MERSCORP Holdings, Inc. v. Malloy ( 2016 )


Menu:
  • ******************************************************
    The ‘‘officially released’’ date that appears near the
    beginning of each opinion is the date the opinion will
    be published in the Connecticut Law Journal or the
    date it was released as a slip opinion. The operative
    date for the beginning of all time periods for filing
    postopinion motions and petitions for certification is
    the ‘‘officially released’’ date appearing in the opinion.
    In no event will any such motions be accepted before
    the ‘‘officially released’’ date.
    All opinions are subject to modification and technical
    correction prior to official publication in the Connecti-
    cut Reports and Connecticut Appellate Reports. In the
    event of discrepancies between the electronic version
    of an opinion and the print version appearing in the
    Connecticut Law Journal and subsequently in the Con-
    necticut Reports or Connecticut Appellate Reports, the
    latest print version is to be considered authoritative.
    The syllabus and procedural history accompanying
    the opinion as it appears on the Commission on Official
    Legal Publications Electronic Bulletin Board Service
    and in the Connecticut Law Journal and bound volumes
    of official reports are copyrighted by the Secretary of
    the State, State of Connecticut, and may not be repro-
    duced and distributed without the express written per-
    mission of the Commission on Official Legal
    Publications, Judicial Branch, State of Connecticut.
    ******************************************************
    MERSCORP HOLDINGS, INC., ET AL. v.
    DANNEL P. MALLOY ET AL.
    (SC 19376)
    Palmer, Zarella, Eveleigh, Espinosa and Robinson, Js.
    Argued October 14, 2015—officially released February 23, 2016
    Linda L. Morkan, with whom were Benjamin C.
    Jensen and, on the brief, James A. Wade and Norman
    H. Roos, for the appellants (plaintiffs).
    Matthew J. Budzik, assistant attorney general, with
    whom were Heather J. Wilson, assistant attorney gen-
    eral, and, on the brief, George Jepsen, attorney general,
    for the appellees (defendants).
    Ryan P. Barry and Michael J. Dyer filed a brief for the
    Connecticut Bankers Association et al. as amici curiae.
    J. L. Pottenger, Jr., Jeffrey Gentes, and Aurelia
    Chaudhury, Nicholas Gerschman and Marian Mess-
    ing, law student interns, filed a brief for the Jerome N.
    Frank Legal Services Organization and the Connecticut
    Fair Housing Center as amici curiae.
    Opinion
    PALMER, J. In 2013, the legislature amended the stat-
    utes governing Connecticut’s public land records sys-
    tem to create a two tiered system in which a mortgage
    nominee operating a national electronic database to
    track residential mortgage loans must pay recording
    fees approximately three times higher than do other
    mortgagees. The plaintiffs, MERSCORP Holdings, Inc.,
    and Mortgage Electronic Registration Systems, Inc.,
    who are currently the only entities required to pay the
    increased recording fees, commenced the present
    action against the defendants, Governor Dannel P. Mal-
    loy, Attorney General George Jepsen, Treasurer Denise
    L. Nappier, Kendall F. Wiggin, the state librarian, and
    LeAnne R. Power, the state public records administra-
    tor,1 seeking, inter alia, injunctive relief and a judgment
    declaring that this two tiered fee structure violates vari-
    ous provisions of the federal and state constitutions.
    Specifically, the plaintiffs alleged that General Statutes
    §§ 7-34a (a) (2) and 49-10 (h), as amended, violate the
    equal protection, due process, and takings provisions of
    the federal and state constitutions, the federal dormant
    commerce clause, and the federal prohibition against
    bills of attainder. The plaintiffs further alleged that
    enforcement of the statutes violates 42 U.S.C. § 1983.
    The parties filed motions for summary judgment, and
    the trial court granted the state’s motion for summary
    judgment on all counts and rendered judgment thereon.
    This appeal followed.2 We affirm the judgment of the
    trial court.
    I
    This case concerns the filing fees that the parties to a
    residential mortgage loan must pay to record mortgage
    documents in the public land records in Connecticut.
    Because the plaintiffs raise both federal and state con-
    stitutional issues of first impression, it will be helpful
    before considering the plaintiffs’ claims to briefly
    review the traditional procedure for recording residen-
    tial mortgage documents, certain relatively recent
    changes to that system, and the novel response of the
    Connecticut legislature to those changes.
    Under the traditional residential mortgage model, a
    person seeking to finance the purchase of a residential
    property obtains a loan from a lender, typically a bank,
    in exchange for a promissory note committing the bor-
    rower to repay the loan. To secure the loan, the bor-
    rower provides the lender a mortgage on the property.
    Although, in Connecticut, there is no legal requirement
    that the lender record the mortgage in the public land
    records, mortgages typically are recorded—via the
    clerk of the town in which the property is situated—
    in order (1) to perfect the lender’s security interest
    by giving public notice thereof, and (2) to maintain a
    complete public chain of title.
    Under the traditional model, the bank or other lender
    maintains the loan on its books and continues to service
    the loan until it is repaid. At that point, the parties
    typically record a release of the mortgage in the land
    records. At a minimum, then, the life of a residential
    mortgage loan may involve only two recordable events,
    although other events—for example, a transfer of the
    mortgage loan to another lender, or the creation or
    subordination of a home equity credit line—also may
    arise under the traditional model.
    The most significant factor in the decline of the tradi-
    tional residential mortgage model has been the develop-
    ment and evolution of the secondary mortgage market.
    A secondary market is created when the initial lender
    sells the mortgage loan to outside investors. Doing so
    provides local lenders with greater liquidity, which facil-
    itates additional home buying, and also allows large
    outside investors to pool—and thus to minimize—the
    risk that any particular loan will go into default.
    Although the modern secondary mortgage market had
    its genesis in the creation of the Federal Housing
    Authority and associated government sponsored financ-
    ing corporations such as Fannie Mae in the 1930s, it
    expanded dramatically in the 1980s with the advent of
    new types of mortgage backed securities for sale in the
    private equity markets.
    For mortgage loans sold in the secondary market,
    the investor typically engages a third party to perform
    servicing functions such as payment collection and file
    maintenance. Both the loan itself and the servicing
    rights may be sold or transferred multiple times over the
    life of a loan. Under the common-law rule, as codified in
    many states, the mortgage follows the note, so that an
    investor who acquires a residential note automatically
    obtains the attached security interest as well.
    Although the development of a robust and sophisti-
    cated secondary market has had a dramatic impact on
    the liquidity and, with some notable exceptions, the
    stability of the residential mortgage loan market, it also
    has created challenges for the public land record sys-
    tem. Because the ownership and servicing rights to a
    loan may be transferred multiple times over the life of
    a loan, the mortgagee of record, which may be either the
    note holder or the servicer as nominee, will frequently
    change. This means that each subsequent holder must
    choose either (1) to undertake the costly and time-
    consuming process of recording each of the numerous
    mortgages that it may briefly hold, subject to the varying
    costs and requirements of each state’s county or, as in
    Connecticut, each town clerk, or (2) to decline to record
    its interest, which may result in potential problems and
    costs resulting from an incomplete public chain of title.
    To address these problems, in the 1990s, the major
    public financial service corporations, in collaboration
    with various private interests, developed the national
    Mortgage Electronic Registration Systems (MERS) sys-
    tem. There are two primary components to the MERS
    model.3 First, MERS operates a national electronic reg-
    istration system that tracks any changes in the owner-
    ship and servicing rights of MERS-registered loans
    between MERS members, who include in-state and out-
    of-state mortgage lenders, servicers and subservicers,
    and public finance institutions. In this sense, MERS
    operates as a centralized, virtual alternative to the hun-
    dreds of traditional county or town land recording sys-
    tems throughout the country. Second, because MERS
    members cannot completely eschew the use of the pub-
    lic land records, MERS becomes the mortgage nominee
    on any loans held by MERS members, and is identified
    as such when the mortgage is initially recorded in the
    land records. Recording a mortgage with MERS as a
    mortgage nominee essentially creates a placeholder for
    the electronic MERS system in the public records,
    allowing the two systems to interoperate. That is to
    say, if a party searching the chain of title on a property
    comes upon a recorded mortgage to MERS, the party
    is thereby notified that the MERS database may be
    consulted to determine the present beneficial owner of
    the mortgage and loan, as well as any related servicing
    rights or subordinate security interests. MERS remains
    the mortgagee of record in the public records until the
    mortgage either is released or assigned to a nonmember
    of MERS.
    One potential advantage of the MERS system is that
    it eliminates the costs, in both time and fees, associated
    with recording each subsequent mortgage assignment
    in the public land records. Although the plaintiffs in
    the present case do not concede that any such savings
    have been realized in Connecticut, the parties do agree
    that, as of 2013, approximately 65 percent of mortgage
