PHH Corporation v. CFPB , 839 F.3d 1 ( 2016 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued April 12, 2016            Decided October 11, 2016
    No. 15-1177
    PHH CORPORATION, ET AL.,
    PETITIONERS
    v.
    CONSUMER FINANCIAL PROTECTION BUREAU,
    RESPONDENT
    On Petition for Review of an Order of
    the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau
    (CFPB File 2014-CFPB-0002)
    Theodore B. Olson argued the cause for petitioners.
    With him on the briefs were Helgi C. Walker, Mitchel H.
    Kider, David M. Souders, Thomas M. Hefferon, and William
    M. Jay.
    C. Boyden Gray, Adam J. White, Gregory Jacob, Sam
    Kazman, and Hans Bader were on the brief for amici curiae
    State National Bank of Big Spring, et al. in support of
    petitioners.
    Kirk D. Jensen and Alexandar S. Leonhardt were on the
    brief for amicus curiae Consumer Mortgage Coalition in
    support of petitioners.
    2
    Joseph R. Palmore and Bryan J. Leitch were on the brief
    for amici curiae American Financial Services Association, et
    al. in support of petitioners.
    Andrew J. Pincus, Matthew A. Waring, Kathryn
    Comerford Todd, and Steven P. Lehotsky were on the brief for
    amicus curiae The Chamber of Commerce of the United
    States in support of petitioners.
    Jay N. Varon and Jennifer M. Keas were on the brief for
    amici curiae American Land Title Association, et al. in
    support of petitioners.
    Phillip L. Schulman and David T. Case were on the brief
    for amicus curiae National Association of Realtors in support
    of petitioners.
    Lawrence DeMille-Wagman, Senior Litigation Counsel,
    Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, argued the cause for
    respondent. With him on the brief were Meredith Fuchs,
    General Counsel, and John R. Coleman.
    Julie Nepveu was on the brief for amicus curiae AARP in
    support of respondent.
    Before: HENDERSON and KAVANAUGH, Circuit Judges,
    and RANDOLPH, Senior Circuit Judge.
    Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge
    KAVANAUGH, with whom Senior Circuit Judge RANDOLPH
    joins, and with whom Circuit Judge HENDERSON joins as to
    Parts I, IV, and V.
    Concurring opinion filed by Senior Circuit Judge
    RANDOLPH.
    Opinion concurring in part and dissenting in part filed by
    Circuit Judge HENDERSON.
    KAVANAUGH, Circuit Judge:
    INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY
    This is a case about executive power and individual
    liberty. The U.S. Government’s executive power to enforce
    federal law against private citizens – for example, to bring
    criminal prosecutions and civil enforcement actions – is
    essential to societal order and progress, but simultaneously a
    grave threat to individual liberty.
    The Framers understood that threat to individual liberty.
    When designing the executive power, the Framers first
    separated the executive power from the legislative and judicial
    powers. “The declared purpose of separating and dividing the
    powers of government, of course, was to ‘diffus[e] power the
    better to secure liberty.’” Bowsher v. Synar, 
    478 U.S. 714
    ,
    721 (1986) (quoting Youngstown Sheet & Tube Co. v. Sawyer,
    
    343 U.S. 579
    , 635 (1952) (Jackson, J., concurring)). To
    ensure accountability for the exercise of executive power, and
    help safeguard liberty, the Framers then lodged full
    responsibility for the executive power in the President of the
    United States, who is elected by and accountable to the people.
    The text of Article II provides quite simply: “The executive
    Power shall be vested in a President of the United States of
    America.” U.S. CONST. art. II, § 1. And Article II assigns
    the President alone the authority and responsibility to “take
    Care that the Laws be faithfully executed.” Id. § 3. As
    Justice Scalia explained: “The purpose of the separation and
    equilibration of powers in general, and of the unitary Executive
    in particular, was not merely to assure effective government
    4
    but to preserve individual freedom.” Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. 654
    , 727 (1988) (Scalia, J., dissenting).
    Of course, the President executes the laws with the
    assistance of subordinate executive officers who are appointed
    by the President, often with the advice and consent of the
    Senate. To carry out the executive power and be accountable
    for the exercise of that power, the President must be able to
    control subordinate officers in executive agencies. In its
    landmark decision in Myers v. United States, 
    272 U.S. 52
    (1926), authored by Chief Justice and former President Taft,
    the Supreme Court therefore recognized the President’s Article
    II authority to supervise, direct, and remove at will subordinate
    officers in the Executive Branch.
    In 1935, however, the Supreme Court carved out an
    exception to Myers and Article II by permitting Congress to
    create independent agencies that exercise executive power.
    See Humphrey’s Executor v. United States, 
    295 U.S. 602
    (1935). An agency is considered “independent” when the
    agency heads are removable by the President only for cause,
    not at will, and therefore are not supervised or directed by the
    President.     Examples of independent agencies include
    well-known bodies such as the Federal Communications
    Commission, the Securities and Exchange Commission, the
    Federal Trade Commission, the National Labor Relations
    Board, and the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.
    Those and other established independent agencies exercise
    executive power by bringing enforcement actions against
    private citizens and by issuing legally binding rules that
    implement statutes enacted by Congress.
    The independent agencies collectively constitute, in effect,
    a headless fourth branch of the U.S. Government. They
    exercise enormous power over the economic and social life of
    5
    the United States. Because of their massive power and the
    absence of Presidential supervision and direction, independent
    agencies pose a significant threat to individual liberty and to
    the constitutional system of separation of powers and checks
    and balances.
    To help mitigate the risk to individual liberty, the
    independent agencies, although not checked by the President,
    have historically been headed by multiple commissioners,
    directors, or board members who act as checks on one another.
    Each independent agency has traditionally been established, in
    the Supreme Court’s words, as a “body of experts appointed by
    law and informed by experience.” Humphrey’s Executor, 
    295 U.S. at 624
     (internal quotation marks omitted).          The
    multi-member structure reduces the risk of arbitrary
    decisionmaking and abuse of power, and thereby helps protect
    individual liberty.
    In other words, to help preserve individual liberty under
    Article II, the heads of executive agencies are accountable to
    and checked by the President, and the heads of independent
    agencies, although not accountable to or checked by the
    President, are at least accountable to and checked by their
    fellow commissioners or board members. No head of either
    an executive agency or an independent agency operates
    unilaterally without any check on his or her authority.
    Therefore, no independent agency exercising substantial
    executive authority has ever been headed by a single person.
    Until now.
    In the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010, Congress established a
    new independent agency, the Consumer Financial Protection
    Bureau. As proposed by then-Professor and now-Senator
    Elizabeth Warren, the CFPB was to be another traditional,
    6
    multi-member independent agency. See Elizabeth Warren,
    Unsafe at Any Rate: If It’s Good Enough for Microwaves, It’s
    Good Enough for Mortgages. Why We Need a Financial
    Product Safety Commission, Democracy, Summer 2007, at 8,
    16-18. The initial Executive Branch proposal in 2009
    likewise envisioned a traditional, multi-member independent
    agency. See DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY, FINANCIAL
    REGULATORY REFORM: A NEW FOUNDATION: REBUILDING
    FINANCIAL SUPERVISION AND REGULATION 58 (2009). The
    House-passed bill sponsored by Congressman Barney Frank
    and championed by Speaker Nancy Pelosi also contemplated a
    traditional, multi-member independent agency. See H.R.
    4173, 111th Cong. § 4103 (as passed by House, Dec. 11, 2009).
    But Congress ultimately departed from the Warren and
    Administration proposals, and from the House bill. Congress
    established the CFPB as an independent agency headed not by
    a multi-member commission but rather by a single Director.
    Because the CFPB is an independent agency headed by a
    single Director and not by a multi-member commission, the
    Director of the CFPB possesses more unilateral authority – that
    is, authority to take action on one’s own, subject to no check –
    than any single commissioner or board member in any other
    independent agency in the U.S. Government. Indeed, as we
    will explain, the Director enjoys more unilateral authority than
    any other officer in any of the three branches of the U.S.
    Government, other than the President.
    At the same time, the Director of the CFPB possesses
    enormous power over American business, American
    consumers, and the overall U.S. economy. The Director
    unilaterally enforces 19 federal consumer protection statutes,
    covering everything from home finance to student loans to
    credit cards to banking practices. The Director alone decides
    7
    what rules to issue; how to enforce, when to enforce, and
    against whom to enforce the law; and what sanctions and
    penalties to impose on violators of the law. (To be sure,
    judicial review serves as a constraint on illegal actions, but not
    on discretionary decisions within legal boundaries; therefore,
    subsequent judicial review of individual agency decisions has
    never been regarded as sufficient to excuse a structural
    separation of powers violation.)
    That combination of power that is massive in scope,
    concentrated in a single person, and unaccountable to the
    President triggers the important constitutional question at issue
    in this case.
    The petitioner here, PHH, is a mortgage lender and was
    the subject of a CFPB enforcement action that resulted in a
    $109 million order against it. In seeking to vacate the order,
    PHH argues that the CFPB’s status as an independent agency
    headed by a single Director violates Article II of the
    Constitution.
    The question before us is whether we may extend the
    Supreme Court’s Humphrey’s Executor precedent to cover this
    novel, single-Director agency structure for an independent
    agency. To analyze that issue, we follow the history-focused
    approach long applied by the Supreme Court in separation of
    powers cases where, as here, the constitutional text alone does
    not resolve the matter.
    Two recent Supreme Court decisions exemplify that
    historical analysis. In its 2010 decision in Free Enterprise
    Fund v. Public Company Accounting Oversight Board, the
    Supreme Court held that the new Accounting Oversight Board
    at issue in that case – with two levels rather than one level of
    for-cause protection insulating the independent agency heads
    8
    from the President – exceeded the bounds on traditional
    independent agencies and thus violated Article II. 
    561 U.S. 477
    , 514 (2010). In so ruling, the Court emphasized, among
    other things, the novelty of the Board’s structure: “Perhaps
    the most telling indication of the severe constitutional problem
    with the PCAOB is the lack of historical precedent for this
    entity.” 
    Id. at 505
     (internal quotation marks omitted). In its
    2014 decision in NLRB v. Noel Canning, the Supreme Court
    held that recess appointments in Senate recesses of fewer than
    10 days were presumptively unconstitutional under Article II.
    
    134 S. Ct. 2550
    , 2567, slip op. at 21 (2014). Why 10 days?
    The Court explained: “Long settled and established practice
    is a consideration of great weight in a proper interpretation of
    constitutional provisions regulating the relationship between
    Congress and the President.” 
    Id. at 2559
    , slip op. at 7 (internal
    quotation marks and alteration omitted). And the historical
    practice of Presidents and Senates had established a de facto
    10-day line so that recess appointments in recesses of fewer
    than 10 days were impermissible. See 
    id. at 2567
    , slip op. at
    20-21.
    As those two cases illustrate, history and tradition are
    critical factors in separation of powers cases where the
    constitutional text does not otherwise resolve the matter. As
    Justice Breyer wrote for the Court in Noel Canning, that
    bedrock principle – namely, that the “longstanding practice of
    the government can inform our determination of what the law
    is” – is “neither new nor controversial.” 
    Id. at 2560
    , slip op. at
    7 (internal quotation marks and citation omitted) (quoting
    McCulloch v. Maryland, 
    17 U.S. 316
    , 401 (1819) and Marbury
    v. Madison, 
    5 U.S. 137
    , 177 (1803)).
    In this case, the single-Director structure of the CFPB
    represents a gross departure from settled historical practice.
    9
    Never before has an independent agency exercising substantial
    executive authority been headed by just one person.
    The CFPB’s concentration of enormous executive power
    in a single, unaccountable, unchecked Director not only
    departs from settled historical practice, but also poses a far
    greater risk of arbitrary decisionmaking and abuse of power,
    and a far greater threat to individual liberty, than does a
    multi-member independent agency.             The overarching
    constitutional concern with independent agencies is that the
    agencies are unchecked by the President, the official who is
    accountable to the people and who is responsible under Article
    II for the exercise of executive power. Recognizing the broad
    and unaccountable power wielded by independent agencies,
    Congresses and Presidents of both political parties have
    therefore long endeavored to keep independent agencies in
    check through other statutory means. In particular, to check
    independent agencies, Congress has traditionally required
    multi-member bodies at the helm of every independent agency.
    In lieu of Presidential control, the multi-member structure of
    independent agencies acts as a critical substitute check on the
    excesses of any individual independent agency head – a check
    that helps to prevent arbitrary decisionmaking and thereby to
    protect individual liberty.
    This new agency, the CFPB, lacks that critical check and
    structural constitutional protection, yet wields vast power over
    the U.S. economy. So “this wolf comes as a wolf.”
    Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. at 699
     (Scalia, J., dissenting).
    In light of the consistent historical practice under which
    independent agencies have been headed by multiple
    commissioners or board members, and in light of the threat to
    individual liberty posed by a single-Director independent
    agency, we conclude that Humphrey’s Executor cannot be
    10
    stretched to cover this novel agency structure. We therefore
    hold that the CFPB is unconstitutionally structured.
    What is the remedy for that constitutional flaw? PHH
    contends that the constitutional flaw means that we must shut
    down the entire CFPB (if not invalidate the entire Dodd-Frank
    Act) until Congress, if it chooses, passes new legislation fixing
    the constitutional flaw. But Supreme Court precedent dictates
    a narrower remedy. To remedy the constitutional flaw, we
    follow the Supreme Court’s precedents, including Free
    Enterprise Fund, and simply sever the statute’s
    unconstitutional for-cause provision from the remainder of the
    statute. Here, that targeted remedy will not affect the ongoing
    operations of the CFPB. With the for-cause provision
    severed, the President now will have the power to remove the
    Director at will, and to supervise and direct the Director. The
    CFPB therefore will continue to operate and to perform its
    many duties, but will do so as an executive agency akin to other
    executive agencies headed by a single person, such as the
    Department of Justice and the Department of the Treasury.
    Those executive agencies have traditionally been headed by a
    single person precisely because the agency head operates
    within the Executive Branch chain of command under the
    supervision and direction of the President. The President is a
    check on and accountable for the actions of those executive
    agencies, and the President now will be a check on and
    accountable for the actions of the CFPB as well.
    Because the CFPB as remedied will continue operating,
    we must also address the statutory issues raised by PHH in its
    challenge to the $109 million order against it. 1 PHH raises
    three main statutory arguments.
    1
    If PHH fully prevailed on its constitutional argument,
    including with respect to severability, the CFPB could not continue
    11
    First, PHH argues that the CFPB incorrectly interpreted
    Section 8 of the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act to bar
    so-called captive reinsurance arrangements involving
    mortgage lenders such as PHH and their affiliated reinsurers.
    In a captive reinsurance arrangement, a mortgage lender (such
    as PHH) refers borrowers to a mortgage insurer. In return, the
    operating unless and until Congress enacted new legislation. As a
    result, we could not and would not remand to the CFPB for any
    further proceedings in this case. By contrast, even if PHH fully
    prevails on the statutory issues, we still will have to remand to the
    CFPB for the agency to conduct the proceeding in accordance with
    the appropriate statutory requirements, under which PHH may still
    be liable for certain alleged wrongdoing. In other words, PHH’s
    constitutional and severability argument, if accepted, would afford it
    full relief from any CFPB enforcement action and thus would afford
    it broader relief than would its statutory arguments. For that reason,
    we have no choice but to address the constitutional issue first. The
    constitutional issue cannot be avoided in any principled way. We
    therefore respectfully but firmly disagree with Judge Henderson’s
    suggestion in her separate opinion that the constitutional issue can be
    avoided. In our view, failing to decide the constitutional issue here
    would be impermissible judicial abdication, not judicial restraint.
    Moreover, apart from that necessity in this case, when a litigant
    raises a fundamental constitutional challenge to the very structure or
    existence of an agency enforcing the law against it, the courts
    ordinarily address that issue promptly, at least so long as
    jurisdictional requirements such as standing are met. See, e.g., Free
    Enterprise Fund, 561 U.S. at 490-91; Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. at 669-70
    ; Buckley v. Valeo, 
    424 U.S. 1
    , 12 (1976). That was the
    approach we took in both Intercollegiate Broadcasting System, Inc.
    v. Copyright Royalty Board, 
    684 F.3d 1332
    , 1334, 1336-37 (D.C.
    Cir. 2012), and Raymond J. Lucia Cos. v. SEC, No. 15-1345, slip op.
    at 7, 
    2016 WL 4191191
    , at *3 (D.C. Cir., Aug. 9, 2016). It can be
    irresponsible for a court to unduly delay ruling on such a
    fundamental and ultimately unavoidable structural challenge, given
    the systemic ramifications of such an issue.
    12
    mortgage insurer buys reinsurance from a mortgage reinsurer
    affiliated with (or owned by) the referring mortgage lender.
    We agree with PHH that Section 8 of the Act allows captive
    reinsurance arrangements so long as the amount paid by the
    mortgage insurer for the reinsurance does not exceed the
    reasonable market value of the reinsurance.
    Second, PHH claims that, in any event, the CFPB departed
    from the consistent prior interpretations issued by the
    Department of Housing and Urban Development, and that the
    CFPB then retroactively applied its new interpretation of the
    Act against PHH, thereby violating PHH’s due process rights.
    We again agree with PHH: The CFPB’s order violated
    bedrock principles of due process.
    Third, in light of our ruling on the constitutional and
    statutory issues, the CFPB on remand still will have an
    opportunity to demonstrate that the relevant mortgage insurers
    in fact paid more than reasonable market value to the
    PHH-affiliated reinsurer for reinsurance, thereby making
    disguised payments for referrals in contravention of Section 8.
    PHH claims, however, that much of the alleged misconduct
    occurred outside of the three-year statute of limitations and
    therefore may not be the subject of a CFPB enforcement
    action. The CFPB responds that, under Dodd-Frank, there is
    no statute of limitations for any CFPB administrative actions to
    enforce any consumer protection law. In the alternative, the
    CFPB contends that there is no statute of limitations for
    administrative actions to enforce Section 8 of the Real Estate
    Settlement Procedures Act. We disagree with the CFPB on
    both points. First of all, the Dodd-Frank Act incorporates the
    statutes of limitations in the underlying statutes enforced by the
    CFPB in administrative proceedings. And under the Real
    Estate Settlement Procedures Act, a three-year statute of
    13
    limitations applies to all CFPB enforcement actions to enforce
    Section 8, whether brought in court or administratively.
    In sum, we grant PHH’s petition for review, vacate the
    CFPB’s order against PHH, and remand for further
    proceedings consistent with this opinion. On remand, the
    CFPB may determine among other things whether, within the
    applicable three-year statute of limitations, the relevant
    mortgage insurers paid more than reasonable market value to
    the PHH-affiliated reinsurer.
    In so ruling, we underscore the important but limited
    real-world implications of our decision. As before, the CFPB
    will continue to operate and perform its many critical
    responsibilities, albeit under the ultimate supervision and
    direction of the President. Section 8 will continue to mean
    what it has traditionally meant: that captive reinsurance
    agreements are permissible so long as the mortgage insurer
    pays no more than reasonable market value for the reinsurance.
    And the three-year statute of limitations that has traditionally
    applied to agency actions to enforce Section 8 will continue to
    apply.
    With apologies for the length of this opinion, we now turn
    to our detailed explanation and analysis of these important
    issues.
    I
    PHH is a large home mortgage lender. When PHH and
    other lenders provide mortgage loans to homebuyers, they
    require certain homebuyers to obtain mortgage insurance.
    Mortgage insurance protects lenders by covering part of the
    lenders’ losses if homebuyers default on their mortgages.
    14
    Homebuyers pay monthly premiums to the mortgage insurer
    for the insurance.
    In turn, mortgage insurers may obtain mortgage
    reinsurance. In the same way that mortgage insurance
    protects lenders, mortgage reinsurance protects mortgage
    insurers. Reinsurers assume some of the risk of insuring the
    mortgage. In exchange, mortgage insurers pay a fee (usually
    a portion of the homebuyers’ monthly insurance premiums) to
    the reinsurers.
    In 1994, PHH established a wholly owned subsidiary
    known as Atrium Insurance Corporation. Atrium provided
    reinsurance to the mortgage insurers that insured mortgages
    generated by PHH. In return, PHH often referred borrowers
    to mortgage insurers that used Atrium’s reinsurance services.
    That is known as a “captive reinsurance” arrangement, which
    was not uncommon in the industry at the time. According to
    PHH, the mortgage insurers did not pay more than reasonable
    market value to Atrium for the reinsurance.
    Originally passed by Congress and signed by President
    Ford in 1974, the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act is a
    broad statute governing real estate transactions. One of its
    stated purposes was “the elimination of kickbacks or referral
    fees that tend to increase unnecessarily the costs of certain
    settlement services.” 
    12 U.S.C. § 2601
    (b)(2).
    To achieve that objective, Section 8(a) of the Act, which is
    titled “Prohibition against kickbacks and unearned fees,”
    provides: “No person shall give and no person shall accept
    any fee, kickback, or thing of value pursuant to any agreement
    or understanding, oral or otherwise, that business incident to or
    a part of a real estate settlement service involving a federally
    related mortgage loan shall be referred to any person.” 
    Id.
    15
    § 2607(a). In plain English, Section 8(a) prohibits, as relevant
    here, paying for a referral – for example, a mortgage insurer’s
    paying a lender for the lender’s referral of homebuying
    customers to that mortgage insurer.
    Standing alone, Section 8(a) perhaps might have been
    construed by government enforcement agencies to cast doubt
    on a mortgage lender’s referrals of customers to mortgage
    insurers who in turn purchased reinsurance from a reinsurer
    affiliated with the lender. But another provision of the Real
    Estate Settlement Procedures Act, Section 8(c), carved out a
    series of expansive exceptions, qualifications, and safe harbors
    related to Section 8(a). Of relevance here, Section 8(c)
    provides: “Nothing in this section shall be construed as
    prohibiting . . . (2) the payment to any person of a bona fide
    salary or compensation or other payment for goods or facilities
    actually furnished or for services actually performed . . . .”
    Id. § 2607(c).
    Before the creation of the CFPB in 2010, the Department
    of Housing and Urban Development, known as HUD,
    interpreted Section 8(c) to establish a safe harbor allowing
    bona fide transactions between a lender and a mortgage insurer
    (or between a mortgage insurer and a lender-affiliated
    reinsurer), so long as the mortgage insurer did not pay the
    lender for a referral. HUD therefore interpreted Section 8(c)
    to allow captive reinsurance arrangements so long as the
    mortgage insurer paid no more than reasonable market value
    for the reinsurance. If the mortgage insurer paid more than
    reasonable market value for the reinsurance, then a
    presumption would arise that the excess payment was indeed a
    disguised payment for the referral, which is impermissible
    under Section 8(a).       HUD repeatedly reaffirmed that
    interpretation, and the mortgage lending industry relied on it.
    16
    When Congress created the CFPB in 2010, Congress
    provided that the CFPB would take over enforcement of
    Section 8 from HUD. By regulation, the CFPB carried
    forward HUD’s rules, policy statements, and guidance, subject
    of course to any future change by the CFPB.
    Therefore, under Section 8(c), as authoritatively
    interpreted by the Federal Government, PHH as a mortgage
    lender could refer customers to mortgage insurers who
    obtained reinsurance from Atrium – so long as the mortgage
    insurers paid Atrium no more than reasonable market value for
    the reinsurance.
    Or so PHH thought. In 2014, notwithstanding Section
    8(c) and HUD’s longstanding interpretation, the CFPB
    initiated an administrative enforcement action against PHH.
    The CFPB alleged that PHH’s captive reinsurance
    arrangement with the mortgage insurers violated Section 8.
    Under the CFPB’s newly minted interpretation, Section 8
    prohibits most referrals made by lenders to mortgage insurers
    in exchange for the insurer’s purchasing reinsurance from a
    lender-affiliated reinsurer. The CFPB said that Section 8 bars
    such a captive reinsurance arrangement even when the
    mortgage insurer pays no more than reasonable market value to
    the reinsurer for the reinsurance.
    In its order in this case, the CFPB thus discarded HUD’s
    longstanding interpretation of Section 8 and, for the first time,
    pronounced its new interpretation. And then the CFPB
    applied its new interpretation of Section 8 retroactively against
    PHH, notwithstanding PHH’s reliance on HUD’s prior
    interpretation. The CFPB sanctioned PHH for previous
    actions that PHH had taken in reliance on HUD’s prior
    interpretation, even though PHH’s conduct had occurred
    17
    before the CFPB’s new interpretation of Section 8. The CFPB
    ordered PHH to pay $109 million in disgorgement and
    enjoined PHH from entering into future captive reinsurance
    arrangements.
    PHH petitioned this Court for review. A motions panel
    of this Court (Judges Henderson, Millett, and Wilkins)
    previously granted PHH’s motion for a stay of the CFPB’s
    order pending resolution of the merits in this case.
    II
    In challenging the enforcement action against it, PHH
    raises a fundamental constitutional objection to the entire
    proceeding. According to PHH, the CFPB’s structure violates
    Article II of the Constitution because the CFPB operates as an
    independent agency headed by a single Director. PHH argues
    that, to comply with Article II, either (i) the agency’s Director
    must be removable at will by the President, meaning that the
    CFPB would operate as a traditional executive agency; or (ii) if
    structured as an independent agency, the agency must be
    structured as a multi-member commission. We agree.
    A
    We begin by describing the background of independent
    agencies in general and the CFPB in particular.
    As the Supreme Court has explained, our Constitution
    “was adopted to enable the people to govern themselves,
    through their elected leaders,” and the Constitution “requires
    that a President chosen by the entire Nation oversee the
    execution of the laws.” Free Enterprise Fund v. Public
    Company Accounting Oversight Board, 
    561 U.S. 477
    , 499
    (2010). Under the text of Article II, the President alone is
    18
    responsible for exercising the executive power. The first 15
    words of Article II of the Constitution provide: “The
    executive Power shall be vested in a President of the United
    States of America.” U.S. CONST. art. II, § 1. And Article II
    assigns the President alone the authority and responsibility to
    “take Care that the Laws be faithfully executed.” Id. § 3.
    Article II makes “emphatically clear from start to finish” that
    “the president would be personally responsible for his branch.”
    AKHIL REED AMAR, AMERICA’S CONSTITUTION: A BIOGRAPHY
    197 (2005); see also Neomi Rao, Removal: Necessary and
    Sufficient for Presidential Control, 
    65 Ala. L. Rev. 1205
    , 1215
    (2014) (“The text and structure of Article II provide the
    President with the power to control subordinates within the
    executive branch.”).
    To exercise the executive power, the President must have
    the assistance of subordinates. See Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 483
    . The Framers therefore provided for the
    appointment of executive officers and the creation of executive
    departments to assist the President “in discharging the duties of
    his trust.” 
    Id.
     (internal quotation marks omitted); see U.S.
    CONST. art. II, § 2.
    In order to maintain control over the exercise of executive
    power and take care that the laws are faithfully executed, the
    President must be able to supervise and direct those
    subordinate executive officers. See Free Enterprise Fund,
    
