Assoc. of American Railroads v. Department of Transportation , 721 F.3d 666 ( 2013 )


Menu:
  •  United States Court of Appeals
    FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA CIRCUIT
    Argued February 19, 2013               Decided July 2, 2013
    No. 12-5204
    ASSOCIATION OF AMERICAN RAILROADS,
    APPELLANT
    v.
    UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF TRANSPORTATION, ET AL.,
    APPELLEES
    Appeal from the United States District Court
    for the District of Columbia
    (No. 1:11-cv-01499)
    Thomas H. Dupree, Jr. argued the cause for appellant.
    With him on the briefs was Louis P. Warchot.
    Michael S. Raab, Attorney, U.S. Department of Justice,
    argued the cause for appellees. With him on the brief were
    Stuart F. Delery, Acting Assistant Attorney General, Ronald
    C. Machen Jr., U.S. Attorney, Mark B. Stern and Daniel
    Tenny, Attorneys, Paul M. Geier, Assistant General Counsel
    for Litigation, U.S. Department of Transportation, Peter J.
    Plocki, Deputy Assistant General Counsel for Litigation, and
    Joy Park, Attorney.
    2
    Before: BROWN, Circuit Judge, and WILLIAMS and
    SENTELLE, Senior Circuit Judges.
    BROWN, Circuit Judge: Imagine a scenario in which
    Congress has given to General Motors the power to coauthor,
    alongside the Department of Transportation, regulations that
    will govern all automobile manufacturers. And, if the two
    should happen to disagree on what form those regulations will
    take, then neither will have the ultimate say. Instead, an
    unspecified arbitrator will make the call. Constitutional? The
    Department of Transportation seems to think so. 1
    Next consider a parallel statutory scheme—the one at
    issue in this case. This time, instead of General Motors, it is
    Amtrak (officially, the “National Railroad Passenger
    Corporation”) wielding joint regulatory power with a
    government agency. This new stipulation further complicates
    the issue. Unlike General Motors, Amtrak is a curious entity
    that occupies the twilight between the public and private
    sectors. And the regulations it codevelops govern not the
    automotive industry, but the priority freight railroads must
    give Amtrak’s trains over their own. Whether the Constitution
    permits Congress to delegate such joint regulatory authority to
    Amtrak is the question that confronts us now.
    Section 207 of the Passenger Rail Investment and
    Improvement Act of 2008 empowers Amtrak and the Federal
    Railroad Administration (FRA) to jointly develop
    performance measures to enhance enforcement of the
    statutory priority Amtrak’s passenger rail service has over
    1
    Counsel for the Appellees embraced precisely this position at
    oral argument, albeit with some preliminary hemming and hawing.
    See Oral Arg. 30:20–33:00.
    3
    other trains. The Appellant in this case, the Association of
    American Railroads (AAR), is a trade association whose
    members include the largest freight railroads (known in the
    industry as “Class I” freight railroads), some smaller freight
    railroads, and—as it happens—Amtrak. Compl. ¶ 10, at 4.
    Challenging the statutory scheme as unconstitutional, AAR
    brought suit on behalf of its Class I members against the four
    Appellees—the Department of Transportation, its Secretary,
    the FRA, and its Administrator (collectively, the
    “government”). Id. ¶¶ 14–17, at 6–7. We conclude § 207
    constitutes an unlawful delegation of regulatory power to a
    private entity.
    I
    A
    To reinvigorate a national passenger rail system that had,
    by mid-century, grown moribund and unprofitable, Congress
    passed the Rail Passenger Service Act of 1970, Pub. L. No.
    91-518, 
    84 Stat. 1327
    . See Nat’l R.R. Corp. v. Atchison,
    Topeka & Santa Fe Ry. Co., 
    470 U.S. 451
    , 453–54 (1985).
    Most prominently, the legislation created the passenger rail
    corporation now known as Amtrak, which would “employ[]
    innovative operating and marketing concepts so as to fully
    develop the potential of modern rail service in meeting the
    Nation’s intercity passenger transportation requirements.”
    Rail Passenger Service Act, § 301, 84 Stat. at 1330. The act
    also made railroad companies languishing under the prior
    regime an offer they could not refuse: if these companies
    consented to certain conditions, such as permitting Amtrak to
    use their tracks and other facilities, they could shed their
    cumbersome common carrier obligation to offer intercity
    passenger service. See Nat’l R.R. Corp., 
    470 U.S. at
    455–56.
    4
    Pursuant to statute, Amtrak negotiates these arrangements
    with individual railroads, the terms of which are enshrined in
    Operating Agreements. 2 See 
    49 U.S.C. § 24308
    (a). Today,
    freight railroads own roughly 97% of the track over which
    Amtrak runs its passenger service.
    Naturally, sharing tracks can cause coordination
    problems, which is why Congress has prescribed that, absent
    an emergency, Amtrak’s passenger rail “has preference over
    freight transportation in using a rail line, junction, or
    crossing.” 
    Id.
     § 24308(c). More recently, this same concern
    prompted enactment of the Passenger Rail Investment and
    Improvement Act of 2008 (“PRIIA”), Pub. L. No. 110-432,
    Div. B, 
    122 Stat. 4848
    , 4907. At issue in this case is the
    PRIIA’s § 207, which directs the FRA and Amtrak to
    “jointly . . . develop new or improve existing metrics and
    minimum standards for measuring the performance and
    service quality of intercity passenger train operations,
    including cost recovery, on-time performance and minutes of
    delay, ridership, on-board services, stations, facilities,
    equipment, and other services.” PRIIA § 207(a), 
    49 U.S.C. § 24101
     (note). If Amtrak and the FRA disagree about the
    composition of these “metrics and standards,” either “may
    petition the Surface Transportation Board to appoint an
    arbitrator to assist the parties in resolving their disputes
    through binding arbitration.” 
    Id.
     § 207(d), 
    49 U.S.C. § 24101
    (note). “To the extent practicable,” Amtrak and its host rail
    carriers must incorporate the metrics and standards into their
    Operating Agreements. 
    Id.
     § 207(c), 
    49 U.S.C. § 24101
    (note).
    2
    If the parties cannot reach agreement, the Surface
    Transportation Board (STB) will “order that the facilities be made
    available and the services provided to Amtrak” and “prescribe
    reasonable terms and compensation.” 
    49 U.S.C. § 24308
    (a).
    5
    Though § 207 provides the means for devising the
    metrics and standards, § 213 is the enforcement mechanism. If
    the “on-time performance” or “service quality” of any
    intercity passenger train proves inadequate under the metrics
    and standards for two consecutive quarters, the STB may
    launch an investigation “to determine whether and to what
    extent delays or failure to achieve minimum standards are due
    to causes that could reasonably be addressed by a rail carrier
    over whose tracks the intercity passenger train operates or
    reasonably addressed by Amtrak or other intercity passenger
    rail operators.” PRIIA § 213(a), 
    49 U.S.C. § 24308
    (f)(1).
    Similarly, if “Amtrak, an intercity passenger rail operator, a
    host freight railroad over which Amtrak operates, or an entity
    for which Amtrak operates intercity passenger rail service”
    files a complaint, the STB “shall” initiate such an
    investigation. 
    Id.
     (emphasis added). Should the STB
    determine the failure to satisfy the metrics and standards is
    “attributable to a rail carrier’s failure to provide preference to
    Amtrak over freight transportation as required,” it may award
    damages or other relief against the offending host rail carrier.
    