    loans nationally and in Connecticut originated with
    MERS acting as the mortgagee. The plaintiffs’ principal
    place of business is in Virginia.
    Turning our attention to the legislation that led to
    the present action, we note that, prior to July 15, 2013,
    § 7-34a required that all filers pay the town clerk $10
    for the first page of each document filed in the land
    records, plus $5 for each subsequent page. General Stat-
    utes (Rev. to 2013) § 7-34a (a). Section 7-34a imposed
    additional fees of $3 and $40 per filing; General Statutes
    (Rev. to 2013) § 7-34a (d) and (e); and an additional fee
    of $2 per assignment after the first two assignments.
    General Statutes (Rev. to 2013) § 7-34a (a).
    In 2013, General Statutes (Rev. to 2013) § 7-34a was
    amended by Public Acts, No. 13-184, § 98 (P.A. 13-184),
    and Public Acts, No. 13-247, § 82 (P.A. 13-247). As
    amended, § 7-34a defines a ‘‘nominee of a mortgagee’’
    as ‘‘any person who (i) serves as mortgagee in the land
    records for a mortgage loan registered on a national
    electronic database that tracks changes in mortgage
    servicing and beneficial ownership interests in residen-
    tial mortgage loans on behalf of its members, and (ii)
    is a nominee or agent for the owner of the promissory
    note or the subsequent buyer, transferee or beneficial
    owner of such note.’’ General Statutes § 7-34a (a) (2)
    (C). The parties agree that MERS is presently the only
    entity that qualifies as a nominee of a mortgagee, as so
    defined, and that the legislature crafted the statutory
    language with MERS specifically in mind.
    Section 7-34a, as amended, further provides that, with
    two exceptions, when a nominee of a mortgagee files
    a document in the land records, the town clerk shall
    collect a fee of $116 for the first page filed and $5 for
    each additional page. General Statutes § 7-34a (a) (2)
    (A). In addition, the clerk continues to collect $3 for
    each document pursuant to § 7-34a (d) and $40 for each
    document pursuant to § 7-34a (e). The two exceptions
    are that, when a nominee of a mortgagee files ‘‘(i) an
    assignment of mortgage in which a nominee of a mort-
    gagee appears as assignor, or (ii) a release of mortgage
    by the nominee of a mortgagee,’’ the town clerk collects
    a fee of $159, plus $10 for the first page and $5 for each
    additional page.4 See General Statutes § 7-34a (a) (1)
    and (2) (B). The recording fees for all other filers remain
    unchanged under the amended statute.
    The net effect of the amendments to § 7-34a (a) is to
    collect from a nominee of a mortgagee, namely, MERS,
    substantially more for the filing of deeds, assignments,
    and other documents in the land records than from any
    other filer. When filing a mortgage deed, for example,
    if MERS is a party to the transaction, the recording fee
    will be $159 ($116 plus $3 plus $40) for the first page
    and $5 for each additional page. See General Statutes
    § 7-34a (a) (2) (A), (d) and (e). If MERS is not a party
    to the transaction, the recording fee will be $53 ($10
    plus $3 plus $40) for the first page and $5 for each
    additional page. See General Statutes § 7-34a (a) (1), (d)
    and (e). When filing a mortgage assignment or release, if
    MERS is a party to the transaction, the recording fee
    will be $159, plus $10 for the first page and $5 for each
    additional page.5 See General Statutes § 7-34a (a) (1)
    and (2) (B). If MERS is not a party to the transaction,
    the recording fee will be $53 ($10 plus $3 plus $40)
    for the first page and $5 for each additional page. See
    General Statutes § 7-34a (a) (1), (d) and (e).
    The 2013 amendments also shifted how the recording
    fees on MERS-related transactions are allocated. See
    generally P.A. 13-184, § 97, and P.A. 13-247, § 81, codi-
    fied at General Statutes § 49-10 (h). The $159 assessed
    for the filing of mortgage deeds in connection with
    MERS transactions is allocated as follows: $10, plus
    any fees for additional pages, to the town clerk; $39 to
    the municipality’s general revenue accounts; and $110
    to the state, of which $36 is paid into the community
    investment account and $74 into the state’s general
    fund. General Statutes § 49-10 (h). The $159 fee
    assessed in connection with MERS-related assignments
    and releases is allocated slightly differently: $32 to
    municipal general revenue accounts; $36 to the state’s
    community investment account; and $91 to the state’s
    general fund. General Statutes § 49-10 (h). By contrast,
    the $53 paid by other mortgagees for all recorded trans-
    actions continues to be allocated as follows: $12 for
    the first page ($10 plus $1 of the $3 fee pursuant to § 7-
    34a [d], plus $1 of the $40 fee pursuant to § 7-34a [e]),
    and $5 per additional page to the town clerk; $3 to
    the municipality for local capital improvement projects;
    and $38 to the state, of which $2 is dedicated to historic
    document preservation and $36 for community invest-
    ment. See General Statutes § 7-34a (a) (1), (d) and (e).
    The parties agree that the legislature adopted the
    amendments to § 7-34a (a) at least in part as a revenue
    enhancing measure to help balance the state budget.
    They also agree that there is no evidence that any mem-
    ber of MERS has discontinued its membership in the
    MERS system or halted or reduced its use of that system
    as a result of the 2013 amendments. Finally, the parties
    agree that, in most cases, the recording fees at issue
    will be collected from the borrowers at closing and not
    paid by MERS itself.
    II
    As an initial matter, we must address the dispute
    between the parties about whether the fees imposed
    by § 7-34a are more properly characterized as user fees
    or taxes. The state contends that the payments are more
    akin to taxes than user fees because the statute was
    enacted primarily to raise revenues for the state and
    its municipalities and because the lion’s share of the
    fees incurred in connection with MERS-related transac-
    tions is allocated to the state’s general fund, the state’s
    community investment account, and municipal general
    revenue accounts, whereas only a small fraction of the
    fees is retained by the town clerks as compensation
    for the recording service. The plaintiffs, by contrast,
    contend that the fees, which are identified in the statute
    as recording ‘‘fees’’; General Statutes § 7-34a; and are
    paid in exchange for a discrete service of benefit to the
    filer, are properly considered user fees. Courts in other
    jurisdictions that have considered the question in other
    contexts—e.g., for purposes of the federal tax injunc-
    tion law, 28 U.S.C. § 1341 (2012)—have reached differ-
    ent conclusions as to whether a purported ‘‘fee’’ that
    generates more revenue than is needed to fund the
    service for which the fee is charged, with the surplus
    allocated to the government’s general fund, constitutes
    a tax or a fee. Compare, e.g., Empress Casino Joliet
    Corp. v. Balmoral Racing Club, Inc., 
    651 F.3d 722
    , 730
    (7th Cir. 2011) (tax), with, e.g., San Juan Cellular Tele-
    phone Co. v. Public Service Commission, 
    967 F.2d 683
    ,
    686 (1st Cir. 1992) (fee). But see S. Wolfe, ‘‘Municipal
    Finance and the Commerce Clause: Are User Fees the
    Next Target of the ‘Silver Bullet’?,’’ 26 Stetson L. Rev.
    727, 729 (1997) (‘‘[r]ecent rulings by the [United States
    Supreme] Court suggest that the difference between
    user fees and taxes may be a distinction without a
    difference’’). Because the payments at issue in this case
    are hybrids, bearing some indicia of both taxes and
    user fees, and because the parties have not fully briefed
    the issue, we will assume, solely for purposes of the
    present appeal, that we must apply the constitutional
    standards governing both taxes and fees.
    III
    We now address the merits of the plaintiffs’ various
    constitutional challenges,6 beginning with the plaintiffs’
    claim that §§ 7-34a (a) (2) and 49-10 (h), by charging
    nominees such as MERS higher recording fees than
    other mortgagees, violate the equal protection guaran-
    tees of the state and federal constitutions.7 We reject
    this claim.
    ‘‘To prevail on an equal protection claim, a plaintiff
    first must establish that the state is affording different
    treatment to similarly situated groups of individuals.
    . . . [I]t is only after this threshold requirement is met
    that the court will consider whether the statute survives
    scrutiny under the equal protection clause.’’ (Citation
    omitted; internal quotation marks omitted.) Keane v.
    Fischetti, 
    300 Conn. 395
    , 403, 
    13 A.3d 1089
    (2011). For
    purposes of this case, we will assume without deciding
    that the similarly situated requirement is satisfied and
    proceed to consider whether the legislature was war-
    ranted in singling out the plaintiffs for disparate treat-
    ment. Cf. City Recycling, Inc. v. State, 
    257 Conn. 429
    ,
    449, 
    778 A.2d 77
    (2001).
    ‘‘When a statute is challenged on equal protection
    grounds, whether under the United States constitution
    or the Connecticut constitution, the reviewing court
    must first determine the standard by which the chal-
    lenged statute’s constitutional validity will be deter-
    mined.’’ (Internal quotation marks omitted.) D.A.
    Pincus & Co. v. Meehan, 
    235 Conn. 865
    , 875, 
    670 A.2d 1278
    (1996). In the present case, to prevail on their
    equal protection claim, the plaintiffs must overcome a
    highly deferential standard of review. ‘‘If the statute
    does not [affect] either a fundamental right or a suspect
    class, its classification need only be rationally related to
    some legitimate government purpose . . . .’’ (Internal
    quotation marks omitted.) 
    Id. This rational
    basis review
    test ‘‘is satisfied [as] long as there is a plausible policy
    reason for the classification . . . the legislative facts
    on which the classification is apparently based ratio-
    nally may have been considered to be true by the gov-
    ernment decisionmaker . . . and the relationship of
    the classification to its goal is not so attenuated as
    to render the distinction arbitrary or irrational . . . .’’
    (Citations omitted; internal quotation marks omitted.)
    