    561 U.S. at 498-502
    . As James Madison stated during the
    First Congress, “if any power whatsoever is in its nature
    Executive, it is the power of appointing, overseeing, and
    controlling those who execute the laws.” 1 ANNALS OF
    CONGRESS 463 (Madison) (1789) (Joseph Gales ed., 1834).
    To supervise and direct executive officers, the President
    must be able to remove those officers at will. See generally
    19
    Myers v. United States, 
    272 U.S. 52
     (1926). Otherwise, a
    subordinate could ignore the President’s supervision and
    direction without fear, and the President could do nothing
    about it. See Bowsher v. Synar, 
    478 U.S. 714
    , 726 (1986)
    (“Once an officer is appointed, it is only the authority that can
    remove him, and not the authority that appointed him, that he
    must fear and, in the performance of his functions, obey.”)
    (internal quotation marks omitted). The Article II chain of
    command depends on the President’s removal power. As
    James Madison explained: “If the President should possess
    alone the power of removal from office, those who are
    employed in the execution of the law will be in their proper
    situation, and the chain of dependence be preserved; the lowest
    officers, the middle grade, and the highest, will depend, as they
    ought, on the President, and the President on the community.”
    1 ANNALS OF CONGRESS 499 (Madison). The Supreme Court
    recently summarized the Article II chain of command this way:
    “The Constitution that makes the President accountable to the
    people for executing the laws also gives him the power to do
    so. That power includes, as a general matter, the authority to
    remove those who assist him in carrying out his duties.
    Without such power, the President could not be held fully
    accountable for discharging his own responsibilities; the buck
    would stop somewhere else.” Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 513-14
    .
    In the late 1800s and the early 1900s, as part of the
    Progressive Movement and an emerging belief in expert,
    apolitical, and scientific answers to certain public policy
    questions, Congress began creating new expert agencies that
    were independent of the President but that exercised executive
    power. The heads of those independent agencies were
    removable by the President only for cause, not at will, and were
    neither supervised nor directed by the President. Some early
    examples included the Interstate Commerce Commission
    20
    (1887) and the Federal Trade Commission (1914).
    Importantly, the independent agencies were all multi-member
    bodies: They were designed as non-partisan expert bodies
    that would neutrally and impartially issue rules, bring law
    enforcement actions, and resolve disputes in their respective
    jurisdictions.
    In a 1926 decision written by Chief Justice and former
    President Taft, the Supreme Court ruled that, under Article II,
    the President must be able to supervise, direct, and remove at
    will certain executive officers. The Court stated: “[W]hen
    the grant of the executive power is enforced by the express
    mandate to take care that the laws be faithfully executed, it
    emphasizes the necessity for including within the executive
    power as conferred the exclusive power of removal.” Myers,
    
    272 U.S. at 122
    .
    A few years later, based on his reading of Article II and the
    Court’s 1926 decision in Myers, President Franklin Roosevelt
    vigorously contested the idea that Congress could create
    independent agencies and thereby prevent the President from
    controlling the executive power vested in those independent
    agencies. President Roosevelt did not object to the existence
    of the agencies; rather, he objected to the President’s lack of
    control over these agencies, which after all were exercising
    important executive power.
    The issue came to a head in President Roosevelt’s dispute
    with William E. Humphrey, a commissioner of the Federal
    Trade Commission.        Commissioner Humphrey was a
    Republican holdover from the Hoover Administration who, in
    President Roosevelt’s view, was too sympathetic to big
    business and hostile to the Roosevelt Administration’s
    regulatory agenda. Asserting his authority under Article II,
    President Roosevelt fired Commissioner Humphrey.
    21
    Humphrey contested his removal, arguing that he was
    protected against firing by the statute’s for-cause removal
    provision, and further arguing that Congress possessed
    authority to create such independent agencies without violating
    Article II. The case reached the Supreme Court in 1935.
    At its core, the case raised the question whether Article II
    permitted Congress to create independent agencies whose
    heads were not removable at will and would operate free of the
    President’s supervision and direction. Representing President
    Roosevelt, the Solicitor General argued that the case was
    straightforward and controlled by the text and history of
    Article II and the Court’s 1926 decision in Myers. But
    notwithstanding Article II and the decision in Myers, the
    Supreme Court upheld the constitutionality of independent
    agencies – a decision that so incensed President Roosevelt that
    it helped trigger his ill-fated court reorganization plan in 1937.
    See Humphrey’s Executor v. United States, 
    295 U.S. 602
    , 624,
    631-32 (1935). In allowing independent agencies, the
    Humphrey’s Executor Court found it significant that the
    Federal Trade Commission was intended “to be non-partisan,”
    to “act with entire impartiality,” and “to exercise the trained
    judgment of a body of experts appointed by law and informed
    by experience.” 
    Id. at 624
     (internal quotation marks omitted).
    Those characteristics, among others, led the Court to conclude
    that Congress could create an independent agency “wholly
    disconnected from the executive department.” 
    Id. at 630
    .
    According to the Court, Congress could therefore limit the
    President’s power to remove the commissioners of the Federal
    Trade Commission and, by extension, Congress could limit the
    President’s power to remove the commissioners and board
    directors of similar independent agencies. 
    Id. at 628-30
    . 2
    2
    To cabin the effects of Humphrey’s Executor on the
    Presidency, some have proposed reading the standard for-cause
    22
    In the wake of the 1935 Humphrey’s Executor decision,
    independent agencies have continued to play an enormous role
    in the U.S. Government. The independent agencies possess
    massive authority over vast swaths of American economic and
    social life.
    Importantly, however, the independent agencies have
    traditionally operated – and continue to operate – as
    multi-member “bod[ies] of experts appointed by law and
    informed by experience.” 
    Id. at 624
     (internal quotation marks
    omitted). 3
    removal restrictions in the statutes creating independent agencies to
    allow for Presidential removal of independent agency heads based
    on policy differences. But Humphrey’s Executor itself rejected that
    interpretation.    As the Supreme Court recently explained,
    Humphrey’s Executor refuted the idea that “simple disagreement”
    with an agency head’s “policies or priorities could constitute ‘good
    cause’ for its removal.” Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 502
    .
    The correct reading of the “for-cause” restrictions, the Court stated
    in Free Enterprise Fund, is that they “mean what they say” and
    preclude removal except in cases of inefficiency, neglect of duty, or
    malfeasance in office. 
    Id.
    3
    The independent agencies have been designed, moreover, to
    avoid “the suspicion of partisan direction.” Humphrey’s Executor,
    
    295 U.S. at 625
    . The independent agency heads are appointed by
    the President with the advice and consent of the Senate (or appointed
    for a temporary period by the President alone in appropriate Senate
    recesses). By statute, certain independent agencies must include
    members of both major political parties. See, e.g., 
    15 U.S.C. § 41
    (Federal Trade Commission); 15 U.S.C. § 78d(a) (Securities and
    Exchange Commission); 
    15 U.S.C. § 2053
    (c) (Consumer Product
    Safety Commission); 
    42 U.S.C. § 7171
    (b)(1) (Federal Energy
    Regulatory Commission).
    23
    The independent agency at issue here, the CFPB, arose out
    of an idea originally proposed by then-Professor and
    now-Senator Elizabeth Warren. In 2007, concerned about
    balkanized and inconsistent federal law enforcement of
    consumer protection statutes, Professor Warren advocated that
    Congress create a new independent agency, which she called a
    Financial Product Safety Commission. This new agency
    would centralize and unify federal law enforcement to protect
    consumers. See Elizabeth Warren, Unsafe at Any Rate: If It’s
    Good Enough for Microwaves, It’s Good Enough for
    Mortgages. Why We Need a Financial Product Safety
    Commission, Democracy, Summer 2007, at 8, 16-18.
    The agency proposed by Professor Warren was to operate
    as a traditional multi-member independent agency. The
    subsequent Executive Branch proposal for such a new agency
    likewise contemplated a multi-member structure.        See
    DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY, FINANCIAL REGULATORY
    REFORM: A NEW FOUNDATION: REBUILDING FINANCIAL
    SUPERVISION AND REGULATION 58 (2009). The originally
    passed House bill sponsored by Congressman Barney Frank
    and supported by Speaker Nancy Pelosi also would have
    created a traditional multi-member independent agency. See
    H.R. 4173, 111th Cong. § 4103 (as passed by House, Dec. 11,
    2009).
    But Congress ultimately strayed from the Warren and
    Executive Branch proposals, and from the House bill, as well
    as from historical practice, by creating an independent agency
    with only a single Director. See Dodd-Frank Wall Street
    Reform and Consumer Protection Act, § 1011, 
    12 U.S.C. § 5491
    . Congress made the Director of the CFPB removable
    only for cause – that is, for “inefficiency, neglect of duty, or
    malfeasance in office” – during the Director’s fixed five-year
    term. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 5491
    (c)(3); Humphrey’s Executor, 295
    24
    U.S. at 620. Under the statute, the President therefore may not
    supervise, direct, or remove at will the Director. As a result,
    this statute means that a Director appointed by a President may
    continue to serve in office even if the President later wants to
    remove the Director based on policy disagreement, for
    example. This statute also means that a Director may even
    continue to serve under a new President (at least until the
    Director’s statutory five-year tenure has elapsed), even though
    the new President might strongly disagree with the Director
    about policy issues or the overall direction of the agency.
    At the same time, Congress granted the CFPB broad
    authority to enforce U.S. consumer protection laws. Under
    the Dodd-Frank Act, the CFPB possesses the power to
    “prescribe rules or issue orders or guidelines pursuant to” 19
    distinct consumer protection laws.                
    12 U.S.C. § 5581
    (a)(1)(A); see also 
    id.
     § 5481(14). That power was
    previously exercised by seven different government agencies.
    See id. § 5581(b) (transferring to the CFPB “[a]ll consumer
    financial protection functions” previously exercised by the
    Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, the Comptroller of
    the Currency, the Office of Thrift Supervision, the Federal
    Deposit Insurance Corporation, the National Credit Union
    Administration, and select functions of the Department of
    Housing and Urban Development and the Federal Trade
    Commission). The CFPB may pursue actions to enforce the
    consumer protection laws in federal court, as well as in
    administrative actions before administrative law judges, and
    may issue subpoenas requesting documents or testimony in
    connection with those enforcement actions.            See id.
    §§ 5562-5564. The CFPB has the power to impose a wide
    range of legal and equitable relief, including restitution,
    disgorgement, money damages, injunctions, and civil
    monetary penalties. Id. § 5565(a)(2). And all of this massive
    power is lodged in one person – the Director – who is not
    25
    supervised, directed, or checked by the President or by other
    directors.
    Because the Director alone heads the agency without
    Presidential supervision, and in light of the CFPB’s broad
    authority over the U.S. economy, the Director enjoys
    significantly more unilateral power than any single member of
    any other independent agency. By “unilateral power,” we
    mean power that is not checked by the President or by other
    colleagues. Indeed, other than the President, the Director of
    the CFPB is the single most powerful official in the entire
    United States Government, at least when measured in terms of
    unilateral power. That is not an overstatement. What about
    the Speaker of the House, you might ask? The Speaker can
    pass legislation only if 218 Members agree. The Senate
    Majority Leader? The Leader needs 60 Senators to invoke
    cloture, and needs a majority of Senators (usually 51 Senators
    or 50 plus the Vice President) to approve a law or nomination.
    The Chief Justice? The Chief Justice must obtain four other
    Justices’ votes for his or her position to prevail. The Chair of
    the Federal Reserve? The Chair needs the approval of a
    majority of the Federal Reserve Board. The Secretary of
    Defense? The Secretary is supervised and directed by the
    President. On any decision, the Secretary must do as the
    President says. So too with the Secretary of State, and the
    Secretary of the Treasury, and the Attorney General.
    To be sure, the Dodd-Frank Act requires the Director to
    establish and consult with a “Consumer Advisory Board.”
    See id. § 5494. But the advisory board is just that: advisory.
    Nothing requires the Director to heed the Board’s advice.
    Without the formal authority to prevent unilateral action by the
    Director, the Advisory Board does not come close to equating
    to the check provided by the multi-member structure of
    traditional independent commissions.
    26
    The Act also, in theory, allows a supermajority of the
    Financial Stability Oversight Council to veto certain
    regulations of the Director. See id. § 5513. But by statute,
    the veto power may be used only to prevent regulations (not to
    prevent enforcement actions or adjudications); only when
    two-thirds of the Council members agree; and only when a
    regulation puts “the safety and soundness of the United States
    banking system or the stability of the financial system of the
    United States at risk,” a standard unlikely to be met in practice
    in most cases. Id. § 5513(c)(3)(B)(ii); see S. Rep. No.
    111-176, at 166 (“The Committee notes that there was no
    evidence provided during its hearings that consumer protection
    regulation would put safety and soundness at risk.”); see also
    Todd Zywicki, The Consumer Financial Protection Bureau:
    Savior or Menace?, 
    81 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 856
    , 875 (2013)
    (“[S]ubstantive checks on the CFPB can be triggered . . . only
    under the extreme circumstance of a severe threat to the safety
    and soundness of the American financial system. It is likely
    that this extreme test will rarely be satisfied in practice.”);
    Recent Legislation, Dodd-Frank Act Creates the Consumer
    Financial Protection Bureau, 
    124 Harv. L. Rev. 2123
    , 2129
    (2011) (“[T]he high standard for vetoing regulations . . . will
    be difficult to establish.”). The veto power could not have
    been used in this case to override the Director’s determination
    regarding Section 8, for example. As with the consultation
    requirement, the Act’s limited veto provision falls far short of
    making the CFPB the equivalent of a multi-member
    independent agency.
    Finally, the Act technically makes the CFPB part of the
    Federal Reserve for certain administrative purposes. See, e.g.,
    
    12 U.S.C. § 5491
    (a); see also 
    id.
     § 5493. But that is irrelevant
    to the present analysis because the Federal Reserve may not
    supervise, direct, or remove the Director.
    27
    In short, when measured in terms of unilateral power, the
    Director of the CFPB is the single most powerful official in the
    entire U.S. Government, other than the President. Indeed,
    within his jurisdiction, the Director of the CFPB can be
    considered even more powerful than the President. It is the
    Director’s view of consumer protection law that prevails over
    all others. In essence, the Director is the President of
    Consumer Finance. The concentration of massive, unchecked
    power in a single Director marks a departure from settled
    historical practice and makes the CFPB unique among
    traditional independent agencies, as we will now explain.
    B
    As a single-Director independent agency exercising
    substantial executive authority, the CFPB is the first of its kind
    and a historical anomaly. Until this point in U.S. history,
    independent agencies exercising substantial executive
    authority have all been multi-member commissions or boards.
    A sample list includes:
    •   Interstate Commerce Commission (1887)
    •   Federal Reserve Board (1913)
    •   Federal Trade Commission (1914)
    •   U.S. International Trade Commission (1916)
    •   Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (1933)
    •   Federal Communications Commission (1934)
    •   National Mediation Board (1934)
    •   Securities and Exchange Commission (1934)
    •   National Labor Relations Board (1935)
    •   Federal Maritime Commission (1961)
    •   National Transportation Safety Board (1967)
    •   National Credit Union Administration (1970)
    28
    •    Occupational Safety and Health Review Commission
    (1970)
    •    Postal Regulatory Commission (1970)
    •    Consumer Product Safety Commission (1972)
    •    Nuclear Regulatory Commission (1974)
    •    Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (1977)
    •    Federal Mine Safety and Health Review Commission
    (1977)
    •    Federal Labor Relations Authority (1978)
    •    Merit Systems Protection Board (1978)
    •    Defense Nuclear Facilities Safety Board (1988)
    •    National Indian Gaming Commission (1988)
    •    Chemical Safety and Hazard Investigation Board
    (1990)
    •    Surface Transportation Board (1995)
    •    Independent Payment Advisory Board (2010). 4
    4
    In general, an agency without a for-cause removal statute is an
    executive agency, not an independent agency, because the President
    can supervise, direct, and remove at will the heads of those agencies.
    That said, in the period from Myers (1926) to Humphrey’s Executor
    (1935), Congress created several multi-member agencies that did not
    include for-cause provisions, apparently because Congress believed
    that Myers had outlawed making agencies independent. Those
    agencies included the FCC and the SEC. After Humphrey’s
    Executor, those multi-member agencies were nonetheless treated as
    independent agencies. Cf. Free Enterprise Fund v. Public
    Company Accounting Oversight Board, 
    561 U.S. 477
    , 487 (2010)
    (deciding case on assumption that SEC is an independent agency);
    Wiener v. United States, 
    357 U.S. 349
    , 352-54 (1958). But because
    those agencies’ statutes do not contain express for-cause provisions,
    some suggest that those agencies should be treated as executive
    agencies. See Kirti Datla & Richard L. Revesz, Deconstructing
    Independent Agencies (and Executive Agencies), 
    98 Cornell L. Rev. 769
    , 834-35 (2013); Note, The SEC Is Not an Independent Agency,
    
    126 Harv. L. Rev. 781
    , 801 (2013). We need not tackle that
    29
    Have there been any independent agencies headed by a
    single person? Prior to oral argument, in an effort to be
    comprehensive, the Court issued an order asking the CFPB for
    all historical or current examples it could find of independent
    agencies headed by a single person removable only for cause.
    The CFPB found only three examples: the Social Security
    Administration, the Office of Special Counsel, and the Federal
    Housing Finance Agency. Tr. of Oral Arg. at 19. But none
    of the three examples has deep historical roots. Indeed, the
    Federal Housing Finance Agency was created only in 2008,
    about the same time as the CFPB. The other two are likewise
    relatively recent.       And those other two have been
    constitutionally contested by the Executive Branch, and they
    do not exercise the core Article II executive power of bringing
    law enforcement actions or imposing fines and penalties
    against private citizens for violation of statutes or agency rules.
    For those reasons, as we will explain, the three examples are
    different in kind from the CFPB and other independent
    agencies such as the FCC, the SEC, and FERC. Those
    examples therefore do not count for much when weighed
    against the deeply rooted historical practice demonstrating that
    independent agencies are multi-member agencies. To borrow
    the words of Justice Breyer in Noel Canning, as compared to
    the settled historical practice, “we regard these few scattered
    examples as anomalies.” NLRB v. Noel Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. 2550
    , 2567, slip op. at 21 (2014); see also Free Enterprise
    Fund v. Public Company Accounting Oversight Board, 
    561 U.S. 477
    , 505-06 (2010).
    question in this case and do not imply an answer one way or the other
    about the executive or independent status of the multi-member
    agencies without express for-cause removal provisions.
    30
    First, the CFPB cited and primarily relied on the example
    of the Social Security Administration, which is an independent
    agency headed by a single Social Security Commissioner.
    See 
    42 U.S.C. §§ 901
    (a), 902(a). But the current structure of
    the agency is relatively recent.          The Social Security
    Administration long existed first as a multi-member
    independent agency and then as a single-Director executive
    agency within various executive departments, most recently
    the Department of Health and Human Services. Only in 1994
    did Congress change the Social Security Administration to a
    single-Director independent agency. Importantly, when the
    agency structure was altered in 1994, President Clinton issued
    a signing statement expressing his view that the change in the
    agency’s structure was constitutionally problematic. See
    President William J. Clinton, Statement on Signing the Social
    Security Independence and Program Improvements Act of
    1994, 2 Pub. Papers 1471, 1472 (Aug. 15, 1994). The status
    of that agency’s structure therefore is constitutionally
    contested. In those circumstances, the historical precedent
    counts for little because it is not settled. Cf. Noel Canning,
    
