Rev. 1362
    , 1366–67
    (1953).
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 77
    Ryder and Lucia thus must rest on a power to create judge-made remedies for
    constitutional violations. But we must act with caution when asked to expand these remedies
    because the weighing of the costs and benefits amounts to a legislative task, not a judicial one.
    See Abbasi, 137 S. Ct. at 1856–57. On the benefits side, Calcutt’s remedy would certainly
    promote the purposes of the Appointments Clause. See United States v. Arthrex, Inc., 
    141 S. Ct. 1970
    , 1979 (2021). But no provision—not even a constitutional one—“pursues its purposes at
    all costs.” Hernandez, 140 S. Ct. at 741–42 (citation omitted). And Calcutt’s remedy comes
    with its burdens too. It would add to the “administrative costs” already associated with the new
    hearings.   Abbasi, 137 S. Ct. at 1856.        More fundamentally, courts long recognized that
    permitting parties to challenge an officer’s validity at all in appeals of the officer’s actions could
    create “endless confusion[.]” Norton, 
    118 U.S. at
    441–42; see Constantineau, supra, § 4, at 7.
    That is why they channeled these challenges into special suits that would oust officers only
    prospectively, not into appeals that would reverse their actions retrospectively.                 See
    Constantineau, supra, § 451, at 635–36. I see no judicial mode of analysis that can resolve this
    legislative weighing of interests.
    All told, the Court’s cautious approach to judge-made remedies comports with traditional
    remedial practice governing challenges to the validity of an officer’s appointment.               See
    Hernandez, 140 S. Ct. at 742. I thus would not read Ryder and Lucia broadly to compel
    administrative judges to disregard all that occurred at a prior hearing. I would instead read them
    literally to compel a new hearing before a properly appointed judge. Calcutt got just that.
    III. Statutory Claims
    In my view, Calcutt’s statutory claims fare better. The statute allowing the FDIC to bar
    bankers from the industry requires it to prove three things: that a banker has engaged in a listed
    kind of misconduct, that the misconduct will harm the bank (or benefit the banker), and that the
    banker acted with a culpable state of mind.         
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)–(C).       The statute
    allowing the FDIC to impose penalties largely covers the same terrain. 
    Id.
     § 1818(i)(2)(B).
    Here, Calcutt argues that the FDIC failed to prove the “misconduct” and “effect” elements.
    I agree that the FDIC misread these provisions and would remand for it to reconsider the case
    under the proper law.
    No. 20-4303                              Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 78
    A. Misconduct
    To remove Calcutt from the Bank, the FDIC first must prove that he engaged in one of
    three types of misconduct. Id. § 1818(e)(1)(A). Specifically, the statute allows the FDIC to
    remove an “institution-affiliated party” if that the party “has, directly or indirectly”:
    (i) violated—
    (I)     any law or regulation;
    (II) any cease-and-desist order which has become final;
    (III) any condition imposed in writing by a Federal banking agency in
    connection with any action on any application, notice, or request by
    such depository institution or institution-affiliated party; or
    (IV) any written agreement between such depository institution and such
    agency;
    (ii) engaged or participated in any unsafe or unsound practice in connection with
    any insured depository institution or business institution; or
    (iii) committed or engaged in any act, omission, or practice which constitutes a
    breach of such party’s fiduciary duty[.]
    Id. The FDIC found that Calcutt violated the second and third clauses by engaging in “unsafe
    or unsound practice[s]” and committing “breach[es]” of his “fiduciary duty.” App. 18–26.
    (It imposed the $125,000 penalty for the same reasons. See App. 35.)
    1. Unsafe or Unsound Practice. The statute gives the FDIC the power to ban a banker
    from the profession if the banker has “engaged or participated in any unsafe or unsound practice