    Id., 876. ‘‘It
    is undisputed that the constitutionality of the taxa-
    tion scheme at issue . . . must be analyzed under
    rational basis review because it neither implicates a
    fundamental right, nor affects a suspect class. Indeed,
    claims that taxation schemes violate the equal protec-
    tion rights of those more heavily taxed are subject to an
    especially deferential rational basis review. The United
    States Supreme Court has explained that in taxation,
    even more than in other fields, legislatures possess the
    greatest freedom in classification. Since the members
    of a legislature necessarily enjoy a familiarity with local
    conditions [that a reviewing] [c]ourt cannot have, the
    presumption of constitutionality can be overcome only
    by the most explicit demonstration that a classification
    is a hostile and oppressive discrimination against partic-
    ular persons and classes. . . . Accordingly, that court
    has repeatedly held that inequalities [that] result from
    a singling out of one particular class for taxation or
    exemption, infringe no constitutional limitation.’’ (Cita-
    tion omitted; internal quotation marks omitted.) Mar-
    kley v. Dept. of Public Utility Control, 
    301 Conn. 56
    ,
    70, 
    23 A.3d 668
    (2011); see, e.g., Alabama Dept. of Reve-
    nue v. CSX Transportation, Inc.,           U.S.      , 135 S.
    Ct. 1136, 1142–43, 
    191 L. Ed. 2d 113
    (2015). ‘‘Similarly,
    this court consistently has held that the state does not
    violate the equal protection clause by singling out a
    particular class for taxation or exemption.’’ Markley v.
    Dept. of Public Utility 
    Control, supra
    , 71. Rather, ‘‘[t]he
    burden is on the one attacking the legislative arrange-
    ment to negative every conceivable basis [that] might
    support it.’’ (Emphasis in original; internal quotation
    marks omitted.) D.A. Pincus & Co. v. 
    Meehan, supra
    ,
    
    235 Conn. 876
    –77. The same deferential standards gov-
    ern equal protection challenges to user fees. See, e.g.,
    United States v. Sperry Corp., 
    493 U.S. 52
    , 65, 110 S.
    Ct. 387, 
    107 L. Ed. 2d 290
    (1989); Kadrmas v. Dickinson
    Public Schools, 
    487 U.S. 450
    , 462–63, 
    108 S. Ct. 2481
    ,
    
    101 L. Ed. 2d 399
    (1988).
    Turning to the case before us, we first consider
    whether the challenged statutes seek to accomplish a
    legitimate public purpose. The parties agree that one
    primary purpose of the legislature in imposing higher
    recording fees on mortgage nominees such as MERS
    was simply to raise additional revenues, either to com-
    pensate for fees allegedly lost as a result of the MERS
    business model or, more generally, to help balance the
    state’s budget. It is well established that raising reve-
    nues is a legitimate purpose—often the primary pur-
    pose—of a tax or a fee. See Harbor Ins. Co. v. Groppo,
    
    208 Conn. 505
    , 511, 
    544 A.2d 1221
    (1988) (tax); Eagle
    Rock Sanitation, Inc. v. Jefferson County, United States
    District Court, Docket No. 4:12-CV-00100-EJL-CWD (D.
    Idaho November 22, 2013) (fee). Accordingly, the first
    prong of the test is satisfied.8
    The dispute between the parties thus centers around
    the question of whether it is permissible for the legisla-
    ture to impose a higher share of the state’s revenue
    burden on nominees such as MERS than it does on other
    recording parties. That is to say, we must determine
    whether the disparate treatment imposed by §§ 7-34a
    (a) (2) and 49-10 (h) is rationally related to the goal of
    raising revenues and recouping lost fees.
    Before considering whether the legislature had a
    rational basis for imposing higher recording fees on
    nominees such as MERS than on other mortgagees, we
    first address the plaintiffs’ contention that we must
    restrict our analysis in this regard to those theories that
    the state raised before the trial court and that find
    evidentiary support in the record. The plaintiffs mis-
    state the law. As the trial court properly recognized,
    the state ‘‘has no obligation to produce evidence to
    sustain the rationality of a statutory classification. [A]
    legislative choice is not subject to courtroom [fact-find-
    ing] and may be based on rational speculation unsup-
    ported by evidence or empirical data. . . . A statute is
    presumed constitutional . . . and [t]he burden is on
    the one attacking the legislative arrangement to nega-
    tive every conceivable basis which might support it
    . . . whether or not the basis has a foundation in the
    record.’’ (Citations omitted; internal quotation marks
    omitted.) Heller v. Doe ex rel. Doe, 
    509 U.S. 312
    , 320–21,
    
    113 S. Ct. 2637
    , 
    125 L. Ed. 2d 257
    (1993). Indeed, it is
    well established that a reviewing court need not restrict
    its analysis even to those rationales proffered by the
    parties but may itself hypothesize plausible reasons why
    a legislative body might have drawn the challenged
    statutory distinctions. See, e.g., Federal Communica-
    tions Commission v. Beach Communications, Inc., 
    508 U.S. 307
    , 318, 
    113 S. Ct. 2096
    , 
    124 L. Ed. 2d 211
    (1993);
    Kadrmas v. Dickinson Public 
    Schools, supra
    , 
    487 U.S. 462
    –63; American Express Travel Related Services Co.
    v. Kentucky, 
    641 F.3d 685
    , 690 (6th Cir. 2011). In the
    present case, in light of the highly deferential standard
    of review that applies to tax and user fee legislation
    and other forms of purely economic regulation, we per-
    ceive at least two conceivable bases on which the legis-
    lature might reasonably have imposed higher recording
    fees on nominees such as MERS than on other mort-
    gagees.
    First, the legislature might simply have concluded
    that a large corporation such as MERS, which is
    involved in nearly two thirds of the nation’s residential
    mortgage transactions, is better able to shoulder high
    recording fees than are smaller mortgagees. Although
    it is true that large banks, loan servicing companies,
    and other well-heeled mortgagees may be no less able
    to afford such fees, a statute subject to rational basis
    review can be under inclusive without running afoul of
    the equal protection clause. See, e.g., Nordlinger v.
    Hahn, 
    505 U.S. 1
    , 11, 
    112 S. Ct. 2326
    , 
    120 L. Ed. 2d 1
    (1992) (‘‘[i]n structuring internal taxation schemes the
    [s]tates have large leeway in making classifications and
    drawing lines [that] in their judgment produce reason-
    able systems of taxation’’ [internal quotation marks
    omitted]); Markley v. Dept. of Public Utility 
    Control, supra
    , 
    301 Conn. 70
    (‘‘[A] legislature is not bound to
    tax every member of a class or none. It may make
    distinctions of degree having a rational basis, and when
    subjected to judicial scrutiny they must be presumed
    to rest on that basis if there is any conceivable state
    of facts [that] would support it.’’ [Internal quotation
    marks omitted.]); Harbor Ins. Co. v. 
    Groppo, supra
    , 
    208 Conn. 511
    (‘‘[R]ecognizing that any plan of taxation
    necessarily has some discriminatory impact . . . we
    have previously stated the operative test for the validity
    of a tax statute to be the following: As long as some
    conceivable rational basis for the difference exists, a
    classification is not offensive merely because it is not
    made with mathematical nicety.’’ [Citations omitted;
    emphasis in original; internal quotation marks omit-
    ted.]). Indeed, our sister state courts have upheld taxa-
    tion schemes that impose a heightened burden on
    individual corporate taxpayers when there is a princi-
    pled basis for doing so. See, e.g., North Pole Corp. v.
    East Dundee, 
    263 Ill. App. 3d 327
    , 336–37, 
    635 N.E.2d 1060
    (1994); Horizon Blue Cross Blue Shield v. State,
    