    134 S. Ct. at 2563-64, 2567
    , slip op. at 14-15, 20-21
    (discounting prior example of appointments during “fictitious”
    inter-session recess because of Senate Committee’s strong
    opposition to those appointments); INS v. Chadha, 
    462 U.S. 919
    , 942 n.13 (1983) (discounting prior statutory legislative
    veto provisions because Presidents had objected to those
    provisions). If anything, when considered against the “settled
    practice,” the Social Security example only highlights the
    “anomal[y]” of an independent agency headed by a single
    person. Noel Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. at 2567
    , slip op. at 21.
    Moreover, the Social Security Administration is not a
    precedent for the CFPB because the Social Security
    Commissioner does not possess unilateral authority to bring
    law enforcement actions against private citizens, which is the
    31
    core of the executive power and the primary threat to
    individual liberty posed by executive power. See Morrison v.
    Olson, 
    487 U.S. 654
    , 706 (1988) (Scalia, J., dissenting). The
    Social Security Administration does not have unilateral power
    to impose fines or penalties on private citizens in Social
    Security benefits cases. Instead, the bulk of the Social
    Security Administration’s authority involves supervision of the
    adjudication of private claims for benefits. Although the
    agency does possess limited power to seek civil sanctions
    against those who file improper claims, the Commissioner may
    initiate such a proceeding “only as authorized by the Attorney
    General” – who is an executive officer accountable to the
    President. 42 U.S.C. § 1320a-8(b).
    Second, the CFPB also cited the example of the Office of
    Special Counsel, an independent agency headed by a single
    Special Counsel. The Office has a narrow jurisdiction and
    mainly enforces certain personnel rules against government
    employers and employees, such as the prohibition against
    improper political activity by government employees. Like
    the Social Security Administration, the Office of Special
    Counsel lacks deep historical roots. Its single-Director
    structure was established in 1978. Also like the Social
    Security Administration, the constitutionality of the Special
    Counsel has been contested since its creation. Under
    President Carter, the Department of Justice opined that the
    Special Counsel “must be removable at will by the President”
    and expressed opposition to a for-cause removal restriction for
    the Special Counsel. Memorandum Opinion for the General
    Counsel, Civil Service Commission, 
    2 Op. O.L.C. 120
    , 120
    (1978).    When Congress passed subsequent legislation
    regarding the Office of Special Counsel, President Reagan
    vetoed the bill due to “serious constitutional concerns” about
    the Office’s status as an independent agency. See President
    Ronald Reagan, Memorandum of Disapproval on a Bill
    32
    Concerning Whistleblower Protection, 2 Pub. Papers 1391,
    1392 (Oct. 26, 1988). The history of the Office of Special
    Counsel confirms what one Special Counsel himself has
    acknowledged: the agency is “a controversial anomaly in the
    federal system.” K. William O’Connor, Foreword to SHIGEKI
    J. SUGIYAMA, PROTECTING THE INTEGRITY OF THE MERIT
    SYSTEM: A LEGISLATIVE HISTORY OF THE MERIT SYSTEM
    PRINCIPLES, PROHIBITED PERSONNEL PRACTICES AND THE
    OFFICE OF THE SPECIAL COUNSEL, at v (1985). The status of
    the agency remains constitutionally contested and does not
    supply a persuasive historical precedent for the CFPB’s
    structure. Cf. Noel Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. at 2563-64, 2567
    , slip
    op. at 14-15, 20-21; Chadha, 
    462 U.S. at
    942 n.13.
    Moreover, the Office of Special Counsel is not a precedent
    for the CFPB because the Office of Special Counsel is
    primarily responsible for enforcing personnel laws against
    government agencies and government employees. Unlike the
    CFPB, the Office of Special Counsel does not have authority to
    enforce laws against private citizens, and does not have power
    to impose fines and penalties on private citizens. 5
    5
    Because the Social Security Administration and the Office of
    Special Counsel do not exercise the core executive power of
    bringing law enforcement actions and because they have narrow
    jurisdiction, a holding invalidating the single-Director structure of
    the CFPB would not necessarily invalidate the single-Director
    structure of the Social Security Administration and the Office of
    Special Counsel.        That said, if those two agencies are
    unconstitutionally structured, the remedy would presumably be the
    same remedy as in Free Enterprise Fund: severing the for-cause
    provision so that the agencies would continue to fully operate, albeit
    as traditional executive agencies rather than independent agencies.
    Cf. infra pp. 65-69. We do not address those questions here.
    33
    Third, the CFPB cited Congress’s 2008 creation of a
    single head of the new Federal Housing Finance Agency. See
    Housing and Economic Recovery Act of 2008, Pub. L. No.
    110-289, § 1101, 
    122 Stat. 2654
    , 2662 (codified at 
    12 U.S.C. §§ 4511-4512
    ). That agency is a contemporary of the CFPB
    and merely raises the same question we confront here. A
    body created only in 2008 obviously does not constitute a
    historical precedent for the CFPB.
    Although not a regulatory agency precedent and not an
    example cited by the CFPB as precedent for its single-Director
    structure (for good reason), there is at least one other modern
    example of an independent entity headed by one person. It is
    the now-defunct independent counsel law that was upheld in
    Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. 654
     (1988). But that decision
    did not expressly consider whether an independent agency
    could be headed by a single director. The independent
    counsel, moreover, had only a limited jurisdiction for
    particular defined investigations. 
    Id. at 671-72
    . In addition,
    the independent counsel experiment ended with nearly
    universal consensus that the experiment had been a mistake
    and that Justice Scalia had been right back in 1988 to view the
    independent counsel system as an unconstitutional departure
    from historical practice and a serious threat to individual
    liberty. See 
    id. at 699
     (Scalia, J., dissenting) (“this wolf
    comes as a wolf”); see also Stanford Lawyer, Spring 2015, at 4
    (quoting Justice Kagan’s statement that Justice Scalia’s dissent
    in Morrison is “one of the greatest dissents ever written and
    every year it gets better”).        The independent counsel
    experience, if anything, strongly counsels caution with respect
    to single-Director independent agencies. 6
    6
    Some have suggested that the CFPB Director is similar to the
    Comptroller of the Currency. But unlike the Director, the
    Comptroller is not independent. The Comptroller is removable at
    34
    So that’s all the CFPB has, and that’s not much. As
    Justice Breyer stated when facing a similar (actually, a more
    robust) historical record in Noel Canning, the few examples
    offered by the CFPB are “anomalies.” 
    134 S. Ct. at 2567
    , slip
    op. at 21. Or as the Court put it in Free Enterprise Fund when
    confronting a novel structure, a “handful of isolated” examples
    does not count for much when assessed against an otherwise
    settled historical practice. 
    561 U.S. at 505
    . To be sure, in
    “all the laws enacted since 1789, it is always possible that
    Congress” created some other independent agencies like the
    CFPB “that exercise[] traditional executive functions” but are
    headed by single Directors. Free Enterprise Fund v. Public
    Company Accounting Oversight Board, 
    537 F.3d 667
    , 699 n.8
    (D.C. Cir. 2008) (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting); see also Noel
    Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. at 2567
    , slip op. at 21 (“There may be
    others of which we are unaware.”). But “the research of the
    parties and the Court has not found such a needle in the
    haystack.” Free Enterprise Fund, 
    537 F.3d at
    699 n.8
    (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting). “Even if such an example were
    uncovered,” there is no question that this kind of
    single-Director independent agency “has been rare at best.”
    
    Id.
    The bottom line is that there is no settled historical
    practice of independent agencies headed by single Directors
    who possess the substantial executive authority that the
    Director of the CFPB enjoys. The CFPB is exceptional in our
    constitutional structure and unprecedented in our constitutional
    history. See Who’s Watching the Watchmen? Oversight of the
    will by the President. See 
    12 U.S.C. § 2
     (“The Comptroller of the
    Currency shall be appointed by the President, by and with the advice
    and consent of the Senate, and shall hold his office for a term of five
    years unless sooner removed by the President, upon reasons to be
    communicated by him to the Senate.”).
    35
    Consumer Financial Protection Bureau: Hearing Before the
    Subcomm. on TARP, Financial Services and Bailouts of Public
    and Private Programs of the H. Comm. on Oversight and
    Government Reform, 112th Cong. 77 (2011) (statement of
    Andrew Pincus) (“Dodd-Frank sets up for the Bureau an
    unprecedented structure that consolidates more power in the
    director than in the head of any other agency that regulates
    private individuals and entities.”); Recent Legislation,
    Dodd-Frank Act Creates the Consumer Financial Protection
    Bureau, 
    124 Harv. L. Rev. 2123
    , 2130 (2011) (“[T]he CFPB’s
    design is troubling because of its unprecedented nature.”);
    Note, Independence, Congressional Weakness, and the
    Importance of Appointment: The Impact of Combining
    Budgetary Autonomy with Removal Protection, 
    125 Harv. L. Rev. 1822
    , 1824 n.15 (2012) (CFPB’s lack of a multi-member
    board is “atypical for independent agencies and will amplify
    the Director’s independence”); Todd Zywicki, The Consumer
    Financial Protection Bureau: Savior or Menace? 
    81 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 856
    , 899 (2013) (“[T]he agency structure
    Congress chose for the CFPB – a single-director structure,
    devoid of accountability, and with vast, ill-defined powers –
    appears to be unique in recent American history.”). 7
    7
    The historical practice is further illustrated by the quorum
    provisions that are applicable to independent agencies. Those
    quorum provisions reinforce the settled understanding that
    independent agencies are to have multiple members. Cf. New
    Process Steel, L.P. v. NLRB, 
    560 U.S. 674
     (2010); Marshall J. Breger
    & Gary J. Edles, Established by Practice: The Theory and Operation
    of Independent Federal Agencies, 
    52 Admin. L. Rev. 1111
    , 1182 &
    app. (2000) (summarizing independent agency quorum
    requirements).
    36
    C
    The CFPB’s departure from historical practice matters.
    A long line of Supreme Court precedent tells us that history
    and tradition are important guides in separation of powers
    cases that, like this one, are not resolved by the constitutional
    text alone. As Justice Breyer wrote for the Supreme Court in
    Noel Canning, the “longstanding practice of the government
    can inform our determination of what the law is.” NLRB v.
    Noel Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. 2550
    , 2560, slip op. at 7 (2014)
    (internal quotation marks and citation omitted). Justice
    Breyer quoted James Madison’s statement that it was “foreseen
    at the birth of the Constitution, that difficulties and differences
    of opinion might occasionally arise in expounding terms &
    phrases necessarily used in such a charter . . . and that it might
    require a regular course of practice to liquidate & settle the
    meaning of some of them.” 
    Id.,
     slip op. at 8 (internal
    quotation marks omitted).            Justice Breyer explained,
    moreover, that the Court “has treated practice as an important
    interpretive factor even when the nature or longevity of that
    practice is subject to dispute, and even when that practice
    began after the founding era.” 
    Id.,
     slip op. at 7-8.
    All of this, Justice Breyer stated, is “neither new nor
    controversial.” 
    Id.,
     slip op. at 7. Consider the following:
    •   “In separation-of-powers cases this Court has often put
    significant weight upon historical practice.”
    Zivotofsky v. Kerry, 
    135 S. Ct. 2076
    , 2091, slip op. at
    20 (2015) (internal quotation marks omitted) (quoting
    Noel Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. at 2559
    , slip op. at 6).
    •   “We therefore conclude, in light of historical practice,
    that a recess of more than 3 days but less than 10 days is
    presumptively too short to fall within the Clause.”
    Noel Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. at 2567
    , slip op. at 21.
    37
    •   “Perhaps the most telling indication of the severe
    constitutional problem with the [agency] is the lack of
    historical precedent for this entity.” Free Enterprise
    Fund v. Public Company Accounting Oversight Board,
    
    561 U.S. 477
    , 505 (2010) (internal quotation marks
    omitted).
    •   “[W]hen we face difficult questions of the
    Constitution’s structural requirements, longstanding
    customs and practices can make a difference.”
    Commonwealth of Puerto Rico v. Sanchez Valle, 
    136 S. Ct. 1863
    , 1884, slip op. at 13 (2016) (Breyer, J.,
    dissenting).
    •   “[T]raditional ways of conducting government give
    meaning to the Constitution.” Mistretta v. United
    States, 
    488 U.S. 361
    , 401 (1989) (internal quotation
    marks and alteration omitted) (quoting Youngstown
    Sheet & Tube Co. v. Sawyer, 
    343 U.S. 579
    , 610 (1952)
    (Frankfurter, J., concurring)).
    •   “Deeply embedded traditional ways of conducting
    government cannot supplant the Constitution or
    legislation, but they give meaning to the words of a text
    or supply them.” Youngstown, 
    343 U.S. at 610
    (Frankfurter, J., concurring).
    •   “A legislative practice such as we have here, evidenced
    not by only occasional instances, but marked by the
    movement of a steady stream for a century and a half of
    time, goes a long way in the direction of proving the
    presence      of    unassailable   ground     for     the
    constitutionality of the practice, to be found in the
    origin and history of the power involved, or in its
    nature, or in both combined.” United States v.
    Curtiss-Wright Export Corp., 
    299 U.S. 304
    , 327-28
    (1936).
    •   “Long settled and established practice is a
    consideration of great weight in a proper interpretation
    38
    of constitutional provisions of this character.” The
    Pocket Veto Case, 
    279 U.S. 655
    , 689 (1929).
    •    “Such long practice under the pardoning power and
    acquiescence in it strongly sustains the construction it
    is based on.” Ex parte Grossman, 
    267 U.S. 87
    , 118-19
    (1925).
    •    “[A] page of history is worth a volume of logic.” New
    York Trust Co. v. Eisner, 
    256 U.S. 345
    , 349 (1921).
    •    “[I]n determining the meaning of a statute or the
    existence of a power, weight shall be given to the usage
    itself – even when the validity of the practice is the
    subject of investigation.” United States v. Midwest
    Oil Co., 
    236 U.S. 459
    , 473 (1915).
    •    “[W]here there is ambiguity or doubt [in the words of
    the Constitution], or where two views may well be
    entertained, contemporaneous and subsequent practical
    construction are entitled to the greatest weight.”
    McPherson v. Blacker, 
    146 U.S. 1
    , 27 (1892).
    •    “[A] doubtful question, one on which human reason
    may pause, and the human judgment be suspended, in
    the decision of which the great principles of liberty are
    not concerned, but the respective powers of those who
    are equally the representatives of the people, are to be
    adjusted; if not put at rest by the practice of the
    government, ought to receive a considerable
    impression from that practice.”          McCulloch v.
    Maryland, 
    17 U.S. 316
    , 401 (1819).
    Stated simply, in separation of powers cases not resolved
    by the constitutional text alone, historical practice matters a
    great deal in defining the constitutional limits on the Executive
    and Legislative Branches. 8 The Supreme Court’s recent
    8
    The Supreme Court has heavily relied on historical practice as
    a guide not just in separation of powers cases, but also in federalism
    39
    decisions in Noel Canning and Free Enterprise Fund illustrate
    how the Court considers historical practice in this context. 9
    cases. In several federalism cases in the last 25 years, the Court has
    invalidated novel congressional statutes that alter the traditional
    federal-state balance. See New York v. United States, 
    505 U.S. 144
    ,
    177 (1992) (“The take title provision appears to be unique. No
    other federal statute has been cited which offers a state government
    no option other than that of implementing legislation enacted by
    Congress.”); Printz v. United States, 
    521 U.S. 898
    , 905 (1997) (“[I]f,
    as petitioners contend, earlier Congresses avoided use of this highly
    attractive power, we would have reason to believe that the power
    was thought not to exist.”); Alden v. Maine, 
    527 U.S. 706
    , 744
    (1999) (“Not only were statutes purporting to authorize private suits
    against nonconsenting States in state courts not enacted by early
    Congresses; statutes purporting to authorize such suits in any forum
    are all but absent from our historical experience. . . . The provisions
    of the FLSA at issue here, which were enacted in the aftermath of
    Parden, are among the first statutory enactments purporting in
    express terms to subject nonconsenting States to private suits.”);
    United States v. Windsor, 
    133 S. Ct. 2675
    , 2692, slip op. at 18-19
    (2013) (“DOMA, because of its reach and extent, departs from this
    history and tradition of reliance on state law to define marriage.”); cf.
    National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius, 
    132 S. Ct. 2566
    , 2586, slip op. at 18 (2012) (binding opinion of Roberts, C.J.)
    (“But Congress has never attempted to rely on that power to compel
    individuals not engaged in commerce to purchase an unwanted
    product.”); 
    id. at 2649
    , slip op. at 14 (joint dissent of Scalia,
    Kennedy, Thomas, and Alito, JJ.) (“[T]he relevant history is not that
    Congress has achieved wide and wonderful results through the
    proper exercise of its assigned powers in the past, but that it has
    never before used the Commerce Clause to compel entry into
    commerce.”).
    9
    Of course, if the constitutional text is sufficiently clear, then
    the existence of any historical practice departing from that text is not
    persuasive. See, e.g., INS v. Chadha, 
    462 U.S. 919
    , 944-46 (1983);
    Powell v. McCormack, 
    395 U.S. 486
    , 546-47 (1969). Here, the
    question concerns the scope of Humphrey’s Executor – which,
    40
    In Noel Canning, the Supreme Court speaking through
    Justice Breyer stressed the importance of history when
    assessing the constitutionality of a novel practice – in that case,
    Presidential recess appointments in Senate recesses of fewer
    than 10 days. The Court said: “Long settled and established
    practice is a consideration of great weight in a proper
    interpretation of constitutional provisions regulating the
    relationship between Congress and the President.” Noel
    Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. at 2559
    , slip op. at 7 (internal quotation
    marks and alteration omitted). Based on that history, the
    Supreme Court ruled that a Senate recess of “less than 10 days
    is presumptively too short” for constitutional purposes. 
    Id. at 2567
    , slip op. at 21. Importantly, the text of the Constitution
    did not draw any such 10-day line. But the historical practice
    between the President and the Senate had settled on a 10-day
    line.
    In ruling out recess appointments in recesses of fewer than
    10 days, the Noel Canning Court stated that it had “not found a
    single example of a recess appointment made during an
    intra-session recess that was shorter than 10 days.” 
    Id. at 2566
    , slip op. at 20. The Court explained that the “lack of
    examples suggests that the recess-appointment power is not
    needed in that context.” 
    Id.
     Although the Court did find “a
    few historical examples of recess appointments made during
    inter-session recesses shorter than 10 days,” the Court stated:
    “But when considered against 200 years of settled practice, we
    depending on one’s perspective, requires either an analysis of a
    court-created exception to Article II or an analysis of ambiguous
    constitutional text in Articles I and II. Either way, in resolving
    those kinds of separation of powers questions, history and tradition
    play a critical role. See Noel Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. at 2559-60
    , slip
    op. at 6-8; Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 505-06
    .
    41
    regard these few scattered examples as anomalies.” Id. at
    2567, slip op. at 20-21.
    According to the Court, therefore, allowing recess
    appointments in Senate recesses of fewer than 10 days would
    depart from the settled historical practice and alter the relative
    powers of the President and Senate over appointments. So,
    too, disallowing recess appointments in Senate recesses of 10
    or more days would depart from settled historical practice. In
    Noel Canning, the Supreme Court therefore converted that
    historical 10-day practice into a constitutional rule. 10
    The Supreme Court engaged in the same kind of
    history-based analysis in Free Enterprise Fund. Independent
    agency heads are ordinarily removable for cause by the
    President. In that case, however, the new Accounting
    Oversight Board’s members were removable only for cause by
    the Commissioners of the SEC, and the SEC Commissioners in
    turn were understood to be removable only for cause by the
    10
    Justice Scalia concurred in the judgment for four Justices in
    Noel Canning, arguing as relevant here that the text of the
    Constitution rendered intra-session recess appointments
    unconstitutional even in Senate recesses of 10 or more days. But
    Justice Scalia did not disagree with the Court’s claim that historical
    practice often matters in separation of powers cases, which is the
    relevant point for our purposes. See Noel Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. at 2594
    , slip op. at 5 (Scalia, J., concurring in the judgment) (“Of
    course, where a governmental practice has been open, widespread,
    and unchallenged since the early days of the Republic, the practice
    should guide our interpretation of an ambiguous constitutional
    provision.”). Rather, Justice Scalia stated that the constitutional
    text in that case was sufficiently clear and dispositive that resort to
    historical practice was unnecessary and unwarranted. See 
    id. at 2592
    , slip op. at 2; see generally John F. Manning, Separation of
    Powers as Ordinary Interpretation, 
    124 Harv. L. Rev. 1939
     (2011).
    42
    President. In other words, there were two levels of for-cause
    removal between the President and the Accounting Oversight
    Board.
    The Supreme Court drew a line between one level of
    for-cause removal, which was the structure of traditional
    independent agencies, and two levels of for-cause removal, the
    novel structure of the new Accounting Oversight Board. See
    Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 484
    . The Court ruled that
    the latter was unconstitutional. The Court drew that line in
    part because historical practice had settled on one level of
    for-cause removal for a President to remove the head of an
    independent agency. There were at most “only a handful of
    isolated” precedents for the new Board. 
    Id. at 505
    . The vast
    majority of the extant independent agencies had only one level
    of for-cause removal. And as the Court noted, there was a
    meaningful difference between one level of for-cause removal
    and two levels of for-cause removal in terms of an agency’s
    insulation from Presidential control. See 
    id. at 495-96
    .
    Therefore, the Court invalidated the structure of the new
    Board. 11
    Those two cases well illustrate the broader jurisprudential
    principle long applied by the Supreme Court: In separation of
    powers cases not resolved by the constitutional text alone,
    historical practice matters.
    11
    Justice Breyer dissented for four Justices in Free Enterprise
    Fund. But importantly, he dissented not because he disagreed with
    the Court’s point that historical practice matters, but rather primarily
    because he did not see a meaningful difference – in practical,
    analytical, or constitutional terms – between one and two levels of
    for-cause removal. See Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 525-26
    (Breyer, J., dissenting).
    43
    D
    The CFPB marks a major departure from the settled
    historical practice requiring multi-member bodies at the helm
    of independent agencies. Because this case is not resolved
    solely by the constitutional text, at least as the text was
    interpreted in Humphrey’s Executor, the CFPB’s departure
    from historical practice matters to the analysis. And the
    departure from historical practice matters even more in this
    instance because this departure from historical practice
    threatens individual liberty. The historical practice of
    structuring independent agencies as multi-member
    commissions or boards is the historical practice for a reason:
    It reflects a deep and abiding concern for safeguarding the
    individual liberty protected by the Constitution.
    “The Framers recognized that, in the long term, structural
    protections against abuse of power were critical to preserving
    liberty.” Bowsher v. Synar, 
    478 U.S. 714
    , 730 (1986); see
    also 
    id. at 721
     (“The declared purpose of separating and
    dividing the powers of government, of course, was to ‘diffus[e]
    power the better to secure liberty.’”) (quoting Youngstown
    Sheet & Tube Co. v. Sawyer, 
    343 U.S. 579
    , 635 (1952)
    (Jackson, J., concurring)). When describing Article II, Justice
    Scalia put the point this way: “The purpose of the separation
    and equilibration of powers in general, and of the unitary
    Executive in particular, was not merely to assure effective
    government but to preserve individual freedom.” Morrison v.
    Olson, 
    487 U.S. 654
    , 727 (1988) (Scalia, J., dissenting).
    The basic constitutional concern with independent
    agencies is that the agencies are unchecked by the President,
    the official who is accountable to the people and who is made
    responsible by Article II for the exercise of executive power.
    Recognizing the broad and unaccountable power wielded by
    44
    independent agencies, Congress has traditionally required
    multi-member bodies at the helm of independent agencies. In
    the absence of Presidential control, the multi-member structure
    of independent agencies acts as a critical substitute check on
    the excesses of any individual independent agency head – a
    check that helps to prevent arbitrary decisionmaking and abuse
    of power, and thereby to protect individual liberty.
    But this new agency, the CFPB, lacks that critical check
    and structural constitutional protection. And the lack of the
    traditional safeguard threatens the individual liberty protected
    by the Constitution’s separation of powers.
    How do multi-member independent agencies fare better
    than single-Director independent agencies in protecting
    individual liberty?       As compared to single-Director
    independent agencies, multi-member independent agencies
    help prevent arbitrary decisionmaking and abuses of power,
    and thereby help protect individual liberty, because they do not
    concentrate power in the hands of one individual. The point is
    simple but profound. In a multi-member independent agency,
    no single commissioner or board member possesses authority
    to do much of anything. Before the agency can infringe your
    liberty in some way – for example, initiating an enforcement
    action against you or issuing a rule that affects your liberty or
    property – a majority of commissioners must agree. That in
    turn makes it harder for the agency to infringe your liberty.
    As the current Chair of the Federal Trade Commission has
    explained, it takes “a consensus decision of at least a majority
    of commissioners to authorize, or forbear from, action.”
    Edith Ramirez, The FTC: A Framework for Promoting
    Competition and Protecting Consumers, 
    83 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 2049
    , 2053 (2015). In a multi-member agency, even
    though each individual commissioner is not accountable to or
    checked by the President, each commissioner is at least still
    45
    accountable to his or her fellow commissioners and needs the
    assent of a majority of commissioners to take significant
    action.
    In addition, unlike single-Director independent agencies,
    multi-member independent agencies “can foster more
    deliberative decision making.” Kirti Datla & Richard L.
    Revesz, Deconstructing Independent Agencies (and Executive
    Agencies), 
    98 Cornell L. Rev. 769
    , 794 (2013). Relatedly,
    multi-member independent agencies benefit from diverse
    perspectives and different points of view among the
    commissioners and board members. The multiple voices and
    perspectives make it more likely that the costs and downsides
    of proposed decisions will be more fully ventilated. See
    Marshall J. Breger & Gary J. Edles, Established by Practice:
    The Theory and Operation of Independent Federal Agencies,
    