    in connection with any insured depository institution or business institution[.]” 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)(ii).     Regulators have long defined the key phrase—“unsafe or unsound
    practice”—using a two-part test that courts have generally accepted. See First Nat’l Bank of
    Eden v. Dep’t of Treasury, 
    568 F.2d 610
    , 611 n.2 (8th Cir. 1978). Under this test, an act
    qualifies as an unsafe or unsound practice if it conflicts with “generally accepted standards of
    prudent operation” and creates an “abnormal risk of loss or harm” to the bank. App. 18 (quoting
    Michael v. FDIC, 
    687 F.3d 337
    , 352 (7th Cir. 2012)).
    This test was not intuitive to me from a review of the text, so I looked into its origins.
    One court transparently identified its source: “Because the statute itself does not define an unsafe
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 79
    or unsound practice, courts have sought help in the legislative history.” In re Seidman, 
    37 F.3d 911
    , 926 (3d Cir. 1994). The Fifth Circuit started down this path. See Gulf Fed. Sav. & Loan
    Ass’n v. Fed. Home Loan Bank Bd., 
    651 F.2d 259
    , 263–65 (5th Cir. 1981). Rather than seek out
    the ordinary meaning of “unsafe or unsound practice,” it jumped to a “lively” debate in the
    congressional record. 
    Id. at 263
    . During this debate, the court noted, a few legislators had
    treated as “authoritative” a definition proposed by an agency chairman. 
    Id. at 264
    . Under the
    chairman’s view, the phrase covered “any action” that “is contrary to generally accepted
    standards of prudent operation, the possible consequences of which, if continued, would be
    abnormal risk or loss or damage to an institution, its shareholders, or the agencies administering
    the insurance funds.” 
    Id.
     (citation omitted). The court accepted his view as law. 
    Id.
     at 264–65.
    This straight-from-the-legislative-history test has spread widely since. The few courts
    with reasoned analysis regurgitate the same bit of legislative history. Seidman, 
    37 F.3d at 926
    .
    Most others, though, simply cite other precedent for this test without considering its origins. See
    Frontier State Bank v. FDIC, 
    702 F.3d 588
    , 604 (10th Cir. 2012); Michael, 687 F.3d at 352;
    Landry v. FDIC, 
    204 F.3d 1125
    , 1138 (D.C. Cir. 2000); Simpson, 
    29 F.3d at 1425
    ; Doolittle v.
    Nat’l Credit Union Ass’n, 
    992 F.2d 1531
    , 1538 (11th Cir. 1993); Nw. Nat’l Bank v. Dep’t of
    Treasury, 
    917 F.2d 1111
    , 1115 (8th Cir. 1990).
    I am troubled by this approach. The test springs from a mode of interpretation that no
    Justice on the Supreme Court would endorse today. In recent decades, the Court has given us
    clear marching orders: the answer to an interpretive question begins by identifying the ordinary
    meaning of Congress’s words when read against their context and structure. See Food Mktg.
    Inst. v. Argus Leader Media, 
    139 S. Ct. 2356
    , 2364 (2019); Ross v. Blake, 
    578 U.S. 632
    , 638
    (2016). This “first canon” is also the “last” if the text has a clear meaning. Conn. Nat’l Bank v.
    Germain, 
    503 U.S. 249
    , 254 (1992). Here, however, courts have viewed the legislative history
    as both the beginning and the end of the analysis. Gulf Federal even claimed that the agency
    chairman’s proposed test had been “adopted in both Houses”—by which the court meant that it
    had been read into the legislative record. 
    651 F.2d at 264
     (citation omitted). “But legislative
    history is not the law.” Epic Sys. Corp. v. Lewis, 
    138 S. Ct. 1612
    , 1631 (2018). And the Court
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 80
    has not been kind to other tests that developed in this manner. See, e.g., Food Mktg., 139 S. Ct.
    at 2364.
    I am also troubled by this approach because courts have chosen it to create a “flexible”
    statute allowing regulators to address “changing business problems[.]” Seidman, 
    37 F.3d at 927
    .
    What does this even mean? If an agency condones a banker’s “new business model,” the agency
    can constrict the statute to give the banker a pass? Henson v. Santander Consumer USA Inc.,
    