    425 N.J. Super. 1
    , 21–23, 
    39 A.3d 228
    (App. Div.), cert.
    denied, 
    211 N.J. 608
    , 
    50 A.3d 41
    (2012); see also Verizon
    New England, Inc. v. Rochester, 
    156 N.H. 624
    , 631, 
    940 A.2d 237
    (2007) (city could tax one public utility more
    heavily than others if selective taxation was reasonably
    related to legitimate public interest).9
    Second, as the trial court recognized, the legislature
    reasonably may have determined that mortgage assign-
    ments that typically would be recorded in the public
    land records are not recorded for loans registered with
    the MERS system because MERS remains the mort-
    gagee of record for its members. Accordingly, the legis-
    lature could have raised the initial recording fee that
    MERS pays, as well as the final fee that is paid when
    the mortgage is released or transferred out of the MERS
    system, to compensate for the fees ‘‘lost’’ over the
    course of the life of the loan.
    The plaintiffs offer four arguments in response: (1)
    there is no evidence in the record to support the con-
    tention that assignments are recorded less frequently
    for MERS loans than for other mortgagees’ loans; (2)
    there is no legal requirement that assignments be
    recorded in the public land records; (3) even if town
    clerks do perform fewer recording duties with respect
    to MERS loans than non-MERS loans, there is no reason
    to compensate town clerks for lost recording revenues
    because they already save the costs associated with not
    having to record assignments of MERS loans, or, put
    differently, clerks are not entitled to payment for ser-
    vices that they do not perform; and (4) even if town
    clerks have lost recording fees under the MERS system,
    there is no rational relationship between those losses
    and the fees imposed under §§ 7-34a (a) (2) and 49-10
    (h) because those fees are primarily allocated to the
    state’s general fund and to municipal accounts, rather
    than to the clerks themselves. We consider each argu-
    ment in turn.
    With respect to the plaintiffs’ argument that there is
    no evidence in the record that mortgage assignments
    are recorded less frequently for MERS-listed loans than
    for non-MERS loans, we already explained that, under
    the rational basis test, our review is not limited to theo-
    ries that the state has documented at trial or that have
    been subject to judicial fact-finding. Rather, courts may
    consider—and it is the plaintiffs who must debunk—
    any rationale that might plausibly have motivated the
    legislature. In the present case, it cannot be seriously
    suggested that the MERS model might not result in
    fewer recordings in the public land records, with con-
    comitant cost savings to MERS and its users. Indeed,
    the plaintiffs’ argument is undercut repeatedly by the
    amici supporting their own position. The amici compris-
    ing two bankers associations and a land title association
    represent, for example, that (1) prior to the advent of
    MERS, recording expenses added at least $30 to the
    cost of each loan, and sometimes substantially more,
    (2) MERS was devised ‘‘with an eye toward eliminating
    many of the unnecessary costs . . . associated with
    land title and recording issues,’’ (3) assignments that
    typically were filed on the land records before the estab-
    lishment of MERS are no longer required, (4) this
    reduced need for assignments results in lower title
    insurance and closing costs for both buyers and sellers
    using the MERS system, and (5) MERS ‘‘made the trans-
    fer of loans in the secondary market both cheaper
    and simpler.’’
    The amici also direct our attention to scholarly litera-
    ture concluding that MERS ‘‘reduces the need to pay
    additional recording fees associated with subsequent
    transfers of mortgage loans or mortgage loan servicing
    rights’’ and to an article published by a former senior
    executive officer of MERS predicting that, because
    MERS ‘‘eliminates the need to record later assignments
    in the public land records . . . MERS will save the
    mortgage industry $200 million a year by eliminating
    the need for many assignments. Because MERS should
    decrease the cost of servicing transfers, mortgage loan
    portfolios may begin to reflect a price difference if
    the loans are MERS registered.’’ Moreover, ‘‘[w]hether
    [town recorders’] assignment revenues will drop [as a
    result] remains an open question.’’ In light of these
    publicly available statements, we have no difficulty con-
    cluding that the legislature might reasonably have deter-
    mined that parties to MERS-listed loans can obtain sig-
    nificant cost savings in recording fees over the life of
    a loan and that, as a result, it is not unfair to ask them
    to pay higher recording fees at the outset and again
    when the mortgage ultimately is released or transferred
    out of the MERS system.
    The plaintiffs’ second argument, namely, that there is
    no legal requirement that assignments of loan servicing
    rights be recorded in Connecticut, is a red herring. It
    is clear from the above quoted statements that, when
    the plaintiffs represent that the MERS system ‘‘elimi-
    nates the need to record later assignments in the public
    land records’’; (emphasis added); they refer not to any
    legal recording requirement but, rather, to the fact that,
    from a practical standpoint, loan assignments must be
    recorded if the holder is to perfect its security interest
    and to avoid potentially costly gaps in the chain of title.
    Nor are we persuaded by the plaintiffs’ third argu-
    ment, namely, that the legislature had no legitimate
    reason to compensate town clerks for lost recording
    revenues because, if a document is not recorded, the
    town clerk has performed no service for which he or
    she deserves to be compensated. There are three flaws
    with this argument. First, the argument accounts for
    only the marginal costs associated with recording a
    document. The costs of running a town clerk’s office,
    including the clerk’s salary and benefits, building and
    utilities, information technology infrastructure, and the
    like, are largely fixed. By contrast, the marginal costs
    associated with recording any particular document—a
    bit of paper and ink, or the digital equivalents thereof—
    are quite limited. Thus, if increased use of the MERS
    system means that a clerk’s workload drops by 10 per-
    cent, it is unlikely that the clerk’s office will recognize
    a corresponding 10 percent cost savings. It therefore
    was reasonable for the legislature to impose higher up-
    front and back-end fees on MERS transactions to help
    the town clerks maintain budget stability.
    Second, the plaintiffs fail to acknowledge that the
    service provided by a clerk’s office only begins with
    the recording of a document. The principal service pro-
    vided, and the principal value to the recording party,
    is that a record of the transaction is perpetually main-
    tained and made available to the public for search by
    any interested party. This is the primary reason parties
    opt to record assignments and other loan documents.
    One value of the MERS system to subsequent transfer-
    ees, then, is that it allows them essentially to free ride
    on the public recording system. They reap the benefit
    of MERS’ initial recording as mortgagee, without having
    to pay—at least without having to pay the clerk—for
    the ongoing benefit of the public notice. It is reasonable
    to assume that the legislature imposed higher up-front
    recording fees on MERS loans as a way to remedy this
    free rider problem.
    Third, the plaintiffs go astray in considering the issue
    solely from the standpoint of the town clerk. Regardless
    of whether the clerks have lost money as a result of a
    lower recording rate for assignments of MERS loans,
    it seems clear that MERS, its members, and the buyers
    and sellers involved in MERS-listed transactions do
    achieve some savings in recording costs. If the legisla-
    ture concluded that this system of loan processing
    results in significant cost savings for MERS members
    and its users, the legislature was free to impose a higher
    tax or fee on those transactions in order to recapture
    a portion of those savings. See Rosemont v. Price-
    line.com, Inc., United States District Court, Docket No.
    09 C 4438 (N.D. Ill. October 14, 2011) (equal protection
    clause was not offended when town imposed hotel tax
    on only those travel companies using distinct business
    model that otherwise would have resulted in tax savings
    for those companies); Horizon Blue Cross Blue Shield
    v. 
    State, supra
    , 
    425 N.J. Super. 22
    –23 (equal protection
    clause was not offended when state imposed tax solely
    on health service companies, of which plaintiff was sole
    exemplar, which previously had advantage of certain
    tax loopholes).
    Finally, the plaintiffs’ fourth argument is that, even
    if town clerks have lost recording fees as a result of the
    MERS system, there is no rational relationship between
    those losses and the heightened fees imposed under
    §§ 7-34a (a) (2) and 49-10 (h), which primarily are allo-
    cated to the state’s general fund and municipal
    accounts. This argument fails because, among other
    things, it assumes a system of municipal financing that
    is largely obsolete. Pursuant to General Statutes § 7-
    34b (b), ‘‘[a]ny town may, by ordinance, provide that
    the town clerk shall receive a salary in lieu of all fees
    and other compensation provided for in the general
    statutes . . . . Upon the adoption of such ordinance
    the fees or compensation provided by the general stat-
    utes to be paid to the town clerk shall be collected by
    such town clerk and he shall deposit all such money
    collected by him in accordance with such provisions
    of law as govern the deposit of moneys belonging to
    such town.’’ On the basis of publicly available docu-
    ments, the legislature reasonably could have concluded
    that only a handful of Connecticut towns still hew to the
    traditional model under which financially independent
    clerks’ offices retain the recording fees they collect,
    and that, in most cases, such fees are now paid into
    a town’s general revenues. See Office of Legislative
    Research, Connecticut General Assembly, Report No.
    2006-R-0297, Town Clerks: Duties, Responsibilities, and
    Fee Collection (April 26, 2006). Accordingly, a falloff in
    recording fees will adversely impact municipal budgets
    and potentially result in a heightened need for local
    community support by the state. For these reasons, we
    conclude that the distinctions established by §§ 7-34a
    (a) (2) and 49-10 (h) are rationally related to legitimate
    public interests and, therefore, do not offend the equal
    protection provisions of the state or federal consti-
    tution.
    IV
    We next consider the plaintiffs’ claim that §§ 7-34a
    (a) (2) and 49-10 (h) violate the dormant commerce
    clause of the federal constitution. The commerce clause
    provides that Congress shall have the power ‘‘[t]o regu-
    late Commerce with foreign Nations, and among the
    Several States, and with the Indian Tribes . . . .’’ U.S.
    Const., art. I, § 8, cl. 3. ‘‘Although the [c]lause is framed
    as a positive grant of power to Congress, [the United
    States Supreme Court has] consistently held this lan-
    guage to contain a further, negative command, known
    as the dormant [c]ommerce [c]lause, prohibiting certain
    state [regulation] even when Congress has failed to
    legislate on the subject.’’ (Internal quotation marks
    omitted.) Comptroller of the Treasury v. Wynne,
    U.S.     , 
    135 S. Ct. 1787
    , 1794, 
    191 L. Ed. 2d 813
    (2015).
    ‘‘[T]he dormant [c]ommerce [c]lause precludes [s]tates
    from discriminat[ing] between transactions on the basis
    of some interstate element. . . . This means, among
    other things, that a [s]tate may not tax a transaction or
    incident more heavily when it crosses state lines than
    when it occurs entirely within the [s]tate. . . . Nor may
    a [s]tate impose a tax [that] discriminates against inter-
    state commerce either by providing a direct commercial
    advantage to local business, or by subjecting interstate
    commerce to the burden of multiple taxation.’’ (Cita-
    tions omitted; internal quotation marks omitted.) 
    Id. Although the
    recording transactions at issue in this
    case may themselves be purely local in nature, the pres-
    ence of MERS as a participant indicates that many of
    the mortgage loans involved ultimately will be trans-
    ferred on the national secondary loan market. For this
    reason, and in light of the unique role that MERS plays
    in the national secondary market, we will assume that
    interstate commerce is implicated. See Camps New-
    found/Owatonna, Inc. v. Harrison, 
    520 U.S. 564
    , 573,
    