    52 Admin. L. Rev. 1111
    , 1113 (2000) (independent agencies
    “are also multi-member organizations, a fact that tends toward
    accommodation of diverse or extreme views through the
    compromise inherent in the process of collegial
    decisionmaking”); Jacob E. Gersen, Administrative Law Goes
    to Wall Street: The New Administrative Process, 
    65 Admin. L. Rev. 689
    , 696 (2013) (“[A] multimember board allows for a
    representation of divergent interests in a way that a single
    decisionmaker simply cannot.”); Glen O. Robinson, On
    Reorganizing the Independent Regulatory Agencies, 
    57 Va. L. Rev. 947
    , 963 (1971) (“It is not bipartisanship as such that is
    important; it is rather the safeguards and balanced viewpoint
    that can be provided by plural membership.”); cf. Harry T.
    Edwards, The Effects of Collegiality on Judicial Decision
    Making, 
    151 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1639
    , 1645 (2003) (“[C]ollegiality
    plays an important part in mitigating the role of partisan
    politics and personal ideology by allowing judges of differing
    perspectives and philosophies to communicate with, listen to,
    46
    and ultimately influence one another in constructive and
    law-abiding ways.”).
    In short, the deliberative process and multiple viewpoints
    in a multi-member independent agency can help ensure that an
    agency does not wrongly bring an enforcement action or adopt
    rules that unduly infringe individual liberty.
    As compared to a single-Director structure, a
    multi-member independent agency also helps to avoid
    arbitrary decisionmaking and to protect individual liberty
    because the multi-member structure – and its inherent
    requirement for compromise and consensus – will tend to lead
    to decisions that are not as extreme, idiosyncratic, or otherwise
    off the rails. Cf. Stephen M. Bainbridge, Why a Board?
    Group Decisionmaking in Corporate Governance, 
    55 Vand. L. Rev. 1
    , 12-19 (2002) (summarizing experimental evidence
    finding group decisionmaking to be superior to individual
    decisionmaking). A multi-member independent agency can
    only go as far as the middle vote is willing to go. Conversely,
    under a single-Director structure, an agency’s policy goals
    “will be subject to the whims and idiosyncratic views of a
    single      individual.”        Joshua     D.    Wright,     The
    Antitrust/Consumer Protection Paradox: Two Policies at War
    with Each Other, 
    121 Yale L.J. 2216
    , 2260 (2012) (internal
    quotation marks omitted); cf. Recent Legislation, Dodd-Frank
    Act Creates the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, 
    124 Harv. L. Rev. 2123
    , 2128 (2011) (multi-member commission
    structure “reduces the variance of policy and improves
    accuracy through aggregation”); Michael B. Rappaport, Essay,
    Replacing Independent Counsels with Congressional
    Investigations, 
    148 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1595
    , 1601 n.17 (2000)
    (“[I]ndependent agencies tend to be headed by multimember
    commissions, which function to prevent aberrant
    actions . . . .”).
    47
    Relatedly, as compared to a single-Director independent
    agency, a multi-member independent agency provides the
    added benefit of “a built-in monitoring system for interests on
    both sides because that type of body is more likely to produce a
    dissent if the agency goes too far in one direction.” Rachel E.
    Barkow, Insulating Agencies: Avoiding Capture Through
    Institutional Design, 
    89 Tex. L. Rev. 15
    , 41 (2010). A
    dissent, in turn, can serve “as a ‘fire alarm’ that alerts Congress
    and the public at large that the agency’s decision might merit
    closer scrutiny.” Id.; see also Dodd-Frank Act Creates the
    Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, 124 Harv. L. Rev. at
    2128 (the “presence of dissenters” in agency proceedings
    “provides new information and forces the proponent to
    articulate a coherent rationale, thus acting as a constraining
    force”).
    Moreover, multi-member independent agencies are better
    structured than single-Director independent agencies to guard
    against “capture” of – that is, undue influence over – the
    independent agencies by regulated entities or interest groups,
    for example. As then-Professor Elizabeth Warren noted in
    her original proposal for a multi-member consumer protection
    agency: “With every agency, the fear of regulatory capture is
    ever-present.” Elizabeth Warren, Unsafe at Any Rate: If It’s
    Good Enough for Microwaves, It’s Good Enough for
    Mortgages. Why We Need a Financial Product Safety
    Commission, Democracy, Summer 2007, at 8, 18. Capture
    can infringe individual liberty because capture can prevent a
    neutral, impartial agency assessment of what rules to issue and
    what enforcement actions to undertake. In a multi-member
    agency, however, the capturing parties “must capture a
    majority of the membership rather than just one individual.”
    Lisa Schultz Bressman & Robert B. Thompson, The Future of
    Agency Independence, 
    63 Vand. L. Rev. 599
    , 611 (2010); see
    48
    also ROBERT E. CUSHMAN, THE INDEPENDENT REGULATORY
    COMMISSIONS 153 (Octagon Books 1972) (1941) (noting, in
    reference to Federal Reserve Act of 1913, that it “seemed
    easier to protect a board from political control than to protect a
    single appointed official”); Barkow, Insulating Agencies, 89
    Tex. L. Rev. at 38 (“[O]nly one person at the apex can also
    mean that the agency is more easily captured.”); Robinson, On
    Reorganizing the Independent Regulatory Agencies, 57 Va. L.
    Rev. at 962 (“[T]he single administrator may be more
    vulnerable” to interest group pressures “because he provides a
    sharper focus for the concentration of special interest power
    and influence.”).
    Importantly, all of those features and benefits of
    multi-member independent agencies are not merely accidental
    or coincidental byproducts. Those points were in the minds of
    the Members of Congress who helped launch independent
    agencies. For example, Senator Newlands, the sponsor of the
    legislation creating the Federal Trade Commission,
    emphasized the need for a commission rather than a single
    Director: “If only powers of investigation and publicity are
    given[,] a single-headed organization, like the Bureau of
    Corporations, might be the best for the work; but if judgment
    and discretion are to be exercised, or if we have in
    contemplation the exercise of any corrective power hereafter,
    or if the broad ends above outlined are to be attained, it seems
    to me that a commission is required.” 51 Cong. Rec. 11,092
    (1914). In his leading study of independent commissions,
    Robert Cushman, former staff member of President Franklin
    Roosevelt’s Committee on Administrative Management,
    analyzed the creation of the Federal Trade Commission and
    explained: “The two ideas, a commission and independence
    for the commission, were inextricably bound together. At no
    point was it proposed that a commission ought to be set up
    unless it be independent or that an independent officer should
    49
    be created rather than a commission.” CUSHMAN, THE
    INDEPENDENT REGULATORY COMMISSIONS, at 188; see also
    THE PRESIDENT’S COMMITTEE ON ADMINISTRATIVE
    MANAGEMENT, REPORT OF THE COMMITTEE WITH STUDIES OF
    ADMINISTRATIVE       MANAGEMENT         IN    THE   FEDERAL
    GOVERNMENT 216 (1937) (noting “popular belief that
    important rule-making functions ought to be performed by a
    group rather than by a single officer, by a commission rather
    than by a department head” as one reason “for the
    establishment of independent regulatory agencies”).
    Examining the consistent historical practice here, we can
    see, moreover, that the consistent historical practice reflects the
    deep values of the Constitution. The Constitution as a whole
    embodies the bedrock principle that dividing power among
    multiple entities and persons helps protect individual liberty.
    The Framers created a federal system with the national power
    divided among three branches. The Framers “viewed the
    principle of separation of powers as the absolutely central
    guarantee of a just Government.” Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. at 697
     (Scalia, J., dissenting).
    And to protect liberty, the same kind of checks and
    balances principle also influenced how the Framers allocated
    power within the three national branches. For example, the
    Framers divided the Legislative Branch into two houses, each
    with multiple members. No one person operates as the
    Legislator-in-Chief. Rather, 535 Members of Congress do so,
    divided among two Houses.             Likewise, the Framers
    established “one supreme Court” composed of multiple
    “Judges” rather than a single judge. No one person operates
    as the lone Justice of the Supreme Court. Rather, the Court
    consists of one Chief Justice and several Associate Justices, all
    of whom have equal votes on cases. “Even a cursory
    examination of the Constitution reveals the influence of
    50
    Montesquieu’s thesis that checks and balances were the
    foundation of a structure of government that would protect
    liberty.” Bowsher, 
    478 U.S. at 722
    .
    Of course, the one exception to the Constitution’s division
    of power among multiple parties within the branches is the
    President, who is the lone head of the entire Executive Branch.
    But the President is the exception that proves the rule. For
    starters, the Framers were concerned that dividing the
    executive power among multiple individuals would render the
    Executive Branch too weak as compared to the more
    formidable Legislative Branch. See THE FEDERALIST NO. 48,
    at 309-10 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (“[I]t
    is against the enterprising ambition” of the Legislative Branch
    “that the people ought to indulge all their jealousy and exhaust
    all their precautions. The legislative department derives a
    superiority in our governments . . . .”). The Framers sought
    “energy in the executive.” THE FEDERALIST NO. 70, at 424
    (Alexander Hamilton).
    At the same time, the Framers certainly recognized the
    risk that a single President could lead to tyranny or arbitrary
    decisionmaking. To mitigate the risk to liberty from a single
    President, the Framers ensured that the President had “a due
    dependence on the people.” 
    Id.
     The President is nationally
    elected by the people. In choosing the President, “the whole
    Nation has a part, making him the focus of public hopes and
    expectations.” Youngstown, 
    343 U.S. at 653
     (Jackson, J.,
    concurring). Presidential candidates are put through the
    wringer precisely because of the power they may someday
    wield. In other words, the Framers concentrated executive
    power in a single President on the condition that the President
    would be nationally elected and nationally accountable.
    51
    The President is therefore the exception to the ordinary
    constitutional practice of dividing power among multiple
    entities and persons.         Apart from the President, the
    Constitution reflects the basic commonsense principle that
    multi-member bodies – the House, the Senate, the Supreme
    Court – do better than single-member bodies in avoiding
    arbitrary decisionmaking and abuses of power, and thereby
    protecting individual liberty. That background constitutional
    principle further supports the conclusion here that a
    single-Director independent agency lies outside the norm and
    poses a risk to individual liberty. After all, the Director of the
    CFPB is not elected by the people and is of course not remotely
    comparable to the President in terms of accountability to the
    people.
    Having identified the ways in which multi-member
    independent agencies surpass single-Director independent
    agencies in protecting liberty, we must acknowledge that
    multi-member independent agencies do not always meet that
    potential. For example, some members of multi-member
    independent agencies may occasionally move in lockstep,
    thereby diminishing the benefits of multi-member bodies. It
    can be harder to find five highly qualified commissioners than
    just one highly qualified commissioner.               Moreover,
    multi-member bodies are often not as efficient as
    single-headed agencies and can be beset by contentious
    relations among the members.           See Breger & Edles,
    Established by Practice, 52 Admin. L. Rev. at 1181 (“even a
    single member” can throw a wrench into the works); Datla &
    Revesz, Deconstructing Independent Agencies, 98 Cornell L.
    Rev. at 794 (“The downside that accompanies increased
    deliberation is the slowness inherent in group action.”)
    (internal quotation marks omitted). That said, “[c]onvenience
    and efficiency are not the primary objectives – or the hallmarks
    – of democratic government.” Bowsher, 
    478 U.S. at
    736
    52
    (internal quotation marks omitted). Indeed, so as to avoid
    falling back into the kind of tyranny that they had declared
    independence from, the Framers often made trade-offs against
    efficiency in the interest of enhancing liberty.
    In any event, notwithstanding some failings and
    downsides, multi-member independent agencies are superior
    to single-Director independent agencies in preventing arbitrary
    decisionmaking and abuse of power, and thereby protecting
    individual liberty.
    For that reason and others, both before and after
    Humphrey’s Executor, Congress has structured independent
    agencies as multi-member agencies.                      Indeed, the
    multi-member agency form has become “synonymous with
    independence.” Breger & Edles, Established by Practice, 52
    Admin. L. Rev. at 1137. As Justice Breyer noted in Free
    Enterprise Fund: “Agency independence is a function of
    several different factors . . . includ[ing] . . . its composition as
    a multimember bipartisan board . . . .” Free Enterprise Fund
    v. Public Company Accounting Oversight Board, 
    561 U.S. 477
    , 547 (2010) (Breyer, J., dissenting). Likewise, Professor
    Barkow has explained that “multimember design” is one of the
    “[t]raditional [l]odestars” of agency independence. Barkow,
    Insulating Agencies, 89 Tex. L. Rev. at 26; see also PETER L.
    STRAUSS, AN INTRODUCTION TO ADMINISTRATIVE JUSTICE IN
    THE UNITED STATES 15 (1989) (defining “independent
    regulatory commission[s]” as “governmental agencies headed
    by multi-member boards acting collegially on the regulatory
    matters within their jurisdiction”) (internal quotation marks
    omitted); Bressman & Thompson, The Future of Agency
    Independence, 63 Vand. L. Rev. at 610 (independent agencies,
    unlike Executive Branch agencies, are “generally run by
    multi-member commissions or boards”); Dodd-Frank Act
    Creates the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, 124 Harv.
    53
    L. Rev. at 2128 (“Most independent agencies have
    multimember boards . . . .”); Paperwork Reduction Act of
    1980, Pub. L. No. 96-511, 
    94 Stat. 2812
    , 2814 (defining
    “independent regulatory agency” by reference to 17
    multi-member agencies) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    E
    To sum up so far: In order to preserve individual liberty
    and ensure accountability, Article II of the Constitution assigns
    the executive power to the President. The President operates
    with the assistance of subordinates, but the President acts as a
    critical check on those subordinates. That check provides
    accountability and protects against arbitrary decisionmaking
    by executive agencies, thereby helping to safeguard individual
    liberty. Article II has been interpreted by the Supreme Court
    to allow independent agencies in certain circumstances.
    Independent agencies lack the ordinary constitutional checks
    and balances that come from Presidential supervision and
    direction. But to ensure some check against arbitrary
    decisionmaking and to help preserve individual liberty,
    independent agencies have traditionally been structured as
    multi-member bodies where the commissioners or board
    members can check one another. The check from other
    commissioners or board members substitutes for the check by
    the President. As an independent agency with just a single
    Director, the CFPB represents a sharp break from historical
    practice, lacks the critical internal check on arbitrary
    decisionmaking, and poses a far greater threat to individual
    liberty than does a multi-member independent agency. All of
    that raises grave constitutional doubts about the CFPB’s
    single-Director structure. 12
    12
    In identifying and cataloging the problems with a
    single-Director independent agency, we do not in any way question
    54
    Before rendering a final conclusion on the CFPB’s
    constitutionality as currently structured, however, we must
    address several other arguments.
    First, in considering precedents for the single-Director
    structure of the CFPB, one might wonder about all of the
    executive departments and agencies headed by a single person.
    Why don’t they provide a precedent for the CFPB? Consider
    for example the Department of Justice, the Department of the
    Treasury, the Department of State, the Department of Defense,
    and the EPA, all headed by a single person.
    As should be clear by now, the distinction, of course, is
    that those departments and agencies are executive agencies.
    They operate within the Executive Branch chain of command
    under the supervision and direction of the President, and those
    agency heads are removable at will by the President. The
    President is a check on those agencies. Those agencies are
    accountable to the President. The President in turn is
    accountable to the people of the United States for the exercise
    of executive power in the executive agencies. So a single
    person at the helm of an executive agency is perfectly
    constitutional. 13
    the integrity of the current Director, a man of substantial
    accomplishment and of longstanding and dedicated devotion to
    public service and the public good. Cf. Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. 654
    , 731 (1988) (Scalia, J., dissenting) (similarly describing the
    Special Division judges and independent counsel at issue in that
    case). But the constitutionality of an agency structure “must be
    adjudged on the basis of what it permits to happen.” 
    Id.
    13
    Congress may of course establish executive agencies that are
    headed by multiple individuals (although it rarely does so), but each
    member must be removable at will by the President for the agency to
    maintain its status as an executive agency.
    55
    By contrast, independent agencies are unaccountable to
    the President and pose a greater threat to individual liberty
    because they operate free of the President’s supervision and
    direction. Therefore, they traditionally have been headed by
    multiple members who check one another. An independent
    agency operates as “a body of experts appointed by law and
    informed by experience.” Humphrey’s Executor v. United
    States, 
    295 U.S. 602
    , 624 (1935) (internal quotation marks
    omitted).
    Second, some may say that Congress’s creation of the
    single-Director structure is unlikely to give Congress any
    greater influence over the CFPB than Congress possesses over
    a multi-member independent agency. That is perhaps true,
    although perhaps not. Either way, however, the Supreme
    Court has emphasized that congressional aggrandizement is
    not a necessary feature of a separation of powers violation in
    this context. The Court squarely said as much in Free
    Enterprise Fund. See Free Enterprise Fund v. Public
    Company Accounting Oversight Board, 
    561 U.S. 477
    , 500
    (2010) (“Even when a branch does not arrogate power to itself,
    therefore, it must not impair another in the performance of its
    constitutional duties.”) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    And to take an obvious example of the point, if Congress
    enacted legislation converting the Department of Justice into
    an independent agency, there would be no formal
    congressional aggrandizement. But there is little doubt that
    such legislation would violate Article II. See Morrison v.
    Olson, 
    487 U.S. 654
    , 695 (1988) (Congress may not impair the
    President in performance of constitutionally assigned
    functions). Congressional aggrandizement is not a necessary
    condition for an Article II violation in this context.
    56
    Relatedly, one might think that a single head of an
    independent agency might actually be more responsive to the
    President than multiple heads of an independent agency are,
    thereby reducing the risk of arbitrary decisionmaking and
    mitigating the Article II concern with a novel single-Director
    independent agency. But there is no meaningful difference in
    responsiveness and accountability to the President. Whether
    headed by one, three, or five members, an independent agency
    is not supervised or directed by the President, and its heads are
    not removable at will by the President. With independent
    agencies, the President is limited in essence to indirect
    cajoling. Cf. Elena Kagan, Presidential Administration, 
    114 Harv. L. Rev. 2245
    , 2323 (2001) (“[A] for-cause removal
    provision would buy little substantive independence if the
    President, though unable to fire an official, could command or,
    if necessary, supplant his every decision.”). 14 As Justice
    14
    The for-cause removal restrictions attached to independent
    agencies ordinarily prohibit removal except in cases of inefficiency,
    neglect of duty, or malfeasance. Those restrictions have significant
    impact both in law and in practice. See Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 502
     (for-cause restrictions “mean what they say”); Freytag v.
    Commissioner of Internal Revenue, 
    501 U.S. 868
    , 916 (1991)
    (Scalia, J., concurring in part and concurring in the judgment)
    (“independent regulatory agencies such as the Federal Trade
    Commission and the Securities and Exchange Commission” are
    “specifically designed not to have the quality . . . of being subject to
    the exercise of political oversight and sharing the President’s
    accountability to the people”) (internal quotation marks and
    alteration omitted); Mistretta v. United States, 
    488 U.S. 361
    , 411
    (1989) (for-cause provisions are “specifically crafted to prevent the
    President from exercising coercive influence over independent
    agencies”) (internal quotation marks omitted).             Humphrey’s
    Executor and Wiener v. United States show, for example, that
    for-cause removal requirements prohibit dismissal by the President
    due to lack of trust in the administrator, see Humphrey’s Executor,
    
    295 U.S. at 625-26
    , differences in policy outlook, 
    id.,
     or the mere
    57
    Scalia once memorably noted, an attempt by the President to
    direct (or threaten to remove) the head of an independent
    agency with respect to a particular substantive decision is
    statutorily impermissible and likely to trigger “an
    impeachment motion in Congress.” Tr. of Oral Arg. at 60,
    Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. 477
    . That is true whether
    there are one, three, or five heads of the independent agency.
    The independent status of an independent agency erects a high
    barrier between the President and the independent agency,
    regardless of how many people head the independent agency
    on the other side of the barrier. So a structure with a single
    independent agency head entails no meaningful benefit over a
    multi-member independent agency in terms of Presidential
    control over the independent agency.
    Although the single-Director structure does not
    necessarily give more control to the President over an
    independent agency, one might say from the other direction
    that the structure at least does not diminish the President’s
    power beyond the diminishment already caused by
    Humphrey’s Executor, and thus should not form the basis of an
    Article II violation. In other words, some might say that
    desire to install administrators of the President’s choosing, Wiener,
    
    357 U.S. 349
    , 356 (1958). In Morrison v. Olson, the Court
    therefore took it as a given that “the degree of control exercised by
    the Executive Branch over an independent counsel is clearly
    diminished in relation to that exercised over other prosecutors, such
    as the United States Attorneys, who are appointed by the President
    and subject to termination at will.” 
    487 U.S. at
    696 n.34; see also
    Buckley v. Valeo, 
    424 U.S. 1
    , 133 (1976) (“The Court in
    [Humphrey’s Executor] carefully emphasized that . . . the members
    of such agencies were to be independent of the Executive in their
    day-to-day operations . . . .”); Humphrey’s Executor, 
    295 U.S. at 628
    (independent agencies “cannot in any proper sense be characterized
    as an arm or an eye of the executive”).
    58
    Humphrey’s Executor already greatly reduced Presidential
    power, and this novel structure is merely a variation on
    Humphrey’s Executor rather than a further diminishment of
    Presidential power. To begin with, that may not be true. A
    President may be stuck for his or her entire four-year term with
    a single Director appointed by a prior President with different
    views. Generally, the members of multi-member agencies
    serve staggered terms, and the President will at least have an
    opportunity to appoint some new commissioners over the
    course of his or her first term.
    In any event, although it is true that Article II violations
    often involve diminishment of Presidential power, neither
    Humphrey’s Executor nor any later case gave Congress a free
    pass, without any boundaries, to create independent agencies
    that depart from history and threaten individual liberty.
    Humphrey’s Executor does not mean that anything goes. See
    Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 514
    . In that respect, keep
    in mind (in case we have not mentioned it enough already) that
    the Constitution’s separation of powers is not solely or even
    primarily concerned with preserving the powers of the
    branches. The separation of powers is primarily designed to
    protect individual liberty. See Stern v. Marshall, 
    564 U.S. 462
    , 483 (2011) (“Yet the dynamic between and among the
    branches is not the only object of the Constitution’s concern.
    The structural principles secured by the separation of powers
    protect the individual as well.”) (internal quotation marks
    omitted) (quoting Bond v. United States, 
    564 U.S. 211
    , 222
    (2011)); Bowsher v. Synar, 
    478 U.S. 714
    , 721 (1986) (“The
    declared purpose of separating and dividing the powers of
    government, of course, was to ‘diffus[e] power the better to
    secure liberty.’”) (quoting Youngstown Sheet & Tube Co. v.
    Sawyer, 
    343 U.S. 579
    , 635 (1952) (Jackson, J., concurring));
    Clinton v. City of New York, 
    524 U.S. 417
    , 450 (1998)
    (Kennedy, J., concurring) (“Liberty is always at stake when
    59
    one or more of the branches seek to transgress the separation of
    powers.”). As with the broader separation of powers,
    moreover, a key purpose of Article II is to preserve individual
    liberty. See Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. at 727
     (Scalia, J.,
    dissenting) (“The purpose of the separation and equilibration
    of powers in general, and of the unitary Executive in particular,
    was not merely to assure effective government but to preserve
    individual freedom.”).
    So the single-Director independent agency – which, as we
    have explained, is a structure that departs from settled
    historical practice and threatens individual liberty far more
    than a multi-member independent agency does – poses a
    constitutional problem even if it does not occasion any
    additional diminishment of Presidential power beyond the
    significant diminishment already caused by Humphrey’s
    Executor itself. 15
    15
    In its brief, PHH has expressly preserved the argument that
    Humphrey’s Executor should be overruled. The reasoning of
    Humphrey’s Executor of course was inconsistent with the reasoning
    in the Court’s prior decision in Myers. See Humphrey’s Executor,
    