    Id.
     § 24308(f)(2).
    B
    Following § 207’s mandate, the FRA and Amtrak jointly
    drafted proposed metrics and standards, which they submitted
    to public comment on March 13, 2009. See Metrics and
    Standards for Intercity Passenger Rail Service Under Section
    207 of Public Law 110-432, 
    74 Fed. Reg. 10,983
     (Mar. 13,
    2009). The proposal attracted criticism, with much vitriol
    directed at three metrics formulated to measure on-time
    performance: “effective speed” (the ratio of route’s distance to
    the average time required to travel it), “endpoint on-time
    6
    performance” (the portion of a route’s trains that arrive on
    schedule), and “all-stations on-time performance” (the degree
    to which trains arrive on time at each station along the route).
    AAR, among others, derided these metrics as “unrealistic”
    and worried that certain aspects would create “an excessive
    administrative and financial burden.” The FRA responded to
    the comments, and a final version of the metrics and standards
    took effect in May 2010. See Metrics and Standards for
    Intercity Passenger Rail Service Under Section 207 of the
    Passenger Rail Investment and Improvement Act of 2008, 
    75 Fed. Reg. 26,839
     (May 11, 2010).
    AAR filed suit on behalf of its Class I freight railroad
    members, asking the district court to declare § 207 of the
    PRIIA unconstitutional and to vacate the promulgated metrics
    and standards. The complaint asserted two challenges: that
    § 207 unconstitutionally delegates to Amtrak the authority to
    regulate other private entities; and that empowering Amtrak to
    regulate its competitors violates the Fifth Amendment’s Due
    Process Clause. Compl. ¶¶ 47–54, at 16–17. The district court
    rejected these arguments, granting summary judgment to the
    government and denying it to AAR. See AAR v. Dep’t of
    Transp., 
    865 F. Supp. 2d 22
    , 35 (D.D.C. 2012). AAR renews
    these constitutional claims on appeal.
    II
    AAR’s argument takes the following form: Delegating
    regulatory authority to a private entity is unconstitutional.
    Amtrak is a private entity. Ergo, § 207 is unconstitutional.
    This proposed syllogism is susceptible, however, to attacks on
    both its validity and soundness. In other words, does the
    conclusion actually follow from the premises? And, if it does,
    are both premises true? Our discussion follows the same path.
    7
    A
    We open our discussion with a principle upon which both
    sides agree: Federal lawmakers cannot delegate regulatory
    authority to a private entity. To do so would be “legislative
    delegation in its most obnoxious form.” Carter v. Carter Coal
    Co., 
    298 U.S. 238
    , 311 (1936). This constitutional prohibition
    is the lesser-known cousin of the doctrine that Congress
    cannot delegate its legislative function to an agency of the
    Executive Branch. See U.S. CONST. art. I, § 1 (“All legislative
    Powers herein granted shall be vested in a Congress of the
    United States . . . .”); see A.L.A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v.
    United States, 
    295 U.S. 495
    , 529 (1935). This latter
    proposition finds scarce practical application, however,
    because “no statute can be entirely precise,” meaning “some
    judgments, even some judgments involving policy
    considerations, must be left to the officers executing the law
    and to the judges applying it.” Mistretta v. United States, 
    488 U.S. 361
    , 415 (1989) (Scalia, J., dissenting). All that is
    required then to legitimate a delegation to a government
    agency is for Congress to prescribe an intelligible principle
    governing the statute’s enforcement. See J.W. Hampton, Jr., &
    Co. v. United States, 
    276 U.S. 394
    , 409 (1928).
    Not so, however, in the case of private entities to whom
    the Constitution commits no executive power. Although
    objections to delegations are “typically presented in the
    context of a transfer of legislative authority from the Congress
    to agencies,” we have reaffirmed that “the difficulties sparked
    by such allocations are even more prevalent in the context of
    agency delegations to private individuals.” Nat’l Ass’n of
    Regulatory Util. Comm’rs v. FCC (“NARUC”), 
    737 F.2d
                                     8
    1095, 1143 (D.C. Cir. 1984) (per curiam). 3 Even an
    intelligible principle cannot rescue a statute empowering
    private parties to wield regulatory authority. Such entities
    may, however, help a government agency make its regulatory
    decisions, for “[t]he Constitution has never been regarded as
    denying to the Congress the necessary resources of flexibility
    and practicality” that such schemes facilitate. Pan. Ref. Co. v.
    Ryan, 
    293 U.S. 388
    , 421 (1935). Yet precisely how much
    involvement may a private entity have in the administrative
    process before its advisory role trespasses into an
    unconstitutional delegation? Discerning that line is the task at
    hand.
    Preliminarily, we note the Supreme Court has never
    approved a regulatory scheme that so drastically empowers a
    private entity in the way § 207 empowers Amtrak. True, § 207
    has a passing resemblance to the humbler statutory
    frameworks in Currin v. Wallace, 
    306 U.S. 1
     (1939), and
    Sunshine Anthracite Coal Co. v. Adkins, 
    310 U.S. 381
     (1940).
    In Currin Congress circumscribed its delegations of
    3
    At least one commentator has suggested that the “doctrine
    forbidding delegation of public power to private groups is, in fact,
    rooted in a prohibition against self-interested regulation that sounds
    more in the Due Process Clause than in the separation of powers.”
    A. Michael Froomkin, Wrong Turn in Cyberspace: Using ICANN
    To Route Around the APA and the Constitution, 50 DUKE L.J. 17,
    153 (2000). Carter Coal offers some textual support for this
    position, describing the impermissible delegation there as “clearly a
    denial of rights safeguarded by the due process clause of the Fifth
    Amendment.” 
    298 U.S. at 311
    . While the distinction evokes
    scholarly interest, neither party before us makes this point, and our
    own precedent describes the problem as one of unconstitutional
    delegation. See NARUC, 737 F.2d at 1143 n.41. And, in any event,
    neither court nor scholar has suggested a change in the label would
    effect a change in the inquiry.
    9
    administrative authority—in that case, by requiring two thirds
    of regulated industry members to approve an agency’s new
    regulations before they took effect. See 
    306 U.S. at 6, 15
    .
    Adkins, meanwhile, affirmed a modest principle: Congress
    may formalize the role of private parties in proposing
    regulations so long as that role is merely “as an aid” to a
    government agency that retains the discretion to “approve[],
    disapprove[], or modif[y]” them. 
    310 U.S. at 388
    . Like the
    private parties in Currin, Amtrak has an effective veto over
    regulations developed by the FRA. And like those in Adkins,
    Amtrak has a role in filling the content of regulations. But the
    similarities end there. The industries in Currin did not craft
    the regulations, while Adkins involved no private check on an
    agency’s regulatory authority. 4 Even more damningly, the
    agency in Adkins could unilaterally change regulations
    proposed to it by private parties, whereas Amtrak enjoys
    authority equal to the FRA. Should the FRA prefer an
    alternative to Amtrak’s proposed metrics and standards, § 207
    leaves it impotent to choose its version without Amtrak’s
    permission. No case prefigures the unprecedented regulatory
    powers delegated to Amtrak. 5
    4
    For what it is worth, Currin also involved the collective
    participation of two thirds of industry members, and the regulations
    in Adkins arose from district boards comprising multiple members of
    the regulated industry. Neither upheld a statute that favored a single
    firm over all its market rivals.
    5
    The government also cites various decisions from other
    Circuits that purportedly support its position. All are
    distinguishable. Several upheld schemes like that in Currin in which
    the effect of regulations was contingent upon the assent of a certain
    portion of the regulated industry. See Ky. Div., Horsemen’s
    Benevolent and Protective Ass’n v. Turfway Park Racing Ass’n, 
    20 F.3d 1406
    , 1416 (6th Cir. 1994); Sequoia Orange Co. v. Yeutter,
    10
    The government also points out that the metrics and
    standards themselves impose no liability. Rather, they define
    the circumstances in which the STB will investigate whether
    infractions are attributable to a freight railroad’s failure to
    meet its preexisting statutory obligation to accord preference
    to Amtrak’s trains. See PRIIA § 213(a), 
    49 U.S.C. § 24308
    (f).
    We are not entirely certain what to make of this argument.
    Taken to its logical extreme, it would preclude all
    preenforcement review of agency rulemaking, so it is probably
    unlikely the government is pressing so immodest a claim. 6 If
    