    117 S. Ct. 1590
    , 
    137 L. Ed. 2d 852
    (1997) (‘‘if it is interstate
    commerce that feels the pinch, it does not matter how
    local the operation [that] applies the squeeze’’ [internal
    quotation marks omitted]).
    We first consider what legal standard governs chal-
    lenges to taxes and user fees under the dormant com-
    merce clause. The plaintiffs, at varying times, suggest
    that the fees at issue in this case should be assessed
    according to the tests and legal analysis that the United
    States Supreme Court has applied to dormant com-
    merce clause challenges against (1) general regulatory
    measures, (2) tax schemes, and (3) user fees. The plain-
    tiffs may be forgiven for any confusion in this regard,
    however, as the United States Supreme Court’s dormant
    commerce clause jurisprudence is less than a model of
    clarity, particularly in the area of user fees and general
    and special revenue taxes.10 That court itself has
    acknowledged ‘‘the uneven course of [its] decisions in
    this field’’; American Trucking Assns., Inc. v. Scheiner,
    
    483 U.S. 266
    , 269, 
    107 S. Ct. 2829
    , 
    97 L. Ed. 2d 226
    (1987); and has indicated that its inability to settle on
    a guiding legal framework has created ‘‘a quagmire of
    judicial responses . . . .’’ (Internal quotation marks
    omitted.) 
    Id., 280; see
    also S. 
    Wolfe, supra
    , 26 Stetson
    L. Rev. 778–81 (discussing ambiguous state of law).
    Moreover, the high court’s recent dormant commerce
    clause decisions have been decided by the narrowest
    of margins, with substantial disagreement among the
    members of that court as to the proper test or tests to
    be applied. See, e.g., Comptroller of the Treasury v.
    
    Wynne, supra
    , 
    135 S. Ct. 1791
    . As a result, several dis-
    tinct but partially overlapping tests may be thought to
    govern the present case. See, e.g., 
    id., 1802 (applying
    internal consistency test to income tax scheme); Dept.
    of Revenue v. Davis, 
    553 U.S. 328
    , 338–40, 
    128 S. Ct. 1801
    , 
    170 L. Ed. 2d 685
    (2008) (general two part test
    governs all state regulations, including taxes, but differ-
    ent rules may govern taxes and fees imposed by state
    in its dual capacity as market participant and regulator);
    Complete Auto Transit, Inc. v. Brady, 
    430 U.S. 274
    ,
    279, 
    97 S. Ct. 1076
    , 
    51 L. Ed. 2d 326
    (1977) (establishing
    four part test governing state taxes that impact inter-
    state commerce); Evansville-Vanderburgh Airport
    Authority District v. Delta Airlines, Inc., 
    405 U.S. 707
    ,
    716–17, 
    92 S. Ct. 1349
    , 
    31 L. Ed. 2d 620
    (1972) (establish-
    ing three part test governing user fees and special reve-
    nue taxes); Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 
    397 U.S. 137
    ,
    142, 
    90 S. Ct. 844
    , 
    25 L. Ed. 2d 174
    (1970) (establishing
    balancing test governing any facially neutral state regu-
    lation). As United States Supreme Court Justice Antonin
    Scalia recently lamented: ‘‘One glaring defect of the
    negative [c]ommerce [c]lause is its lack of governing
    principle. Neither the [c]onstitution nor our legal tradi-
    tions offer guidance about how to separate improper
    state interference with commerce from permissible
    state taxation or regulation of commerce. So we must
    make the rules up as we go along. That is how we
    ended up with the bestiary of ad hoc tests and ad hoc
    exceptions that we apply nowadays . . . .’’ (Citations
    omitted.) Comptroller of the Treasury v. 
    Wynne, supra
    ,
    1809 (Scalia, J., dissenting).
    Fortunately, we need not wade into this quagmire or
    attempt to divine the precise standards by which the
    United States Supreme Court might judge the statutes at
    issue in this case. This is because the parties apparently
    agree that their dispute boils down to the question of
    whether two central criteria—criteria that reappear
    throughout the United States Supreme Court’s various
    dormant commerce clause tests and frameworks—are
    satisfied. First, a state user fee or tax is presumed to
    violate the dormant commerce clause if it facially dis-
    criminates against interstate commerce. See, e.g.,
    United Haulers Assn., Inc. v. Oneida-Herkimer Solid
    Waste Management Authority, 
    550 U.S. 330
    , 338, 
    127 S. Ct. 1786
    , 
    167 L. Ed. 2d 655
    (2007). ‘‘In this context,
    discrimination simply means differential treatment of
    in-state and out-of-state economic interests that bene-
    fits the former and burdens the latter. . . . Discrimina-
    tory laws motivated by simple economic protectionism
    are subject to a virtually per se rule of invalidity . . .
    [that] can . . . be overcome [only] by a showing that
    the [s]tate has no other means to advance a legitimate
    local purpose . . . .’’ (Citations omitted; internal quo-
    tation marks omitted.) 
    Id., 338–39. Second,
    a fee or
    tax that is facially neutral nevertheless may offend the
    dormant commerce clause if it has the practical effect
    of imposing a burden on interstate commerce that is
    disproportionate to the legitimate benefits. See, e.g.,
    Dept. of Revenue v. 
    Davis, supra
    , 
    553 U.S. 365
    (Kennedy,
    J., dissenting). We consider each criterion.
    A
    Facial Discrimination
    The plaintiffs first contend that the challenged stat-
    utes discriminate on their face against interstate com-
    merce because they impose higher recording fees only
    on those transactions involving a mortgage nominee,
    such as MERS, that operates in conjunction with a
    national electronic database. The plaintiffs argue that
    there is no apparent justification for penalizing compa-
    nies that operate national databases, as opposed to a
    hypothetical nominee operating a database that tracks
    only mortgage loans transferred between Connecticut-
    based entities or securing Connecticut-based proper-
    ties. For this reason, they contend, §§ 7-34a (a) (2) and
    49-10 (h) presumptively violate the dormant commerce
    clause. There are at least four problems with this
    argument.
    First, although the plaintiffs correctly note that a
    statute can facially discriminate against interstate com-
    merce even if it does not expressly favor in-state over
    out-of-state businesses; see Healy v. Beer Institute, 
    491 U.S. 324
    , 340–41, 
    109 S. Ct. 2491
    , 
    105 L. Ed. 2d 275
    (1989); the United States Supreme Court nevertheless
    has emphasized that ‘‘[t]he central rationale for the rule
    against discrimination is to prohibit state or municipal
    laws whose object is local economic protectionism,
    laws that would excite those jealousies and retaliatory
    measures the [c]onstitution was designed to prevent.’’
    C & A Carbone, Inc. v. Clarkstown, 
    511 U.S. 383
    , 390,
    