    295 U.S. at 626
     (“In so far as” the expressions in Myers are “out of
    harmony with the views here set forth, these expressions are
    disapproved.”). The Humphrey’s Executor decision subsequently
    has received significant criticism. See Geoffrey P. Miller,
    Independent Agencies, 
    1986 Sup. Ct. Rev. 41
    , 93 (“Humphrey’s
    Executor, as commentators have noted, is one of the more egregious
    opinions to be found on pages of the United States Supreme Court
    Reports.”); Peter L. Strauss, The Place of Agencies in Government:
    Separation of Powers and the Fourth Branch, 
    84 Colum. L. Rev. 573
    , 611-12 (1984) (“Remarkably, the Court did not pause to
    examine how a purpose to create a body ‘subject only to the people
    of the United States’ – that is, apparently, beyond control of the
    constitutionally defined branches of government – could itself be
    sustained under the Constitution.”). Moreover, the reasoning of
    Humphrey’s Executor is in tension with some of the reasoning of the
    60
    Third, in considering the constitutionality of the CFPB’s
    structure, some might speak of the CFPB as a one-off
    congressional experiment and say we should let it go as a
    matter of judicial restraint. But even apart from the
    fundamental point that our job as judges is to enforce the law,
    not abdicate to the political branches, cf. Boumediene v. Bush,
    
    553 U.S. 723
    , 765-66 (2008), we cannot think of this as a
    one-off case because we could not cabin the consequences in
    any principled manner if we were to uphold the CFPB’s
    single-Director structure. As the Supreme Court has warned:
    “Slight encroachments create new boundaries from which
    legions of power can seek new territory to capture.” Stern,
    
    564 U.S. at 503
     (internal quotation marks omitted). Justice
    Frankfurter captured it well in his opinion in Youngstown:
    “The accretion of dangerous power does not come in a day. It
    does come, however slowly, from the generative force of
    unchecked disregard of the restrictions that fence in even the
    most disinterested assertion of authority.” 
    343 U.S. at 594
    (Frankfurter, J., concurring). That fairly describes what a
    Supreme Court’s recent decision in Free Enterprise Fund. See In re
    Aiken County, 
    645 F.3d 428
    , 444-46 (D.C. Cir. 2011) (Kavanaugh,
    J., concurring); Neomi Rao, Removal: Necessary and Sufficient for
    Presidential Control, 
    65 Ala. L. Rev. 1205
    , 1208 (2014). Of
    course, overruling Humphrey’s Executor would not mean the end of
    the agencies that are now independent. The agencies would simply
    transform into executive agencies supervised and directed by the
    President. So the question is not the existence of the agencies; the
    question is the President’s control over the agencies and the resulting
    accountability of those agencies to the people. In any event, as a
    lower court, we of course must follow Supreme Court precedent. It
    is not our job to decide whether to overrule Humphrey’s Executor.
    But it is emphatically our job to make sure that Humphrey’s
    Executor is applied in a manner consistent with settled historical
    practice and the Constitution’s protection of individual liberty.
    61
    ruling upholding the CFPB’s single-Director structure would
    mean. As the CFPB acknowledged at oral argument, a ruling
    in its favor would necessarily allow all extant independent
    agencies to be headed by one person. Tr. of Oral Arg. at
    18-19. We would be green-lighting Congress to make other
    heads of independent agencies a single Director rather than a
    multi-member commission. A single-Director SEC, with the
    power to unilaterally impose $500 million penalties? A
    single-Director FCC, with the power to unilaterally require
    “net neutrality”? A single-Director NLRB, with the power to
    unilaterally    supervise   employer-employee        relations
    nationwide? That’s what we would be ushering in with a
    ruling upholding the CFPB’s single-Director structure.
    At a more general level, however, some might think that
    judges should simply defer to the elected branches’ design of
    the administrative state. But that hands-off attitude would
    flout a long, long line of Supreme Court precedent.
    Agreement by the two elected branches at a particular moment
    or period in time has never been a ground for the courts to
    simply defer regardless of whether the legislation violates the
    Constitution’s separation of powers. Far from it. See Free
    Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 497, 508
     (invalidating structure
    of Public Company Accounting Oversight Board);
    Boumediene, 
    553 U.S. at 765-66, 792
     (invalidating provision
    of Military Commissions Act); Clinton, 
    524 U.S. at 448-49
    (invalidating Line Item Veto Act); Metropolitan Washington
    Airports Authority v. Citizens for the Abatement of Aircraft
    Noise, Inc., 
    501 U.S. 252
    , 266-69 (1991) (invalidating
    structure of Metropolitan Washington Airports Authority
    Board of Review); Bowsher, 
    478 U.S. at 733-34
     (invalidating
    Comptroller General’s powers under “reporting provisions” of
    Balanced Budget and Emergency Deficit Control Act); INS v.
    Chadha, 
    462 U.S. 919
    , 942 n.13, 957 (1983) (invalidating
    legislative veto provision of Immigration and Nationality Act);
    62
    Buckley v. Valeo, 
    424 U.S. 1
    , 134-35, 140 (1976) (invalidating
    structure of Federal Election Commission); Myers v. United
    States, 
    272 U.S. 52
     (1926) (invalidating provision requiring
    Senate consent to President’s removal of executive officer).
    In that same vein, even though a particular President might
    accept a novel practice that violates Article II, “the separation
    of powers does not depend on the views of individual
    Presidents, nor on whether the encroached-upon branch
    approves the encroachment.” Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 497
     (internal quotation marks and citation omitted). A
    President cannot “choose to bind his successors by diminishing
    their powers.” 
    Id.
    In this case, moreover, it bears mention that Congress’s
    choice of a single-Director CFPB was not an especially
    considered legislative decision. There are no committee
    reports, nor substantial legislative history, delving into the
    benefits of single-Director independent agencies versus
    multi-member independent agencies.           The CFPB has
    identified no congressional hearings studying the question.
    Congress apparently stumbled into this single-Director
    structure as a compromise or landing point between the
    original Warren multi-member independent agency proposal
    and a traditional executive agency headed by a single person.
    Fourth, one might argue that the CFPB’s decisions are
    checked by the courts, so we should not worry about the
    single-Director structure. But much of what an agency does –
    determining what rules to issue within a broad statutory
    authorization and when, how, and against whom to bring
    enforcement actions to enforce the law – occurs in the twilight
    of judicially unreviewable discretion. Those discretionary
    actions have a critical impact on individual liberty. And
    courts do not review or only deferentially review such
    exercises of agency discretion. See Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v.
    63
    Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    ,
    844-45 (1984); Motor Vehicle Manufacturers Association of
    U.S., Inc. v. State Farm Mutual Automobile Insurance Co., 
    463 U.S. 29
    , 41-43 (1983); Heckler v. Chaney, 
    470 U.S. 821
    ,
    831-33 (1985). Therefore, the probability of judicial review
    of some agency action has never excused or mitigated an
    otherwise extant Article II problem in the structure of the
    agency. See, e.g., Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. 477
    ;
    Buckley, 
    424 U.S. 1
    .
    From another direction, one might argue that the CFPB is
    checked by Congress through Congress’s oversight and
    ultimate control over appropriations. To begin with, Congress
    does not have the power to direct the Director or to remove the
    Director at will. Congress cannot supervise or direct the
    Director regarding what rules to issue, what enforcement
    actions to bring (or decline to bring), or how to resolve
    adjudications. More to the point, by further impairing the
    President’s control over the Executive Branch, day-to-day
    congressional control over an executive or independent agency
    generally would exacerbate, rather than mitigate, any Article II
    problem with the structure of the agency. To satisfy Article II,
    the check on an agency must come from the President or from
    other internal Executive Branch or agency checks, not from
    Congress. The bottom line, as the Supreme Court said in
    Bowsher, is that the “separated powers of our Government
    cannot be permitted to turn on judicial assessment of whether
    an officer exercising executive power is on good terms with
    Congress.” 
    478 U.S. at 730
    . “The Framers did not rest our
    liberties on such bureaucratic minutiae.” Free Enterprise
    Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 500
    . 16
    16
    On top of the Director’s unilateral power to issue rules and
    take enforcement actions to enforce 19 separate consumer protection
    statutes, the CFPB is not subject to the ordinary annual
    64
    In sum, the CFPB departs from settled historical practice
    regarding the structure of independent agencies. And that
    departure makes a significant difference for the individual
    liberty protected by the Constitution’s separation of powers.
    Applying the Supreme Court’s separation of powers
    precedents, we therefore conclude that the CFPB is
    unconstitutionally structured because it is an independent
    agency headed by a single Director. 17
    appropriations process. Instead, the Dodd-Frank Act requires the
    Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve to transfer “from the
    combined earnings of the Federal Reserve System” the amount
    “determined by the Director,” not to exceed 12 percent of the “total
    operating expenses of the Federal Reserve System.” 
    12 U.S.C. § 5497
    (a)(1)-(2). As those who have labored in Washington well
    understand, the appropriations process brings at least some measure
    of oversight by Congress. According to PHH, the CFPB’s
    exemption from that process enhances the concern in this case about
    the massive power lodged in a single, unaccountable Director. That
    said, the single Director would constitute a constitutional problem
    even if the CFPB were subject to the usual appropriations process.
    The CFPB’s exemption from the ordinary appropriations process is
    at most just “extra icing on” an unconstitutional “cake already
    frosted.” Yates v. United States, 
    135 S. Ct. 1074
    , 1093, slip op. at 6
    (2015) (Kagan, J., dissenting). In any event, Congress can always
    alter the CFPB’s funding in any appropriations cycle (or at any other
    time). Section 5497 is not an entrenched statute shielded from
    future congressional alteration, nor could it be. See, e.g., Manigault
    v. Springs, 
    199 U.S. 473
    , 487 (1905).
    17
    Nothing in our opinion casts any doubt on traditional
    structures under which Congress may establish a process for
    designating the Chair of an independent board or independent
    commission, and for assigning the Chair various additional
    administrative responsibilities. Those responsibilities are distinct
    from substantive authority. A Chair may not unilaterally issue a
    rule, unilaterally bring an enforcement action, or unilaterally decide
    65
    III
    Having concluded that the CFPB is unconstitutionally
    structured because it is an independent agency headed by a
    single Director, we must decide on the appropriate remedy.
    When the constitutional problem involves a provision of a
    statute, the legal term for that question is severability. In light
    of this one specific constitutional flaw in the Dodd-Frank Act,
    must we strike down that whole Act? Or must we strike down
    at least those statutory provisions creating the CFPB and
    defining the CFPB’s duties and authorities? Or do we just
    narrowly strike down and sever the one for-cause removal
    provision that is the source of the constitutional problem?
    Not surprisingly, PHH wants us, at a minimum, to strike
    down the CFPB and prevent its continued operation, if not
    strike down the entire Dodd-Frank Act. But Supreme Court
    precedent on severability demands a narrower remedy for the
    CFPB’s constitutional flaw.
    an adjudication. See Marshall J. Breger & Gary J. Edles,
    Established by Practice: The Theory and Operation of Independent
    Federal Agencies, 
    52 Admin. L. Rev. 1111
    , 1166-67 (2000) (“As our
    survey of some thirty federal multi-member agencies suggests, all of
    the reorganization statutes and their progeny fundamentally assign
    substantive authority to the agency as a whole and administrative
    authority to the chairman.”). We note, moreover, that many Chairs
    traditionally are removable at will by the President from their
    position as Chair, albeit not from the commission. See Rachel E.
    Barkow, Insulating Agencies: Avoiding Capture Through
    Institutional Design, 
    89 Tex. L. Rev. 15
    , 38 & n.124 (2010).
    Nor does our decision cast any doubt on the independent status
    of administrative law judges who are protected by for-cause
    provisions. Those judges conduct only adjudications (of a sort) and
    are not covered or affected in any way by our decision here.
    66
    “Generally speaking, when confronting a constitutional
    flaw in a statute, we try to limit the solution to the problem,
    severing any problematic portions while leaving the remainder
    intact.” Free Enterprise Fund v. Public Company Accounting
    Oversight Board, 
    561 U.S. 477
    , 508 (2010) (internal quotation
    marks omitted). The “normal rule is that partial, rather than
    facial, invalidation is the required course.” 
    Id.
     (internal
    quotation marks omitted). That is true so long as we conclude
    that (i) Congress would have preferred the law with the
    offending provision severed over no law at all; and (ii) the law
    with the offending provision severed would remain “fully
    operative as a law.” 
    Id. at 509
     (internal quotation marks
    omitted).
    First, in considering Congress’s intent with respect to
    severability, courts must decide – or often speculate, truth be
    told – whether Congress would “have preferred what is left of
    its statute to no statute at all.” Ayotte v. Planned Parenthood
    of Northern New England, 
    546 U.S. 320
    , 330 (2006); see also
    Alaska Airlines, Inc. v. Brock, 
    480 U.S. 678
    , 685 (1987)
    (“[T]he unconstitutional provision must be severed unless the
    statute created in its absence is legislation that Congress would
    not have enacted.”). Importantly, courts need not speculate
    and can presume that Congress wanted to retain the
    constitutional remainder of the statute when “Congress has
    explicitly provided for severance by including a severability
    clause in the statute.” Alaska Airlines, 
    480 U.S. at 686
    ; see
    also 
    id.
     (“[T]he inclusion of such a clause creates a
    presumption that Congress did not intend the validity of the
    statute in question to depend on the validity of the
    constitutionally offensive provision.”).
    In this case, as was the case in Free Enterprise Fund,
    “nothing in the statute’s text or historical context makes it
    67
    evident that Congress, faced with the limitations imposed by
    the Constitution, would have preferred no” CFPB at all (or no
    Dodd-Frank Act at all) to a CFPB whose Director is removable
    at will. 
    561 U.S. at 509
     (internal quotation marks omitted).
    Indeed, the Dodd-Frank Act itself all but answers the question
    of presumed congressional intent through its express
    severability clause, which instructs: “If any provision” of the
    Act “is held to be unconstitutional, the remainder of” the Act
    “shall not be affected thereby.” 
    12 U.S.C. § 5302
    . It will be
    the rare case when a court may ignore a severability provision
    set forth in the text of the relevant statute. See Alaska
    Airlines, 
    480 U.S. at 686
    . We have no reason or basis to tilt at
    that windmill in this case.
    Second, we also must look at “the balance of the
    legislation” to assess whether the statute is capable “of
    functioning” without the offending provisions “in a manner
    consistent with the intent of Congress.” 
    Id. at 684-85
    (emphasis omitted); see also United States v. Booker, 
    543 U.S. 220
    , 227 (2005) (“[T]wo provisions . . . must be invalidated in
    order to allow the statute to operate in a manner consistent with
    congressional intent.”). That prong of the severability
    analysis in essence turns on whether the truncated statute is
    “fully operative as a law.” Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 509
     (internal quotation marks omitted). To take just one
    example, in Marbury v. Madison, the Court concluded that
    Section 13 of the Judiciary Act of 1789 was unconstitutional in
    part. 
    5 U.S. 137
    , 148, 179-80 (1803). But the Court did not
    disturb the remainder of the Judiciary Act. 
    Id. at 179-80
    .
    Here, the Dodd-Frank Act and its CFPB-related
    provisions will remain “fully operative as a law” without the
    for-cause removal restriction. Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 509
     (internal quotation marks omitted). Operating
    without the for-cause removal provision and under the
    68
    supervision and direction of the President, the CFPB may still
    “regulate the offering and provision of consumer financial
    products or services under the Federal consumer financial
    laws,” 
    12 U.S.C. § 5491
    (a), much as the Accounting Oversight
    Board has continued fulfilling its regulatory mission in the
    wake of the Supreme Court’s decision in Free Enterprise
    Fund. 18 Moreover, the CFPB’s operation as an executive
    agency will not in any way prevent the overall Dodd-Frank Act
    from remaining operative as a law.
    To be sure, one might ask whether, instead of severing the
    for-cause removal provision, we should rewrite and add to the
    Dodd-Frank Act by restructuring the CFPB as a multi-member
    independent agency. But doing so would require us to create
    a variety of new offices, designate one of the offices as Chair,
    and specify various administrative details of the reconstituted
    agency. All of that “editorial freedom” would take us far
    beyond our judicial capacity. Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. at 510
    . In addition, that approach would thwart the ongoing
    operations of the CFPB unless and until the President
    nominated and the Senate confirmed new members, potentially
    18
    The Dodd-Frank Act contains a five-year tenure provision
    for the Director, see 
    12 U.S.C. § 5491
    (c)(1), akin to the similar
    10-year tenure provision for the Director of the FBI and the 5-year
    tenure provision for the Commissioner of the IRS. See Crime
    Control Act of 1976, § 203, reprinted in 
    28 U.S.C. § 532
     note (FBI
    Director “may not serve more than one ten-year term”); 
    26 U.S.C. § 7803
    (a)(1)(B) (term of the IRS Commissioner “shall be a 5-year
    term”). But under Supreme Court precedent, such tenure provisions
    do not prevent the President from removing at will a Director at any
    time during the Director’s tenure. See Parsons v. United States, 
    167 U.S. 324
    , 343 (1897). Therefore, we need not invalidate and sever
    the tenure provision. If such a provision did impair the President’s
    ability to remove the Director at will, then it too would be
    unconstitutional, and it would be invalidated and severed.
    69
    shutting the agency down for months if not years. No
    Supreme Court case in comparable circumstances has adopted
    such an approach. We may not do so here. Of course, if
    Congress prefers to restructure the CFPB as a multi-member
    independent agency rather than as a single-Director executive
    agency, Congress may enact new legislation that creates a
    Bureau headed by multiple members instead of a single
    Director. Cf. 
    id.
     (“Congress of course remains free to pursue
    any of these options going forward.”).
    In similar circumstances, the Supreme Court in Free
    Enterprise Fund severed the unconstitutional for-cause
    provision but did not otherwise disturb the Sarbanes-Oxley Act
    or the operation of the new Accounting Oversight Board
    created by that Act. See id. at 508-10. Similarly, in a recent
    case involving the Copyright Royalty Board, we severed the
    for-cause provision that rendered that Board unconstitutional,
    but did not otherwise disturb the copyright laws or the
    operation of the Copyright Royalty Board.                  See
    Intercollegiate Broadcasting System, Inc. v. Copyright Royalty
    Board, 
    684 F.3d 1332
    , 1340-41 (D.C. Cir. 2012). We do the
    same here.
    In light of Congress’s clear textual expression of its intent
    regarding severability, and because the Dodd-Frank Act and
    the CFPB may function without the CFPB’s for-cause removal
    provision, we remedy the constitutional violation here by
    severing the for-cause removal provision from the statute. As
    a result, the CFPB now will operate as an executive agency.
    The President of the United States now has the power to
    supervise and direct the Director of the CFPB, and may remove
    the Director at will at any time. 19
    19
    We need not here consider the legal ramifications of our
    decision for past CFPB rules or for past agency enforcement actions.
    70
    IV
    Because our constitutional ruling will not halt the CFPB’s
    ongoing operations or the CFPB’s ability to uphold the $109
    million order against PHH, we must also consider PHH’s
    statutory objections to the CFPB enforcement action in this
    case.
    In its enforcement action against PHH, the CFPB alleged
    that PHH violated Section 8 of the Real Estate Settlement
    Procedures Act. Passed by Congress and signed by President
    Ford in 1974, the Act dramatically reformed the real estate
    industry. One of the textually stated purposes of the Act was
    “the elimination of kickbacks or referral fees that tend to
    increase unnecessarily the costs of certain settlement services.”
    