    137 S. Ct. 1718
    , 1725–26 (2017). But if the agency disapproves of a competitor’s practice, it can
    expand the statute to punish the competitor? This accordion-like view of the rule of law has no
    place in our constitutional order—one in which the President lacks any “dispensing” prerogative.
    Cf. Clark v. Martinez, 
    543 U.S. 371
    , 382 (2005); McConnell, supra, at 115–19. If anything, this
    view has things backwards. This statute can deprive citizens of their property and livelihoods.
    So it would better align with our interpretive traditions if we construed the phrase “strictly”
    rather than flexibly. 1 Blackstone, supra, *88; United States v. Wiltberger, 
    18 U.S. 76
    , 95
    (1820). After all, the rule of lenity (the rule that we resolve ambiguities against the government)
    historically applied not just to criminal laws, but also to all laws considered “penal”—“that is,
    laws inflicting any form of punishment” like a civil penalty. Wooden v. United States, 
    142 S. Ct. 1063
    , 1086 n.5 (2022) (Gorsuch, J., concurring in the judgment). This statute fits that bill. See
    Proffitt v. FDIC, 
    200 F.3d 855
    , 860–62 (D.C. Cir. 2000). At the least, courts should give a
    phrase that affects core private rights its ordinary meaning—not a malleable one.
    How might an ordinary banker interpret the phrase? The legislative history reaches any
    “imprudent act.” Seidman, 
    37 F.3d at 932
    ; see Gulf Federal, 
    651 F.2d at 264
    . Yet this definition
    does not adequately account for two parts of the actual text. For starters, the statute uses the
    word “practice,” not “act.” 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)(ii). Those words mean different things.
    If an otherwise conscientious banker makes a single imprudent loan to a couple down on their
    luck, the banker might have engaged in an unsound “act.” But nobody would say that the banker
    has made it a “practice” of issuing bad loans after just the one. This word includes a connotation
    of repetition (of habitual acts). The banker must have a habit of making bad loans (or, at the
    least, the bank must have that habit and the banker must “participate[] in” it). Id.; cf. Nw. Nat’l
    Bank, 
    917 F.2d at 1115
    . That is because a “practice” is a “habitual or customary performance,”
    No. 20-4303                           Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 81
    American College Dictionary 951 (1970), or a “habitual or customary action or way of doing
    something,” American Heritage Dictionary of the English Language 1028 (1973).
    The statute itself contemplates this distinction. One clause bars bankers from engaging in
    “any unsafe or unsound practice[.]” 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)(ii). The next bars them from
    engaging in “any act, omission, or practice” that breaches their fiduciary duties.               
    Id.
    § 1818(e)(1)(A)(iii) (emphases added). We presume that Congress meant different things when
    it used different words in clauses that sit right next to each other. See Nat’l Ass’n of Mfrs. v.
    Dep’t of Def., 
    138 S. Ct. 617
    , 631 (2018). So even a single act or omission “that breaches [a]
    fiduciary duty” suffices for punishment, but only a habit of “unsafe or unsound” actions does.
    Next, the statute does not cover every unsafe or unsound practice in the abstract. Rather,
    the practice must be “in connection with” a bank. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)(ii). The Supreme
    Court has recognized that this phrase has an “indeterminat[e]” scope. Maracich v. Spears,
    