    114 S. Ct. 1677
    , 
    128 L. Ed. 2d 399
    (1994); see also Dept.
    of Revenue v. 
    Davis, supra
    , 
    553 U.S. 337
    –38 (‘‘economic
    protectionism . . . designed to benefit in-state eco-
    nomic interests by burdening out-of-state competitors’’
    is paradigmatic form of discrimination [internal quota-
    tion marks omitted]); Healy v. Beer 
    Institute, supra
    ,
    326 (challenged statute ensured favorable pricing for
    residents of Connecticut and maintained competitive-
    ness of Connecticut-based retailers); Philadelphia v.
    New Jersey, 
    437 U.S. 617
    , 624, 
    98 S. Ct. 2531
    , 
    57 L. Ed. 2d
    475 (1978) (‘‘[t]he crucial inquiry . . . must be
    directed to determining whether [the challenged stat-
    ute] is basically a protectionist measure, or whether it
    can fairly be viewed as a law directed to legitimate local
    concerns, with effects [on] interstate commerce that
    are only incidental’’). In the present case, there is no
    indication that the legislative choice to impose higher
    fees on nominees—whether in state or out of state—
    who operate national mortgage databases reflected an
    invidious discrimination against out-of-state interests,
    or an effort to favor Connecticut-based financial compa-
    nies. If anything, the opposite is true, as the likely result
    will be that Connecticut homeowners, who, the parties
    agree, typically absorb the higher upfront fees for
    MERS-listed loans, will subsidize out-of-state banks and
    government sponsored financing corporations or their
    agents, who, upon acquiring the loans in the secondary
    market, will receive the benefits of recordings in the
    public land records without having to pay the associated
    costs. See United Haulers Assn., Inc. v. Oneida-Herki-
    mer Solid Waste Management 
    Authority, supra
    , 
    550 U.S. 345
    .
    Nor do we believe that the hypothetical favored mort-
    gage nominee the plaintiffs conjure up—one that oper-
    ates a Connecticut only electronic database—is any-
    thing other than a chimera. Because the secondary resi-
    dential mortgage market is national in scope and is
    dominated by federal agencies that are located outside
    of this state, there would be no reason for a company
    to invest in an electronic registration system that tracks
    only loan transfers between Connecticut investors, or
    only loans issued in connection with Connecticut-based
    properties.11 The plaintiffs do not contend that any such
    competitor currently exists or is likely to emerge in the
    foreseeable future. As the Supreme Court explained in
    Associated Industries v. Lohman, 
    511 U.S. 641
    , 114 S.
    Ct. 1815, 
    128 L. Ed. 2d 639
    (1994), ‘‘[it has] never deemed
    a hypothetical possibility of favoritism to constitute
    discrimination that transgresses constitutional com-
    mands.’’ 
    Id., 654; see
    also Exxon Corp. v. Governor, 
    437 U.S. 117
    , 125, 
    98 S. Ct. 2207
    , 
    57 L. Ed. 2d
    91 (1978)
    (disparate treatment claim was meritless when state’s
    entire gasoline supply flowed in interstate commerce).
    Second, notwithstanding the statutory reference to
    national electronic databases; General Statutes § 7-34a
    (a) (2) (C); we do not interpret the challenged statute
    to be a facial attack on interstate commerce. Rather,
    the record suggests—and the plaintiffs conceded at oral
    argument—that the language in question appears in § 7-
    34a only because the legislature cut and pasted it from
    MERS’ own corporate documents describing the com-
    pany’s business model. In other words, the legislature’s
    apparent intent was not to impose higher recording fees
    on residential mortgage transactions with a national
    character but, rather, merely to indicate that the higher
    fees are directed at MERS and any other mortgage nom-
    inees that may develop virtual recording systems to
    facilitate transactions in the secondary mortgage mar-
    ket. It is only because that market, like many modern
    financial markets, happens to be national in scope that
    the ‘‘national electronic database’’ language found its
    way into § 7-34a.12 Both this court and the United States
    Supreme Court have emphasized in this regard ‘‘the
    importance of looking past the formal language of [a]
    tax statute [to] its practical effect . . . .’’ (Internal quo-
    tation marks omitted.) Chase Manhattan Bank v.
    Gavin, 
    249 Conn. 172
    , 210, 
    733 A.2d 782
    , cert. denied,
    
    528 U.S. 965
    , 
    120 S. Ct. 401
    , 
    145 L. Ed. 2d 312
    (1999);
    accord Quill Corp. v. North Dakota ex rel. Heitkamp,
    
    504 U.S. 298
    , 310, 
    112 S. Ct. 1904
    , 
    119 L. Ed. 2d 91
    (1992).
    As we discuss hereinafter, we perceive no deleterious
    effect of the challenged legislation on the national sec-
    ondary mortgage market.
    Third, the United States Supreme Court has explained
    that ‘‘a fundamental element of dormant [c]ommerce
    [c]lause jurisprudence [is] the principle that any notion
    of discrimination assumes a comparison of substan-
    tially similar entities.’’ (Internal quotation marks omit-
    ted.) Dept. of Revenue v. 
    Davis, supra
    , 
    553 U.S. 342
    . As
    we explained in part III of this opinion, MERS is not
    substantially similar to other mortgagees—even other
    mortgage nominees—with respect to the roles they play
    in Connecticut’s residential mortgage recording market.
    Whereas traditional mortgagees are primarily lenders
    or loan servicing companies, MERS is identified as a
    mortgagee in the public land records as a sort of place-
    holder, indicating to interested parties that the recent
    chain of title to a MERS-listed property may be traced
    by consulting the MERS database. Accordingly, the stat-
    utes do not facially discriminate against interstate com-
    merce. Rather, they simply recognize that MERS, which
    uses the public land records as a means of enhancing
    the value that its member companies obtain from its
    electronic registration services, may realize a distinct
    and greater benefit from recording its interests than do
    other mortgagees.
    Fourth, and relatedly, even if we believed that the
    statutes in question discriminated against interstate
    commerce, we would conclude, for reasons discussed
    in part III of this opinion, that there is no constitutional
    violation because such discrimination advances a legiti-
    mate local purpose. See, e.g., Camps Newfound/Owa-
    tonna, Inc. v. 
    Harrison, supra
    , 
    520 U.S. 581
    . It is well
    established that interstate commerce can be made to
    ‘‘pay its way’’ under a state regulatory scheme without
    running afoul of the dormant commerce clause. (Inter-
    nal quotation marks omitted.) Commonwealth Edison
    Co. v. Montana, 
    453 U.S. 609
    , 616, 
    101 S. Ct. 2946
    , 
    69 L. Ed. 2d 884
    (1981). In the present case, to the extent
    that the purpose of the challenged legislation was
    merely to recoup from MERS the recording fees that
    its members otherwise would have paid upon the trans-
    fer of a mortgage in the secondary market, §§ 7-34a (a)
    (2) and 49-10 (h) represent a legitimate attempt to level
    the playing field between MERS members and nonmem-
    bers and to ensure that recording revenues are not lost
    as a result of MERS’ novel business model. For all of
    the foregoing reasons, we agree with the state that
    the statutes do not discriminate impermissibly against
    interstate commerce.
    B
    Undue Burden
    We next consider the plaintiffs’ claim that the chal-
    lenged statutes place an undue burden on the national
    secondary mortgage market. Their argument appears
    to be that, despite the dearth of any evidence that the
    increased fees have adversely impacted MERS’ business
    or the secondary mortgage market in general, the simple
    fact that the state receives more than $5 million per
    year in increased fees on MERS-related transactions is,
    ipso facto, proof that interstate commerce has been
    burdened. The plaintiffs further contend that, because
    both the costs to the state and the benefits to the filers
    are the same for the recording of MERS and non-MERS
    transactions, but MERS is forced to pay fees that are
    approximately three times higher than other mortgag-
    ees, the costs imposed are necessarily disproportionate
    to the benefits. We are not persuaded.
    The amount of a tax or user fee is presumed to be
    appropriate; S. 
    Wolfe, supra
    , 26 Stetson L. Rev. 739;
    and the plaintiffs must demonstrate that the burdens
    imposed on interstate commerce clearly outweigh the
    benefits. See, e.g., Dept. of Revenue v. 
    Davis, supra
    ,
    