    12 U.S.C. § 2601
    (b)(2).
    We note, however, that this is not an uncommon situation. For
    example, in just the last few years, the NLRB, the Public Company
    Accounting Oversight Board, and the Copyright Royalty Board have
    all been on the receiving end of successful constitutional and
    statutory challenges to their structure and legality. See NLRB v.
    Noel Canning, 
    134 S. Ct. 2550
     (2014); New Process Steel, L.P. v.
    NLRB, 
    560 U.S. 674
     (2010); Free Enterprise Fund, 
    561 U.S. 477
    ;
    Intercollegiate Broadcasting System, Inc., 
    684 F.3d 1332
    . Without
    major tumult, the agencies and courts have subsequently worked
    through the resulting issues regarding the legality of past rules and of
    past or current enforcement actions. See, e.g., Noel Canning v.
    NLRB, 
    823 F.3d 76
    , 78-80 (D.C. Cir. 2016); Intercollegiate
    Broadcasting System, Inc. v. Copyright Royalty Board, 
    796 F.3d 111
    , 118-19 (D.C. Cir. 2015). Because, as we will explain in the
    next section, the CFPB’s enforcement action against PHH in this
    case must be vacated in any event, we need not consider any such
    issues at this time.
    71
    To further that purpose, Section 8(a) of the Act bans
    payments for referrals in the real estate settlement process.
    Section 8(a) provides: “No person shall give and no person
    shall accept any fee, kickback, or thing of value pursuant to any
    agreement or understanding, oral or otherwise, that business
    incident to or a part of a real estate settlement service involving
    a federally related mortgage loan shall be referred to any
    person.” 
    Id.
     § 2607(a). 20
    Importantly for this case, however, Section 8(c) contains a
    series of qualifications, exceptions, and safe harbors. Of
    relevance here, Section 8(c) carves out a safe harbor against
    overly broad interpretations of Section 8(a): “Nothing in this
    section shall be construed as prohibiting . . . (2) the payment to
    any person of a bona fide salary or compensation or other
    payment for goods or facilities actually furnished or for
    services actually performed.” Id. § 2607(c)(2).
    In 1995, PHH, a mortgage lender, began participating in
    so-called captive reinsurance agreements. PHH would refer
    borrowers to certain mortgage insurers. Those mortgage
    insurers, in turn, would purchase mortgage reinsurance from
    Atrium, a wholly owned subsidiary of PHH. According to
    PHH, this was not a problem under Section 8 because the
    mortgage insurers would pay no more than reasonable market
    value to Atrium for the reinsurance they purchased. PHH
    argues that the mortgage insurers were thus paying reasonable
    market value for reinsurance from Atrium, as allowed by the
    statute’s safe harbor, and were not paying anything for the
    referrals made by PHH, which would have been unlawful. 21
    20
    Section 8 of the Act is codified at 
    12 U.S.C. § 2607
    . For
    consistency, we refer to Section 8 rather than Section 2607.
    21
    It is worth noting that Sections 8(a) and 8(c), as relevant here,
    do not speak directly to transactions between mortgage lenders and
    homebuyers.       Instead, those two provisions speak to the
    72
    Many other mortgage lenders did the same thing as PHH.
    They did so in part because the U.S. Department of Housing
    and Urban Development, known as HUD, the federal
    government agency responsible for enforcing this real estate
    law, repeatedly said (beginning in 1997) that captive
    reinsurance arrangements were permissible under Section 8 so
    long as the mortgage insurer paid no more than reasonable
    market value for the reinsurance.
    In this action against PHH, however, the CFPB changed
    course and, for the first time, interpreted Section 8 to prohibit
    captive reinsurance agreements even if the mortgage insurers
    pay no more than reasonable market value to the reinsurers.
    The CFPB then retroactively applied that new interpretation
    against PHH based on conduct that PHH engaged in before the
    CFPB issued its new interpretation.
    PHH advances two alternative and independent arguments
    on the statutory issue. First, PHH argues that the CFPB
    misinterpreted Section 8(c). Second, in the alternative, PHH
    argues that the CFPB violated bedrock due process principles
    by retroactively applying its new interpretation of the statute
    against PHH. We agree with PHH on both points.
    transactions between the mortgage lender and mortgage insurer.
    The sections prohibit one specific kind of activity in that market:
    payment to the lender by the mortgage insurer for the lender’s
    referral of a customer to the mortgage insurer.
    Although not required by Section 8(c)(2), PHH nonetheless
    typically provided its borrowers with a disclosure. The disclosure
    said that if a borrower selected a mortgage insurer with which PHH
    had a referral arrangement, the insurer would pay a reinsurance fee
    to Atrium, which was affiliated with PHH. See J.A. 332.
    73
    A
    The basic statutory question in this case is not a close call.
    The text of Section 8(c) permits captive reinsurance
    arrangements where mortgage insurers pay no more than
    reasonable market value for the reinsurance. Section 8(c)
    contains a broad range of exceptions, qualifications, and safe
    harbors to Section 8(a). As relevant here, Section 8(c) creates
    a safe harbor, stating: “Nothing” in Section 8 “shall be
    construed as prohibiting” the “payment to any person of a bona
    fide salary or compensation or other payment for goods or
    facilities actually furnished or for services actually
    performed.” See 
    12 U.S.C. § 2607
    (c)(2). Nothing means
    nothing.
    Section 8(a) prohibits, in this context, payment by a
    mortgage insurer to a lender for the lender’s referral of a
    customer to the mortgage insurer. But Section 8(a) and 8(c)
    do not prohibit bona fide payments by the mortgage insurer to
    the lender for other services that the lender (or the lender’s
    subsidiary or affiliate) actually provides to the mortgage
    insurer.
    How do we determine whether the mortgage insurer’s
    payment to the lender was a bona fide payment for the
    reinsurance rather than a disguised payment for the lender’s
    referral of a customer to the insurer? As HUD had long
    explained, the answer is commonsensical: If the payment to
    the lender-affiliated reinsurer is more than the reasonable
    market value of the reinsurance, then we may presume that the
    excess payment above reasonable market value was not a bona
    fide payment for the reinsurance but was a disguised payment
    for a referral. Otherwise, there is no basis to treat payment of
    reasonable market value for the reinsurance as a prohibited
    payment for the referral – assuming, of course, that the
    74
    reinsurance was actually provided. In other words, in the text
    and context of this statute, a bona fide payment means a
    payment of reasonable market value. 22
    To be sure, one might say that the mortgage insurer –
    although paying reasonable market value for the reinsurance –
    would have preferred not to purchase reinsurance at all or to
    purchase it from a different reinsurer. In that sense, the
    lender’s actions create a kind of tying arrangement in which the
    lender says to the mortgage insurer: We will refer customers
    to you, but only if you purchase another service from our
    affiliated reinsurer, albeit at reasonable market value. But the
    statute does not proscribe that kind of arrangement. As
    relevant here, Section 8(a) proscribes payments for referrals.
    Period. It does not proscribe other transactions between the
    lender and mortgage insurer. Nor does it proscribe a tying
    arrangement, so long as the only payments exchanged are bona
    fide payments for services and not payments for referrals.
    The CFPB says, however, that the mortgage insurer’s
    payment for the reinsurance is not “bona fide” if it was part of a
    tying arrangement.      That makes little sense.           Tying
    arrangements are ubiquitous in the U.S. economy. To be sure,
    tying arrangements are outlawed in certain circumstances, but
    they were not outlawed by Section 8 in the circumstances at
    issue here. 23 A payment for a service pursuant to a tying
    22
    When we use the phrase “reasonable market value” in this
    opinion, we use that phrase as shorthand for a payment that bears a
    reasonable relationship to the market value of the services performed
    or products provided, as HUD has long explained it. We do not
    opine on what constituted reasonable market value for the
    reinsurance at issue in this case. That factual question is not before
    us.
    23
    Tying arrangements are rarely prohibited in the American
    economy, unless the party doing the tying has market power.
    75
    arrangement does not make the payment any less bona fide, so
    long as the payment for the service reflects reasonable market
    value. A bona fide payment means a payment of reasonable
    market value.
    Recognizing, however, that an aggressive government
    enforcement agency or court might interpret other transactions
    between businesses in the real estate market as connected to,
    conditioned on, or tied to referrals, and might try to sweep such
    transactions within the scope of Section 8(a)’s prohibition,
    Congress explicitly made clear in Section 8(c) that those other
    transactions were lawful so long as reasonable market value
    was paid and the services were actually performed. In other
    words, Section 8(c) specifically bars the aggressive
    interpretation of Section 8(a) advanced by the CFPB in this
    case. Section 8(c) was designed to provide certainty to
    businesses in the mortgage lending process. The CFPB’s
    interpretation flouts that statutory goal and upends the entire
    system of unpaid referrals that has been part of the market for
    real estate settlement services.
    Our interpretation of the text accords with the
    longstanding interpretation of the Department of Housing and
    Otherwise, tying arrangements can be beneficial to consumers and
    the economy by enhancing efficiencies and lowering costs. As the
    Supreme Court has stated, “Many tying arrangements . . . are fully
    consistent with a free, competitive market.” Illinois Tool Works,
    Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., 
    547 U.S. 28
    , 45 (2006); see also
    National Fuel Gas Supply Corp. v. FERC, 
    468 F.3d 831
    , 840 (D.C.
    Cir. 2006). In this context, moreover, the Real Estate Settlement
    Procedures Act allows vertical integration of lenders and other
    settlement service providers under its affiliated business provisions.
    If such vertical integration is allowed, it would not make much sense
    to conclude that similar vertical contractual relationships are
    proscribed.
    76
    Urban Development.         For decades, HUD explained to
    mortgage lenders that captive reinsurance arrangements where
    reasonable market value was paid were entirely permissible
    under Section 8. Indeed, HUD adopted a rule, Regulation X,
    under which captive reinsurance arrangements were permitted
    so long as the insurer paid reasonable market value for the
    reinsurance. See 
    24 C.F.R. § 3500.14
    (g) (2011); see also 
    24 C.F.R. § 3500.14
    (e)-(f) (1992). That regulation remains in
    place as a CFPB regulation. See 
    12 C.F.R. § 1024.14
     (2016).
    Yet in its decision here and its argument to this Court, the
    CFPB has not adhered to the regulation. On the contrary, the
    CFPB now says the opposite of what HUD’s prior
    interpretations and Regulation X all say. In the next section,
    we will consider the due process implications of the CFPB’s
    retroactive application of its about-face. For now, we simply
    note that the CFPB’s interpretation flouts not only the text of
    the statute but also decades of carefully and repeatedly
    considered official government interpretations.
    Our interpretation of the text also accords with the
    statute’s multiple purposes, as revealed by the text. One goal
    of the statute was to eliminate payments for referrals because
    “referral fees . . . tend to increase unnecessarily the costs of
    certain settlement services.”         
    12 U.S.C. § 2601
    (b)(2).
    Another purpose of the statute, as the text shows, was to allow
    market participants to refer customers to other service
    providers, albeit without demanding or receiving payment for
    the referral. 
    Id.
     § 2607(a). After all, such referrals often
    enhance the efficiency of the homebuying process. Another
    purpose was to assure market participants that they could
    engage in transactions – other than payments for referrals – so
    long as reasonable payments were made for services actually
    performed. Id. § 2607(c); see also Glover v. Standard
    Federal Bank, 
    283 F.3d 953
    , 964 (8th Cir. 2002); Geraci v.
    Homestreet Bank, 
    347 F.3d 749
    , 751 (9th Cir. 2003). If
    77
    payments for services actually performed reflect the
    reasonable market value of the services, as they must to fall
    within Section 8(c), then they square with the Act’s various
    purposes.
    Our interpretation of the text also aligns with how key
    Members of Congress intended Sections 8(a) and 8(c) to work
    together. When the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act
    was reported out of the Senate Committee on Banking,
    Housing and Urban Affairs in 1974, the accompanying
    committee report stated: “Reasonable payments in return for
    services actually performed or goods actually furnished are not
    intended to be prohibited.” S. Rep. No. 93-866, at 6 (1974).
    Note the Senate Committee’s use of the word “reasonable.”
    Here, the CFPB has argued that the phrase “bona fide
    payment” in the statute somehow means something different
    from “reasonable payment.” CFPB Br. 29 & n.18. But the
    Senate Committee, following the commonsense meaning,
    expressly equated the two terms. Contrary to the CFPB’s
    strained interpretation, the committee report indicates that
    those Members of Congress intended Sections 8(a) and 8(c) to
    mean what they say and to say what they mean: Payments for
    referrals are proscribed, but payments for other services
    actually performed are permitted, so long as the payments
    reflect reasonable market value.
    In seeking to defend its interpretation, the CFPB argues
    that its interpretation of the Real Estate Settlement Procedures
    Act is entitled to Chevron deference. But Chevron instructs
    us at step one to first employ all of the traditional tools of
    statutory interpretation, as we have done. See Chevron U.S.A.
    Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
    467 U.S. 837
    ,
    843 n.9 (1984). After we employ those tools, only if an
    ambiguity remains do we defer to the agency, if its
    interpretation is at least reasonable. Here, we conclude at
    78
    Chevron step one that the statute permits captive reinsurance
    arrangements. Indeed, Section 8(c) eliminates any potential
    ambiguity that might have existed if all we had were Section
    8(a) alone. Section 8(c) clearly permits captive reinsurance
    arrangements so long as the mortgage insurer pays reasonable
    market value for reinsurance actually provided. So the
    CFPB’s interpretation fails at Chevron step one.                   Cf.
    Kingdomware Technologies, Inc. v. United States, 
    136 S. Ct. 1969
    , 1979, slip op. at 12 (2016); FERC v. Electric Power
    Supply Association, 
    136 S. Ct. 760
    , 773 n.5, slip op. at 14 n.5
    (2016); Adams Fruit Co. v. Barrett, 
    494 U.S. 638
    , 642 (1990);
    Loving v. IRS, 
    742 F.3d 1013
    , 1021-22 (D.C. Cir. 2014). For
    those same reasons, if we reached Chevron step two, we would
    conclude that the CFPB’s interpretation is not a reasonable
    interpretation of the statute in light of the statute’s text, history,
    context, and purposes.
    The policy and ethics of captive reinsurance arrangements
    no doubt can be debated, as can the policy and ethics of the
    wide variety of similar tying and referral arrangements that are
    ubiquitous in the American economy. But the initial question
    before us (and that was before the CFPB) is not one of policy or
    ethics. The question is one of law. Under Section 8(a) and
    Section 8(c), the relevant questions are whether the payment
    from the mortgage insurer to the lender-affiliated reinsurer is
    bona fide – that is, commensurate with the reasonable market
    value of the reinsurance – and whether the services were
    actually performed. If so, then the payment is permissible, as
    HUD had long stated.
    The CFPB obviously believes that captive reinsurance
    arrangements are harmful and should be illegal. But the
    decision whether to adopt a new prohibition on captive
    reinsurance arrangements is for Congress and the President
    when exercising the legislative authority. It is not a decision
    79
    for the CFPB to make unilaterally. See King v. Burwell, 
    135 S. Ct. 2480
    , 2496, slip op. at 21 (2015) (“In a democracy, the
    power to make the law rests with those chosen by the people.”).
    We hold that Sections 8(a) and 8(c) of the Real Estate
    Settlement Procedures Act allow captive reinsurance
    arrangements so long as the mortgage insurance companies
    pay no more than reasonable market value to the reinsurers for
    services actually provided. On remand, the CFPB may
    determine whether the relevant mortgage insurers in fact paid
    more than reasonable market value to the reinsurer Atrium for
    the reinsurance. 24
    B
    Even if the CFPB’s interpretation of Section 8 were
    permissible, it nonetheless represented a complete about-face
    from the Federal Government’s longstanding prior
    interpretation of Section 8. Agency change is not a fatal flaw
    in and of itself, so long as the change is reasonably explained
    and so long as the new interpretation is consistent with the
    statute. See FCC v. Fox Television Stations, Inc., 
    556 U.S. 502
    , 514-16 (2009). But change becomes a problem – a fatal
    one – when the Government decides to turn around and
    retroactively apply that new interpretation to proscribe conduct
    that occurred before the new interpretation was issued.
    Therefore, even if the CFPB’s new interpretation were
    consistent with the statute (which it is not), the CFPB violated
    due process by retroactively applying that new interpretation to
    PHH’s conduct that occurred before the date of the CFPB’s
    new interpretation.
    24
    If a mortgage insurer did pay more than reasonable market
    value for reinsurance, the disgorgement remedy is the amount that
    was paid above reasonable market value.
    80
    Before the creation of the CFPB in 2010, the Department
    of Housing and Urban Development administered the Real
    Estate Settlement Procedures Act. In 1997, HUD sent a letter
    to a mortgage company. The mortgage company had
    requested that HUD clarify the application of Section 8 of the
    Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act to captive reinsurance
    arrangements.
    In the letter, HUD analyzed the relationship between
    Sections 8(a) and 8(c). HUD said that “Subsection 8(c) of
    RESPA sets forth various exemptions from these
    prohibitions.” Letter from Nicolas P. Retsinas, Assistant
    Secretary for Housing, Department of Housing and Urban
    Development, to Countrywide Funding Corporation 3 (Aug. 6,
    1997) (J.A. 251-58). HUD further stated that its “view of
    captive reinsurance” was that “the arrangements are
    permissible” if “the payments to the reinsurer: (1) are for
    reinsurance services ‘actually furnished or for services
    performed’ and (2) are bona fide compensation that does not
    exceed the value of such services.” 
    Id.
     (J.A. 253).
    The 1997 HUD letter was widely disseminated and relied
    on in the industry. In 2004, a title association again asked
    HUD about the legality of captive reinsurance programs under
    the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act. HUD restated the
    position it had taken in 1997 with respect to captive mortgage
    reinsurance. As it had in 1997, HUD wrote that captive
    reinsurance agreements are permissible if the payments made
    to the reinsurer (1) are “for reinsurance services actually
    furnished or for services performed” and (2) are “bona fide
    compensation that does not exceed the value of such services.”
    Letter from John P. Kennedy, Associate General Counsel for
    Finance and Regulatory Compliance, Department of Housing
    81
    and Urban Development, to American Land Title Association
    1 (Aug. 12, 2004) (J.A. 259).
    In accord with those letters, HUD’s Real Estate Settlement
    Procedures Act regulations were set forth in Regulation X,
    which was first issued in 1976 and updated, as relevant here, in
    1992. See 
    24 C.F.R. §§ 3500.01-3500.14
     (1977); see also 
    24 C.F.R. § 3500.14
     (1993). As it initially read, Regulation X
    stated: “The payment and receipt of a thing of value that bears
    a reasonable relationship to the value of the goods or services
    received by the person or company making the payment is not
    prohibited by RESPA section 8. To the extent the thing of
    value is in excess of the reasonable value of the goods provided
    or services performed, the excess is not for services actually
    rendered and may be considered a kickback or referral fee
    proscribed by RESPA section 8.” 
    24 C.F.R. § 3500.14
    (e)
    (1977). Regulation X was slightly reworded in 1992: “If the
    payment of a thing of value bears no reasonable relationship to
    the market value of the goods or services provided, then the
    excess is not for services or goods actually performed or
    provided.” 
    24 C.F.R. § 3500.14
    (g)(3) (1993). Regulation X
    described “bona fide” payments for services actually
    performed as payments that “Section 8 of RESPA permits.”
    
    Id.
     § 3500.14(g)(1). After the CFPB inherited HUD’s
    enforcement and rulemaking authority under the Act, the
    CFPB itself codified HUD’s Regulation X provisions
    governing Section 8. See 
    12 C.F.R. § 1024.14
    (g) (2012).
    In our Court, the CFPB acknowledges that, at the time of
    PHH’s conduct, Regulation X stated “that, if a payment bears
    no reasonable relationship to the value of the services
    provided, then the excess may be a payment for a referral.”
    CFPB Br. 31 n.23. But the CFPB argues that “this does not
    mean that, if the payment does bear a reasonable relationship to
    the value of the services provided, then those payments are
    82
    never for referrals.” 
    Id.
     The CFPB’s interpretation is a
    facially nonsensical reading of Regulation X. As Regulation
    X made clear, if an insurer makes a payment at reasonable
    market value for services actually provided, that payment is not
    a payment for a referral.
    HUD’s consistent and repeated interpretation of Section 8
    was widely known and relied on in the mortgage lending
    industry. It was reflected in the leading treatise on the Act.
    See JAMES H. PANNABECKER & DAVID STEMLER, THE RESPA
    MANUAL: A COMPLETE GUIDE TO THE REAL ESTATE
    SETTLEMENT PROCEDURES ACT § 8.04[6][a] (2013). And
    courts had acknowledged and approved HUD’s interpretation.
    See, e.g., Glover v. Standard Federal Bank, 
    283 F.3d 953
    , 964
    (8th Cir. 2002) (the “permissive language of Section 8(c) . . .
    clearly states that reasonable payments for goods, facilities or
    services actually furnished are not prohibited by RESPA, even
    when done in connection with the referral of a particular loan
    to a particular lender”); cf. Carter v. Welles-Bowen Realty,
    Inc., 
    736 F.3d 722
    , 728 (6th Cir. 2013) (Section 8(c)(2) is a
    “safe harbor[]” from Section 8(a)’s “ban on referral fees”);
    Geraci v. Homestreet Bank, 
    347 F.3d 749
    , 751 (9th Cir. 2003)
    (describing Section 8(c)(2) as a “safe harbor” and noting that
    HUD, when evaluating whether payments from mortgage
    lenders to mortgage brokers fall within Section 8(c), considers
    whether the payments for services “are reasonably related to
    the value of the . . . services that were actually performed”).
    At the time PHH engaged in its captive reinsurance
    arrangements, everyone knew the deal: Captive reinsurance
    arrangements were lawful under Section 8 so long as the
    mortgage insurer paid no more than reasonable market value to
    the reinsurer for reinsurance actually furnished.
    83
    In 2015, however, the CFPB decided that captive
    reinsurance agreements were prohibited by Section 8. The
    CFPB then applied its new interpretation of Section 8
    retroactively against PHH, ruling against PHH based on
    conduct that had occurred as far back as 2008. The
    retroactive application of the CFPB’s new interpretation
    violated the Due Process Clause.
    The Due Process Clause limits the extent to which the
    Government may retroactively alter the legal consequences of
    an entity’s or person’s past conduct. That anti-retroactivity
    principle “is deeply rooted in our jurisprudence, and embodies
    a legal doctrine centuries older than our Republic.” Landgraf
    v. USI Film Products, 
    511 U.S. 244
    , 265 (1994); see also
    Eastern Enterprises v. Apfel, 
    524 U.S. 498
    , 547 (1998)
    (Kennedy, J., concurring in the judgment and dissenting in
    part) (“[F]or centuries our law has harbored a singular distrust
    of retroactive statutes.”).
    Retroactivity – in particular, a new agency interpretation
    that is retroactively applied to proscribe past conduct –
    contravenes the bedrock due process principle that the people
    should have fair notice of what conduct is prohibited. As the
    Supreme Court has emphasized, “individuals should have an
    opportunity to know what the law is and to conform their
    conduct accordingly.” Landgraf, 
    511 U.S. at 265
    . Due
    process therefore requires agencies to “provide regulated
    parties fair warning of the conduct a regulation prohibits or
    requires.” Christopher v. SmithKline Beecham Corp., 
    132 S. Ct. 2156
    , 2167, slip op. at 10-11 (2012) (internal quotation
    marks and alteration omitted); see also FCC v. Fox Television
    Stations, Inc., 
    132 S. Ct. 2307
    , 2317, slip op. at 11 (2012) (“A
    fundamental principle in our legal system is that laws which
    regulate persons or entities must give fair notice of conduct that
    is forbidden or required.”); cf. United States v. Pennsylvania
    84
    Industrial Chemical Corp., 
    411 U.S. 655
    , 674 (1973) (“Thus,
    to the extent that the regulations deprived PICCO of fair
    warning as to what conduct the Government intended to make
    criminal, we think there can be no doubt that traditional notions
    of fairness inherent in our system of criminal justice prevent
    the Government from proceeding with the prosecution.”); Cox
    v. Louisiana, 
    379 U.S. 559
    , 571 (1965) (“[U]nder all the
    circumstances of this case, after the public officials acted as
    they did, to sustain appellant’s later conviction for
    demonstrating where they told him he could would be to
    sanction an indefensible sort of entrapment by the State –
    convicting a citizen for exercising a privilege which the State
    had clearly told him was available to him. The Due Process
    Clause does not permit convictions to be obtained under such
    circumstances.”) (internal quotation marks and citation
    omitted); Bouie v. City of Columbia, 
    378 U.S. 347
    , 350-51
    (1964) (Due Process Clause violated when state punished
    defendants “for conduct that was not criminal at the time they
    committed it” because the “underlying principle” of fair
    warning dictates that “no man shall be held criminally
    responsible for conduct which he could not reasonably
    understand to be proscribed”) (internal quotation marks
    omitted); Raley v. Ohio, 
    360 U.S. 423
    , 438-39 (1959) (“There
    was active misleading. The State Supreme Court dismissed
    the statements of the Commission as legally erroneous, but the
    fact remains that at the inquiry they were the voice of the State
    most presently speaking to the appellants. We cannot hold
    that the Due Process Clause permits convictions to be obtained
    under such circumstances.”) (internal citation omitted). 25
    25
    In the criminal context, Article I’s two Ex Post Facto Clauses
    bar retroactive criminal statutes. That principle is so fundamental to
    the protection of individual liberty that the Framers included it in the
    original Constitution, and made it applicable against both the
    National and State governments. See U.S. CONST. art. I, § 9, cl. 3;
    id. art. I, § 10, cl. 1. The Framers well understood that a free society
    85
    In SmithKline, for example, the Supreme Court refused to
    defer to the Department of Labor’s changed interpretation of a
    regulation because the regulated industry “had little reason to
    suspect that its longstanding practice” violated the law. 132
    S. Ct. at 2167, slip op. at 12. Neither the relevant statute nor
    any regulations provided clear notice of the Department of
    Labor’s new interpretation. “Even more important,” the
    Court said, was that “despite the industry’s decades-long
    practice,” the “DOL never initiated any enforcement actions”
    or “otherwise suggested that it thought the industry was acting
    unlawfully.” Id. at 2168, slip op. at 12.
    In SmithKline, in a sentence that all but decides the case
    before us, the Supreme Court further stated: An “agency
    should not change an interpretation in an adjudicative
    proceeding where doing so would impose new liability on
    individuals for past actions which were taken in good-faith
    reliance on agency pronouncements.” Id. at 2167, slip op. at
    11-12 (internal quotation marks and alterations omitted)
    (quoting NLRB v. Bell Aerospace Co., 
    416 U.S. 267
    , 295
    (1974)). The Court elaborated: “It is one thing to expect
    regulated parties to conform their conduct to an agency’s
    interpretations once the agency announces them; it is quite
    could not function if retroactive punishment were tolerated. See id.;
    see also Landgraf v. USI Film Products, 
    511 U.S. 244
    , 266-67
    (1994); THE FEDERALIST NO. 84, at 511-12 (Alexander Hamilton)
    (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961) (“[T]he subjecting of men to
    punishment for things which, when they were done, were breaches
    of no law, and the practice of arbitrary imprisonments, have been, in
    all ages, the favorite and most formidable instruments of tyranny.”);
    cf. GEORGE ORWELL, 1984, at 40 (1949) (“Day by day and almost
    minute by minute the past was brought up to date. . . . [N]or was
    any item of news, or any expression of opinion, which conflicted
    with the needs of the moment, ever allowed to remain on record.”).
    86
    another to require regulated parties to divine the agency’s
    interpretations in advance or else be held liable when the
    agency announces its interpretations for the first time in an
    enforcement proceeding and demands deference.” Id. at
    2168, slip op. at 14. Because automatically accepting the
    Department of Labor’s new interpretation “would result in
    precisely the kind of unfair surprise against which our cases
    have long warned,” the Supreme Court refused to defer to the
    Department of Labor’s retroactive application of a changed
    interpretation of its own regulations. Id. at 2167, slip op. at 11
    (internal quotation marks omitted).
    All of those fundamental anti-retroactivity principles are
    Rule of Law 101.             And all of those fundamental
    anti-retroactivity principles fit this case precisely. PHH did
    not have fair notice of the CFPB’s interpretation of Section 8 at
    the time PHH engaged in the conduct at issue here. PHH
    participated in captive reinsurance arrangements in justifiable
    reliance on the interpretation stated by HUD in 1997 and
    restated in 2004. The CFPB therefore violated due process by
    retroactively applying its changed interpretation to PHH’s past
    conduct and requiring PHH to pay $109 million for that
    conduct.
    The CFPB retorts that there is a presumption in favor of
    retroactive application of agencies’ interpretations of
    ambiguous statutes. CFPB Br. 42-43. But here, the CFPB
    was changing the Government’s longstanding interpretation of
    that statute and then applying that changed interpretation
    retroactively. The CFPB’s decision was a reversal of position
    – an “abrupt departure” from a consistent, longstanding
    position. Clark-Cowlitz Joint Operating Agency v. FERC,
    