    570 U.S. 48
    , 59–60 (2013); see Mont v. United States, 
    139 S. Ct. 1826
    , 1832 (2019). If we read
    it broadly here, it could cover practices with the remotest of relations to banking—such as a
    banker’s decision to speed to work every morning. See Maracich, 570 U.S. at 59. One regulator
    even thought that the phrase covered a decision to seek judicial review of the regulator’s own
    regulatory decision. Johnson v. Off. of Thrift Supervision, 
    81 F.3d 195
    , 202 (D.C. Cir. 1996).
    Could Calcutt’s decision to file a petition in this court also be an “unsound practice” because we
    reject his appeal? I would not read the statute this broadly. Courts instead must interpret the
    clause to adopt the “limiting principle” that best comports with the statute’s context and
    structure. See Maracich, 570 U.S. at 59–60; Chadbourne & Parke LLP v. Troice, 
    571 U.S. 377
    ,
    387–91 (2014).
    For the reasons that a D.C. Circuit decision has explained, I would read this clause to
    cover only “unsafe or unsound banking practices.”         Grant Thornton, LLP v. Off. of the
    Comptroller of the Currency, 
    514 F.3d 1328
    , 1332–33 (D.C. Cir. 2008).             This definition
    “harmonizes” this subsection with the rest of § 1818. Id. at 1332. The section includes several
    other provisions that regulate unsafe or unsound practices “in conducting the business” of a
    bank, including one permitting the FDIC to issue cease-and-desist orders.              
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (b)(1). It would be odd to permit a limited remedy (a cease-and-desist order) only for
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 82
    unsound banking practices but a severe remedy (removal from a bank) for any unsound practice
    with any connection to the bank. And a definition that covered only “banking” practices would
    exclude, for example, an outside auditor’s deficient audit, see Grant Thornton, 
    514 F.3d at
    1332–
    33, or a decision to seek judicial review.
    All of this said, courts that apply a broad legislative-history test have recognized that
    their reading could lead to “open-ended supervision.” Gulf Fed., 
    651 F.2d at 265
    . So they
    compensate by adding a limiting principle that I do not necessarily see in the text either. They
    have read the phrase “unsafe or unsound practice” to require that an action pose a risk of extreme
    harm—one that threatens the bank’s “financial stability,” Seidman, 
    37 F.3d at 928
    , or “integrity,”
    Johnson, 
    81 F.3d at 204
     (quoting Gulf Fed., 
    651 F.2d at 267
    ). An “unsafe” practice (one that
    exposes the bank to “danger or risk”) may well require a risk of some harm. 2 Oxford Universal
    Dictionary 2312 (3d ed. 1968).       But the statute also covers an “unsound” practice in the
    disjunctive (a practice that is “not based on proven practice, established procedure, or practical
    knowledge”). Webster’s New International Dictionary 2511 (3d ed. 1966). Perhaps the entire
    phrase “unsafe or unsound” may be one of those “doublets” that Congress uses to convey a
    single idea (like “aid and abet” or “cease and desist”). Doe v. Boland, 
    698 F.3d 877
    , 881 (6th
    Cir. 2012) (citing Freeman v. Quicken Loans, Inc., 
    566 U.S. 624
    , 635–36 (2012)). Even still, I
    would not think that this text requires the risk of financial collapse. A loan officer at a massive
    bank who has followed a consistent pattern of making bad loans may have engaged in an “unsafe
    or unsound practice” even if the banker’s portfolio cannot threaten the bank’s existence.
    Be that as it may, I would save the required financial-risk level for another appeal. When
    sanctioning Calcutt here, the FDIC did not apply my reading that the statute requires unsafe or
    unsound banking practices. I would remand for it to do so in the first instance. Most notably,
    the FDIC nowhere indicated that it must identify a banking “practice” as I read the phrase—i.e.,
    a “habitual or customary action[.]” American Heritage, supra, at 1028. To the contrary, as
    Calcutt notes, the vast majority of its findings relied on a single loan—the Bedrock Transaction.
    It concluded, among other things, that Calcutt violated the Bank’s lending policies and engaged
    in imprudent lending by approving that transaction. App. 19–21. It is not clear that Calcutt’s
    actions with respect to this loan can rise to the level of an unsafe or unsound “practice.”
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 83
    This fact contrasts Calcutt’s case with those that the FDIC cited—which involved a pattern of
    bad loans. See, e.g., First State Bank of Wayne Cnty. v. FDIC, 
    770 F.2d 81
    , 82–83 (6th Cir.
    1985).
    2. Breach of Fiduciary Duty. The statute also gives the FDIC the authority to ban a
    banker from the profession if the banker has “committed or engaged in any act, omission,
    or practice which constitutes a breach of such party’s fiduciary duty[.]”              
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(A)(iii). The parties’ briefing on this portion of the statute raises more questions in
    my mind than it answers.
    Start with a choice-of-law question. Citing Atherton v. FDIC, 
    519 U.S. 213
     (1997), my
    colleagues and Calcutt suggest that the relevant state’s corporate-governance law supplies the
    rule of decision for determining whether a banker has breached a “fiduciary duty” within the
    meaning of § 1818(e)(1)(A)(iii). (The FDIC does not enlighten us with its position on this
    choice-of-law subject.) I am skeptical that their reading is correct. The relevant portion of
    Atherton that they cite was not interpreting federal statutory language like the “fiduciary duty”
    text in § 1818(e). It was rejecting the claim that purely federal common law should supply the
    “corporate governance standards” for federally chartered entities. See 
    519 U.S. at
    217–26. Here,
    by contrast, we must determine the proper “interpretation of a federal statute,” not whether we
    may create federal common law. 
    Id. at 218
    . And when a federal statute uses a common-law
    term of art, the Supreme Court generally interprets its language to adopt a uniform standard of
    conduct for all 50 states based on generic common-law concepts. See, e.g., Burlington Indus.,
    Inc. v. Ellerth, 
    524 U.S. 742
    , 754–55 (1998); Cmty. for Creative Non-Violence v. Reid, 
    490 U.S. 730
    , 739–41 (1989). I might take that approach here. It would likely mean that we should
    interpret this phrase to codify the well-known duties of care and loyalty as they existed in this
    corporate-governance context at the time that Congress adopted this language in 1966. See, e.g.,
    Harry G. Henn, Handbook of the Law of Corporations and Other Business Enterprises 362–70
    (1961); William J. Grange & Thomas C. Woodbury, Corporation Law: Operating Procedures
    for Officers and Directors § 268, at 286–87, § 311, at 325–26 (2d ed. 1964); Dow Votaw,
    Modern Corporations 63–64 (1965); Harold Koontz, The Board of Directors and Effective
    Management 84–86 (1967).
    No. 20-4303                              Calcutt v. FDIC                                   Page 84
    Turn to the substantive standards. The Board held that Calcutt had breached his duty of
    care to the Bank by acting incompetently in his approval of the Bedrock Transaction and in his
    failure to manage the Nielson Loans. App. 23–24. But from my review of the FDIC’s order,
    I cannot even determine the substantive standards of conduct that it applied. Its order did not use
    the words “negligence” or “gross negligence.” And for decades, courts have debated which of
    these standards the statute incorporates. Julie Andersen Hill & Douglas K. Moll, The Duty of
    Care of Bank Directors and Officers, 
    68 Ala. L. Rev. 965
    , 986–92 (2017). The Board also
    neglected to mention the traditional “business-judgment rule,” the application of which is also
    contested. Patricia A. McCoy, A Political Economy of the Business Judgment Rule in Banking:
    Implications for Corporate Law, 
    47 Case W. Res. L. Rev. 1
    , 22–60 (1996). Yet another layer in
    this morass is that in the 1980s, Congress also adopted a “gross negligence” floor to govern the
    conduct of officers and directors in a related context. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1821
    (k); see Atherton,
    