    553 U.S. 353
    . As we explained in part III of this opinion,
    we are not convinced that either the costs or the bene-
    fits of recording a MERS-listed mortgage are the same
    as for any other mortgagee. Let us assume that a hypo-
    thetical non-MERS thirty year mortgage loan is trans-
    ferred to a different lender every ten years during the
    life of the loan and that each subsequent holder records
    its interest in the public land records. Under that sce-
    nario, the original lender’s recording fees would afford
    it the benefit of ten years of public notice of its interest
    in the property, and the clerk’s office would receive
    three recording fees—the initial one and the fees for
    two assignments—to subsidize its costs of operation
    over the term of the loan, not including the release when
    the loan is fully repaid. Under the same circumstances,
    however, MERS and its members would continue to
    receive the benefit of the initial filing fee for the entire
    thirty year term of the loan, regardless of the number
    of intervening assignments among MERS members, and
    the clerk’s office will be correspondingly poorer. See
    S. 
    Wolfe, supra
    , 742 (noting that length of use of public
    service ‘‘strongly affects cost’’); 
    id., 744 (noting
    impor-
    tance of intangibles in calculating value of public ser-
    vice and that continued consumer use suggests that
    fees are not disproportionate to value provided).
    Accordingly, we cannot say that imposing higher front-
    end and back-end fees on MERS transactions in order
    to compensate for the reduced number of recorded
    mortgage assignments imposes an undue burden on
    MERS or, by extension, interstate commerce. See Asso-
    ciated Industries v. 
    Lohman, supra
    , 
    511 U.S. 647
    (inter-
    state and intrastate transactions may be taxed dif-
    ferently, as long as ultimate burdens are comparable).
    The United States Supreme Court also has suggested
    that, in gauging the burdens imposed on interstate com-
    merce, a reviewing court should consider whether, if
    every state were to adopt the challenged policy, the
    result would be to ‘‘place interstate commerce at a
    disadvantage as compared with commerce intrastate.’’
    (Internal quotation marks omitted.) Comptroller of the
    Treasury v. 
    Wynne, supra
    , 
    135 S. Ct. 1802
    . In the present
    case, even if every state were to charge $106 extra to
    record MERS-listed mortgages in its corresponding land
    records, there is nothing in the record to suggest that
    those higher fees, taken together, would unduly burden
    interstate commerce. There is no indication that higher
    recording fees would so overshadow the benefits of
    participation in a national electronic registration system
    that borrowers and lenders would opt not to participate
    in MERS or that the vitality of the secondary mortgage
    market would be compromised. The parties have agreed
    that higher fees have not resulted in a loss of MERS
    business within this state, and there is no reason to
    believe the outcome would differ elsewhere, or nation-
    ally. Nor is there any evidence of (1) what share of
    the estimated $5.4 million that the state will receive in
    additional annual recording fees will be borne by MERS
    and its members, and how that amount compares to
    the annual profits on their residential mortgage lending
    business in Connecticut, (2) what share of the increased
    fees will be borne by borrowers, and what impact those
    fees will have on their total closing costs, or (3) what
    cost savings MERS, its members, and borrowers in
    MERS-related transactions have achieved as a result of
    the MERS system. We are mindful in this regard of the
    United States Supreme Court’s recent guidance that the
    judiciary is particularly ill-suited to making the sorts of
    complex predictions and subtle cost-benefit calcula-
    tions necessary to assess whether a particular tax
    scheme is unduly burdensome. See Dept. of Revenue
    v. 
    Davis, supra
    , 
    553 U.S. 355
    .
    In Davis, the United States Supreme Court also cau-
    tioned that a court ‘‘should be particularly hesitant to
    interfere . . . under the guise of the [c]ommerce
    [c]lause [when] a [state or] local government engages
    in a traditional government function,’’ of which the
    maintenance of public land records is clearly an exam-
    ple. (Internal quotation marks omitted.) 
    Id., 341, quoting
    United Haulers Assn., Inc. v. Oneida-Herkimer Solid
    Waste Management 
    Authority, supra
    , 
    550 U.S. 344
    . In
    light of this guidance, and given the parties’ stipulation
    that the legislation at issue has not redounded to the
    tangible detriment of the MERS business model, we are
    compelled to defer to the legislature’s judgment that
    the fees at issue represent a reasonable approximation
    of the savings in recording costs generated by use of
    the MERS system. Accordingly, §§ 7-34a (a) (2) and 49-
    10 (h) do not offend the dormant commerce clause,13
    and we reject the plaintiffs’ claim to the contrary.14
    The judgment is affirmed.
    In this opinion the other justices concurred.
    1
    We hereinafter refer to the defendants collectively as the state.
    2
    The plaintiffs appealed from the judgment of the trial court to the Appel-
    late Court, and we transferred the appeal to this court pursuant to General
    Statutes § 51-199 (c) and Practice Book § 65-1.
    The plaintiffs have not appealed from the trial court’s ruling that the
    challenged statutes do not offend the takings provisions of the federal and
    state constitutions, and, accordingly, those claims are not before us.
    We granted permission for two groups to file amicus curiae briefs: the
    Connecticut Bankers Association, Connecticut Mortgage Bankers Associa-
    tion, and American Land Title Association; and the Jerome N. Frank Legal
    Services Organization and the Connecticut Fair Housing Center.
    3
    For the sake of brevity, in this opinion, we use the term MERS to refer
    to (1) the electronic recording system, (2) the entities that are the plaintiffs
    in this case, in their capacity as operators of the MERS system, and (3) the
    general model according to which changing legal interests in residential
    mortgages and mortgage loans are recorded in the MERS system.
    4
    The state interprets § 7-34a (a) (2) (B) to mean that, in addition to the
    $159 recording fee, a nominee of a mortgagee filing an assignment or release
    under that subparagraph must pay $10 for the first recorded page and $5
    for each additional page pursuant to § 7-34a (a) (1). The plaintiffs contend
    that it is unclear whether town clerks are permitted to charge these addi-
    tional fees, in light of the statement in § 7-34a (a) (2) (B) that ‘‘[n]o other
    fees shall be collected from the nominee for such recording.’’ For purposes
    of this appeal, because we glean from the state’s brief that these additional
    fees are in fact being imposed on the plaintiffs, and that they are therefore
    a subject of the plaintiffs’ complaint, we assume without deciding that the
    statute authorizes such additional fees.
    5
    See footnote 4 of this opinion.
    6
    Because a challenge to the constitutionality of a statute presents a ques-
    tion of law, our review is plenary. E.g., Keane v. Fischetti, 
    300 Conn. 395
    ,
    402, 
    13 A.3d 1089
    (2011). We recognize, however, that legislation that struc-
    tures and accommodates the burdens and benefits of economic life carries
    a strong presumption of constitutionality. See, e.g., Schieffelin & Co. v.
    Dept. of Liquor Control, 
    194 Conn. 165
    , 186, 
    479 A.2d 1191
    (1984).
    7
    The equal protection clause of the fourteenth amendment to the United
    States constitution provides that no state shall ‘‘deny to any person within
    its jurisdiction the equal protection of the laws.’’ U.S. Const., amend. XIV,
    § 1. Article first, § 20, of the constitution of Connecticut provides in relevant
    part: ‘‘No person shall be denied the equal protection of the law . . . .’’
    Neither party contends that the state and federal constitutional analyses
    diverge with respect to equal protection challenges to tax and fee statutes.
    Accordingly, for purposes of this case, we treat the relevant state and federal
    protections as coextensive. See, e.g., Keane v. Fischetti, 
    300 Conn. 395
    , 403,
    