    973 F.2d 752
    , 759 (9th Cir. 1992). The others resemble Adkins
    insofar as they approve structures in which private industry
    members serve in purely advisory or ministerial functions. See
    Pittston Co. v. United States, 
    368 F.3d 385
    , 394–97 (4th Cir. 2004);
    United States v. Frame, 
    885 F.2d 1119
    , 1128–29 (3d Cir. 1989),
    abrogated on other grounds by Glickman v. Wileman Bros. &
    Elliott, Inc., 
    521 U.S. 457
     (1997); Sorrell v. SEC, 
    679 F.2d 1323
    ,
    1325–26 (9th Cir. 1982); First Jersey Sec., Inc. v. Bergen, 
    605 F.2d 690
    , 697 (3d Cir. 1979); Todd & Co. v. SEC, 
    557 F.2d 1008
    ,
    1012–13 (3d Cir. 1977); R.H. Johnson & Co. v. SEC, 
    198 F.2d 690
    ,
    695 (2d Cir. 1952). In none of these cases did a private party stand
    on equal footing with a government agency.
    6
    AAR’s Reply Brief treated this argument as an ordinary
    ripeness challenge. See Br. 18–21. If that is what the government
    intended, then we are not persuaded. As a purely legal question,
    § 207’s constitutionality is appropriate for immediate judicial
    resolution. See Abbott Labs. v. Gardner, 
    387 U.S. 136
    , 149 (1967),
    overruled on other grounds by Califano v. Sanders, 
    430 U.S. 99
    (1977). And depriving AAR of review at this stage would result in
    considerable hardship. See United Christian Scientists v. Christian
    Sci. Bd. of Dirs., First Church of Christ, Scientist, 
    829 F.2d 1152
    ,
    1160 n.29 (D.C. Cir. 1987). The record is replete with affidavits
    from the freight railroads describing the immediate actions the
    11
    the point is merely that the STB adds another layer of
    government “oversight” to Amtrak’s exercise of regulatory
    power, this precaution does not alter the analysis. Government
    enforcement power did not save the rulemaking authority of
    the private coal companies in Carter Coal, nor the power of
    private landowners in Washington ex rel. Seattle Title Trust
    Co. v. Roberge, 
    278 U.S. 116
     (1928), to impose a zoning
    restriction on a neighbor’s tract of land. As is often the case in
    administrative law, the metrics and standards lend definite
    regulatory force to an otherwise broad statutory mandate. See,
    e.g., Whitman v. Am. Trucking Ass’ns, 
    531 U.S. 457
    , 465
    (2001). The preference for Amtrak’s traffic may predate the
    PRIIA, but the metrics and standards are what channel its
    enforcement. Certainly the FRA and Amtrak saw things that
    way, responding to one public comment by noting the STB “is
    the primary enforcement body of the standards.” J.A. 63
    (emphasis added). Not only that, § 207 directs “Amtrak and
    its host carriers” to include the metrics and standards in their
    Operating Agreements “[t]o the extent practicable.” PRIIA
    § 207(c), 
    49 U.S.C. § 24101
     (note). The STB’s involvement is
    no safe harbor from AAR’s constitutional challenge to § 207.
    As far as we know, no court has invalidated a scheme like
    § 207’s, but perhaps that is because no parallel exists.
    Unprecedented constitutional questions, after all, lack clear
    and controlling precedent. We nevertheless believe Free
    Enterprise Fund v. Public Co. Accounting Oversight Board,
    