    519 U.S. at
    226–28. That separate section’s implications for § 1818(e) are unclear.
    Yet I would not authoritatively answer these choice-of-law or substantive questions now.
    As I explain below, I would remand to allow the FDIC to reconsider whether Calcutt’s
    misconduct was the cause of any of the claimed harms. On remand, I would give the FDIC a
    chance to clarify its views on these legal questions about the meaning of this fiduciary-duty
    statute.
    B. Causation
    The statute next requires the FDIC to prove either that Calcutt’s misconduct had the
    potential to harm the Bank or that Calcutt received a benefit from that misconduct.              See
    
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B). This “effect” subparagraph provides in full:
    (B) by reason of the violation, practice, or breach described in any clause of
    subparagraph (A)—
    (i) such insured depository institution or business institution has suffered
    or will probably suffer financial loss or other damage;
    (ii) the interests of the insured depository institution’s depositors have
    been or could be prejudiced; or
    (iii) such party has received financial gain or other benefit by reason of
    such violation, practice, or breach[.]
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 85
    
    Id.
     The specific civil-penalty provisions on which the FDIC relied required similar “effects.”
    See 
    id.
     § 1818(i)(2)(B)(ii)(II)–(III); App. 34–35.
    The FDIC misinterpreted the causation element in this subparagraph. To show why,
    I start with the causation basics. The common law has long recognized two types of causation:
    factual (or “but for”) causation and legal (or “proximate”) causation. See William L. Prosser,
    Handbook of the Law of Torts §§ 45–46, at 311, 321–22 (1941). But-for causation creates a
    simple rule. As its name suggests, it requires a plaintiff to show that an injury would not have
    occurred “but for” the defendant’s wrongful conduct. See Burrage v. United States, 
    571 U.S. 204
    , 211–12 (2014); Univ. of Tex. Sw. Med. Ctr. v. Nassar, 
    570 U.S. 338
    , 347 (2013). Suppose,
    for example, that after a neighbor’s dam breaks and floods a plaintiff’s property, the plaintiff
    sues the neighbor for building the dam negligently. See Restatement (Second) of Torts § 432
    illus. 2 (Am. L. Inst. 1965). But-for causation requires a court to ask whether the plaintiff would
    have suffered this injury (the flooding) in a counterfactual world in which the neighbor did not
    commit the wrongful act (the negligent construction). See id. § 432(1) & cmt. a. And if a once-
    in-a-century storm would have caused the flooding even if the neighbor had built the dam to
    perfection, the negligent construction did not cause the harm. See id. § 432 illus. 2; Burrage,
    571 U.S. at 211–12.
    Proximate causation arose from the premise that a factual-cause test alone would lead to
    excessive liability. Prosser, supra, § 45, at 312. Courts recognized that, “[i]n a philosophical
    sense, the consequences of an act go forward to eternity, and the causes of an event go back to
    the discovery of America and beyond.” Id. They thus adopted “proximate cause” rules to cut off
    liability even if a defendant was a but-for cause of harm. Holmes v. Secs. Inv. Prot. Corp.,
    
    503 U.S. 258
    , 268 (1992). As one example, a defendant’s conduct (say, its failure to keep a ship
    docked) may set in motion a chain of events that leads another party to negligently cause an
    injury (say, the captain incompetently runs the ship aground). See Exxon Co., U.S.A. v. Sofec,
    Inc., 
    517 U.S. 830
    , 832–34 (1996). Under a superseding-cause test, courts will not hold the
    defendant liable if the other party’s negligence was unforeseeable. 
    Id. at 837
    . As another
    example, a defendant’s misconduct (say, stock manipulation) may directly harm one person
    (a stockbroker who goes bankrupt) and indirectly harm third parties (the stockbroker’s creditors).
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                    Page 86
    See Holmes, 
    503 U.S. at
    262–63. Under a directness test, courts will not allow the third parties
    to recover. 
    Id.
     at 271–72.
    These common-law rules have significance in this case. The Supreme Court presumes
    that Congress enacts statutory text with common-law concepts in mind. See Lexmark Int’l, Inc.
    v. Static Control Components, Inc., 
    572 U.S. 118
    , 132 (2014). It thus has long read common-law
    causation rules into statutes that use causal language like “because of” or “results from.” See
    Burrage, 571 U.S. at 213–14; Nassar, 570 U.S. at 350–52. Congress used one such phrase (“by
    reason of”) here. The FDIC must prove that the Bank suffered (or will likely suffer) a loss or
    that Calcutt received a benefit “by reason of” his misconduct. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B). So
    I would interpret this statute to require both but-for and proximate causation. See Comcast Corp.
    v. Nat’l Ass’n of African American-Owned Media, 
    140 S. Ct. 1009
    , 1015 (2020); Holmes,
    
    503 U.S. at
    265–67.
    But the FDIC has not adopted these causation rules. Its enforcement orders have all but
    ignored but-for cause. In fact, I have found only one such order that even used this phrase. See
    In re Adams, 
    1997 WL 805273
    , at *5 (F.D.I.C. Nov. 12, 1997). And it suggested that a “‘but
    for’ relationship” was not required. 
    Id.
     (quoting ABKCO Music, Inc. v. Harrisongs Music Ltd.,
    