    13 A.3d 1089
    (2011).
    8
    The plaintiffs also contend that the amendments to §§ 7-34a and 49-10
    were motivated by an impermissible desire to punish MERS for its business
    model. The trial court rejected this allegation, and we find no support for
    it in the legislative history. Even if it were true, however, the outcome of
    our analysis would be no different. As long as the challenged distinction is
    rationally related to some legitimate public purpose that conceivably may
    have motivated the legislature, it is irrelevant whether certain legislators
    also may have been motivated by animus toward the plaintiffs. See, e.g.,
    United States v. O’Brien, 
    391 U.S. 367
    , 383–84, 
    88 S. Ct. 1673
    , 
    20 L. Ed. 2d 672
    (1968); see also Wisconsin Education Assn. Council v. Walker, 
    705 F.3d 640
    , 653 (7th Cir. 2013).
    9
    The equal protection cases on which the plaintiffs rely are readily distin-
    guishable, as they primarily address legislative distinctions that (1) implicate
    federalism or other constitutional interests, (2) are transparently arbitrary
    and without rational basis, or (3) impose criminal or quasi-criminal sanc-
    tions. See, e.g., Cleburne v. Cleburne Living Center, Inc., 
    473 U.S. 432
    ,
    449–50, 
    105 S. Ct. 3249
    , 
    87 L. Ed. 2d 313
    (1985) (in rare case in which
    United States Supreme Court held that challenged social legislation failed
    to withstand rational basis review, court concluded that irrational fear of
    mentally disabled individuals did not justify discriminatory zoning ordi-
    nance); Williams v. Vermont, 
    472 U.S. 14
    , 23, 
    105 S. Ct. 2465
    , 
    86 L. Ed. 2d 11
    (1985) (state impermissibly discriminated against nonresidents); Zobel
    v. Williams, 
    457 U.S. 55
    , 64, 65, 
    102 S. Ct. 2309
    , 
    72 L. Ed. 2d 672
    (1982)
    (apportioning state benefits on basis of duration of residency would imper-
    missibly divide citizens into castes and unduly infringe interstate travel
    rights); James v. Strange, 
    407 U.S. 128
    , 138–39, 
    92 S. Ct. 2027
    , 
    32 L. Ed. 2d 600
    (1972) (statute imposed ‘‘unduly harsh or discriminatory terms’’ on
    indigent criminal defendants and potentially infringed right to counsel); City
    Recycling, Inc. v. 
    State, supra
    , 
    257 Conn. 453
    (trial court’s specific factual
    findings ‘‘directly negate[d] every conceivable rational basis for the legisla-
    tion’’); State v. Reed, 
    192 Conn. 520
    , 531–32, 
    473 A.2d 775
    (1984) (quasi-penal
    statute imposing liability for hospital care expenses on certain confined
    individuals but not others was deemed to be ‘‘entirely arbitrary’’); Caldor’s,
    Inc. v. Bedding Barn, Inc., 
    177 Conn. 304
    , 316–18, 
    417 A.2d 343
    (1979)
    (applying stricter standard in case of penal statute); see also Allegheny
    Pittsburgh Coal Co. v. County Commission, 
    488 U.S. 336
    , 345, 
    109 S. Ct. 633
    , 
    102 L. Ed. 2d 688
    (1989) (county assessor failed to comply with uniform
    state tax policy).
    10
    Because the statutory scheme at issue in this case allocates a portion
    of the nominee filing fees to the state’s general fund and municipal accounts,
    and a portion to the town clerks and the state’s community investment
    account, the fees have characteristics of both general and special reve-
    nue taxes.
    11
    To the extent that they suggest otherwise, the plaintiffs place the cart
    before the horse. The amici consisting of the bankers associations and the
    land title association, who support the plaintiffs’ position in this case, have
    presented scholarship indicating that it was the national mortgage lending
    industry and government sponsored financing corporations such as Fannie
    Mae and Freddie Mac that partnered to create MERS to fill the need for a
    central registry for the national residential mortgage industry. See R. Arnold,
    ‘‘Yes, There Is Life on MERS,’’ 11 Prob. & Prop. 33, 33 (1997); see also P.
    Sargent & M. Harris, ‘‘The Myths and Merits of MERS’’ (September 25, 2012).
    From its very inception, then, the MERS business was necessarily national
    in scope.
    12
    Although the plaintiffs suggest in their reply brief that the statutes
    bespeak a legislative intent to punish MERS for transacting business outside
    of Connecticut, there is no evidence in either the record of this case or the
    legislative history to support such a suggestion.
    13
    It might also be argued that, insofar as the state’s purpose in imposing
    higher recording fees on MERS-listed mortgages is to prevent a competitor
    in the mortgage recording business from free riding on its public recording
    system, the state acts as a market participant—as well as a regulator—
    with respect to MERS and, therefore, is immune from challenge under the
    dormant commerce clause. See, e.g., Dept. of Revenue v. 
    Davis, supra
    , 
    553 U.S. 339
    ; SSC Corp. v. Smithtown, 
    66 F.3d 502
    , 510–12 (2d Cir. 1995), cert.
    denied, 
    516 U.S. 1112
    , 
    116 S. Ct. 911
    , 
    133 L. Ed. 2d 842
    (1996); see also
    McBurney v. Young,           U.S.     , 
    133 S. Ct. 1709
    , 1720, 
    185 L. Ed. 2d 758
    (2015) (state, having created market by offering program, does not offend
    dormant commerce clause by restricting access to that market so as to favor
    local interests). Because neither party has raised this argument, however, we
    need not consider it.
    14
    On appeal, the plaintiffs also contend that enforcement of the challenged
    statutes violates their substantive due process rights under the federal and
    state constitutions, the federal constitutional prohibition against bills of
    attainder, and 42 U.S.C. § 1983. We have reviewed these claims and, for
    essentially the same reasons that we rejected the equal protection and
    commerce clause claims, we find them to be without merit.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: SC19376

Filed Date: 2/23/2016

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 2/9/2016

Authorities (34)

San Juan Cellular Telephone Company, Etc. v. Public Service ... , 967 F.2d 683 ( 1992 )

ssc-corp-plaintiff-counter-defendant-appellee-v-town-of-smithtown-town , 66 F.3d 502 ( 1995 )

American Express Travel Related Services Co. v. Kentucky , 641 F.3d 685 ( 2011 )

North Pole Corp. v. VILL. OF E. DUNDEE , 263 Ill. App. 3d 327 ( 1994 )

Markley v. Department of Public Utility Control , 301 Conn. 56 ( 2011 )

Caldor's, Inc. v. Bedding Barn, Inc. , 177 Conn. 304 ( 1979 )

Healy v. Beer Institute , 109 S. Ct. 2491 ( 1989 )

Verizon New England, Inc. v. City of Rochester , 156 N.H. 624 ( 2007 )

HORIZON BLUE CROSS v. State , 425 N.J. Super. 1 ( 2012 )

Quill Corp. v. North Dakota Ex Rel. Heitkamp , 112 S. Ct. 1904 ( 1992 )

American Trucking Assns., Inc. v. Scheiner , 107 S. Ct. 2829 ( 1987 )

Exxon Corp. v. Governor of Maryland , 98 S. Ct. 2207 ( 1978 )

City of Philadelphia v. New Jersey , 98 S. Ct. 2531 ( 1978 )

Commonwealth Edison Co. v. Montana , 101 S. Ct. 2946 ( 1981 )

Federal Communications Commission v. Beach Communications, ... , 113 S. Ct. 2096 ( 1993 )

Heller v. Doe Ex Rel. Doe , 113 S. Ct. 2637 ( 1993 )

Associated Industries of Mo. v. Lohman , 114 S. Ct. 1815 ( 1994 )

Camps Newfound/Owatonna, Inc. v. Town of Harrison , 117 S. Ct. 1590 ( 1997 )

Alabama Dept. of Revenue v. CSX Transp., Inc. , 135 S. Ct. 1136 ( 2015 )

Comptroller of Treasury of Md. v. Wynne , 135 S. Ct. 1787 ( 2015 )

View All Authorities »