    130 S. Ct. 3138
     (2010), offers guidance. There the Supreme
    Court deemed it a violation of separation of powers to endow
    inferior officers with two layers of good-cause tenure
    metrics and standards have forced them to take. See Decl. of Paul E.
    Ladue ¶¶ 6–9, at 3–5; Decl. of Mark M. Owens ¶ 9, at 4; Decl. of
    Virginia Marie Beck ¶¶ 9–11, at 4–6; Decl. of Peggy Harris ¶¶
    8–14, at 3–5.
    12
    insulating them from removal by the President. See 
    id. at 3164
    . Two principles from that case are particularly resonant.
    To begin with, just because two structural features raise no
    constitutional concerns independently does not mean
    Congress may combine them in a single statute. Free
    Enterprise Fund deemed invalid a regime blending two
    limitations on the President’s removal power that, taken
    separately, were unproblematic: the establishment of
    independent agencies headed by principal officers shielded
    from dismissal without cause, see Humphrey’s Ex’r v. United
    States, 
    295 U.S. 602
    , 629–31 (1935), and the protection of
    certain inferior officers from removal by principal officers
    directly accountable to the President, see Morrison v. Olson,
    
    487 U.S. 654
    , 691–93 (1988). See 
    130 S. Ct. at
    3146–47. So
    even if the government is right that § 207 merely synthesizes
    elements approved by Currin and Adkins, that would be no
    proof of constitutionality.
    As for the second principle, Free Enterprise Fund also
    clarifies that novelty may, in certain circumstances, signal
    unconstitutionality. That double good-cause tenure, for
    example, lacked an antecedent in the history of the
    administrative state was one reason to suspect its legality:
    “Perhaps the most telling indication of the
    severe constitutional problem with the PCAOB
    is the lack of historical precedent for this
    entity. Neither the majority opinion nor the
    PCAOB nor the United States as intervenor has
    located any historical analogues for this novel
    structure. They have not identified any
    independent agency other than the PCAOB that
    is appointed by and removable only for cause
    by another independent agency.”
    13
    Id. at 3159 (quoting Free Enter. Fund v. Pub. Co. Accounting
    Oversight Bd., 
    537 F.3d 667
    , 699 (D.C. Cir. 2008)
    (Kavanaugh, J., dissenting)); accord Nat’l Fed’n of Indep.
    Bus. v. Sebelius, 
    132 S. Ct. 2566
    , 2586 (2012). In defending
    § 207, the government revealingly cites no case—nor have we
    found any—embracing the position that a private entity may
    jointly exercise regulatory power on equal footing with an
    administrative agency. This fact is not trivial. Section 207 is
    as close to the blatantly unconstitutional scheme in Carter
    Coal as we have seen. The government would essentially limit
    Carter Coal to its facts, arguing that “[n]o more is
    constitutionally required” than the government’s “active
    oversight, participation, and assent” in its private partner’s
    rulemaking      decisions.    Appellee’s     Br.    19.   This
    proposition—one we find nowhere in the case law—vitiates
    the principle that private parties must be limited to an
    advisory or subordinate role in the regulatory process.
    To make matters worse, § 207 fails to meet even the
    government’s ad hoc standard. Consider what would have
    happened if Amtrak and the FRA could not have reached an
    agreement on the content of the metrics and standards within
    180 days of the PRIIA’s enactment. Amtrak could have
    “petition[ed] the Surface Transportation Board to appoint an
    arbitrator to assist the parties in resolving their disputes
    through binding arbitration.” PRIIA 207(d), 
    49 U.S.C. § 24101
     (note). And nothing in the statute precludes the
    appointment of a private party as arbitrator. 7 That means it
    7
    The government notes § 207’s arbitration provision does not
    require the arbitrator be a private party. This is irrelevant. “[A]n
    agency can[not] cure an unlawful delegation of legislative power by
    adopting in its discretion a limiting construction of the statute.”
    Whitman, 
    531 U.S. at 472
    . Nor does the canon of constitutional
    14
    would have been entirely possible for metrics and standards to
    go into effect that had not been assented to by a single
    representative of the government. Though that did not in fact
    occur here, § 207’s arbitration provision still polluted the
    rulemaking process over and above the other defects besetting
    the statute. As a formal matter, that the recipients of illicitly
    delegated authority opted not to make use of it is no antidote.
    It is Congress’s decision to delegate that is unconstitutional.
    See Whitman, 
    531 U.S. at 473
    . As a practical matter, the
    FRA’s failure to reach an agreement with Amtrak would have
    meant forfeiting regulatory power to an arbitrator the agency
    would have had no hand in picking. Rather than ensuring
    Amtrak would “function subordinately” to the FRA, Adkins,
    