    772 F.2d 988
    , 995–96 (2d Cir. 1983)). The FDIC also failed to mention but-for cause in this
    case. It simply indicated: “An actual loss is not required; a potential loss is sufficient so long as
    the risk of loss to the Bank was ‘reasonably foreseeable’ to someone in [Calcutt’s] position.”
    App. 26 (citations omitted). The FDIC is correct that, unlike most statutes imposing liability for
    harm, this statute does not require a past loss. It also applies if a bank “will probably suffer” a
    loss in the future “by reason of” the banker’s misconduct. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B)(i). But it
    incorporates but-for cause all the same. For a past loss, the FDIC must show that it “would not
    have occurred without” the misconduct. Nassar, 570 U.S. at 347 (citation omitted). For a future
    loss, the FDIC must show that the probability of loss would not have occurred without that
    misconduct. See id. The FDIC’s jurisprudence leaves no hint that it adheres to these first-year
    torts-class concepts.
    The FDIC’s legal error is all the more pronounced for proximate causation. For years, it
    has rejected outright any need to prove this causation. See Adams, 
    1997 WL 802573
    , at *5; In re
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                 Page 87
    ***, 
    1985 WL 303871
    , at *114 (F.D.I.C. Aug. 19, 1985). It did so in this case too, noting that
    “an individual respondent need not be the proximate cause of the harm to be held liable[.]” App.
    26–27. Confusingly, however, the FDIC suggested that the loss needs to be “foreseeable.” App.
    26, 31. Foreseeability is one component of the proximate-causation requirement that the FDIC
    said it was rejecting. See Hemi Grp., LLC v. City of New York, 
    559 U.S. 1
    , 12 (2010). If the
    FDIC meant to imply that the statute incorporates only proximate cause’s foreseeability element,
    it still erred. Proximate causation contains a group of concepts other than foreseeability. See 
    id.
    So the Supreme Court has already rejected this type of argument that a federal statute contains
    only a foreseeability test. See Bank of Am. Corp. v. City of Miami, 
    137 S. Ct. 1296
    , 1305–06
    (2017).
    *
    Maybe we could overlook the FDIC’s failure to identify the governing causation law if it
    correctly applied that law to Calcutt.      But it did no such thing.    The FDIC held Calcutt
    responsible for three injuries to the Bank and one benefit to him. The Bank incurred $6.443
    million in charge-offs from the Nielson Loans. App. 27–29. It incurred a $30,000 charge-off
    from the $760,000 Bedrock Transaction. App. 27. And it paid its lawyers and accountants for
    work related to these loans. App. 29–31. Calcutt lastly received dividends from the Bank’s
    holding company despite the loans’ poor condition. App. 31–32. None of these “effects”
    sufficed.
    As an initial matter, I agree with my colleagues that the FDIC failed to explain why the
    statute should even cover fees paid to lawyers or accountants. The statute reaches “financial loss
    or other damage” from Calcutt’s misconduct. 
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1)(B)(i). It would be unusual
    to describe the money paid for these services as “financial loss” or “other damage.” One does
    not normally use such terms to describe a payment of money for something of
    commensurate value.       Cf. Summit Valley Indus. Inc. v. Loc. 112, United Brotherhood of
    Carpenters & Joiners of Am., 
    456 U.S. 717
    , 722–23 (1982). The payment is more naturally
    described as an “expense” or “cost.” Our country’s litigation traditions reinforce this view. We
    have long followed the “American Rule” in which a plaintiff’s legal costs are not recoverable
    “damages” even if the defendant’s conduct is their but-for cause. See Alyeska Pipeline Serv. Co.
    No. 20-4303                           Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 88
    v. Wilderness Soc’y, 
    421 U.S. 240
    , 249–50 (1975) (citing Arcambel v. Wiseman, 
    3 U.S. 306
    (1796)). When a statute allows a plaintiff to recover “damages,” then, courts do not read that
    phrase to cover attorney’s fees—or other expert fees for that matter.        See Summit Valley,
    