    826 F.2d 1074
    , 1081 (D.C. Cir. 1987) (en banc) (internal
    quotation marks omitted). The Due Process Clause does not
    allow retroactive application of such a change.
    87
    The CFPB responds that nothing, including the 1997
    letter, gave regulated entities such as PHH a reason to rely on
    HUD’s interpretation. CFPB Br. 44-45. But in the 1997
    letter, the Presidentially appointed and Senate-confirmed
    Assistant Secretary of HUD stated: “I trust that this guidance
    will assist you to conduct your business in accordance with
    RESPA.”        Letter from Nicolas P. Retsinas, Assistant
    Secretary for Housing, Department of Housing and Urban
    Development, to Countrywide Funding Corporation 8 (Aug. 6,
    1997) (J.A. 258). We therefore find this particular CFPB
    argument deeply unsettling in a Nation built on the Rule of
    Law. When a government agency officially and expressly
    tells you that you are legally allowed to do something, but later
    tells you “just kidding” and enforces the law retroactively
    against you and sanctions you for actions you took in reliance
    on the government’s assurances, that amounts to a serious due
    process violation. The rule of law constrains the governors as
    well as the governed.
    The CFPB protests that the HUD pronouncements were
    not reflected in a binding HUD rule. To begin with, that is
    wrong.      As discussed, Regulation X reflected HUD’s
    longstanding interpretation that Section 8(c) allowed payments
    of reasonable market value for services actually performed.
    See 
    12 C.F.R. § 1024.14
     (2012) (CFPB codification of
    Regulation X Section 8 provisions); 
    24 C.F.R. § 3500.14
    (2011) (HUD Regulation X Section 8 provisions). In any
    event, the CFPB is confusing (i) the administrative law issue of
    whether an agency rule is sufficiently authoritative to obtain
    Chevron deference or to constitute a norm of proscribed
    conduct that the agency may enforce and (ii) the due process
    issue of whether an agency statement pronouncing the legality
    of certain conduct was sufficiently official for citizens to rely
    on it as the citizens arranged their conduct. To trigger the
    88
    latter due process protection, an agency pronouncement about
    the legality of proposed private conduct need not have been set
    forth in a rule preceded by notice and comment rulemaking, or
    the like. Here, the agency guidance was provided by top HUD
    officials and was given repeatedly. Although we do not imply
    that those two conditions are necessary to justify citizens’
    reliance for purposes of the Due Process Clause, they are
    surely sufficient. Here, the regulated industry reasonably
    relied on those agency pronouncements.
    Put aside all the legalese for a moment. Imagine that a
    police officer tells a pedestrian that the pedestrian can lawfully
    cross the street at a certain place. The pedestrian carefully and
    precisely follows the officer’s direction. After the pedestrian
    arrives at the other side of the street, however, the officer hands
    the pedestrian a $1,000 jaywalking ticket. No one would
    seriously contend that the officer had acted fairly or in a
    manner consistent with basic due process in that situation.
    See Cox v. Louisiana, 
    379 U.S. 559
    , 571 (1965). Yet that’s
    precisely this case. Here, the CFPB is arguing that it has the
    authority to order PHH to pay $109 million even though PHH
    acted in reliance upon numerous government pronouncements
    authorizing precisely the conduct in which PHH engaged.
    The Due Process Clause does not countenance the CFPB’s
    gamesmanship. As Justice Kennedy eloquently explained in a
    related scenario: “If retroactive laws change the legal
    consequences of transactions long closed, the change can
    destroy the reasonable certainty and security which are the
    very objects of property ownership. . . . Groups targeted by
    retroactive laws, were they to be denied all protection, would
    have a justified fear that a government once formed to protect
    expectations now can destroy them. Both stability of
    investment and confidence in the constitutional system, then,
    are secured by due process restrictions against severe
    89
    retroactive legislation.” Eastern Enterprises, 524 U.S. at
    548-49 (Kennedy, J., concurring in the judgment and
    dissenting in part); see also General Electric Co. v. EPA, 
    53 F.3d 1324
    , 1328-29 (D.C. Cir. 1995) (“In the absence of notice
    – for example, where the regulation is not sufficiently clear to
    warn a party about what is expected of it – an agency may not
    deprive a party of property by imposing civil or criminal
    liability.”); Satellite Broadcasting Co. v. FCC, 
    824 F.2d 1
    , 3-4
    (D.C. Cir. 1987) (“Traditional concepts of due process . . .
    preclude an agency from penalizing a private party for
    violating a rule without first providing adequate notice of the
    substance of the rule. . . . Otherwise the practice of
    administrative law would come to resemble ‘Russian
    Roulette.’).
    In sum, even if the CFPB’s new interpretation of Section 8
    were a permissible interpretation of the statute, which it is not,
    the CFPB’s interpretation could not constitutionally be applied
    retroactively to PHH’s conduct that occurred before that new
    interpretation. 26 On remand, to reiterate, the CFPB may
    determine whether the relevant mortgage insurers paid more
    than reasonable market value to the reinsurer Atrium, which is
    what the statute proscribes and what HUD’s longstanding
    pronouncements provided. 27
    26
    To be clear, Section IV-A and Section IV-B of this opinion
    represent alternative holdings on the question of whether the CFPB
    permissibly determined that PHH violated Section 8. As alternative
    holdings, both holdings constitute binding precedent of the Court.
    See Association of Battery Recyclers, Inc. v. EPA, 
    716 F.3d 667
    , 673
    (D.C. Cir. 2013).
    27
    Proving that the mortgage insurer paid more than reasonable
    market value – and thus made a disguised payment for the referral –
    is an element of the Section 8 offense that the CFPB has the burden
    of proving by a preponderance of the evidence. See 
    12 C.F.R. § 1081.303
    (a) (2016); see also Director, Office of Workers’
    90
    V
    In order to hold PHH liable, the CFPB must therefore
    show that the relevant mortgage insurers paid more than
    reasonable market value to Atrium for the reinsurance. On
    remand, the CFPB may attempt to make that showing,
    assuming that any relevant conduct by PHH occurred within
    the applicable statute of limitations period. That in turn brings
    us to the statute of limitations issue. PHH contends that most
    of its relevant activity occurred outside of the three-year statute
    of limitations applicable in this case.
    “Statutes of limitations are intended to promote justice by
    preventing surprises through the revival of claims that have
    been allowed to slumber until evidence has been lost,
    memories have faded, and witnesses have disappeared.”
    Gabelli v. SEC, 
    133 S. Ct. 1216
    , 1221, slip op. at 5 (2013)
    (internal quotation marks omitted). Statutes of limitations
    Compensation Programs, Department of Labor v. Greenwich
    Collieries, 
    512 U.S. 267
    , 271, 276 (1994) (APA’s use of “burden of
    proof” in 
    5 U.S.C. § 556
     places both burden of persuasion and
    burden of production on proponent of order); 
    12 U.S.C. § 5563
    (a)
    (CFPB is authorized to conduct adjudication proceedings “in the
    manner prescribed by chapter 5 of title 5,” which includes
    Administrative Procedure Act burden of proof requirements in 
    5 U.S.C. § 556
    ). The CFPB characterizes this issue as an affirmative
    defense. That is wrong. If there were express payments in
    exchange for referrals in this case, and PHH was trying to argue that
    the payments nonetheless were justified under some exception, that
    might potentially fit within the affirmative defense box. But here,
    there were no such express payments in exchange for referrals. It is
    the CFPB’s burden to prove that the payments for reinsurance were
    more than reasonable market value and were disguised payments for
    referrals.
    91
    also “provide security and stability to human affairs” by
    affording “certainty” about “a defendant’s potential liabilities.”
    
    Id.
     (internal quotation marks omitted).
    The general working presumption in federal civil and
    criminal cases is that a federal civil cause of action or criminal
    offense must have some statute of limitations and must not
    allow suits to be brought forever and ever after the acts in
    question. See 28 U.S.C § 2462; 
    18 U.S.C. § 3282
    . As Chief
    Justice Marshall stated, allowing parties to sue “at any distance
    of time” would be “ utterly repugnant to the genius of our laws.
    In a country where not even treason can be prosecuted after a
    lapse of three years, it could scarcely be supposed that an
    individual would remain forever liable to a pecuniary
    forfeiture.” Adams v. Woods, 
    6 U.S. 336
    , 342 (1805).
    The Dodd-Frank Act authorizes the CFPB to “conduct
    hearings and adjudication proceedings” to enforce the Real
    Estate Settlement Procedures Act. 
    12 U.S.C. § 5563
    (a). The
    Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act, in turn, provides that
    the CFPB may “bring an action to enjoin violations” of Section
    8. 
    Id.
     § 2607(d)(4). As it now reads, the Real Estate
    Settlement Procedures Act also provides that “actions” brought
    by various government agencies, including the CFPB, to
    enforce Section 8 “may be brought within 3 years from the date
    of the occurrence of the violation.” Id. § 2614.
    The CFPB says that no statute of limitations applies to its
    case against PHH. CFPB Br. 38. The CFPB advances two
    primary arguments. First, the CFPB contends it is broadly
    authorized to bring enforcement actions under the Dodd-Frank
    Act, and the CFPB says that the Dodd-Frank Act contains no
    statute of limitations on CFPB enforcement actions brought in
    an administrative proceeding, as opposed to in court.
    Notably, that broad argument would apply to all 19 of the
    92
    consumer protection statutes that the CFPB enforces, and
    would mean that no statute of limitations applies to CFPB
    administrative actions enforcing any of those statutes.
    Second, if the Dodd-Frank Act does not override the
    statutes of limitations in all of the underlying statutes enforced
    by the CFPB, meaning that the CFPB must abide by the
    statutes of limitations in the underlying statutes, the CFPB
    contends that the statute at issue here – the Real Estate
    Settlement Procedures Act – imposes a three-year statute of
    limitations only on those enforcement actions that the CFPB
    brings in court. According to the CFPB, the Real Estate
    Settlement Procedures Act does not impose any statute of
    limitations for those enforcement actions that the CFPB brings
    in administrative proceedings.
    Neither of the CFPB’s arguments is correct.
    First, the CFPB argues that we should ignore any statute
    of limitations contained in the Real Estate Settlement
    Procedures Act. Instead, the CFPB claims that we should
    look to the general enforcement provisions of the Dodd-Frank
    Act because those Dodd-Frank provisions, according to the
    CFPB, trump the statutes of limitations in the underlying
    statutes enforced by the CFPB.
    Under the Dodd-Frank Act, the CFPB may bring an
    enforcement action either in an administrative action or in
    court. See 
    12 U.S.C. §§ 5563-5564
    . According to the CFPB,
    that choice matters for statute of limitations purposes. The
    CFPB says that the Dodd-Frank “provision that authorizes
    court actions includes a statute of limitations,” but the
    “provision authorizing administrative enforcement does not.”
    CFPB Br. 38 (emphasis added).            Because the CFPB
    challenged PHH’s conduct through an administrative action
    93
    rather than in court, the CFPB concludes that there is no
    applicable statute of limitations.
    Importantly, the CFPB’s Dodd-Frank-based argument – if
    accepted here – would apply not only to actions to enforce
    Section 8 of the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act. The
    CFPB’s argument that it is not bound by any statute of
    limitations in administrative proceedings would extend to all
    19 of the consumer protection laws that Congress empowered
    the CFPB to enforce.          Cf. Integrity Advance, LLC,
    2015-CFPB-0029, Doc. No. 33, CFPB Opposition to Motion to
    Dismiss, at 12 (arguing no statute of limitations applies to
    CFPB administrative action to enforce the Truth in Lending
    Act and the Electronic Fund Transfer Act).
    The CFPB’s argument misreads the enforcement
    provisions of the Dodd-Frank Act. Section 5563 authorizes
    the CFPB “to conduct hearings and adjudication proceedings
    . . . in order to ensure or enforce compliance with” 19 federal
    consumer protection laws, in addition to other rules,
    regulations, and orders. 
    12 U.S.C. § 5563
    (a). But Congress
    limited the enforcement power granted in Section 5563. The
    CFPB may enforce those federal laws “unless such Federal law
    specifically limits the Bureau from conducting a hearing or
    adjudication proceeding.” 
    Id.
     § 5563(a)(2) (emphasis added).
    Obviously, one such “limit” is a statute of limitations. By its
    terms, then, Section 5563 ties the CFPB’s administrative
    adjudications to the statutes of limitations of the various
    federal consumer protection laws it is charged with
    enforcing. 28 The Dodd-Frank Act therefore makes clear that
    28
    Similarly, for actions the CFPB brings in court under any of
    the 18 pre-existing consumer protection statutes, the CFPB may only
    “commence, defend, or intervene in the action in accordance with the
    requirements of that provision of law, as applicable.” 
    12 U.S.C. § 5564
    (g)(2)(B).
    94
    in its enforcement action against PHH, the CFPB was bound by
    any statute of limitations located in the Real Estate Settlement
    Procedures Act.
    Second, as to the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act
    itself, the CFPB argues that the three-year limitations period in
    Section 2614 of that Act applies only to CFPB actions to
    enforce Section 8 in court, not to CFPB administrative actions
    to enforce Section 8 before the agency. We again disagree.
    Section 2614 supplies the appropriate statute of limitations
    period not only for CFPB actions to enforce Section 8 that are
    brought in court, but also for CFPB actions to enforce Section
    8 that are brought administratively. 29
    The first part of Section 2614 specifies a general one-year
    statute of limitations for any “action pursuant to” Section 8
    “brought in the United States district court or in any other court
    of competent jurisdiction.” 
    Id.
     § 2614.
    The second part of Section 2614 supplies a longer,
    three-year statute of limitations for “actions” to enforce
    Section 8 “brought by the Bureau, the Secretary, the Attorney
    29
    In full, Section 2614 provides: “Any action pursuant to the
    provisions of section 2605, 2607, or 2608 of this title may be brought
    in the United States district court or in any other court of competent
    jurisdiction, for the district in which the property involved is located,
    or where the violation is alleged to have occurred, within 3 years in
    the case of a violation of section 2605 of this title and 1 year in the
    case of a violation of section 2607 or 2608 of this title from the date
    of the occurrence of the violation, except that actions brought by the
    Bureau, the Secretary, the Attorney General of any State, or the
    insurance commissioner of any State may be brought within 3 years
    from the date of the occurrence of the violation.” 
    12 U.S.C. § 2614
    .
    Note that the referenced Section 2607 of Title 12 is Section 8 of the
    Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act.
    95
    General of any State, or the insurance commissioner of any
    State.” 
    Id.
     In this second part of Section 2614, the term
    “actions” is not limited to actions brought in court. Section
    2614 does not specify a jurisdiction or forum for actions by the
    Bureau, the Secretary, the Attorney General of any State, or the
    insurance commissioner of any State. Section 2614 simply
    requires that those actions be brought within a three-year
    limitations period.
    On its face, the statute of limitations for actions under
    Section 8 is therefore straightforward: Private plaintiffs can
    bring actions under Section 8 only in court. Private plaintiffs
    cannot bring administrative actions. For those private-party
    suits, a one-year statute of limitations applies. The relevant
    government enforcement agencies – including the CFPB – may
    bring actions to enforce Section 8 in courts or in administrative
    proceedings.      For those cases, a three-year statute of
    limitations applies.
    In response, the CFPB claims that the term “actions” in
    Section 2614 refers only to court actions, not to administrative
    actions. The CFPB argues that Congress uses the word
    “proceedings” rather than “actions” when it wants to refer to
    administrative actions. That is flatly wrong. Indeed, the
    Dodd-Frank Act itself, which amended Section 2614 to its
    current form, directly contradicts the CFPB’s assertion about
    the meaning of the term “action.” The Dodd-Frank Act
    repeatedly uses the term “action” to encompass court actions
    and administrative proceedings. See, e.g., 
    id.
     § 5497(d)(1)
    (“If the Bureau obtains a civil penalty against any person in any
    judicial or administrative action under Federal consumer
    financial laws . . . .”); id. § 5537(b)(1) (establishing grant
    program for States “to hire staff to identify, investigate, and
    prosecute (through civil, administrative, or criminal
    enforcement actions) cases involving misleading or fraudulent
    96
    marketing”); id. § 5538(b)(6) (“Whenever a civil action or an
    administrative action has been instituted by or on behalf of the
    Bureau . . . .”); id. § 5565(c) (subsection entitled “Civil money
    penalty in court and administrative actions”). The same can
    be said for various provisions scattered throughout the U.S.
    Code. See, e.g., 7 U.S.C. § 2279d (“Such liability shall apply
    to any administrative action brought before October 21, 1998,
    but only if the action is brought within the applicable statute of
    limitations . . . .”); 15 U.S.C. § 78u-6(a)(1) (“The term
    ‘covered judicial or administrative action’ means any judicial
    or administrative action brought by the Commission under the
    securities laws that results in monetary sanctions exceeding
    $1,000,000.”); 
    42 U.S.C. § 9628
    (b)(1)(B) (“The President may
    bring an administrative or judicial enforcement action under
    this chapter . . . .”); 
    49 U.S.C. § 60120
    (a)(1) (“The maximum
    amount of civil penalties for administrative enforcement
    actions under section 60122 shall not apply to enforcement
    actions under this section.”).
    The CFPB also cites BP America Production Co. v.
    Burton, 
    549 U.S. 84
     (2006). There, the Supreme Court ruled
    that 
    28 U.S.C. § 2415
    (a) – a civil statute of limitations
    provision for “every action for money damages” brought by
    the Government – encompassed only court actions, and not
    agency enforcement actions. BP America, 
    549 U.S. at 89, 101
    (internal quotation marks and emphasis omitted). To arrive at
    that conclusion, the Court looked to a wide array of textual and
    structural clues in that statutory scheme. For example, the
    Court noted that the “key terms in th[e] provision – ‘action’
    and ‘complaint’ – are ordinarily used in connection with
    judicial, not administrative, proceedings.” 
    Id. at 91
    . That
    conclusion was reinforced by Congress’s use of the word
    “action” as part of the term “action for money damages,”
    which is “generally used to mean pecuniary compensation or
    indemnity, which may be recovered in the courts.” 
    Id.
     at
    97
    91-92 (internal quotation marks omitted). The Supreme Court
    also noted Congress’s use of the term “right of action” in the
    same provision, which is defined as the “right to bring suit; a
    legal right to maintain an action, with suit meaning any
    proceeding . . . in a court of justice.” 
    Id. at 91
     (internal
    quotation marks omitted) (quoting BLACK’S LAW DICTIONARY
    1488, 1603 (4th ed. 1951)).
    At the very most, BP America articulated a presumption
    that the term “action” means court proceedings. But it is at
    most a presumption. BP America certainly never said that the
    term “actions” always means actions in court. Far from it.
    Indeed, Supreme Court cases interpret the term “actions” to
    encompass administrative actions. See West v. Gibson, 
    527 U.S. 212
    , 220-21 (1999); Pennsylvania v. Delaware Valley
    Citizens’ Council for Clean Air, 
    478 U.S. 546
    , 557-60 (1986).
    The question of whether the term “actions” in a particular
    statute encompasses administrative actions thus turns on the
    overall text, context, purpose, and history of the statute. Here,
    the textual and contextual clues convincingly demonstrate that
    administrative actions are covered. Unlike in BP America,
    the key part of Section 2614 – which refers to “actions”
    brought by the CFPB – speaks of an “action” generically and is
    not limited to an “action for money damages.” Section 2614
    also lacks other “key terms” like “complaint” or “right of
    action” that were present in the statute at issue in BP America.
    The broader purpose and history of the Dodd-Frank Act
    strongly reinforce the conclusion that the CFPB is bound by a
    three-year statute of limitations in its administrative actions to
    enforce Section 8. Before 2010, HUD could not bring
    administrative enforcement actions to enforce Section 8.
    HUD could sue only in court. The CFPB acknowledges that a
    three-year statute of limitations applied to all of those HUD
    98
    actions to enforce Section 8. When passing the Dodd-Frank
    Act in 2010, Congress empowered the CFPB (taking over for
    HUD) to enforce Section 8 not just in courts, but also in
    administrative actions. Importantly, the CFPB has complete
    discretion to institute enforcement actions in courts or through
    administrative actions. See 
    12 U.S.C. §§ 5563-5564
    . And
    the CFPB can obtain administratively all of the remedies that it
    could obtain in court. 
    Id.
     § 5565(a)(2). The CFPB’s theory
    is that Congress – for some unstated reason – did not carry
    forward the three-year statute of limitations for CFPB
    administrative actions to enforce Section 8. Under the
    CFPB’s theory, the agency therefore can always circumvent
    the three-year statute of limitations simply by bringing the
    enforcement action administratively rather than in court. But
    Congress did not suggest that by transferring authority from
    HUD to the CFPB, it intended to relax the longstanding
    three-year statute of limitations.
    Moreover, “Congress ‘does not, one might say, hide
    elephants in mouseholes.’”         Puerto Rico v. Franklin
    California Tax-Free Trust, 
    136 S. Ct. 1938
    , 1947, slip op. at 11
    (2016) (quoting Whitman v. American Trucking Associations,
    Inc., 
    531 U.S. 457
    , 468 (2001)). If by means of the
    Dodd-Frank Act, “Congress intended to alter” the fundamental
    details of the statutes of limitations for enforcement of this
    critical consumer protection law, “we would expect the text of
    the amended” statute “to say so.” 
    Id.
     (internal quotation
    marks omitted). In other words, we would expect Congress to
    actually say that there is no statute of limitations for CFPB
    administrative actions to enforce Section 8, especially given
    that the CFPB has full discretion to pursue administrative
    actions instead of court proceedings and can obtain all of the
    same remedies through administrative actions that it can obtain
    in court. But the text of Dodd-Frank says no such thing.
    99
    Nor, moreover, has the CFPB cited any legislative history that
    says anything like that.
    Of course, there is good reason Congress did not say that
    the CFPB need not comply with any statutes of limitations
    when enforcing the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act
    administratively. That would be absurd. Why would
    Congress allow the CFPB to bring administrative actions for an
    indefinite period, years or even decades after the fact? Why
    would Congress create such a nonsensical dichotomy between
    CFPB court actions and CFPB administrative actions? The
    CFPB has articulated no remotely plausible reason why
    Congress would have done so. See Griffin v. Oceanic
    Contractors, Inc., 
    458 U.S. 564
    , 575 (1982) (“absurd results
    are to be avoided” where “alternative interpretations consistent
    with the legislative purpose are available”). The CFPB’s
    interpretation is especially alarming because the agency can
    seek civil penalties in these administrative actions. 
    12 U.S.C. § 5565
    (a)(2). But the Supreme Court has emphatically
    stressed the importance of statutes of limitations in civil
    penalty provisions. As the Supreme Court stated in Gabelli:
    “Chief Justice Marshall used particularly forceful language in
    emphasizing the importance of time limits on penalty actions,
    stating that it ‘would be utterly repugnant to the genius of our
    laws’ if actions for penalties could ‘be brought at any distance
    of time.’” 133 S. Ct. at 1223, slip op. at 9 (quoting Adams, 
    6 U.S. at 342
    ); see also 3M Co. v. Browner, 
    17 F.3d 1453
    , 1457
    (D.C. Cir. 1994) (“Justice Story, sitting as a circuit justice in a
    civil penalty case, made the same point as Chief Justice
    Marshall: ‘it would be utterly repugnant to the genius of our
    laws, to allow such prosecutions a perpetuity of existence.’”)
    (quoting United States v. Mayo, 
    26 F. Cas. 1230
    , 1231 (No.
    15,754) (C.C.D. Mass. 1813)).
    100
    The absurdity of the CFPB’s position is illustrated by its
    response to a hypothetical question about the CFPB’s bringing
    an administrative enforcement action 100 years after the
    allegedly unlawful conduct. Presented with that question, the
    CFPB referenced its prosecutorial discretion. But “trust us” is
    ordinarily not good enough. Cf. McDonnell v. United States,
    