    310 U.S. at 399
    , this backdrop stacked the deck in favor of
    compromise. Even for government agencies, half an apple is
    better than none at all.
    We remain mindful that the Constitution “contemplates
    that practice will integrate the dispersed powers into a
    workable government.” Youngstown Sheet & Tube Co. v.
    Sawyer, 
    343 U.S. 579
    , 635 (1952) (Jackson, J., concurring).
    But a flexible Constitution must not be so yielding as to
    become twisted. Unless it can be established that Amtrak is an
    organ of the government, therefore, § 207 is an
    unconstitutional delegation of regulatory power to a private
    party.
    B
    avoidance offer a solution. The statute’s text precludes the
    government’s suggestion that we construe the open-ended language
    “an arbitrator” to include only federal entities. The constitutional
    avoidance canon is an interpretive aid, not an invitation to rewrite
    statutes to satisfy constitutional strictures. Reno v. ACLU, 
    521 U.S. 844
    , 884–85 (1997).
    15
    Now the crucial question: is Amtrak indeed a private
    corporation? If not—if it is just one more government
    agency—then the regulatory power it wields under § 207 is of
    no constitutional moment.
    Many of the details of Amtrak’s makeup support the
    government’s position that it is not a private entity of the sort
    described in Carter Coal. Amtrak’s Board of Directors
    includes the Secretary of Transportation (or his designee),
    seven other presidential appointees, and the President of
    Amtrak. See 
    49 U.S.C. § 24302
    (a). The President of
    Amtrak—the one Board member not appointed by the
    President of the United States—is in turn selected by the eight
    other members of the Board. See 
    id.
     § 24303(a). Amtrak is
    also subject to the Freedom of Information Act. See id.
    § 24301(e). Amtrak’s equity structure is similarly suggestive.
    As of September 30, 2011, four common stockholders owned
    9,385,694 outstanding shares, which they acquired from the
    four railroads whose intercity passenger service Amtrak
    assumed in 1971. BDO USA, LLP, NATIONAL RAILROAD
    PASSENGER CORPORATION AND SUBSIDIARIES (AMTRAK)
    CONSOLIDATED FINANCIAL STATEMENTS: YEARS ENDED
    SEPTEMBER 30, 2011 AND 2010, at 18 (2011) (J.A. 351). At
    the same time, however, the federal government owned all
    109,396,994 shares of Amtrak’s preferred stock, each share of
    which is convertible into 10 shares of common stock. Id. at 17
    (J.A. 350). And, all that stands between Amtrak and financial
    ruin is congressional largesse. See id. at 6 (J.A. 339).
    That being said, Amtrak’s legislative origins are not
    determinative of its constitutional status. Congress’s power to
    charter private corporations was recognized early in our
    nation’s history. See McCulloch v. Maryland, 17 U.S. (4
    16
    Wheat.) 316, 409 (1819). And, as far as Congress was
    concerned, that is exactly what it was doing when it created
    Amtrak. As Congress explained it, Amtrak “shall be operated
    and managed as a for-profit corporation” and “is not a
    department, agency, or instrumentality of the United States
    Government.” 
    49 U.S.C. § 24301
    (a). We have previously
    taken Congress at its word and relied on this declaration in
    deciding whether the False Claims Act applies to Amtrak. See
    United States ex rel. Totten v. Bombardier Corp., 
    380 F.3d 488
    , 490 (D.C. Cir. 2004) (“Amtrak is not the Government.”);
    
    id. at 491
     (“Amtrak is Not the Government.”); 
    id. at 502
    (“Amtrak is not the Government.”). Amtrak agrees: “The
    National Railroad Passenger Corporation, also known as
    Amtrak, is not a government agency or establishment [but] a
    private corporation operated for profit.” NAT’L R.R.
    PASSENGER CORP., FREEDOM OF INFORMATION ACT
    HANDBOOK 1 (2008). And, somewhat tellingly, Amtrak’s
    website is www.amtrak.com—not www.amtrak.gov.
    How to decide? Since, in support of its claim that Amtrak
    is a public entity, the government looks past labels to how the
    corporation functions, it is worth examining what functional
    purposes the public-private distinction serves when it comes
    to delegating regulatory power. We identify two of particular
    importance. First, delegating the government’s powers to
    private parties saps our political system of democratic
    accountability. See Mich. Gaming Opposition v. Kempthorne,
    