    456 U.S. at
    722–23; cf. W. Va. Univ. Hosps., Inc. v. Casey, 
    499 U.S. 83
    , 88–92 (1991). And the
    Court has stuck with this rule even if a law uses a phrase (“expenses”) that is “capacious enough
    to include” these fees. Peter v. Nantkwest, Inc., 
    140 S. Ct. 365
    , 372 (2019). So I would not read
    the text “loss” or “damage” to cover them here.
    That leaves the other three “effects.” The FDIC did not apply basic causation rules to
    any of them. Most tellingly, the FDIC held Calcutt responsible for all $6.443 million in charge-
    offs on the $38 million in Nielson Loans—that is, for the entire loss. App. 27–28; see 
    id.
     at 6–7.
    But these loans were underwater in the aftermath of the Great Recession before Calcutt
    committed most of the identified misconduct. App. 625–26. As with my hypothetical about the
    negligently made dam, then, the FDIC needed to ask a “counterfactual” question: How much in
    charge-offs would the Bank have incurred if Calcutt had not engaged in that misconduct?
    Comcast, 140 S. Ct. at 1015. Suppose that the (hopefully) once-in-a-century recession would
    have caused $7 million in charge-offs if the Bank started collection efforts immediately because
    of the collapsed real-estate market. If so, a decision to enter into the Bedrock Transaction would
    have helped (not harmed) the Bank. And Calcutt’s misconduct (for example, the failure to
    undertake the usual underwriting efforts, see App. 19) could not be described as a but-for cause
    of loss. I see nothing in the record on appeal that would help answer this critical but-for
    question, confirming that the FDIC did not even ask it.
    The same error underlies the FDIC’s decision to hold Calcutt liable for the $30,000
    charge-off for the Bedrock Transaction.           App. 27.   The FDIC did not consider the
    “counterfactual” of what would have occurred if Calcutt had not engaged in misconduct.
    Comcast, 140 S. Ct. at 1015. As a generic matter, the Bank suffered a total of $6.473 million in
    charge-offs on all Nielson Loans (including the Bedrock Transaction) and the FDIC needed to
    consider the amount of likely charge-offs without this transaction. Would it have lost more?
    Less? The FDIC did not ask these questions. More granularly, Calcutt told the FDIC that the
    administrative law judge had erred “by failing to tether the $30,000 charge-off (and other actual
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 89
    and potential losses) to specific acts of misconduct[.]” App. 27. The judge found, for instance,
    that Calcutt breached his fiduciary duty of candor to the Bank’s directors by failing to seek their
    preapproval for the Bedrock Transaction. App. 25–26. Suppose the directors would have
    approved the transaction even if he had done so. How could this specific misconduct have
    caused this harm? The FDIC responded that it was “unpersuaded” by this causation argument
    because the Bedrock Transaction was a “main focus” of the hearing and the judge catalogued
    Calcutt’s many misdeeds in approving it. App. 27. This (non)response said nothing about
    causation—an element distinct from misconduct.
    Both but-for and proximate-cause problems undergird the FDIC’s decision that Calcutt
    benefited from his misconduct. He was the largest shareholder of the Bank’s holding company,
    and the FDIC held that his misconduct allowed him to obtain a dividend from this company.
    App. 31–32. Its conclusion rested on the administrative law judge’s finding that the Bank paid
    its own shareholder (the holding company) a $462,950 dividend in mid-2011 and that the FDIC
    would not have approved this payment (to the holding company) if it had known that the Nielson
    Loans were not performing. App. 287, 751. As a matter of but-for causation, the FDIC did not
    ask whether the holding company would have paid its shareholders the same dividend even if the
    FDIC had known of the Nielson Loans’ true condition. See Comcast, 140 S. Ct. at 1015. It cites
    no testimony from the company’s directors about what they would have done. And Calcutt
    testified that the holding company had sufficient assets to pay the dividend even if the Bank had
    paid it nothing. A580.
    As a matter of proximate causation, the FDIC failed to consider a “directness” issue.
    If “by reason of” incorporates usual proximate-cause rules, it would require that Calcutt directly
    benefit from his misconduct. Under the FDIC’s theory, though, the holding company was the
    direct beneficiary that received the dividend; Calcutt was an indirect beneficiary as a shareholder
    of that separate company. Is this a sufficiently “direct” benefit (analogous to a larger salary)?
    “The general tendency” in the law has been “not to go beyond the first step.” Bank of Am.,
    
    137 S. Ct. at 1306
     (citation omitted). And this theory potentially rests on the “independent”
    decision of the holding company. Hemi, 
    559 U.S. at 15
    . But I would leave this question for the
    FDIC.
    No. 20-4303                            Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 90
    All told, I would remand for the FDIC—the fact finder—to apply the correct causation
    rules to the two charge-offs and the dividend payment in the first instance. My colleagues
    recognize many of the FDIC’s legal errors but say there is no need to remand. I disagree. They
    first invoke the deferential substantial-evidence test. But that test governs our review of the
    agency’s factual findings. See Dickinson, 
    527 U.S. at 162
    . I do not quibble with those. I take
    issue with the FDIC’s failure to follow the proper causation law. The substantial-evidence test
    has nothing to say on that subject. And even the FDIC does not claim that we should defer to its
    legal views. See Grant Thornton, 
    514 F.3d at 1331
    ; cf. Epic, 
    138 S. Ct. at
    1629–30.
    If anything, my colleagues’ analysis runs afoul of basic administrative-law principles.
    When an agency’s decision rests on a collapsed legal foundation, we cannot affirm the decision
    on the ground that the agency might have reached the right outcome under a correct legal view.
    We must let the agency apply the proper law in the first instance. See Gonzales v. Thomas,
    