    136 S. Ct. 2355
    , 2372-73, slip op. at 23 (2016) (declining to
    construe a statute “on the assumption that the Government will
    use it responsibly”) (internal quotation marks omitted). The
    CFPB also suggested that the equitable defense of laches might
    apply to such a case, and that “a court would look askance at a
    proceeding” initiated 100 years after the challenged conduct
    occurred. CFPB Br. 38 n.28. We need not wait for an
    enforcement action 100 years after the fact. This Court looks
    askance now at the idea that the CFPB is free to pursue an
    administrative enforcement action for an indefinite period of
    time after the relevant conduct took place. A much more
    logical, predictable interpretation of the agency’s authority is
    that the three-year limitations period in Section 2614 applies
    equally to CFPB court actions and CFPB administrative
    actions. And most importantly for our purposes, that is what
    the relevant statutes actually say. 30
    ***
    We grant PHH’s petition for review, vacate the CFPB’s
    order, and remand for further proceedings consistent with this
    opinion. On remand, the CFPB may determine, among other
    things, whether, consistent with the applicable three-year
    30
    We do not here decide whether each alleged
    above-reasonable-market value payment from the mortgage insurer
    to the reinsurer triggers a new three-year statute of limitations for
    that payment. We leave that question for the CFPB on remand and
    any future court proceedings.
    101
    statute of limitations, the relevant mortgage insurers paid more
    than reasonable market value to Atrium.
    So ordered.
    RANDOLPH, Senior Circuit Judge, concurring: After the
    enforcement unit of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau
    filed a Notice of Charges against petitioners, an Administrative
    Law Judge held a nine-day hearing and issued a recommended
    decision, concluding that petitioners had violated the Real Estate
    Settlement Procedures Act of 1974. In the administrative
    appeal, the Director “affirm[ed]” the ALJ’s conclusion that
    petitioners violated the Act.
    I believe that the ALJ who presided over the hearing was an
    “inferior Officer” within the meaning of Article II, section 2,
    clause 2 of the Constitution. That constitutional provision
    requires “inferior Officers” to be appointed by the President, the
    “Courts of Law,” or the “Heads of Departments.” This ALJ
    was not so appointed. Pursuant to an agreement between the
    Bureau and the Securities and Exchange Commission, the SEC’s
    Chief Administrative Law Judge assigned him to the case. This
    in itself rendered the proceedings against petitioners
    unconstitutional.
    To me, the case is indistinguishable from Freytag v.
    Commissioner of Internal Revenue, 
    501 U.S. 868
     (1991). My
    reasoning is set forth in Landry v. Federal Deposit Insurance
    Corp., 
    204 F.3d 1125
    , 1140-44 (D.C. Cir. 2000) (Randolph, J.,
    concurring in part and concurring in the judgment). There is no
    need to repeat what I wrote there. The majority opinion in
    Landry disagreed with my position, but petitioners have
    preserved the issue for review by this court en banc or by the
    Supreme Court on certiorari. Pet. Br. 51 n.8. The Bureau, in its
    brief, argues that petitioners waived the issue because they did
    not raise it before the ALJ or on appeal to the Bureau’s Director.
    But the Freytag petitioners also raised their constitutional
    objection to the appointment of the special trial judge for the
    first time on appeal. See Freytag, 
    501 U.S. at 892-95
     (Scalia, J.,
    concurring). There is no difference between this case and
    Freytag, except that in light of Landry it would have been futile
    to object, a point that cuts in petitioners’ favor.
    KAREN LECRAFT HENDERSON, Circuit Judge, concurring
    in part and dissenting in part:
    In no uncertain terms, PHH has asked this Court to vacate
    the CFPB’s order, outlining three distinct reasons why it is
    entitled to that relief. As my colleagues ably demonstrate,
    PHH’s statutory arguments are sufficient to accomplish its
    goal—I agree that: (1) the Bureau’s interpretation of section
    8(c)(2) contravenes the language of the statute; (2) “action” in
    
    12 U.S.C. § 2614
     includes enforcement proceedings brought
    by the Bureau for a violation of section 8(a) and a three-year
    statute of limitations applies to those proceedings; (3) the
    Bureau’s interpretation of section 8(c)(2) is a new
    interpretation retroactively applied against PHH without fair
    notice; and (4) although the Bureau has the authority to order
    disgorgement as a sanction under 
    12 U.S.C. § 5565
    (a)(2)(D),
    the amount of any disgorgement award must be reduced by
    the amount the captive reinsurer paid the insurers for their
    reinsurance claims. 1 But my colleagues don’t stop there.
    Instead, they unnecessarily reach PHH’s constitutional
    challenge, thereby rejecting one of the most fundamental
    tenets of judicial decisionmaking. With respect, I cannot join
    them in this departure from longstanding precedent.
    Although courts remain resolute in “our duty as the
    bulwar[k] of a limited constitution against legislative
    encroachments,” at the same time we recognize “a well-
    established principle governing the prudent exercise of this
    Court’s jurisdiction that normally the Court will not decide a
    constitutional question if there is some other ground upon
    which to dispose of the case.” Nw. Austin Mun. Util. Dist. No.
    One v. Holder, 
    557 U.S. 193
    , 205 (2009) (quoting THE
    FEDERALIST No. 78, p. 526 (J. Cooke ed. 1961) (A.
    Hamilton); Rostker v. Goldberg, 
    453 U.S. 57
    , 64 (1981))
    1
    Accordingly, I concur in Parts I, IV and V of the majority
    opinion.
    2
    (internal quotations omitted). An unbroken line of Supreme
    Court cases teaches that “[i]t is not the habit of the court to
    decide questions of a constitutional nature unless absolutely
    necessary to a decision of the case.” Ashwander v. Tenn.
    Valley Auth., 
    297 U.S. 288
    , 347 (1936) (Brandeis, J.,
    concurring); accord Bond v. United States, 
    134 S. Ct. 2077
    ,
    2087 (2014); Union Pac. R. Co. v. Bhd. of Locomotive
    Engineers & Trainmen Gen. Comm. of Adjustment, Cent.
    Region, 
    558 U.S. 67
    , 80 (2009); Greater New Orleans Broad.
    Ass’n, Inc. v. United States, 
    527 U.S. 173
    , 184 (1999); Dep’t
    of Commerce v. U.S. House of Representatives, 
    525 U.S. 316
    ,
    343 (1999); Blum v. Bacon, 
    457 U.S. 132
    , 137 (1982).
    Determining the applicability of this judicial restraint
    principle is not a difficult task; indeed, a two-step inquiry
    decides whether constitutional analysis is necessary. First, we
    ask what relief a party seeks. See Nw. Austin Mun. Util. Dist.
    No. One, 
    557 U.S. at 205
     (determining whether statutory
    remedy affords aggrieved party “all the relief it seeks”).
    Federal Rule of Appellate Procedure 28(a)(9) makes this
    simple, as it requires that the party’s brief include “a short
    conclusion stating the precise relief sought.” Fed. R. App.
    Pro. 28(a)(9) (emphasis added). PHH makes its requested
    relief quite clear: “the appropriate remedy . . . is vacatur.” 2
    Petitioners’ Br. at 61.
    2
    My colleagues state that “PHH wants us, at a minimum, to
    strike down the CFPB and prevent its continued operation.” Maj.
    Op. at 65. Besides describing, if anything, the maximum relief
    available, they stray from the relief requested in PHH’s brief—
    vacatur. Petitioners’ Br. at 61. To the extent PHH changed its
    requested relief at oral argument, I believe we are to choose its
    writing over its speech. See, e.g., Whitehead v. Food Max of
    Mississippi, Inc., 
    163 F.3d 265
    , 270 (5th Cir. 1998) (citing Fed. R.
    3
    The next question, then, is whether the court can provide
    the requested relief—to its fullest extent—on statutory
    grounds. See Nw. Austin Mun. Util. Dist. No. One, 
    557 U.S. at 205
    . If so, we are to leave any constitutional question for
    another day. See Ashwander, 
    297 U.S. at 347
     (Brandeis, J.,
    concurring) (“The Court will not pass upon a constitutional
    question although properly presented by the record, if there is
    also present some other ground upon which the case may be
    disposed of.”). Indeed, my colleagues conclude that vacatur is
    warranted on statutory grounds. Maj. Op. at Parts IV, V.
    Because the statutory holding is sufficient, I believe our
    analysis should begin and end there. United States v. Wells
    Fargo Bank, 
    485 U.S. 351
    , 354 (1988) (“[O]ur established
    practice is to resolve statutory questions at the outset where to
    do so might obviate the need to consider a constitutional
    issue.”).
    My colleagues, however, insist that the constitutional
    issues be addressed before the statutory ones because
    resolution of the former could afford PHH broader relief. Maj.
    Op. at 10 n. 1. Notwithstanding their approach turns on its
    head the “fundamental rule of judicial restraint” that “[p]rior
    to reaching any constitutional questions, federal courts must
    consider nonconstitutional grounds for decision,” Jean v.
    Nelson, 
    472 U.S. 846
    , 854 (1985); Gulf Oil Co. v. Bernard,
    
    452 U.S. 89
    , 99 (1981); Mobile v. Bolden, 
    446 U.S. 55
    , 60
    (1980); Kolender v. Lawson, 
    461 U.S. 352
    , 361, n. 10 (1983),
    it misses the point—our focus should be on providing the full
    relief requested by the prevailing party, not the broadest relief
    implicated by its claim. See Nw. Austin Mun. Util. Dist. No.
    One, 
    557 U.S. at 205
    . Granted, in Nw. Austin Mun. Util. Dist.
    No. One, the Supreme Court rejected the argument that
    App. Pro. 28) (limiting relief to that requested in appellate brief
    rather than alternate relief first proposed at oral argument).
    4
    resolving the case solely on statutory grounds “would not
    afford [a plaintiff] all the relief it seeks”—even though the
    plaintiff’s constitutional challenge, if successful, would
    provide broader relief—because the plaintiff had “expressly
    describe[d] its constitutional challenge . . . as ‘being in the
    alternative’ to its statutory argument.” 
    Id.
     at 205–06; cf.
    Zobrest v. Catalina Foothills School Dist., 
    509 U.S. 1
    , 7–8
    (1993) (reaching Establishment Clause argument despite
    statutory ground because “[r]espondent did not urge any
    statutory grounds for affirmance upon the Court of
    Appeals . . . [and] [i]n the District Court, too, the parties
    chose to litigate the case on the federal constitutional issues
    alone”). Similarly, PHH has expressly relied on “three
    independent reasons” why vacatur is appropriate, treating its
    constitutional arguments as alternatives to its statutory
    counterparts. Petitioners’ Br. at 23. Thus, our duty is quite
    clear: “[A] federal court should not decide federal
    constitutional questions where a dispositive nonconstitutional
    ground is available.” Jean v. Nelson, 
    472 U.S. at 854
     (1985);
    Spector Motor Serv. v. McLaughlin, 
    323 U.S. 101
    , 105 (1944)
    (“If there is one doctrine more deeply rooted than any other in
    the process of constitutional adjudication, it is that we ought
    not to pass on questions of constitutionality . . . unless such
    adjudication is unavoidable.”).
    Nevertheless, my colleagues conclude that we must
    decide the constitutional issue because it involves “a
    fundamental constitutional challenge to the very structure or
    existence of an agency enforcing the law against it.” Maj. Op.
    at 10 n. 1. I again believe prudential considerations counsel
    against our reaching out to invalidate the for cause removal
    provision. See Spector Motor Serv., 
    323 U.S. at 105
    .
    First, the Supreme Court’s leading removal caselaw is
    distinguishable. In both Myers v. United States, 
    272 U.S. 52
    ,
    5
    106–07 (1926), and Humphrey’s Executor v. United States,
    
    295 U.S. 602
    , 618–19 (1935), the suit was brought by the
    officer removable for cause only and only after he had been
    removed from office. In Myers, the President, through the
    Postmaster General, removed a postmaster (Myers). 
    272 U.S. at 106
    . Myers protested the removal and eventually brought
    suit for back pay. 
    Id.
     After determining that laches did not
    prevent Myers from challenging his removal, the Court had to
    resolve whether the President had lawfully removed him. 
    Id.
    at 106–07. Humphrey’s Executor presented a similar
    question—the President removed a member (Humphrey) of
    the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) before his seven-year
    term concluded and without cause. 
    295 U.S. at
    618–19.
    Humphrey then sought back pay. 
    Id.
     The Court could not
    decide his back pay claim without first addressing the validity
    of Humphrey’s for-cause only removal restriction on the
    President’s Article II removal power. 
    Id.
     at 626–31.
    The holdings in Morrison v. Olson, 
    487 U.S. 654
     (1988),
    and Free Enter. Fund v. Pub. Co. Accounting Oversight Bd.,
    
    561 U.S. 477
     (2010), are equally inapposite. In Morrison, the
    appellees sought to quash subpoenas issued on behalf of the
    independent counsel by challenging the constitutionality of
    the legislation providing for appointment of an independent
    counsel removable by the Attorney General for cause only.
    
    487 U.S. at
    668–69. Other than the collateral issue of the
    proper scope of review of a contempt order, 
    id.
     at 669–70, the
    only challenges the appellees made throughout the litigation
    were constitutional in nature. 
    Id.
     at 668–70. Accordingly,
    although there were several grounds on which the appellees
    could have won their requested relief (quashing the
    subpoenas), each required consideration of a constitutional
    issue.
    6
    Free Enterprise Fund is perhaps the closest precedent yet
    it too is distinguishable. The Public Company Accounting
    Oversight Board (PCAOB) investigated an accounting firm
    for potential violations of statutes and regulations relating to
    the auditing of public companies. Free Enterprise Fund v.
    Pub. Co. Accounting Oversight Bd., No. 06–0217, 
    2007 WL 891675
    , at *2 (D.D.C. March 21, 2007). The PCAOB issued a
    report detailing the result of its preliminary investigation and
    plaintiffs Free Enterprise Fund and its accounting-firm
    member brought suit to enjoin the ongoing disciplinary
    proceedings. 
    Id.
     They sought a declaratory judgment “that the
    provisions of the Act establishing the PCAOB are
    unconstitutional” and “an order enjoining the Board from
    taking any further action against [the accounting firm].” 
    Id.
    Thus, the only challenge was a facial one to the
    constitutionality of the PCAOB—there was no statutory
    ground on which to reverse any PCAOB action because it had
    not yet taken action against the firm. Id. at *6. On review,
    we addressed the “facial challenge” that “Title I of the
    Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 . . . violates the Appointments
    Clause of the Constitution and separation of powers because it
    does not permit adequate Presidential control of the
    [PCAOB].” Free Enterprise Fund v. Pub. Co. Accounting
    Oversight Bd., 
    537 F.3d 667
    , 668 (D.C. Cir. 2008). Likewise,
    the Supreme Court granted relief on the constitutional
    removal power ground. 3 
    561 U.S. at
    510–14.
    This case does not fit the Court’s removal precedents.
    Myers and Humphrey’s Executor raised only constitutional
    questions. And unlike the challenges in Morrison and in Free
    Enterprise Fund, PHH has challenged—successfully—the
    3
    The Court separately affirmed the district court’s jurisdiction
    based on a direct review provision of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. 
    561 U.S. at
    489–90.
    7
    Bureau’s exercise of its statutory authority. Again, PHH can
    obtain full relief without our addressing the Bureau’s
    challenged structure. 4 Although I agree that “[w]hen
    constitutional questions are ‘indispensably necessary’ to
    resolving the case at hand, ‘the court must meet and decide
    them.’” Citizens United v. FEC, 
    558 U.S. 310
    , 375 (Roberts,
    C.J., concurring) (quoting Ex parte Randolph, 
    20 F. Cas. 242
    ,
    254 (No. 11, 558) (C.C.Va. 1833) (Marshall, C.J.)), I do not
    believe that it is “indispensably necessary” to resolve the for-
    cause removal issue here.
    To the extent the majority concludes that judicial restraint
    is irrelevant because PHH raises a structural constitutional
    issue, Supreme Court precedent on waiver of structural
    constitutional arguments advises otherwise. It is settled that a
    nonjurisdictional constitutional argument, including an Article
    III structural claim, can be waived. See, e.g., Plaut v.
    Spendthrift Farm, Inc., 
    514 U.S. 211
    , 231–32 (1995) (“[T]he
    proposition that legal defenses based upon doctrines central to
    the courts’ structural independence can never be waived
    simply does not accord with our cases.”); see also Al Bahlul v.
    United States, 
    792 F.3d 1
    , 33 (D.C. Cir. 2015) (Henderson, J.,
    dissenting) (“[T]he only nonforfeitable argument is subject-
    matter jurisdiction.”). Although waiver of an Article III
    structural challenge “cannot be dispositive,” Commodity
    4
    I do not suggest that the Bureau is immune from challenge.
    A deposed director or a regulated party could challenge the
    constitutionality of the Bureau, either in a stand-alone constitutional
    challenge as in Free Enterprise Fund or as part of an appeal of a
    Bureau enforcement proceeding if the statutory remedy did not
    provide full relief. And in all likelihood, that challenge will be
    before this Court relatively quickly. See, e.g., State Nat’l Bank of
    Big Spring v. Lew, No. CV 12-1032 (ESH), 
    2016 WL 3812637
    , at
    *1 (D.D.C. July 12, 2016) (holding in abeyance resolution of
    challenge to CFPB’s constitutionality until the decision here).
    8
    Future Trading Commission v. Schor, 
    478 U.S. 833
    , 851
    (1986), the Supreme Court has recently clarified that it
    remains within our discretion whether to reach such a
    challenge. See B&B Hardware, Inc. v. Hargis Industries, Inc.,
    
    135 S. Ct. 1293
    , 1304, 1305 n.2 (2015) (declining to consider
    Article III structure challenge not properly briefed); Wellness
    International Network, Ltd. v. Sharif, 
    135 S. Ct. 1932
    , 1942,
    1948–49 (2015) (reversing Seventh Circuit decision holding
    that Article III structural challenge could not be forfeited and
    remanding to determine forfeiture vel non); Plaut, 
    514 U.S. at
    231–32 (noting Schor Court “cho[se] to consider [Schor’s]
    Article III challenge” notwithstanding [his] consent to
    jurisdiction in the Article I tribunal and waiver of that
    challenge). Because resolution of the constitutionality of the
    Bureau’s structure is unnecessary in providing PHH full relief
    and because the Supreme Court’s removal jurisprudence does
    not lead to a contrary result, I believe we should stay our
    hand. Greater New Orleans Broad. Ass’n, Inc. v. United
    States, 
    527 U.S. 173
    , 184 (1999) (“It is . . . an established part
    of our constitutional jurisprudence that we do not ordinarily
    reach out to make novel or unnecessarily broad
    pronouncements on constitutional issues when a case can be
    fully resolved on a narrower ground.”).
    Accordingly, I respectfully dissent from Parts II and III
    of the majority opinion. In addition, I do not join the
    Introduction and Summary to the extent it “hold[s] that the
    CFPB is unconstitutionally structured.” Maj. Op. at 10.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 15-1177

Citation Numbers: 839 F.3d 1

Filed Date: 10/11/2016

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/12/2023

Authorities (94)

bennie-whitehead-susan-whitehead-individually-and-as-mother-and-adult-next , 163 F.3d 265 ( 1998 )

Lonnie Glover Dawn Glover v. Standard Federal Bank, ... , 283 F.3d 953 ( 2002 )

National Fuel Gas Supply Corp. v. Federal Energy Regulatory ... , 468 F.3d 831 ( 2006 )

3m-company-minnesota-mining-and-manufacturing-v-carol-m-browner , 17 F.3d 1453 ( 1994 )

Satellite Broadcasting Company, Inc. v. Federal ... , 824 F.2d 1 ( 1987 )

Gregory Geraci and Beverly Geraci, Husband and Wife on ... , 347 F.3d 749 ( 2003 )

Buckley v. Valeo , 96 S. Ct. 612 ( 1976 )

Alden v. Maine , 119 S. Ct. 2240 ( 1999 )

The Pocket Veto Case , 49 S. Ct. 463 ( 1929 )

Landry v. Federal Deposit Insurance Corp. , 204 F.3d 1125 ( 2000 )

Free Enterprise Fund v. Public Co. Accounting Oversight ... , 537 F.3d 667 ( 2008 )

In Re Aiken County , 645 F.3d 428 ( 2011 )

General Electric Company v. United States Environmental ... , 53 F.3d 1324 ( 1995 )

clark-cowlitz-joint-operating-agency-v-federal-energy-regulatory , 826 F.2d 1074 ( 1987 )

Manigault v. Springs , 26 S. Ct. 127 ( 1905 )

Immigration & Naturalization Service v. Chadha , 103 S. Ct. 2764 ( 1983 )

West v. Gibson , 119 S. Ct. 1906 ( 1999 )

Wellness Int'l Network, Ltd. v. Sharif , 191 L. Ed. 2d 911 ( 2015 )

King v. Burwell , 135 S. Ct. 2480 ( 2015 )

FERC v. Electric Power Supply Assn. , 136 S. Ct. 760 ( 2016 )

View All Authorities »