    525 F.3d 23
    , 34 (D.C. Cir. 2008) (Brown, J., dissenting in
    part). This threat is particularly dangerous where both
    Congress and the Executive can deflect blame for unpopular
    policies by attributing them to the choices of a private entity.
    See NARUC, 737 F.2d at 1143 n.41; cf. New York v. United
    States, 
    505 U.S. 144
    , 169 (1992) (“[W]here the Federal
    Government directs the States to regulate, it may be state
    17
    officials who will bear the brunt of public disapproval, while
    the federal officials who devised the regulatory program may
    remain insulated from the electoral ramifications of their
    decision.”). This worry is certainly present in the case of
    § 207, since Congress has expressly forsworn Amtrak’s status
    as a “department, agency, or instrumentality of the United
    States Government.” 
    49 U.S.C. § 24301
    (a)(3). Dislike the
    metrics and standards Amtrak has concocted? It’s not the
    federal government’s fault—Amtrak is a “for-profit
    corporation.” 
    Id.
     § 24301(a)(2).
    Second, fundamental to the public-private distinction in
    the delegation of regulatory authority is the belief that
    disinterested government agencies ostensibly look to the
    public good, not private gain. For this reason, delegations to
    private entities are particularly perilous. Carter Coal
    specifically condemned delegations made not “to an official
    or an official body, presumptively disinterested, but to private
    persons whose interests may be and often are adverse to the
    interests of others in the same business.” 
    298 U.S. at 311
    .
    Partly echoing the Constitution’s guarantee of due process,
    this principle ensures that regulations are not dictated by those
    who “are not bound by any official duty,” but may instead act
    “for selfish reasons or arbitrarily.” Roberge, 
    278 U.S. at 122
    .
    More recent decisions are also consistent with this view. See
    Pittston Co., 368 F.3d at 398; NARUC, 737 F.2d at 1143–44;
    Sierra Club v. Sigler, 
    695 F.2d 957
    , 962 n.3 (5th Cir. 1983).
    Amtrak may not compete with the freight railroads for
    customers, but it does compete with them for use of their
    scarce track. Like the “power conferred upon the
    majority . . . to regulate the affairs of an unwilling minority”
    in Carter Coal, § 207 grants Amtrak a distinct competitive
    advantage: a hand in limiting the freight railroads’ exercise of
    18
    their property rights over an essential resource. 
    298 U.S. at 311
    .
    Because Amtrak must “be operated and managed as a
    for-profit corporation,” 
    49 U.S.C. § 24301
    (a)(2), the fact that
    the President has appointed the bulk of its Board does nothing
    to exonerate its management from its fiduciary duty to
    maximize company profits. Also consistent with this purpose,
    “Amtrak is encouraged to make agreements with the private
    sector and undertake initiatives that are consistent with good
    business judgment and designed to maximize its revenues and
    minimize Government subsidies.” 
    Id.
     § 24101(d). Yet § 207
    directs Amtrak and its host carriers to incorporate the metrics
    and standards in their Operating Agreements. See id.
    § 24101(c) note. So to summarize: Amtrak must negotiate
    contracts that will maximize its profits; those contracts
    generally must, by law, include certain terms; and Amtrak has
    the power to define those terms. Perverse incentives abound.
    Nothing about the government’s involvement in Amtrak’s
    operations restrains the corporation from devising metrics and
    standards that inure to its own financial benefit rather than the
    common good. And that is the very essence of the
    public-private distinction when a claim of unconstitutional
    delegation arises.
    No discussion of Amtrak’s status as a private or public
    institution would be complete, however, without an
    examination of the Supreme Court’s decision in Lebron v.
    National Railroad Passenger Corp., 
    513 U.S. 374
     (1995). 8
    8
    Strangely, the government’s brief places almost no emphasis
    on Lebron. Perhaps this indicates the government’s agreement with
    AAR’s reading of the case. Whatever the reason for this
    near-silence, we think it important to address the Supreme Court’s
    most explicit discussion of Amtrak’s status.
    19
    There the Court held that Amtrak “is part of the Government
    for purposes of the First Amendment.” 
    Id. at 400
    . Otherwise,
    the majority cautioned, the government could “evade the most
    solemn obligations imposed in the Constitution by simply
    resorting to the corporate form.” 
    Id. at 397
    . What the Court
    did not do in Lebron was conclude that Amtrak counted as
    part of the government for all purposes. On some