    547 U.S. 183
    , 186 (2006) (per curiam); SEC v. Chenery Corp., 
    318 U.S. 80
    , 88 (1943); Henry J.
    Friendly, Chenery Revisited: Reflections on Reversal and Remand of Administrative Orders,
    
    1969 Duke L.J. 199
    , 209–10. But my colleagues all but find facts by applying their view of the
    law to the record. Recall, for example, that the FDIC held Calcutt liable for all $6.443 million in
    charge-offs on the Nielson Loans—a finding that leaves no doubt that the agency erred. My
    colleagues do not defend this finding. They nevertheless say that the FDIC “could have” found
    that Calcutt’s misconduct caused some unquantified percentage of the losses. Maj. Op. 48. But
    this “judicial judgment cannot be made to do service for an administrative judgment.” Chenery,
    
    318 U.S. at 88
    .
    Even if we could now find Calcutt liable for an (unknown) loss amount on a good-
    enough-for-government-work approach, I would still remand. The statute says that the FDIC
    “may” seek to remove a banker—not that it must do so—when the other requirements are met.
    
    12 U.S.C. § 1818
    (e)(1). It thus leaves the FDIC with discretion over whether to bar Calcutt
    “from working in his chosen profession for the remainder of his career.” Doolittle, 
    992 F.2d at 1538
    . The amount of harm properly chargeable to Calcutt should influence its discretionary
    decision. The FDIC found removal proper after holding Calcutt responsible for well over
    $8 million (including professional fees and charge-offs). If, on remand, the FDIC were to find
    No. 20-4303                             Calcutt v. FDIC                                  Page 91
    that Calcutt’s conduct caused a tiny fraction of this harm, it might reconsider its “draconian”
    sanction. 
    Id.
     In fact, this logic led the Eleventh Circuit to remand a similar removal order so that
    a related agency could reconsider the order after the court jettisoned part of its reasoning. 
    Id.
    Even a case that my colleagues cite issued this type of remand when it upheld only part of the
    FDIC’s order—given the “extraordinary” nature of the sanction.            De la Fuente v. FDIC,
    
    332 F.3d 1208
    , 1227 (9th Cir. 2003). Because the FDIC’s order is riddled with legal error, I find
    it inexplicable that we are not doing so here.
    * * *
    For these reasons, I respectfully dissent.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 20-4303

Filed Date: 6/10/2022

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 6/13/2022

Authorities (110)

Dean Hoye, Trustee of the Estate of Guaranty Trust Company ... , 795 F.2d 893 ( 1986 )

Ronald J. Grubb v. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation , 34 F.3d 956 ( 1994 )

John R. Doolittle, as a Person Participating in the Affairs ... , 992 F.2d 1531 ( 1993 )

Augustus I. Cavallari, Jr. v. Office of the Comptroller of ... , 57 F.3d 137 ( 1995 )

E. Howard Hunt, Jr. v. Victor L. Marchetti, Liberty Lobby, ... , 824 F.2d 916 ( 1987 )

Katharina Wagner Gully, A/K/A Karin Gully v. National ... , 341 F.3d 155 ( 2003 )

National Labor Relations Board v. Jackson Hospital Corp. , 557 F.3d 301 ( 2009 )

Frank E. Jameson v. Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation , 931 F.2d 290 ( 1991 )

B & G Mining, Inc. v. Director, Office of Workers' ... , 522 F.3d 657 ( 2008 )

John R. Mickowski v. Visi-Trak Worldwide, LLC , 415 F.3d 501 ( 2005 )

Gulf Federal Savings and Loan Association of Jefferson ... , 651 F.2d 259 ( 1981 )

Robert M. Wilson v. Commissioner of Social Security , 378 F.3d 541 ( 2004 )

in-the-matter-of-lawrence-b-seidman-and-john-bailey-individually-as , 37 F.3d 911 ( 1994 )

mark-waldorf-in-no-97-5195-v-edward-j-shuta-carolyn-wood-kenneth-c , 142 F.3d 601 ( 1998 )

Northwest National Bank, Fayetteville, Arkansas v. United ... , 917 F.2d 1111 ( 1990 )

Morgan v. Tennessee Valley Authority , 115 F.2d 990 ( 1940 )

Charlene M. CUTLIP, Plaintiff-Appellant, v. SECRETARY OF ... , 25 F.3d 284 ( 1994 )

Jess T. Simpson, Former President and Chairman of the Board ... , 29 F.3d 1418 ( 1994 )

United States v. Cunningham , 679 F.3d 355 ( 2012 )

in-re-air-crash-disaster-chester-h-polec-kris-grigg-mary-kahle-james , 86 F.3d 498 ( 1996 )

View All Authorities »