    questions—Does the Administrative Procedure Act apply to
    Amtrak? Does Amtrak enjoy sovereign immunity from
    suit?—Congress’s disclaimer of Amtrak’s governmental
    status is dispositive. See 
    id. at 392
    ; Totten, 
    380 F.3d at
    491–92. This makes sense: Congress has the power to waive
    certain governmental privileges, like sovereign immunity, that
    are within its legislative control; but it cannot circumvent the
    Bill of Rights by simply dubbing something private.
    Whether § 207 effects an unconstitutional delegation is a
    constitutional question, not a statutory one. But just because
    Lebron treated Amtrak as a government agency for purposes
    of the First Amendment does not dictate the same result with
    respect to all other constitutional provisions. To view Lebron
    in this way entirely misses the point. In Lebron, viewing
    Amtrak as a strictly private entity would have permitted the
    government to avoid a constitutional prohibition; in this case,
    deeming Amtrak to be just another governmental entity would
    allow the government to ignore a constitutional obligation.
    Just as it is impermissible for Congress to employ the
    corporate form to sidestep the First Amendment, neither may
    it reap the benefits of delegating regulatory authority while
    absolving the federal government of all responsibility for its
    exercise. The federal government cannot have its cake and eat
    it too. In any event, Lebron’s holding was comparatively
    narrow, deciding only that Amtrak is an agency of the United
    States for the purpose of the First Amendment. 
    513 U.S. at
    20
    394. It did not opine on Amtrak’s status with respect to the
    federal government’s structural powers under the
    Constitution—the issue here.
    This distinction is more than academic. When Lebron
    contrasted “the constitutional obligations of Government”
    from “the ‘privileges of the government,’” it was not drawing
    a distinction between questions that are constitutional from
    those that are not. Any “privilege” of the federal government
    must also be anchored in the Constitution. 
    Id. at 399
    . As our
    federal government is one of enumerated powers, the
    Constitution’s structural provisions are the source of
    Congress’s power to act in the first place. See United States v.
    Lopez, 
    514 U.S. 549
    , 552 (1995); THE FEDERALIST NO. 45
    (James Madison). And, generally speaking, these provisions
    authorize action without mandating it. Congress’s power to
    regulate interstate commerce, for example, does not dictate
    the enactment of this or that bill within its proper scope. By
    contrast, individual rights are “affirmative prohibitions” on
    government action that become relevant “only where the
    Government possesses authority to act in the first place.”
    Nat’l Fed’n of Ind. Bus., 
    132 S. Ct. at 2577
    . While often
    phrased in terms of an affirmative prohibition, Congress’s
    inability to delegate government power to private entities is
    really just a function of its constitutional authority not
    extending that far in the first place. In other words, rather than
    proscribing what Congress cannot do, the doctrine defines the
    limits of what Congress can do. And, by designing Amtrak to
    operate as a private corporation—to seek profit on behalf of
    private interests—Congress has elected to deny itself the
    power to delegate it regulatory authority under § 207. Cf.
    Religious Freedom Restoration Act of 1993, 42 U.S.C.
    §§ 2000bb to bb-4 (requiring, beyond what the Constitution
    mandates, that the federal government “not substantially
    21
    burden a person’s exercise of religion even if the burden
    results from a rule of general applicability” unless the
    restriction satisfies strict scrutiny).
    We therefore hold that Amtrak is a private corporation
    with respect to Congress’s power to delegate regulatory
    authority. Though the federal government’s involvement in
    Amtrak is considerable, Congress has both designated it a
    private corporation and instructed that it be managed so as to
    maximize profit. In deciding Amtrak’s status for purposes of
    congressional delegations, these declarations are dispositive.
    Skewed incentives are precisely the danger forestalled by
    restricting delegations to government instrumentalities. And
    as a private entity, Amtrak cannot be granted the regulatory
    power prescribed in § 207.
    III
    We conclude § 207 of the PRIIA impermissibly delegates
    regulatory authority to Amtrak. We need not reach AAR’s
    separate argument that Amtrak’s involvement in developing
    the metrics and standards deprived its members of due
    process. Accordingly, the judgment of the district court is
    Reversed.
    

Document Info

Docket Number: 12-5204

Citation Numbers: 406 U.S. App. D.C. 34, 721 F.3d 666

Filed Date: 7/2/2013

Precedential Status: Precedential

Modified Date: 1/12/2023

Authorities (33)

fed-sec-l-rep-p-97106-first-jersey-securities-inc-a-corporation-of , 605 F.2d 690 ( 1979 )

R. H. Johnson & Co. v. Securities & Exchange Commission , 198 F.2d 690 ( 1952 )

Sierra Club v. James M. Sigler, Etc., Pelican Terminal ... , 695 F.2d 957 ( 1983 )

United States v. L. Robert Frame, Sr. And Vintage Sales ... , 885 F.2d 1119 ( 1989 )

kentucky-division-horsemens-benevolent-protective-association-inc , 20 F.3d 1406 ( 1994 )

TODD AND COMPANY, INC. and Thomas K. Langbein, Petitioners, ... , 557 F.2d 1008 ( 1977 )

Michigan Gambling Opposition v. Kempthorne , 525 F.3d 23 ( 2008 )

A. L. A. Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States , 55 S. Ct. 837 ( 1935 )

Currin v. Wallace , 59 S. Ct. 379 ( 1939 )

Free Enterprise Fund v. Public Co. Accounting Oversight ... , 537 F.3d 667 ( 2008 )

Panama Refining Co. v. Ryan , 55 S. Ct. 241 ( 1935 )

Ronald G. SORRELL, Petitioner, v. SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE ... , 679 F.2d 1323 ( 1982 )

Sequoia Orange Co. v. Clayton Yeutter , 973 F.2d 752 ( 1992 )

United States Ex Rel. Totten v. Bombardier Corp. , 380 F.3d 488 ( 2004 )

Free Enterprise Fund v. Public Company Accounting Oversight ... , 130 S. Ct. 3138 ( 2010 )

Washington Ex Rel. Seattle Title Trust Co. v. Roberge , 49 S. Ct. 50 ( 1928 )

Carter v. Carter Coal Co. , 56 S. Ct. 855 ( 1936 )

Reno v. American Civil Liberties Union , 117 S. Ct. 2329 ( 1997 )

Whitman v. American Trucking Assns., Inc. , 121 S. Ct. 903 ( 2001 )

National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius , 132 S. Ct. 2566 ( 2012 )

View All Authorities »